Sei sulla pagina 1di 8

Special articles

Indian Economy since 1980


Virtuous Growth or Polarisation?
It is widely believed that India’s economic growth in the 1990s accelerated – in response
to the orthodox economic reforms initiated in 1991 – mainly on account of a faster growth
in the tertiary sector. There is also a growing consensus that (i) the improved growth
since 1980-81 reduced poverty, and (ii) the reforms in the 1990s increased the growth rate
further, without dampening the process of poverty reduction. This study seeks to verify
these propositions. Further, it examines some dimensions of income distribution – a
neglected issue in the recent times – to assess if the developments during the last two
decades led to a diffusion of growth – or a polarisation in the economy.
R NAGARAJ

I trend that appears to have continued after accelerated reforms” [Kelkar 1999:2326,
Introduction the recovery from the 1991 crisis and reform 2329].
[T N Srinivasan, The Financial Times, Thus, the emerging consensus is:
September 27, 1999]. (1) Improved economic growth since in

P
icture the economic discourse in the
early 1980s. There was widespread That the (orthodox) economic reforms 1980-81 has reduced poverty significantly.
gloom about India’s macroeconomic initiated in 1991 have improved economic (2) The growth rate improved as a result
performance – perhaps, best captured in growth with a continued positive effect in of the economic reforms initiated since
the words of Raj Krishna: reducing poverty has made scholars opti- 1991, without affecting the trend decline
mistic that accelerating the growth further in poverty.
A review of the economic development of
will banish poverty very quickly. Partici- (3) Therefore, more reforms – popularly
India in the last three decades reveals an
astonishing fact: a large number of the pating in the same debate, Deepak Lal called the ‘second generation reforms’, or
indicators of development have remained argued: ‘completing the reform agenda’ – will
stuck at very unsatisfactory levels...The ...dispute about the poverty numbers in further improve the growth rate, and re-
stability of numerous parameters would India merely reflects the fact that rapid duce poverty.2
not be a matter of concern but for the fact growth has not occurred or has not been More recently, there is a growing view
that their stable values epitomise a large sustained to make a marked dent on pov-
in popular writings that Indian economy
and a growing mass of unrelieved erty. The stalled reforms have failed to
raise growth rate appreciably. Some esti-
is increasingly driven by services, as the
suffering...For 32 years the rate of growth tertiary sector now accounts for close to
of national income has been stagnating mates that...I have made...show that if the
growth rate rises to 9-10 per cent that one-half of GDP. Therefore, India is per-
around a miserable mean of about 3.5 per
cent. This rate keeps India as low as 71st China has seen, by 2006 the poverty ratio ceived as a post-industrial society – a
in the list of 104 countries ordered accord- can fall from its current rate of over 30 per ‘knowledge’ based economy. Such opti-
ing to the rate of growth of income per cent to just over 5 per cent [Deepak Lal, mism is perhaps largely based on the recent
capita [Raj Krishna 1984:62-63). The Financial Times, October 8, 1999]. spurt in software exports and the perceived
Now, consider the discourse, one and half These views reflect the dramatic change potential of trade in services such as in-
decades later. Intervening in a popular in the professional perception about the formation technology, communications
debate on the development policy, T N Indian economic performance and pros- and entertainment.
Srinivasan illustrated his arguments with pects – especially in the international circles The foregoing views and perceptions
an assessment of India’s recent economic – over the last two decades.1 Vijay Kelkar have considerable significance, both for
performance: also echoed a similar view recently: “There the current policy initiatives in India, as
is, in fact, some evidence that during the well as for the development discourse in
During 1980-90, the rate of growth in-
creased to 5.8 per cent and was exceeded nineties the growth rate in India has shown general. Therefore, there is a need for a
by only eight out of 113 countries. During some acceleration”. He further contended, careful examination of these propositions,
1990-98, the growth rate further increased “As we enter the new century, the economy both for their analytical soundness and
to 6.1 per cent and was exceeded by only stands at the crossroads. It can take either empirical validity.
9 out of 131 countries...Only after the the ‘business as usual’ road which means Whether the reforms – as defined by
growth accelerated in the 1980s, was there continued poverty and the low-growth trap stabilisation and structural adjustment
a significant declining trend in poverty, a or the high road to prosperity through programme, or as popularly called the

