Sei sulla pagina 1di 24

Advocate

ISSN 1175-978X

ISSUE 16

Observations, Analysis and Research from NZ AA Motoring Policy


WINTER 2007

In this issue...

Social value of transport...........p3

AA environmental survey..........p5

A new safety ballgame.............p6

Biofuels - sustainable?..............p8

Emissions trading.....................p11

RMA & infrastructure...............p14

On the popular, yet undeserved, Longevity of Govt Strategies...p18

demonisation of your car


Linking MAG to Next steps.....p24
It’s official: Even 62% of Automobile New Zealand’s total Greenhouse Gas
Association Members believe cars emissions. Or to put it another way AA Advocate is produced by AA
are bad for the environment. And 92% of New Zealand’s Greenhouse Motoring Policy. All articles by AA
yet their belief is a long way from Gas emissions come from the other Research Editor, Peter King, unless
proportional to the actual damage sources. stated.
their cars actually do. And believe it or not the same is true
This is partly because every time a when it comes to local air pollution too. fine particulate (PM10) emissions
television journalist or documentary Although Christchurch has the worst come from diesel vehicles and these
film-maker air quality in vehicles currently produce up to 50
wants a Government figures show New New Zealand times more PM10 than an equivalent
symbol of our Zealand’s 2.2 million private cars most of this petrol vehicle.” Dr Kuschel says.
impact on the account for only 8% of New Zealand’s is attributable The same is also true for Volatile
environment total Greenhouse Gas emissions to home Organic Compounds. Once again
they show heating. It is most of the VOC emissions come from
pictures of car exhaust pipes. only in Auckland where transport air diesel vehicles, and in particular heavy
Certainly cars emit greenhouse gases pollution is the most significant source. diesel vehicles.
and exhaust fumes but comparatively According to Auckland Regional CLEAN. This is not to say that
they are not as bad as many may Council Air Quality scientist Dr Gerda improving emissions from vehicles
think. Kuschel air quality in the urban area is not necessary. But for the past 20
Transport’s share of New Zealand’s of Auckland currently breaches years car manufacturers have been
Greenhouse gas emissions is acceptable levels required under the making vehicles cleaner and cleaner.
19.3% according to the Climate Air Quality National Environmental According to the OECD report “Can
Change Office. But tucked away Standards in relation to fine particulate Cars Come Clean” by 2014 most new
on that website is the revelation (PM10), with the key sources of cars will be effectively low-emitting
that household users of cars only emissions in the region being motor vehicles due to increasingly tough
account for 41% of this. The other vehicles (51%), domestic fires (41%), emissions standards in the main
59% is mostly taken up by trucks and industry (8%). But it’s not the manufacturing nations. As that report
and airplanes. That means that New average petrol car that is causing all says:
Zealand’s 2.2 million private cars the problems.
only account for less than 8% of “In the transport sector, 91% of the continues


The United Nations Food and Agriculture Organisation’s report “Livestock’s Long Shadow” explicitly states
livestock poses a greater climate change threat than transport.

Over the last 20 years, tighter standards have led adopted in other countries), all new conventional petrol
to progressive improvements in vehicle technology. and diesel vehicles that meet these tighter standards will
Improved engine technologies and fuels have be extremely low emitters (and therefore “near clean”)
contributed to significant reductions in emissions in terms of local air pollutants.
of local air pollutants from new vehicles. New petrol COWS. Strangely enough while cars have been taking
vehicles sold in Europe from 2000 onwards (and thus all the rap other significant sources of pollution have
meeting Euro-3 standards) emit around 90% less been quietly excused. Take cows for instance.
CO, NOx and HC than vehicles sold in the 1980s, The average dairy cow emits 2.5 tonnes of CO 2
and emissions from new diesel vehicles have also equivalent per annum. That’s slightly less than the
been reduced significantly. This has contributed to average medium sized car. But we have more than twice
reductions in local pollutants as newer vehicles with as many cows as cars. And while there is every prospect
lower emissions have replaced older, more polluting of a technological solution for reducing our transport
vehicles. emissions to practically nil in the next 50 years there
is far less scope for optimism surrounding agriculture.
In most OECD countries, fleet emissions of NOx, Indeed the Food and Agriculture Organisation of the
CO and HC were at their highest levels in the early United Nations has written a report on the topic entitled
1990s. Since then, they have dropped significantly “Livestock’s Long Shadow” which explicitly states:
(by 20-50%), despite a continuous increase in vehicle- “The livestock sector is a major player, responsible for
kilometres travelled (+25% between 1990 and 2000). 18% of [global] greenhouse gas emissions measured in
The overall result illustrates that technological CO2 equivalent. This is a higher share than transport.”
improvements have made a significant contribution Not only Greenhouse gas emissions are considered. The
to improvements in local air quality in most OECD report also looks at the impact on water resources and
countries over this period. biodiversity. Indeed the overall picture is not a pretty
The current vehicle emission standards have been one. So while the mythology of vehicle pollution was
tightened further (Tier 2 in the United States in 2004, formed in the 1970s when, indeed, car pollution was
Euro-4 in Europe in 2005 and new long-term regulation terrible, since then vehicles have come a very long way.
in Japan in 2005). After the programmed introduction Perhaps it’s time we started looking for more deserving
of these new standards (and equivalent standards icons of pollution that the family car.


Counting for nothing? The automobile,


TDM, and the social value of human bonding
What is the value of visiting grandma? From a purely
materialistic or environmental point of view, the answer
is “none at all”. But that’s not the way we as individuals
or as communities, see it. Grandparents generate a lot of
trips but we have no real understanding of how important
these trips are.
It’s often disparagingly called “our love affair with
the automobile” but what this bit of environmental
monocularism fails to appreciate is the value of the
automobile in the “love economy”. What is the “love
economy”? It’s that part of society’s time and energy
expenditure not devoted to making a return but carried
out for, or out of, love.
Land Transport New Zealand’s Economic Evaluation
Manual has an average value for the economic value of
driving around. For those not involved in work this is given
as around $6.90 per hour while pedestrians and cyclists
time is rated at $4.25 per hour. These figures are used to
determine the value of the time saved through roading
projects to the economy and are based on surveys of road
users own values of their time. But they are silent on the
social value of these trips to those being visited. had no value under traditional metrics. In particular issues
TDM. The topic of travel demand management raises this surrounding the raising of children and care for elderly
question of the social value of ‘bonding” trips between parents have gained attention with occasional, but largely
friends and family members. What is the value of a trip fruitless, efforts to quantify the scale of the love economy
versus a trip deferred? How many telephone conversations generally focussing on volunteerism.
with grandma equate to having a nice cup of tea with LOVE. For the social value of love in the economy is easier
her? And should we price road use so that we make more to assess when we consider its absence. Jennifer Roback
phone calls and have fewer cups of tea? What are the Morse in her book “The Laissez-Faire Family doesn’t work”
implications of putting environmental concerns ahead of uses the example of the costs a orphanage raised, love-
social and mental health ones? deprived, individual.
In the literature the issue of “love economics” has been
The disapproval of others does not deter this child
championed largely by female economists who have been
from bad behaviour because no other person, even
quicker to notice that it is often women who are expected
someone who loves him very much, matters very much
to take on more unpaid work out of “love” than their male
to him. He responds only to physical punishment and
counterparts. Marilyn Waring, for example, in “Counting
for Nothing” pointed out that the entire love economy
continues

Where love is at stake the


value of time increases and
public transport is a poor option


The role of the car in the wedding ceremony


demonstrates its symbolic integration into
our love lives. Not too many brides would
accept a “bicycle built for two” substitute.

