Sei sulla pagina 1di 12

..

J8I

Chapter

13

The Black-Scholes-Merton
SOLUTIONS
Problem 13.1.

Model

TO QUESTIONS

AND PROBLEMS

The Black-Scholes option pricing model assumes that the probability distribution of the stock price in I year (or at any other future time) is lognormal. It assumes that the continuously compounded rate of return on the stock during the year is normally distributed. Problem 13.2. The standard deviation of the percentage price change in time f..t is (5v;Ij where (5.is the
volatility. In this problem (5 = 0.3 and, assuming 252 trading days in one year, f..t = 1/252 = 0.004 so that (5v;Ij

= 0.3vO.004 = 0.019 or 1.9%.

Problem 13.3. The price of an option or other derivative when expressed in terms of the price of the underlying stock is independent of risk preferences. Options therefore have the same value in a risk-neutral world as they do in the real world. We may therefore assume that the world is risk neutral for the purposes of valuing options. This simplifies the analysis. In a riskneutral world all securities have an expected return equal to risk-free interest rate. Also, in a risk-neutral world, the appropriate discount rate to use for expected future cash flows is the risk-free interest rate. Problem 13.4.
In this case So

= 50,

= 50, r = O. I,

(5

= 0.3,

T = 0.25, and =0.2417

dl =

In(50/50) + (0.1 +0.09/2)0.25


0.3vO.25

d2 = d1 - 0.3vO.25

= 0.0917

The European put price is


50N( -0.0917)e-O.l xO.25 - 50N( -0.2417)
X 0.4045

= 50 x 0.4634e-0.lxO.25 - 50
or $2.37.

= 2.37

----

83 Problem 13.5.

In this case we must subtract the present value of the dividend from the stock price before using Black-Scholes. Hence the appropriate value of So is So = 50As before K
1.50e-O.\667xO.1

= 48.52
In this case = 0.0414

= 50, r = 0.1,
d 1=

(J

= 0.3, and T = 0.25.

In(48.52/50) + (0.1 +0.09/2)0.25 0.3VO.25

d2 = d1 - 0.3\1"0.25 = -0.1086 The European put price is


50N(0.1086)e-0.\ xO.25- 48.52N(-0.0414)

= 50 x 0.5432e-0.lxO.25 -48.52
or $3.03. Problem 13.6.

x 0.4835

= 3.03

The implied volatility is the volatility that makes the Black-Scholes price of an option equal to its market price. It is calculated using an iterative procedure. Problem 13.7. In this case J1 = 0.15 and (J

rate of return over a 2-year period with continuous compounding is:


rfo. 'Y

= 0.25.

From equation (13.7) the probability distribution for the

0.15 -

0.252

0.25

'

J2

I.e., (jJ(0.11875,0.1768)

The expected value of the return is 11.875% per annum and the standard deviation is 17.68% per annum. Problem 13.8. (a) The required probability is the probability of the stock price being above $40 in six months' time. Suppose that the stock price in six months is ST InST 0352 (jJ(In38+ (0.16 - ~ )0.5, 0.35v(5) 2

rv

.
84

Chapter 13. The Black-Scholes-Merton I.e.,


InST rv <1>(3.687,0.247)

Model

Since In40 = 3.689, the required probability is J- N

3.689 - 3.687
0.247

From normal distribution tables N(0.008) 0.5032 so that the required probability 0.4968. In general the required probability is N((h). (See Problem 13.22).
(b) In this case the required probability $40 in six months' time. It is

)= =

1- N(0.008) is

is the probability of the stock price being less than

I - 0.4968 Problem 13.9. From equation (13.3):

= 0.5032

aInST rv <1> [InSo + (J.1- - )T, aVT]

')

95% confidence intervals for InST are therefore

and

a-') InSo+ (J.1- -)T 2

- 1.96aVT

a-') InSo + (J.1- -)T 2 95% confidence intervals for ST are therefore

+ J.96aVT

e InSo+(,u-a2/2)T -1.96aVT

and
elnSo+(,u-a2 /2)T + J.96aVT

I.e.
Soe(,u-a2 /2)T - J.96aVT

and
Soe(,u-a2 /2)T + 1.96aVT

Problem 13.10. The statement is misleading in that a certain sum of money, say $ J000, when invested for 10 years in the fund would have realized a return (with annual compounding) of less than 20% per annum. The average of the returns realized in each year is always greater than the return pcr annum (with annual compounding) realized over 10 years. The first is an arithmetic average of the returns In each year; the second is a geometric average of these returns.

