Sei sulla pagina 1di 67

ECO 120- Macroeconomics

Weekend School #1 8th April 2006 Lecturer: Rod Duncan Previous version of notes: PK Basu

Topics for discussion


Module 1- basic macroeconomic concepts
Income determination, basic macroeconomic theory, investment decision

Module 2- the money market


The Australian financial system, the role of money, the market for money

What will not be discussed


Answers to Assignment #1 (use the CSU forum for this)

Forms of economics
Microeconomics- the study of individual decision-making
Should I go to college or find a job? Should I rob this bank? Why are there so many brands of margarine?

Macroeconomics- the study of the behaviour of large-scale economic variables


What determines output in an economy? What happens when the interest rate rises?

Economics as story-telling
In a story, we have X happens, then Y happens, then Z happens. In an economic story or model, we have X happens which causes Y to happen which causes Z to happen. There is still a sequence and a flow of events, but the causation is stricter in the economic story-telling.

Kobe, the naughty dog

Modelling Kobe
Kobe likes to unmake the bed. Kobe likes treats. We assume that more treats will lead to fewer unmade beds. (Not a very good) Model: Treats Unmaking the bed We can use this model to explain the past or to predict the future.

Elements of a good story


All stories have three parts
1. Beginning- description of how things are initially- the initial equilibrium. 2. Middle- we have a shock to the system, and we have some process to get us to a new equilibrium. 3. End- description of how things are at the new final equilibrium- the story stops.

Equilibrium- a system at rest.

Timeframes in economics
In economics we also talk in terms of three timeframes:
short run- the period just after a shock has occurred where a temporary equilibrium holds. medium run- the period during which some process is pushing the economy to a new long run equilibrium. long run- the economy is now in a permanent equilibrium and stays there until a new shock occurs.

You have to have a solid understanding of the equilibrium and the dynamic process of a model.

What are the big questions?


What drives people to study macroeconomics? They want solutions to problems such as:
Can we avoid fluctuations in the economy? Why do we have inflation? Can we lower the unemployment rate? How can we manage interest rates? Is the foreign trade deficit a problem? [How can we make the economy grow faster?] Not taken up in this class. This class focuses on short-run problems.

Economic output
Gross domestic product- The total market value of all final goods and services produced in a period (usually the year).
Market value- so we use the prices in markets to value things Final- we only value goods in their final form (so we dont count sales of milk to cheesemakers) Goods and services- both count as output

Nominal versus real GDP


We use prices to value output in calculating GDP, but prices change all the time. And over time, the average level of prices generally has risen (inflation).
Nominal GDP: value of output at current prices Real GDP: value of output at some fixed set of prices

Nominal versus real GDP


So how to correct for rising prices over time?
Measure average prices over time (GDP deflator, Consumer Price Index, Producer Price Index, etc) Deflate nominal GDP by the average level of prices to find real GDP Real GDP = Nominal GDP / GDP Deflator

Some Australian economic history


Australian GDP 1950-1995
600 000

500 000

400 000

Million A$

GDP 300 000 GDP Change Real GDP 200 000

100 000

0 1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Business cycle
The economy goes through fluctuations over time. This movement over time is called the business cycle.
Recession: The time over which the economy is shrinking or growing slower than trend Recovery: The time over which the economy is growing more quickly than trend Peak: A temporary maximum in economic activity Trough: A temporary minimum in economic activity.

Australian business cycle


Aust Business Cycle
10 8 6 4 % Ch RGDP 2 0 1950 -2 -4

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Unemployment
To be officially counted as unemployed, you must:
Not currently have a job; and Be actively looking for a job

Labour force- the number of people employed plus those unemployed Unemployment rate
(Number of unemployed)/(Labour force)

Unemployment
Working age population = Labour force + Not in labour force Labour force = Employed + Unemployed

Unemployment
Unemployment over the Business Cycle
12 10 8 6 4 2 0 1965 1968 1971 1974 1977 1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 -2 -4 Unemployment Change in GDP

Percent (%)

Inflation
Inflation is the rate of growth of the average price level over time. But how do we arrive at an average price level?
The Consumer Price Index surveys consumers and derives an average level of prices based on the importance of goods for consumers, ie. a change in the price of housing matters a lot, but a change in the price of Tim Tams does not.