Economic and Political Weekly August 5, 2000 2831


‘Washington Consensus’ – result in a that there is no evidence of a positive of causation goes from high initial income
superior economic performance has been association between reforms and growth. inequality to high taxes and from large
seriously questioned in the literature. In addition to growth and poverty, there redistributions to low growth. An alterna-
Dornbusch had warned a decade ago; is a considerable evidence of growing tive argument is that the rich in very unequal
“Stabilisation may be inevitable but is not inequality among countries that have sys- societies have the political and economic
resources to escape taxation by exiting the
a ticket to prosperity...One should not tematically followed the reforms. Grow-
economy with capital flight or by tax
presume that the market automatically ing inter-regional disparities in China after evasion. Thus, demand for redistribution
solves the coordination problems...” market-oriented reforms were initiated in policies with a vanishing tax base may lead
[Dornbusch 1990:42-43]. 1978 is, by now, a well-accepted propo- to large budget deficits.
More recently, there has been consider- sition [Tsuui 1996]. In the context of similar A second channel linking inequality and
able rethinking on the neo-liberal ortho- reforms in the 1980s in Thailand, John macroeconomic performance goes through
doxy (Washington consensus) within the Lewis and Devesh Kapur (1990) had political instability. Income inequality
mainstream economics.3 This is perhaps warned of a growing rural-urban divide. fosters social discontent and unrest. The
best illustrated in the writings of Joseph Quite apart from the question of how the associated threats to property rights, policy
Stiglitz. According to him, reforms affect income distribution, recent volatility and government fragility depress
economic literature has witnessed a re- productive investment, promote capital
The goal of the Washington Consensus flight and ultimately reduce growth [Alisena
was to provide a formula for creating a newed interest on the effects of growth on
inequality, from a variety of analytical 1998:301].
vibrant private sector and stimulate eco-
nomic growth. In retrospect, the policy perspectives. Empirically, it has been found that in the
recommendations were highly risk-averse OECD countries, in the post-war period,
– they were based on the desire to avoid
Bringing Income Distribution
economies with less unequal income dis-
Back In
worst disasters. Although the Washington tribution have performed better.5 Simi-
Consensus provided some of the founda- In the Keynesian literature, income distri- larly, comparing the performance of the
tions for well functioning markets, it was bution is central to the pace and pattern east Asian economies with those of Latin
incomplete and sometimes even mislead- of economic growth in terms of its impli- America, Jeffery Sachs contended, “...high
ing [Stiglitz 1998:30]. cations for aggregate demand. Within the income inequality...[In Latin America]
Empirically, there is little unambiguous mainstream economic discourse, micro- contributes to intense political pressure for
positive association between the reforms economic arguments are increasingly macroeconomic policies to raise income
and economic growth. The 1999 annual brought in to understand how greater of lower income groups, which in turn
report of the World Bank Operation Evalu- equality is conducive to faster economic contributes to bad policy choices and weak
ation Department has reported some star- growth.4 Yet another strand in the recent economic performance” [Sachs 1989:9].
tling facts. In its assessment of the World years, following the public choice theoretic Seen in this background, a near total lack
Bank lending for 28 countries between 1981 literature, has shown how income distri- of interest in how the gains of the improved
and 1997, the annual report came to the bution influences economic growth as it growth in India since the 1980s are dis-
following conclusions. To quote the report, affects voting behaviour in a democracy tributed is surprising.6 Perhaps, it is im-
[Tanzi and Chu 1998]. In this genre of lite- plicitly believed that the problem of ab-
The facts of growth and poverty in the 28
countries between 1981 and 1997 are rature, there are several chains of causa- solute poverty is more acute in India, and
sobering: tion, in which initial level of inequality that a decline in it implies an improvement
– In 40 per cent of the countries, per capita
affects economic outcomes. These are perhaps in income distribution. Since there is a
income either failed to grow or shrank. best described in Alberto Alesina’s words: widespread consensus on the positive
– In 25 per cent, the share of population Several channels imply an inverse rela- effects of growth on poverty reduction
in absolute poverty increased. tionship running from initial income in- over the last quarter century or so, con-
– In 23 per cent, life expectancy declined. equality to growth. A fiscal channel sug- cerns of income distribution seem to have
– In 54 per cent, the people experienced gests that income inequality creates a taken a back seat.
stagnating per capita income, rising pov- demand for redistributive fiscal policy. In The brief discussion above on growth,
erty and declining life expectancy, or a median voter model, the key measure of reforms and inequality – both from ana-
a combination of these events. inequality is the level of income or wealth lytical and comparative economic perspec-
– In 85 per cent, per capita income grew of the median voter relative to the average. tives – provides a meaningful background
1 per cent a year or less in the 1990s. The poorer the median voter, relative to to formulate working hypotheses to exam-
– In 59 per cent, gross savings as a per- the average, the larger the amount of re-
centage of GDP were low (less than 10
ine the recent Indian experience. In light
distribution that a majority of voters will of the foregoing, we will examine the
per cent) or declining. favour. More generally, a large, impover-
– In 67 per cent, investment efficiency following propositions:
ished fraction of the population creates
was less than 10 per cent or declining. – Has GDP, or any of its major compo-
political pressure for redistributive poli-
These findings confirm the view...that the cies. The pressure may take different forms
nents, shown a statistically valid change
battle against poverty is being lost and that in different institutional contexts but it is in its growth rate since 1991?
business as usual will not accomplish the generally felt in both democracies and – How valid is the postulated association
objectives of the development community dictatorships. In fact, in order to survive, between economic growth, poverty and
[World Bank 2000:17]. even dictators cannot totally ignore popu- the policy reform. Does the inverse re-
In a careful assessment of the structural lar demands. Redistributive fiscal polices lationship between growth and poverty
adjustment in Latin America since 1980, lead to high levels of taxation, which reduction hold at the disagregated level?
Agarwal and Sengupta (1999), conclude negatively affects growth. Thus, the chain – How has the improved growth rate since