to the suspension of privileges. . . . He lies if he thinks it


back in the 1970s when fewer suburban mothers
is advantageous to lie. He steals if he can get way with
could escape by driving a great many more ended up
it. . . . As he grows into adolescence, he may become a
“running to the shelter of mother’s little helper” as the
sophisticated manipulator. He can charm therapists, social
Rolling Stones put it.
workers, counsellors, and later perhaps even judges and
The same is true of the elderly. Medical conditions
parole officers.
can mean older people stop walking before they stop
This chilling description of a notional individual seems driving. According to the 1999 Travel Survey visiting
remarkably close to so many of those who grace the headlines friends was the motivation behind half the trips made
in this country. Morse develops the argument that only by an by retirees. Those trips are very important to these
initial offering of trust by one individual that is reciprocated by people and arguably prolongs life considerably.
another can a society escape the “prisoners dilemma” where Artificially increasing the cost of those trips simply to
the pursuit of self-interest fails to bootstrap the society into ration the road because they have no apparent value
a civilisation rather than a chaotic collection of rational but is discount the value of elderly lives.
ultimately bestial individuals. And then there is the role of the automobile in New
So why is the car so much a part of the love economy? Zealand mating rituals. For most young people a car
TIME.The simple answer is what we know instinctively: where is the first place where they can claim a private space
love is concerned time matters. If a child is sick at school it away from the interruptions of family and friends.
matters that a parent can pick him or her up before the end Automobility is also an important part of attracting
of the school day. When someone needs a hug it’s not a time a mate in that many young men invest considerable
to lecture them on global warming. A car connects one place sums of money in their vehicles, not just to compete
with another directly and efficiently without the frustration of with one another, but also to attract young women.
making multiple connections, waiting for buses which are late It is doubtful, if this was a complete waste of money,
or finding change which shopkeepers won’t give. Cars make that they would continue to do so.
connections between people easier than any other form of SEVERANCE? For while the car has been accused
transport. of creating “community severance” by breaking up
The interesting thing about love however is that it can result the neighbourhood village (as visibly evidenced in
in people paying higher prices. In California tolled express 47 years of Coronation Street episodes) the car also
lanes tend to be used by those who can afford them and brings people together again. Every summer New
women who will spend any amount of money to get to their Zealanders take to the roads in their millions not just
children quickly. When love is tested the notion of rational as tourists but also to visit their friends and family. The
self-interest can go out the window. It would be cynical in the commercial importance of friends and family is what
extreme in any road pricing scheme however to exploit such drives retail advertising in the telecommunications
human vulnerabilities to obtain greater returns. sector. Instead of being geographical communities
Our love affair with automobiles is linked to our expressions we have become networked communities.
of care for one another. Cars gain sentimental value because Ultimately the issue is the value of social benefits.
of the associations we have with them in relation to other And while we have values for social costs of PM10
people. Cars are used to convey love in a far more personal emissions, road crashes and the dollar value of the
sense than a telephone can. market economy it is odd that we have no social
Mothers are huge users of cars. Certainly the biggest difference benefit value for social connectedness, or indeed
between the number of cars on the road in the 1970’s and the love. Placing any kind of value on it is, to say the least,
number today is that a far greater proportion of women are highly problematic. But to suggest it has no value at all
licensed and have access to a car. And increasingly mid-day would be to completely misunderstand the nature of
traffic is boosted considerably by mothers with pre-school transport demand, and, the factors that come to play
children driving around visiting one another. This is a perfectly when attempting to ‘manage’ demand for it.
normal response to the pressures of motherhood. Indeed


AA Environmental Survey Results

New Zealanders are very concerned about climate change majority (87%) were concerned about humanity’s effect
but have very little idea what to do about it. This is the on the environment. Some 52% disagreed with the
main outcome of the latest AA Membership survey on suggestion that the Government was overreacting to
the environment.The Survey, carried out in March 2007, climate change while only 22.3% agreed. A significant
obtained 547 valid responses with a margin of error of majority (62%) agreed with the suggestion that cars are
4.55% in a demographic spread closely matching the New bad for the environment. That said 75% couldn’t imagine
Zealand 2006 census. giving up their cars; 72% disagreed with the suggestion
The survey found that 3% of AA Members had been that the costs for using cars should be increased; and
engaged in environmental protests or activism in the past 12 71% disagreed with the suggestion that the Government
months, and a further 14% subscribed to an environmental should stop investing in roads.
group or Party. In addition 19% had once subscribed to an A slight majority (55%) agreed they would be prepared
environmental group. However 52% had never had anything to pay more for a fuel that reduced their Greenhouse Gas
to do with environmentalism. emissions.In terms of general environmental consumerism
Our first objective was to determine (where possible) where the only activity that had widespread habitual support
attitudes had changed and what sort of responses Members (89.2%) was rubbish recycling. Using permanent shopping
had to concerns about the environment. By repeating our bags (30%) or buying environmentally friendly goods
2002 survey questions on motoring concerns and our 2003 (38%) were not widespread habits nor was walking or
question on car qualities we were able to determine that cycling to avoid car use (15.8%).
a definite shift in attitudes had occurred. Where driver ACTION. In response to carbon emissions the most
behaviour dominated the 2002 concerns about motoring popular option for action was to substitute one in five trips
in 2007 this had been eclipsed by investment in public with walking or cycling (67%), then came learning to drive
transport, although driver behaviour, investment in roads more economically (60%) and switching to biofuels (58%).
and traffic congestion effects were close behind. Curiously Less popular options were to buy a scooter or hybrid car,
concern about petrol prices itself was lower in 2007 than or paying for carbon credits.
in 2002. The overall picture the survey finds is one of a nation of
BUYERS. When it came to car qualities, however, economy people who care about the environment and are willing to
and safety tied for first place, closely followed by price, do something but are not prepared to be disadvantaged.
history etc. In 2003 the main concern was whether a vehicle People value their personal mobility far higher than any
was the right size to meet the buyers needs. It is clear notional concerns about the planet. They don’t mind
that concerns about the safety of New Zealand’s driving walking or cycling, but only if convenient. They rely
environment still weigh heavily on buyers minds and may heavily on their cars and would like to see a better public
lead buyers to sacrifice some economy for a better sense transport system available. They are also generally well
of security. disposed to learning to drive more economically and/or
Asked the extent to which they agreed or disagreed to using biofuels.
statements about the environment, the overwhelming


It’s Not Working


Needed - a whole new road safety paradigm
2010 is now only two and a half years away. The 2010 Road and vehicles) has increased.
Safety Strategy is to achieve a roading system which kills IDIOTS. Does this matter? Politically the brutal answer is
no more than 300 people and hospitalises no more than probably not. After years of Government propaganda the
4,500 others by 2010. As of 5 June 2007 the 12-month voting public (who inherently think they are better than
rolling death toll was 401 with data on hospitalisations not average drivers) believe road trauma is caused by human
available. This is some improvement on the 461 figure for error, by other drivers who are socially irresponsible or not
2003 when the strategy was published but not much on as good as he or she is. It is in the nature of sharing the
the 2002 figure of 405 the year previously. road to get irritated with other road users so it is easy for
In fact, despite the 2010 Road Safety Strategy, on an end-of- motorists to imagine that road trauma is caused by the
April annual basis, for the years 2002 to 2007 there has been “bloody idiots” who vex them so often.
no appreciable change in the road toll at all. The figure has The problem is that not all the drivers who are killed and
fluctuated around the 400 mark. Meanwhile hospitalisations injured are bloody idiots. In fact a tour of the Crash Analysis
from 2002 to 2006 have climbed from 6,500 to 7,500, well System with the maps set to differentiate between crashes
shy of the 4,500 target. Indeed this, if anything, is more caused by speed, alcohol or “other” shows that at least
of an indicator of the failure of the strategy than number half of the crashes are caused by factors other than the
killed which is a more random number. traditional “bloody idiot” ones. In fact CAS shows quite
When the 2010 Road Safety Strategy was first proposed clearly that the causes of road crashes vary considerably by
in 2000 it was based on the notion that we would achieve locale. In some spots crashes are linked to road geometry,
year 2000 level of world’s best practice in ten years. Seven in others fatigue is a recurrent theme, while in others again
and a half years later and we are now even further behind alcohol is a significant factor.
world’s best practice than we were when we started. Up until recently these factors would have been tackled
EVIDENCE. To be blunt so far there isn’t much evidence piecemeal by various agencies depending on their interest.
that the 2010 Road Safety Strategy has really changed Thus engineers would investigate engineering solutions,
anything. We still operate a land transport system that police would investigate enforcement solutions and road
expects to kill 400 people every year and hospitalise 7,500. safety coordinators would chip in with whatever local
Over a decade that’s 4,000 dead and 75,000 hospitalised. authorities could do. But a new approach has recently been
Who takes responsibility for this? pioneered by Transit in the Waikato which has shown how
One can hardly blame the “average” motorist. Over the cross-discipline teams can have a far greater impact on
period the percentage of passengers wearing seatbelts has road safety than these uncoordinated efforts.
improved to around 95%, Rural speeds have come down, SWATT 2010. The South Waikato and Taupo Target 2010
such that in 2006 the fastest 15% travel average 103km/h project has reduced crash costs by nearly two-thirds for a
while the average speed is 96km/h. The number of drunk 200 kilometre stretch of road from Piarere to the Desert
drivers killed has remained fairly static at around 60 per Road Summit. The road had a poor safety record, with 803
year. The only good news is that the proportion of the reported crashes between 1998 and 2002, 118 of which
population killed has reduced as the population (of people were fatal or serious.


