Sei sulla pagina 1di 42

Contracts – Scott: Fall 2010

Table of Contents
Introduction........................................................................................................................................................ 4
Enforcing Promises........................................................................................................................................... 7
Consideration.............................................................................................................................................................. 7
Bargain vs. Gift............................................................................................................................................................................ 7
Adequacy........................................................................................................................................................................................ 8
Promisory Estoppel.................................................................................................................................................... 9
Intrafamiliar Context.................................................................................................................................................................. 9
Employment Context.................................................................................................................................................................. 9
Material Benefit Rule.............................................................................................................................................. 10
Bargain Context.............................................................................................................................................. 11
Offer and Acceptance.............................................................................................................................................. 11
Offer.............................................................................................................................................................................................. 11
Acceptance................................................................................................................................................................................. 12
Revocation................................................................................................................................................................................... 14
Offer and Counteroffer........................................................................................................................................... 15
Common Law View................................................................................................................................................................. 15
UCC §2-207................................................................................................................................................................................ 15
Relational Contracts...................................................................................................................................... 18
Uncertainty................................................................................................................................................................ 18
Preliminary Negotiations........................................................................................................................................................ 19
Binding Preliminary Agreements......................................................................................................................................... 20
Output/Requirements/Exclusive Dealings........................................................................................................... 20
Output/Requirement................................................................................................................................................................. 21
Exclusive Dealings Contracts.............................................................................................................................................. 22
Reducing Conflicts of Interest............................................................................................................................................... 23
Modification of Existing Agreements................................................................................................................... 25
Regulating the Bargaining Process............................................................................................................. 26
Duress......................................................................................................................................................................... 26
Fraud.......................................................................................................................................................................... 27
Willfull + Negligent................................................................................................................................................................. 28
Disclosure + Concealment...................................................................................................................................................... 28
Unconscionability.................................................................................................................................................. 29
Statute of Frauds...................................................................................................................................................... 30
Identifying + Interpreting Terms................................................................................................................ 32
Identifying Terms..................................................................................................................................................... 32
Common Law: Hard Parol Evidence Rule........................................................................................................................ 32
UCC: Soft Parol Evidence Rule........................................................................................................................................... 32
Mistake + Excuse............................................................................................................................................ 33
Mistake....................................................................................................................................................................... 34
Modern Excuse of Impracticability...................................................................................................................... 35
Remedies........................................................................................................................................................... 37

1
Basic Remedies......................................................................................................................................................... 37
Compensation............................................................................................................................................................................. 38
Expectation Damages: Cost to Complete vs. Diminution of Value...........................................................................39
Specific Performance............................................................................................................................................................... 40
Limitations on Compensation................................................................................................................................ 40
Certainty....................................................................................................................................................................................... 41
Duty to Mitigate........................................................................................................................................................................ 41

2
ISSUE SPOTTTING:
UCC or Common Law/Restatements?

Is there an enforceable contract?


Consideration (§71)
Promissory Estoppel (§90)
Material Benefit (§86)
Implied in Fact
Quasi-Contract
Statute of Frauds
Indefiniteness
§2-207
Offer
Acceptance

What are the terms?


Parole Evidence
Leval Test
§2-207
Modification

Was there a breach?


Which Right or Duty?

Can it be voided?
Duress
Fraud: Willful/Negligent
Fraud: Concealment/Non-Disclosure
Unconscionability
Impractability
Frustration
Mutual Mistake
Unilateral Mistake
Risk allocation

What are the Damages?


Specific Performance
Thick Market v. Thin Market
Foreseeability
Certainty
Duty to Mitigate
Expectation
Reliance
Restitution

3
Cost to Complete vs. Diminution of Value

Introduction
R2d §1: Contract Defined: A contract is a promise or a set of promises for the breach of which the
law gives a remedy, or the performance of which the law in some way recognizes as a duty

R2d§ 2: Promise; Promisor; Promisee; Beneficiary


(1) A promise is a manifestation of intention to act or refrain from acting in a specified way, so made as
to justify a promisee in understanding that a commitment has been made.
(2) The person manifesting the intention is the promisor.
(3) The person to whom the manifestation is addressed is the promisee.
(4) Where performance will benefit a person other than the promisee, that person is a beneficiary.