.
85

Problem 13.11.
(a) At time t, the expected value oflnST is, from equation (\3.3)
(J-

InS+(,u--)(T-t) 2

In a risk-neutral world the expected value of InSr is therefore: InS + (r - - ) (T - t) 2 Using risk-neutral valuation the value of the security at time tis:
(J-

e-,(T-'j
(b) If: .f

[Ins + (r - ~2 )(T - t)]

= e-,(T-'j [Ins + (r -

~2 )(T - t)]
(J2 . 2

af (J2 -=re-r(T-t) InS+(r--)(T-t) at [ 2


af
e-r(T -t)

-e-r(T-t)(r--

as -

S
e-r(T -t) S2

a2f as2

The left-hand side of the Black Scholes differential equation is

e-r(T-t) rlnS+ r(r[

)(T -t) - (r- 2) + r- ' 2 2 ]


(J(J-

(J-

=re-,(T-'j [Ins+(r-

~2)(T-t)]

= rf
Hence equation (13.16) is satisfied.

.
86 Chapter 13. The Black-Scholes-Merton Model

Problem 13.12.
This problem is related to Problem 12.10. (a) If C(S,t) obtain
') hI + rIm + -(rhl1(l12

I )SII-2 where hI = dh/dt. Substituting intodC/dS = the Black-Scholes and d2C/dS2 equation we differential = hl1(l1I
I)

= h(t, T)SII then dC/dt

= hlSII,

hI1SII-],

= rh

(b) The derivative is worth SII equation is therefore h(T, T) (c) The equation

when t = T. The boundary condition for this differential = 1

h(t, T) = eIO.S(J"211(1I-])+r(II-I)I(T-I)

satisfies the boundary condition since it collapses to h = 1 when t = T. It can also be shown that it satisfies the differential equation in (a). Alternatively we can solve the
differential equation in (a) directly. The differential equation can be written hI 1 - - -r(n-1)--(rl1(n-l) h 2

')

The solution to this is Inh

= [-r(n

where k is a constant. Since Inh =

1 ') -1) - -(;-n(11 -1 )]t +k 2 0 when t = T it follows that

1 ') k ~ [r(n - 1)+ 2:cr-n(n- 1)]T so that 1 1nh = [r(n - 1)+ -cr-n(n - 1)](T- t)
')

or

h(t, T) = eIO.5(J"2n(II-I)+r(n-I)I(T-I)

Problem 13.13. In this case So = 52, K


dl

= 50, r = 0.12, = In(52/50)

cr = 0.30 and T

= 0.25.
=0.5365
.

+(0.12+0.32/2)0.25

0.30JO.25 d2 = dl - 0.30JO.25 = 0.3865

"

87

The price of the European call is


52N(0.5365) - 50e-0.J2xO.25 N(0.3865)

= 52 x 0.7042 = 5.06
or $5.06. Problem 13.14. In this case So = 69, K
d 1=

50e-0.03 x 0.6504

= 70, r = 0.05,

<J = 0.35 and T

= 0.5.
= 0.1666

In(69/70) + (0.05 + 0.352/2) x 0.5 0.35J63

d2 = dl -0.35J<f5 = -0.0809
The price of the European put is
- 69N( -0.1666) 70e-0.025 x 0.5323 - 69 x 004338 = 70e-0.05XO.5N(0.0809)

= 6040
or $6040.