2832 Economic and Political Weekly August 5, 2000


the 1980s been distributed across rural private corporate sector since the mid- the primary sector as well, at 3.2 per cent
and urban areas, between the organised 1980s, as systematic accounts for this sector per year.
and unorganised sectors, across the are available. Though modest, there is a statistically
major Indian states, and between the In analysing growth rates, we use semi- significant slow down in the growth rate
factors of production in the private log trend analysis; and employ a dummy of the secondary sector, after 1991-92.
corporate sector? variable to test for statistically significant Thus, the widely held view that there has
breaks in the trends. We use as long a time been acceleration in the GDP growth rate
II series as possible to minimise problems since the introduction of the reforms is not
Data Sources and Their caused by the omitted years. Where data statistically correct. The same holds true
Limitations are available for discrete time points, we for the tertiary sector as well. However,
have computed implicit growth rates using since the secondary sector growth rate has
This study mostly uses the National compound growth rate principle. modestly slowed, the tertiary sector has
Accounts Statistics (NAS). Recently a new become the fastest growing sector in the
series of NAS has been introduced with III 1990s – but not because its growth rate
the base year 1993-94, replacing the earlier Findings has improved in that decade, statistically
one with the base year 1980-81. As the new significantly.
series are available only from 1993-94, Trends in GDP A further disaggregation of GDP suggests
and the old series stopped with 1996-97, Table 1 (i) provides estimated growth that none of the industry group (at one digit
we had to use a chain index to convert the rates for GDP, and its main sectors, be- level) show a statistically significant im-
data for the recent years to the old base tween 1980-81 and 1999-2000; and tests provement its growth rate after the reforms.
year. To this extent, the findings report of significance of the dummy variable. However, (i) total manufacturing and
here are tentative. As the data for 1998-99 Evidently, there is no statistically valid (ii) public, social and personal services –
and 1999-2000 are based on quick and break in the series at 1991, implying that, constituting around 30 per cent of GDP
revised estimates respectively, they are so far, on a trend basis, GDP has continued in the 1990s – have witnessed a statistically
subject to revision. Hence our growth to grow since 1991-92 at the same rate as significant slow down since 1991-92.
estimates are tentative on this count also. it did during the previous decade – at
Growth and Poverty Reduction
State domestic product (SDP) data, 5.7 per cent per year.8 This result holds,
though available in time series, have many even when the year 1991-92 is excluded. Figure 1, describes the official estimates
limitations for comparability across states There is no change in the trend growth of poverty levels (right-hand scale) and the
[Nagaraj 1998]. Planning Commission rate between the 1980s and the 1990s for absolute number of persons below the
computes ‘comparable estimates’ of SDP
Table 1(i): Trend Growth Rate of GDP and Its Principal Sectors, 1980-81 to 1999-2000
that are used for the finance commission (Per cent per year)
awards.7 Apparently, these estimates,
though comparable across states, are not Sector 1980-81 to 1980-81 to Dummy Variable
1990-91 1999-2000 Sign Significance
comparable over time. Therefore, in prin-
ciple, it is difficult to be sure, which series Primary 3.4 3.2 - Not significant
Secondary 7.0 6.8 - Significant**
is superior. Thus, it would be useful to Tertiary 6.7 7.1 - Not significant
check if the two series give similar results. GDP 5.6 5.7 - Not significant
However, such a question will remain GDP# 5.6 6.2 + Not significant
hypothetical, as the ‘comparable estimates’ Notes: Data for 1999-2000 represents the revised estimates, released in June 2000.
are not made public. # Excluding 1991-92.
Data on poverty and employment are ** Statistically significant at 99 per cent confidence interval.
Source: NAS, various issues, and the official press releases.
based on the widely used five-yearly sur-
veys conducted by the NSS. We avoided Table 1 (ii): GDP Growth Rates – Disaggregated Trends, 1980-81 to 1999-2000
using the results based on the yearly ‘thin (Per cent per year)
sample’ surveys, which are found to have Industry (1-digit NIC) 1980-81 to 1980-81 to Dummy Variable
a large variance, and hence unreliable. We 1890-91 1999-2000 Sign Significance
have followed the official definition of
1 Agriculture and allied 3.1 3.1 - Not significant
poverty and used the head count ratio. 2 Mining 7.7 5.8 - Not significant
Since the unorganised sector accounts 3 Manufacturing 7.4 7.0 - Significant**
for over 60 per cent of NDP and over 90 3.1 Reg Mfg 8.3 7.7t - Significant
3.2 Unregd Mfg 6.1 5.8t - Significant
per cent of workforce, ‘mixed income’ 4 Electricity, gas and water 8.9 8.3 + Not significant
forms a large share of India’s national 5 Construction 4.6 5.1 + Not significant
income. As mixed income is a composite 6 Trade, hotel and restaurent 6.1 7.3 - Not significant
7 Transport, communication 7.3 6.2 + Not significant
of wage income and property income, it 7.1 Railways 4.1 3.4t - Not Significant
is difficult to study factor incomes system- 8 Finance and real estate 7.4 8.1 + Not significant
8.1 Banking and Insurance 13.0 13.1t + Not significant
atically. Therefore, we examine the distri- 9 Services 6.5 6.2 - Significant
bution of income across broad structural 9.1 Public admin and defense 7.7 6.2t - Significant
categories like rural and urban, organised GDP 5.6 5.7 - Not significant
and unorganised and across regions. τ - These estimates are for the period, 1980-81 to 1997-98, based on the NAS.
However, we study factor incomes in the Source: NAS, Economic Surveys, various issues, and the official press releases.

Economic and Political Weekly August 5, 2000 2833


2834 Economic and Political Weekly August 5, 2000

Figure 1: Poverty in India, 1973-74 to 1993-94 Figure 2: Poverty Ratio


335 60 78
76
No of poor (in million)

330 50 74

PEr cent of poor


325

Per cent of poor


40 72
320 70
315 30 68
310 66
20
64
305
10 62
300 60
295 0 58
1973-74 1977-78 1983 1987-88 1993-94 1972-73 1983 1993-94
Year Year
Number Poverty Ratio Poverty ratio

