Sei sulla pagina 1di 178

1

A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS OF THE


ECONOMIC GROWTH OF MALAYSIA AND
THE PHILIPPINES: ITS IMPLICATIONS
FOR THE ROLE OF GOVERNMENT FROM
AN INSTITUTIONAL PERSPECTIVE


By: Dwight B. Perez



2




2010

ABSTRACT
This study was conducted based on the following research questions:

1. What was the economic growth of Malaysia as compared to the Philippines from 1991 to
2007?
2. What were some of the critical economic indicators that contributed to Gross Domestic
Product for both countries?
3. What were the economic policies of both countries during this period?
4..What are the implications of the economic growth for the role of government for both
countries?

The study found and concluded that:
1. The economic growth of Malaysia was much better than the Philippines from 1991 to
2007.
2. The eight critical economic indicators contributed to the economic growth of both
countries; and
3. The economic policies and the role of government were important in promoting
economic growth for both countries wherein Malaysian state emerged as stronger state tin
3

promoting economic growth than the Philippine state which was weaker in developing
its own economy.
In the over-all, the state as an economic institution is an important actor in economic
development. A strong state is one that can penetrate society for changes and reforms while a
weak state is a captive of its oligarchy and is influenced by certain particular classes or interests.
Thus, a strong state can effectively promote economic development. Malaysian had shown
that it is a strong state as shown by its high governance index as well as its impressive economic
progress while the Philippines historically was weak as the state were not able to succeed in
promoting a strong economic growth for the country.

















4






Contents
CHAPTER ONE: INTRODUCTION ........................................................................................................... 7
CONTEXT OF THE PROBLEM ............................................................................................ 7
STATEMENT OF THE PROBLEM/RESEARCH QUESTIONS ....................................... 9
SIGNIFICANCE OF THE STUDY ......................................................................................... 9
ORGANIZATION OF THE STUDY .................................................................................... 10
CHAPTER TWO: REVIEW OF LITERATURE ....................................................................................... 11
LINEAR STAGES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH THEORY .............................................. 11
LONG-TERM ECONOMIC GROWTH .............................................................................. 12
STATE THEORIES OF DEVELOPMENT ......................................................................... 12
INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS AND NEW GROWTH THEORY .............................. 17
THE NATURE OF THE PHILIPPINE STATE AS AN ECONOMIC INSTITUTION .. 19
THE NATURE OF THE MALAYSIAN STATE AS AN ECONOMIC INSTITUTION 23
THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK AND HYPOTHESES .................................................. 24
CHAPTER THREE: METHODS OF DATA COLLECTION AND METHODOLOGY ......................... 26
RESEARCH OBJECTIVES .................................................................................................. 26
HISTORICAL METHOD ...................................................................................................... 27
MIXED RESEARCH METHODS ........................................................................................ 27
MULTIPLE REGRESSION ANALYSIS ............................................................................. 27
Table 1a Variables for Malaysia Regression Model ............................................................ 31
Table 1b Variables for Philippine Regression Model .......................................................... 33
LONG-TERM ECONOMIC GROWTH PROCESS .......................................................... 34
Figure 1 Long-Term Economic Model .................................................................................. 34
DATA GATHERING METHOD .......................................................................................... 35
VALIDITY OF DATA ............................................................................................................ 36
5

ORIGINALITY AND LIMITATIONS ................................................................................. 36
RESEARCH ETHICS ............................................................................................................ 36
CHAPTER FOUR: RESULTS ................................................................................................................... 38
ECONOMIC TRENDS FROM 1990-1994 ........................................................................... 38
Table 2 Economic Trend Analysis for Philippines and Malaysia, 1990-1994................... 39
ECONOMIC TREND FROM 1995-1999 ............................................................................. 39
Table 2b Economic Trend Analysis for Philippines and Malaysia, 1995 - 1999 ............... 40
ECONOMIC TREND FROM 2000-2004 ............................................................................. 41
Table 3 Economic Trend Analysis for Philippines and Malaysia, 2000-2004 ................... 42
ECONOMIC TREND FROM 2005-2007 ............................................................................. 43
Table 4 Economic Trend Analysis for Philippines and Malaysia, 2005-2007 ................... 44
Figure 1b .................................................................................................................................. 45
Gross Domestic Product at Current Prices of Malaysia and the Philippines, 1980-2007 45
LONG-TERM ECONOMIC GROWTH .............................................................................. 46
Table 4b Malaysia Real GDP, Real Gross Capital Stock, and Employment, 1980 to 2007
................................................................................................................................................... 46
Table 4c Philippines Real GDP, Real Gross Capital Stock, and Employment, 1980 to
2007 ........................................................................................................................................... 47
Table 4d Malaysia and Philippines Real GDP, Real Capital Stock, and Employment,
1980 and 2007 .......................................................................................................................... 48
Table 4e Malaysia and Philippines Long-Term Economic Growth Averages from 1980 to
2007 (in percent) ...................................................................................................................... 49
Table 4f Malaysia and Philippines Long-Term Economic Growth Averages by Periods,
1980 to 2007 (in percent) ...................................................................................................... 50
Table 4g Malaysia and Philippines Real Output per Capita, and ...................................... 51
Capital/Labor Ratio, 1980 and 2007 ...................................................................................... 51
Figure 1c Malaysia and the Philippines GDP growth rate trend (annual %) from 1980-
2007 ........................................................................................................................................... 52
COMPETITIVENESS OF MALAYSIA AND THE PHILIPPINES ................................. 53
Table 5 Competitiveness Indicators for Malaysia and Philippines .................................... 53
Table 5b Cost of Doing Business Indicators ......................................................................... 55
Table 5c Doing Business Regulations Measures ................................................................... 56
6

Table 5d Tax Incentives in Malaysia and the Philippines ................................................... 56
CONTRIBUTION OF CRITICAL ECONOMIC INDICATORS ..................................... 57
Table 5e Malaysia Critical Economic Indicators, 1977-2007 (in USD billion) .................. 59
Table 6 Philippines Selected Economic Indicators, 1977 to 2007 (in USD billion) ........... 60
Table 7 Malaysia GDP, Investment, Consumption, Government Expenditures, Balance
of Payments, 1991 to 2007 (in USD billion). .......................................................................... 62
Table 7b Philippines GDP, Investment, Consumption, Government Expenditures,
Balance of Payments, 1991 to 2007 (in USD billions) .......................................................... 63
Table 8 Malaysia Total Reserves, Total Debt Service (% of GNI), Manufacturing Value
Added As % of GDP, 1977 to 2007 ........................................................................................ 64
Table 8b Philippines Total Reserves, Total Debt Service (% of GNI), Manufacturing
Value Added as % of GDP, 1977 to 2007 .............................................................................. 65
Table 9 Malaysia Interest Rates, M1 and M2, Lending Interest Rate, Interest Rate
Spread 1977 to 2007 ............................................................................................................... 67
Table 10 Philippines Real Interest Rate, M1 and M2, Lending Interest Rate, and Interest
Rate Spread, 1977 to 2007 ...................................................................................................... 68
MULTIPLE REGRESSION ANALYSIS ............................................................................. 69
Table 11 Summary of Multiple Regression Results ............................................................. 70
CHAPTER FIVE: ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL POLICIES .............................................................. 71
CHAPTER SIX: CONCLUSIONS ............................................................................................................. 80
INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................................... 80
REPHRASING THE RESEARCH QUESTIONS ............................................................... 83
THE HYPOTHESES AND TEST FOR HYPOTHESES .................................................... 83
CONCLUSION ...................................................................................................................... 111
RECOMMENDATIONS ...................................................................................................... 111
SUGGESTIONS FOR FURTHER STUDIES .................................................................... 113
REFERENCES ......................................................................................................................................... 116
APPENDICES .......................................................................................................................................... 124




7










CHAPTER ONE: INTRODUCTION

CONTEXT OF THE PROBLEM

The Philippines presents a stark example of a state that has failed to effect the kind of socio-
economic change found among the newly industrializing countries of East Asia. However,
despite its weak degree of efficacy, the Philippine state plays an enormously important role in the
creation of wealth. Access to the state apparatus remains the major avenue to private
accumulation.
It is, indeed, paradoxical that a weak state should be a central subject of analysis. Even as it
is often incapable of meeting even the most basic infrastructural needs of the economy, the
Philippine state is central to any comprehensive analysis of the countrys political economy. In
other words, it is necessary to focus analysis on the nature of the Philippine state, and seek
frameworks that would be able to capture fully the dynamics of state-society interactions even in
8

countries such as the Philippines where the state has failed to effect an impressive degree of
socio-economic transformation.
The weak state in the Philippines has failed to provide basic provisions such as employment,
and housing. The countrys population majority are suffering from poverty and homelessness. It
is a cruel kind of underdevelopment that has not changed over the years.
The phenomena of underdevelopment or the existence of a chronic state of underdevelopment
is not only a question of economics or even of quantitative measurement of incomes,
employment, and inequality. Underdevelopment is real. It is real for the Philippines and over two
billion people in the world. It is what Andre Gunder Frank would call, the development of
underdevelopment (Frank 1967). It is a state of dependency towards the help of others who
have the access to wealth and power. Underdevelopment is a state of misery and helplessness in
the Philippines and in all Third World countries. As Dennis Goulet (1971) succinctly put it:
Underdevelopment is shocking: the squalor, disease, unnecessary deaths, and hopelessness of it
all! No man understands if underdevelopment remains for him a mere statistic reflecting low
income, poor housing, premature mortality or underemployment. The most emphatic observer
can speak objectively about underdevelopment only after undergoing, personally or vicariously,
the shock of underdevelopment. This unique culture shock comes to one as he is initiated to
the emotions which prevail in the culture of destitution when a new self-understanding reveals
to them that in their life is neither human nor inevitable (Goulet,1971, p. 23).

Malaysia, on the other hand made good progress in economic development and foreign
investments soared in the country and became one of Asias promising economies. Its
technological, economic as well as institutional backbone as a government became more stable
and organized and was recognized by many international agencies as excellent in governance.
Thus, in this study, Malaysias take-off as an economy as it had overtaken the Philippines will
be evaluated as well as the Philippines failure as a country and government will be analyzed
comparably.
9

STATEMENT OF THE PROBLEM/RESEARCH QUESTIONS
1. What was the economic growth of Malaysia as compared to the Philippines from 1991 to
2007?
2. What were some of the critical economic indicators that contributed to Gross Domestic
Product for both countries?
3. What were the economic policies of both countries during this period?
4 What were the implications of the economic growth for the role of government for both
countries?
SIGNIFICANCE OF THE STUDY

This study is significant because the institutional analysis of Malaysia and the Philippines
under the institutional economics theory is a new research that is important for academicians,
management consultants, economists and businessmen in the Southeast Asia region. It is
important to compare the performance of both countries and evaluate what went wrong and what
went right.
Moreover, it also contributes to the role of the states and institutions in economic
development that by using the state as a conceptual variable in pursuing specific kinds of
economic policies in the Philippines and Malaysia, this study would promote comparative
understanding of the capacity of the third world state in this area.
Furthermore, also, another significance of this study is that by examining state economic
policies and performance in Malaysia and the Philippines, the role of government as an
economic institution, the factors that caused underdevelopment in the Philippines will be
uncovered so that long-term policies can be formulated in order to promote sustainable and
balanced socio-economic development. On the one hand, Malaysias formula for success in its
10

take-off in economic development can also be evaluated in the light of helping the economic
development of other developing countries.
ORGANIZATION OF THE STUDY

The organization and structure of the study is based on the format of the American
Psychological Association (APA). This dissertation is organized and divided into six chapters.
Chapter one discusses the context of the problem, the statement of the problem, hypotheses,
objectives of the study, significance of the study, scope and limitations of the study,
methodology, definition of terms, and the organization of the study. Chapter two discusses the
review of literature of this study as well as the theoretical framework and hypotheses and chapter
three explains the nature of the research methodology and processes used in the study..
Chapter four presents the results and findings of the study, and finally, chapter five presents
the discussion of findings. Finally, chapter six presents the conclusions of the study.
The references and appendices can be found at the end of the text of the study.









11










CHAPTER TWO: REVIEW OF LITERATURE

LINEAR STAGES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH THEORY

The linear stages of economic growth theory was originally conceived by Walt
Rostow (1962) and it viewed economic development as linear starting from the traditional stage
of society which have limited levels of production and productivity and whose economy is
basically agricultural. In the next stage, a society has to make preparations for preconditions for
the take-off.
The linear growth theory were later further developed by Harrod and Domar (Todaro 2000,
pp. 80-83) which later formulated the Harrod-Domar Growth Model which basically
reemphasized the importance of savings, and investment in the development of an economy.
This position of emphasizing technology, and investments in a nations competitive advantage
have also been reiterated by Michael Porter (1990) of Harvard University.
12

LONG-TERM ECONOMIC GROWTH

The long-term economic growth model as explained through the Cobb-Douglas production
function is that output (GDP) is a function of capital, labor, and technology. As such, the long-
term economic growth of a country would depend upon investments and savings in order to
support the capital stock of a country. In addition, labor or employment is also important in
contributing to output especially with the integration of technology which would result to
productivity (Todaro, 2000). The computations as well as the model for the long-term economic
growth as based on the Cobb-Douglas production function can be found in the appendices as
well as in Figure 1.


STATE THEORIES OF DEVELOPMENT

State theories in economic development will also be reviewed as governments also play a
vital role in the development of a country.
As Skocpol writes:
A sudden upsurge of interest in the state has occurred in comparative social science in the
past decade. Whether as an object of investigation or as something invoked to explain outcomes
of interest, the state as an actor or an institution has been highlighted in an extraordinary
outpouring of studies by scholars of diverse theoretical proclivities from all the major disciplines.
The range of topics explored has been very wide. Students of Latin America, Africa, and Asia
have examined the roles of states in instituting comprehensive political reforms, helping to shape
national economic development, and bargaining with multinational corporations (Skocpol 1985,
p. 457).

Thus, there is this renewal of interest about the role of the government in developing the
economy. State is defined by Max Weber (Roth 1968) as compulsory associations claiming
13

control over territories and the people within them. Administrative, legal, extractive, and
coercive organizations are the core of any state. These organizations are variably structured in
different countries, and they may be embedded in some sort of constitutional-representative
system of parliamentary decision making and electoral contests for key executive and legislative
posts (Roth, 1968).
Skocpol (1985) viewed states as organizations which has control over territories and people
and that they may formulate and implement objectives that might not be what the people wants
society and this is called as state autonomy. If there is no independence in the formulation
and implementation of objectives, the state is irrelevant as a player in socio-economic
development.
For Migdal (1988), it is clear that only a strong state can be effective in transforming
society, on the other hand, a weak state is ineffective, and in a sense, it has no relative autonomy
to effect much needed change in a given country. This can be exemplified with the existence of
power elites in a given society which would tend to predominate politics, and economic policies
particularly in many underdeveloped countries such as the Philippines. As Migdal stated:
Capabilities include the capacities to penetrate society, regulate social relationships, extract
resources, and appropriate or use resources in determined ways. Strong states are those with high
capabilities to complete these tasks while weak states are on the low end of a spectrum of
capabilities (Migdal 1988, pp. 4-5)

In another school of thought, Evans (1989) predatory to developmental states continuum is a
heuristic tool in determining the degree of the state to effect socio-economic development. As
Evans (1989) explains:
Some states may extract such large amounts of otherwise investable surplus and provide so
little in the way of collective goods in return that they indeed impede economic
transformation. It seems reasonable to call these states predatory. Zaire might be considered an
archetypal case of such a stateOther states, however, are also able to foster long-term
entrepreneurial perspectives among private elites by increasing incentives to engage in
14

transformative investments, and lowering the risks involved in such investments. They may not
be immune to rent seeking or to using some of the social surplus for the balance, the
consequences of their actions promote rather than impede transformation. They are legitimately
transformation considered as developmental states (Evans 1989, pp. 562-563).

The predatory state is basically one that exploits the countrys resources for the good of a few
and not for the well being of the majority (Evans cited Zaire as classic example of such a state)
while the developmental states are those that utilized the surplus of society for the improvement
of its constituents. Evans theorized that embedded autonomy is the key to a states
developmental effectiveness.
In contrast to capitalist development theories, Althusser (1984) think that states are a captive
of the oligarchy in capitalist countries since the economic base which is controlled by the
oligarchy dictates the policies of the state. As such, he viewed that there can be no relative
autonomy of the state in these countries.
As explained by Althusser, the state is composed of two basic components and these are: 1)
state power, and 2) the state apparatus. The state is a captive of the oligarchy in capitalist
countries even in developing countries like the Philippines.
However, from the Weberian perspective, the capacities of states to promote economic
development is possible and these include societal penetration for development as well as in the
regulation of social relationships. The state can also extract resources and appropriate them in
such a way that it could benefit society as a whole (Migdal 1988, pp. 4-5).
Richard Edward Deeg (1992) in his dissertation entitled, Banks and the State in Germany:
The Critical Role of Subnational Institutions in Economic Governance, argued that the capacity
of the German Banks to influence the decisions of non-financial firms and coordinate the
activities of industry is significantly more circumscribed than is widely assumed in the
comparative political economy literature. The weakening influence of the banks over industry is
15

the result of several factors: the growing competition since the late 1960s between commercial,
cooperative and public savings banks; the growing financial independence of large non-financial
firms; the increasing importance of small and medium-sized firms as customers group for the
banks which has favored savings and cooperative banks as sources of industrial finance; and the
growth of state economic intervention, especially by the federal states. The institutional role of
the banking system in the German political economy is increasingly better characterized as one
of information mediation. In this role banks supply firms, especially small and medium-sized
firms, with an ever wider range of non-financial information and services. The banks and the
state must be understood as increasingly complimentary, not alternative institution for industrial
policymaking.
Deeg further argued that the state played a crucial role in promoting the competitiveness of
local and regional savings and cooperative banks partly in order to limit the economic power of
the large commercial banks. Strong competition among the three banking groups inhibits banks
influence over industry and foster the growth of their information mediation role. His study also
showed the changing role of the banks in the economy and the growing importance of
subnational institutions, including governments, in promoting the economic adaptation of small
and medium-sized firms.
Osman Babikir Ahmed (1990) in his dissertation, The Contribution of Islamic Banking to
Economic Development: The Case of the Sudan, showed that the contribution of Islamic banks
in financing productive projects in development were minimal. The attitude of the Islamic banks
managements, state policies, and the structural rigidities characterizing the Sudanese economy
contributed to this dismal performance. His study also showed that the financial facilities
provided by the commercial banks, and the pattern of allocating these facilities provide evidence
16

that smaller firms in the Sudan are at a disadvantage in terms of type, volume, and conditions of
financing. Thus, commercial banks contributed partly to the smaller business finance gap in the
Sudan. Banks have been highly security-conscious and profit-oriented.
Michael Todaro (1985) viewed that in developed countries the role of the state is important in
expanding economic activity through fiscal and monetary policies and this can be done through
increasing or decreasing the interest rates of money being lent to the private sector and this is so
because of highly efficient organizations that promote money and credit markets (Todaro 1985,
pp. 502-503).
However in less developed countries, markets and financial organizations are not that
organized and usually they are dependent upon other countries as well as they are fragmented.
Todaro states:
Many LDC commercial banks are merely overseas branches of major private banking
institutions in developed countries. Their orientation therefore, like that of multinational
corporations, may be more toward external and less toward internal monetary situations. The
ability of third world governments to regulate the national supply of money is further constrained
by the openness of their economies and by the fact that the accumulation of foreign currency
earnings is a significant but highly variable source of their domestic financial resources (1985, p.
502).

These inefficient and fragmented financial structure disrupt economic development in third
world countries. The funds for loan are also rationed to selected bankable individuals and as
such development is only limited. Todaro writes:
Most important, the commercial banking system of the LDCs restricts its activities almost
exclusively to rationing scarce loanable funds to credit worthy medium and large scale
enterprises in the modern manufacturing sector. Small farmers and indigenous manufacturing
and service sectors must normally seek finance elsewhere-usually through local money lenders
and loan sharks who charge exorbitant rates of interest (1985, p. 503).

As such in most less developed countries, these inefficient rationing of credit as well as the
existence of the underground credit lenders that offers loans to non-bankable borrowers with
17

very high rates of interest undermine the economic development of small businesses in these
countries.







INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS AND NEW GROWTH THEORY

Institutions
The effect of institutions such as the state on economic performance according to Yoshihara
(2004):
Institutions define the incentives and penalty for economic activities. For example, an
effectively enforced tax law determines how much one can retain his earning and how much he
has to pay to the government. If the rate is too high, it is discouraging for private initiative, in
particular risk-taking. If a tax law is enforced with a great deal of discretion, there may be
incentives for cultivating relations with politicians and bureaucrats. If such activity becomes
important for business, national productivity suffers (Yoshihara, 2004, p.6).

Thus, governments as an institution can make things easier for business men by enforcing
taxes that are affordable and reasonable and which promotes them to do business in the country
by giving reasonable rates. As such, productivity can be affected if policy on taxes and other
factors are not right.
In addition, Yoshihara (2004) further writes:

Institutions determine the degree of economic freedom. How free is it to import goods
and services from abroad? How free is it to invest? Does a foreign investor enjoy the same
freedom, or if he does not, to what extent is his investment restricted? Is one discriminated on
the basis of ethnicity? If so, to what extent? Is it free to start business in any areas? Or if it
18

is not, what areas are not free or to what extent is freedom restricted. Institutions answer these
questions (Yoshihara, 2004, p.6).




As such, the degree of economic freedom is also an important factor for businessmen since if
there are many restrictions then this can affect their productivity.







New Growth Theory

According to Cortright (2001), institutions are important in shaping development particularly
the increased in knowledge-based economies. As he explains:
History, institutions and geography all shape the development of knowledge-based economies.
History matters because increasing returns generate positive feedbacks that tend to cause
economies to lock in to particular technologies and locations. Development is in part chaotic
because small events at critical times can have persistent, long term impacts on patterns of
economic activity. Institutions matter because they shape the environment for the production
and employment of new knowledge. Societies that generate and tolerate new ideas, and that
continuously adapt to changing economic and technological circumstances are a precondition to
sustained economic growth. Geography matters because knowledge doesnt move frictionlessly
among economic actors. Important parts of knowledge are tacit, and embedded in the routines of
individuals and organizations in different places (Cortright, 2001, p. ii).

In addition, Cortright (2001) view the new growth theory as one that should emphasize new
knowledge and that the economy should grow because of increasing knowledge. He writes:
New Growth Theory emphasizes that economic growth results from the increasing returns
associated with new knowledge. Knowledge has different properties than other economic goods
(being non-rival, and partly excludable). The ability to grow the economy by increasing
knowledge rather than labor or capital creates opportunities for nearly boundless growth
(Cortright, 2001, p. ii).

19

Thus, the economic development of a country can be supported by increasing the quality of
human capital and promoting new knowledge is an important factor in it.
THE NATURE OF THE PHILIPPINE STATE AS AN ECONOMIC INSTITUTION

The Philippine state as an economic institution will be reviewed in this section as it is the
contention of this study that the problem with the Philippines as an institution is rooted to the
traditions of spoils and patronage that has turned the state bureaucracies into fiefdoms of
particularistic interest mediated by the oligarchy and dominant political families. Under the
Marcos government, the dispensation of these privileges became concentrated, in fact, in a
narrower circle of interests. In a very real sense, therefore the state was a captive of these vested
interest, unable to exercise any significant degree of autonomy for transformative, and economic
projects (Rivera 1994, p. 117).
As such, Rivera argued that the Philippine state was not autonomous from the pre-colonial
period up to the Marcos government since the power elites were influencing state policy-making
in favor of their vested interests.
According to Villacorta (1994), the root of the weakness of the Philippine state is its
incapacity to severe itself from the interests of the affluent class. The dominance of this ruling
class supported the view that the state is not autonomous in a capitalist system. Villacorta states:
At the root of the weakness of the Philippine state is its inability to dissociate itself from the
interests of oligarchy. In the Philippines, the landed elite also dominate the industrial sector. This
oligopolistic control of the economy replicates itself in the political system. Most law-makers
have either come from or have been supported by the landed-capitalist elite. The bureaucracy is
likewise not insulated from these vested interests (Villacorta 1994, p. 67).

Villacorta (1994) also using the findings of the Ateneo Center for Social Policy regarding the
predominance of oligarchs in the Philippine House of Representatives mentioned 25
congressmen owned or partially owned rural banks; 27 were connected with commercial banks;
20

with 17 having insurance businesses; and 28 had investments in holding, management and
investment companies, Villacorta continues:
The career and economic backgrounds of congressmen in the House of Representatives
prior to the May 1992 elections is illustrative of the domination of the economic elite. Of the 200
elected members, 137 were landowners and agricultural businessmenthe congressmen elected
in 1987: 38 congressmen were businessmen prior to their election; 25 were top officials of
corporations and big-business enterprises; 94 congressmen directly owned agricultural and
pasture lands; 36 were major league landlords, owning farmlands and pasturelands worth more
than P1 million; about 53 congressmen were owners or officers of real estate agencies; at least 42
were controlling owners of manufacturing enterprises and factories25 owned or partially
owned rural banks; 27 were connected with commercial banks(Villacorta 1994, p. 76).

As such, Villacorta concluded that because of the elitist background of most congressmen,
the House of Representatives had become the power base of elite agenda.
In addition Buendia (1993) also proposed that also added that colonialism as a major factor
in Philippine underdevelopment. He explains:
Philippine political development has been shaped by its colonial history and postcolonial elitist
political system. As the country is ushered into the 21
st
century. The problems of
underdevelopment remain. These problems are rooted on the unresolved question of nationhood,
skewed concept of public service, alienated political system, and ambivalent political culture.
These problems contributed significantly to the weakness of the countrys political and economic
instiutions(Buendia 1993, p.141).

Thus, Buendia (1993) viewed that the political and economic institutions in the Philippines
are both weak. This is further compounded by post-colonial influences in our state and economic
policies which disrupts the countrys socio-economic development.
In his study of the Philippine state, Hutchcroft (1994) contends that powerful elites who
are autonomous and independent of the State resisted change. He explains:
Political administrationwhether in pre-martial law, martial law or in the Aquino yearsis
often treated as a personal affair. The state apparatus is choked continually by an anarchy of
particularistic demands and particularistic action on behalf of those oligarchs and cronies who
are currently more favored by its top officials. One will obtain a highly coveted loan, another
21

will enjoy a stake in a cartelized industry unfettered by effective state regulation(Hutchcroft
1994, p. 66).

Hutchcroft (1991) argues that this elitist and patrimonial aspect of Philippine politics were
entrenched after the World War 11 period because: (1) personal contacts became even more
important for entrance in the central bureaucracy; (2) patrons, who historically relied on their
own local resources, found expanded opportunities in enriching themselves through the
bureaucracy. This did not diminish the power of local elites, but merely increased the role of
state resources within long standing patron-client relationships; and (3) as the oligarchy
diversified its economic holding beyond agriculture to include commerce, manufacturing and
finance, access to state machinery become more important than ever for the creation of wealth
(1991, pp. 414-450).
The Philippine state did not have a serious program for social housing over the years. Its
failure to generate adequate housing for the lower echelon of the Filipino masses persistently
over the years led the researcher to wonder why is it that there is no clear and and adequate
explanation to these phenomenon. This study would argue that this issue can best be explained
from the perspective of house financing which is a crucial area in its development.
The spiraling cost of housing had been triggered by the staggering increase in land prices as
well as the cost of materials in constructing houses. Thus, at the heart of the problem of social
housing is the issue of financing and banking in this area because of the housing cost factors
mentioned.
The state institutionalized the Housing and Urban Development Coordinating Council
(HUDCC) as the premier policy-making body in finding solutions and program implementation
on social housing and the Government Financial Institutions (GFIs) that were identified as the
22

principals in providing financial support were the following: Social Security System (SSS),
Government Service Insurance System (GSIS), the Home Development Mutual Fund (HDMF),
the National Home Mortgage Finance Corporation (NHMFC), and the Home Insurance Guaranty
Corporation (HIGC).
The private banking sector is expected to play a crucial role in contributing to the social
housing program of the government. The viability of banking on mass housing must indeed be
profitable if properly managed because of the economies of scale. However, the private banking
sectors dismal performance in helping the states housing program in the past few years was
buffling.
The role of Government Financial Institutions (GFIs) in financing social housing, and in
relation to the private banks in the Philippines is an issue that must be examined and addressed in
the light of the worsening housing problems in the country. The amount which the state allocated
for the socialized housing program was insufficient to cover the real needs of housing for the
poor. The state, thus, resorted to a financial policy for housing which relied on the private sector
to enhance the construction of social housing.
Simbulan (1998) stated that the government only has a small budget for social housing and
left the rest of these housing needs for the private sector to solve. The problem with this policy is
that the funds of the private sector are more tied-up with investments in real estate, and other
highly profitable form of business interests.
In terms of the slums and squatter settlements in the Philippines, a World Bank (1996) report
states:
Slums and squatter settlements around the world reflect the failures of housing and land
markets as much as poverty. In the Philippines, it is the underlying failure of the land market
which has made land so costly that urban housing has become not affordable to many. With such
a high proportion of urban dwellers surviving with uncertain land tenure, improved security of
23

settlement is critical to the reduction of poverty in urban areas. With secure tenure, the majority
of the poor can meet their own needs for shelter, constructing their own houses (World Bank
1996, p.27).

The World Bank reported the failure of social housing, and increasing problems of poverty in
the Philippines. The underlying factor that caused this according to them is the failure of the land
market.