SWATT 2010 deployed 114kms of


edgeline. The cost of applying it to
the entire State Highway network is
relatively low. The benefits enormous.
Transit Waikato manager Alan Burkett started the ball rolling Police have to stop 2,133 people to get 26 prosecutions.
when he made it a personal mission to improve the safety That’s 2,107 drivers stopped for nothing.
performance of this area. The team he ultimately collected More likely to be effective would be introduce a compulsory
included Police, local authorities, engineering consultants, alcohol treatment programme for all those on their second
academics and even comedians. or third drink-driving offence. Recidivist drink-drivers are
The cornerstone of the effort was CAS. It showed what the generally alcoholics whose illness costs the country in more
problems were. In a lot of places – particularly Taupo and ways than road trauma. Tools such as interlocks are useful
Tokaroa – fatigue was major factor. In others road geometry but do not treat the underlying disease. In Sweden the
and others again speed and run-off-road problems. The response has been specialist prisons for alcoholics which
engineering solutions included: 114km of audible edgeline have been successful.
(“rumblestrips”); better skid resistance on some curves; and Low cost road treatments can also have a dramatic impact
a new approach to signage on difficult corners. But it was on road safety. A recent study by TERNZ has found audible
the social solutions which were novel. roadmarkings can have a profound effect on two of New
In many parts of the route the myth had developed that Zealand’s most common accident types: run-off road and
crashes were largely due to through-traffic. CAS however crossed centre line. A benefit-cost ratio of around 14 has
showed that in fact local drivers were a significant part of been found for a reasonably high volume section of state
the problem. Getting this through to local people took on highway. The cost of edgelining most of the state highway
a variety of different forms. One of these was to employ network is small compared to the benefits so there is clearly
comedian Mike King to educate mill workers in Tokoroa much to be gained from applying the technology far more
during their breaks on fatigue issues. Mr Burkett says this widely than it has been to date
had the full support of mill management and achieved far EDUCATION. Finally the Automobile Association has long
higher message retention rates than more conventional held that road safety authorities have consistently under-
publicity efforts. estimated the importance of road user education. Indeed
ONE-OFF. Despite a BCR of over 7 SWATT 2010 is a one- the focus on road safety education has diminished since the
off. Although a lot of lessons have been learned there is no amalgamation of Transfund and the Land Transport Safety
plan to replicate this approach around the whole country. Authority. The example of “Mike King’s” in-the-workplace
And it is unclear from the Next Steps process where safety education shows that there is more to getting through to
will fall in the new Land Transport and Ministry structure. people than a large television advertising budget.
For there is a tendency for agencies to retreat into the core What SWATT 2010 has shown is that if road controlling
business they know so well. Take alcohol for example. The authorities are prepared to take road safety personally
Police campaigns to target drink-driving have probably and apply best-practice engineering, enforcement and
saved 400 lives a year since the worst years back in the education the reduction in trauma can be significant. Now
mid-1980s. But reliving this past glory by reducing the all we need is a structure that can deliver this on a routine
drink-drive limit is unlikely to have much impact. A recent basis to the whole country.
Herald-on-Sunday article showed that even in Northland


Biofuels – Sustainable fuel?

Before and After. Tropical rainforest “cleaned” (as it is termed there) in Bolivia for soybeans

AA Membership surveys have found that motorists are of embodied CO2. Although Brazil claims its biofuels are
generally well-disposed towards the idea of biofuels. The produced sustainably environmental groups claim that it
perception among consumers appears to be that they has no real control on Amazonian deforestation. While
are an easy, guilt-free way to do something about climate scientists disagree about the net affect of forest cover in
change with minimal increased cost and inconvenience. other parts of the world all agree that tropical rain forests
The reality, however may be something quite different. are a vital global sink for carbon.
There are two main forms of biofuel. Ethanol (alcohol) Thus the combination of a biofuel sales obligation and
distilled from plants, and edible oils, either from plants ordinary market economics strongly suggests that the New
or from animal fats. On the 13th of February 2007 the Zealand Government could be adding to the problem
Government announced it would require oil companies to of international biofuel demand without necessarily
increase the quantity of biofuels they sell each year such contributing much to the issue of international biofuel
that by 2012 they reach 3.4% of total fuel volume (7.25 supply. This raises the whole question of why biofuels are
petajoules). In all cases the biofuels would be blended so attractive in the first place.
with mineral fuels, hence the terminology B5 or E3 refers UNFCCC. Under the United Nations Framework
to a 5% biodiesel or 3% ethanol blend with mineral fuel. Convention on Climate Change if one digs up mineral
These appear to be the levels the Government seems to oil one is not liable for any emissions other than those
expect to apply to all fuel sales by 2012. associated with refining it. It is not until it is burnt that the
It was initially thought that this could be achieved by mineral oil is deemed to be released. But if one grows
sourcing biofuels from Fonterra, which manufactures biofuels they are deemed to be released as soon as they
ethanol as a by-product of casein production, and from are harvested. One only has to account for any emissions
tallow, which is rendered from animal carcasses. There is, if the land is not replanted with more biofuel feedstock
however, no restriction on oil companies on where they plants. Thus if one imports biofuels one doesn’t have to
source biofuels to meet this obligation from. account for their emissions at all, because the accounting
DEFORESTATION. The problem is one of price. Biofuels must be done in the harvesting nation. Now of course
in New Zealand are not viable below US$60 a tonne but most harvesting nations are not Annex I or Annex II nations
Brazil already produces ethanol for US$37 a tonne. The and have not signed up to reduce their Greenhouse gas
reason is that producing biofuel requires four main things: emissions. In other words the Kyoto Protocol itself tacitly
land; labour; sunshine and water. The cheapest land and rewards Western nations for replacing their mineral oil
labour plus the most abundant sunshine and water is to imports with biofuel imports.
be found on Earth’s equator in areas currently covered in The Biofuel Sales Obligation creates an attractive
rainforests. And already there are signs that a growing environment for oil companies to cash in on this loophole.
interest in biofuels in the West is leading to perverse The Government has imposed a $20-30 million per
environmental outcomes. Petajoule penalty for each Petajoule the oil companies
“ Biofuels are rapidly becoming the main cause of fall short of their biofuel sales obligation. The failure to
deforestation in countries like Indonesia, Malaysia and substitute a petajoule of biofuel for a petajoule of petrol
Brazil,” Simone Lovera, managing coordinator of the Global results in a carbon liability of 67,240 tonnes of CO2e (ie
Forest Coalition an environmental NGO based in Asunción, the burning of a petajoule of petrol). A $20 million penalty
Paraguay told Interpress Service. Since 2004 Paraguay has is therefore the equivalent of a carbon price of $297 per
enacted tough anti-deforestation laws in order to preserve tonne CO2e. This is 27 times higher than the $9.60 per
the forests it has left. Other nations are not necessarily so tonne which the Government uses to account for its own
interested. Kyoto Treaty obligation.
It is estimated by the FAO that deforestation is occurring Having created a demand the question is where will the
at 20,000 hectares per day. Since 1999 Palm oil production fuel come from to meet it; New Zealand or international
in South East Asia has doubled, often through draining markets. Hale and Twomey’s “Biofuels Supply Options”
wetlands which then go on to emit hundreds of years worth (March 2006) attempted to answer this question.


Currently the only industrial producer of biofuel in New Waste Solutions is Dunedin based company using also
Zealand is Fonterra’s ethanol production from whey. Of developing biodigestors but its approach is to use
this the report says: putrifying waste streams. The company has teamed
up with Dunedin district councils for pilot plants. The
Currently the only ethanol produced in New Zealand is
company estimates the total ethanol potential of all the
from Anchor Ethanol, which produces ~ 16 million litres
major putrescible waste sources in New Zealand to be 275
per annum. Current oil prices landed in New Zealand
million litres/annum (5.8PJ). It is however still, very much,
would likely attract only about 2-4 million litres of Anchor
a research and development firm.
Ethanol production to a fuels market because of the
IMPORTS.If the actual availability of biofuels in New
higher realization available for the rest of production.
Zealand is not large according to Hale and Twomey the
Anchor’s ethanol production is highly seasonal so this
international market for biofuels is an extremely thin one
could be problematic for sales obligations defined as set
as well.
percentages of unit sales. Flexibility for Anchor capacity
Discussions with market participants indicate traded
to process other wastes for a further ~15 million litres
volumes of ethanol internationally are around 2.4 bln
would require investment in handling facilities at site.
litres, of which 1.6 bln litres goes to industrial beverage
Given that ethanol yields 21.2 MJ of energy per litre this markets and the balance 0.8 bln litres to the fuels market.
means that 4 million litres of ethanol is only 84.8 terajoules F.O Licht’s analysis would suggest that virtually all of the
or 0.084 of a petajoule, well short of the target. However trade flow came from Brazil.That means that as of the end
At current realization some 2-4 million litres of Anchor of 2005 there were only 16.9 Petajoules of fuel based
Ethanol’s current production could be attracted to fuel ethanol traded in the whole world.
ethanol, although this would still be unacceptable against Production volumes for biodiesel are much smaller at less
the alternative of lactose. For additional production, than 5 bln litres. The bulk of production occurs mainly in
i.e. diverting whey from edible lactose production, the the EU and there is little in the way of internationally traded
capital and operating costs are about the same for both biodiesel. However like bioethanol the impact of various
lactose and ethanol production, so ethanol would need policies supporting biodiesel is expected to see strong
to compete against the international price of lactose growth in biodiesel production as well.
(US$800/tonne). This is equivalent to US$1.60/litre of So there was practically no biodiesel market by 2005
ethanol (1 tonne of lactose makes 500 litres of ethanol) either.