R2d§ 4: How a Promise May Be Made : A promise may be stated in words either oral or written, or
may be inferred wholly or partly from conduct.

3 types of Contracts
1. Express
2. Implied-in-fact (§4)
3. Quasi (Implied-in-law)

Quasi-Contract (Implied-in-Law): benefit is conferred where there is no promise


1. Benefit conferred
2. Appreciated (comprehended not enjoyed)
3. Unjust enrichment would result – inequitable to not contract
Typically no recovery unless(either):
1. “Last clear chance” – watched benefit conferred and didn’t stop it (ex-post)
2. Deception/trickery/inducement - (ex-ante)

Is there a promise? Thumb on the scales against using coercive power of the state
 Autonomy: respect for individual rights, must have clear justification
 Instrumentalist: too much enforcement, activity level effect + costly precautions

Why Enforce at All?


 Social benefit of ability to make plans (better choices from bringing future to present)
 While it reduces total number of promises, increases quality of promises
 Promotes freedom to bind yourself and make plans

Instant Retraction: Not allowed because we want to enhance the perceived credibility of promises

Objective Theory: Judge intent (existence of promise) by “reasonable person” standard; Gallup pole
 Auto: Provides manifestation of assent available to all, preserves individual boundaries
 Inst: Easier/cheaper for idiosyncratic to act normal than for normal to worry about idiosyncrasy

4
Bailey v. West RI (1969)
 Facts: Δ purchased horse from seller. When delivered, it was lame. Δ instructed trainer to send
horse back to trainer, who refused delivery. Trainer then delivered horse to Π, though not at the
direction of Δ. Π sends bill to Δ, who refuses to pay.
 Holding: (1) Π didn’t introduce any evidence for the “quasi-contract” argument upon which the
trial judge ruled (2) Neither a contract, or intent to enter into implied contract, ever existed between
Δ and Π, and (3) Π acted as volunteer, so he can’t recover on Quasi Contractual basis.

Lucy v. Zehmer SCOA of VA (1954)


 Facts: Δ (and his wife) agrees to sell farm to Π while both were drinking. Δ alleges the contract was
created as part of a drunken joke upon Π that can not be taken seriously as a legal transaction.
 Holding: Genuine intent is not necessary for parties to signal willingness to enter into contract.
Rather, a contract may be initiated through words or actions from which reasonable person would
infer intent to enter a contract. Objective theory.
 NOTE: Δ should have argued that it was unreasonable for Π to not know Δ was joking given
context (in a bar, written on informal )

Leonard v. Pepsico USDC, S. Dis. (1997)


 Facts: Π attempts to redeem commercial “offer” of a Harrier Jet in exchange for Pepsi points. Δ
refused to provide the jet, saying that the commercial and the “offer” of jet were obviously done in
jest.
 Holding: The court held that the commercial and offer were clearly being done in jest, and that a
reasonable person would have the offer was not legitimate. Viewed in context, π’s position was
absurd.

R2d §18: Manifestation of mutual assent to an exchange requires that each party either make a
promise or begin or render a performance.

R2d §20: Effect of Misunderstanding


(1) There is no manifestation of mutual assent to an exchange if the parties attach materially different
meanings to their manifestations and
(a) neither party knows or has reason to know the meaning attached by the other; or
(b) each party knows or each party has reason to know the meaning attached by the other.
(2) The manifestations of the parties are operative in accordance with the meaning attached to them by
one of the parties if:
(a) that party does not know of any different meaning attached by the other, and the other knows the
meaning attached by the first party; or
(b) that party has no reason to know of any different meaning attached by the other, and the other has
reason to know the meaning attached by the first party.

Default Rules: facilitative, majoritarian rules reduce costs of transaction and promotes contracting.
 Created by courts, best guess at what majority would want ex-ante
 Must be explicitly opted out of, with substitutes provider to not apply

5
 Fill gaps (1) allocate risk of performance, (2) provide measure of performance and (3)
specify consequences of non-performance
UCC

GET IN:
§2-102: Scope of transaction covered by UCC, only “goods”
§2-105: Definitions of “Goods”- movable at the time of identification to the contract.