THE NATURE OF THE MALAYSIAN STATE AS AN ECONOMIC INSTITUTION

In comparison with the Philippines, the Malaysian state has been able to move forward and it
became an instrument of economic development and reform that made the country very
progressive and which surpassed the Philippine state in its economic performance.
The Malaysian state had been able to score high among other countries in terms of good
governance and having imposed the rule of law. In addition its corruption index is impressive
and is respected by the World Bank as compared to the governance and corruption of the
Philippines which did register good ratings (The World Bank, 2009).
What are the factors that made Malaysia better than the Philippines? According to Yoshihara
(2004), Malaysia adopted new economic policies in the early 70s and restricted the economic
freedom of the Chinese who were the backbone of the economy then but the Malaysian was not
that strict to the Chinese. As Yoshihara (2004) explains:
Consider Malaysia vs. the Philippines first. One favorable institutional factor for Malaysia
is that it did not adopt as restrictive policy as the Philippines. True, Malaysia adopted New
24

Economic Policy in the early 1970s and restricted the economic freedom of the Chinese who
had been the main pillar of the economy together with foreign capital. But Philippine
institutions had been generally more restrictive on economic freedom, at least until the early
1990s. First of all, the Chinese, most of whom were not Filipinos at the time of independence,
were discriminated more severely in the Philippines than in Malaysia. Chinese discrimination
eased in the mid 1970s under Marcos marshal law, but before that, the effect of discrimination
was quite severe (the major discriminatory institution was the Retail Nationalization Law passed
in 1954). Besides, the Philippines restricted foreign investment and imports to greater extent
than Malaysia. Furthermore, the Philippine government created monopolies on commodity
trade and intervened in the economy through creating government corporations (especially,
banks), setting minimum wages at relatively high level, and controlling the prices of basic
commodities and services (Yoshihara, 2004, p. 11).

As such, during the Marcos regime, the Philippines restricted foreign investments and
imports much more than Malaysia. In addition, the Philippine state developed monopolies on
commodity trade and interrupted the economy by creating government corporations which
controlled the prices of basic commodities and services.
Furthermore, the Philippines and Malaysia had communist insurgency problems but
Malaysia was able to shut it down while in the Philippines it still continues and continued to
create havoc to the economy. Crimes in the Philippines had been higher in terms of kidnapping
of businessmen especially Chinese (Yoshihara, 2004).
THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK AND HYPOTHESES

This study is influenced by many of the concepts and ideas of the authorities that were
reviewed.. Since the central problem of this study concerns the economic development of the
Philippines and in comparison to Malaysia, the institutional economics theory of Douglass North
(1990) and the strong and weak states theory of Migdal (1985) will be utilized as a framework in
this study.
This framework is also supported by Douglas Norths economic growth theory and as he states:
Economic changes will change transformation and transaction costs, possibly leading
25

to institutional change, but changes in institutions will affect the efficiency of economic
transactions, and thus shape future economic growth. This duality is at times overlooked, simply
by not recognizing that they both can be happening concurrently (North, 1990).

Thus, the economic growth of Malaysia and the Philippines will be evaluated in terms of its
efficiency and as such it is recognized that the change in economic growth would lead also to
institutional change. On the other hand, the institutional change can also affect economic growth
and this is a duality that can happen for both countries in this study.
As such, economic institutions as termed as polities or governments shape economic
performance since they create policies to improve development and this had been applied and
focused in the United States and other developed countries (North, 1990). This new institutional
economics should be also applied to developing countries such as the Philippines and Malaysia
as a framework in analyzing the differences in their economic growth.
The framework of this study will also be adopted fromr Migdal (1988) and as for him it is
clear that only a strong state can be effective in transforming society, on the other hand, a weak
state is ineffective, and in a sense, it has no relative autonomy to effect much needed change in a
given country. This can be exemplified with the existence of power elites in a given society
which would tend to predominate politics, and economic policies particularly in many
underdeveloped countries such as the Philippines. As Migdal stated:
Capabilities include the capacities to penetrate society, regulate social relationships, extract
resources, and appropriate or use resources in determined ways. Strong states are those with high
capabilities to complete these tasks while weak states are on the low end of a spectrum of
capabilities (Migdal 1988, pp. 4-5)

Hypotheses
1. The economic growth of Malaysia was superior and higher than the Philippines from 1991 to
2007.
26

2. The eight critical economic indicators namely government expenditures, gross capital
formation, goods exports, goods imports, gross domestic savings, gross fixed capital formation,
foreign investments, consumption were related to the economic growth (GDP) for both
countries.
3. The Malaysian government was more effective than the Philippines in shaping economic
development and these were due to better economic policies and implementation by the former
as compared to the latter.



CHAPTER THREE: METHODS OF DATA COLLECTION AND
METHODOLOGY

RESEARCH OBJECTIVES

This study was conducted based on the following research objectives:
1. To evaluate the historical and comparative economic growth of Malaysia and the
Philippines;
2. To evaluate the critical economic indicators that contributed or hampered the economic
growth of both countries;
3. To evaluate the economic policies of both countries and its impact to their economic
growth; and
4. To evaluate the role of government in the development of their economy in these two
countries..
27

HISTORICAL METHOD

The historical method was utilized in this study. This method was appropriate for this study
since the period being studied happened already in the past. Historical data were gathered during
these periods and were analyzed based on state policies and actual performance
Historical research in this study proceeded with the systematic collection and objective
evaluation of data related to past occurrences in order to test hypotheses concerning causes,
effects, or trends of those events that may help to explain present events and anticipate future
events.

MIXED RESEARCH METHODS

In as much as the study can be explained through the historical method, the researcher also
integrated other methods of research such as the quantitative, and descriptive research methods.
These methods have been integrated since some of the data and phenomena being studied are
also current in Malaysia and the Philippines.
The descriptive method was utilized to support the historical method. Some of the data in
this study were quite recent and as such this method was utilized to describe the situation.
Furthermore, the data were analyzed utilizing charts and tables through chart analysis and
trend determination
Quantitative data were measured based on numerical measurements and it test causal
hypotheses (Thomas, 2003). This was an excellent approach used in this research since numbers
are specific and phenomena can be measured.
MULTIPLE REGRESSION ANALYSIS
28


In some areas of the economic study, regression analysis was utilized to determine
relationships between certain economic factors that caused the increase or decrease in economic
development such as money supply, gross domestic product, and other economic factors.
Multiple Regression Analysis refers to a set of techniques for studying the straight-line
relationships among two or more variables. Multiple regression estimates the 's in the equation


The Xs are the independent variables (IVs). Y is the dependent variable. The subscript j
represents the observation (row) number.
Multiple regression analysis (Allen, 1982) studies the relationship between a dependent

(response) variable and p independent variables (predictors, regressors, IVs). The sample

multiple regression equation is:


If p = 1, the model is called linear regression.

The intercept,
0
b
, is the point at which the regression plane intersects the Y axis. The
i
b
are the

slopes of the regression plane in the direction of
i
x
. These coefficients are called the partial-

regression coefficients. Each partial regression coefficient represents the net effect the ith

variable has on the dependent variable, holding the remaining Xs in the equation constant.
A large part of a regression analysis consists of analyzing the sample residuals,
j
e
, defined as

j j j
e y y =

Once the 's have been estimated, various indices are studied to determine the reliability of
these estimates. One of the most popular of these reliability indices is the correlation coefficient.
29

The correlation coefficient, or simply the correlation, is an index that ranges from -1 to 1. When
the value is near zero, there is no linear relationship. As the correlation gets closer to plus or
minus one, the relationship is stronger. A value of one (or negative one) indicates a perfect linear
relationship between two variables.
Assumptions made with multiple regression
A fundamental assumption in the multiple regression model is that the effect of each IV is
additive. Now, no one really believes that the true relationship is actually additive. Rather, one
believes that this model is a reasonable first-approximation to the true model. To add validity to
this approximation, you might consider this additive model to be a Taylor-series expansion of the
true model.
Another assumption is that the relationship of the DV with each IV is linear (straight-line).
Here again, no one really believes that the relationship is a straight-line. However, this is a
reasonable first approximation.
In order obtain better approximations, methods have been developed to allow regression
models to approximate curvilinear relationships as well as non-additivity. Although nonlinear
regression models can be used in these situations, they add a higher level of complexity to the
modeling process (Allen, 1982).
Multiple Regression Technical Details

This section presents the technical details of least squares regression analysis using a
mixture of summation and matrix notation. Because this module also calculates weighted
multiple regression, the formulas will include the weights (Allen, 1982).
Definition of the following vectors and matrices:
30






Least Squares
The essence of the least square method is to look for a vector b such that Xb is an
approximation of Y.
Using this notation, the least squares estimates are found using the equation.

( )
1
' '

= b X WX X WY

where X is the transpose of matrix X.
Note that when the weights are not used, this reduces to

( )
1
' '

= b X X X Y

The predicted values of the dependent variable are given by

= Y Xb

31

The residuals are calculated using

= = e Y Y Y Xb

The least square method chooses b in such a way that the (weighted) sum of the
values e_1, ..., e_N is as small as possible.
In this study, the multiple regression model would be using Y GDP as the dependent variable
for Malaysia and the dependent variables are the following:
X1 Consumption
X2 Foreign Direct Investment (net inflow)
X3 Government Expenditures
X4 Exports
X5 Imports
X6 Investment
X7 Gross Domestic Savings
X8 Gross Fixed Capital Formation

Table 1a Variables for Malaysia Regression Model

Time
Y
GDP
X1
Cons
X2
FDI
net
X3
Govt
Exp
X4
Exports
X5
Imports
X6
Investment
X7
GDS
X8
GFCF
1977 14 9 0 2 6 5 3 4 3
1978 17 11 0 3 7 6 4 5 4
1979 22 14 1 3 11 8 6 8 5
1980 25 17 1 4 13 11 7 7 7
1981 25 18 1 4 12 12 8 6 9
1982 27 20 1 5 12 13 9 7 10
1983 31 21 1 5 14 13 10 9 11
32

1984 35 22 1 5 17 14 10 11 11
1985 32 22 1 5 15 12 8 9 9
1986 28 19 0 5 14 10 7 8 7
1987 32 20 0 5 18 12 7 11 7
1988 35 22 1 5 21 16 8 12 9
1989 39 25 2 5 25 20 11 13 11
1990 44 29 2 6 29 26 14 15 15
1991 49 32 4 7 34 33 19 17 18
1992 59 37 5 8 40 37 21 22 22
1993 67 41 5 8 46 43 26 26 26
1994 74 45 4 9 57 55 31 29 30
1995 89 54 4 11 72 72 39 35 39
1996 101 58 5 11 77 73 42 43 43
1997 100 56 5 11 78 74 43 44 43
1998 72 37 2 7 72 54 19 35 19
1999 79 42 4 9 84 61 18 38 17
2000 94 51 4 10 98 78 25 43 24
2001 93 54 1 11 88 70 23 39 23
2002 101 58 3 13 93 75 25 42 24
2003 110 63 2 14 105 79 25 47 25
2004 125 71 5 16 127 99 29 54 26
2005 138 79 4 17 142 109 28 59 28
2006 156 89 6 19 161 123 33 68 33
2007 187 108 8 23 176 139 41 79 40
Source: The World Bank

Also, for the Philippines multiple regression model, GNP is the Y dependent variable and the
following are the dependent variables:
X1 Consumption
X2 Foreign Direct Investment (net inflow)
X3 Government Expenditures
X4 Exports
X5 Imports
33

X6 Investment
X7 Gross Domestic Savings
X8 Gross Fixed Capital Formation
Table 1b Variables for Philippine Regression Model

Time
Y
GDP
X1
Consumption
X2
FDI Net
X3
Govt.
Exp
X4
Exports
X5
Imports
X6
Investments
X7
GDS
X8
GFCF
1977 20 14 0 2 3 4 6 5 5
1978 23 17 0 2 3 5 7 6 6
1979 28 20 0 3 5 6 8 7 7
1980 32 24 0 3 6 8 9 8 9
1981 36 26 0 3 6 8 10 9 10
1982 37 28 0 3 5 8 10 8 10
1983 33 24 0 3 5 7 10 8 10
1984 31 24 0 2 5 6 6 6 7
1985 31 25 0 2 5 5 4 5 5
1986 30 24 0 2 5 5 5 6 5
1987 33 26 0 3 6 7 6 6 5
1988 38 30 1 3 7 8 7 8 7
1989 43 34 1 4 8 10 9 8 9
1990 44 36 1 4 8 12 11 8 10
1991 45 38 1 5 9 12 9 8 9
1992 53 45 0 5 10 15 11 9 11
1993 54 47 1 5 11 18 13 8 13
1994 64 55 2 7 13 21 15 11 15
1995 74 63 1 8 17 26 17 11 16
1996 83 71 2 10 21 32 20 13 19
1997 82 71 1 11 25 36 20 12 20
1998 65 57 2 9 29 30 13 9 14
1999 76 65 1 10 34 40 14 14 15
2000 76 63 2 10 37 43 16 18 16
2001 71 59 0 9 31 38 14 11 13
2002 77 62 2 9 34 40 14 13 14
2003 80 64 0 9 35 41 13 9 13
2004 87 69 1 9 39 44 15 11 14
2005 99 78 2 10 40 48 14 10 14
2006 118 94 3 11 47 53 17 16 16
2007 144 114 3 14 50 58 22 23 21
Source: The World Bank
34



Time Series Analysis
The study also utilized least squares method in analyzing and projecting the time series
analysis as to project the trend of internet users from 1986 to 2008 for Malaysia and the
Philippines. The least squares method is similar to regression analysis but this is only a simple
linear regression using one dependent variable and one independent variable.
Growth Rate Analysis
The study also used the growth rate analysis wherein the GDP annual growth rates of both
countries were computed and the graph would show the trend of the GDP for Malaysia and the
Philippines from 1980 to 2007.
LONG-TERM ECONOMIC GROWTH PROCESS

The long-term economic growth model was also used in the study using a time series of real
GDP, real capital stock, and employment for Malaysia and the Philippines from 1980 to 2007.
The model that was followed can be seen in the figure below:
Figure 1 Long-Term Economic Model

35


To understand this, lets look at the sources of economic growth.where
does production come from?
( ) L K A F Y , , =
Real GDP
is a function of
Productivity
Capital
Stock
Labor
Real GDP = Constant Dollar (Inflation adjusted) value of all goods and
services produced in the United States
Capital Stock = Constant dollar value of private, non-residential fixed assets
Labor = Private Sector Employment
Productivity = Production unaccounted for by capital or labor

The computations for the model can be seen in the appendices.
DATA GATHERING METHOD

The data collection and gathering of this study were based on searches in the internet since it
is the only way to gather data worldwide. The data comes from the websites of the following
sources:
1. Asian Development Bank
2. The World Bank
3. United Nations Development Programme
4. International Monetary Fund
5. Malaysian Government Agencies
6. Philippine Government Agencies

36

VALIDITY OF DATA

The data are valid since these were taken from reliable sources in the internet. Most of the
data came from valid sources such as the The World Bank, Asian Development Bank, United
Nations Development Programme, International Monetary Fund, Malaysian Government
Agencies, and Philippine Government Agencies.
ORIGINALITY AND LIMITATIONS

The data are original. The limitations are that these sources came from the web and some of
these data came from secondary sources.
RESEARCH ETHICS

Ethics is important in economic research since students should be able to know and feel that
they are morally responsible in writing a research.
It is possible that students can violate ethics in research and as such, they should be
concerned with this as they plan their research as well during their contact with respondents.
In the universality stance of ethics, it is important that ethical precepts should not be violated
and that research respondents should not be treated as a means to an end. Thus, the researchers
right to know should be balanced with the rights of the respondents such as their privacy, dignity
and self determination.
. Furthermore, in writing a research project, all the respondents will be briefed about the topic
and its restrictions and assurance will be guaranteed in terms of verbal and nonverbal
information provided according to Data protection Act of 1998. It is further important to be
ethical in management research in terms of reliability of data, its validity and generalizability as
37

it is important in ethics about the truthfulness of the study. Researchers are legally required to
protect their data
In the UK Data Protection Act of 1998, personal data must be:obtained for specific, explicit
and lawful purposes and should not be further processed if these are incompatible with those
purposes. The data must be adequate, relevant and not excessive in relation to the objectives.
The data must also be accurate and a general updated requirement is suspended in the case
of anonymized research data. This data must be secured in a form that allows identification of
data subjects for no longer than is necessary
There are four ethical principles that should be observed in research. Firstly, the researcher
must avoid harm to participants. Secondly, there must be informed consent from them. Thirdly,
the researcher must avoid invasion of their privacy. Fourthly, there must be the avoidance of
deception.
Participants must be informed about information that are needed for them to make a
decision about whether or not they wish to join in a study. This information should be what the
research is about and why it is being undertaken. They should also be informed of who is
funding the research. Information of what is exactly the participants role in the study should be
clear in order to avoid misunderstanding.
Privacy issues in research ethics are linked to anonymity and confidentiality and this can be
problematic in qualitative research wherein rich contextual is provided by participants. The
respondents should be protected in terms of anonymity in their comments in the interviews since
their identities can easily be revealed if they are not protected by the researcher. This can be done
by not stating their names as well as possibly the organization where they came from especially
if there are only a few people in the organization or department where they came from.
38

CHAPTER FOUR: RESULTS

ECONOMIC TRENDS FROM 1990-1994

In terms of the current account balance, Malaysia had a negative (see Table2) figure with
USD- 0,918 billion and this deficit further decreased to USD -5,628 billion in 1994 while the
Philippines posted a deficit of USD -2,690 billion in 1990 and this also further increased to USD
-2,849 billion in 1994. Thus, both countries incurred deficits during this period and Malaysia had
higher deficits. The current account balance as a percent of GDP for Malaysia was -2.1% percent
in 1990 and increased further to -7.6% in 1994. The Philippines current balance as a percentage
of GDP was --6.1 % in 1990 and this also further improved to -4.4% in 1994.
In terms of gross domestic product per capita at current prices, Malaysia had USD 2,431,973
in 1990 and this increased to USD 3,703,376 in 1994. In comparison, the Philippines had only
USD718,114 in 1990 and this increased to USD 949,209. In this area, the Philippines had a much
lower figure as compared to Malaysia.
In the area of GDP (in constant prices) annual percent change, Malaysia had 9% percent in
1990 and this increased slightly to 9.2% in 1994 while Philippines had 3 percent in 1990 and this
increased to 4.4% in 1994. The GDP in current prices was USD 44.025 billion in 1990 and this
improved to USD 74.481 billion in 1994. Comparably, the Philippines had USD 44.164 billion in
1990 and this also improved to USD 64.085 billion in 1994 which was lower to the figure of
Malaysia.
As regard to inflation in annual percent change, Malaysia had a low 2.6% rate in 1990 and
this increased slightly to 3.9% in 1994 while the Philippines had a much higher rate at 13.2% in
1990 and it decreased to 9% in 1994.
39


Table 2 Economic Trend Analysis for Philippines and Malaysia, 1990-1994
Country Subject Description Units Scale 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994
Malaysia Current account balance
Billion
s
US
dollars - 0,918 -4,234 -2,207 -3,079 -5,628
Malaysia
Current account balance in percent of
GDP Ratio - 2,1 - 8,6 - 3,7 - 4,6 - 7,6
Malaysia
Gross domestic product per capita,
current prices Units
US
dollars
2,431,97
3
2,680,86
7
3,152,68
4
3,419,33
5
3,703,37
6
Malaysia
Gross domestic product, constant prices,
annual percent change
Percen
t 9,0 9,5 8,9 9,9 9,2
Malaysia Gross domestic product, current prices
Billion
s
US
dollars 44,025 49,134 59,151 66,895 74,481
Malaysia Inflation, annual percent change
Percen
t 2,6 4,4 4,8 3,6 3,9
Philippine
s Current account balance
Billion
s
US
dollars -2,690 - 0,944 - 0,993 -3,003 -2,849
Philippine
s
Current account balance in percent of
GDP Ratio - 6,1 - 2,1 - 1,9 - 5,5 - 4,4
Philippine
s
Gross domestic product per capita,
current prices Units
US
dollars 718,114 719,384 822,695 825,012 949,209
Philippine
s
Gross domestic product, constant prices,
annual percent change
Percen
t 3,0 - 0,6 0,3 2,1 4,4
Philippine
s Gross domestic product, current prices
Billion
s
US
dollars 44,164 45,418 52,976 54,368 64,085
Philippine
s Inflation, annual percent change
Percen
t 13,2 18,4 8,9 7,6 9,0
Source: IMF
ECONOMIC TREND FROM 1995-1999

During the period 1995 to 1999, Malaysias current account balance (see Table 2) which
started with a negative USD -8.644 billion 1995 improved much further with a surplus of USD
12,604 billion in 1999. Comparably, the Philippines started with a negative current account
balance of USD -1,965 billion in 1995 to a surplus of USD 7,219 billion in 1995 which was a
lower figure compared to Malaysia. In terms of current account balance as a percentage of GDP,
Malaysia had a -9.7% rate in 1995 and this increased to 15.9% in 1999. The Philippines had a -
2.6% rate in 1995 and this increased to a positive 9.5% in 1995. Again, Malaysia had a better and
higher current account balance rate than the Philippines during this period.
40

In terms of GDP per capita in current prices, Malaysia had USD 4,293,662 in 1995 but this
declined to USD 3,484,888 in 1999. In comparison, the Philippines had only USD 1,104,985 in
1995 but this declined slightly to USD 1,018,882 in 1999. In addition, the GDP in constant prices
annual percent change for Malaysia was 9.8% in 1995 but this declined to 6.1% in 1999. On the
one hand, the Philippines had 4.7% in 1995 but this decreased slightly to 3.4% in 1999. It can
still be observed that Malaysia had a better figure compared to the Philippines in this category
during this period.
As regard to the GDP in current prices, Malaysia posted USD 88.833 billion in 1995 but this
declined to USD 79.148 billion in 1999. In comparison, the Philippines had USD74.120 billion
in 1995 and this increased slightly to 76.157 billion in 1999 which was again lower compared to
the GDP of Malaysia during this period.
In terms of inflation in annual percent change, Malaysia had 3.5% in 1995 and this improved
further to only 2.8% in 1999. In contrast, the Philippines had a much higher inflation rate with
8.5% in 1995 which declined slightly to 6.7% in 1999.
Table 2b Economic Trend Analysis for Philippines and Malaysia, 1995 - 1999
Country Subject Description Units Scale 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999
Malaysia Current account balance
Billion
s
US
dollars -8,644 -4,462 -5,935 9,529 12,604
Malaysia Current account balance in percent of GDP Ratio - 9,7 - 4,4 - 5,9 13,2 15,9
Malaysia
Gross domestic product per capita, current
prices Units
US
dollars
4,293,66
2
4,764,12
6
4,623,42
7
3,254,12
5
3,484,88
8
Malaysia
Gross domestic product, constant prices,
annual percent change
Percen
t 9,8 10,0 7,3 - 7,4 6,1
Malaysia Gross domestic product, current prices
Billion
s
US
dollars 88,833 100,852 100,169 72,175 79,148
Malaysia Inflation, annual percent change
Percen
t 3,5 3,5 2,6 5,1 2,8
Philippine
s Current account balance
Billion
s
US
dollars -1,965 -3,861 -4,330 1,510 7,219
Philippine
s Current account balance in percent of GDP Ratio - 2,6 - 4,6 - 5,2 2,3 9,5
Philippine
s
Gross domestic product per capita, current
prices Units
US
dollars
1,104,98
5
1,206,13
6
1,170,31
8 910,436
1,018,88
2
Philippine
s
Gross domestic product, constant prices,
annual percent change
Percen
t 4,7 5,8 5,2 - 0,6 3,4
Philippine Gross domestic product, current prices Billion US 74,120 82,848 82,344 65,172 76,157
41

s s dollars
Philippine
s Inflation, annual percent change
Percen
t 8,5 9,1 5,9 9,7 6,7
Source: IMF


ECONOMIC TREND FROM 2000-2004
The economic trend from 2000 to 2004 in terms of the (see Table 3) current account balance
was a great improvement for Malaysia after the Asian crisis which registered USD 8,487 billion
in 2000. This soared to USD 14,872 in 2004. This was because the policy reforms adopted by
the government were already in placed and these macro-economic fundamentals played a key
role in the continued increase in the economic growth of the country. Comparably, the
Philippines posted USD 6,258 billion in 2000 but this decreased to USD 2,312 billion in 2004.
The current account balance as a percentage of GDP improved further for Malaysia which
registered 9.4% in 2000 and which further improved to 12.6% in 2004. On the other hand, the
Philippines performance in this area was poor which started well with 8.2% in 2000 but this
declined to only 2.7% in 2004. This decline can be attributed to the fiscal deficits of the
government and the poor political will of the government to improve its current account balance.
In terms of GDP per capita in current prices, Malaysia did well with USD 3,844,239 in 2000
and this improved further to USD 4,645,874 in 2004. However, the Philippines had a lower GDP
per capita with only USD 994,291 in 2000 and only improved slightly to USD 1,041,860 in
2004. In terms of GDP (in constant prices) annual percent change, Malaysia had a high rate at
8.9% in 2000 but declined slightly to 7.1% in 2004. In comparison, the Philippines had a lower
42

rate with 6% in 2000 and had the same rate of change of 6% in 2004 and this means it did not
improve in this area.
As regard to the GDP in current prices, Malaysia had a good performance with USD 93.790
billion in 2000 and this increased further to USD 124.749 billion in 2004. On the one hand, the
Philippines had a lower GDP of only USD 75.913 billion and increased to only USD 86.930
billion in 2004 which was again much lower to the GDP of Malaysia during this period.
The inflation rate of Malaysia was very low which was actually good for the economy with
1.6% in 2004 and which improved slightly to 1.4% in 2004. The low inflation rate in Malaysia
can be attributed to the lower cost-push factor for prices such as Malaysia had its own oil
reserves and sources. Moreover, the transactional cost as well as the transformational cost of
running the economy as caused by the efficiency of the Malaysia state also should contribute to
lower inflation rate in the country. On the other hand, Philippines had a higher 4.3% inflation
rate in 2004 and this increased to 6% in 2004. This higher inflation rate as well as higher lending
rates can be attributed to the increasing oil prices in the world market which resulted to the
spiralling increase in cost to goods and services. Furthermore, the transactional cost and
transformational cost of running the economy were higher since the Philippine state was not
efficient in running the country.

Table 3 Economic Trend Analysis for Philippines and Malaysia, 2000-2004
Country Subject Description Units Scale 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004
Malaysia Current account balance
Billion
s
US
dollars 8,487 7,286 8,025 13,207 14,872
Malaysia Current account balance in percent of GDP Ratio 9,4 8,3 8,4 12,7 12,6
Malaysia
Gross domestic product per capita, current
prices Units
US
dollars
3,844,23
9
3,664,73
0
3,884,22
0
4,159,32
1
4,645,87
4
Malaysia
Gross domestic product, constant prices,
annual percent change
Percen
t 8,9 0,3 4,4 5,4 7,1
Malaysia Gross domestic product, current prices
Billion
s
US
dollars 93,790 92,784 100,846 110,202 124,749
43

Malaysia Inflation, annual percent change
Percen
t 1,6 1,4 1,8 1,1 1,4
Philippine
s Current account balance
Billion
s
US
dollars 6,258 1,323 4,383 1,396 2,312
Philippine
s Current account balance in percent of GDP Ratio 8,2 1,9 5,7 1,8 2,7
Philippine
s
Gross domestic product per capita, current
prices Units
US
dollars 994,291 913,900 966,176 976,829
1,041,86
0
Philippine
s
Gross domestic product, constant prices,
annual percent change
Percen
t 6,0 1,8 4,4 4,5 6,0
Philippine
s Gross domestic product, current prices
Billion
s
US
dollars 75,913 71,216 76,814 79,634 86,930
Philippine
s Inflation, annual percent change
Percen
t 4,3 6,1 2,9 3,5 6,0
Source: IMF
ECONOMIC TREND FROM 2005-2007

As Malaysias policy of liberalization and export led strategy worked very well during the
2001 to 2004 period, this same policy and strategy worked well also from 2005 to 2007. On the
one hand, the Philippines policy was also focus on liberalization as well as on export led
strategy but its performance in terms of exports and in the GDP measure were much lower than
Malaysia.
During the period from 2005 to 2007, the current account balance (see Table 4) of Malaysia
further improved from USD 20,355 billion in 2005 to USD 22,784 billion in 2007. In contrast,
the Philippines current account balance was much smaller and continued to decline further from
USD 2,938 billion in 2005 to USD 2,096 billion in 2007.
As Malaysias current account balance as percentage of GDP improved to 15.6% as
compared to the previous period, it declined slightly to 14.7% in 2007. However, the Philippines
had a much smaller ratio with 3% in 2005 and which declined further to 1.6% in 2007.
Malaysias GDP per capita in current prices continued to improved much further with USD
5,040,048 in 2005 to USD 5,756,397 in 2007. In comparison, the Philippines only had USD
44

1,159,207 in 2005 which increased to USD 1,455,301 in 2007. The GDP in constant prices
annual change for Malaysia was 5.3% in 2005 and improved slightly to 5.8%. In comparison, the
Philippines had a similar rate with 5.1% in 2005 which also increased slightly to 5.6% in 2007.
The GDP in current prices for Malaysia further increased to USD 137.954 billion in 2005
from the previous year. This further increased to USD 186.721 billion in 2007. In comparison,
the Philippines had a lower GDP of USD 98.824 in 2005 but this further increased to USD
144.043 billion. However, the 2007 figure is till lower compared to Malaysias USD 186.721
billion.
The annual inflation rate for Malaysia was only 5.3% in 2005 and this increased slightly to
5.8% in 2007. In comparison, the Philippines had a higher inflation rate of 7.6% in 2005 and
declined slightly to 4.7% in 2007.
In the over-all, all these economic indicators proved that Malaysia did better economically in
comparison with the Philippines.