New Zealand maize will always be more expensive than Brazilian sugar

PLAYERS. Thus, not only is the volume wrong, so is the But this state of affairs is unlikely to remain for long as
price. But if New Zealand producers are going to enter the New Zealand is not alone in mandating more biofuels.
biofuels market they are going to need to start building According to Hale and Twomey the US will require 4.6%
plants quite soon. So far the only companies which have of fuel consumption to include biofuels by 2012, the EU
declared a clear interest are Argent Energy, Lanzatech and has non-binding targets for 5.75% by 2012, and Japan and
Waste Solutions. Thailand are also setting relatively high targets for 2010.
Argent Energy is an offshoot of a British biodiesel In other words there will be international demand.
manufacturer which has established an office in Mt The question then becomes will it be more cost-effective
Maunganui but has yet to announce the construction of to develop a New Zealand capability or rely on growing
a biodiesel factory. The British firm has developed in an international supply from places like Malaysia, Indonesia,
environment with a good deal of Government support, and Brazil?
none of which is available in this country. RETURN. The test will come from biodiesel for bioethanol
Lanzatech is a Waikato research and development is simply not in the race. According to Hale and Twomey
enterprise which claims to have developed a biological even the meanest Northland dairy country is currently
process for converting carbon monoxide to ethanol. While returning $200 per hectare more from dairying than it
the company has an excellent technical pedigree and a would from growing maize. Moreover in “An Estimate
investor list most firms would give their right arms for it is
not a volume producer of ethanol in any market. continues
10

The Government has funded a great deal


of research into the viability of biofuel
production in New Zealand but ultimately its
own business risk exposure is zero.

of the Cost, Energy Ratio and Carbon Balance of Maize the Government, which is already struggling with the issue
Ethanol in New Zealand ” the author, Dr Henderson, of consentability in the energy sector, may wish to admit.
estimates production of 1PJ of ethanol from maize would Then there is regime change risk. Any investor would like
require 9,750 hectares (the equivalent of about 100 dairy to think that the biofuel sales obligation would not cease
farms). With the current market price ($295/tonne) the with the next election. And of course there are commercial
quantity of maize needed to produce 1PJ would cost $34 risks. The latest price for edible tallow on the Wall Street
million. A PJ of petrol at the current importer cost of 77.9 Journal price centre is $900/T which is double the 2006
cents per litre currently costs $24 million. This suggests price and considerably higher than the $700/T upper limit
that maize based ethanol would require either a significant used by Covec in their 2006 economics study where $700/T
reduction in the market price of maize or a significant yielded a biodiesel price of 75c/l. The CO2 price on the
increase in the price of petrol to be economic. EU ETS collapsed months after that study was completed
TALLOW. But to produce biodiesel New Zealand has the and this was a large part of the justification for biodeisel.
advantage that it already produces 150,000 tonnes of Mineral diesel import prices have gone from 70c/l to 90c/l
tallow of which 134,000 tonnes is suitable for biodiesel and back down to 77c/l in less than 18 months – making the
production. This is shipped from Bluff (18kT), Timaru (37kT), competitive price very difficult to assess. And steel prices
Napier (18kT), New Plymouth (18kT), Mt Maunganui (18kT) (used to assess plant cost) are up between 60-100% in the
and Auckland (25kt). Each tonne of tallow effectively can Asian region since December 2005 according to MEPS.
be transformed into a tonne of biodiesel. Finally, of course, interest rates have increased 125 basis
The logistics question is what size plant or plants to build points since 2005 and show little signs of declining.
and how to integrate these into the diesel supply chain. RISK. Thus while it is relatively easy for Government
This is discussed at length in “Enabling Biofuels – Biofuel departments to convince themselves that the risk of
Distribution Options” another Hale and Twomey paper. investment is worthwhile based on historic data the actual
Essentially the issue boils down to whether biodiesel is business of carrying out such investments is somewhat more
manufactured centrally or locally and blended with mineral fraught. Moreover New Zealand does not have a good
diesel at the refinery or at oil terminals. Hale and Twomey track-record when it comes to private sector investment in
calculate the lowest cost option is to manufacture at two new technology ventures. All too often foreign investors
or three $30 million plants and blend at the refinery. find our regulations, reluctance to intervene in markets
This, of course, is all very well for Government and its and local opposition uncompetitive with other nations. The
consultants, but there is precious little risk in manufacturing Government has made much of New Zealand becoming
reports and significantly more in spending real money a centre of research-led development. Biofuels will be
to establish a biofuel plant. And the risks and costs are an interesting indicator of the competitiveness of our
not necessarily those the Government may want to sustainability-focused development model compared to
consider. For example consent risks may be more than those in Malaysia, Indonesia and Brazil.
11

Emissions trading – means, or end in itself?

She can’t help emitting so under


emissions trading farmers must
pay, one way or another.

The Government has announced that it has begun a process price of the penalties is the limit of the price any market
to rapidly develop a greenhouse gas emissions trading participant will be willing to pay in the market.
market for New Zealand. By August this year it will reveal the It should not be forgotten that carbon markets differ
design it hopes to bring before the Parliament. Outlining the to other markets in that they are a tax on a by-product,
principles the market will The only sanction on New Zealand agreed under the Kyoto not a component
operate under Climate Protocol is an increase in liability in a subsequent commitment of production.
Change Minister David period of 1.3 times the outstanding commitment. For example cows
Parker said it will apply to produce milk and
all greenhouse gases and be applied high in the value chain methane as a by-product. To make money Fonterra needs
to corporates such as Fonterra, electricity generators, oil milk, the permits for methane are a tax on the level of by-
importers and the top 15 industrial emitters. On the other product emissions that implies. In the fisheries market the
side of the balance sheet individual forest owners will also right to a level of quota is a licence to sell fish. Without fish
be able to participate. According to the Minister the regime processors have no product. The equivalent to a carbon tax
will have negligible effect on Gross Domestic Product and in fishing would be a tradable permit system on by-catch.
milk solid payouts. This, according to economists however, Thus the obligation to cover emissions is effectively a tax
can only be so if the price of carbon remains fiscally neutral on production based on the level of by-product created
– i.e less than the level of the business tax cuts. by a given type of technology.
TARGETS. The price, however, depends very much on RESPONSE.To reduce this tax a market participant has
the degree of greenhouse gas reduction the Government three main options: reduce production; improve the
targets in each sector. Were the Government to adopt the technology ; or pay for offsets which mitigate the effects
Green Party’s call to reduce emissions to 1990 levels it is of emission (i.e plant trees). In nearly all cases reducing
highly likely that the price would be ruinously expensive. production also means reducing income so unless the
One cannot fit a size nine (88 kilotonnes CO2e by 2012) market price of carbon has reached 100% of a product’s
carbon “footprint” into a size six carbon “shoe” (62 CO2e marginal profit it is highly unlikely a firm will choose this
kilotonnes in 1990) without a lot of gory amateur surgery. option.
The alternative, of course, to paying the market price, The different markets touched by emissions trading are
is to pay the penalty for not covering emissions with the not equal when it comes to the first option.For example
necessary permits. And ultimately it is the scale of these oil importers can import biofuels which do not count for
penalties which determines the price in the market. For the continues
12

CO2 emissions almost immediately, while dairy farmers For motorists the question is how tight will the screws on
will have to wait several bovine generations for breeds the oil companies be? The fewer permits the oil companies
which produce less methane, and cement sinters have are allocated the more they will have to buy permits in the
only marginal technological improvement options for the emissions market to cover their fuel sales. The tighter the
process of burning limestone inevitably emits CO2. permit market becomes, the higher the price, and therefore
Paying for offsets is effectively an indirect subsidy for the more the incentive for oil companies to either import
forestry. And it is notable that if New Zealand incorporates biofuels, or pay for forest owners to grow trees. But the
forestry it will be the first carbon market in the world to do money for permits has to come from somewhere, and
so as the European Trading System (ETS) has no plans to it is inevitable that that “somewhere” will be motorists
incorporate sinks in the next (2008-12) containment period. pockets.
As an industry forestry relies heavily on low value land and How much money? That depends on how much the
international demand for logs and paper. With depressed Government thinks the transport sector can improve its
international log prices in recent times, high land values in emissions performance by. It has already set a target for a
the Southern Waikato have led some foresters to pull out technological fix through the Biofuel Sales Obligation. This
of the industry (partly because they feared Kyoto charges requires the substitution of 3.4% of current imports with
for land use change) because better money could be biofuels by 2012. If the permit level is higher than this it will
made selling pretty farms than dark foreboding forests. have to come from either offsets or volume reduction.
Until a value for carbon is established in this market it will According to “Impacts of Petrol Prices on Consumption
not be possible for foresters to know whether to resume and Travel Demand – New Zealand Evidence” by David
planting or not. Kennedy and Ian Wallis it would require something like a
ALLOCATION.The Government has not yet indicated 30% increase in petrol prices to obtain a 5% reduction in
how it will allocate carbon permits. In Europe this proved total petrol consumption. This is the difference between
to be the undoing of the first trial market period when petrol at $1.60 and $2.00. But to obtain a 5% reduction in
it was realised that more permits had been issued than demand by hiking the price 40 cents a litre would require a
were required in March 2006. This led the ETS price to whopping carbon price of about $175 a tonne CO2e. This
fall from €25 tonne to €2 tonne in fairly short order. Under simply isn’t going to happen.
the ETS permits are allocated by EU nations based on For long before the price reaches $175 a tonne someone
Kyoto accounting procedures to emitting (large) firms will be offering forest sink credits. That’s because a forester
over a certain size. Allocations for the coming Kyoto could make $150,000 per square kilometre per year at even
commitment period have already proved vexed with Britain $50 per tonne CO2e. Indeed economic consultancy Motu
and Germany (which under the Kyoto Protocol already have has found that a carbon tax of $50 per tonne would prompt
over-allocations of carbon because they have switched to considerable land use change all over the country.
nuclear and natural gas from coal since 1990) complaining SINKS. And its just as well sink credits are available because
that the other European nations are continuing to seek if prices could skyrocket our export sector would be in deep
to over-allocate ETS permits in order to shield their doo-doo. For a dairy farmer the average cow produces
industries from the need for Kyoto cut-backs. Naturally 322kg of milksolid and 2.7 tonnes of CO2e per annum.
Britain and Germany wish to see more ETS pressure to Fonterra’s last payout was $4.59 per kilo of milk solids. A
reduce emissions on their neighbours so they maximise $50 a tonne CO2e carbon price would reduce that by 42
the advantage of their Kyoto based over-allocations for a cents effectively reducing average dairy farm incomes from
better price. And equally naturally they don’t want forestry $126,500 to $114,900, the equivalent of a 10% additional
in the market because it would spoil their advantage. income tax. At $175 per tonne the milksolid equivalent is
Minister Parker has indicated that the Government will $1.47 per kilo equal to an extra 33% income tax. In other
allocate permits to sectors on the basis of previous words without forestry under an emissions trading scheme
emissions less a degree of reduction deemed possible in gunning for motorists would be a fine way to kill New
each sector. An alternate approach would be to place an Zealand’s leading export industry.
overall limit on the number of permits available, create a And that is one of the problems with any emissions trading
legal obligation to have permits to cover emissions, and market. It links a series of industries by a tradable tax on
simply auction the permits to the obliged parties. This is one common by-product. Normally there is very little that
the approach being pursued in Britain and advocated by connects the economics of the aluminium market to the
the Green Party. Econometrists have, however warned cement market to the dairy market to the forestry market. A
that such an allocation method would produce significant single emissions trading market now means these industries
disruption to real markets. will be linked through the taxes levels they pay on one
How far the Government tightens the screws on various of their by-products. If one industry creates demand for
sectors will depend very much on what it thinks the effect of permits which hikes the price of carbon all the connected
doing so will bring. And in effect in doing so it is providing industries will feel the burn.
an indicator of the break-points between “encouraging” There is little doubt that the design of the market announced
the adoption of less emitting technologies until these by Minister Parker will, indeed, be world leading. It will
become too expensive and simply purchasing sink credits cover all gases, all sectors and include sinks. No other
from foresters. The tighter the screws become the higher market does that. Indeed it is hard to escape the impression
the effective subsidy to the forestry sector. that having a “world leading” market has to a large extent
13