Consumer Price Index


Then the CPI expresses average prices each year relative to a reference year, which is a CPI of 100.
CPIt = (Average prices in year t)/(Average prices in reference year) x 100

Inflation can then be measured as the growth in CPI from the year before:
Inflationt = (CPIt CPIt-1) / CPIt-1

14.0 12.0 10.0 8.0 6.0 4.0

20.0 18.0 16.0

Sep-70 Sep-72 Sep-74 Sep-76 Sep-78 Sep-80 Sep-82 Sep-84 Sep-86 Sep-88 Sep-90 Sep-92 Sep-94 Sep-96 Sep-98 Sep-00 Sep-02 Sep-04

2.0 0.0 -2.0

Inflation

Consumer Price Inflation

Inflation

Calculating GDP
Gross domestic product- The total market value of all final goods and services produced in a period (usually the year). Alternates methods of calculating GDP
Income approach: add up the incomes of all members of the economy Value-added approach: add up the value added to goods at each stage of production Expenditure approach: add up the total spent by all members of the economy

The expenditure approach forms the basis of the AD-AS model.

Expenditure approach
GDP is calculated as the sum of:
Consumption expenditure by households (C) Investment expenditures by businesses (I) Government purchases of goods and services (G) Net spending on exports (Exports Imports) (NX) Aggregate Expenditure: AE = C + I + G + NX

Consumption and savings


We assume consumption (C) depends on households disposable income:
Disposable income YD = (Income Taxes)

The consumption function shows how C changes as YD changes. Household savings (S) is the remainder of disposable income after consumption. The savings function shows how S changes as YD changes.

Consumption function
Consumption is a function of YD or C = C(YD). We assume that this relationship takes a linear (straight-line) form C = a + b YD where a is C when YD is zero and b is the proportion of each new dollar of YD that is consumed. We assume that C is increasing in YD, so 0 < b < 1.

Savings function
Household savings is a function of YD or S = S(YD). We assume S = c + d YD where c is S when YD is zero and d is the proportion of each new dollar of YD that is saved. We assume that S is increasing in YD, so 0 < d < 1. But also households must either consume or save their income, so C + S = YD. This can only be true if c = -a and b +d = 1.

More terms
Average Propensity to Consume (APC) is consumption as a fraction of YD: APC = C / YD Average Propensity to Save (APS) is savings as a fraction of YD: APS = S / YD Since all disposable income is either consumed or saved, we have: APC + APS = 1

More terms
Marginal Propensity to Consume (MPC) is the change in consumption as YD changes: MPC = (Change in C) / (Change in YD) Marginal Propensity to Save (APS) is the change in savings as YD changes: MPS = (Change in S) / (Change in YD) For our linear consumption and savings functions, MPC = b and MPS = d. If YD changes, then consumption and savings must change to use up all the change in YD , so MPC + MPS = 1.

Graphing the functions


When YD = 0, C + S = 0, so at point A, the intercept terms are both just below 2 and of opposite sign. The 45 degree line in the top graph shows the level of YD. At point D, C is equal to YD, so S = 0. MPC = 0.75 is the slope of the C function. MPS = 0.25 is the slope of the S function.

What else determines C?


Household consumption will also depend on:
Household wealth Average price level of goods and services Expectations about the future

Changes in these factors will produce a shift of the whole C and S functions.

Shifts of C and S functions


A rise in household wealth will increase C for every level of YD, so C shifts up. A rise in average prices will lower the real wealth of households and so lower C for every level of YD, so C shifts down.

Exogenous variables
Exogenous variables are variables in a model that are determined outside the model itself, so they appear as constants. For the aggregate expenditure model, we treat as exogenous:
Investment (I) Government consumption (G) Taxes (T) Net Exports (NX)

Aggregate expenditure
In a closed (no foreign trade) economy: AE = C(Y) + I + G In an open economy: AE = C(Y) + I + G + NX Changes in a or the exogenous variables (I, G, T or NX) will shift the AE curve. A change in b will tilt the AE curve. Equilibrium occurs when goods supply, Y, is equal to goods demand, AE.

Equilibrium in the AE model


Supply of goods equals demands of goods (in the closed economy): Y=C+I+G Y = a + mpc(Y T) + I + G (1 mpc)Y = a mpcT + I + G Finally we get:
1 Y [a mpcT I G] 1 mpc

Expenditure multiplier
Imagine the government wishes to affect the economy. One tool available is government consumption, G, or government taxes, T. This is called fiscal policy. Any change in G (G) in our AE model will produce:

1 Y G 1 - mpc

Multiplier
If mpc=0.75, then the multiplier is (1/0.25) or 4, so $1 of new G will produce $4 of new Y. Our multiplier is equal to 1/(1-MPC). Since 0<MPC<1, our multiplier will be greater than 1. The larger is the MPC, the larger is our multiplier.

Deriving aggregate demand


How do average prices affect demand for goods and services?
Wealth effect: higher prices means our assets have less value so people are poorer and consume less. Interest rates: higher prices drive up the demand for money and so drive up interest rates, at higher interest rates, investment falls (see later) Net exports: at higher Australian prices, foreign goods are cheaper, so net exports falls (see later)

As the average price level rises, demand for goods and services should fall, with all else held constant.