Table 4 Economic Trend Analysis for Philippines and Malaysia, 2005-2007
Country Subject Description Units Scale 2005 2006 2007
Malaysia Current account balance
Billion
s
US
dollars 20,355 21,526 22,784
Malaysia Current account balance in percent of GDP Ratio 15,6 14,9 14,7
Malaysia Gross domestic product per capita, current prices Units
US
dollars
5,040,04
8
5,457,35
5
5,756,39
7
Malaysia Gross domestic product, constant prices, annual percent change
Percen
t 5,3 5,5 5,8
Malaysia Gross domestic product, current prices
Billion
s
US
dollars 137,954 156,408 186,721
Malaysia Inflation, annual percent change
Percen
t 3,0 3,1 2,7
Philippine
s Current account balance
Billion
s
US
dollars 2,938 2,369 2,096
Philippine
s Current account balance in percent of GDP Ratio 3,0 2,1 1,6
Philippine
s Gross domestic product per capita, current prices Units
US
dollars
1,159,20
7
1,297,86
7
1,455,30
1
Philippine
s Gross domestic product, constant prices, annual percent change
Percen
t 5,1 5,0 5,6
Philippine Gross domestic product, current prices Billion US 98,824 117,534 144,043
45

s s dollars
Philippine
s Inflation, annual percent change
Percen
t 7,6 7,4 4,7
Source: IMF

From 1980 to 1990, the Philippines had been higher in GDP than Malaysia until 1991 where
Malaysia had overtaken the Philippines until today (see Figure 1b)
Figure 1b
Gross Domestic Product at Current Prices of Malaysia and the Philippines, 1980-2007

Source: IMF







0
20000
40000
60000
80000
100000
120000
140000
160000
180000
1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27
Years
Malaysia
Philippines
46


LONG-TERM ECONOMIC GROWTH

The growth in the long term from 1980 to 2007 for Malaysias (see Table 4b) real GDP was
tremendous as it increased from USD 26.4 billion in 1980 to USD 132 billion in 2007. In terms
of real gross capital stock, it grew from USD 6.6 billion in 1980 to USD 29.3 billion in 2007.
In addition, the labor force of Malaysia increased from 4,976,959 in 1980 to 11,474,574 in
2007. From the production point of view, capital stock and employment were major contributors
to the output (GDP) of the country.
Table 4b Malaysia Real GDP, Real Gross Capital Stock, and Employment, 1980 to 2007
Time GDP (constant 2000
US$)
Gross capital
formation (constant
2000 US$)
Labor force, total
1980 26,414,956,465 6,679,149,135 4,976,959
1981 28,248,670,150 7,827,342,525 5,112,875
1982 29,926,902,978 8,952,473,763 5,245,655
1983 31,797,409,675 9,635,992,448 5,380,412
1984 34,265,500,871 10,163,474,170 5,533,535
1985 33,880,956,782 8,158,061,836 5,729,949
1986 34,271,437,817 7,060,898,678 5,945,260
1987 36,118,204,026 6,877,384,304 6,157,329
1988 39,707,531,539 8,661,770,992 6,380,551
1989 43,304,430,757 10,651,934,988 6,695,517
1990 47,206,008,084 12,930,554,616 7,003,834
1991 51,712,041,005 16,744,791,467 7,231,448
1992 56,306,715,785 17,316,926,995 7,457,551
1993 61,878,235,380 21,260,876,316 7,675,969
1994 67,578,484,906 23,951,787,316 7,907,288
1995 74,220,829,683 30,126,221,878 8,157,353
1996 81,644,917,419 31,867,614,904 8,428,794
1997 87,623,564,853 35,448,146,252 8,703,883
1998 81,174,982,743 20,189,729,854 9,002,151
1999 86,157,186,506 19,409,980,022 9,283,538
2000 93,789,738,019 25,198,947,685 9,724,275
2001 94,275,264,341 22,850,526,603 10,001,253
47

2002 99,357,632,826 24,657,631,888 10,250,829
2003 105,108,948,687 24,285,000,305 10,493,105
2004 112,238,948,777 25,951,052,957 10,735,294
2005 118,223,685,694 25,312,105,581 10,982,445
2006 125,050,527,885 28,217,631,933 11,217,771
2007 132,987,633,248 29,330,789,842 11,474,574
Source: The World Bank

On the other hand, the Philippines real GDP increased from (see Table 4c) USD 47.5 billion
in 1980 to USD 106.7 billion in 2007. The real gross capital stock as a contributor to real GDP
also increased from USD 10.8 billion in 1980 to USD 1.7 billion in 2007.
Table 4c Philippines Real GDP, Real Gross Capital Stock, and Employment, 1980 to 2007
Time GDP (constant
2000 US$)
Gross capital
formation
(constant 2000
US$)
Labor force,
total
1980 47,575,477,646 10,826,315,251 17,817,125
1981 49,204,114,308 11,132,948,042 18,390,193
1982 50,984,972,401 12,070,187,767 19,015,752
1983 51,940,745,090 12,842,684,624 19,661,427
1984 48,136,769,787 8,092,497,741 20,195,682
1985 44,619,604,313 5,514,752,422 20,729,699
1986 46,144,159,280 6,069,541,342 21,658,316
1987 48,133,726,918 7,264,884,951 22,576,249
1988 51,383,978,240 8,331,915,978 23,061,365
1989 54,572,513,953 10,035,804,894 23,436,092
1990 56,229,862,808 11,624,824,140 24,099,598
1991 55,904,666,027 9,614,840,150 24,771,833
1992 56,093,401,874 10,367,979,215 25,648,643
1993 57,280,510,565 11,184,299,960 26,186,155
1994 59,793,763,616 12,152,189,522 26,894,754
1995 62,591,329,783 12,577,926,500 28,086,519
1996 66,250,339,726 14,144,630,514 28,799,125
1997 69,685,659,849 15,798,915,090 29,527,555
1998 69,283,767,186 13,227,420,725 30,593,952
1999 71,636,918,558 12,965,283,968 31,271,608
2000 75,912,538,425 16,067,907,730 31,479,295
2001 77,245,314,676 14,896,156,430 33,064,728
48

2002 80,682,273,266 14,254,929,595 33,843,319
2003 84,659,692,054 14,680,464,929 34,635,029
2004 90,060,548,960 15,732,574,326 35,276,034
2005 94,520,229,499 14,348,253,037 35,530,965
2006 99,568,571,504 15,075,467,020 36,046,752
2007 106,616,846,806 16,939,254,912 36,843,186
Source: The World Bank

The labor force of the Philippines grew from 17,817, 125 to 36,046,752 in 2007. In
comparison, the real GDP grew faster and higher than the Philippines. The real capital formation
which was much higher than the Philippines played a major part in the output of the country. As
regard to labor, the Philippines output were more on the growth of labor wherein Malaysia had
less (see Table 4d).
Table 4d Malaysia and Philippines Real GDP, Real Capital Stock, and Employment, 1980
and 2007
Country Year Real GDP
(in USD
millions
Real Capital
Stock (in
USD millions
Employment
(in
thousands)
Malaysia 1980 26,415 6,679 4,978
Malaysia 2007 132,988 29,331 11,475
Philippines 1980 47,575 10,826 17,817
Philippines 2007 106,617 16,939 36,843
Source: The World Bank
The long-term economic average of Malaysia from 1980 to 2007 (see Table 4e) in terms of
output was 38.06% while the Philippines had only 21.08%. It can be observed that the long-term
growth were higher than the developed countries. It was observed that developed economies had
lower growth rates since they had already reached the maturity stage of economic growth while
developing countries such as the Philippines and Malaysia were still in the transition stage. The
real capital stock long-term economic average was 8.09% for Malaysia and it was higher than the
Philippines which was only 2.18%. As such, real capital stock played a major part in the output
49

(real GDP) of Malaysia while the Philippines had less. It was typical for developing countries
like the Philippines and Malaysia for having shortages in capital since their economies lacked
maturity in terms of financial markets as well as low savings which were needed for capital
formation.
Furthermore, the long-term economic average for labor or employment of Malaysia was only
2.32% while the Philippines had a higher average with 6.8%. It can be seen here that the higher
output of Malaysia was more of capital driven rather than labor driven while the Philippines
output was driven by labor growth. In addition, long-term productivity growth rate in Malaysia
was higher with 33.82% while the Philippines had only 15.81%.
Table 4e Malaysia and Philippines Long-Term Economic Growth Averages from 1980 to
2007 (in percent)
Malaysia Philippines
Output 38.06 21.08
Capital 8.09 2.18
Labor 2.32 6.8
Productivity 33.82 15.81
Source: The World Bank

The Malaysian long-term economic growth average for output from (see Table 4f) the 1980
to 1989 period was 16.89% while the Philippines had only 6.99%. Malaysias long-term
economic average for output further increased to 42.90% during the 1989 to 1999 period while
the Philippines had a lower growth rate with 17.06%. Finally, Malaysias output increased
further to 52.03% during the 1999 to 2007 period while the Philippines had a lesser long-term
average for output of 38.87% during the same period.
50

In general, long-term output gradually declines as economies matures but since these two
countries were still in the developing and transition stage, output were still increasing during the
periods mentioned.
Malaysias long-term economic average for real capital stock was only 3.97% during the
1980 to 1989 period while the Philippines had a negative growth rate with -0.79% during the
same period. Furthermore, Malaysias real capital stock long-term average grew to 8.76% during
the 1989 to 1999 period while the Philippines had a lower figure with 2.9% during the same
period. However, the Philippines recovered from the negative growth rate during the previous
period mentioned. Finally, during the 1999 to 2007 period the real capital stock long-term
average of Malaysia grew to 11.02% while the Philippines only had 4.42% during the same
period.
In terms of Malaysias labor long-term average growth during the 1980 to 1989 period, it
posted only 1.72% while the Philippines had higher with 5.62% during the same period.
Table 4f Malaysia and Philippines Long-Term Economic Growth Averages by Periods,
1980 to 2007 (in percent)
Malaysia Philippines
1980 to
1989
1989 to
1999
1999 to
2007
1980 to
1989
1989 to
1999
1999 to
2007
Output
16.89 42.90 52.03 6.99 17.06 38.87
Capital 3.97 8.76 11.02 -0.79 2.93 4.42
Labor 1.72 2.60 2.43 5.62 7.84 6.19
Productivity 14.42 38.25 46.74 2.98 10.85 33.27
Source: The World Bank

During the 1989 to 1999 period, Malaysias labor long-term average grew to 2.60% while the
Philippines long-term labor average grew to 7.84% which was again higher than Malaysia.
However, the long-term average for labor for the Philippines declined to 6.19% during the 1999
51

to 2007 period while Malaysias labor long-term average also declined slightly to 2.43% during
the same period.
Malaysias long-term average productivity was 14.42% during the 1980 to 1989 period while
the Philippines only had a meager 2.98%. This further increased to 38.25% for Malaysia while
the Philippines long-term average productivity also increased to 10.85%. Finally, the long-term
productivity average of Malaysia further grew to 46.74% during the 1999 to 2007 period while
the Philippines had a lower long-term average productivity rate although it increased to 33.27%.
A better measure of economic performance was real output (real GDP) per capita and the real
capital stock per capita or the capital/labor ratio (see Table 4g). Malaysias real output per capita
grew from USD 5,306 in 1980 to USD 11,589 in 2007 while the Philippines real output per
capita increased from only USD 2,670 in 1980 to USD 2,894 in 2007 which were much lower
compared to Malaysia.
Table 4g Malaysia and Philippines Real Output per Capita, and
Capital/Labor Ratio, 1980 and 2007
Country Year Real Output
per Capita
Capital/Labor
Ratio
Malaysia 1980 5,306 I,342
Malaysia 2007 11,589 2,556
Philippines 1980 2,670 608
Philippines 2007 2,894 460
Source: The World Bank
Furthermore, the capital/labor ratio of Malaysia increased from USD 1,342 in 1980 to USD
2,556 in 2007 while the Philippines had a capital/labor ratio of only USD 608 in 1980 and this
further decreased to USD 460 in 2007. Developing countries typically have low capital/labor
ratio and the Philippines was no exception but its capital/labor ratio was really low in 2007
because as was mentioned already, its low domestic savings generation cannot cope with the
capital needs of the growing economy.
52

The annual growth rates of the Malaysia were generally much higher from 1980 to 2007
and it showed the superiority of its economic performance due to better resources, policies, as
well as its determination to succeed (see Figure 1c).


Figure 1c Malaysia and the Philippines GDP growth rate trend (annual %) from 1980-
2007


Source: World Bank

As such, it can be concluded that the long-term economic averages of Malaysia in terms of
real output, real capital stock, and productivity were much higher than the Philippines and these
were major factors that made Malaysia more economically superior than the Philippines. On the
other hand, the long-term labor growth rate of the Philippines was much better compared with
-8
-6
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
1
9
8
0
1
9
8
1
1
9
8
2
1
9
8
3
1
9
8
4
1
9
8
5
1
9
8
6
1
9
8
7
1
9
8
8
1
9
8
9
1
9
9
0
1
9
9
1
1
9
9
2
1
9
9
3
1
9
9
4
1
9
9
5
1
9
9
6
1
9
9
7
1
9
9
8
1
9
9
9
2
0
0
0
2
0
0
1
2
0
0
2
2
0
0
3
2
0
0
4
2
0
0
5
2
0
0
6
2
0
0
7
P
e
r
c
e
n
t
a
g
e

(

%

)

Year
Malaysia GDP
growth (annual
%)
Philippines GDP
growth (annual
%)
53

Malaysia but this was not enough to produce an output that can compete with the long-term
economic growth of Malaysia.
COMPETITIVENESS OF MALAYSIA AND THE PHILIPPINES

The competitiveness indices of Malaysia were much better than the Philippines (see Table
5).The ranking of the Malaysia and The Philippines (out of a total of 102 countries in 2004 and
125 countries in 2006) in terms of three sets of competitiveness indicators: growth
competitiveness, macro environment, and public institutions indices. The growth
competitiveness index covers measures of competitiveness such as institutions, infrastructure,
macro economy, health and primary education, higher education and training, market efficiency,
technological readiness, business sophistication, and innovation. The macro environment index
was based on macroeconomic stability, country credit risk, and wastage in government
expenditures while the public institutions index is based on measures of the enforcement of
contracts and law and degree of competition.
Table 5 Competitiveness Indicators for Malaysia and Philippines
Country Growth
Competitiveness
Index
Macro
Environment
Index
Public
Institution
Index
2004 2006 2004 2006 2004 2006
Malaysia 29 26 27 31 43 18
Philippines 66 71 60 62 85 88
Source: World Economic Forum, Global Competitiveness Report, 2003-2004 and 2006-2007.

A recent study by the Asian Development Bank-World Bank (2009) confirmed these
findings. The ADB study (see Table 5b) indicated that macro instability in the Philippines
remains a major concern for investors because of the countrys serious fiscal problems.
Moreover, the poor quality of key infrastructure services, a fragile and underdeveloped financial
54

system, and a perception that contracting and regulatory uncertainty adds to the costs of doing
business which also makes investors hesitant. The surveyed firms identified corruption and
macroeconomic instability as the two biggest impediments to a good investment climate in the
Philippines. Electricity supply, security and regulatory uncertainty also figured prominently.
A recent study by the Asian Development Bank-World Bank (2009) confirmed these
findings. The ADB study indicated that macro instability in the Philippines remains a major
concern for investors because of the countrys serious fiscal problems. Moreover, the poor
quality of key infrastructure services, a fragile and underdeveloped financial system, and a
perception that contracting and regulatory uncertainty adds to the costs of doing business which
also makes investors hesitant. The surveyed firms identified corruption and macroeconomic
instability as the two biggest impediments to a good investment climate in the Philippines.
Electricity supply, security and regulatory uncertainty also figured prominently.
A comparison of the business costs indicators for Malaysia and the Philippines and the
World Banks doing business indicators showed the same concerns on costs of doing business as
well as complexity and uncertainty in contract enforcement. It also revealed that the Philippines
in 2006 data made substantial improvements in the indicators such as time to start a business,
cost to register business, procedures to enforce contracts, and employments laws index which all
showed reductions. Malaysia was still ahead of Philippine performance in term of effectiveness
and efficiency of its business institutional framework except for number of procedures to enforce
a contract and cost to register a business wherein the Philippines had an edge over Malaysia.




55



Table 5b Cost of Doing Business Indicators

Country Number of
start-up
procedures
Time to
start a
business
(days)
Cost to
register
Business
(% of per
capita GNI)
Procedures
to enforce a
contract
Time to
enforce a
contract
(days)
Employment
laws index:
range 0 (less
rigid) to 100
(very rigid)
Year
A B A B A B A B A B A B
Malaysia 8 9 31 30 27 19.7 22 31 270 450 25 10
Philippines 11 11 59 48 24 18.7 28 25 164 600 60 39
Note: A: 2003-2004 and B: 2006-2007.
Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators, 2004 and 2006.


The ADB-World Bank (2009) survey on (see Table 5c) business costs in the Philippines
showed differences in perceptions between foreign and domestic firms. In general, the findings
revealed that macro instability and corruption are the most important constraints to business,
followed by electricity and tax rates. Foreign firms, however, regarded customs regulations,
telecommunications, transportation, labor regulations, crime and labor skills as the most
important constraints.
Furthermore, in another study by the World Bank Group, economies were ranked (see Table
14) on their ease of doing business, from 1 183, with first place being the best. A high ranking
on the ease of doing business index means the regulatory environment was conducive to the
operation of business. This index averages the country's percentile rankings on 10 topics which
were made up of a variety of indicators, giving equal weight to each topic.
Protection to investors was much better in Malaysia than in the Philippines. In the overall,
Malaysia business regulations, policies in conducting business and attracting investors were
much more favorable.
56



Table 5c Doing Business Regulations Measures
Ranked by Region: East Asia and Pacific
Economy Ease of
Doing
Busine
ss
Rank
Startin
g a
Busine
ss
Dealing
with
Constructi
on Permits
Employi
ng
Workers
Registeri
ng
Property
Gettin
g
Credit
Protecti
ng
Investor
s
Payin
g
Taxes
Tradin
g
Across
Border
s
Enforcin
g
Contrac
ts
Closing
a
Busine
ss
Malaysia 4 10 19 14 13 1 3 7 5 8 7
Philippin
es
21 23 20 20 15 16 18 23 11 17 19
World Ranking
Malaysia 23 88 109 61 86 1 4 24 35 59 57
Philippin
es
144 162 111 115 102 127 132 135 68 118 153
Source: The World Bank Group (2009) IFC


In terms of other tax incentives (see Table 15), Malaysia and the Philippines, offered almost
similar incentives such as tax holidays, reduced corporate income tax rates, investment
allowances and credits, import duty and VAT exemptions; although there were some differences
on the terms and conditions under which the incentives can be availed of.
Table 5d Tax Incentives in Malaysia and the Philippines

Tax Incentive Malaysia Philippines
Tax holidays 5 years on 70-100% of statutory income &
10
years for companies of national strategic
interest
3-8 years
Reduced
corporate
income tax rates
3% for offshore companies in Labuan &
10% for foreign fund management
companies
For zone enterprises, exemption
from national & local taxes &
instead a special 5% tax rate on
gross income
Import duty &
VAT
exemptions
Exemptions & reduced import duty &
VAT rates on inputs in certain sectors
especially exporters
Tax & duty free importation of
capital equipment & raw
materials for zone enterprises; tax
credit on raw materials &
supplies for BOI registered firms
Investment
allowances &
credits
Investment allowance of 60-100% of
qualifying capital expenditure
Tax credits for purchases of
domestic breeding stocks &
genetic material as well as
57

for incremental revenue
Accelerated
depreciation
Accelerated depreciation of computer
technology &
Environmental protection investments
Immediate expensing of major
Infrastructure investments by
export enterprises in less
developed areas
Source: Chalk (2001) and Price Waterhouse Coopers (2001) as cited in Fletcher (2002).


Thus, in the overall, the competitiveness of Malaysia through the indicators above
contributed more to the economy and business of the country as compared to the Philippines.
CONTRIBUTION OF CRITICAL ECONOMIC INDICATORS

Consumption in Malaysia increased from USD 14 billion in 1977 to USD 187 billion in
2007 (see Table 5e) and this contributed to the growth of GDP in the country. On the other
hand, consumption in the Philippines grew from USD 14 billion in 1977 to USD 114 billion in
2007 which was lesser than Malaysias growth in this category. The foreign direct investments
(net inflow) in Malaysia increased from USD 1 billion in 1979 to USD 8 billion in 2007 while
for the Philippines it had foreign direct investments (net inflow) of USD 1 billion in 1988 and
this increased to USD 3 billion in 2007. It can be observed here that Malaysia had foreign direct
investments as early as 1979 while the Philippines had foreign investments only in 1988.
Moreover, the foreign direct investments in Malaysia were much bigger as compared to the
Philippines and this was an advantage for the economic development of Malaysia.
The general government final expenditure of Malaysia increased from USD 2 billion in 1977
to USD 23 billion in 2007 and this had definitely contributed to the growth of GDP as it was the
role of government to help in the development of the economy (see Table 5). In comparison, the
Philippines (see Table 6) had a government expenditure of USD 2 billion in 1977 and this
increased to USD 14 billion in 2007. If we compare the government expenditures for both
58

countries, it can be observed that Malaysia had a much bigger figure as compared to the
Philippines.
Another critical economic indicator for economic growth is gross capital formation
(investment) and Malaysia posted USD 3 billion in 1977 and this improved to USD 41 billion in
2007. In contrast, the Philippines had a higher investment with USD 6 billion in 1977 and this
improved to USD 22 billion in 2007 which was lower compared to Malaysia. It can be observed
here that the GDP of Malaysia was lower compared to the Philippines from 1977 to 1989 and
was equal in 1990. In 1991, the GDP of Malaysia started to be higher than the Philippines and
became much higher until 2007. Malaysias GDP was only USD 14 billion in 1977 while the
Philippines had a higher GDP with USD 20 billion for the same year. However, the GDP of
Malaysia increased to USD 49 billion in 1991 while the Philippines had a lower GDP with USD
45 billion. The GDP of Malaysia further increased to USD 187 billion in 2007 while the
Philippines had a much lower economic growth with a GDP of USD 144 billion for the same
year.
Again, it can be observed here that the gross capital formation of Malaysia was almost
double than that of the Philippines. This is where the investment policy of Malaysia had been
implemented well in the country with its 20 year long term development plan which had paid off.
The Philippines had a shorter development horizon through medium term development plans and
earlier planning was not that centralized as compared to the planning agency of Malaysia. The
implementation of getting investments was also reflected in the gross domestic savings of the
country. A crucial economic indicator for any country is domestic savings and Malaysia had only
USD 4 billion in 1997 but this ballooned to USD 79 billion in 2007. On the other hand, the
Philippines had a higher domestic savings in 1977 with USD 5 billion in 1977 and this increased
59

to only USD 23 billion in 2007 as compared to Malaysia with USD 79 billion for the same year.
The Medium Term Development Plan for the Philippines (see appendix) calls for increased in
domestic savings but because of the low savings rate and the absence of a mature financial
market in the country, domestic savings did not take off as compared with Malaysia.
Table 5e Malaysia Critical Economic Indicators, 1977-2007 (in USD billion)
Time GDP Cons FDI
net
Govt
Exp
Exports Imports investment GDS GFCF
1977 14 9 0 2 6 5 3 4 3
1978 17 11 0 3 7 6 4 5 4
1979 22 14 1 3 11 8 6 8 5
1980 25 17 1 4 13 11 7 7 7
1981 25 18 1 4 12 12 8 6 9
1982 27 20 1 5 12 13 9 7 10
1983 31 21 1 5 14 13 10 9 11
1984 35 22 1 5 17 14 10 11 11
1985 32 22 1 5 15 12 8 9 9
1986 28 19 0 5 14 10 7 8 7
1987 32 20 0 5 18 12 7 11 7
1988 35 22 1 5 21 16 8 12 9
1989 39 25 2 5 25 20 11 13 11
1990 44 29 2 6 29 26 14 15 15
1991 49 32 4 7 34 33 19 17 18
1992 59 37 5 8 40 37 21 22 22
1993 67 41 5 8 46 43 26 26 26
1994 74 45 4 9 57 55 31 29 30
1995 89 54 4 11 72 72 39 35 39
1996 101 58 5 11 77 73 42 43 43
1997 100 56 5 11 78 74 43 44 43
1998 72 37 2 7 72 54 19 35 19
1999 79 42 4 9 84 61 18 38 17
2000 94 51 4 10 98 78 25 43 24
2001 93 54 1 11 88 70 23 39 23
2002 101 58 3 13 93 75 25 42 24
2003 110 63 2 14 105 79 25 47 25
2004 125 71 5 16 127 99 29 54 26
2005 138 79 4 17 142 109 28 59 28
2006 156 89 6 19 161 123 33 68 33
2007 187 108 8 23 176 139 41 79 40
Source: The World Bank
60


Another critical economic indicator was exports and Malaysia posted USD 6 billion in 1977
and this improved very much in 2007 with USD 176 billion which was almost the GDP figure of
USD 187 billion. However, the Philippines had only goods exports of USD 3 billion in 1977 and
this increased to only USD 50 billion in 2007. As such, it can be evaluated here that in this
category alone, the Philippines economic performance was quite inferior compared to Malaysia.
Table 6 Philippines Selected Economic Indicators, 1977 to 2007 (in USD billion)
Time GDP Consumption FDI Net Govt.
Exp
Exports Imports Investments GDS GFCF
1977 20 14 0 2 3 4 6 5 5
1978 23 17 0 2 3 5 7 6 6
1979 28 20 0 3 5 6 8 7 7
1980 32 24 0 3 6 8 9 8 9
1981 36 26 0 3 6 8 10 9 10
1982 37 28 0 3 5 8 10 8 10
1983 33 24 0 3 5 7 10 8 10
1984 31 24 0 2 5 6 6 6 7
1985 31 25 0 2 5 5 4 5 5
1986 30 24 0 2 5 5 5 6 5
1987 33 26 0 3 6 7 6 6 5
1988 38 30 1 3 7 8 7 8 7
1989 43 34 1 4 8 10 9 8 9
1990 44 36 1 4 8 12 11 8 10
1991 45 38 1 5 9 12 9 8 9
1992 53 45 0 5 10 15 11 9 11
1993 54 47 1 5 11 18 13 8 13
1994 64 55 2 7 13 21 15 11 15
1995 74 63 1 8 17 26 17 11 16
1996 83 71 2 10 21 32 20 13 19
1997 82 71 1 11 25 36 20 12 20
1998 65 57 2 9 29 30 13 9 14
1999 76 65 1 10 34 40 14 14 15
2000 76 63 2 10 37 43 16 18 16
2001 71 59 0 9 31 38 14 11 13
2002 77 62 2 9 34 40 14 13 14
2003 80 64 0 9 35 41 13 9 13
2004 87 69 1 9 39 44 15 11 14
61

2005 99 78 2 10 40 48 14 10 14
2006 118 94 3 11 47 53 17 16 16
2007 144 114 3 14 50 58 22 23 21
Source: The World Bank
The export development policy of Malaysia was better and implemented well as it also
pursued the development of high-technology exports that were in demand in other countries
while the Philippines lagged behind in terms of high-technology exports and was inferior in
terms of implementing its export development plan.
In addition, gross fixed capital formation which was important in manufacturing and
industrialization was again favorable for Malaysia which posted USD 3 billion in 1977 but this
jumped to USD 40 billion in 2007. Although the Philippines gross fixed capital formation was
higher in 1977 with USD 5 billion, this increased to only USD 21 billion in 2007. Again, in
comparison, this indicator which was vital for industrialization was much lower as compared to
Malaysia.
Analysis of the Components of GDP and Balance of Payments
The balance of payments of Malaysia was always on a surplus which increased from USD 1
billion in 1991 to USD 37 billion in 2007. On the contrary, the Philippines balance of payments
were always negative which increased from negative USD 3 billion in 1991 to negative -USD 8
billion in 2007. As such, this was one factor that hampered the growth of GDP in the Philippines
and which was favorable for Malaysia. The investments portion of Malaysia contributed to the
growth of GDP as it increased from USD 19 billion in 1991 to USD 41 billion in 2007. On the
other hand, the Philippines investment portion contributed to GDP with USD 38 billion in 1991
which resulted to a GDP of USD 45 billion during the same year. Its net exports (BOP),
however, was a negative factor and it decreased the GDP with negative USD 3 billion for the
same year. The GDP of the Philippines grew to USD 144 billion in 2007 and the biggest
62

contributor was again consumption with USD 114 billion while investment also contributed with
only USD 22 billion. Government expenditures also helped in GDP growth with USD 14 billion
in 2007 while net exports (BOP) was a disaster sinking the GDP growth with negative USD 8
billion in 2007. On the other hand, Malaysias consumption was the biggest contributor with
USD 32 billion to its GDP of USD 49 billion. Also for the same period, government
expenditures contributed USD 7 billion. The contribution of net exports (BOP) to the GDP was
USD 1 billion for the same period. This had increased over the years and in 2007, its GDP
valued at USD billion was supported by investment which contributed USD 41 billion while
consumption was again the biggest contributor with USD 108 billion. Net exports (BOP) also
contributed USD 37 billion to the GDP.
Table 7 Malaysia GDP, Investment, Consumption, Government Expenditures, Balance of
Payments, 1991 to 2007 (in USD billion).
Time GDP investment Cons Govt
Exp
Exports Imports BOP
1991 49 19 32 7 34 33 1
1992 59 21 37 8 40 37 3
1993 67 26 41 8 46 43 3
1994 74 31 45 9 57 55 2
1995 89 39 54 11 72 72 0
1996 101 42 58 11 77 73 4
1997 100 43 56 11 78 74 4
1998 72 19 37 7 72 54 18
1999 79 18 42 9 84 61 23
2000 94 25 51 10 98 78 20
2001 93 23 54 11 88 70 18
2002 101 25 58 13 93 75 18
2003 110 25 63 14 105 79 26
2004 125 29 71 16 127 99 28
2005 138 28 79 17 142 109 33
2006 156 33 89 19 161 123 38
2007 187 41 108 23 176 139 37
Source: The World Bank