European carbon prices are based on


European currencies, EU targets and
relatively enormous firms - importing
them should only be done with care

been an objective from the outset. Some naively hope that of ETS prices (on the grounds they would relatively be
New Zealand can bootstrap itself to become a centre for inflated) but the prices he refers back to under the Clean
carbon trading. But given that penalties and allocations are Development Mechanism are ultimately derived from
limited by legal jurisdiction and unlike stock markets are companies responding to the ETS price. This is simply
integral to the market price it is rather difficult to envisage because outside of the EU no entity has an obligation
how exactly this would happen. Moreover New Zealand’s to purchase credits. In short the price being used is a
market will always be minute compared to those in major derivative of the European market.
emitting nations. It is therefore an interesting question as to how the New
LINKS. This raises another issue that has not been Zealand Government will value its obligation if there is a
determined: the connection between the New Zealand domestic price under an emissions trading regime. Will it
emissions trading regime and any other emissions trading use this price or the ETS derivative? It is also an interesting
regime: in particular Europe’s. To connect the two regimes question as to whether there is really any justification for
would be in effect to import Euro denominated prices the Government to target (through withholding permits)
set by European Union allocation systems into the New a domestic market price which is any higher than its own
Zealand economy. In other words the tax on dairy farmer’s $9.60/T CO2e obligation value. Why should the cost to the
methane by-product in New Zealand would be determined private economy be more than that to the government?
by a combination of international exchange rates and SANCTIONS.In fact the only sanction on New Zealand
the dubious politics of EU ETS allocations. In most cases agreed under the Kyoto Protocol is an increase in liability
the firms trading on the ETS are far larger than any which in a subsequent commitment period of 1.3 times the
will trade on the New Zealand system. The only possible outstanding commitment. With no monetary penalty for
advantage is when, or if, New Zealand returns to a carbon non-compliance there is, in fact, no real cost of carbon to
surplus due to forestry, but the danger is that as a nation the New Zealand Government. In reality the New Zealand
we would end up farming for EU climate change credits Government won’t owe any other Kyoto partner a bean if
rather than the real economy. it fails to meet its commitments under the Protocol.
The Government already has an indirect link to the ETS For the moment however, this remains in the realm of
price through the valuation of its Kyoto obligation on the speculation. After nearly a decade of on-again, off-again
Crown Account. The New Zealand treasury commissioned proposals, years of analysis, international conferences (that
Geoff Sinclair (LSE) and the Allen Consulting Group to have added no end to global emissions), careers built and
estimate a financial value of New Zealand’s Kyoto Protocol consultancies launched the Government has now, at the
obligation. Mr Sinclair returned a figure of $9.60 per tonne 11th hour, finally made a decision. It believes what it is
CO2e. Although this is now enshrined in New Zealand’s proposing will have no effect on gross domestic product.
annual financial statement Mr Sinclair points out that there Only time will tell. At least it is a decision and (politics
is no simple market price for carbon as New Zealand is not notwithstanding) that can only assist to provide one sorely
a party to any international carbon trading market. needed component to the entire climate change issue: a
It should be noted Mr Sinclair explicitly rejects the use little policy stability.
14

Electric cars, roads and our infrastructure


- can we build it fast enough ?
If the Ministry of Economic Development is correct in
about 23 years time the majority of cars on our roads will
have a choice of three types of fuel: mineral fuel; biofuels
or electricity. The technology shift is already underway.
Already enthusiasts are re-jigging hybrid vehicles with
larger batteries so that they can be recharged as well
as refuelled. And where customers are leading car This is where it begins.
manufacturers are following with plans to make “plug-in” The Chinese-made Xebra
hybrids a reality by the end of this decade. low cost, all-electric car on
The advantage of a fuel-electric drive-train has been the streets of New York.
known since World War Two. At first technology restricted
diesel-electric drive to submarines and ships but this was
rapidly followed by locomotives. Now trucks and cars
are joining the revolution and already manufacturers are
experimenting with the weight and control advantages
one-per-wheel electric-drive motors could have for
vehicle control, safety and efficiency.
But it goes further than shiny new technology. Given
a litre of petrol is the equivalent of 9 kilowatt hours of
electricity the Ministry of Economic Development has
calculated that at 16.7c/KWh the retail cost of operating
a plug-in vehicle is the equivalent of paying only 40
cents per litre for petrol! This includes an efficiency factor
of 25% which is actually relatively conservative as even
electric retrofitting of existing production cars achieve a
better efficiency factor than this.
CHEAPER. If the cost of buying electricity is low the
cost of producing it is even lower. An extra KWh of drive vehicles goes from around 20% to 60% of the national
electricity is estimated (using East Harbour Management fleet. Can we build power stations quickly enough?
Services figures) to be around 6 cents per kilowatt hour. That depends what sort of power stations we want to build.
Thus the cost of producing electricity for transport (by According to the 2006 Energy Outlook:
the same formula) is 13.5 cents per litre equivalent of
“The available evidence suggests there are three forms of
petrol. Not only is electricity a cheaper alternative option
generation – coal, gas, and wind –that are available in large
for consumers than the projected US$60 a barrel for
quantities and cost about the same. They are so similar in
mineral fuels or indeed for biofuels it is also cheaper for
cost that relatively minor changes in assumptions in our
producers. This has significant implications not only for
model can produce very different generation outcomes.
transport but also for energy. It means that there will be
This closeness in costs suggests that government policy
considerable new demand for electric energy from the
could have a great deal of influence over the decisions
transport sector.
that will be made.”
Current annual residential demand for electricity is 45
petajoules or 12.7 Gigawatt hours per annum. Current BASELOAD. It should be pointed out however that wind
demand for petrol is about 100 petajoules and diesel energy does not provide baseload capacity because it is
is another 100 petajoules. However according to MED not reliable. Essentially wind capacity substitutes for fuel
electric drive vehicles are roughly 33% more energy (including water in storage) when the wind is blowing. But
efficient than petrol vehicles. So even if we assume that it can be assumed that motorists will wish to recharge their
half of all vehicles will continue to burn fuel instead of vehicles whether the wind is blowing or not. Essentially it is a
recharging (either because they are too old or too heavy) preferred option at dispatch time but does not contribute to
we are still potentially looking at about 66 petajoules total capacity. The next cheapest form of renewable energy
of additional electricity demand for transport in 23 is geothermal which does contribute to baseload. According
years time. That’s 18.6 Gigawatt hours in electricity to East Harbour Management Services geothermal energy in
terms, or around 50% of today’s total national electricity the 6-8 cents per KWh is a significant resource. The reason
production. it has not been raised however is due to the problem of
Worse, even using MED’s estimated growth rates that gaining resource consents.
demand rises very rapidly over the ten years between The principle constraint on new electricity supply (as
2020 and 2030. During this period it is predicted electric estimated by East Harbour Management Services) was
15

Wind farms substitute for


stored fuel (water, gas or coal)
used to generate electricity
but do not increase the reliable
capacity of the grid to meet new
demands such as those from
electric vehicles.