Problem 13.15.
Using the notation of Section 13.12, DJ = D2 = 1, K(l - e-r(T-t2)) 1.07, and K( 1 - e-r(t2-tl)) = 65( 1- e-o.J XO.25)= 1.60. Since
Dl <K(I-e-r(T-t2))

= 65(1

- e-0.JXO.J667) =

and D2 < K(1- e-r(t2-tl)) It is never optimal to exercise the call option early. DerivaGem shows that the value of the option is 10.94. Problem 13.16. In the case c = 2.5, So = 15, K = 13, T = 0.25, r = 0.05. The implied volatility must be calculated using an iterative procedure. A volatility of 0.2 (or 20% per annum) gives c = 2.20. A volatility of 0.3 gives c = 2.32. A volatility of 004 gives c = 2.507. A volatility of 0.39 gives c = 20487. By interpolation the

implied volatility is about 0.397 or 39.7% per annum.


.>

.
88

Chapter 13. The Black-Scholes-Merton

Model

Problem 13.17. (a) Since N(x) is the cumulative probability that a variable with a standardized normal distribution wilI be less than x, N' (x) is the probability density function for a standardized normal distribution, that is,
I N'(x) = -e-2 J2ii ,2

(b)

N'(dd =N'(d2+avT-t)

=v5

exp --=- - ad? v~]? - t - -a-(T - t) T


[

d~
2

= N'(d,)exp [-ad,~
Because
d?

- ~a'(T -t)]

-=

In(S/ K) + (r -

a2

/2) (T - t)

avff=t =
Ke-r(T-t)

it follows that
I? exp -ad2VT-t-"2(r(T-t) [

As a result SN'(dd which is the required result. (c) d1 =

= Ke-r(T-I)N'(d2)
0

In ~ + (r+ T) (T - t)
avT - t

InS -InK + (r+


Hence adl

T )(T 0

t)

avT - t 1

as = SaJT -t

Similarly
d?

-=

In S - InK + (r - a,,2) - t) - (T

avT -t
ad2 1 as SavT -t

and

Therefore:
ad)
'>

dd2 as

as -

J.

.
89 (d) c

= SN(dl)

- Ke-r(T -I) N(d2)

ac
From (b):

SN1 (dl) at = at

adl

- rKe-r(T -I) N(d2) - Ke-r(T-I) N' (d2) a(h


.

at

SN'(dI) Hence

= Ke-r(T-I)N'(d2)

Since

ac

-rKe-1 at =

.(T

- I ) N(d2 ) +SN , (dl)

( at

adl -

ad.,
=at )

dl -d2

= a~
a
1~

ad, a{h at at = i(a~) at


-

Hence

(e) From differentiating the BJack-Scholes formula for a call price we obtain

ac a at = -rKe-r(T-I)N(d2) -SN'(d,) 1JT-t

=N (d I ) +SN' (d I ) adl -Ke-r(T-t)N' as as


From the results in (b) and (c) it follows that ( ) as = N d I

ac

(d7 )

ad2

- dS

ac

(f) Differentiating the result in (e) and using the result in (c), we obtain
a2c

aS2

= N' (d I )
=N'(dl)

adl as Sa

From the results in (d) and (e)

T- t

- +rS-

ac at

ac 1 7 7 a2c as + -a-S-- as2 = -rKe 2

a + 2JT=t 1 7 7 , 1 +rSN(dl) + -a-S-N (dJ) 2 Sa JT=t T-t


-r ( T-t)

N (d2) -SN ' (d I )

= r[SN(dl) = rc
formula This shows that the Black-Scholes Black~Scholes differential equation.

- Ke-r(T -f) N(d2)]

for a call option does indeed satisfy the

.
90 Chapter 13. The Black-Scholes-Merton Model
(g) Consider what happens in the formula for c in part (d) as t approaches T. If S > K, dl and d2 tend to infinity and N(dI) and N((h) tend to I. If S < K, dl and d2 tend to zero. It follows that the formula for c tends to max(S - K, 0).

Problem 13.18.
From the Black-Scholes equations

p + So = Ke-rT N( -dJ Because I


-

- SoN( -dl)

+ So

N( -dl)

= N(dl) this is Ke-rT N( -d2) +SoN(dl)

Also: c + Ke-rT = SoN(dl) - Ke-rT N(d2) + Ke-rT Because I - N(d2) = N( -d2), this is also Ke-rT N( -d2) + SoN(dJ) The Black-Scholes equations are therefore consistent with put-call parity.

Rroblem 13.19.