poverty line (left-hand scale) since 1973-74, reasonable to infer that the suggested inverse and other complementary items, and
for all-India combined for rural and urban relationship between primary sector growth (ii) an increase in ‘overhead’ cost of
areas (Economic Survey, 1998-99). It and poverty reduction in rural India is at best acquiring the same level of nutrition.
shows that the proportion of population a weak one.9 In other words, changes in the cropping
living in poverty has steadily come down As officially reported, if poverty has pattern and the institutional setting in
– from 55 per cent in 1973-74, to 36 per cent indeed declined by about 20 per cent in rural India seem to have wiped out the
in 1993-94. Evidently, the widely believed the two decades after 1973-74, it would be potential benefits of improved – albeit
poverty reduction started in the 1970s, reasonable to expect a steady improvement modest – average consumption growth
quite a few years before the economy got on in average per capita consumption, espe- in value terms.
to the higher growth path after 1980-81. cially of the bottom half of the population. Thus, when measured in terms of nutri-
Thus, Srinivasan’s propositions that pov- Expectedly, as Suryanarayana (2000) has tional status there is, in fact, a definite
erty began to decline only after the growth shown, the monthly per capita consumption evidence of an increase in poverty in India
rate improved and, that the growth accel- expenditure in rural India has increased by (Figure 2). The proportion of the rural
erated in response to the reforms in 1991 32 per cent during the two decades, from population not getting adequate nutrition
– as we have seen above – are not sustainable. the level of Rs 18.40 in 1973-74.
Table 2 (i): Correlation between Levels of
Admittedly, the official estimates for However, on a closer examination, the Poverty and Per Capita SDP across
all-India do suggest an inverse relation- whole process largely appears a statistical Major Indian States
ship between growth and poverty, at least mirage. If one takes a longer period since (No of observations = 14)
since the 1980s. But does it hold across 1960, as Suryanarayana has documented, Year Simple Correlation Rank Correlation
the states? To find it out, we estimated two there was a drop of about 20 per cent in Coefficient Coefficient
kind of correlation: one, between the the average consumption during 1960-65. 1973-74 –0.683* –0.535*
levels, and two, between the growth rates. And, it took over a decade (ending in 1977-78 –0.525* –0.341
This we did for the years since 1973-74 1977-78) to recover this consumption loss. 1983 –0.722* –0.605*
across 13 major states for which data are Nevertheless, during the subsequent 16 1987-88 –0.702* –0.627*
1993-94 –0.596* –0.682*
available – 5 for the levels, and 4 for the year period, between 1977-78 and 1993-94,
growth rates. There is an unambiguous, the average consumption grew annually at * Statistically significant at 95 per cent confidence
level.
statistically significant, inverse relation- 0.9 per cent. More significant, the average
ship between per capita SDP and levels for the bottom half of rural population Table 2 (ii): Correlation between Growth in
of poverty across the states, for all the years increased annually at 1.5 per cent.10 Though Per Capita SDP and Change in Poverty
(Table 2 (i)). But, no such relationship was modest, these trends indeed suggest a Level across Major Indian States
(No of observations = 13)
found between growth in per capita SDP process of growth with redistribution in
and change in poverty for all the four rural India. Change Over Simple Rank
periods (Table 2 (ii)). This is true, both But the growth in per capita consump- the Years Correlation Correlation
Coefficient Coefficient
with simple correlation coefficient, as well tion did not result in any improvement in
as with the rank correlation coefficient. the nutritional status of the poor, mainly 1977-78 over 1973-74 –0.043 –0.007
1983 over 1977-78 –0.254 –0.118
Thus, our finding provides a basis to for the following reasons. 1987-88 over 1983 –0.493 –0.350
question the widely believed virtuous – Since the 1970s, to acquire the same 1993-94 over 1987-88 –0.493 –0.484
association between output growth and level of nutrition, the poor had to sub-
Source: EPWRF (1998), Economic Survey (1998-99)
poverty reduction at a disagregated level. stitute expensive cereal like rice and
However, since the bulk of poverty is wheat for jowar, bajra and other millets Table 2 (iii): Correlation between Growth
in rural areas, with agriculture as the main whose production has fallen sharply in in Per Capita SDP in Primary Sector and
source of livelihood, we estimated the per capita terms. Change in Rural Poverty Level across
Major Indian States
association between growth in SDP per – The decline in the institution of perma- (No of observations = 14)
capita in the primary sector and poverty nent farm servants and an increase in
Change Over Simple Rank
reduction in rural India across the major casualisation of rural workforce resulted the Years Correlation Correlation
Indian states (Table 2 (iii)). The associa- in monetisation of the rural economy.
tion is negative and statistically significant This required (i) a ‘diversification’ of 1987-88 over 1983 –0.738* –0.654*
1993-94 over 1987-88 – 0.273 –0.375
in only one out of two cases. Thus, it seems consumption of the poor to include fuel

2834 Economic and Political Weekly August 5, 2000


Figure 3: Ratio of Rural-Urban Per Capital a sustained growth in per capita income for ration in the quality of employment. Be-
Income nearly two decades since 1980-81, there has tween 1977-78 and 1993-94, the share of
44
been no real improvement in the nutritional – the organised sector in total workforce
urban income

43 status of the poor. Intuitively, one could argue declined from 8.7 per cent to 8.1 per cent;
Per cent of

42 that a large-scale subsidised food distribution – wage employment in the unorganised


41 could have, in principle, improved the nutri- sector went up from 6.6 per cent to 7 per cent;
tional status. In the absence of such a – self-employed in total work force de-
40
programme, perhaps one should look at how clined from 56.5 per cent to 51.7 per
39 the labour market has performed, since it is cent; and,
1970-71 1980-81 1993-94
Years only through gainful employment on a large – casual wage employment went up from
12
12 Ratio of rural-urban per capita income scale that demand for food could go up, and 28.2 per cent to 33.2 per cent.
thus improve the nutritional status of the poor. Some of these changes, in principle, could
Figure 4: Ratio of Unorganised to As Amit Bhaduri rightly reminded us, have improved labour market flexibility.13
Organised Sector NDP Per Capita It is through the labour market that both However, they could have been equally
20 the stimulus to economic growth and the responsible for the changes in the level and
18 process of social justice could largely composition of aggregate demand that
16 operate. And, the extent of increase in could have adversely affected the con-
14 gainful employment opportunities provides sumption growth of the unemployed.14 If
the crucial bridge between economic growth
Per cent

12 the suggested implications for the labour


10 and efficiency on the one hand and social
justice on the other...Economic reforms, market have any value, then the observed
8
no matter labelled ‘capitalist or socialist’ growth process is likely to have been
6
– are bound to falter without enough popular inequalising. In other words, since the
4
2
support, unless they meet this latter test” improved growth since the 1980s did not
[Bhaduri 1996:15]. result in a proportionate increase in em-
0
1970-71 1980-81 1993-94 ployment (and poverty reduction), it is
Years Trends in Employment
12 very likely that the growth has helped only
12 Ratio of unorganised to organised sector NDP
Since the incidence of poverty and those persons, regions, or segments of the
per capita
unemployment as highly correlated, one economy that are already employed or better
Figure 5: Coefficient of Variation of would expect that if poverty has really off. To test this proposition, we now look
SDP Per Capita declined, then it would have reduced at some dimensions of income distribution.
50 - unemployment and underemployment. But
Trends in Income Distribution
Coefficient of variation