consentability under the RMA. To date New Zealand has for energy sector policy which makes renewable energy
shown itself to be a relatively benign regulatory environment projects more buildable. As the Reference Group itself
for coal, gas and wind but a relatively hostile environment for points out (p7: What NPSs may and may not contain),
hydro and geothermal. Indeed although 3,500MW of new an NPS:
generation has been installed since 1991 only 17% of that
• must promote the Act’s purpose (the promotion
has been from renewable sources – all wind.
of sustainable management of natural and physical
As the RMA National Policy Statement reference group put
resources). An NPS cannot be used to promote the
it in “The Merits and Potential Scope of National Guidance
purpose of other legislation or to promote ease of RMA
on the Management of Electricity Generation under the
administration or uniform RMA practices per se;
RMA”
The Reference Group suggests (based on a review of • cannot be used as a de facto method of changing
recent trends and assumptions about the nature of new or redefining either primary or secondary legislation
generation projects) that major growth in new generation (for example they can’t be used to “clarify” particular
might face greater resistance through the RMA processes sections of the Act in such a way that limits other lawful
than past generation projects have faced. That is partly interpretations);
because most post-1991 projects have been gas-fired In other words the objectives of an NPS cannot
thermal stations located on or adjacent to existing overcome the fact that our predominant planning
generating stations. A shift to coal, to greenfield sites and, legislation is innately inimical to development for the
in the case of wind, to more highly valued landscapes, purpose of economic advancement. Only by sliding new
might result in greater environmental risk (actual or developments in on the coat-tails of old ones has the
perceived) and heightened community sensitivity. electricity sector managed to add new capacity at all.
RMA. In short the Resource Management Act, a law widely Now in addition to its need to keep pace with New
praised for enshrining sustainability, is the reason most of Zealand’s electricity demand the industry is coming under
our new electricity generation comes from unsustainable and increasing pressure to provide to do so in a manner
carbon intensive sources such as natural gas and coal. which does not involve environmental impacts that are
The Reference Group ultimately did not agree that a perceived to be negative at both a local and global
National Policy Statement would add much value to the level. For although projects may actually have positive
existing environment. This is, perhaps, more a reflection on environmental consequences what is killing them is the
the efficacy of National Policy Statements than the need continues
16

perception that they don’t, stirred up by those who have measurable national objectives against which roading
objected to new generation and transmission lines but have projects can be evaluated. This framework would enable
failed to stop projects based on existing sites. better alignment in the planning and decision-making
PARALLELS. The growing contradiction between the processes between the agencies and regional and local
objectives of Government energy policy, the legislation government. The strategies would take account of the urban
as it is used, and the objectors will seem all too familiar to planning context and the roading network considerations
those watching progress in the road construction sector. that will influence all major roading projects in the future.
In this sector the costs associated with development The “next steps” review of governance structures in land
are becoming very high indeed compared to those of transport following upon the report has led to yet another
similar projects in other jurisdictions. So much so that the large-scale restructure in the sector - the third in six years.
Government appointed a task force to find out why it is But the big question not included in its terms of reference
that despite spending ever increasing sums of money on of the review team was whether the New Zealand Transport
construction so little is built so slowly by comparison to Strategy, the Resource Management Act and the Land
other nations. Transport Management Act are as much part of the problem
The Ministerial Advisory Group on Roading Costs was as the structures under review.
created because the Government is beginning to recognise CONFUSION. As more than one observor has noted the
that a development process which has failed to deliver on MAG report recommendations differ to the outcomes of the
plans which are now 50 years old (in some cities) is actually “Next Steps” review. The “Next Steps” recommendations
an enormous waste of money. As other nations deliver increase Government’s control over transport purchasing
larger transport projects quicker and for significantly less agencies but do not seem to address core issues over
the unsettling truth is about New Zealand high costs is value for money and the workability of transport and
beginning too obvious to ignore. environmental legislation found by the MAG to have caused
Interestingly the Advisory Group (which reported back in cost escalation.
August 2006) has not called for a National Policy Statement For example as the MAG report noted the Zealand
for transport but a land transport planning document which Transport Strategy does not provide for the kind of trade-
fits between the principles outlined in the New Zealand offs needed when investing in transport. Its aim is to meet
Transport Strategy (NZTS) and the National Land Transport all economic, social and environmental objectives. This
Programme. is scope change at its very core.Until the advent of the
GAP. The Advisory Group believes that there is a strategic NZTS transport’s sole objective was to provide a safe and
gap between the NZTS and existing strategic and planning efficient land transport system. To add on new social and
processes that needs to be filled. The development of environmental objectives and not expect costs to increase
a national strategy for land transport, together with a is somewhat optimistic. Had there been more consultation
more detailed roading strategy, is required to provide on this foundation strategy (as there have been with the
better direction for the agencies, with clearly defined and Energy Strategy) such issues might have been ironed out,
17

Auckland’s congestion is
simply a symptom of a
deeper malaise - a lack of
integrated planning

but in the effort to establish the strategy the NZTS was


never exposed to this sort of public scrutiny. Section five of the RMA should adopt the UN’s
But the real problem goes beyond the shortcomings of the more anthropocentric definition of sustainable
New Zealand Transport Strategy, the consent-ability issue development while section six be amended
in the energy sector or even the Resource Management to allow for a whole-of-government National
Act. The problem is one of a lack of integration. Development Plan as a matter of national
INTEGRATION. The New Zealand Government has not importance.
connected the dots between the implications of migration
policy, efficiency and effectiveness of local government, refer to the UN defined notion of Sustainable Development.
economic policy, land prices, energy policy, climate This would essentially make the Act anthropocentric
change policy, and transport planning. During the 1980s instead of ecocentric and allow for development which was
“reforms” government adopted a philosophical mindset sustainable rather than focus on management of natural
that “development” was a task for the private sector, and physical resources. Moreover there is a need for the
and set about readying all its development agencies for Government to incorporate under section six reference
sale. Ultimately many sales never happened but the legal to an agreed national development plan as a matter of
framework was enacted. This draws no distinction between national importance. This national development plan
government owned state owned enterprises (be they Transit should be a whole of Government plan for the delivery of
New Zealand or TransPower) and a private company. The specific infrastructural outputs to achieve specific goals by a
whole notion that there is a level between macroeconomic specific time. Components of the plan should be required
settings, and microeconomic behaviour, in the form of to meet National Environmental Standards and National
national development agencies was effectively lost. Policy Statements.
Now government is beginning to realise that national The gap between the rate of change in the private sector
competitiveness does rely on competitive infrastructure and transport market and the provision of infrastructure has
that in a nation as small and as isolated as New Zealand been growing steadily. That gap will become increasingly
the government has a crucial role in enhancing national expensive by 2030 when electric cars may well be 30%
productivity. The problem is the philosophy that underpins of the fleet. There is time to do something about it but
the legal framework has gone but the laws remain. every year that we drift on, making do with what we have
There is a serious need for the Resource Management Act will cost us more and more productivity, and ultimately
1991 objectives under sections 5 and 6 to be amended. competitiveness.
Instead of Sustainable Management section five should
18

Protection or opportunity
The Government is developing 50-year transport and energy strategies
to be its lasting legacy. But do they take political cycles into account?
It comes down to this: do New Zealanders want Government
Provence may seem
to provide opportunities or do they want it to provide
idyllic but it is proudly
protection? This is the question that underpins all others
nuclear powered.
as the Government asks “where are we going in 10,25 or
50 years?”
For over the past 12 months Government has been asking
itself about transport policy, energy policy, climate change
policy, and road safety. Each has had exhaustive consultative
documents, chock-full of high-level information making just
reading them a major under-taking. Put together, however,
the issues of energy and transportation largely define
what sort of nation we can potentially become in the 21st
century.
Taking a step back to look at such major issues, rather than
scurrying around the three-year political cycle like mice
on an exercise wheel, is always a useful endeavour and
the Government should be commended for encouraging
all sectors to undertake this kind of review. It does not
happen often enough. But it is one thing to encourage
thinking and yet another to encourage public debate. For
despite the effort put into obtaining a mass of views few
of these exercises have demonstrated a process which anthem) and – from its economic indicators - achieves it as
results in a debate. The suspicion becomes that like so well. And while our retiring middle class may aspire to some
many consultative efforts those consulting already have a kind of Peter Mayle lifestyle “en Provence”, in fact, France is
view of what they are going to do anyway. as much a nation of superhighways, aerospace industry and
CONSENSUS. And while nobody can argue with the need nuclear power as it is one of 4-day working weeks, lavender
for leadership, the more these issues are discussed the fields and curious cheeses. The French, like the Japanese,
clearer it becomes that there is a great need for a broad treasure their traditions and countryside but keep pressing
political consensus on development. Such a consensus the accelerator of progress flat to the floor.
cannot be achieved by a few officials doing sums in In these cases, plus others like Ireland or Finland, there is
Wellington. It requires a better understanding of the deeper a clear distinction in the popular mind between national
economic and political drivers at work in this country. pride in nature, and national pride in development.
For officials should know (by now) that politics trump This is the difference between foreign notions of
analysis every time. By its nature analysis is based on sustainable development – where the emphasis is still
assumptions but if these are out of step with the electorate very much on development – and the RMA’s emphasis on
the analysis will not survive one electoral cycle let alone sustainable management, where the focus nationwide is
a dozen. To project into the future not only do we need on conservation.
to look at the physical realities of changing technologies CONFLICT. As such the RMA merely reflects New Zealand’s
and international economics we also need to look at the inner conflict. We want to take pride in our natural
political tides which underpin the assumptions on which environment. Under the Act five nesting dotterils can hold
our analysis is based. up a multi-million highway while five hundred nesting
Thus, it is not sufficient to blame our failure to build new dotterils being disturbed by dogs and small children next
energy or transport infrastructure over the past decade and to a holiday camping ground are ignored. The Act is about
a half on the vagaries of the Resource Management Act protection not development. But like it or not development,
1991. The Resource Management Act did not come from like growth, is key to maintaining our lifestyle.
nowhere. It may place emphasis on subjective objections It all comes down to our balance of payments, i.e the
but it is not in itself the source of those objections. Those value we buy from the world and the value the world
objections come from a deeper well in the psyches of this buys from us. The more we consume without producing
generation of New Zealanders. commensurate exports the more we ultimately end up
How do we know this? Well, mostly by contrast. Although borrowing from the rest of the world to pay for it all. While
similar Australian culture is far more comfortable with the Government or public international debt is now at a very
notion of progress (its even written into their national low level compared to GDP, our private international debt
19