63




Table 7b Philippines GDP, Investment, Consumption, Government Expenditures, Balance
of Payments, 1991 to 2007 (in USD billions)
Time GDP Investments Consumption Govt.
Exp
Exports Imports BOP
1991 45 9 38 5 9 12 -3
1992 53 11 45 5 10 15 -5
1993 54 13 47 5 11 18 -7
1994 64 15 55 7 13 21 -8
1995 74 17 63 8 17 26 -9
1996 83 20 71 10 21 32 -11
1997 82 20 71 11 25 36 -11
1998 65 13 57 9 29 30 -1
1999 76 14 65 10 34 40 -6
2000 76 16 63 10 37 43 -6
2001 71 14 59 9 31 38 -7
2002 77 14 62 9 34 40 -6
2003 80 13 64 9 35 41 -6
2004 87 15 69 9 39 44 -5
2005 99 14 78 10 40 48 -8
2006 118 17 94 11 47 53 -6
2007 144 22 114 14 50 58 -8
Source: The World Bank


Initial Endowment, Reserves, Debt, and Manufacturing
In terms of initial endowment, Malaysia had large oil reserves and energy where they export
them to other countries while the Philippines only had a small oil reserve which was being
developed during the period from 1977 to 2007. As such, this initial endowment gave a critical
edge to Malaysias economic development. The property rights in Malaysia was a success and it
64

was crucial to its development while in the Philippines, land reform was a failure and this
hampered the countrys economic growth.
Moreover, the total reserves of Malaysia was over USD 3 billion in 1977 and it grew to USD
102 billion in 2007 and this showed the economic strength of Malaysia as this was an indicator
of its economic surplus. On the other hand, the total reserves of the Philippines was only USD
1.6 billion in 1977 and this grew to only USD 34 billion in 2007. As such, the strength of
Malaysias reserves was three times higher than the Philippines.
In addition, the debt service as a % of GNI of Malaysia posted 6% in 1977 and this still
remained at 6% in 2007 while the Philippines had 3% in 1977 and increased to 6% in 2007. As
such, there was not that much disparity for both countries in this category.
In terms of industrialization as a % of GDP, Malaysia posted 19% in 1977 and it grew to
28% in 2007. On the other hand, the Philippines had 25% in 1977 which was higher than
Malaysia initially but it fell to only 22% in 2007. As such, while Malaysia was increasing its
industrialization, the Philippines was declining.
Table 8 Malaysia Total Reserves, Total Debt Service (% of GNI), Manufacturing Value
Added As % of GDP, 1977 to 2007
Time Total reserves (includes gold,
current US$)
Total debt service (% of GNI) Manuf valued as % of GDP
1977 3,070,865,766 6 19

1978 3,670,452,656 7 20 3,300,991,801

1979 5,005,509,030 4 20 4,369,624,213

1980 5,754,998,625 4 22 5,374,619,146

1981 5,024,214,147 5 21 5,327,141,591

1982 4,832,355,575 6 19 5,199,735,754

1983 4,672,614,680 7 19 5,925,836,267

1984 4,441,615,462 8 19 6,674,883,342

1985 5,677,019,647 18 19 6,137,393,596

1986 6,942,089,619 13 19 5,458,522,341

1987 8,572,963,559 15 20 6,373,234,215

1988 7,490,587,819 18 22 7,697,036,909

1989 8,733,333,838 12 24 9,246,898,921

65

1990 10,658,832,532 10 24 10,664,719,314

1991 11,716,563,664 6 26 12,553,725,881

1992 18,023,987,500 8 26 15,274,397,891

1993 28,182,868,709 8 26 17,343,149,068

1994 26,338,866,593 9 27 19,842,244,208

1995 24,698,753,699 7 26 23,432,358,193

1996 27,891,911,688 9 28 28,079,812,580

1997 21,470,189,843 7 28 28,428,124,086

1998 26,235,703,349 9 29 20,774,007,824

1999 30,930,645,528 6 31 24,485,526,135

2000 28,650,938,059 7 31 28,946,842,468

2001 29,845,803,324 7 29 27,219,474,026

2002 33,761,681,180 8 29 29,493,684,581

2003 44,309,888,341 9 30 32,982,105,677

2004 66,393,548,615 8 30 37,896,579,423

2005 70,458,191,541 7 30 40,837,813,462

2006 82,876,090,372 5 30 46,279,101,467

2007 101,994,769,392 6 28 52,223,602,140

Source: The World Bank

Table 8b Philippines Total Reserves, Total Debt Service (% of GNI), Manufacturing Value
Added as % of GDP, 1977 to 2007
Time Total Reserves Total debt service (% of
GNI)
Manufacturing, value added (% of
GDP)
1977 1,653,546,073 3 25
1978 2,104,978,493 6 26
1979 3,121,121,301 6 25
1980 3,977,980,295 7 26
1981 2,725,396,313 8 26
1982 1,740,333,175 10 25
1983 857,185,285 9 24
1984 844,406,816 9 25
1985 1,098,200,654 9 25
1986 2,611,227,401 10 25
1987 2,312,132,594 10 25
1988 2,168,908,351 9 26
1989 2,398,208,886 8 25
1990 2,036,231,563 8 25
1991 4,436,166,921 7 25
1992 5,335,691,000 8 24
66

1993 5,933,972,406 9 24
1994 7,146,366,699 7 23
1995 7,780,875,204 7 23
1996 11,775,611,252 6 23
1997 8,744,996,306 5 22
1998 10,837,476,487 7 22
1999 15,068,980,979 8 22
2000 15,074,070,373 9 22
2001 15,682,884,986 12 23
2002 16,321,044,786 12 23
2003 17,083,609,581 12 23
2004 16,234,406,188 12 23
2005 18,474,495,834 9 23
2006 22,963,019,934 11 23
2007 33,740,202,851 6 22
Source: The World Bank
Money and Interest Rates
In terms of money (M1/M2) as % of GDP, Malaysia had 63% in 1977 and this grew to
116% in 2007 while the Philippines had only 22% in 1977 and it grew to only 53% in 2007. As
such, compared to Malaysia, the velocity and circulation of money were much lower and this
was crucial for its economic growth from 1997 to 2007.
As regard to real interest rates, Malaysia had 5% in 1987 and this decreased to only 1% in
2007 while the Philippines had 3% in 1977 and this increased to 6% in 2007. In terms of lending
rates, Malaysia had 10% in 1987 and increased to 12% during the Asian crisis but this decreased
to 6% in 2007. On the other hand, the lending rates in the Philippines increased from 12% in
1977 to 17% during the Asian crisis and gradually declined to 9% in 2007. Thus, the lending
rates were lower in Malaysia than in the Philippines. Lower interest rates means easy money
policy and this explains the huge circulation of money in Malaysia while in the Philippines, it
had in most of the years tight money policy which discouraged entrepreneurs to borrow money
and this affected its economic growth.
67




Table 9 Malaysia Interest Rates, M1 and M2, Lending Interest Rate, Interest Rate Spread
1977 to 2007
Time Real
Inter
M1
and
M2 as
% of
GDP
Lend
Int R
Int R
spread
1977 .. 63 .. ..
1978 .. 66 .. ..
1979 .. 66 .. ..
1980 .. 71 .. ..
1981 .. 81 .. ..
1982 .. 87 .. ..
1983 .. 91 .. ..
1984 .. 93 .. ..
1985 .. 108 .. ..
1986 .. 130 .. ..
1987 5 126 10 7
1988 5 116 9 6
1989 4 118 9 4
1990 5 89 9 3
1991 6 62 9 2
1992 8 81 10 2
1993 6 101 10 3
1994 5 105 9 4
1995 5 107 9 3
1996 6 111 10 3
1997 7 117 11 3
1998 3 125 12 4
1999 9 125 9 4
2000 -1 117 8 4
2001 9 130 7 4
2002 3 127 7 3
2003 3 123 6 3
2004 0 120 6 3
2005 1 118 6 3
2006 3 117 6 3
68

2007 1 116 6 3
Source: The World Bank
Furthermore, the interest rate spread in Malaysia was 7% in 1987 and this declined to 3% in
2007 while the interest rate spread in the Philippines was 5% in 1987 and remained at 5% in
2007.

Table 10 Philippines Real Interest Rate, M1 and M2, Lending Interest Rate, and Interest
Rate Spread, 1977 to 2007
Time Real
Int R
M1/M2
as %
of
GDP
Lend
Int R
Int R Spread
1977 3 21 12 4
1978 2 23 12 4
1979 -1 23 14 5
1980 0 22 14 2
1981 3 23 15 2
1982 9 24 18 4
1983 4 28 19 6
1984 -16 26 28 7
1985 9 27 29 10
1986 14 27 18 6
1987 5 26 13 5
1988 6 26 16 5
1989 9 29 19 5
1990 10 31 24 5
1991 6 32 23 4
1992 11 34 19 5
1993 7 38 15 5
1994 5 42 15 5
1995 7 47 15 6
1996 7 51 15 5
1997 9 56 16 6
1998 6 59 17 5
1999 3 60 12 4
2000 4 59 11 3
2001 6 58 12 4
2002 4 57 9 5
69

2003 5 56 9 4
2004 4 53 10 4
2005 3 51 10 5
2006 4 52 10 4
2007 6 53 9 5
Source: The World Bank


MULTIPLE REGRESSION ANALYSIS

The multiple regression analysis of the critical economic indicators above for Malaysia and
the Philippines for the period 1991 to 2007 yielded (see Table 11) an adjusted R2 of 0.999882
for Malaysia which means that there was a very high positive relationship with GDP between the
eight critical economic indicators which were consumption (X1), foreign direct investment (net
inflow) (X2), government expenditures (X3), exports (X4), imports (X5), investments (X6),
gross domestic savings (X7), and gross fixed capital formation (X8).
The regression coefficient for consumption (X1) was 1.04 while for foreign direct investment
(X2) was -0.21. The regression coefficient for government expenditures (X3) was 0.08 while for
exports (X4) was -0.13. The regression coefficient for imports was 0.09 and for investments (X6)
is -0.03. Finally, the regression coefficient for gross domestic savings (X7) was 1.12 and for
gross fixed capital formation (X8) was 0.07. The regression coefficient was the expected
change per unit for every unit changed in the dependent variable Y all other things being equal.
On the other hand, the Philippines had an adjusted R square of 0.996163 which also means
that there was a strong relationship between the growth of GDP and the eight critical economic
indicators which were consumption (X1), foreign direct investment (net inflow) (X2),
70

government expenditures (X3), exports (X4), imports (X5), investments (X6), gross domestic
savings (X7), and gross fixed capital formation (X8).
The regression coefficients for X1 was 1.28 and for X2 was -0.57. In addition,(see details of
multiple regression output in the appendix) the regression coefficients for X3 was -2.41 while
for X4 was 0.60. In addition, X5 registered a regression coefficient of -0.25 and X6 resulted to
1.44. Finally, the regression coefficient for X7 was 0.27 and for X8 it was -1.0.

Table 11 Summary of Multiple Regression Results
Country Adj. R
Square
X1
Coef
X2
Coef
X3
Coef
X4
Coef
X5
Coef
X6
Coef
X7
Coef
X8
Coef
Malaysia .999882 1.04 -0.21 0.08 -0.13 0.09 -0.03 1.12 -0.07
Philippines .996163 1.28 -0.57 -2.41 0.60 -0.25 1.44 0.27 -1.09

In the over-all the eight critical economic indicators were vital for the economic
development of both countries as supported by the multiple regression analysis.









71

CHAPTER FIVE: ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL POLICIES

What were the factors that made Malaysia better than the Philippines? According to
Yoshihara (2004), Malaysia adopted new economic policies in the early 70s and restricted the
economic freedom of the Chinese who were the backbone of the economy then but the
Malaysian was not that strict to the Chinese. During the Marcos regime, the Philippines restricted
foreign investments and imports much more than Malaysia. In addition, the Philippine state
developed monopolies on commodity trade and interrupted the economy by creating government
corporations which controlled the prices of basic commodities and services.
Furthermore, the Philippines and Malaysia had communist insurgency problems but
Malaysia was able to shut it down while in the Philippines it still continues and continued to
create havoc to the economy. Crimes in the Philippines had been higher in terms of kidnapping
of businessmen especially Chinese (Yoshihara, 2004).
Thus, Malaysia was really a stronger state than the Philippines in the sense that it had
destroyed its bad habits and created new programs that made its government more effective and
with lesser graft and corruption as compared to the Philippines.
The Malaysian strategy concentrated on liberalization, privatization, and globalization and
these were successfully done from the 1970s to the 1990s. As such, investments in the country
increased and became one of the highest in Southeast Asia. And this was a major factor in the
change in the structure of the economy which shifted from agriculture to manufacturing.
Liberalization was adopted throughout the country this greatly enhanced the economic strength
and competitiveness of the nation. Most of the investments were focused into electronics and
exports whereas a big part went into capital-intensive infrastructure and the real estate sector.
72

The state made various changes which cut the deficits of the government, and was able to
restore fiscal balance. Reforms were made to open up the economy in terms of traded as well as
in terms of the payment system and as such supported the development of the export base of the
country. The high growth during the 1980s persisted and this resulted to high improvements in
living standards. The economy diversified and this was supported with the restructuring of the
banking sector during the decade of the 1980s.
The strong economic development of the country persisted during the 1990s before the crisis.
However, some signs of stress already existed as exports declined and a big current account
deficit occurred due to the appreciation of the ringgit exchange rate. However, the investment-
based plan was effective in increasing production and income although the quality of the
investments decreased. As such, crucial financial weaknesses in the banking sector as well as in
the corporate world made it vulnerable for the crisis in Asia that was forthcoming. The crisis
pressured the currencies the countries in Asia and triggered a currency crisis followed also by a
banking crisis.. Nevertheless, the countrys external debt which was quite low helped in
preventing a crisis in external debt.
The fragile economy of Malaysia weakened and this increased during early 1997 and up to
the middle of the same year. The country experienced a market confidence crisis and this was
also the experience of the other countries in the region including the Philippines. Major portfolio
investments flowed out of the country and equities and real estate values hugely declined. The
Malaysian currency was under tremendous pressure and traders made speculative actions in
anticipating a large devaluation of the ringgit. As a result, the offshore ringgit interest rates s
increased in relation to domestic rates. This resulted to the increased in the outflow of ringgit
73

funds and this had affected the liquidity of banks as well hampered their financial strucures. The
corporate world also experienced major financial problems because of the decreased in real
estate value and the equities utilized as collateral for banks.
The state initially responded to the crisis by increasing interest rates and squeezed fiscal
policy in order to restore market confidence to the financial system. However, these policies did
not work well and as such in early 1998, fiscal policy was modified to an expansion posture. At
any rate, this policy was not enough to restore external imbalances.
Thus, the Malaysian state implemented a policy package in September 1998 and this was
designed to protect monetary policy from the volatility of the external economy. The policy
integrated an exchange rate based on the U.S. dollar and selected exchange and financial
measures. Furthermore, a fiscal stimulus package increased investment spending and these
measures resulted to the gradual decline in interest rates. The Malaysian state also made major
reforms in the banking and corporate sectors and this consolidated and upgraded financial
regulations based on international standards.
Some weaknesses in the Malaysian economy during the 2000 to 2004 period occurred such
as major dependence on electronic exports made the economy vulnerable to the global slowdown
in the areas of computers and information technology. The depreciations of the yen and other
currencies in the regions affected the ringgit and resulted to its large appreciation during March
and April of 2001. This resulted to capital outflows and reserves losses in the short-term. This
problems which simultaneously happened in the context of a global slowdown hitting the
economy affected the confidence in the market. At any rate, this external volatility of Malaysia
was well controlled because of the large current account surplus of the country as well as its low
74

short-term external debt. Moreover, the country strong reserves position also helped in
maintaining economic balance. The financial sector at this time also had improved banks
capacity in risks management.
There is the continuing process of industrialization in Malaysia and it is going up the value
chain in manufacturing with higher technology utilizing skills, and with new and materials which
are advanced (see Appendix 7).The breakthroughs in R and D worldwide in terms of materials,
products, and processes have developed investors in manufacturing along this line. The academe
and the industry joined in hand in developing high technology in manufacturing and this was
reflected in the high technology exports of Malaysia. This exports were also responsible for the
its high GDP growth rate from 2001 to 2007.
The government offers tax incentives for those who were in Pioneer Status for high
technology products and services and so far the government had invested RM 8.1294 billion for
the advancement of this projects during 2001 and 2004.
Hutchcroft (1994) in his study of the Philippine state in the banking industry concluded that
the state was weak in terms of its poor performance and efficacy in the financial system.
However, he discovered that the state as represented by the Central Bank was a captive of
powerful elites who were autonomous and powerful. It was a also a source for cheap loans vital
to their further accumulation of wealth. He further contend that the Philippine state is continually
bombarded with demands of favored elites with particularistic demands such as favored loans or
licenses in the banking industry.
According to him, the Philippine Financial System is defective and it does not work for the
greater benefits of those who need it in society. Hutccroft explains further: If the system
75

genuinely worked for the greater good, perhaps weak state regulation and rampant favoritism
could be overlooked. But it does not: there are four major areas in which the Philippine financial
system performs poorly and hampers larger developmental objectives. First, it discourages the
efficient allocation of credit. There are three major types of commercial banks: patronage-
infested government banks (most importantly, the Philippine National Bank, but formerly two
small banks as well), a large number of private banks, most of which are family-dominated, and
four highly profitable branches of foreign banks, all of which have been in operation since at
least the late 1940s (1994, p. 66).
According to Hutchcroft (1994), the other major areas in which the Philippine financial
system are weak and which hampers growth are the following:
1. First priority in loan allocation by government banks generally goes to those with
greatest proximity to the political machinery. Within private domestic banks, first priority
on loans commonly goes to related enterprises of the extended family owning the bank.
The basic building blocks of the Philippine business community are extended family
conglomerates, and the surest means for such groups to secure a credit is through
ownership (or partial ownership) of a commercial bank. If an entrepreneur lacks access
through either of these channels, credit is very hard to obtain no matter how well it might
be put to use (1984, p. 66).
2. The banking system has a weak record of mobilizing savings, a key element in most any
successful program of economic development. In part because real savings deposit rates
have generally been negative over the past two decades, the Philippines has by far the
worst record of promoting financial intermediation M3/GNP have been very weak: .20 in
76

1970, peaking at .31 in 1983, and falling to .23 in 1988. This has led to considerable
reliance on foreign savings, which may have been allocated even more inefficiently than
domestic savings (1994, p. 66).
3. The banking system has created a high degree of financial instability, the root cause of
which is regulators inability to curb the milking of loan portfolios by bank owners,
directors, and officers for related family enterprises. Banks have occupied a central role
in profit-making strategies of the large family-based conglomerates that control much of
the Philippine economy. In the 1980s and particularly in the early 1960s, oligarchs
acquired banks to serve the credit needs of their family business empires; by 1965, nearly
every major family had gotten in on the act. Among bank owners, loyalty is rarely to
banking per se, but rather to the family conglomerate that the bank is meant to serve. In
some cases, banks have been literally milked to death (1994, pp. 66-67).
4. Finally, the banking system provides enormous profits to those banks that are primarily in
the business of banking for the sake of banking profits. Bankers enjoy oligopolistic power
that is unchallenged by the Central Bank, and the head staffers at the Bankers Association
of the Philippines actually admitted that prices for banking services are set by the actions
of a cartel. The large interest rate spreads guarantee high levels of profitability for those
banks whose loan portfolios are less fragrantly milked by their directors, officers, and
stockholders. As a result, the four foreign banks find profits from their Philippines
branches to be among the highest in their international branch network (1994, p. 67).
Rivera (1994) in his study also recognized the existence of a cartel in the banking system
where a few banks control the financial system and wherein there was a web of complex between
the industrial and banking sector. He writes:
77

Not only do the landed families dominate the manufacturing sector; they also
control the leading private commercial banks in the country. Of the top 10 local
private banks in 1986, six, including the largest private banks in 1986, including
the oldest and largest, the Bank of the Philippine Islands, were controlled by
landed capitalist families (1994, p.50).
Rivera also mentioned in his study that the affluent class as represented by local
manufacturers availed of low-interest, long-term loans offered by government financial
institutions (GFIs) and these have proven to be an indispensable source of capital for them. He
writes:
Both the landed and non-landed segments of the manufacturing class, including
Chinese-Filipino capitalists have availed themselves of this important resource. In
particular, a number of textile, cement, fertilizer, and pulp and paper companies
received substantial loans from GFIs like the Development Bank of the
Philippines (DBP), the Philippine National Bank (PNB), the National Investment
and Development Corporation (NIDC), and the Government Service Insurance
System (GSIS) (1994, pp, 57-58).
Rivera further explains the abuse of the use of GFIs both by the state and by the aristocracy:
While there exists a long tradition of borrowing from GFIs, it was grossly abused
during the Marcos regime through cronyism and the state practice of guaranteeing
loans incurred by private corporations, particularly of the cronies, many of whom
later defaulted on their payments (Rivera 1994, p. 58). For instance, by 1992, the
Philippine National Bank (PNB) had loaned over 60 percent of its equity to a
single corporation, the crony-controlled Construction and Development
Corporation of the Philippines (CDCP), and was later forced to convert its loans
into company equity upon default by CDCP on its outstanding debts (1994,
p.58).
In the case of a major housing financial institution which is the Government Service
Insurance System (GSIS), it was also the source of funds for pet projects of Marcos and his
cronies. Manapat (1991) writes:
The majority of investments and loans of the GSIS in 1971 were policy, salary,
and housing loans to GSIS members.These loans represented 82% of GSIS
investments. These loans to members, however, had dramatically declined by
78

1980. Housing loans for members, for example, were phased out. But during the
same period, loans and investments of the GSIS in Marcos-connected companies
and Imelda-inspired projects rose to USD843 million or 65% of the USD 1.3
billion the GSIS earned as income by the end of 1980. The CDCP conglomerate
of Cuenca was a constant recipient of GSIS money, from the start of the
construction boom until the time that this conglomerate collapsed (Manapat 1991,
p. 372).
Again, GSIS money, not available for housing for almost two thirds of the population of the
Philippines, were used to fatten the coffers of the Marcos cronies. Government Financial
Institutions (GFIs) were the favorite sources of low-interest and long term loans by a particular
class or group which had access to the state machinery.
On the other hand, the financial system in the Philippines provides enormous profits to those
financial institutions and banks that were primarily in the business of banking for the sake of
banking profits.
According to a World Bank study (World Bank, 1988: iii 73), pre-tax profit margins in the
Philippines were roughly 300 percent higher than the average of such margins in eight other. The
World Banks analysis concentrates on the distinction that must be made between the profit
structures of the stronger and weaker banks in the Philippine banking system: the more efficient
banks priced their products and services with reference to the cost structure of the smaller banks,
a practice which effectively enabled them to capture higher profits. In early 1991, savings
deposit rates were at 11 percent per annum, while prime lending rates surpassed 23 percent
interest per annum. Analysis of interest rates from 1987 to 1998 would show the same pattern of
high spreads as was in 1991. These large spreads guarantee high levels of profitability for
financial institutions and banks. The interest spread to savings ratio was 196 percent in 1987 and
290 percent in 1988. In 1989, the interest spread to savings ratio was 215 percent and dropped
79

gradually to 90 percent in 1997. Nevertheless, the spreads were still too high in the banking
system.
This financial policy which concerns the interest rate spreads in the Philippines which were
very high and which continued even today affected the growth of savings which were needed for
sustainable investments in the Philippines. Since the savings were low due to these interest
spreads that resulted lower investment levels, the GDP growth of the country was lower as
compared to Malaysia which had tremendous increased in investments.
Moreover, the Philippines during the past had utilized import-substitution strategy but it had
some adverse affects which was based on high-tariff, quantitative restriction, and overvalued
exchange rate. However, during the period 1993-1998, policy changes meant to increasing the
competitiveness and efficiency of the industrial sector were started. The liberalization of foreign
investments were done and implemented, and as such, the foreign exchange market was also
deregulated. The Airline, banking, telecommunications, and oil industries were liberalized.
Public enterprises were encouraged to be privatized and the tariff rates were rationalized.
As a result, the macroeconomic environment significantly improved during this period. The
infrastructure problem was also solved through build, operate and transfer (BOT) schemes.
However, the problems of overvalued exchange rate, low savings rate and poor productivity have
remained. The goal of the country is to move the economy towards investments, trade and
exports. Moreover, the Medium-Term Philippine Development Plan (MTPDP) has stressed the
need to achieve global competitiveness in selected industries (see Appendices).
Competition policy in the Philippines consists of policy reforms aimed at promoting
competitive environment as well as measures formulated to prevent a decrease in competition.
80

These were exemplified as mentioned policy reforms aimed at promoting competition in the
banking industry as well as policies to encourage more players in the shipping, airline, and oil
industries. Examples of measures designed to prevent a reduction in competition are policies to
discourage mega-mergers in deregulated industries and policies against unfair business practices
in liberalized industries.
As such, the long-term economic policies of Malaysia were better than the Philippines
medium-term economic policies and these policies were also implemented well by the former as
compared to the latter.





CHAPTER SIX: CONCLUSIONS

INTRODUCTION

This study is important since the institutional analysis of Malaysia and the Philippines is a
new research that is crucial for academicians, management consultants, economists and
81

businessmen in the Southeast Asia region. It is important to compare the performance of both
countries and evaluate what went wrong and what went right.
Moreover, this study also contributes to the role of the states and institutions in economic
development that by using the state as a conceptual variable in pursuing specific kinds of
economic policies in the Philippines and Malaysia, this study would promote comparative
understanding of the capacity of the third world state in Southeast Asia.
This study utilized the institutional economics theory as well as state theory as the
conceptual framework of the study. Furthermore trend analysis of critical economic indicators
were conducted for both Malaysia and the Philippines. As such, a multiple regression analysis
was conducted in these critical economic indicators utilizing GDP as the dependent variable and
the eight critical economic indicators as independent variables as follows:
X1 Consumption
X2 Foreign Direct Investment (net inflow)
X3 Government Expenditures
X4 Exports
X5 Imports
X6 Investment
X7 Gross Domestic Savings
X8 Gross Fixed Capital Formation
Multiple Regression Analysis refers to a set of techniques for studying the straight-line
relationships among two or more variables. Multiple regression estimates the 's in the equation

82


The Xs are the independent variables (IVs). Y is the dependent variable. The subscript j
represents the observation (row) number.
Also, the historical method was utilized in this study. This method was appropriate for this
study since the period being studied happened already in the past. Historical data were gathered
during these periods and were analyzed based on state policies and actual performance.
Historical research in this study proceeded with the systematic collection and objective
evaluation of data related to past occurrences in order to test hypotheses concerning causes,
effects, or trends of those events that may help to explain present events and anticipate future
events. The descriptive method was utilized to support the historical method. Some of the data in
this study were quite recent and as such this method was utilized to describe the situation.
The originality of the data came from the World Bank, International Monetary Fund, Asian
Development Bank. The limitations of the study are that these sources came from the internet
and only a few of these data came from secondary sources.
This study was conducted based on the following research objectives:
1. To evaluate the historical and comparative economic growth of Malaysia and the
Philippines;
2. To evaluate the critical economic indicators that contributed or hampered the economic
growth of both countries;
3. To evaluate the economic policies of both countries and its impact to their economic
growth; and
4. To evaluate the role of government in the development of the economy in these two
countries.
83

REPHRASING THE RESEARCH QUESTIONS

The research questions of this study are the following:
1. What was the economic growth of Malaysia as compared to the Philippines from 1991 to
2007?
2. What were some of the critical economic indicators that contributed to Gross Domestic
Product for both countries?
3. What were the economic policies of both countries during this period?
4. What were the implications of the economic growth for the role of government for both
countries?








THE HYPOTHESES AND TEST FOR HYPOTHESES

The hypotheses of this study which are supposed to answer the research questions and
temporarily guide the study are the following:
1. The economic growth of Malaysia was superior and higher than the Philippines from 1991 to
2007.
84

2. The eight critical economic indicators namely government expenditures, gross capital
formation, goods exports, goods imports, gross domestic savings, gross fixed capital formation,
foreign investments, consumption were related to the economic growth (GDP) for both countries
3. The Malaysian government was more effective than the Philippines in shaping economic
development and these were due to better economic policies and implementation by the former
as compared to the latter.