40 -
we find is that since 1973-74, there has
been an economywide decline in employ- As in most developing economies, there
30 - ment elasticity of output (Table 3).11 For is no information on personal income
instance, the elasticity for the economy as distribution since over 9/10th of the
20 -
a whole has declined from 0.61 between workforce is in the unorganised sector
10 - 1972-73 and 1977-78, to 0.47 between where the majority of the population is
1987-88 and 1993-94. The fall is more self-employed. As a proxy, the consump-
0- pronounced in the secondary and tertiary tion distribution is widely used. As noted
1995
1992
1989
1986
1983
1980
1977
1974
1971

sectors. Although there has been a modest earlier, there has been a modest improve-
decline in the proportion of population in ment in the per capita consumption of the
Year ending
—– Coefficient of variation of SDP per capita
agriculture since the 1970s, and there has bottom half in rural India in value terms,
been some diversification of rural since 1977-78. But it has not improved
has gone up by 10 percentage points from workforce into non-farm activities espe- their nutritional status mainly as they have
65 per cent in two decades after 1972-73. cially in the 1980s, there is no evidence been compelled to consume costlier cereal
Admittedly, a nutrition-based measure of a sustained reduction in unemployment like wheat and rice, since the output of
of poverty has limitations [Lipton and levels, however measured [Ghose 1999].12 inferior cereals has fallen sharply.
Ravallion 1995]. But considering the prob- On the contrary, there is a distinct deterio- However, there is evidence to suggest
lems of measurement when changes in the
Table 3: Employment Elasticity of Output, by Industry
rural economy and the cereal output mix
significantly affect consumption patterns, 1-Digit Industry Group 1977-78 Over 1983 Over 1987-88 Over 1993-94 Over
it may nevertheless be valuable to know 1972-73 1977-78 1983 1987-88

how a nutrition-based poverty measure has 1 Agriculture 0.54 0.49 0.26 0.54
performed. Therefore, a simple yet robust 2 Mining 0.95 0.67 0.81 0.36
3 Manufacturing 1.05 0.68 0.35 0.39
nutrition based measure perhaps has some 4 Electricity 1.67 0.74 0.74 0.53
merit. This is particularly so, since food 5 Construction 0.35 1.00 3.43 0.01
still accounts for about 80 per cent of the 6 Transport, storage and comm. 0.76 0.92 0.39 0.62
7 Trade, hotel and restaurants 0.76 0.59
consumption basket of the bottom half of 8 Services 0.80 0.90 0.52 0.68
the rural population. 8.1 Services including trade 0.39 0.76
9 Total 0.61 0.55 0.32 0.47
If the above finding is valid, then the
question arises, how is it that in spite of Source: Bhalla (1997:217).

Economic and Political Weekly August 5, 2000 2835


Figure 6: Per Capita SDP of Top and Botton Three States Figure 7: Wages and Profits in Private Corporate Sector
5.4 40

Per cent of gross value added


35
5.2
Log of index values

30
5
25
4.8 20

4.6 15
10
4.4
5
4.2 0

1997
1996
1995
1994
1993
1992
1991
1990
1989
1988
1987
1986
1996
1994
1992
1991
1989
1987
1985
1983
1981

Year Year
Average of top 3 states Average of bottom 3 states Share of wages in GVA Share of PBT in GVA

that the distribution of income measured in GDP in the 1990s, it uses a much greater It is widely believed – especially among the
other structural and institutional categories share of domestic savings and attracts a dis- policy-makers and in the development pro-
has deteriorated over the last two decades. proportionately large attention of policy- fession – that India’s economic performance
Figure 3 shows the rural (nominal) per capita makers. As Figure 7 shows, the share of during the last quarter century or so has been
income as a proportion of urban per capita wages in value added, in current prices, has a virtuous one: growth with poverty reduc-
income. Evidently, the ratio, which improved fallen from about 35 per cent in 1985-86 to tion. Moreover, the economic reforms initi-
in favour of rural India between 1970-71 and about 20 per cent in 1996-97. During the ated since 1991 are believed to have im-
1980-81, deteriorated during the subsequent same period, the profit share (measured by proved the growth rate further, without
14-year period. The per capita rural income profit before tax, after depreciation and in- adversely affecting the trend reduction in
has declined relative to urban per capita terest) has gone up by about 15 percentage poverty. The findings reported in this study
income, from 42 per cent in 1980-81 to 38 points – roughly equal to the fall in the wage question these stylised views of the recent
per cent in 1993-94.15 share. Although such a simplistic comparison economic performance. We found:
A similar comparison of (nominal) per may have analytical limitations, perhaps the (1) There is, at least as yet, no statistically
capita income in the organised and unorgan- sharp changes in factor incomes, in just over significant acceleration in India’s growth
ised sectors is even more revealing (Figure a decade does indicate, however crudely, a rate after 1991-92. This holds excluding
4). Over the decade since 1983, the per distinct change in income distribution in favour 1991-92 as well, the year of external
capita NDP in the unorganised sector as of owners of capital, and against workers.18 payment crisis. Thus, on a trend basis,
a proportion of that in the organised sector In a highly diverse and heterogeneous GDP growth rate between 1991-92 and
has steadily gone down by 3 per cent. This economy like ours, perhaps one can docu- 1999-2000 is the same as it was between
decline is not just because of a faster growth ment many more dimensions of economic 1980-81 and 1990-91.
in employment in that sector, but its output inequality. But perhaps our limited inquiry (2) The secondary sector growth rate
growth has also been slower. does suggest an unambiguous increase in witnessed a modest, statistically signifi-
Another aspect of income distribution in inequality in Indian economy over the last cant, slow down after 1991-92.
a heterogeneous country like India is inter- two decades or so. (3) Contrary to the popular view, there is
regional inequality. This inequality, mea- no statistically significant acceleration in
sured by the coefficient of variation in per IV the growth rate of the tertiary sector in the
capita SDP across the major states, has Conclusions 1990s. On a trend basis, the primary and
nearly doubled in 25 years since 1970-71, the tertiary sectors, like GDP, have grown
from about 0.2 to 0.4 (Figure 5). However, What does all this add up to? Between at the same rates as in the 1980s.
more significantly, the divergence in per 1980-81 and 1999-2000, on a trend basis, (4) As the widely believed decline in
capita income between the top three and the domestic economy has grown annu- poverty started before the growth rate
the bottom three states has widened sharply ally, at about 5.7 per cent. The growth is improved in the 1980s – and the reforms
since 1986-87 (Figure 6). In 1980-81, the likely to have been faster in per capita in 1991 – there is no association between
average per capita SDP of the bottom three terms in the 1990s, when the population the widely believed poverty reduction with
states (Bihar, Orissa and Assam) was 43 growth rate is said to have declined no- the improved growth rate, or with the
per cent of that of the top three states ticeably. The growth is laudable in a economic reforms.
(Punjab, Haryana and Maharashtra). This comparative perspective as well, as (5) There is no statistically significant
ratio fell to 27 per cent in 1995-96. Srinivasan noted. While debt and inflation association between the growth in per capita
Moreover, in absolute terms, the per capita ravaged large parts of the developing world income (SDP) and poverty reduction across
SDP of the bottom three states was lower in the 1980s, India improved its growth the major India states. Further, the corre-
in 1995-96, compared to 1988-89.16 rate, with a greater stability. Moreover, lation between the growth in primary sector
Finally, we look at the distribution of India withstood the 1991 external payment SDP per capita and poverty reduction is
value added between wages and profits in crisis as well as the recent east Asian con- found to be ambiguous. This evidence con-
the private corporate sector.17 Although this tagion, without any slow down in the growth tests the widely held view of an inverse
sector accounts for roughly about a tenth of momentum. relationship between growth and poverty