Aggregate demand
We would like to have a relationship between the demand for goods and services and the price level. We call this the aggregate demand (AD). The AD curve is downward-sloping in prices.

Shifts of the AD curve


Factors that affect the AE curve will affect the AD curve. For example, if household wealth rose, then C would increase for all levels of disposable income. Demand would be higher for all levels of prices, so the AD curve shifts to the right.
C: household wealth, household expectations about the future I: interest rates, business expectation about the future, technology G and T: changes in fiscal policy NX: the currency exchange rate, change in output in foreign countries

AD and the multiplier


A change in I will shift the AE curve up. This will produce a shift to the right of the AD curve. The shift in the AD curve will be the change in I times the multiplier.

Aggregate supply
Likewise, there must be a relationship between goods supply and the average level of pricesthe aggregate supply (AS) curve. How do prices affect goods supply?
Short-term: Since wages are determined by contracts, wages do not change in the short-term. A rise in prices holding wages fixed means that firms are making higher profits on production, so firms will expand supply of goods. Long-term: Wage contracts will be renegotiated if prices rise. In the long-term, we would expect that there is no relationship between goods supply and prices.

Aggregate supply
There will be a short-run AS curve which is upward-sloping in prices. The long-run AS curve is vertical at the level of potential output, since wages will change proportionately to price changes. What factors will shift the AS curves?
Changes in prices of inputs, like land, capital energy or entrepreneurial skill Changes in technology that affect productivity Changes in taxes, subsidies or laws affecting business productivity

Shift in AD

Shift in AD in the SR
The price level rises, which pushes the AE curve back down to where the AD-AS curves intersect. But output is above the potential rate of output at point C. This means that there is a shortage of labour and will push up wages.

Shift in AD in the LR
In the long-run, workers renegotiate wages based on the higher prices. This raises the cost of production to firm and shifts the short-run AS curve to the left. It is only when we get back to potential output that wages stop rising, at point A.

Investment
Investment refers to the purchase of new goods that are used for future production. Investment can come in the form of machines, buildings, roads or bridges. What determines investment?
Businesses make an investment if they expect the investment to be profitable.

Investment decision-making
How to determine profitability of investment? Example: An investment involves the current cost of investment (I). The investment will pay off with some flow of expected future profits. The future stream of profits is R1 in one years time, R2 in two years time, up to Rn at the nth year when the investment ends. Net Present Value (NPV) = Present Value of Future Profits (PV) Investment (I)

Interest rates
Interest rates are a general term for the percentage return on a dollar for a year:
that you earn from banks for saving that you pay banks for borrowing or investing

For example, the interest rate might be 10%, so if you put $1 in the bank this year, it will become $(1+i) in one years time. Or if you borrow $100 today, you will have to repay $(1+i)100 next year.

Interest Rates
18.00 16.00 14.00 12.00 10.00 8.00 6.00 4.00 2.00 0.00
Jan-70 Jan-73 Jan-76 Jan-79 Jan-82 Jan-85 Jan-88 Jan-91 Jan-94 Jan-97 Jan-00 Jan-03

Bank Interest Rates

Discounting future values


How do we place a value today on $1 in t years time? This is called discounting the future value. One way to think about this question is to ask:
How much would we have to put in the bank now to have $1 in t years time? Money in the bank earns interest at the rate at the rate i, i>0. If I put $1 in the bank today, it will grow to be $(1+ i)1 in one years time, will grow to be $(1+i)(1+i)1 = $(1+i)2 in two years time and will grow to $(1+i)n in n years time.

How much is a future $1?


In order to have $1 next year, we would have to put x in today: $1 = (1+ i) $x x = 1/(1+i) $1 next year is worth 1/(1 + i) today. Since i>0, $1 next year is worth less than $1 today. In order to have $1 in n years time, we would have to put x in today: x = 1/(1+i)n $1 in n years time is worth 1/(1+i)n < 1 today.

Net present value


NPV = R1/(1+i) + R2/(1+ i)2 + + Rn/(1+ i)n I If NPV >=0, then go ahead and make the investment. If NPV < 0, then the investment is not worthwhile. As i rises, the PV of future profits will drop, so the NPV will fall. If we imagine that there are thousands of potential investments to be made, as i rises, fewer of these potential investments will be profitable, and so investment will fall. We expect then that I falls as i rises.