GET OUT:
§1-103: Door out: Where the UCC is silent, common law applies

SUPPLEMENT TERMS:
§2-208: Course of Performance within contract relevant to determine meaning of agreement
§1-205(1): Course of Dealing – previous dealings between the parties can be used to interpret terms
§1-205(2): Usage of Trade – general industry practice can be used

§2-103: Definitions of Terms (e.g. Good Faith)


§2-104: Definition of Merchant

6
Enforcing Promises
Consideration (R2d §71): Four-lane highway
Promissory Estoppel (R2d §90): Gravel road
Material Benefit Rule (R2d §86): Deer trail

Consideration

Consideration (R2 §71):


1. Performance or return promise must be bargained for
2. Bargain means promise/performance given in exchange of promise (reciprocal inducement)
3. Promises to make gifts are not enforceable
R2d §73: Performance of legal duty doesn’t constitute consideration
R2d §74: Settlement of legal claims – (1) invalid claim is consideration if claimant believes claim to be
valid. (2) Is consideration if bargained for, regardless of belief of claimant or intentions to raise claim.
R2d §79: Adequacy of Consideration is immaterial as long as the performance/return promise met
(peppercorn is fine if it’s bargained for)
R2d §81: Private motives of the promisor are irrelevant
Bargain vs. Gift

Why not enforce all serious promises?


 Non-gratuitous: Increase in Quality/Reliability > Decrease in quantity; enforcement is good
o Feedback loop of bargaining mitigates quantity decrease (offer more $)
 Gratuitous: Inherently high quality/reliability (often family members etc.); enforcement doesn’t
increase quality as much and decreases quantity
o Non-reciprocal so no feedback loop to limit quantity decrease
 Autonomy: No intent to be bound in gratuitous promise
 Instrumentalist: reduces number of promising without adding to quality/reliability

Enforcement of Nominal consideration:


 Pro: Autonomy - intention to make enforceable gift
 Con: might not be “deliberate” enough, fear of false claims, providence of legislature

Williston’s Tramp - actions incidental to the receipt of a gratuity or gratuitous promise do not
constitute consideration (not bargained for).

Hamer v. Sidway NY (1891)


 Facts: Executor of Π’s uncle’s estate refuses to honor uncle’s promise to pay Π $5,000 if Π
restrained from vices until his 21st birthday. Π acted accordingly, and received a further promise
from uncle that debt would be honored and paid once Π had matured. Δ alleges promises had no
consideration and are thus unenforceable.
 Holding: Π forfeited a legal right in consideration for his uncle’s promise. Therefore, the promise is
enforceable.

7
 Black Letter Law: Consideration doesn’t depend on conferring of benefit upon the parties to a
promise, but rather the forfeiture of a legal right as prescribed by a promise.

Kirksey v. Kirksey AL (1845)


 Facts: Π, the widow of husband’s Δ-brother, moved to land owned by Δ after receiving invitation to
do so.
 Holding: The invitation was a promise to give a gift and had no consideration by Π. Relocation was
incidental to receiving gift. Therefore, she may not recover.
 Note: background facts (∆ may have attempted to benefit from π’s presence); better argued under
promissory estoppel

In re Green USDC, SDNY (1930


 Facts: Mistress seeks to enforce sealed contract containing promises to make payments on housing.
Consideration cited by claimant includes payment of $1, waiver of claims, and “other goods and
consideration”.
 Holding: The payments were made for past consideration, which is not valid. The other cited
“considerations” in the contract were held to be invalid, and were made merely in attempt to frame
a promise to give a gift as an enforceable contract; Nominality

St. Peter v. Pioneer Theatre 1940 SC of IA


 Facts: Δ offered “bank night’, for which Π stood outside the theatre. When Π’s name was called, Π
followed rules but was denied the prize. Π claimed there was lack of consideration to promise,
incidental to receipt of gratuity.
 Holding: Δ entered into a unilateral contract with Π, whereby the performance of a promise is made
contingent on the other party doing some act. The act indicates acceptance of offer, and functions as
consideration. Π performed necessary acts, so the promise must be enforced. Non-pecuniary
consideration made it legal.
Adequacy

R2 §79: It is up to parties to determine value of consideration


 Peppercorn Theory
 Love and Affection can be valid consideration (Wolford)

Batsakis v. Demotsis C. of Civ. App. TX (1949)


 Facts: During WWII in Greece, Δ borrowed $25 from Π in exchange for a note promising $2000
after the war.
 Holding: The loan by Π was valid consideration for the promise to pay $2,000, regardless of the
lopsidedness of the arrangement. Both parties got what they bargained for. No fraud or duress.
 Note: Contextual influence; wartime contract impacts parties intentions

Wolford v. Powers IN (1882)


 Facts: Charles Lehman (CL) promised $10,000 to Π if he named his son CL. Π did as asked, and
brought suit when the administrator of CL’s estate refused to pay.
 HOLDINg: The name of the child was valid consideration for the promise to pay $10,000.