The 2.5km long Millau


viaduct over the river Tarn.
Built for NZ$631 million and a
lasting source of French national pride

is at shockingly high levels. As of December 2006 New the most destructive period of warfare in human history.
Zealanders net international liabilities were $143 billion And our environment, while unsullied by Giardia or Didymo,
against a GDP of $125 billion. Worse the high levels of was still being cleared of bush and swamp and being
international private debt have mostly been to borrow for regularly doused in huge quantities of organochlorides.
the privilege of owning property ($142 billion) that we used Even after Rachel Carson’s “Silent Spring” there remains
to own previously (without as much foreign borrowing), a national conspiracy not to mention anything that might
or to buy consumer goods from overseas ($4 billion sully our national image.
outstanding on credit cards as at December 2006) which MYTH. Much of the national self-image founded at
are depreciating through technological acceleration at an this time is pure myth. In fact the 1950s and 60s were a
ever increasing rate. period of rapid expansion for New Zealand, both in terms
BUDGET. If this continues it cannot end well. Ultimately it of infrastructure and industry. And it was this period of
can only lead to greater foreign ownership of our country expansion and development which funded the childhoods
and increasing impoverishment of our people. The of the baby-boomer generation as they grew up. However
Government’s budget 2007 is, aimed at addressing these like all self-obsessed teenage generations the boomers were
issues. First it is attempting to improve New Zealanders oblivious to this and found fault with their “development-
savings rate (reducing the need for offshore borrowing) crazed” forebears eventually galvanising the nation with the
through the Kiwisaver scheme, and it is investing in “Save Manapouri Campaign”. This was the most popular
improving New Zealand’s productivity by investing in much expression of conservation over development during the
needed infrastructure. If there is any quibble with such 1960s – incidentally delivering Labour the 1972 election
measures it is only that they are long overdue. after 12 years of Holyoake’s National government.
But what the Budget can’t do is get through to New Thirty-five years later, older and wiser, and the baby-boomer
Zealanders that the fundamental problem at the heart of generation has begun to recognise the importance of
our culture is that we think we can get rich without building generating wealth. But to maintain its integrity with its
anything. This is based on reminiscences of the 1960s political origins this has become “economic transformation”.
when New Zealand was among the world’s most wealthy This vague term effectively means generating more value
nations on a per capita income basis and its environment while reducing our impact on the environment. It’s about
was apparently unsullied. We were rich and “clean and all the clichés of “working smarter not harder”, being
green” without even trying. “sustainable” and all those good things which nobody can
But take away the rose-tinted spectacles and it soon argue with, but which are embraced more enthusiastically
becomes apparent New Zealand was only relatively wealthy by officials in Government than they are by industry.
because the rest of the world was only just recovering from continues
20

Shanghai, home of one fifth of the world’s


construction cranes. The mega-economies of China
and India will re-balance economic power away
from Europe and North America over the 21st
century. As an economic culture we have not fully
come to terms with this new reality.

This notion of economic transformation is what is Auckland has experienced on-going transport and power
underpinning the National Energy Strategy and the failures. Would we have done better if a 20-year energy
transport strategy revision. And while it is good to look strategy or a 40-year transport policy had been written in
ahead it is difficult to have too much faith because to date, 1990? It’s impossible to say.
our officials haven’t done the economic “vision thing” FARMING. Where we have been deliberately successful is
particularly well. Indeed New Zealand’s development seems in expanding our agricultural marketing into Asia. Demand
to have been driven forward while looking in the rear view for food, and in particular quality food, has kept our
mirror as other nations zoomed past. agricultural prices relatively high. Nevertheless this is a far
STRATEGY. During the 1980s Japan demonstrated that cry from the low-carbon high-knowledge economy sought
a nation with a relatively coordinated, research-driven, in “economic transformation”. Agriculture is inherently
export-oriented, economic policy and a huge pool of energy and transport intensive whether the goods being
domestic savings could readily compete with open, exported are low or high margin. And while the British may
consumer-oriented economies such as those in the United rail about “food miles”, their once crucial market is being
States and Europe. New Zealand spent the 1980’s and eclipsed by the stampede to provide goods and services
early 1990’s engrossed in extracting itself from the debt to Asia, and in particular, China.
and energy intensive, political-economy of “Muldoonery” For today the Chinese “Dragon” economy (which has been
(as The Economist termed it) through the somewhat naïve bootstrapping itself since the mid-1970s at the astonishing
Rogernomics-era of state amateur auto-neurosurgery and rate of over 8% per annum) has become dominant
corporate kleptocracy when merchant bankers bought their everywhere and there is now every indication that China’s
own fiefdoms from the state. economic power will eclipse that of the United States by
As Japan’s economy faltered in the 1990s (essentially the middle of this century. India’s growth too, though not as
drowning in money), smaller nations such as South Korea, spectacular indicates that this mega-economy too is going
Singapore, Taiwan, Ireland, Finland and to a lesser extent to catch up with the first world sometime this century.
Malaysia, Thailand, Denmark and Israel, followed the For the average New Zealander the emergence of these
Japanese formula and found (after tweaks to attract foreign mega-economies has simply meant huge reductions in
multinational direct investment) it worked very well for the price of clothing and consumer durables. Only now
them too. While these nations developed industries New are we beginning to see the slow collapse of domestic
Zealand’s high growth in the late 1990s came from importing manufacturing as the Asian ‘black hole” sucks in enterprises
800,000 new citizens, mostly from Hong Kong and Asia. Of which until recently could afford to employ New Zealanders.
course we weren’t ready for was their demand for roads Eventually this too will include information based industries
to drive on or energy for their homes and businesses, so as Chinese and Indian engineers and artists bring their
21

New Zealand has mineral wealth


on a very significant scale but
we would rather import the
results of other’s mining than
dig up our landscape.

formidable talents to bear in cyberspace. ceramics. It would be possible to build roads and ports
This brings us back to the question of New Zealand’s best to extract them. With the right legislative and investment
long-term strategy and what that means for investments in climate, the minerals sector had the potential to grow from
energy and transport today. For either it will be transport 12,000 to 20,000 regional jobs and from $1 billion to $2
and energy intensive or it won’t be. And the questions we billion in annual turnover GNS estimated in 2000.
have to ask ourselves are what futures are we excluding THAT SORT OF NATION. The problem: most of these
today because we have developed a kind of national minerals are in our National Parks and we don’t want to
consensus against them? dig them up. Why not? It doesn’t stop the Australians. It
NUKES. Whaling and nuclear energy are easy examples is because as a nation we have developed a view about
of this cultural decision-making. New Zealanders have very mining, particularly in National Parks, which means that we
little general interest in resuming whaling or exploring just don’t do it. We aren’t “that sort of nation”.
nuclear energy options. We have reached a reasonably What about genetic engineering? The Royal Commission
strong nation-wide consensus that we just aren’t “that sort on Genetic Engineering did a sterling job in examining
of nation”. Of course, these are relatively trivial examples the potential risks, rewards and cultural issues involved in
economically speaking. Whale meat is hardly a burgeoning employing the technology. Its findings exploded myths and
market (even in Japan it reminds people of wartime provided valuable insights into the future of agriculture,
rationing) and nuclear power is uncompetitive against our forestry and medicine. And yet despite the millions it
other energy options anyway. But there are less obvious spent in patient analysis its views were totally eclipsed
examples of futures foregone because “we aren’t that sort by a tiny minority spouting the same Luddite phrases the
of nation”. Commission had dismissed. The hysteria over “corngate”
Minerals are a perfect example of this. Where Australia only added to the impression that GE is a political non-
is mining its mineral wealth as fast as Chinese buyers starter. Once again political passion trounced informed
can write cheques New Zealand’s minerals remain largely debate.
buried under our “iconic” landscapes. GNS Science has Currently there is limited political or economic interest in
conservatively estimated that New Zealand has at least minerals or GE. But consider coal. New Zealand has about
NZ$86 billion worth of metallic mineral resources in known 700 years worth of coal, mostly in Southland. Coal is one
and undiscovered deposits. Moreover, some of our non- of the cheapest potential sources of energy there is in New
metallic minerals are valuable, niche materials such as Zealand for both electricity, and from about 2030, transport
zeolite, perlite and diatomite. They can earn valuable and has to be considered a serious energy option. It is also
export revenue and some can be used as the base for very dirty. One of the big questions in the National Energy
developing innovative materials such as sophisticated continues
22