This problem naturally leads on to the material in Chapter 16 on volatility smiles. Using
DerivaGem we obtain the following table of implied volatilities:
Strike Price ($) 45 50 55

12 34.02 32.03 30.45 The option prices are not exactly consistent with Black-Scholes. If they were, the implied volatilities would be all the same. We usually find in practice that low strike price options on a stock have significantly higher implied volatilities than high strike price options on the same stock.

3 37.78 34.15 31.98

Maturity (months) 6 34.99 32.78 30.77

Problem 13.20. Black's approach in effect assumes that the holder of option must decide at time zero whether it is a European option maturing at time tn (the final ex-dividend date) or a European option maturing at time T. In fact the holder of the option has more flexibility than this. The holder

can choose to exercise at time tn if the stock price at that time is above some level but not otherwise. Furthennore, if the option is not exercised at time tn, it can still be exercised at
time T.>

.
91

It appears from this argument that Black's approach understates the true option value. However, the way in which volatility is applied can lead to Black's approach overstating the option value. Black applies the volatility to the option price. The binomial model, as we will see in Chapter 17, applies the volatility to the stock price less the present value of the dividend. This issue is also discussed in Example 13.9. Problem 13.21.
I

With the notation in the text


DI

= D2 = 1.50,

tl

= 0.3333,

t2

= 0.8333,

T = 1.25, r = 0.08 and K = 55

K [1-e-r(T-t2)]

= 55(I-e-O.08xOAI67) = 1.80

Hence
D2 < K [1-e-r(T-t2)]
Also: K [1-e-r(12-IJ)]

= 55(1-e-0.08xO.5)

= 2.16

Hence:
D) < K [1 - e-r(t2-ld] It follows from the conditions established in Section 13.12 that the option should never be

exercised early. The present value of the dividends is


.

1.5e-0.3333xO.08

1.5e-0.8333xO.08

2.864

The option can be valued using the European pricing formula with:
So

= 50 -

2.864

= 47.136,

K=55,

(J

= 0.25, r = 0.08, T = 1.25

dl -

_In(47.136/55)+(0.08+0.252/2)1.25
. - - 00

0.25V1.25 d2 = dl - 0.25v1125 = -0.3340 N(dJ) and the call price is


47.136 x 0.4783 - 55e-0.08x 1.25x 0.3692

54 5

= 0.4783,

N(d2)

= 0.3692
= 4.17

or $4.17.
'>

.
92

Chapter 13. The Black-Scholes-Merton

Model

Problem 13.22. The probability that the call option will be exercised is the probability that ST > K where ST is the stock price at time T. In a risk neutral world /2)T, (JVT] The probability that ST > K is the same as the probability that InST > InK. This is I -N InK -lnSo - (r- (J2/2)T
[
(JVf
]

InST rv ct> So + (r [In

(J2

=N

In (So/ K) + (r - (J2/2)T
[
(JVf
]

= N(d2)
The expected value at time T in a risk neutral world of a derivative security which pays off $100 when ST > K is therefore IOON(d2) From risk neutral valuation the value of the security at time t is
IOOe-rT N(d2)

Problem 13.23.
2 ') If 1= s-_r / 0- then

aI
aS2

s-2r/o-2-1 as = - (J2

2r

a21

al at =0

( )(
(J2

2r

2r
(J2

+1

S-2r/o-2-2

at
I

aI

+r S

aI

2s2 I -2r/o-2 = rI as + 2(J aS2 = rs


.

a2

This shows that the Black-Scholes equation is satisfied. S-2r/o-2 could therefore be the price of a traded security. Problem 13.24. The answer is no. If markets are efficient they have already taken potential dilution into account in determining the stock price. This argument is explained in Business Snapshot 13.3.

93
Problem 13.25.
I

ffhe Black-Scholes price of the option is given by setting So = 50, K = 50, r = 0.05, 0.25, ~nd T = 5. It is 16.252. From an analysis similar to that in Section 13.10 the cost=to the ~ompany of the options is 10 x 16.252= 12.5 10+3 or about $12.5 per option. The total cost is therefore 3 million times this or $37.5 million. If :themarket perceives no benefits from the options the stock price will fall by $3.75.
(j

Potrebbero piacerti anche