8
 Law: If an act is done in return for a promise, that act—no matter how minor—will function as
consideration.

Promisory Estoppel

R2d §90: Detrimental Reliance + Calculated Inducement


1) A promise made that should reasonably be expected to induce reliance (action or forbearance)
2) Specifically induced reliance occurs – must be the reliance reasonably expected by the promisor
3) There must be injustice

While no bargain exists (there’s no consideration!), enforcement only typical in general bargain context

All promises will induce a form of reliance, must be the expected reliance (dangling a promise in front
of someone)

Charitable Promises: can be enforced under §90(2), but rarely litigated or adopted. Fear of chilling
effect. Donees rarely sue (bad PR). Often, a bargain context exists (what will named after you etc.)
Intrafamiliar Context

Haase v. Cardoza DCOA, 3rd D. CA (1958)


 Facts: Π alleges that Δ stated in a conversation that her dead husband had desired that she leave
$10k to Π. Δ then asked if Π would accept $50/month, and then ceases payments when Π requested
formalize promise in writing and that the balance on the $10k be paid.
 Holding: No consideration by Π. Reliance itself insufficient, must be specific, “dangling”;
insufficient grounds for promissory estoppel.

Ricketts v. Scothorn NE (1898) p. 164


 Facts: Π-Scothorn received note from grandfather stating that she need not work and promised her
$2,000. Π then quit her job. Lack of funds prevented the payment of the gift, which the grandfather
maintained that he would pay as soon as he sold off property. Upon his death, Δ-administrator
refused payment to Π.
 Holding: equitable estoppel because detrimental reliance + inducement. Promisor died without
repudiating, form of promise (promissory note) shows deliberation

Allegheny College (p.180)


 Facts: Promise to donate after death and promise to name scholarship; estate refused to donate
 Holding: Cardozo found consideration from return promise by school. Recognized §90 as
alternative, but unnecessary when consideration is found. Better explained under §90
Employment Context

Feinberg v. Pfeiffer Co COA of MO (1959) p. 174


 Facts: Board of directors of Δ-Company decided to give monthly pension to Π in gratitude for years
of employment. A change in management led to decision to revoke pension. Π brought suit,
claiming reliance.

9
 Holding: The contract is enforceable under promissory estoppel since the pension promise induced
reliance to retire and not compete.

Hayes v. Plantations Steel Co. St. Louis COA, MO (1959) p. 174


 Facts: Π announced retirement, and then inquired about a pension. Δ promised Π “would be taken
care of.” Π received pension for several years, and then brought suit when pension ceased.
 Holding: Pension promise unenforceable since there was neither (1) consideration(from few weeks
worked), or (2) evidence that the promise shaped Π’s thinking/induced change in position.

Case Haase Ricketts Feinberg Hayes


Context Gift Gift Gift Gift
Explicit No No No No
Bargain
Reliance Yes Yes Yes Yes
Calculated No Yes Yes No
Inducement
Form Oral Written Written Oral
Revocation Yes No Yes Yes
Contract No Yes Yes No

Material Benefit Rule


R2d § 86: Promise for Benefit Received
 Material, non-donative benefit conferred
 Subsequent promise to reimburse – “completes” the incomplete bargain, fixes value of benefit
to initial recipient.