Testing of Hypotheses
Hypothesis 1 - The economic growth of Malaysia was superior and higher than the
Philippines from 1991 to 2007
The current account balance, Malaysia had a negative figure with USD- 0,918 billion but
this improved tremendously to USD 22,784 billion in 2007 while the Philippines posted a deficit
of USD -2,690 billion in 1990 and this also improved to USD 2,096 billion in 2007. The current
account balance as a percent of GDP for Malaysia was -2.1% percent in 1990 and improved
further to 14.7% in 2007. The Philippines current balance as a percentage of GDP was --6.1 % in
1990 and this also further improved to only 1.6% in 2007.
The gross domestic product per capita at current prices of Malaysia was USD 2,431,973 in
1990 and this increased to USD 5,756,397 in 2007. In comparison, the Philippines had only
USD718,114 in 1990 and this increased to USD 1,455,301 in 2007. In this area, the Philippines
had a much lower figure as compared to Malaysia.
In the area of GDP (in constant prices) annual percent change, Malaysia had 9% percent in
1990 and this increased to 5.8% in 2007 while the Philippines had 3 percent in 1990 and this
increased to 5.6% in 2007. The GDP in current prices of Malaysia was USD 44.025 billion in
85

1990 and this improved to USD 186.721 billion in 2007. Comparably, the Philippines had USD
44.164 billion in 1990 and this also improved to USD 144.043 billion in 2007 which was lower
than the figure of Malaysia.
As regard to inflation in annual percent change, Malaysia had a low 2.6% rate in 1990 and
this increased to 5.8% in 2007 while the Philippines had a much higher rate at 13.2% in 1990 and
it decreased to 4.7% in 2007
. In the over-all, all these economic indicators proved that Malaysia did better economically in
comparison with the Philippines.
The long-term economic average of Malaysia from 1980 to 2007 in terms of output was
38.06% while the Philippines had only 21.08%. It can be observed that the long-term growth
were higher than the developed countries. It was observed that developed economies had lower
growth rates since they had already reached the maturity stage of economic growth while
developing countries such as the Philippines and Malaysia were still in the transition stage. The
real capital stock long-term economic average was 8.09% for Malaysia and it was higher than the
Philippines which was only 2.18%. As such, real capital stock played a major part in the output
(real GDP) of Malaysia while the Philippines had less. It was typical for developing countries
like the Philippines and Malaysia for having shortages in capital since their economies lacked
maturity in terms of financial markets as well as low savings which were needed for capital
formation.
Furthermore, the long-term economic average for labor or employment of Malaysia was only
2.32% while the Philippines had a higher average with 6.8%. It can be seen here that the higher
output of Malaysia was more of capital driven rather than labor driven while the Philippines
86

output was driven by labor growth. In addition, long-term productivity growth rate in Malaysia
was higher with 33.82% while the Philippines had only 15.81%.
The Malaysian long-term economic growth average for output from the 1980 to 1989 period
was 16.89% while the Philippines had only 6.99%. Malaysias long-term economic average for
output further increased to 42.90% during the 1989 to 1999 period while the Philippines had a
lower growth rate with 17.06%. Finally, Malaysias output increased further to 52.03% during
the 1999 to 2007 period while the Philippines had a lesser long-term average for output of
38.87% during the same period.
In general, long-term output gradually declines as economies matures but since these two
countries were still in the developing and transition stage, output were still increasing during the
periods mentioned.
Malaysias long-term economic average for real capital stock was only 3.97% during the
1980 to 1989 period while the Philippines had a negative growth rate with -0.79% during the
same period. Furthermore, Malaysias real capital stock long-term average grew to 8.76% during
the 1989 to 1999 period while the Philippines had a lower figure with 2.9% during the same
period. However, the Philippines recovered from the negative growth rate during the previous
period mentioned. Finally, during the 1999 to 2007 period the real capital stock long-term
average of Malaysia grew to 11.02% while the Philippines only had 4.42% during the same
period.
In terms of Malaysias labor long-term average growth during the 1980 to 1989 period, it
posted only 1.72% while the Philippines had higher with 5.62% during the same period.
During the 1989 to 1999 period, Malaysias labor long-term average grew to 2.60% while the
Philippines long-term labor average grew to 7.84% which was again higher than Malaysia.
87

However, the long-term average for labor for the Philippines declined to 6.19% during the 1999
to 2007 period while Malaysias labor long-term average also declined slightly to 2.43% during
the same period.
Malaysias long-term average productivity was 14.42% during the 1980 to 1989 period while
the Philippines only had a meager 2.98%. This further increased to 38.25% for Malaysia while
the Philippines long-term average productivity also increased to 10.85%. Finally, the long-term
productivity average of Malaysia further grew to 46.74% during the 1999 to 2007 period while
the Philippines had a lower long-term average productivity rate although it increased to 33.27%.
A better measure of economic performance was real output (real GDP) per capita and the real
capital stock per capita or the capital/labor ratio. Malaysias real output per capita grew from
USD 5,306 in 1980 to USD 11,589 in 2007 while the Philippines real output per capita increased
from only USD 2,670 in 1980 to USD 2,894 in 2007 which were much lower compared to
Malaysia.
Furthermore, the capital/labor ratio of Malaysia increased from USD 1,342 in 1980 to USD
2,556 in 2007 while the Philippines had a capital/labor ratio of only USD 608 in 1980 and this
further decreased to USD 460 in 2007. Developing countries typically have low capital/labor
ratio and the Philippines was no exception but its capital/labor ratio was really low in 2007
because as was mentioned already, its low domestic savings generation cannot cope with the
capital needs of the growing economy.
As such, it can be concluded that the long-term economic averages of Malaysia in terms of
real output, real capital stock, and productivity were much higher than the Philippines and these
were major factors that made Malaysia more economically superior than the Philippines. On the
other hand, the long-term labor growth rate of the Philippines was much better compared with
88

Malaysia but this was not enough to produce an output that can compete with the long-term
economic growth of Malaysia.
Furthermore, the results also showed that the competitiveness of Malaysia were much better
than the Philippines in terms of three sets of competitiveness indicators: growth competitiveness,
macro environment, and public institutions indices. The growth competitiveness index covered
measures of competitiveness such as institutions, infrastructure, macro economy, health and
primary education, higher education and training, market efficiency, technological readiness,
business sophistication, and innovation. The macro environment index was based on
macroeconomic stability, country credit risk, and wastage in government expenditures while the
public institutions index was based on measures of the enforcement of contracts and law and
degree of competition. In addition the cost of doing business and measures of business
regulations.were better in Malaysia as compared to the Philippines.
Thus, hypothesis 1 is accepted.



Hypothesis 2.- The eight critical economic indicators namely government expenditures,
gross capital formation, goods exports, goods imports, gross domestic savings, gross fixed
capital formation, foreign investments, consumption were related to the economic growth
(GDP) for both countries.
Consumption in Malaysia increased from USD 14 billion in 1977 to USD 187 billion in 2007
and this contributed to the growth of GDP in the country. On the other hand, consumption in the
Philippines grew from USD 14 billion in 1977 to USD 114 billion in 2007 which was lesser than
89

Malaysias growth in this category. The foreign direct investments (net inflow) in Malaysia
increased from USD 1 billion in 1979 to USD 8 billion in 2007 while for the Philippines it had
foreign direct investments (net inflow) of USD 1 billion in 1988 and this increased to USD 3
billion in 2007. It can be observed here that Malaysia had foreign direct investments as early as
1979 while the Philippines had foreign investments only in 1988. Moreover, the foreign direct
investments in Malaysia were much bigger as compared to the Philippines and this was an
advantage for the economic development of Malaysia.
The general government final expenditure of Malaysia increased from USD 2 billion in 1977
to USD 23 billion in 2007 and this had definitely contributed to the growth of GDP as it was the
role of government to help in the development of the economy. In comparison, the Philippines
had a government expenditure of USD 2 billion in 1977 and this increased to USD 14 billion in
2007. If we compare the government expenditures for both countries, it can be observed that
Malaysia had a much bigger figure as compared to the Philippines.
Another critical economic indicator for economic growth is gross capital formation
(investment) and Malaysia posted USD 3 billion in 1977 and this improved to USD 41 billion in
2007. In contrast, the Philippines had a higher investment with USD 6 billion in 1977 and this
improved to USD 22 billion in 2007 which was lower compared to Malaysia. It can be observed
here that the GDP of Malaysia was lower compared to the Philippines from 1977 to 1989 and
was equal in 1990. In 1991, the GDP of Malaysia started to be higher than the Philippines and
became much higher until 2007. Malaysias GDP was only USD 14 billion in 1977 while the
Philippines had a higher GDP with USD 20 billion for the same year. However, the GDP of
Malaysia increased to USD 49 billion in 1991 while the Philippines had a lower GDP with USD
45 billion. The GDP of Malaysia further increased to USD 187 billion in 2007 while the
90

Philippines had a much lower economic growth with a GDP of USD 144 billion for the same
year.
Again, it can be observed here that the gross capital formation of Malaysia was almost
double than that of the Philippines. This is where the investment policy of Malaysia had been
implemented well in the country with its 20 year long term development plan which had paid off.
The Philippines had a shorter development horizon through medium term development plans and
earlier planning was not that centralized as compared to the planning agency of Malaysia. The
implementation of getting investments was also reflected in the gross domestic savings of the
country. A crucial economic indicator for any country is domestic savings and Malaysia had only
USD 4 billion 1997 but this ballooned to USD 79 billion in 2007. On the other hand, the
Philippines had a higher domestic savings in 1977 with USD 5 billion in 1977 and this increased
to only USD 23 billion in 2007 as compared to Malaysia with USD 79 billion for the same year.
The Medium Term Development Plan for the Philippines (see appendix) calls for increased in
domestic savings but because of the low savings rate and the absence of a mature financial
market in the country, domestic savings did not take off as compared with Malaysia.

Another critical economic indicator was exports and Malaysia posted USD 6 billion in 1977
and this improved very much in 2007 with USD 176 billion which was almost the GDP figure of
USD 187 billion. However, the Philippines had only goods exports of USD 3 billion in 1977 and
this increased to only USD 50 billion in 2007. As such, it can be evaluated here that in this
category alone, the Philippines economic performance was quite inferior compared to Malaysia.
The export development policy of Malaysia was better and implemented well as it also
pursued the development of high-technology exports that were in demand in other countries
91

while the Philippines lagged behind in terms of high-technology exports and was inferior in
terms of implementing its export development plan.
In addition, gross fixed capital formation which was important in manufacturing and
industrialization was again favorable for Malaysia which posted USD 3 billion in 1977 but this
jumped to USD 40 billion in 2007. Although the Philippines gross fixed capital formation was
higher in 1977 with USD 5 billion, this increased to only USD 21 billion in 2007. Again, in
comparison, this indicator which was vital for industrialization was much lower as compared to
Malaysia.
The balance of payments of Malaysia was always on a surplus which increased from USD 1
billion in 1991 to USD 37 billion in 2007. On the contrary, the Philippines balance of payments
were always negative which increased from negative USD 3 billion in 1991 to negative -USD 8
billion in 2007. As such, this was one factor that hampered the growth of GDP in the Philippines
and which was favorable for Malaysia. The investments portion of Malaysia contributed to the
growth of GDP as it increased from USD 19 billion in 1991 to USD 41 billion in 2007. On the
other hand, the Philippines investment portion contributed to GDP with USD 38 billion in 1991
which resulted to a GDP of USD 45 billion during the same year. Its net exports (BOP),
however, was a negative factor and it decreased the GDP with negative USD 3 billion for the
same year. The GDP of the Philippines grew to USD 144 billion in 2007 and the biggest
contributor was again consumption with USD 114 billion while investment also contributed with
only USD 22 billion. Government expenditures also helped in GDP growth with USD 14 billion
in 2007 while net exports (BOP) was a disaster sinking the GDP growth with negative USD 8
billion in 2007. On the other hand, Malaysias consumption was the biggest contributor with
USD 32 billion to its GDP of USD 49 billion. Also for the same period, government
92

expenditures contributed USD 7 billion. The contribution of net exports (BOP) to the GDP was
USD 1 billion for the same period. This had increased over the years and in 2007, its GDP
valued at USD billion was supported by investment which contributed USD 41 billion while
consumption was again the biggest contributor with USD 108 billion. Net exports (BOP) also
contributed USD 37 billion to the GDP.
In terms of initial endowment, Malaysia had large oil reserves and energy where they export
them to other countries while the Philippines only had a small oil reserve which was being
developed during the period from 1977 to 2007. As such, this initial endowment gave a critical
edge to Malaysias economic development. The property rights in Malaysia was a success and it
was crucial to its development while in the Philippines, land reform was a failure and this
hampered the countrys economic growth.
Moreover, the total reserves of Malaysia was over USD 3 billion in 1977 and it grew to USD
102 billion in 2007 and this showed the economic strength of Malaysia as this was an indicator
of its economic surplus. On the other hand, the total reserves of the Philippines was only USD
1.6 billion in 1977 and this grew to only USD 34 billion in 2007. As such, the strength of
Malaysias reserves was three times higher than the Philippines.
In addition, the debt service as a % of GNI of Malaysia posted 6% in 1977 and this still
remained at 6% in 2007 while the Philippines had 3% in 1977 and increased to 6% in 2007. As
such, there was not that much disparity for both countries in this category.
In terms of industrialization as a % of GDP, Malaysia posted 19% in 1977 and it grew to
28% in 2007. On the other hand, the Philippines had 25% in 1977 which was higher than
Malaysia initially but it fell to only 22% in 2007. As such, while Malaysia was increasing its
industrialization, the Philippines was declining.
93

In terms of money (M1/M2) as % of GDP, Malaysia had 63% in 1977 and this grew to
116% in 2007 while the Philippines had only 22% in 1977 and it grew to only 53% in 2007. As
such, compared to Malaysia, the velocity and circulation of money were much lower and this
was crucial for its economic growth from 1997 to 2007.
As regard to real interest rates, Malaysia had 5% in 1987 and this decreased to only 1% in
2007 while the Philippines had 3% in 1977 and this increased to 6% in 2007. In terms of lending
rates, Malaysia had 10% in 1987 and increased to 12% during the Asian crisis but this decreased
to 6% in 2007. On the other hand, the lending rates in the Philippines increased from 12% in
1977 to 17% during the Asian crisis and gradually declined to 9% in 2007. Thus, the lending
rates were lower in Malaysia than in the Philippines. Lower interest rates means easy money
policy and this explains the huge circulation of money in Malaysia while in the Philippines, it
had in most of the years tight money policy which discouraged entrepreneurs to borrow money
and this affected its economic growth.
Furthermore, the interest rate spread in Malaysia was 7% in 1987 and this declined to 3% in
2007 while the interest rate spread in the Philippines was 5% in 1987 and remained at 5% in
2007. Finally, the multiple regression analysis indicated a strong relationship between the
dependent variable y which is the GDP and the independent variables which were consumption
(X1), foreign direct investment (net inflow) (X2), government expenditures (X3), exports (X4),
imports (X5), investments (X6), gross domestic savings (X7), and gross fixed capital formation
(X8) with an adjusted r square of 0.999882 for Malaysia and 0.996153 for the Philippines
Thus, hypothesis 2 is accepted.
94

Hypothesis 3 - The Malaysian government was more effective than the Philippines in
shaping economic development and these were due to better economic policies and
implementation by the former as compared to the latter.
According to Yoshihara (2004), Malaysia adopted new economic policies in the early 70s
and restricted the economic freedom of the Chinese who were the backbone of the economy then
but the Malaysian was not that strict to the Chinese. During the Marcos regime, the Philippines
restricted foreign investments and imports much more than Malaysia. In addition, the Philippine
state developed monopolies on commodity trade and interrupted the economy by creating
government corporations which controlled the prices of basic commodities and services.
Furthermore, the Philippines and Malaysia had communist insurgency problems but
Malaysia was able to shut it down while in the Philippines it still continues and continued to
create havoc to the economy. Crimes in the Philippines had been higher in terms of kidnapping
of businessmen especially Chinese (Yoshihara, 2004).
Thus, Malaysia was really a stronger state than the Philippines in the sense that it had
destroyed its bad habits and created new programs that made its government more effective and
with lesser graft and corruption as compared to the Philippines.
The Malaysian government has implemented a number of medium- to long-term
development plans and this was initiated with the 20-year New Economic Policya
development plan that strived for greater economic well-being for the ethnic Malays, or
bumiputras. This was later supported by the National Development Policy in the early 1990s.
The most recent development plan is the Third Outline Perspective Plan which is somewhat the
general thrust of Malaysia's development strategy for the period 200110.
95

The development plans of Malaysia which focused on liberalization, privatization, and
globalization were implemented effectively and from the 1970s to the mid-1990s. As a result, the
country's investment ratio was among the highest in the region, resulting in a dramatic shift in
the structure of the economy from agriculture and mining to manufacturing. Liberalization
measures were made throughout the country and this really helped improved competitiveness
and productivity. Majority of the investments went into electronics and other export-oriented
industries, while a large portion also went into non-tradable sectors including capital-intensive
infrastructure and the real estate sector.
Malaysia's robust economic improvement continued during the 1990s prior to the crisis.
However, there were also symptoms of stress as exports decreased and a large current account
deficit developed in the context of a gradual appreciation of the effective exchange rate. At any
rate, the investment-led growth strategy was successful in raising output and income, investment
quality had declined. This later resulted to major balance sheet weaknesses in the banking and
corporate sectors which exposed the economy to the problems of the Asian crisis. The crisis in
Asia pressured the currencies of many Asian countries and resulted to a currency crisis as well as
banking crisis. However, Malaysias external debt which were at a low level spared it from an
external debt crisis
The starting response of the state to the crisis was to increase interest rates and tighten fiscal
policy in an attempt to anchor market confidence in the financial system. However, during early
1998, fiscal policy was changed to a more expansionary position. This policy was not sufficient
to correct external imbalances and bring about the needed economic adjustment. Imbalances in
the domestic economy quickly emerged as growth rates slowed and then turned sharply negative
96

in early 1998. The confidence in the market declined because of regional uncertainties. As such,
by the summer of 1998, the stock market had fallen to its lowest level in recent history.
The Malaysian authority launched a policy package in September 1998 and was meant to
insulate monetary policy from external volatility. The policy included an exchange rate pegged
to the U.S. dollar and selected exchange and capital controls. This was also supported by a fiscal
stimulus package that increased capital spending. These controls resulted to the gradual
decreased in interest rates. The Malaysian state also made some crucial reforms in the financial
and corporate sectors which included bank consolidation policies upgrading of financial
regulation and supervision based on global standards.
The government offers tax incentives for those who were in Pioneer Status for high
technology products and services and so far the government had invested RM 8.1294 billion for
the advancement of these projects during 2001 and 2004.
Hutchcroft (1994) in his study of the Philippine state in the banking industry concluded that
the state was weak in terms of its poor performance and efficacy in the financial system.
However, he discovered that the state as represented by the Central Bank was a captive of
powerful elites who were autonomous and powerful. It was a also a source for cheap loans vital
to their further accumulation of wealth. He further contend that the Philippine state is continually
bombarded with demands of favored elites with particularistic demands such as favored loans or
licenses in the banking industry.
According to him, the Philippine Financial System is defective and it does not work for the
greater benefits of those who need it in society. Hutccroft explains further: If the system
97

genuinely worked for the greater good, perhaps weak state regulation and rampant favoritism
could be overlooked. But it does not: there are four major areas in which the Philippine financial
system performs poorly and hampers larger developmental objectives. First, it discourages the
efficient allocation of credit. There are three major types of commercial banks: patronage-
infested government banks (most importantly, the Philippine National Bank, but formerly two
small banks as well), a large number of private banks, most of which are family-dominated, and
four highly profitable branches of foreign banks, all of which have been in operation since at
least the late 1940s (1994, p. 66).
According to Hutchcroft (1994), the other major areas in which the Philippine financial
system are weak and which hampers growth are the following:
1. First priority in loan allocation by government banks generally goes to those with
greatest proximity to the political machinery. Within private domestic banks, first priority
on loans commonly goes to related enterprises of the extended family owning the bank.
The basic building blocks of the Philippine business community are extended family
conglomerates, and the surest means for such groups to secure a credit is through
ownership (or partial ownership) of a commercial bank. If an entrepreneur lacks access
through either of these channels, credit is very hard to obtain no matter how well it might
be put to use (1984, p. 66).
2. The banking system has a weak record of mobilizing savings, a key element in most any
successful program of economic development. In part because real savings deposit rates
have generally been negative over the past two decades, the Philippines has by far the
worst record of promoting financial intermediation M3/GNP have been very weak: .20 in
98

1970, peaking at .31 in 1983, and falling to .23 in 1988. This has led to considerable
reliance on foreign savings, which may have been allocated even more inefficiently than
domestic savings (1994, p. 66).
3. The banking system has created a high degree of financial instability, the root cause of
which is regulators inability to curb the milking of loan portfolios by bank owners,
directors, and officers for related family enterprises. Banks have occupied a central role
in profit-making strategies of the large family-based conglomerates that control much of
the Philippine economy. In the 1980s and particularly in the early 1960s, oligarchs
acquired banks to serve the credit needs of their family business empires; by 1965, nearly
every major family had gotten in on the act. Among bank owners, loyalty is rarely to
banking per se, but rather to the family conglomerate that the bank is meant to serve. In
some cases, banks have been literally milked to death (1994, pp. 66-67).
4. Finally, the banking system provides enormous profits to those banks that are primarily in
the business of banking for the sake of banking profits. Bankers enjoy oligopolistic power
that is unchallenged by the Central Bank, and the head staffers at the Bankers Association
of the Philippines actually admitted that prices for banking services are set by the actions
of a cartel. The large interest rate spreads guarantee high levels of profitability for those
banks whose loan portfolios are less fragrantly milked by their directors, officers, and
stockholders. As a result, the four foreign banks find profits from their Philippines
branches to be among the highest in their international branch network (1994, p. 67).
Rivera (1994) in his study also recognized the existence of a cartel in the banking system
where a few banks control the financial system and wherein there was a web of complex between
the industrial and banking sector.
99

Rivera also mentioned in his study that the affluent class as represented by local
manufacturers availed of low-interest, long-term loans offered by government financial
institutions (GFIs) and these have proven to be an indispensable source of capital for them.
In the case of a major housing financial institution which is the Government Service
Insurance System (GSIS), it was also the source of funds for pet projects of Marcos and his
cronies.
Again, GSIS money, not available for housing for almost two thirds of the population of the
Philippines, were used to fatten the coffers of the Marcos cronies. Government Financial
Institutions (GFIs) were the favorite sources of low-interest and long term loans by a particular
class or group which had access to the state machinery.
On the other hand, the financial system in the Philippines provides enormous profits to those
financial institutions and banks that were primarily in the business of banking for the sake of
banking profits.
According to a World Bank study (World Bank, 1988: iii 73), pre-tax profit margins in the
Philippines were roughly 300 percent higher than the average of such margins in eight other. The
World Banks analysis concentrates on the distinction that must be made between the profit
structures of the stronger and weaker banks in the Philippine banking system: the more efficient
banks priced their products and services with reference to the cost structure of the smaller banks,
a practice which effectively enabled them to capture higher profits. In early 1991, savings
deposit rates were at 11 percent per annum, while prime lending rates surpassed 23 percent
interest per annum. Analysis of interest rates from 1987 to 1998 would show the same pattern of
high spreads as was in 1991. These large spreads guarantee high levels of profitability for
100

financial institutions and banks. The interest spread to savings ratio was 196 percent in 1987 and
290 percent in 1988. In 1989, the interest spread to savings ratio was 215 percent and dropped
gradually to 90 percent in 1997. Nevertheless, the spreads were still too high in the banking
system.
This financial policy which concerns the interest rate spreads in the Philippines which were
very high and which continued even today affected the growth of savings which were needed for
sustainable investments in the Philippines. Since the savings were low due to these interest
spreads that resulted lower investment levels, the GDP growth of the country was lower as
compared to Malaysia which had tremendous increased in investments.
Moreover, the Philippines during the past had utilized import-substitution strategy but it had
some adverse affects which was based on high-tariff, quantitative restriction, and overvalued
exchange rate. However, during the period 1993-1998, policy changes meant to increasing the
competitiveness and efficiency of the industrial sector were started. The liberalization of foreign
investments were done and implemented, and as such, the foreign exchange market was also
deregulated. The Airline, banking, telecommunications, and oil industries were liberalized.
Public enterprises were encouraged to be privatized and the tariff rates were rationalized.
As a result, the macroeconomic environment significantly improved during this period. The
infrastructure problem was also solved through build, operate and transfer (BOT) schemes.
However, the problems of overvalued exchange rate, low savings rate and poor productivity have
remained. The goal of the country is to move the economy towards investments, trade and
exports. Moreover, the Medium-Term Philippine Development Plan (MTPDP) has stressed the
need to achieve global competitiveness in selected industries (see Appendices).
101

Competition policy in the Philippines consists of policy reforms aimed at promoting
competitive environment as well as measures formulated to prevent a decrease in competition.
These were exemplified as mentioned policy reforms aimed at promoting competition in the
banking industry as well as policies to encourage more players in the shipping, airline, and oil
industries. Examples of measures designed to prevent a reduction in competition are policies to
discourage mega-mergers in deregulated industries and policies against unfair business practices
in liberalized industries.
The government type of Malaysia is a constitutional monarch and the country is nominally
headed by a king and bicameral parliament which consisted of a non-elected upper house and an
elected lower house. All the states in the Peninsula are headed by hereditary rulers which are
known as Sultans with the exception of Melaka and Pulau Pinang and they are headed by
governors along with Sabah and Sarawak in East Malaysia. The state government authority is
limited by the federal constitution with some exceptions to Sabah and Sarawak. The Philippines
form of government is a presidential system patterned after the United States wherein the country
is headed by a President which would rule for six years if elected but cannot run for another term
again. The executive system is run by the President and the legislative is run by Congress which
is divided into the upper house which is the senate and the lower house which is the congress.
Both upper and lower houses are elected by the people.
The problem with the presidential form of government in the Philippines is that there is no
continuity in economic development plans because when a new President is elected, a new set of
economic plans will be developed and the old plans would be changed. As such, the orientation
of economic plans in the Philippines is short to medium terms.
102

On the other hand, the advantage of the Malaysian form of government is that there is a
king that rules continuously and even the prime minister who is not doing his job can be fired
right away if his economic plans are not effective. Thus, the central planning in Malaysia which
formulated a 20 year development plan was effective because of its long=term horizon and this
had resulted to the effective economic growth of the country.
Skocpol (1985) looked at states as organizations that has control over territories and people
and just like corporations they also formulate strategies and objectives and implement them. If
there is independence from certain particular individuals or elites in such formulation, then there
is state autonomy. At any rate, the effectiveness of the state in economic transformation can be
seen in terms of the economic indicators that resulted from its performance.
Malaysia did well in its economic development and achieved high GDP per capita income
for its population and did well in terms of performance for governance according to the World
Bank. The aggregate indicator for voice and accountability (see appendices) for its governance
was higher than 40% as compared to other countries in 1996 and it was 35% higher than other
countries in 2008. In the category of political stability and absence of violence, it was 70%
higher than other countries in 1996 and in 2008 it was still higher by 50% than other countries in
this category. In terms of government effectiveness, the Malaysian government scored higher by
80% than other countries in 1996 and in 2008 it was 85% higher in this category to other
countries in 2008.
In terms of regulatory quality, the Malaysian government scored higher by 75% than other
countries in 1996 and in 2008 it scored higher by 60% than other governments in this category in
2008. In the category of rule of law, the Malaysian government was higher by 78% than other
countries in 1996 and even up to 2008 it was still higher by 65% than other governments.
103

In the category of control of corruption, the Malaysian government was higher by 72% in
1996 and in 2008 it was still higher by 62% in this category than other governments. These
indicators also showed that in terms of the behavior of organizations as the government of
Malaysia is an institution, their behavior is much more progressive than the Philippines and other
countries.
On the other hand, the Philippines governance indicator was significantly better than
countries with similar gross domestic product per capital in the category of voice and
accountability from 1998 to 2006. In the category of political stability, it was significantly lower
than countries with similar gross domestic product per capita from 1996 to 2006.
The capacities of states to promote economic development include societal penetration for
development as well as in the regulation of social relationships. The state can also do the
extracting of economic resources in such a way that it could benefit society as a whole (Migdal,
1988).
In the area of government effectiveness, the Philippines was significantly (see appendices)
higher in 1996 but it was significantly lower from 2005 to 2006. In the category of regulatory
quality, it was significantly higher from 1996 to 2003 and continued to be higher from 2005 to
2006. In the area of rule of law, the Philippine government was significantly higher from 1996 to
1998. However, in this same category, it was significantly lower from 2002 to 2006. Finally, in
terms of control of corruption, it was significantly lower from 1996 to 2006 (see appendices).
In terms of the direct involvement of the government (see appendices) in helping the
economy, government expenditures can help propel it. The general government final expenditure
of Malaysia increased from USD 6.728 billion in 1991 to USD 22.777 billion in 2007 and this
had definitely contributed to the growth of GDP as it is the role of government to help in the
104

development of the economy. The Philippines state had a government expenditure of USD 4.508
billion in 1991 and this increased to USD 14.166 billion in 2007. If we compare the government
expenditures for both countries, it can be observed that Malaysia had a much bigger figure as
compared to the Philippines.
In the area of national government revenues as a % of GDP, the Philippines posted a lower
figure as compared to Malaysia (see appendices).
The government development expenditures as a percentage of GDP has been of the lowest
in the region (see appendices) and declined from 3.3% in 2002 to only 3% in 2006. As such, its
inability to generate sufficient revenues resulted to a drop on budgets for social and economic
services and it was not able to arrest fiscal deficits which led the state to borrow from the private
sector. Thus, government expenditures as a percentage of GDP dropped to 2.9% in 2005 which
originally had 5.4% in 1997. In terms of social services, its expenditures fell from 6.5% to 4.7%
from 1997 to 2005
On the other hand, Malaysia had higher development (see appendices) expenditure as a
percentage of GDP which had 9% in 1997 but dropped slightly to 6.8% in 2005. According to
the Asian Development Bank (2008), The poor fiscal position of the Philippines was due to a
poor generation of revenues as well as insufficient infrastructure such as in electricity and
transportation. In addition, confidence of investors are weak because of poor ratings and
perception of corruption and instability. The government also was a failure in creating and
developing a sufficient base for industrialization and as such its scope led only to a small and
narrow industrial foundation.
According to Migdal, strong states are able to promote economic development and impose
its will to improve social progress and weak states are those that cannot be able to improve its
105

economic as well as improve its social structure. As such, the Philippines as a weak state had
development expenditures as a percentage of GDP which had been one of the lowest in the
region and declined from 3.3% in 2002 to only 3% in 2006. As such, its inability to generate
sufficient revenues resulted to a drop on budgets for social and economic services and it was not
able to arrest fiscal deficits which led the state to borrow from the private sector. Thus,
government expenditures as a percentage of GDP dropped to 2.9% in 2005 which originally had
5.4% in 1997. In terms of social services, its expenditures fell from 6.5% to 4.7% from 1997 to
2005.
In contrast, Malaysia can be considered a strong state in promoting economic development
as well as the ability to change the social landscape of its country and people because it had a
higher development expenditure as a percentage of GDP which had 9% in 1997 but dropped
slightly to 6.8% in 2005.
Rivera (1994) argued that the Philippine state was not autonomous from the pre-colonial
period up to the Marcos government since the power elites were influencing state policy-making
in favor of their vested interests.
According to Villacorta (1994), the root of the weakness of the Philippine state is its
incapacity to severe itself from the interests of the affluent class. The dominance of this ruling
class supported the view that the state is not autonomous in a capitalist system.