The disconnect between liberal indulgence of protest and demand


for a better standard of living is based on a deep sense of civic alienation.
Strategy is, “is New Zealand a nation that ‘does coal’”? Or WHO LEADS? Because if we aren’t going to “do coal” what
do we, like the billions of dollars worth of minerals, buried are we going to do? Natural gas? Arguably less sustainable
under our national parks, just leave it in the ground? Are than coal. Hydro? Not consentable. Geothermal? Not
we “that kind of nation”? consentable either. Bioenergy? Currently uneconomic
The National Energy Strategy process certainly asked the except as a by-product. Wind doesn’t count because it isn’t
question. But in the context of the political environment reliable. Tidal? Still experimental. Nevertheless demand is
it is hard to interpret it as anything other than rhetorical. growing, and from 2020 may grow very quickly indeed. We
For it seems clear that the current “consensus” is that New seriously need a consensus on what kind of environment we
Zealand is not a nation that “does coal”. want and how much energy we need because we cannot
WHO SAYS? But let’s look more closely at where this rely on Greenpeace to manage our energy needs over the
“consensus” comes from. In almost every case it starts next few decades for us.
with a small and determined group with strong views. This Then there is transport. Even as we move to spend huge
group of activists carries out newsworthy actions in order catch-up sums on transport costs escalate and Green Party
to draw attention to its concerns and generally simplifies pressure increases for more public transport systems and
complex issues down to easily remembered slogans. The less roads.
activists begin a symbiotic relationship with the media The public has bought the need for better public transport
who are naturally drawn to the drama of the conflict. but remains sceptical about the “less roads” part of the
Thus journalists end up reporting the protests of activists equation. It is easy to see why people like the idea of public
and then balancing these against the pronouncements transport. Most New Zealanders travel. When they do, they
of “the establishment”. The public is then invited to see public transport systems that meet their needs and
adopt a middle position between the activists and the remove the stress of driving in a foreign city. Because fares
establishment. Through repetition this process hauls the rarely meet the full cost of P.T systems tourists find them
rest of the community along to the activists point of view. inexpensive and convenient and think how nice it would
Over time it tends to mean that the so-called consensus be to have one back home.
view in New Zealand is only slightly more conservative than The difference is between being a tourist and living abroad.
that of activist groups. In most places long term residents want a car. Back in New
Is this the kind of process that will deliver an energy and Zealand 90% of the population don’t use public transport,
transport strategy which will allow New Zealand to maintain nor do they intend to. Even in Wellington with the highest
a sustainable economic position as the mega-economies PT share in the country the commuter share is only 23%
of China and India come to dominance? Is it the kind of - leaving 77% to other modes. And commuting is declining
process that will deliver a country with improving terms in its share of total trips. Do we want to spend 50% of our
of trade? transport funds on 10% of the trips? This is where the public
23

New Zealanders notions of


development are based on
dog-in-the manger politics

(sometimes shamefacedly) votes with their wallets for the stress government-for-protection and government-for-
car, but votes in opinion polls for public transport and then opportunity. Under a protection oriented government
sit in their cars cursing the congestion! regulation increases and the wings of the powerful are
CONFIDENCE. The problem with all of these issues of clipped. Under an opportunity oriented government
consensus is a general fear of foreign opinion. We fear regulation is relaxed and to date, a favoured few make
the British may think less of us for not being committed fortunes. Neither is associated with any one political party.
to climate change and boycott our cheese. We fear the The 1984 Labour government saw itself as a government-
Germans may not maintain their myth of New Zealand as of-opportunity while the 1978 Muldoon government was
a South Pacific paradise and stop visiting. The only people a government-of-protection.
we don’t mind annoying are the Americans and Australians Politically protection is welcomed at first, but as its coils
– even as we emigrate to their nations in ever increasing strangle opportunity it quickly wears out its welcome – just
numbers to seek fame and fortune! Despite this back home as it did in 1984. Long-term New Zealanders need a greater
we nervously ask tourists their opinion of our country and sense of opportunity and less need for protection. This is
flinch at every criticism. By contrast the Australians and the essential because no amount of protective legislation will
French can’t imagine why tourists wouldn’t come. maintain our balance of payments in a world dominated by
Thus we have a cultural conundrum. New Zealanders seek the mega-economies of China and India. And if we don’t
reassurance from the good opinion of other nationals. become a nation of entrepreneurs and opportunists we
The media rely on activists for material. Business and will end up a nation of wreckers, living beyond our means,
Government need the approval of the populace to get and forlornly trying to lure investors on to the hidden shoals
consents. The populace is concerned about its own of our planning laws.
welfare but is happy to waste the money of business and CYCLICAL. There are already signs today that the tide of
Government. Politicians need the populace and the media political mood is turning. Just as the public appetite for
to be elected. All of this puts activists in the box seat to set opportunity replaced protection in 1984, and protection
the national consensus and waste the money of business replaced opportunity in 1996, so now the era of protection-
and government – hence “scope change” in transport and led government is coming to the end of its 12-year
project frustration in energy. electoral cycle. This does not have to mean a change of
OPPORTUNITY. The fundamental failure of communication ruling coalition as Jim Bolger demonstrated in 1996. It
is that New Zealanders appear to be alienated from notions does however mean that the electorate is beginning to
of development and opportunity. They generally see feel more frustrated than protected by protection-oriented
development as something that enriches a few by taking legislation and is seeking to remove the self-restraints to
away those natural or cultural benefits that they previously opportunity.
got for nothing. This leads to “dog-in-the-mangerism”. The It is probable that this transition will create a new form of
tendency to use planning law to extract maximum benefit consensus although it is difficult to know what form it will
from those who would develop. take. The anti-nuclear consensus has survived numerous
Law changes that simply make development easier will not changes in government and the activist-media symbiosis
alter this fundamental alienation. What is needed is not is unlikely to dry up quickly. Environmental protection is no
only better law but a greater sense of national opportunity. five-minute wonder.
A sense that opportunity is not restricted to newcomers However whoever wins the 2008 election will need to be
or robber barons but one that is in our air, as it is in the very mindful that the public seeks change and it will need
United States. to be more than cosmetic. It is unlikely that a series of
And ultimately this comes down to our philosophy of strategies and plans that don’t recognise this transition will
government. Since its establishment government in survive much past 2008, let alone until 2050.
New Zealand has swung between philosophies that
24

From MAG Report to Next Steps


Is taxpayer value-for-money still driving the process? Give
MAG Report Findings (August 2006) Next Steps Findings (April 2007)
The roading sector has been subject to much change This Report concludes that a lack of sector collaboration
in recent years. The introduction of the New Zealand and integration underpins many of the issues present
Transport Strategy (NZTS) and the Land Transport in the sector. The lack of role clarity, sector leadership,
Management Act 2003 (LTMA) in particular have and common expectations about how the sector should
established far wider transport objectives. engage has helped perpetuate a fragmented sector
culture.
Several of the case studies commissioned by the
Advisory Group indicate that changes in project scope More explicit guidance on the Government’s funding
through the investigation, design, and, to a lesser priorities would be provided for the land transport sector
extent, construction phases have been the major through two published documents: “Implementation of
contributor to increased cost forecasts. the New Zealand Transport Strategy” - currently under
development by the Ministry and due in March 2008;
The Group noted that time pressures appeared to be and a Government Policy Statement with a six year
a major factor in the ready acceptance of increases outlook and a three-yearly update process;
in project scope; in order to overcome potential
opposition to a project. It would have expected a more All land transport plans would be produced every three
robust process of scope evaluation, similar to that years rather than annually;
demonstrated for some other smaller projects.
Regional councils, probably through their Regional Land
While commending the objectives of the NZTS and the Transport Committees, would become responsible for
LTMA, the Advisory Group considers that to achieve prioritisation of all land transport activities, including
value for money, there needs to be a strengthening State highways, within their Regional Land Transport
of the focus on cost efficiency in the evaluation of Programmes; separate consideration could be needed
projects. for Auckland; and

The Advisory Group believes that there is a strategic gap All consultation on activities that would be funded
between the NZTS and existing strategic and planning through the National Land Transport Programme would
processes that needs to be filled. The development of take place at regional level.
a national strategy for land transport, together with a
more detailed roading strategy, is required to provide All revenue raised from Fuel Excise Duties would be
better direction for the agencies, with clearly defined directed into the National Land Transport Fund - this
and measurable national objectives against which would usefully demonstrate to road users that road
roading projects can be evaluated. charges are being used for, or match the level of
transport investments.
The Advisory Group also recommends that value-for-
money indicators should be incorporated into the The Review … on balance .. recommends the more
performance monitoring system. Land Transport NZ significant structural change to disestablish Land
should take an enhanced role in evaluating major Transport NZ and Transit NZ as separate agencies and
projects and monitoring scope and cost. Collaborative merge their new functions into a new statutory Crown
leadership in an environment of partnership between entity (which would retain the statutorily independent
the Ministry of Transport (the Ministry) and the transport functions currently held by Land Transport NZ).
entities is also essential.
A Few Questions
Ten-year forecast maintenance expenditure levels have Will this structure make the necessary changes to stop the
been increasing significantly faster than inflation since scope-creep issues raised by the MAG report?
2003/04 for both local roads and state highways. The
How will local communities influence road construction in
reasons for increases in forecast expenditure primarily
their areas between 3-year cycles? Via their MP?
relate to higher forecasts of heavy commercial vehicle
growth. How will national organisations be consulted on national
safety issues such as state highway edgelining?
How will Regional Councils be accountable for local
roading issues?

If you are interested in responding to the Advocate, or joining our circulation list
please email AA Research Editor, Peter King (pking@aa.co.nz)

Potrebbero piacerti anche