2836 Economic and Political Weekly August 5, 2000


reduction in India, at a disaggregated level. both from analytical and comparative Interestingly, such an inequalising process
(6) Moreover, the widely believed poverty economic perspectives. There is an in- of economic growth has occurred at a time
reduction is probably a statistical mirage. creasing appreciation – both in theory and when there is a distinct diffusion of political
The nutritional status – a contentious yet experience – that greater equality is con- power towards the erstwhile disenfranchsed
robust measure of poverty – of the average ducive for growth. Further, recent evi- classes and castes, which broadly represent
(as well as that of the bottom half) in rural dence suggests that the economic reforms those left behind in economic development.20
India has not improved at all in the entire have, more often than not, accentuated To quote Pranab Bardhan’s recent assess-
period since the early the 1970s. Recent inequalities since the 1980s across the ment of the political changes in India:
research cited, in fact, suggests that rural developing world. It is with this concern Along with political power drifting from
poverty, measured in terms of nutritional that we looked at some aspects of inequal- the centre to the regions, there is an as-
deficiency, has gone up by 10 percentage ity in India over the last two decades. The sociated drift towards the backward and
points since 1972-73, from 65 per cent. results, though limited to a few dimensions lower castes. This is clearly a sign of demo-
The absence of an association between of the problem, appear quite startling: cratic progression in an unequal society.
growth and poverty reduction across the – The ratio of rural to urban (nominal) The numerical strength and increased
major India states – contrary to much per capita income, which improved assertiveness of some of the historically
popular and scholarly writing – is perhaps during the 1970s, deteriorated during subordinated groups have compelled the
upper classes and castes to form downward
not surprising (or intuitively understand- 14 years after 1980-81.
alliances and brought to the fore political
able), if one looks at the labour market – There is a secular deterioration in the actors from backward communities and
performance. After all, if the growth is ratio of the unorganised to organised regions. These players may not be initiated
poverty reducing, it should then, in prin- (nominal) per capita income since 1982- in the etiquette of parliamentary democ-
ciple, work through a large-scale rural 83. racy and social grace of modernity, but are
employment creation, especially in poorer – Since 1970, there has been a steady quite astute in pursuing the interests of
states, as the unemployed and under- increase in inequality across the major their constituencies (and, of course, their
employed form the bulk of the poor. states, as measured by the coefficient own self interest) [Bardhan 1988:132].
The study shows that while the growth of variation in SDP per capita. If such an iniquitous growth process is not
rate improved since 1980-81, there is no – The ratio of per capita income of the corrected – and corrected quickly – Indian
sustained reduction in unemployment rates, bottom three states, as a proportion of society may have to pay a huge political
however measured. Although employment that of the top three states, has widened price for it.
growth roughly kept pace with the growth significantly since 1986-87. Further, the
in workforce – as has been widely docu- level of per capita SDP of the bottom
Notes
mented – there has been an economywide three states is lower in 1995-96, com- [Following the usual disclaimers, I thank Errol
D’Souza, Veena Mishra, K V Ramaswamy,
decline in employment elasticity of output pared to seven years earlier. C Rammanohar EPW Reddy, S L Shetty and
since the mid-1970s, suggesting that the – In the decade since the mid-1980s, in M H Suryanarayana for their comments and
fruits of higher growth are largely restricted the private corporate sector, the share suggestions on earlier drafts of this study. Jayan
Jose Thomas’s computational assistance is
to those already employed. Further, the of (nominal) gross value added accru- gratefully acknowledged.]
quality of employment has deteriorated ing to labour has steadily declined by 1 Reviewing books on India in the Times Literary
during the 16 years since 1977-78. For about 15 per cent, while that of capital Supplement, Jagdish Bhagwati wrote,
instance, there has been (i) a declining the (profit before tax, after depreciation and “...India’s liberal and outward oriented
economic reforms, began in earnest after the
share of regular wage employment in the interest) has gone up correspondingly. external-payment crisis of 1991, have been
organised sector, (ii) an increase in the These changes in income distribution do accomplished by a sustained increase in a
share of wage employment in the seem to indicate that the growing inequal- growth rate that had remained stuck at a drama-
tically low level of around 3.5 per cent over
unorganised sector, (iii) a decline in self- ity – as in the case of poverty – represent nearly three decades of illiberal and autarkic
employment in rural India, and (iv) an long-term tendencies in India. However, it policies. The 1980s, treated to only a small
increase in casualisation of the workforce. may be reasonable to infer that the increas- dose of such reforms, were already registering
higher growth rates...” (March 31, p 28).
While these changes may have reduced ing market orientation of the economy 2 The meaning of the term, ‘second generation
some of the widely perceived rigidities in since the early the 1980s probably hastened reforms’ is far from clear, except to broadly
mean a continuation of the market-oriented
the industrial labour market, they have not the process of widening of disparities. changes in policies initiated earlier. Reportedly,
resulted in greater labour absorption – as If the above findings and inferences are Sebastian Edwards coined the term in an
anticipated in the mainstream economic valid, then the gains of faster economic unpublished note in 1996 to mean (i) central
bank independence, (ii) budgetary constraint
theory. Considering these, the widely held growth since 1980-81 have been unequally on all levels of government, (iii) creation of
inverse association between growth and shared by different sections of the Indian an efficient civil service, (iv) improvement in
poverty reduction in India, during the last society. Growth has favoured urban India, citizens’ security, and (v) judicial reforms to
strengthen the rule of law.
two decades or so, seems suspect. organised sector, richer states and property 3 This is best illustrated by the deliberations of
In recent years, attention has been mainly owners – against rural India, unorgansed a group constituted by the United Nations “to
focused on the widely believed virtuous sector, poorer states and wage earners. To review some of the key questions that arise
in formulating strategies for development in
effects of growth on poverty reduction, answer the question posed in the title of the contemporary world”, in the forward by
overlooking how the improved growth this study: India’s growth process during Edmond Malinvaud and Amartya Sen
since the 1980s is distributed. Such a neglect the last two decades does not seem to have [Malinvaud et al 1997:v].
4 For a fine set of recent essays on this issue,
of concerns of equity is surprising, since been a virtuous one – it has polarised the see Solimano (1998). Also, see Osmani (1996)
there has been a renewed interest in this economy. It has been a period of growth with for a lucid review of various strands of thought
question in the recent economic discourse, inequality.19 on the relationship between economic growth
and income distribution.