The Philippines as an institution is rooted to the traditions of spoils and patronage that has
turned the state bureaucracies into fiefdoms of particularistic interest mediated into fiefdoms of
particularistic interest mediated by the oligarchy and dominant political families. Under the
Marcos government, the dispensation of these privileges became concentrated, in fact, in a
narrower circle of interests. In a very real sense, therefore the state was a captive of these vested
106

interest, unable to exercise any significant degree of autonomy for transformative, and economic
projects (Rivera 1994).
Michael Todaro (1985) said that in developed countries the role of the state is important in
expanding economic activity through fiscal and monetary policies and this can be done through
increasing or decreasing the interest rates of money being lent to the private sector and this is so
because of highly efficient organizations that promote money and credit markets.
However in less developed countries, markets and financial organizations are not that
organized and usually they are dependent upon other countries as well as they are fragmented.
Private investment would be low if social returns to investment will be low. If the private
appropriability of the social returns is too minimal,and/or the financing cost high, these factors
will result to low levels of private investment and entrepreneurship. Poor social returns to
investment could be affected by poor levels of production factors such as human capital,
technology, and infrastructure.
As such, in terms of investment rates (% of GDP), the Philippines had 22% in 1990 and
declined to 15% in 2007 (see appendices) while Malaysia had a higher investment rate at 32% in
1990 and decreased to 19% in 2007. In terms of wealth, the foreign direct investment to
Malaysia increased from US $ 1 billion in 1980 to a staggering US $7 billion in 1996 while the
Philippines had US $100 million in 1980 and increased to US 1.8 billion in 1996. Malaysia
received much higher foreign investment flows than the Philippines. The Philippines as an
institution is rooted to the traditions of spoils and patronage that has turned the state
bureaucracies into fiefdoms of particularistic interest mediated into fiefdoms of particularistic
interest mediated by the oligarchy and dominant political families. Under the Marcos
government, the dispensation of these privileges became concentrated, in fact, in a narrower
107

circle of interests. In a very real sense, therefore the state was a captive of these vested interests,
unable to exercise any significant degree of autonomy for transformative, and economic projects
(Rivera 1994).
During the period from 1991 to 2007, the economic trends for both countries were
evaluated. In terms of the current account balance, Malaysia had a negative figure with USD-
0,918 billion and this deficit further decreased to USD -5,628 billion in 1994 while the
Philippines posted a deficit of USD -2,690 billion in 1990 and this also further increased to USD
-2,849 billion in 1994. Thus, both countries incurred deficits during this period and Malaysia had
higher deficits. The current account balance as a percent of GDP for Malaysia was -2.1% percent
in 1990 and increased further to -7.6% in 1994. The Philippines current balance as a percentage
of GDP was --6.1 % in 1991 and this also further increased to -4.4% in 1994.
In terms of gross domestic product per capita at current prices, Malaysia had USD 2,431,973
in 1990 and this increased to USD 3,703,376 in 1994. In comparison, the Philippines had only
USD718,114 in 1990 and this increased to USD 949,209. In this area, the Philippines had a much
lower figure as compared to Malaysia.
In the area of GDP (in constant prices) annual percent change, Malaysia had 9% percent in
1990 and this increased slightly to 9.2% in 1994 while Philippines had 3 percent in 1990 and this
increased to 4.4% in 1994. The GDP in current prices was USD 44.025 billion in 1990 and this
improved to USD 74.481 billion in 1994. Comparably, the Philippines had USD 44.164 billion in
1990 and this also improved to USD 64.085 billion in 1994 which was lower to the figure of
Malaysia.
108

As regard to inflation in annual percent change, Malaysia had a low 2.6% rate in 1990 and
this increased slightly to 3.9% in 1994 while the Philippines had a much higher rate at 13.2% in
1990 and it decreased to 9% in 1994.
The current account balance of Malaysia further improved from USD 20,355 billion in 2005
to USD 22,784 billion in 2007. In contrast, the Philippines current account balance was much
smaller and continued to decline further from USD 2,938 billion in 2005 to USD 2,096 billion in
2007.
As Malaysias current account balance as percentage of GDP improved to 15.6% as
compared to the previous period, it declined slightly to 14.7% in 2007. However, the Philippines
had a much smaller ratio with 3% in 2005 and which declined further to 1.6% in 2007.
Malaysias GDP per capita in current prices continued to improved much further with USD
5,040,048 in 2005 to USD 5,756,397 in 2007. In comparison, the Philippines only had USD
1,159,207 in 2005 which increased to USD 1,455,301 in 2007. The GDP in constant prices
annual change for Malaysia was 5.3% in 2005 and improved slightly to 5.8%. In comparison, the
Philippines had a similar rate with 5.1% in 2005 which also increased slightly to 5.6% in 2007.
The GDP in current prices for Malaysia further increased to USD 137.954 billion in 2005
from the previous year. This further increased to USD 186.721 billion in 2007. In comparison,
the Philippines had a lower GDP of USD 98.824 in 2005 but this further increased to USD
144.043 billion. However, the 2007 figure is till lower compared to Malaysias USD 186.721
billion.
The annual inflation rate for Malaysia was only 5.3% in 2005 and this increased slightly to
5.8% in 2007. In comparison, the Philippines had a higher inflation rate of 7.6% in 2005 and
declined slightly to 4.7% in 2007.
109

From 1980 to 1990, the Philippines had been higher in GDP than Malaysia until 1991 where
Malaysia had overtaken the Philippines until today. In the over-all, all these economic indicators
proved that Malaysia did better economically in comparison with the Philippines.
In terms of road network coverage (see appendices), the Philippines had a higher rate of
roads paved for 4-wheel vehicle than Malaysia and also in terms of all roads per 4-wheel vehicle
but Malaysia had higher rate for all roads per 100 people and in terms of paved per 100 people.
Roads are important infrastructures for development and in the case of the Philippines their
scores are more or less even.
As regard to per capita electricity consumption which indicates the technological and
infrastructure advantage of the countries, Malaysia had a much higher rate in 2003-2004 with
2,800 kilowatt per hour in 2000. This even increased to 3100 kilowatt per hour in 2004. Malaysia
posted the highest rate in this category as compared to the Philippines. The Philippines had a
very low per capita electricity consumption of 400 kilowatt per hour in 2000 and this increased
to only 500 kilowatt per hour in 2004 (see appendices).
Furthermore, comparing the growth rates of manufacturing exports (see appendices) of
Malaysia to the Philippines, Malaysia had a higher 12% growth rate for the period 2000 to 2005
while the Philippines had a growth rate of only 2%.
The high technology exports of as a percentage of manufactured exports was 59% in 1999
and this decreased to 52% in 2007Malaysia from 1999 to 2007, the Philippines had 75% in 1999
and this decreased to 69% in 2007. As such, the Philippines had higher rates of high technology
exports than in Malaysia.
However, in terms of high-technology exports in current U.S. dollars, Malaysia had much
higher with USD 39,963,570,717 in 1999 and this increased further to USD 64,584,188,242 in
110

2007. The Philippines had only USD 24,163,367,392 in 1999 and this increased to only USD
29,507,842,699.
In terms of internet users, Malaysia had 2,800,000 in 1999 and this increased tremendously
to 14,792,700 in 2007. The Philippines had lower figures of internet users with only 1,090,000 in
1999 and this increased only to 5,300,000. As such, the use of this technology in Malaysia is
much higher than in the Philippines.
In the area of mobile and fixed-line telephone subscribers, Malaysia had 7,420,000 in 1999
and this increased to 27,697,000 in 2007. The Philippines had 5.742,415 in 1999 and this
increased tremendously to 61,284,896 in 2007.
In the category of the number of personal computers, Malaysia had 1,800,000 in 1999 and
this increased to 6,040,000 in 2007 while the Philippines had 1,260,000 in 1999 and this
increased to 6,300,000 in 2007. As such, the number of personal computers were slightly higher
during this period.
In terms of research and development expenditure as percentage of GDP, Malaysia had 1%
in 2002 and remains the same at 1% in 2006 while the Philippines had no available figures in this
area or nothing. Malaysia also had 40 technicians in Research and Development per million
people in 1999 and this increased to 63 in 2004 and decreased again 44 in 2006. The Philippine
had no figures in this area or nothing.
In the area of telecommunications investment as a percentage of revenues, Malaysia had 34%
in 1999 but this decreased to 23% in 2004. The Philippines had 11% in 2003 and this decreased
slightly to 10% in 2005.
111

In terms of its telecommunications revenue as a percentage of GDP, Malaysia had 4% in
1999 and this increased slightly to 5% in 2004. The Philippines had 47% in 1999 and this
decreased to 24% in 2004.
Thus, hypothesis 3 is accepted.
CONCLUSION

Thus, since the all the hypotheses are accepted, It can therefore be concluded that:
1. The economic growth of Malaysia was superior and higher than the Philippines from 1991 to
2007.
2. The eight critical economic indicators namely government expenditures, gross capital
formation, goods exports, goods imports, gross domestic savings, gross fixed capital formation,
foreign investments, consumption were related to the economic growth (GDP) for both countries
3. The Malaysian government was more effective than the Philippines in shaping economic
development and these were due to better economic policies and implementation by the former
as compared to the latter.
In the over-all, the state as an economic institution is an important actor in economic
development. A strong state is one that can penetrate society for changes and reforms while a
weak state is a captive of its oligarchy and is influenced by certain particular classes or interests.
Thus, a strong state can effectively promote economic development. Malaysian had shown that is
a strong state as shown by its high governance index as well as its impressive economic progress
while the Philippines historically was weak as the state was not autonomous from certain classes
or interests and this had disrupted its economic growth.
RECOMMENDATIONS

112

Based on the findings and conclusion, the recommendations are geared towards the
Philippine state which should be able to strengthen its government and become more credible to
its people, investors as well as to the outside world. Malaysia had more foreign investments
because it had credibility. As such, economic policies as well as it political institutions must be
changed for the better. Old institutions and policies should undergo creative destruction as was
done in Malaysia. Human capital and technology must further be developed to improve its
capacity to promote economic development. The state must be strong and autonomous and the
Philippines will not develop if the political will of its leaders will not be as strong in
implementing its economic goals.
As such, the only way for the Philippines to improve and develop further as a country is to
improve its political institution and minimize graft and corruption if not totally eradicate it.
The following measures are further recommended for the Philippines:
1. Accelerate and promote the growth of private investments;
2. Improve the infrastructures such as road, electricity, telephone lines, etc.;
3. Improve the use of computers as well as other technological advancements;
4. Improve the promotion of the flow of foreign investments;
5. Improve the development of capital formation as well the capital markets;
6. Increase the base of entrepreneurs and enterprises for small, medium and large scale
enterprises;
7. Focus on the promotion of industrialization and manufacturing;
8. Develop the domestic savings in the country through offering higher savings rate so that
sufficient capital can be promoted to finance economic development;
113

9. Improve the exports of the country and lessen imports which are not needed for
industrialization;
10. Lower the interest rates for financing so that the cost of capital for businessmen and
investors could encourage the development and expansion of business in the country;
11. Increase government revenues and increase the budget for development expenditures;
12. Promote policies that would encourage the development of new enterprises and provide
financial and lending support for small and medium-scale enterprises.
13. The education and learning institutions must be encouraged and restructured towards
industrialization and entrepreneurship and also the quality of education must also be
improved in terms of its standards;
14. Promote endogenous technology using local resources in order to lessen imports and
using also local human capital and technology as a base.
15. Promote nationalism and develop a culture of unity among the Filipinos and this can be
done through the educational institutions; and
16. Promote industrialization which are geared towards utilizing labor-intensive industries
and not capital intensive ones.

SUGGESTIONS FOR FURTHER STUDIES

The human development indicator (hdi) which was reflective of the Malaysian governments
performance in terms of per capita income, life expectancy, and education, it posted a .68 hdi
index in 1980 and this even increased to .82 in 2005 which was higher than countries in Latin
America and Carribean and also in East Asia and Pacific. Its human development index was
also higher than the Philippines (see appendix).
114

The human development index (hdi) for the Philippines was .67 in 1980 and increased to .73
in 2005. These figure in 2008 was lower than countries in East Asia and the Pacific and was also
much lower compared to Malaysia.
In terms of human capital, Malaysia had an unemployment rate of 5% in 1990 and this
decreased further to only 3.5% in 2006 while the Philippines had a much higher unemployment
level of 8% in 1990 and increased to 11% in 2004 but still remained at 8% in 2006.
In the area of human capital in terms of expenditures per student per capita in the primary,
Malaysia had 12% in 2000 and this decreased slightly to 11% in 2006 while the Philippines had
13% in 2000 and this decreased to 9% in 2005. As such, the Philippines had a lower rate in the
category compared with Malaysia.
In the secondary division, the expenditures per student per capita Malaysia had 22% in 2000
and this decreased slightly to 20% in 2004 while the Philippines had only 11% in 2000 and this
decreased to 9% in 2005. As such, Malaysia invested much more in its human capital than the
Philippines in the secondary division.
In the important tertiary division, the expenditures per student per capita of Malaysia posted
a high 81% in 1991 and this decreased to only 60% in 2006. The Philippines had only 15% in
1999 and this decreased further to 12% in 2005.
The literacy rate of adult female was 85% in 2000 while the Philippines had 93% in 2000
and this increased to 94% in 2004. The total literacy rate for Malaysia was 89% in 2000 while
the Philippines had 93% and remained the same at 93% in 2003.
Although, the literacy rate in the Philippines were slightly higher than Malaysia, the
expenditures per student were higher in Malaysia and the state had invested plenty for the
115

development of their human capital and this had resulted to an economic transformation that
were much high higher than the Philippines from 1991 to 2007 (see appendix).
Furthermore, human capital and technology had developed much more in Malaysia
compared to the Philippines because the Malaysian state spent much in expenditures per student
as well as in terms of the technological advancement of its people and institutions. As Cortright
(2001) stated in his new growth theory:


New Growth Theory emphasizes that economic growth results from the increasing returns
associated with new knowledge. Knowledge has different properties than other economic goods
(being non-rival, and partly excludable). The ability to grow the economy by increasing
knowledge rather than labor or capital creates opportunities for nearly boundless growth
(Cortright, 2001, p. ii).

Thus, the contribution of labor and fixed capital to GDP growth were better in Malaysia as
compared to the Philippines and it can also be hypothesized that total factor productivity was
better in Malaysia than the Philippines.

Thus, the economic progress of a country can be supported by the increased through new
knowledge which resulted to the development of its human capital and this was translated in
terms of the superior economic performance and economic productivity of Malaysia as the
results had shown from 1991 to 2007 as compared with the Philippines.
As such, it is suggested that a similar study would be conducted using new growth theory not
only for the Philippines but the area of study must also be conducted for other countries in
Southeast Asia. This can include Thailand, Singapore, Indonesia, and South Korea using the
same questions as had been formulated in this study.

116















REFERENCES

Acemoglu, D.& Fabrizio Z (1997). Was prometheus unbound by chance? risk,
diversification,and growth.. Journal of Political Economy 105(4), 70951
(2001) Productivity differences. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116(2), 563606.
Acemoglu, D. & Angrist, J. (2001). How large are human-capital externalities? evidence from
compulsory schooling laws. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, Vol. 15 (pp. 9-59).
Bernanke, B. &Rogoff, K. (Eds.).(pp. 9-59). Cambridge and London: MIT Press. pp. 959.

Acemoglu, D., Simon, J. & Robinson, J. (2001). The colonial origins of
comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review 91(5),
13691401.

Aghion, P., and Bolton, P. (1997) A trickle-down theory of growth and development
with debt overhang. Review of Economic Studies 64(2), 15172.
117


Ahmed, O.B. (1990).The contribution of islamic banking to economic
development: The case of the Sudan. Ph.D. dissertation submitted to the University
Durham, United Kingdom, Dissertation Abstracts International. 53-07,
Section: A, page 2842.

Aghion, P.,& Howitt, P. (1992). A model of growth through creative destruction.
Econometrica 60(2), 323351.

Aghion, P., Howitt, P. & Mayer-Foulkes, D. (2004) The effect of financial
development on convergence: Theory and evidence. Working Paper 10358, National Bureau
of Economic Research

Aiyagari, S. R. (1994). Uninsured idiosyncratic risk and aggregate saving. Quarterly Journal
of Economics 109, 569684.

Aleem, I.(1990).Imperfect information, screening and the costs of informal lending: A study
of a rural credit market in Pakistan. World Bank Economic Review 3, 329349.

Alesina, A., & Dani, R. (1994). Distributive politics and economic growth. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 109(2), 465490.


Allen, D. & Cady, F. (1982). Analyzing experimental data by regression. Wadsworth. Belmont,
Calif.

Anderson, S., & Baland, J. (2002). The economics of roscas and intrahousehold
resource allocation. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(3), 963995.

Angeletos, G., & Calvet, L. (2003). Idiosyncratic production risk, growth and
the business cycle. Mimeo, MIT.


Aportela, F. (1998). The effects of financial access on savings by low-income people.
Mimeo, MIT.

Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte
Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations.. Review of Economic Studies
58(2), 277297.

Althusser, L. (1970, 1984). Essays on ideology. London: Verso.

Bello, W., Kinley, D., & Elinson, E. (1982). Development Debacle: The
World Bank in the Philippines. San Francisco, C.A.: Institute for Food & Development Policy.

Buendia, R. G.. (April 1993). Colonialism and elitism in Philippine political
118

development: Assessing the roots of underdevelopment. Philippine Journal of
Public Administration, Vol. XXXVII, No. 2.

Banerjee, A.V., & Newman, A. (1991). Risk bearing and the theory of income
distribution.Review of Economic Studies 58(2), 211235.

Banerjee, A.V., & Duflo, E. (2000) Reputation effects and the limits of contracting:
A study of the indian software industry. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115(3), 9891017.

Banerjee, A.V., & Munshi, K. (2004) How efficiently is capital allocated? Evidence
from the knitted garment industry in Tirupur. Review of Economic Studies 71(1), 1942.

Banerjee, A.V., Duflo, E., & Munshi, K. (2003). The (mis)allocation of capital.
Journal of the European Economic Association 1(23), 484494.

Banerjee, A.V., Gertler, P., & Ghatak, M. (2002). Empowerment and efficiency:
Tenancy reform in West Bengal. Journal of Political Economy 110(2), 239280.

Bardhan, P. (1969). Equilibrium growth in a model with economic obsolescence of
machines. Quarterly Journal of Economics 83(2), 312323.

Bardhan, P.,& Udry, C. (1999). Development microeconomics.Oxford, New York: Oxford
University Press.

Barro, R.J. (1974). Are government bonds net wealth? Journal of Political Economy 82(6),
10951117.

Barro, R.J., & Lee, J.W. (2000). International data on educational attainment updates
and implications. Working Paper 7911, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Barro, R.J., & Xavier, S. (1995). Economic growth. New York: McGraw Hill.

Bottomley, A. (1963). The cost of administering private loans in underdeveloped rural areas.
Oxford Economic Papers 15(2), 154163.

Bourguignon, F., & Chiappori, P.A. (1992). Collective models of household
Behavior..European Economic Review 36, 355364.

Buera, F. (2003). A dynamic model of entrepreneurship with borrowing constraints.
Mimeo, University of Chicago.

Cagetti, M., & De Nardi, M. (2003). Entrepreneurship, frictions and wealth. Staff Report
324, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.

Carroll, C. (1997). Buffer-stock saving and the life cycle/permanent income
hypothesis. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, 156.
119


Carvalho, I. (2000). Household income as a determinant of child labor and school
enrollment in Brazil: Evidence from a social security reform. Mimeo, MIT.

Case, A., & Paxson, C. (2001). Mothers and others: Who invests in childrens
health? Journal of Health Economics 20(3), 301328.

Case, A., Paxson, C. & Ableidinger, J. (2002). Orphans in Africa. Working
Paper 9213, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Case, A.,& McLanahan, S. (2000). How hungry is the selfish gene? Economic Journal
110(466), 781804.

Caselli, F. (2004). The missing input: Accounting for cross-country income differences.
Mimeo, Harvard University, forthcoming in Handbook of Development Economcis,
Aghion, P. & S. Durlauf, (Eds).

Caselli, F.,& Gennaioli, N. (2002). Dynastic management. Mimeo, Harvard
University (2004) Dynastic management, legal reform and regulatory reform. Mimeo,
London School of Economics.

Coate, S., & Ravallion, M. (1993). Reciprococity without commitment:
Characterization & performance of informal insurance arrangements. Journal of
Development Economics 40, 124.

Cole, H., Mailath, G., & Postlewaite, A. (1992).Social norms, savings behavior
and growth. Journal of Political Economy 100(6), 10921126.

Carter, A.F. (1985). The sociology of development. Lancashire: Causeway Press Ltd.

Chenery, H.B. (1979). Structural change & Development policy. Baltimore:
Johns Hopkins University.

Cortright, J. (2001).New growth theory, technology & learning: A Practitioners Guide
Reviews of Economic Development Literature and Practice: No. 4 Impresa, Inc.
.
Conley, T., & Udry, C. (2003). Learning about a new technology: Pineapple in
Ghana. Mimeo, Northwestern University.

Dasgupta, A. (1989). Reports on informal credit markets in India: Summary. New Delhi:
National Institute of Public Finance and Policy.

Dasgupta, P., & Debraj, R. (1986). Inequality as a determinant of malnutrition and
unemployment theory. The Economic Journal 96(384), 10111034.

Deaton, A. (1992). Understanding Consumption. Oxford: Oxford University Press
120

(1997). The Analysis of Household Surveys (World Bank, International Bank for
Reconstruction and Development).

Deaton, A., & Paxson, C. (1994). Intertemporal choice and inequality. Journal of Political
Economy 1-2(3), 437467.

Deininger, K., & Squire, L. (1996). A new data set measuring income inequality. World Bank
Economic Review 10, 565591.

Djankov, S., La Porta, R.,Lopez de Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2002). The
regulation of entry. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(1), 137.

Do, T., & Iyer, I. (2003. Land rights and economic development: Evidence from
Vietnam. Mimeo, Harvard Business School.

Dreze, J., & Kingdon, G.G. (2001). School participation in rural India. Review of
Development Economics 5(1), 124.

Duflo, E. (2001). The medium run effects of educational expansion: Evidence from a large
school construction program in Indonesia. Working Paper 2003-2, Bureau for Research in
Economic Analysis of Development. forthcoming, Journal of Developemnt Economics
(2003) Poor but rational. Mimeo, MIT.

Deeg, R.E. (1992).. Banks and the state in Germany: The critical role of
subnational institutions in economic governance. Ph.D. dissertation presented to the
Massachussets Institute of Technology, Dissertation Abstracts International. Volume: 53-06,
Section: A, page: 2085.

Harrod, R. & Domar, E. (2000). Harrod-Domar growth model. Economic
Development, 7
th
ed.,Todaro, M., Singapore: Pearson Education Asia Pte. Ltd.

Evans, P. (1989). Predatory, developmental, and apparatuses: A comparative
political economy perspective in the third world state. Sociological Forum 4,
No. 4: 561-587.

Frank, A.G.. (1967). Capitalism and underdevelopment in Latin America.
New York & London: Modern Readers Paperbacks.

Furtado, C. (1976). Economic development of Latin America: Historical background
& contemporary problems, 2
nd
ed., Cambridge.

Gutierrez, E., et.al. (1992). All in the family: A study of elites and power relations in
the Philippines. Quezon City: Institute for Popular Democracy.

Harris, N. (1990). The end of the third world: Newly industrializing countries & the
decline of an ideology. Middlesex, England: Penguin Books.
121


Hunt, D. (1989). Economic theories of development: An analysis of competing
paradigms. Hertfordshire: Harvester Wheatsheaf,

Hutchcroft, P. D. (1993). Predatory oligarchy, patrimonial state: The politics
of private domestic commercial banking in the Philippines. Ph.D. Yale
University.

_______________. (1994). Power and politics in the Philippine banking industy:
An analysis of state-oligarchy relations. Patterns of Power & Politics in
the Philippines: Implications for Development, Eder, J.F.& Youngblood, R. (Eds.).
Arizona University.

_______________. (April 1991).Oligarchs and cronies in the Philippine state: The politics of
patrimonial plunder. World Politics, Vol. 43,: 414-450.

Kuznets, S. (September 1973). Modern economic growth; findings and
reflections. The American Economic Review 63: 247-258.

Lenin, Vladimir (1917, 1975). Imperialism, the highest stage of capitalism. Moscow: Progress
Publishers.
____________ (1976). The state and revolution. Peking: Foreign Language Press.

____________(1972). Marxism on the state. Moscow: Progress Publishers.

Lindsey, C.W., & Valencia, E.M. (1981). Foreign direct investment in the
Philippines: A review of the literature. Philippine Institute for Development
Studies Working Paper No. 81-11. Manila: Philippine Institute for Development
Studies.

Manapat, R. (1991). Some Are Smarter Than Others: The history of Marcos crony
capitalism. New York: Alethia Publications.

Marx, K. (1951). Karl Marx and Frederick Engels: Selected works Vol. 1. Moscow:
Foreign Language Publishing House.

McCoy, A. & de Jesus E. (Eds.) (1982). Philippine social history:
Ateneo de Manila Press.

Migdal, J. (1988). Strong societies and weak states: State-society relations and
state capabilities in the third world. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.

Nava, A., Karlan, D.S., & Yin, W. (2004). Tying Odysseus to the mast: Evidence
from a commitment savings product in the Philippines. Mimeo, Harvard University.

North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change & economic performance.
122

Cambridge University Press.

Porter, M. E. (1990). The competitive advantage of nations. London: The Macmillan Press Ltd.

Rivera, T. C. (1994). Landlords & capitalists: Class, family, & state in
Philippine manufacturing. Quezon City: University of the Philippines Press.

Rostow, W. W. (1961). The stages of economic growth: A non-communist manifesto.
Cambridge University Press.

Roth, G. & Wittich, C. (Eds.). (1968). Economy and society. New York:
Bedsminter Press.

Rueschemeyer, D. & Evans, P.B. (1985). The state and economic
tranformation: Toward an analysis of the condition underlying effective
intervention. Bringing the State Back In. Cambridge University Press.
.
Simbulan, D. (1965). A study of the socio-economic elite in Philippine politics &
government, 1946-63. Ph.D. Political Science, Australian National University.

Skocpol, T. (1985). Bring the ztate back-in: Strategies of analysis in current
Research. Bring the State Back In: Cambridge University Press.
.
Silverman, D. (2002). Interpreting qualitative data. London: SAGE Publication.
Stepan, A. (1978). The state and society: Peru in comparative perspective.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.

Thomas, R. M. (2003) Blending qualitative & quantitative research methods in theses &
dissertations. California: Corwin Press, Inc.
Todaro, M. (1978). Economic development in the third world, 3
rd
ed. White
Plains, N.J.: Transaction Books.

_____________ (2000). Economic development. White Plains, N.J.: Transaction
Books.

Trimberger, E.K. (1985). Revolution from above: Military bureaucrats &
development in Japan, Turkey, Egypt and Peru. New Brunswick, N.J.: Longman, Inc.

Villacorta, W. (1994). The curse of the weak state: Leadership imperatives for
the Ramos government. Contemporary Southeast Asia, (16) 1.

Wolters, W. (1983). Politics, patronage & class conflict in Central Luzon. The
Hague: Institute of Social Studies., June 2004.

Yoshihara, K. (2004). The comparative economic performance of Malaysia:
123

An analysis. Southeast Asian Studies, Vol. 42, No. 1.

Yin, R. (1989). Case study research: Design and methods. Newbury Park, CA: Sage.