Investment
If we graphed the investment demand for goods and services (I), it would be downward-sloping in i. What can shift the I curve? Factors that affect current and expected future profitability of projects:
New technology Business expectations Business taxes and regulation

Money
Money has three main functions in the economy.
1. Money is a medium of exchange. We use exchange money when we buy/sell to each other. 2. Money is a unit of account. Money is an agreed measure for stating the value of other goods and services. 3. Money is a store of value. Money can be kept under the bed or inside a jar and used to exchange for goods and services in the future.

Official measures of money


M1 is the amount of notes and coins (currency) in circulation plus current deposits with banks. M3 is M1 plus all other bank deposits. Credit cards are not counted as money, since using a credit card is accumulating debt, whereas deposits at a bank can be turned into money without accumulating debt.

Money multiplier
What happens when you take $1 cash to a bank to deposit it?
(1) You deposit the cash in the bank, and the bank creates an account for you with $1 in it.
Money = $1

(2) The bank doesnt keep the cash. Instead the bank has to keep R, called the reserve ratio (0 < R < 1), of the $1 as reserves and then loans out $(1 - R). (3) The person who receives the loan of $(1-R) spends the cash, and the merchant who receives the $(1-R) puts that in his bank. This increases the merchants account by $(1-R).
Money = $1 + $(1-R)

Money multiplier
(4) The second bank keeps $R(1-R) as reserves and loans out $(1-R)(1-R) = $(1-R)2 as new loans. Money = $1 + $(1-R) + $(1-R) 2 +

If this process continues, the value of money created is 1/R = 1 + (1-R) + (1-R)2 + ... So for every $1 floating in the economy in currency, we have $1/R in currency plus deposits in the economy. This ratio m = 1/R is called the simple money multiplier. For every $1 in currency that the government prints, the money supply increases by m.

Equilibrium in the money market


Equilibrium in the money market means supply of money equals demand for money. Supply of money
The supply of money depends on the level of currency in the economy and the money multiplier. The supply of money does not depend on the interest rate.

Demand for money


People require money to make purchases, ie. How much currency is in your pocket?

Demand for money


The higher is income and prices, the greater the amount of money required to make the purchases people will wish to make. But a $1 in your pocket is a $1 not in the bank. In the bank, that $1 would be accumulating interest, but in your pocket, it accumulates no interest. So the interest rate is the price of holding money as currency rather than as a deposit in the bank. So we would expect that as the interest rate rises, people will lower the level of currency that they hold. The demand for money is downward-sloping in the interest rate, i, and increases in income and prices.

Equilibrium in the money market


The supply of money does not depend on the interest rate, so it is vertical. The interest rate is the price of holding wealth as currency, so money demand falls as i rises.

Monetary policy
The government can control the supply of money and thus the interest rate. These actions are called monetary policy. Open market operations are a means of the government controlling the supply of money. The government (in our case the Reserve Bank of Australia or RBA) buys and sells government securities, such as government bonds to control the amount of money in the economy. If the RBA buys a bond with currency, the RBA increases the money supply (by the change in currency times the money multiplier).

Monetary policy
If the RBA sells bonds for currency, it decreases the supply of money. Monetary policy shifts the money supply curve and so changes the equilibrium interest rate.

Resources
There are many resources available to you. Often students hurt themselves by not taking advantage of the resources they have. Books: There are plenty of macroeconomics principles books. If you dont understand Jackson and McIvers coverage, get to a library and read a different textbook. There is also a study guide by Bredon and Curnow referenced in the subject outline. Online: There is an enormous amount of material on the Web. Just use a search engine and look around.

Resources
Forum: Get into a habit of reading the CSU forums once a week. Post questions on the forum and join in the discussion. Official websites: Have a look at the websites for government agencies like the Reserve Bank of Australia or the Australian Bureau of Statistics. CSU help: Student Services at CSU has a lot of help it can provide students with problems- look at http://www.csu.edu.au/division/studserv/.

Tips for preparing for the exam


Practice. Do the problems in the back of the book chapters. Do the problems on the books website. Do the problems in the study guide. Read the question. Read carefully. Answer the question. Dont answer the question you think was asked. Answer the question that actually was asked. Most exam errors happen here. Remember to read the question.

Tips for preparing for the exam


Be sure to answer all of the question. Dont put down too much. Dont provide a whole background of a model unless the question asks for it. If the question asks you to analyse a scenario, go straight into the scenario. Dont put down too little. In an essay question, provide your reasoning and analysis. Draw a relevant graph and talk about the graph. Dont just say Yes.

Final exam tip


Dont panic! Relax and breath. You do not need to write for 3 hours to do well in an economics exam. Often a well-ordered sentence is worth more than 2 pages of semi-coherent babbling. Stop and think about your answer.

Potrebbero piacerti anche