Economic and Political Weekly August 5, 2000 2837


5 There is a large literature on this issue. See public infrastructure investment in absolute S Subramanian (ed), Measurement of
Persson and Tabellini (1994). decline of states like Bihar is being increasingly Inequality and Poverty, Oxford University
6 One could contend that our emphasis on appreciated among the policy-makers. Press, Delhi.
inequality is misplaced since what matters in Recently, Raja Chelliah (1999) advocated a Ghose, Ajit (1999): ‘Current Issues in Employment
India is not so much inequality as much as the special development programme for Bihar. Policy in India’, Economic and Political
need to focus on human development. Since 17 This is based on CMIE data. Weekly, Vol 24, No 36, September 4-10.
there has been a steady improvement in human 18 Roughly during the same period, a similar Kelkar, Vijay (1999): ‘India’s Emerging Economic
development, one could argue for improving pattern is evident in Europe as well. Oliver Challenges’, Economic and Political Weekly,
it further rather than focus on inequality. Such Blanchard (1997) found a steady rise in profit Vol 24, No 33, August 14-20.
a view can be contested both on empirical and share in Europe in the 1980s. I am grateful to Krishna, Raj (1984): ‘Stagnant Parameters’,
analytical considerations. Empirically, Kaushik Basu for this reference. Seminar, January.
improvement in human development across 19 One may nevertheless draw comfort from the Lewis, John and Devesh Kapur (1990): ‘Updating
the Indian states depend on public fact that the observed growth process is fol- a Country Study: Thailand’s Needs and
expenditure, and not on GDP growth [Dutta lowing the Kuznetsian inverted U. Alter- Prospects in 1990s’, World Development,
et al 1997]. Analytically, whether public natively, one may defend the process as being Vol 18, No 10, October.
spending is used for improving human Pareto superior. These arguments are of ques- Lipton, Michael and Martin Ravallion (1995):
development or for providing subsidised tionable validity. Evidence during the last half ‘Poverty and Policy’ in Jere Behrman and
services for the better off would in turn depend a century of development experience does not T N Srinivasan (eds), Handbook of
on income distribution. Therefore, inequality support the Kuznets hypothesis unequivo- Development Economics, Vol 3B, North
would be central to how public resources are cally. Invoking Pareto could be misleading, as Holland, Amsterdam.
raised and the pattern of their spending. it ignores initial income distribution. As Frances Malinvaud, Edmond, et al (1997): Development
7 These estimates are not made public. Uma Stewart had warned, “If a given income dis- Strategy and Management of the Market
Dutta Roy Chaudhary (1993) published these tribution is considered to be wrong, then Economy, Vol 1, Clarendon Press, Oxford.
estimates for the years 1966-76 to 1985-86. As maximising on that may lead to a worse out Nagaraj, R (1998): India’s National Accounts and
the data for more recent years are not available, come than taking a Pareto-inferior decision Balance of Payments, a study done for the
we could not crosscheck our findings with the that leads to a better income distribution. Data Archives committee of the Indian Council
another data source. Welfare conclusions...cannot occur indepen- of Social Science Research, New Delhi.
8 Unless mentioned otherwise, all estimates dently of an assessment of income distribu- Nagaraj, R, A Varoudakis and M-A Veganzones
reported in this study are at constant prices. tion in two situations” [Stewart 1988:286]. (2000): ‘Long-Term Growth Trends and Con-
9 Ahluwalia’s (1978) evidence on the relationship 20 We are aware, our inference, in turn, raises vergence across Indian States’, Journal of Inter-
between rural poverty and agriculture growth many questions. For instance, if political power national Development, Vol 12, No 1, January.
was ambiguous. Recently, Ravallion and Dutt has really shifted in favour of the erstwhile Osmani, S R (1996): ‘Is Income Equality Good
(1999) have sought to address somewhat disenfranchised classes and castes, why have for Growth?’ in Abu Abdullah and Azizur
similar questions. However, they seem to have they not been able to grab a larger share of Rahman (eds), State, Market and Development,
overlooked simple yet robust associations that the domestic output? We have no answer at Oxford University Press, Delhi.
we have reported. the moment, as the question lies outside the Persson, Torstern and Guido Tabellini (1994): ‘Is
10 I gratefully acknowledge M H Suryanarayana scope of the present study. inequality Harmful for Growth? Theory and
for providing these estimates. Evidence’, American Economic Review,
11 There is a sharp fall in the elasticities between References Vol 28.
1983 and 1987-88, and an improvement during Raj, K N (1990): ‘Bridging Rural-Urban Gap’,