124





















APPENDICES


125

Appendix 1 HDI for the Philippines and Malaysia


126



Appendix 2
Human Development Index, 1975 -2007 Using 2007 Ranking








Appendix 3
Microsoft Excel Multiple Regression Results for Malaysia
SUMMARY OUTPUT

Regression Statistics
Multiple R 0.999957
R Square 0.999913
Adjusted R
Square
0.999882
Standard
Error
0.484819
Rank Country
Years

1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2006 2007
66 Malaysia 0.619 0.666 0.689 0.737 0.767 0.797 0.821 0.825 0.829
105 Philippines 0.648 0.652 0.651 0.697 0.713 0.726 0.744 0.747 0.751
Source: UNDP (Human Development Report 2009)




127

Observatio
ns
31

ANOVA
df SS MS F Significanc
e F

Regression 8 59538.7
6
7442.34
6
31662.8
4
7.71E-43
Residual 22 5.17109
7
0.23505
Total 30 59543.9
4


Coefficien
ts
Standar
d Error
t Stat P-value Lower
95%
Upper
95%
Lower
95.0%
Upper
95.0%
Intercept 0.545676 0.36303
2
1.50310
5
0.14703
2
-0.20721 1.29855
9
-
0.20721
1.29855
9
X Variable 1 1.037559 0.08169
1
12.7010
9
1.33E-
11
0.868144 1.20697
5
0.86814
4
1.20697
5
X Variable 2 -0.21413 0.09683
1
-
2.21136
0.03770
6
-0.41495 -
0.01331
-
0.41495
-
0.01331
X Variable 3 0.07872 0.26231
1
0.30010
3
0.76691
6
-0.46528 0.62272
1
-
0.46528
0.62272
1
X Variable 4 -0.13135 0.08925
9
-
1.47157
0.15529
9
-0.31646 0.05376
1
-
0.31646
0.05376
1
X Variable 5 0.093143 0.09742
8
0.95602 0.34945 -0.10891 0.29519
6
-
0.10891
0.29519
6
X Variable 6 -0.03496 0.15646
4
-
0.22345
0.82524
6
-0.35945 0.28952
4
-
0.35945
0.28952
4
X Variable 7 1.123325 0.09734
8
11.5392
2
8.4E-11 0.921437 1.32521
3
0.92143
7
1.32521
3
X Variable 8 -0.07126 0.13657
6
-
0.52179
0.60703
2
-0.3545 0.21197
7
-0.3545 0.21197
7

Appendix 4 Microsoft Excel Multiple Regression Results for the Philippines
SUMMARY OUTPUT

Regression Statistics
Multiple R 0.998592
R Square 0.997186
Adjusted R
Square
0.996163
Standard
Error
1.838069
128

Observations 31

ANOVA
df SS MS F Significance
F

Regression 8 26338.06 3292.258 974.4741 3.17E-26
Residual 22 74.32693 3.378497
Total 30 26412.39

Coefficients Standard
Error
t Stat P-value Lower 95% Upper
95%
Lower
95.0%
Upper
95.0%
Intercept 0.638482 1.615345 0.39526 0.696457 -2.71154 3.988502 -2.71154 3.988502
X Variable 1 1.283743 0.068588 18.71677 5.3E-15 1.141501 1.425986 1.141501 1.425986
X Variable 2 -0.56598 0.654681 -0.86452 0.396632 -1.92371 0.791742 -1.92371 0.791742
X Variable 3 -2.41243 0.650526 -3.70843 0.001225 -3.76154 -1.06332 -3.76154 -1.06332
X Variable 4 0.595446 0.285068 2.088789 0.048511 0.004252 1.18664 0.004252 1.18664
X Variable 5 -0.24848 0.300741 -0.82624 0.41754 -0.87218 0.375215 -0.87218 0.375215
X Variable 6 1.440834 0.575065 2.505515 0.020123 0.248222 2.633446 0.248222 2.633446
X Variable 7 0.270924 0.211256 1.282443 0.213036 -0.16719 0.709043 -0.16719 0.709043
X Variable 8 -1.09238 0.561219 -1.94645 0.064483 -2.25628 0.071513 -2.25628 0.071513






Appendix 5 Expenditures per student/literacy rate, Malaysia and Philippines
Malaysia
2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000
Expenditure per student, primary (% of GDP per capita) .. 11 .. 14 18 19 16 12
Expenditure per student, secondary (% of GDP per
capita)
.. .. .. 20 25 27 26 22
Expenditure per student, tertiary (% of GDP per capita) .. 60 .. 68 89 98 109 81
Literacy rate, adult female (% of females ages 15 and
above)
.. .. .. .. .. .. .. 85
Literacy rate, adult male (% of males ages 15 and above) .. .. .. .. .. .. .. 92
Literacy rate, adult total (% of people ages 15 and above) .. .. .. .. .. .. .. 89
Source: The World Bank
129



Philippines
2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000
Expenditure per student, primary (% of GDP per capita) .. .. 9 9 12 11 12 13
Expenditure per student, secondary (% of GDP per capita) .. .. 9 9 10 9 10 11
Expenditure per student, tertiary (% of GDP per capita) .. .. 12 13 14 15 14 15
Literacy rate, adult female (% of females ages 15 and above) .. .. .. .. 94 .. .. 93
Literacy rate, adult male (% of males ages 15 and above) .. .. .. .. 92 .. .. 93
Literacy rate, adult total (% of people ages 15 and above) .. .. .. .. 93 .. .. 93
Source: The World Bank







Appendix 5b

Educational Attainment in Malaysia and Philippines

Literacy rate, adult
total (% of people ages
15 and above)
% Gross Primary
Enrolment
% Gross Secondary
Enrolment

% Gross Tertiary
Enrolment

Emigration
rate of
tertiary
educated (%
of total
tertiary
educated
population
ECONOMY 1980 1990 2000 1980 1990 2000 1980 1990 2000 1980 1990 2000 1990 2000
Malaysia 70 83 89 101 96 100 53 58 69 - 8 29 26 11
Philippines 83 94 93 104 107 109 67 77 83 -
28
4

27 13 14
Note: For 1985
For 1995
For 2005
For 1991

4
For 1999

130

Source: World Bank (2010)


Appendix 6
http://www.imf.org/external/np/loi/031198.htm
March 11, 1998


MEMORANDUM OF ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL POLICIES
OF THE PHILIPPINE GOVERNMENT
I. BACKGROUND
1. In recent years, the Philippine economy has made impressive progress, reflecting the
implementation of prudent macroeconomic policies and sound structural reforms, as well as a
favorable external environment. By 1996, GNP growth had accelerated to nearly 7 percent, led
by exports and investment; inflation had fallen to well within single digits; and the external
position had strengthened with rapid export growth, increasing reserves, and a steady reduction
of the debt burden.
2. During 1997, economic conditions became markedly more difficult with the onset of the
regional currency crisis. Particularly since the floating of the Thai baht last July, financial
markets have been under severe pressure. Economic and financial policies have been adjusted to
manage these pressures, contain their impact on the real economy, and prepare for an early return
of confidence. In particular, the peso has been allowed to float, accompanied by a tightening of
fiscal and monetary policies, while we have moved forward with our structural reform agenda
notwithstanding the difficult economic environment.
131

3. Our efforts, which were supported by an extension and augmentation of the Philippines'
extended arrangement with the Fund, have met with considerable success. In particular,
economic growth held up well in 1997 (real GNP grew by nearly 6 percent), inflation (5 percent
average) was contained below the target, and the depreciation of the peso, although substantial,
has been less than that of some other currencies in the region. Critical in this respect has been the
limited damage so far to our financial and corporate sectors, which, although facing strains, have
weathered the crisis relatively well. While much of the resilience of the economy is rooted in the
successful reform policies of the 1990s, the pragmatic and flexible policy response in recent
months has contributed as well.
4. The economy is now at a delicate juncture. While the regional crisis has not cut as deep as in
some countries, some risks remain and we must guard against further shocks in the months to
come. The economic environment remains challenging, and further shifts in confidence are
possible. While the priority is to manage the present crisis effectively and restore confidence as
soon as possible, we also recognize that recent developments have exposed certain
vulnerabilities of our economy. Our goal is to contain these risks through an economic program
that involves a tightening of fiscal and monetary policies; continuation of the floating exchange
rate regime; bolstering our pro-active strategy to strengthen the banking sector; and pursuing
other structural reforms.
5. Beyond the immediate concerns of crisis management, economic policies are being focused to
address the remaining barriers to sustained rapid growth and poverty reduction. Key medium
term requirements in this respect are to raise domestic saving, strengthen the financial system,
reduce external vulnerability, and ensure fiscal sustainability. In order to support our economic
132

program and bolster market confidence in these uncertain times, we wish to support our efforts
through a precautionary arrangement in the form of a two-year stand-by arrangement with the
Fund.

II. THE PROGRAM FOR 1998-99

A. Program Objectives

6. The main economic objectives for 1998-99 are to:
- Contain the slowdown of real GNP growth to 3 percent in 1998, followed by 5 percent in 1999
and 6 percent thereafter;
- Limit average inflation to around 8 percent in 1998, 6-7 percent in 1999, and 5 percent in
subsequent years; and
- Reduce the current account deficit to 3.1 percent of GNP in 1998 and to 2.7 percent in 1999,
and increase reserve cover to 1.9 months of imports in 1998 and to 2.3 in 1999.
In order to achieve these goals, we have formulated a comprehensive policy package centered
on: (i) prudent macroeconomic policies; (ii) accelerated banking sector reform; and (iii) other
reforms to address the structural impediments to sustained high growth.
B. Fiscal Policy

7. An immediate priority is to arrest the deterioration in the fiscal accounts that occurred in 1997,
133

mainly as a result of worsening economic conditions and continuing weaknesses in tax
administration. Although some deviation from the medium-term consolidation path envisaged
earlier is unavoidable in current circumstances, the government remains committed to the longer-
term goals of raising public sector saving and achieving overall fiscal surpluses. We consider
these commitments as integral to our broader goals of rapid economic growth, external viability,
and successful poverty reduction.
8. After registering a deficit of P 21.8 billion (0.9 percent of GNP) in 1997, the consolidated
public sector position in 1998 will be limited to a deficit of P 26.5 billion (0.9 percent of GNP)
and to balance in 1999. While these targets are somewhat less ambitious than envisaged earlier,
they require a major effort in light of the recent deterioration in the fiscal accounts. Besides, they
still imply sizable primary surpluses in both years (4.2 percent of GNP in 1998, and 4.7 percent
of GNP in 1999). Consistent with the overall fiscal targets, the National Government budget
seeks to attain a small surplus in 1998 (P 5 billion, including privatization receipts and excluding
(negative) net income from the CB-BOL) and a significantly larger surplus of P 22 billion (0.7
percent of GNP) in 1999. The fiscal plan for 1998-99 has been drawn up in line with our
medium-term fiscal strategy (Paragraph 26).
9. Although the budget submitted to Congress for 1998 envisaged a surplus of P 16 billion, the
revenue assumptions underlying the budget have been undermined by the sharp deterioration in
the economic environment and the lower than expected net revenue impact of the final version of
the CTRP. Moreover, the tariff exemptions for agriculture and fisheries enterprises adopted by
Congress recently risk reducing revenues further, although their implementation is expected only
in the second half of 1998. Furthermore, the expenditure program has been burdened
134

substantially by the impact of the depreciation of the peso and higher interest rates on interest
payments. In the absence of corrective action the budget deficit for this year could reach P 50-60
billion (1 1/2 - 2 percent of GNP). Faced with this prospect, and with Congress adjourned until
after the May elections, the government has adopted the following emergency measures:
- a 25 percent mandatory reserve on all expenditures, including government-owned and
controlled corporations other than personnel and debt service (Paragraph 11);
- a 10 percent deferment in the internal revenue allocation (IRA) for local government units;
- suspension of all tax subsidies of National Government agencies, government owned and
controlled corporations, and local government units;
- continuation of the selective ban on the creation of new civil service positions as well as
restrictions on the filling of vacant positions (exempting health, education, and peace and
order);
- suspension through Presidential veto of P 14.4 billion of new programs and projects from the
1998 budget; and
- a renewed effort to strengthen tax administration, following an action plan drawn up in
collaboration with the Fund (Paragraph 12);
10. The above measures are sufficient to keep the fiscal program on track at least until mid-year
when the new government and Congress take office. However, to reach the targeted surplus of P
5 billion for the year as a whole, and to complete the structural reforms in our budget, additional
measures will be needed during the second half of the year. These could include legislative
revenue measures such as a restructuring of motor vehicle taxes and a rationalization of fiscal
incentives with a view to making them more transparent and limited. In particular, the plan is to
135

re-submit to Congress legislation to rationalize and limit the wide range of tax incentives for
both public and private businesses. Adoption of an appropriate package of measures if necessary
to achieve the P 5 billion target for 1998 will be a condition for completion of the second
program review. Quantitative limits on the public sector borrowing requirement have been
established as a performance criteria under the program.
11. In implementing the 25 percent cut in discretionary expenditures, the government will make
best efforts to protect social programs, especially those directed at poverty reduction. Measures
are being pursued by the government to minimize, if not insulate, poverty alleviation programs
from the budgetary cuts, particularly those for the 21 poorest provinces and the fifth and sixth
class municipalities. And should fiscal developments during the year permit a relaxation of the
cuts, affected social programs will be the first to be restored. Given the predominant need to
stabilize macroeconomic conditions, such relaxation will only be envisaged, however, once all
measures are in place to ensure attainment of the fiscal target for the year as a whole.
12. The improvement in the fiscal position under the program depends critically on
implementation of the action plan to strengthen tax administration drawn up in collaboration
with the Fund. We have requested follow-up technical assistance from the Fund to help with
implementation of this plan. In this regard, particular emphasis will be given to strengthening the
BIR's focus on large taxpayers as well as to a comprehensive audit plan to enhance taxpayer
compliance. Specifically, a large-taxpayer unit will be re-established and made fully operational
at BIR headquarters by the time of the first program review. The unit will be empowered to
supervise all aspects of large taxpayers' compliance including the conduct of audits. A
comprehensive audit program will be reinstated and the pending audit of one of the large tobacco
136

excise taxpayers will be promptly completed and appropriate follow-up action taken. A
mechanism to monitor tax credits issued will be set up, and action is under way to speed up the
transfer of tax revenues from commercial banks to the Treasury. To further improve customs
administration the government will curtail sharply the scope of duty-free shopping facilities that
have proven to add leakages to the system. To allow time for these reforms to be implemented,
the scheduled reorganization of the regional and district offices of the BIR will be put on hold.
13. The government is committed to further strengthening the social safety net and reducing
poverty, issues of particular relevance as we strive to cushion the impact of the regional crisis on
the most vulnerable. Under the Social Reform Agenda initiated in 1994, we are committed to
reducing the incidence of poverty through better provision of social services and more effective
poverty alleviation programs. We plan to take further measures in this area, in addition to trying
to minimize, as described in Paragraph 11, the effect of the emergency budget cuts on the poor.
In particular, we are ensuring the availability of rice stocks especially in poor communities and
developing livelihood and training programs with focus on small farmers and fisher folks.
Beyond these immediate concerns, poverty reduction continues to pervade the government's
economic strategy as an over-arching goal. Besides the major importance of sustained rapid
growth, we consider the following medium-term policies, among others, as appropriate to reduce
poverty: (i) reforms and higher budgetary allocations for education and health, with a focus on
rural areas; (ii) development of the agricultural sector requiring, in particular, improvements in
rural infrastructure and extension services, and (iii) improved targeting and efficiency of
government programs directed at poverty reduction.
C. Monetary and Exchange Rate Policy
137


Monetary policy

14. The task of monetary policy during 1998 is to restore confidence in the peso. The proximate
goals in this regard are to stabilize the external position and contain the inflationary impact of the
recent peso depreciation. In pursuit of these objectives, interest rate policy will be guided
primarily by the targets established for base money and international reserves (NIR). Accelerated
banking sector reforms, described in Paragraph 25, will support these policies by ensuring the
continued safety and soundness of the system.
15. Consistent with the program's objectives for growth and inflation, broad money growth
during 1998 is projected to decelerate to 17 percent in 1998 (from 21 percent in 1997). Base
money is to grow by 15.6 percent (test period basis), and net international reserves (NIR) are
targeted to rise by around $920 million. In line with this, quarterly limits have been placed on the
stock of base money during 1998, and monthly indicative limits have been set to guide policy
implementation. Monetary targets for 1999 will be established during the third program review.
16. The BSP will set its overnight and term interest rates in a manner consistent with achieving
the base money and NIR targets. In setting policy interest rates on a day-to-day basis, emphasis
will be given to the signals from market interest rates and the exchange rate, recognizing the
relationship between interest rates and exchange rate stability. The central bank will adjust
interest rates as necessary during the program period, especially if the peso comes under renewed
pressure. In view of possible shifts in the demand for money, monetary targets may have to be
revised during the program period, in consultation with the Fund.
138

17. To reduce the intermediation bias against the peso, among other measures (Paragraph 22) the
central bank intends to reduce gradually the reserve requirements on peso deposits. As a first
step, and taking into account the current need for a tight monetary policy stance, we intend to
reduce the statutory reserve requirement from 13 percent to 10 percent with a simultaneous
increase in the liquidity reserve requirement from 4 to 7 percent during the program. In addition,
prior to the end of the program the plan is for a reduction in the total reserve requirement
(statutory plus liquidity), depending on monetary developments under the program. The central
bank will ensure, through open market operations, that any reduction in total reserve
requirements will be implemented in a manner that will avoid any undesired liquidity expansion.
Exchange rate policy

18. In current circumstances the Philippine economy is best served by a floating exchange rate.
Thus, our policy is to limit intervention in the foreign exchange market to what is necessary to
achieve the NIR target under the program, minor "smoothing" operations, and intervention to
maintain orderly market conditions during periods of market turbulence. Monthly indicative
targets have been set for NIR of the BSP, which the BSP will aim to meet as a prime objective of
monetary and exchange rate policy under the program. Consistent with these targets, quarterly
floors on NIR have been set as performance criteria under the program. Deviations from the
indicative NIR targets will not be sterilized, with base money targets to be adjusted accordingly.
19. To improve the functioning of the foreign exchange market and to increase flexibility of the
exchange rate, the volatility band established by the Bankers' Association of the Philippines
(BAP) will be reviewed by the BSP in consultation with BAP with a view to phasing it out as
139

soon as possible, but not later than by end-1998. In the meantime, measures will be taken to
ensure that trading outside the band will not be stopped for more than an hour. Outstanding
contracts under the nondeliverable forward (NDF) facility will be unwound gradually over the
next 18 months and no new contracts (except roll-overs) or similar schemes will be undertaken
by the BSP. The BSP henceforth will channel all its spot foreign exchange transactions (except
those with the government) through the Philippine Dealing System (PDS).
D. External Debt Management

20. Given the recent experience in a number of emerging market economies, strengthening
external debt management is a particular focus under the program. This includes an enhanced
effort both to improve the monitoring of debt flows and stocks, especially of short-term debt.
Regarding debt statistics, the BSP is using a computerized debt management system to facilitate
the compilation of statistics. We are also considering the use of survey methods to add a further
dimension to our monitoring effort. In this context, ongoing technical assistance from the Fund
in the area of balance of payments statistics will pay particular attention also to the debt
statistics. To ensure that the private sector bears the full risks of its borrowing, the government
will continue to refrain from providing any explicit or implicit guarantees on their external loans.
21. We are taking a number of steps to reduce short-term debt and encourage a better maturity
structure of debt flows as well as higher non-debt creating flows. These include, in particular,
several measures to diminish the disincentives to peso intermediation. In this regard, in addition
to the measures described in paragraph 17, foreign currency deposits of residents have been
made subject to a 7.5 percent tax on interest income, and a 15 percent liquid-asset cover
140

requirement, to be raised to 30 percent by mid-1998, has been introduced on foreign currency
deposits. (This is in addition to the 100 percent cover requirement on foreign currency deposits.)
New official external borrowing will be subject to quantitative ceilings under the program.
E. Financial Sector Reform

22. Notwithstanding the sharp deterioration of the economic environment, we are confident that
the Philippine banking system can weather the resulting difficulties and emerge from the
regional crisis in a healthier position. Nevertheless, to maintain the fundamental health of the
system, and to guard against the risk that could arise from a further economic downturn, we are
fully committed to accelerating ongoing efforts to improve our prudential and supervisory
systems as well as to resolve without delay any problems that might emerge in individual
institutions.
23. There are four main elements to our banking reform strategy. First, we are enhancing the
banks' capacity to withstand shocks by raising their capital and encouraging some consolidation
in the industry. Second, bank risks are being reduced by tightening provisioning requirements
and strengthening regulatory oversight. Third, we are leveling the playing field between different
types of instruments, especially with a view to reducing disincentives to peso intermediation.
And fourth, our bank resolution strategy is geared to the twin objectives of dealing expeditiously
with any problem banks while safeguarding the soundness of the banking system. To support
implementation of this plan, we have requested an FSAL from the World Bank as well as follow-
up technical assistance from the Fund/World Bank.
F. Structural Reforms
141


Medium-term fiscal sustainability

24. Our medium-term fiscal strategy envisages an increased revenue effort in order to achieve
higher public savings while also allowing room for increased public investment in infrastructure
and human capital. Accordingly, the medium-term framework provides for the overall public
sector balance to gradually turn from a deficit of 0.9 in 1998 to a surplus of 0.9 in 2003. Over the
same period, investment in infrastructure by the national government will increase from the 1998
level of 2 percent of GNP to 3.2 percent in 2003. Underlying this framework are measures to
increase the tax ratio, as well as a re-prioritization of expenditures through containing public
sector personnel costs, and rationalizing the transfer of funds and responsibilities to local
governments.
25. Major tax policy reform in all areas - income taxes, excises, tariffs and VAT - has taken
place over the past four years, most recently with the passage in December 1997 of the final
phase of the Comprehensive Tax Reform Package (CTRP, the income tax component of reform).
This latter package will have a positive impact on revenues in the medium term, based on a more
rational tax structure. Moreover, the adoption of revenue enhancing measures such as the
planned rationalization of fiscal incentives (paragraph 12) will have a significant revenue impact
over the medium term. Overall, these measures should permit an increase in the tax revenue to
GNP ratio of about 1.8 percentage points over the medium term.
26. Medium-term expenditure reforms to be initiated during the program period will include
shifting to a medium-term budgeting framework under which appropriations will be defined
142

within a three-year rolling macroeconomic framework. This will ensure that the future financial
implications of new expenditure decisions in each budget are made in the context of the medium-
term macroeconomic program. It will also help arrest key sources of expenditure drift, including
the growth of personnel expenditures and of transfers to local governments. Implementation of
this framework is being targeted for 1999 with the assistance of the World Bank in the contest of
the Public Sector Adjustment Loan (PSAL).
27. We will endeavor to move forward the Government Re-engineering Program which was
initiated in 1994. We will re-submit to Congress before the end of 1998, the "Re engineering the
Bureaucracy" Bill in order to obtain full authority to restructure the Executive Branch of
government. We expect the reduction in staffing will result from the merger or abolition of
redundant agencies, the devolution of activities and programs to local governments, and the
further privatization of public services to improve the effectiveness and efficiency of
government. Pending the passage of this Bill, overall national government staffing will continue
to be held down. However, efforts have been undertaken to rationalize compensation in
government to narrow the gap with those of the private sector. With low and middle level
salaries now broadly in line with the private sector, attention can be focused on the remaining
issues of raising civil service executive compensation, de-compressing the salary structure, and
improving overall personnel management.
28. Increased infrastructural investment is critical to our medium-term growth and development
prospects. While part of the increase must come from the National Government (the medium-
term fiscal plan provides for an increase of 0.5 percent of GNP), the private sector and local
governments will need to play a more active role as well. We shall further strengthen the
143

environment for investment in general, and for private sector investment in infrastructure in
particular.
Strengthening the corporate sector
29. Our structural reform agenda will increase the resiliency of the corporate sector mainly by
improving the enabling legal framework, continuing trade and investment liberalization,
developing the domestic capital market, additional privatization, and further strengthening
external debt management.
30. Significant liberalization of the trade regime has been achieved in recent years through
continued tariff reform and steady elimination of nontariff barriers. The average nominal tariff
rate was reduced from 28 percent in 1990 to 13 percent in 1997, with the maximum tariff rate
(which applies to a few agricultural products) lowered from 100 percent in 1996 (after WTO
tarification) to 80 percent in 1997. Quantitative import restrictions were lifted on all agricultural
imports (except rice) in March 1996, accompanied by their tarification as agreed under the WTO.
31. Trade liberalization will continue in 1998-99 and beyond. The average nominal tariff rate has
been reduced to 11.2 percent in 1998, and will be lowered to 10.2 percent in 1999 and to 9.1
percent in 2000. The maximum tariff rate (which applies to some agricultural imports) will be
reduced to 65 percent in 1999. We are also taking measures to increase the transparency of quota
allocation under the minimum access volumes arrangements. Furthermore, in the context of the
WTO, we are committed to reviewing the restriction on rice imports by 2004.
32. We are continuing to make best efforts toward creating an attractive environment and liberal
regime for investment. To this end, further simplification and liberalization of registration
144

requirements will be implemented during the program period. We intend to liberalize the retail
trade sector, particularly to investments in medium-and large-scale firms; draft legislation to this
end will be submitted to Congress during the program period. Investment houses are being
opened up further to foreign investment based on a law passed in late 1997 which raises the
foreign equity participation from 49 percent to 60 percent voting shares.
33. The government remains committed to carrying forward its privatization plans in the coming
years. In 1998, the privatization program is expected to generate P 7 billion, most of which will
come from the completion of the sale of the Fort Bonifacio property. Going forward,
privatization efforts will focus on disposing of remaining major items which are strategically
vital to industrial development particularly the National Power Corporation (paragraph 36).
Other key assets remaining to be sold include the PNOC-Energy Development Corporation and
the Food Terminal.
34. A comprehensive restructuring reforms of the electric power sector has been pursued by the
government, possibly with assistance from the World Bank and ADB. Under this restructuring
reform, the government intends to pursue wholesale competition and produce implementation of
retail competition through the following strategies, among others: (a) separating (unbundling) the
transmission activities of NPC from its generation activities and establishing them as a separate
legal corporate entity; (b) establishing generation companies, followed by incorporation and
subsequent privatization of certain generation companies; (c) refocusing the role and functions of
National Electrification Administration (NEA); (d) encouraging the consolidation/merger of
distribution entities; (e) applying unbundled tariffs at generation, transmission, sub-transmission,
145

and distribution levels; and (f) strengthening the Energy Regulation Board's organizational and
regulatory capacity.
35. To implement this restructuring program, the Omnibus Electricity Bill will be resubmitted to
Congress before end-1998. Based on the new framework, and in close collaboration with the
World Bank and the ADB, an action plan to restructure and privatize the NPC will be launched.
Oil Deregulation

36. A key plank of our structural reform agenda has been the deregulation of the oil sector. The
downstream oil industry was fully deregulated in February 1997, but, effective December 8, the
Supreme Court ruled parts of the deregulation law unconstitutional. A new law was passed in
February 1998, restoring most of the deregulation provisions of the original law while correcting
its constitutional deficiencies. As part of the new regime, a transition period of up to 5 months
was introduced during which prices of domestic petroleum products remain regulated and limited
subsidies can be provided, at the discretion of the President, for the most socially-sensitive
products (liquefied petroleum gas, kerosene, and regular gasoline). By March 15, the President
will issue an Executive Order terminating the transition period for all products except for the
most socially sensitive products. For these latter products, prices will remain regulated until July
1998, at which time they will also be freed. The cost of any price subsidies for socially-sensitive
products will not exceed P 2.9 billion during 1998. This amount will be accommodated within
the revised fiscal program for 1998. Moreover, the outstanding balance under the Oil Price
Stabilization Fund (OPSF) (P 2.6 billion at end-1997) will be gradually repaid through the
application of reimbursement certificates, following the provisions of RA 8479. The total amount
146

used under the new buffer fund for socially sensitive products will not exceed P 2.9 billion, as a
performance criterion under the program.
* * * * *

37. In the current environment of regional uncertainty, close monitoring of developments under
the program will be critical. We are also committed to consulting closely with the fund on
progress with implementing the program. Accordingly, quarterly reviews are envisaged under
the program. The first review, to be completed in May 1998, and subsequent reviews will focus
on (i) implementing the financial program including interest and exchange rate policies, as well
as on (ii) progress with banking reforms and (iii) tax administration. In addition, the second
review, to be completed by August 1998, will provide an opportunity to discuss the new
government's economic agenda, including the measures needed to meet the fiscal target for 1998.

Appendix 7 Philippine Medium Term Development Plan 2004-2010
II. GOALS, STRATEGIES AND ACTION PLANS
A. Targets
Investment rate is targeted to increase from 19 percent to 28 percent of GDP as a result of
increased investment promotion activities. Increased spending on public infrastructure by
PhP100 billion shall be pursued through greater private sector investments. Exports of goods and
services are targeted to increase from US$39 billion to US$50 billion in two years or a minimum
growth of 10 percent every year as the government focuses on priority areas such as ICT,
automotive, electronics, mining, health care, and tourism. These are where the country has
147

comparative advantage because of its human resources and geographic location and the
revitalization of the power, airlines, and shipping industries.The government will strengthen its
program to support three million entrepreneurs and small and medium enterprises (SMEs) by
providing credit, technology, and marketing assistance. Loans to selfemployed small business
owners will be tripled.
B. Strategic Measures
To strengthen and sustain our global competitiveness and create 10 million jobs, the government
will focus on five strategic measures:
1. Make food plentiful at reasonable prices to make our labor cost globally competitive
(Chapter 2: Agirbusiness).
2. Reduce the cost of electricity to make the cost of running our machines and our
manufacturing processes regionally competitive (Chapter 11: Power Sector Reforms).
3. Modernize the physical infrastructure and logistics system at least cost to ensure efficient
movement of goods and people (Chapter 6: Infrastructure).
4. Mobilize and disseminate knowledge to upgrade our technologies and increase our
peoples productivity (Chapter 19: Science and Technology).
5. Reduce red tape in all government agencies to reduce transaction costs (Chapter 21: Anti-
Corruption).
C. Job Creation Thrusts
Job creation shall focus on the following:
1. High skill industries and services, namely, software, business processing outsourcing or
BPO, contact centers, fashion garments, jewelry, medical services, automotive,
electronics, health care;
148

2. Medium skill industries and services, namely, agribusiness (Chapter 2), mining (Chapter 3),
tourism (Chapter 5), hotels and restaurants, entertainment; and
3. Simple skill industries and services such as construction, SMEs, micro-enterprise.
D. Policy Objectives
1. Promote investments in agribusiness.
2. Promote entrepreneurship and SME development.
3. Promote energy independence and savings.
4. Promote investments in infrastructure.
5. Promote investments in exports.





Appendix 8 Philippine Medium Term Macro-Economic Development Plan 2004-2010
Growth strategy
Addressing the fiscal problem is primary and essential to achieve a sustained and accelerated
pace of growth (Chapter 7: Fiscal Strength). If the fiscal problem is not addressed, growth will
considerably be much lower on account of a severe erosion in investors confidence, which could
create balance of payment difficulties, as well as deep cuts in government spending if the
government will seek to achieve fiscal balance by 2010 in the face of lower revenue growth. The
lack of progress on the fiscal front will also increase the risk premium on interest and exchange
rates and undermine long-term investment. The national government is aiming to balance the
149

budget by 2010 and to reduce the CPSD to 1.0 percent by 2010. Underpinning the fiscal program
are measures to boost the revenue to GDP ratio to 18 percent in 2010 from 14.6 percent in 2004,
mainly from higher revenue collection efficiency. A credible fiscal program will lead to a
positive shift in investor and creditor confidence. It will also boost growth by providing the fiscal
resources to raise public infrastructure spending from 2.6 percent of GDP in 2003 to 4.2 percent
of GDP by 2010.
The government is targeting inflation to decline to 3-4 percent by 2007 based on expectations of
a drop in global oil prices and a modest depreciation of the exchange rate. The inflation target is
based on the assumption that Dubai oil prices will fall to less than US$30 per barrel by 2006 as
oil producers, such as Russia, increase supply and geopolitical tensions normalize in Iraq.
Moreover, the peso is to remain stable as market participants see fiscal reforms taking place. The
peso will also be supported by strong capital inflows arising from an improvement in investor
sentiment and higher receipts from exports of goods and services and remittances of OFWs,
which will lead to a current account surplus of 0.5 percent of GDP.
The government is aiming to achieve its growth targets on account of strong investment spending
and exports. Investment spending is targeted to increase to 28 percent by 2010 from around 20
percent in 2003, while exports of both goods and services are targeted to reach more than US$50
billion by 2006. To achieve these targets, the government shall pursue policies that address the
root causes of declining competitiveness (Chapter 1: Trade and Investment). These include
keeping the cost of food items and other wage goods at competitive rates through greater
productivity; reducing transport and distribution costs through better transport and digital
infrastructure and logistics, especially with the completion of the nautical highway system
(Chapter 6: Infrastructure); providing more competitive power
150

rates through the elimination of cross-subsidy between industrial and residential users and
other power sector reforms (Chapter 11: Power Sector Reforms); mobilizing and
upgrading knowledge to increase productivity; and addressing corruption and simplifying
business procedures (Part V).
In addition to policy reforms that will benefit all economic sectors, vigorous support
is given to micro, small and medium enterprises (MSMEs) and agribusiness to decentralize
development and address the problem of high unemployment and rural poverty.
Government financial institutions (GFIs) are being tapped to enhance the access of MSMEs
to credit, technology and marketing information (Chapter 1: Trade and Investment).
The growth strategy also rests on maximizing the use of the countrys natural resources and
geographical competitive advantage through wealth creating projects in mining, exploration of
oil/gas wells, land reclamation, reforestation and maximizing the use of upland resources, and
the development of Subic-Clark as the logistics-center in Asia. Major infrastructure investments
such as the nautical highway and roads in tourist
destinations shall be financed mostly from build-operate-transfer (BOT)-type modes and
nonrecourse project financing where the cash flows of a financially viable project will not
require the proponent to seek government guarantee. Other innovative financing strategies and
revenue-generating strategies include capturing the increase in property values arising from the
development of major roads and highways such as the Subic- Clark-Tarlac Highway. Given the
fiscal constraints, the investment priority plan shall be focused on areas where the Philippines
has natural and human resource advantage. These are identified as: IT-related industries,
BPO/contact centers, tourism, fashion garment, jewelry, medical services/healthcare/wellness,
electronics, automotive, agribusiness/mariculture, and shipbuilding.
151

This investment and export-led growth strategy is expected to boost the industrial
sectorsmining, manufacturing, construction, and utilities. Industry growth is expected to
rise from the modest rate of 4.4-5.2 percent in 2004 to 8.5-9.5 percent by 2010. It shall be
the fastest growing sector. Construction is expected to receive a boost from higher
infrastructure spending and the construction of new power plants to meet 5,200
megawatts of demand to avert a power crisis by 2010. The development of a Halal food
industry in Southern Mindanao is also expected to kick up the food processing industry.
The services sector is seen to expand from 5.7-6.6 percent in 2004 to 7.2-8.2
percent by 2010. It shall benefit from the sustained growth of information and
communications technology (ICT)-related businesses like contact/call centers and BPOs,
which shall prop up the real estate industry. The governments support for tourism is seen
to greatly boost private services. In addition, the financial and banking sector is seen to
grow at a faster pace as business confidence improves and as savings products for small
savers and OFWs are developed (Chapter 8: Financial Sector)
II. GOALS, STRATEGIES AND ACTION PLANS
The primary goal of reforms in the domestic financial system is to mobilize savings to achieve a
savings to GDP rate of 25 percent to 30 percent. This will support an increase in investment ratio
to 28 percent of GDP, with an increasing amount of resources channeled to support the
development of agribusiness, including lending to micro, small and medium enterprises.
Key reforms in the financial market shall focus on: (a) ensuring macroeconomic stability
through prudent monetary and fiscal policy (see Chapter 7 for fiscal reforms); (b) promoting a
152

stronger, stable, and deeper financial system; (c) reforming the pension system; and (d)
providing easier access to funds by SMEs to achieve the target of tripling lending to SMEs and
support their development.
A. Ensure stable macroeconomic environment to reduce long-term risk by managing
inflation
Prudent monetary policy is important for price stability. However, inflationary pressures,
especially those which arise from supply cost factors cannot be addressed by monetary policy
alone since controlling supply and cost shocks through tight monetary policy can undermine
growth and ultimately affect inflation itself. Thus, inflation management will necessitate
pursuing both monetary policy and measures to ease supply constraints and cost build-up.
1. Manage inflationary expectations by announcing inflation target and intensifying
information dissemination on the concept of inflation targeting and core inflation.
2. Mitigate impact of cost-push pressures on the economy:
a. Ensure ample supply of commodities in the domestic market by improving agriindustry
productivity; reducing postproductive costs through improvement in logistics and transport
system; and timely and adequate importation of necessary basic food items and agricultural
inputs (Chapters 2 and 6).
b. Strengthen coordination among public and private stakeholders under the umbrella
of the National Price Coordinating Council.
c. Lessen the impact of imported fuel and energy prices by shifting to least cost
source of energy and reducing dependence on imported energy sources. In
addition, the government shall promote the use of energy-saving devices and timeof-
use demand management practices in the consumption of electricity by
153

industries (Chapter 10).
B. Promote a stronger, stable and deeper financial system
1. Accelerate reduction of nonperforming assets
The Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP) will accelerate financial sector restructuring by
pushing for the intensified implementation of the SPV law to facilitate the offloading of
idle assets from the books of banks and other financial institutions. This will significantly
pare down the banks nonperforming assets.
2. Prevent and minimize systemic risks by strengthening regulations in accordance with
international standards for greater transparency and accountability
a. Amend the BSP charter to include immunity of supervisors from law suits,
authority to compel banks to implement prompt corrective action and higher
capital build-up, shift away from the strategy of forbearance and liquidity
assistance, and stronger criminal and administrative penalties for violations of
banking laws;
b. Amend the Insurance Code to empower the Insurance Commission to preempt
financial distress or intervene to help resolve financial problems of an insurance
company;
c. Provide the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) with adequate legal
protection, access to bank records in an investigation, ability to obtain freeze
orders, and visitorial powers over regulated companies and their auditors.
Furthermore, SECs enforcement actions shall be strengthened through effective
coordination with the Department of Justice, the Supreme Court, the National
Bureau of Investigation and the Philippine Judicial Academy by means of
154

enhancing its law enforcements partners capability to investigate and prosecute
securities fraud cases;
d. Strengthen the framework for quick resolution of financially-distressed enterprises
through the passage of the Corporate Recovery Act;
e. Enhance and rationalize the regulatory framework on investment companies and
the sale of preneed plans through the governments support on the passage of the
Revised Investment Company Act and the Preneed Code;
f. Restructure the Cooperative Development Authority into a regulatory body
through the amendment of the CDA charter to provide the regulatory framework
for the development of cooperatives nationwide. In addition, capacity building for
CDA and other stakeholders shall be pushed in order to implement an effective
regulation and supervision of credit cooperatives;
g. Introduce the risk-based capital adequacy framework for providers of financial
services and products under SEC regulation and supervision;
h. Strengthen consolidated supervision mechanisms via closer cooperation and
coordination among financial services regulatory agencies. This is to rationalize
the incentive structure for the financial sector and achieve competitive parity
across bank and nonbank sectors. The government shall also ensure consistency
of rules and regulations intended for promoting a level playing field and that
overlaps/gaps in supervision are minimized;
i. Intensify coordination and consultation among government agencies, market
participants and private sector groups. This includes the creation of a Financial
Governance Council, establishment of an organized forum to facilitate
155

coordination activities and consultations, and conduct of consultation meetings,
trainings, symposia and related activities on a periodic basis;
j. Implement a coordinated disaster recovery plan to ensure undisrupted operations
or timely reopening of financial sector institutions in the aftermath of a
catastrophic event; and
k. Implement a long-term development plan or blueprint for the Nonbank Financial
Sector to promote growth and expand contributions to the economy.
3. Improve market liquidity
a. Establish a Fixed-Income Exchange capable of providing a modern screen-based
system for dealers of fixed-income securities. This includes the establishment of a
competitive secondary market for corporate debt, a settlement mechanism that
supports an appropriate delivery versus payment process, and firm legal
ownership of bonds being traded recording of ownership to beneficial owner level;
b. Encourage new listings of equities in the Philippine Stock Exchange (PSE). This
includes listing of Board of Investments/Department of Energy -mandated
companies, select government companies, SMEs, and bonds issued to retail
investors and overseas Filipino workers. To promote listings, information
campaigns and related investment-promotion activities shall be conducted from
2005-2010. Likewise, PSEs competitiveness shall be enhanced by improving
liquidity for secondary market transactions and development of in-house think
tank for new products that can be introduced in the exchange; and
c. Develop and fasttrack mortgage-backed securities market encouraging the
immediate securitization of housing loan portfolios of various government
156

Medium-Term Philippine Development Plan 2004-2010
institutions. This can also be done by developing a transition strategy toward
nondistortionary housing support programs, standards and systems in lending,
underwriting and servicing, and fast and effective collateral foreclosure regime
for mortgage lending.
4. Protect investor and creditor rights
a. Minimize investor risk by improving the settlement, clearing, and custodianship of
instruments (e.g., centralized ownership records and elimination of physical
certificates, and introduction of national identification numbers). A national
financial market infrastructure shall be established that will seamlessly link market
activities from trading, clearing and settlement to postsettlement disposition of
equity and debt securities. This includes migration from checks to electronic
payment system, expansion of delivery versus payment coverage to investor level
and across all instrument types, development of custody activities for equity and
debt securities, and dematerialization of all securities;
b. Support amendments to the Corporation Code to enhance minority shareholder
rights and provide remedies for corporate malfeasance;
c. Sustain reforms in corporate governance by aligning corporate practices and
financial reporting structures with international best practices. This includes
strengthening the role of independent directors for public companies and adopting
International Accounting Standards and International Standards for Auditing in
SECs rules and regulations. This also includes implementing certification
procedures for at least one officer or director of financing companies, investment
157

houses, fund managers, distributors and mutual fund/investment companies and
preneed plan companies certified by examination as compliance officers;
d. Support the passage of a Credit Reporting Bill. This would permit sharing of
information to protect investors and lenders and reduce the cost of borrowings by
investors and consumers; and
e. Pursue amendments to the Consumer Act to include protection against fraudulent
consumer financial products and services.
5. Tap savings through new financial products
Support the passage of the Personal Equity Retirement Account Act to improve the
countrys savings rate.
6. Remove tax distortions
Harmonize the tax treatment of financial instruments and institutions to support the
development of the capital market. This shall include, among others, removing the double
taxation of insurance products.
C. Rationalize government pension and retirement schemes
1. Allow increase of members contribution to pension fund to narrow the funding gap.
This will require the updating of actuarial study that shall be the basis for
determining the increase in members contribution to ensure that the financial
condition of pension funds is actuarially sound.
2. Introduce a clear set of credentials or qualifications that will become the basis for
the appointments to the boards of main pension providers, namely SSS and GSIS.
3. Designate an appropriate agency as the regulator to supervise the activities of
pension funds and ensure their viability.
158

D. Increase SME access to financing (Chapter 1: Trade and Investment)














Appendix 7
Majlis Perasmian Kongres Teknologi Maju (Advanced Technology Congress
(ATC) 2003) , Hotel Marriot, Putrajaya 20 Mei 2003, 9.30 pagi
Monday, September 06, 2004
Kongres selaras dengan proses perindustrian Malaysia, yang mana sudah jelas
mengalami peralihan / transition kepada industri-industri yang mempunyai kandungan
teknologi yang tinggi, di samping didorongi oleh proses-proses yang berasaskan
pengetahuan / knowledge based.
Malaysia sudah mempunyai landasan / foundation, untuk menampung industri-industri
159

yang berasaskan teknologi maju dan terkini, dan, diiringi oleh sokongan kerajaan,
dalam menggalakkan pembangunan industri-industri tersebut. Sungguhpun pada
asasnya, industri elektronik dan elektrik merupakan berpotensi yang besar, untuk
perkembangan ke arah aplikasi proses dan bahan-bahan, serta teknologi maju dan
terkini, industri-industri lain, seperti kejuruteraan, pertanian, bioteknologi, dan asas
sumber, juga mempunyai ruang untuk penggunaan teknologi maju, serta bahan-bahan
dan proses-proses terkini.
The continuing process of industrialization in Malaysia, is witnessing the shifting of the
manufacturing value chain up on to a higher plane with higher inputs of technology
and skills, and utilization of new and advanced materials. The breakthroughs in
Research and Development globally, in materials, products and processes, have
enabled investors in the manufacturing, and related sectors, to bring in such new
technology and processes into their Malaysian operations, and on the domestic front,
collaboration between academia and industry have contributed towards market - driven
technological development and research and development.
Malaysia's substantial bio-diversity, and abundance of biomass, have also spurred
R&D into a variety of applications, and spawning projects in the bio-composite
industry, such as the manufacture of products, from fibre - reinforced polymer
composite, utilizing materials such as oil-palm bio-mass, rice husks, and other
agricultural waste fibres.
The government offers tax incentives of either the Pioneer Status or the Investment
Tax allowance for projects manufacturing value-added products from oil palm biomass,
and other agricultural waste, or by-products, and todate, 16 projects with total
investments of RM118.4 million have been approved, with 8 already in operation.
The increasing application of new and advanced technology, has also spurred the
160

establishment of projects to produce automatic and semi-automatic equipment and
systems for production processes and material handling, and more than 30 such
projects are in operation in Malaysia.
Within the electronics industry the utilization of cutting - edge technology has enabled
manufacturers to produce the latest high technology and high value-added products.
Robotics, advanced packaging, micro-electromechanical systems and the manufacture
of other advanced electronic components, as well as nano-technology, are some of the
promoted activities for which tax incentives are offered by the government.
In 2001 and 2002, investments in advanced manufacturing in electronics projects
amounted to RM8.1294 billion.
Although the development of high-technology manufacturing is largely spearheaded
by the private sector, in order to have the necessary competitive edge operating in
the global market, the government, on its part, has put into place, a range of support
programmes, to complement the private sector effort.
The Malaysian Technology Development Corporation (MTDC) has been given the
task of promoting the usage and application of advanced technologies amongst local
industries, through the management of grants, under the Technology Development
Programme (TDP) and the Technology Development Cluster programme.
The Technology Development programme emphasizes the promotion of high
technology application amongst local companies, and the commercialization of R&D
results, through the grants available under the commercialization of R&D Fund and the
Technology Acquisition Fund.
Between 1997 and 2003, a total of 165 projects have been approved with grants
amounting to RM164.98 million, under the programmes. Out of these, 50 projects were
given grants totaling RM45.102 million for the commercialization of R&D, and 115
161

projects were approved grants for Technology Acquisition, totaling RM118.88 million.
The Technology Development Cluster Programme of the MTDC, introduced in
1996, has the objective of providing a physical platform for technopreneurs to
collaborate with local universities and research institutions, in efforts to promote
the commercialization of technology. The programme involves the developing and
managing of technology incubation centers, built within the confines of universities and
research institutions, in which technopreneurs can rent space, and take advantage of
available R&D facilities.
Todate, RM73 million has been allocated in both the RM7 and RM8 for the
development of the Technology Development Centres, and 4 incubation centers have
been built viz:
1. The UPM - MTDC Technology Incubation Centre one, in Serdang, focusing
on IT and Multimedia.
2. The UKM-MTDC Smart Technology Centre in UKM, Bangi, focusing on
biotechnology.
3. UTM-MTDC Technovation Centre at UTM, Saudi, with emphasis on IT and
electronics.
4. UM-MTDC Technology Incubation Centre at UM, Kuala Lumpur focusing on
advanced manufacturing. Another incubation Centre is being proposed by
MTDC, in collaboration with FRIM, to develop a cluster of high-technology
companies involved in forestry-based technology.
Todate, 67 projects have been started in the various technology Incubation Centres.
Close collaboration between Universities and Research Centres, and industry
is essential in order to ensure that there is a matching of supply and needs and
requirement. In particular, R&D efforts should be market driven, and geared towards
162

the need for industry to be increasingly cost efficient, highly productive, and have the
necessary competitive edge that advancements in technology and processes, can
provide.
Industry should optimally utilize the available R&D resources in the Universities and
research centers, and undertake formalized arrangements, to task researchers to
upgrade their manufacturing technology and processes over time. While much of the
advanced technology can be imported sourced from abroad through various licensing,
and other acquisition arrangements the government would like to see more efforts in
developing endogenous technology, particularly in areas and sectors, where Malaysia
already has the competitive edge, and is already a significant market player.
In addition, investments are encouraged in the manufacturing and fabrication of
machinery and equipment which can directly enhance the technological capabilities of
the manufacturing and related sectors, as well as have export potential.
Special incentives are given to encourage such investment, in the form of Pioneer
Status with 100% tax exemption for 10 years, or the Investment Tax Allowance of
100% on qualifying Capital expenditure incurred within period of 5 years. Amongst the
machinery and equipment for which their manufacturing can be given the incentives
are:
Material handling equipment
Robotics and factory automation equipment
Specialized and process machinery for equipment for specific industries
Machine tools.
It is hoped that Universities and research centers can serve as catalysts and prime
movers to encourage small and medium sized manufacturing entities to move towards
automation and systems integration, and to optimize the use of new technology and
163

processes to reduce costs, improve efficiency and quality, minimize wastage, and
meet the dictates of the market place, for responsible care of the environment.
Conferences such as this one organized by Institute of Advanced Technology should
always be market oriented, so that the outcome of the deliberations can help to move
the industrialization forward.









Appendix 8
Governance Indicators


-2.00
-1.50
-1.00
-0.50
0.00
0.50
1.00
1996 1998 2000 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008
Malaysia
Philippines
Political Stability & Absence of Violence/Terrorism
164



Source: The World Bank, 2009

Source: The World Bank, 2009

-0.80
-0.60
-0.40
-0.20
0.00
0.20
0.40
0.60
1996 1998 2000 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008
Malaysia
Philippines
Voice & Accountability
-0.50
0.00
0.50
1.00
1.50
1996 1998 2000 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008
Malaysia
Philippines
Government Effectiveness
165


Source: The World Bank, 2009


Source: The World Bank, 2009

-0.40
-0.20
0.00
0.20
0.40
0.60
0.80
1996 1998 2000 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008
Malaysia
Philippines
Regulatory Quality
-1.00
-0.50
0.00
0.50
1.00
1996 1998 2000 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008
Malaysia
Philippines
Rule of Law
166


Source: The World Bank, 2009






Appendix 9

-1.00
-0.80
-0.60
-0.40
-0.20
0.00
0.20
0.40
0.60
0.80
1996 1998 2000 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008
Malaysia
Philippines
Control of Corruption
Summary of Governance indicators for the Philippines (Selected Years)
Governance
Indicator
Years
1996 1998 2000 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008
Voice and
Accountability
+ + + + + + + - - -
Political Stability - - - - - - - - - -
Governance
Effectiveness
- - - - - - - - - 0
Regulatory
Quality
+ + + - - - - - - -
Rule of Law - - - - - - - - - -
Control of - - - - - - - - - -
167


Source: The World Bank, 2009















Corruption
Summary of Governance indicators for the Malaysia (Selected Years)
Governance
Indicator
Years
1996 1998 2000 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008
Voice and
Accountability
- - - - - - - - - -
Political Stability + + + + + + + + + +
Governance
Effectiveness
+ + + + + + + + + +
Regulatory
Quality
+ + + + + + + + + +
Rule of Law + + + + + + + + + +
Control of
Corruption
+ + + + + + + + + +
168


Appendix 10
Comparison of National Government Revenues (% of GDP)



Source: Asian Development Bank, 2008










169



Appendix 11

Source: Asian Development Bank, 2008
Appendix 12
Selected Technological Indicators, Malaysia, 1999 to 2007
2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999
High-technology exports (%
of manufactured exports)
52 54 55 56 59 58 58 60 59
High-technology exports
(current US$)
64,584
,188,242
63,410
,667,185
57,650
,291,242
53,222
,673,792
47,331
,742,991
43,543
,951,769
40,912
,481,519
46,998
,538,988
39,963
,570,717
Internet users
14,792
,700
13,474
,800
12,465
,300
10,636
,500
8,643,
000
7,842,
000
6,346,
000
4,977,
000
2,800,
000
Mobile and fixed-line
telephone subscribers
27,697
,000
23,805
,822
23,910
,648
19,057
,264
15,695
,561
13,722
,903
12,094
,564
9,756,
093
7,420,
799
Personal computers ..
6,040,
000
5,600,
000
4,900,
000
4,200,
000
3,600,
000
3,000,
000
2,200,
000
1,800,
000
Research and development
expenditure (% of GDP)
.. 1 .. 1 .. 1 .. 0 ..
Technicians in R&D (per
million people)
.. 44 .. 63 .. 57 .. 40 ..
Telecommunications
investment (% of revenue)
.. .. .. 23 23 26 26 28 34
Telecommunications revenue
(% GDP)
.. .. .. 5 5 5 5 4 4

Source: The World Bank

170



Appendix 13
Selected Technological Indicators, Philippines, 1999 to 2007

2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999
High-technology exports (%
of manufactured exports)
69 68 71 73 74 74 72 73 75
High-technology exports
(current US$)
29,507
,842,699
27,625
,618,563
25,997
,824,194
25,855
,091,670
23,942
,090,486
23,867
,718,529
21,013
,784,543
25,240
,098,062
24,163
,367,932
Internet users
5,300,
000
5,000,
000
4,614,
759
4,400,
000
4,000,
000
3,500,
000
2,000,
000
1,540,
000
1,090,
000
Mobile and fixed-line
telephone subscribers
61,284
,896
46,502
,100
38,146
,248
36,373
,368
25,849
,560
18,693
,934
15,474
,254
9,515,
746
5,742,
415
Personal computers ..
6,300,
000
4,521,
000
3,684,
000
2,847,
000
2,200,
000
1,700,
000
1,480,
000
1,260,
000
Research and development
expenditure (% of GDP)
.. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. ..
Technicians in R&D (per
million people)
.. .. .. .. 10 10 .. .. 20
Telecommunications
investment (% of revenue)
.. .. 10 .. 11 .. .. .. ..
Telecommunications revenue
(% GDP)
.. .. .. 24 25 25 44 47 47

Source: The World Bank
Appendix 13b
Internet users (per 100 people)
Economy Years
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008
Malaysia 1 2 7 12 21 27 32 35 42 49 52 56 56
Philippines 0 0 1 1 2 3 4 5 5 5 6 6 6

Source: World
Bank (2010)






171





Appendix 13c Malaysia Internet Users, 1996 to 2008 S Curve

Appendix 13d Philippines Internet Users, 1996 to 2007 S Curve







-20
0
20
40
60
80
M
a
l
a
y
s
i
a

I
n
t
e
r
n
e
t

U
s
e
r
s

Year
Year Line Fit Plot
Malaysia Internet
Users
Predicted Malaysia
Internet Users
-2
0
2
4
6
8
P
h
i
l
i
p
p
i
n
e
s

I
n
t
e
r
n
e
t

U
s
e
r
s

Year
Year Line Fit Plot
Philippines Internet
Users
Predicted
Philippines Internet
Users
172





Appendix 14

Source: ADB








173


Appendix 15

Source: ADB

Appendix 16

Source: ADB

174


Appendix 17


Source: ADB
Appendix 18
Computation Procedure for the Long-term Economic Growth Model
175



|
.
|

\
|
|
.
|

\
|
+ |
.
|

\
|
|
.
|

\
|
+ |
.
|

\
|
|
.
|

\
|
=
L
dL
Y
L
dL
dY
K
dK
Y
K
dK
dY
A
dA
Y
A
dA
dY
Y
dY
Now, divide through by Y and we are done!
Percentage
change in
Production
Elasticity of
Production with
respect to
technology
Percentage
change in
Technology
( ) ( ) ( ) L K A Y
L K A
A + A + A = A % % % % c c c
This is the basic growth accounting equation
Y
X
dX
dY
X
= c
where

176

3
2
3
1
L AK Y =
The most common production function used in Macroeconomics is the Cobb-Douglas
production function
1
3
2
3
1
3
2
3
1
=
|
|
|
.
|

\
|
= =
L AK
A
L K
Y
A
dA
dY
A
c
3
1
3
1
3
2
3
1
3
2
3
2
=
|
|
|
.
|

\
|
|
.
|

\
|
= =

L AK
K
L AK
Y
K
dA
dY
K
c
3
2
3
2
3
2
3
1
3
1
3
1
=
|
|
|
.
|

\
|
|
.
|

\
|
= =

L AK
K
L AK
Y
L
dA
dY
L
c
( ) ( ) ( ) L K A Y A + A + A = A %
3
2
%
3
1
% %
This is the basic growth accounting equation

Year Real GDP (Billions of
2000 dollars)
Real Capital Stock
(Billions of 2000 dollars)
Employment (thousands)
1939 1,142 1,440 29,923
2006 11,257 12,632 135,155
2007 11,467 12,883 137,180
Lets decompose the most recent data first
( ) ( ) | | 85 . 1 100 * 257 , 11 ln 467 , 11 ln % = = AY
( ) ( ) | | 97 . 1 100 * 632 , 12 ln 883 , 12 ln % = = AK
( ) ( ) | | 48 . 1 100 * 155 , 135 ln 180 , 137 ln % = = AL
Note that capital is
growing faster than
employment
( ) ( ) 20 . 48 . 1
3
2
97 . 1
3
1
85 . 1 % = = AA

177

Year Real GDP (Billions of
2000 dollars)
Real Capital Stock
(Billions of 2000 dollars)
Employment (thousands)
1939 1,142 1,440 29,923
2006 11,257 12,632 135,155
2007 11,467 12,883 137,180
Now, lets look at long term averages
( ) ( ) | |
39 . 3 100 *
68
142 , 1 ln 467 , 11 ln
% =

= AY
( ) ( ) | |
22 . 3 100 *
68
440 , 1 ln 883 , 12 ln
% =

= AK
( ) ( ) | |
23 . 2 100 *
68
923 , 29 ln 180 , 137 ln
% =

= AL
( ) ( ) 84 . 23 . 2
3
2
22 . 3
3
1
39 . 3 % = = AA

1939 - 1948 1948 - 1973 1973-1993 1993-2007
Output
5.79 4.10 1.96 2.63
Capital
3.34 4.24 2.10 2.94
Labor
4.46 2.10 1.86 1.60
Productivity 1.71 1.28 0.02 0.59
A few things to notice:
Real GDP growth is declining over time.
Capital has been growing faster than labor
Contributions to growth from capital, labor, and technology vary across time
period

178

( ) L K A F Y , , =
We are concerned with capital based growth. Therefore, growth in technology
and employment will be takes as given
Technology
grows at rate
A
g
Pop
Pop
LF
LF
L
L
|
|
.
|

\
|
|
.
|

\
|
=
Population
grows at rate
L
g
Employment
Labor Force
= Employment Ratio
( Assumed Constant)
Labor Force
Population
= Participation rate
( Assumed Constant)




Appendix 19
Remittance inflows as a % of
GDP
HDI Rank Country 2007
66 Malaysia 1
105 Philippines 11.6

Source: UNDP

Potrebbero piacerti anche