the subsequent 5-year period. This is due to Agarwal, Manmohan and Dipankar Sengupta Economic and Political Weekly, January 6.
the severe drought in 1987-88. However, this (1999): ‘Structural Adjustment in Latin America: Ravallion, Martin and Gaurav Datt (1999): When
does not vitiate the long-term decline in the Policies and Performance’, Economic and is Growth Pro-poor? Evidence from the
employment elasticities. Political Weekly, Vol 24, No 44, October 30. Diverse Experiences of India’s States, Policy
12 Undoubtedly, during this period, there has Ahluwalia, Montek S (1978): ‘Rural Poverty in Research Working Paper WPS 2263, World
been a significant growth in real wages in India: 1956-57 to 1973-74’, India: Occasional Bank, Washington, DC.
agriculture, both for men and women. Between Papers, World Bank Staff Working paper Sachs, Jeffrey (1989): ‘Social Conflicts and
1977-78 and 1993-94, real wage rate for men No 279, Washington, DC. Populists Policies in Latin America: Labour
and women rose at 2.9 per cent and 3.1 per Alisena, Alberto (1998): ‘The Political Economy of Relations and Economic Performance’, NBER
cent per year respectively. However, since the Macroeconomic Stabilisations and Income Working Paper No 2897, Cam. Mass.
absolute level of wages are so low that wage Inequality: Myths and Reality’ in Vito Tanzi Solimano, Andres (1998) (ed): Social Inequality:
growth did not enable rural poor to acquire and Ke-young Chu (eds), Income Distribution Values, Growth and the State, Michigan
adequate consumption to come out of poverty. and High Quality Growth, MIT Press, Cam University Press, Ann Arbor.
13 Robert Solow has recently argued that the Massachusetts . Solow, Robert (1998): Work and Welfare,
much discussed employment elasticity with Bardhan, Pranab (1998): Political Economy of Princeton University Press, Princeton.
respect to labour market flexibility may be India, Second edition, Oxford University Press, Stewart, Frances (1988): ‘The Fragile Foundations
modest. To quote him, “...the issue is whether Delhi. of the Neoclassical Approach to Development’,
lower wages, on average, will more or less Bhaduri, Amit (1996): ‘Employment, Labour Market Journal of Development Studies, Vol 25.
automatically provide new jobs...I think it is Flexibility and Economic Liberalisation in India’, Stiglitz, Joseph (1997): More Instruments and
fare to say that the measured responsiveness Indian Journal of Labour Economics, Vol 39, Broader Goals: Moving Toward the Post-
has been disappointedly small” [Solow 1998:30- No 1. Washington Consensus, World Institute for
31]. Bhalla, Sheila (1997): ‘Trends in Poverty, Wages Development Economics Research, Lecture
14 Further, as Bhaduri explained, “...a more flexible and Employment in India’, The Indian Journal No 2.
market permitting lower real (more exactly of Labour Economics, Vol 40, No 2. Suryanarayana, M H (2000): ‘How Real Is the
product) wage rates would induce profit Blanchard, Oliver (1997): ‘The Medium Term’, Secular Decline in Poverty?’, Economic and
maximising firms to produce more through Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, No 2, Political Weekly, Vol 35, No 25, June 17-23.
greater employment, until the diminishing Washington, DC. Tsuui, Kai-yuen (1996): ‘Economic Reforms and
marginal product equals that lower wage rate. Chelliah, Raja J (1999): ‘Economic Reforms Strategy Interprovincial Inequities in China’, Journal
This neo-classical view in which the economic for the Next Decade’, Economic and Political of Development Economics, Vol 50, No 2,
transmission mechanism operates from the Weekly, Vol 24, No 36, September 4-10. August.
‘active’ labour market to the ‘passive’ product Roy Choudhury, Uma Datta (1993): ‘Inter-State Williamson, John (1996): ‘Washington Consensus
market may be contrasted against the and Intra-State Variation in Economic Revisited’ in Louis Emmerij (ed), Economic
‘Keynesian’ view, which claims the opposite. Development and Standard of Living’, Journal and Social Development into the XXI Century,
(Bhaduri 1996:15). of Indian School of Political Economy, Vol 5, Inter-American Development Bank,
15 A decade ago, in a popular lecture, K N Raj No 1, January-March. Washington, DC.
(1990) hinted at the growing rural-urban divide Dornbusch, Rudiger (1991): ‘Policies to Move World Bank (2000): 1999 Annual Review of
– a caution that was largely ignored. from Stabilisation to Growth’, Proceedings of Development Effectiveness, World Bank
16 One of the reasons for it could be the sharp the World Bank Annual Conference on Operations Evaluation Department, The World
fall in public investment – much of which Development Economics, 1990, World Bank, Bank, Washington, DC.
is in infrastructure – as we know it has a Washington, DC.
dampening effect on increase in equality Dutta, Bhaskar, Manoj Panda and Wilima Wadhwa
(Nagaraj et al 2000). Significance of inadequate (1997): ‘Human Development in India’ in

2838 Economic and Political Weekly August 5, 2000

Potrebbero piacerti anche