General form of exceptions to “Past Consideration = No Consideration”


 Enforceable promise; bar to recovery; subsequent promise to honor; enforceable
 Eg. R2d §82 – statute of limitations, §83 – Bankrupcy, §85 – Infancy

Why only non-donative benefits? Likely says something about the ‘donativity’ of the subsequent
promise; performed with expected compensation (implicit bargain), not gratuitous (mere volunteer)

Webb v. McGowin: (Worker + falling block); §86 applies, non-donative, worker expected
compensation, not revoked during promisor’s lifetime
Mills v. Wyman: (Son ill at sea; cared for until death; father promises to pay for expenses); “Good
Samaritan”, donative action.
Booth v. Fitzpatrick: (escaped bull); business context; non-donative, expected compensation and kept
records
Desny v. Wilder: (screenwriter) Non-donative, done in bargaining/business context; unequal bargaining
power

10
Bargain Context
Offer and Acceptance
Offer

R2d § 17: Requirement of a Bargain: K = bargain w/ manifestation of mutual assent (MoMA) +


consideration. Exceptions in §82-94.

§ 22: Mode of Assent: Offer and Acceptance: MoMA typically = offer + acceptance
MoMA may be made with offer + acceptance unidentified and moment of formation undetermined.

§ 24: Offer Defined


An offer is the manifestation of willingness to enter into a bargain, so made as to justify another person
in understanding that his assent to that bargain is invited and will conclude it.

§ 26: Preliminary Negotiations


A manifestation of willingness to enter into a bargain is not an offer if the person to whom it is
addressed knows or has reason to know that the person making it does not intend to conclude a bargain
until he has made a further manifestation of assent.

Mailbox Rule (R2d §63(a) and (b) + UCC §2-206)


 Acceptance is binding by mail once it is sent out (mailbox rule)
 If it’s a “firm offer” or an “option contract,” acceptance only triggered upon receipt by offeror (R2d
§63(b)).
 Revocation of offer is binding only upon receipt by the offeree (R2d §40)

Offer or Preliminary Negotiations? Offer only exists if it is complete and only acceptance is left
 CL does not like indefiniteness and errs towards preliminary negotiations if there are missing
material terms
o Overenforcement affects activity level and offerors will take extra costly precautions
o Cheap talk is valuable (brings parties together) and don’t want to discourage it
 UCC §2-204(3): UCC says indefinite terms are okay if parties intended to contract because of
default rules in the UCC
 Price quote + advertisements typ. not offers: seller would have no control of quality of buyer or
quantity – unless clear, definite, explicit + leaves nothing open

Dyno Construction Company v. McWane Inc 6th Cir. (1999)


 Facts: Π and Δ enter into negotiations for piping. Δ sends Π a fax stating price plan. Π agrees, and
Δ sends package to Π containing credit terms, order form and waiver information. Π loses
packages; Δ faxes order form, but forgets to send waiver. Piping goes bad, prompting suit.
 Holding: The contract was valid on date fax formed was signed. The earlier fax was not an offer
that Π was to accept since 1) terms were indefinite; and 2) no evidence Δ was done negotiating or
intending to be legal bound. Purchase orders = invitation to a negotiation, ≠ offer or promise.

11
Lefkowitz v. Great American Minneapolis Surplus Store MN (1957)
 Facts: Δ advertises on 2 consecutive weeks for special giveaway promotion. Π responds both
weeks, and is told that the sale applies only to women. Π brought suit; Δ alleges ad was invitation
to negotiate.
 Holding: Advertisement generally not offer unless clear, definite, explicit and leaves nothing
open for negotiation, acceptance (by performance) completed contract.
 Note: should π have notice of “house rule” on the 2nd week?

Acceptance

R2d §30: Form of Acceptance Invited


(1): Offeror can invite acceptance by:
 Affirmative answer in words
 Performance or forbearance
 May empower offeree to make a selection of terms in his acceptance
(2): Unless indicated by language or circumstances, offer invites acceptance in any manner and by any
medium reasonable in the circumstances
UCC§2-206: UCC Equivalent

R2d §32: Invitation of Promise or Performance


 If in doubt, acceptance by promise or by return performance per offeree’s choice

R2d §35: The Offeree's Power of Acceptance (transferred from offeror to offeree after offer)
1. An offer gives power to offeree to complete MoMA by acceptance of the offer
2. No K by acceptance of an offer power of acceptance terminated via § 36.

R2d § 36 Methods of Termination of the Power of Acceptance


1) An offeree's power of acceptance may be terminated by
a) rejection or counter-offer by the offeree, or
b) lapse of time, or
c) revocation by the offeror, or
d) death or incapacity of the offeror or offeree.
2) In addition, an offeree's power of acceptance is terminated by the non-occurrence of any condition
of acceptance under the terms of the offer.

R2d §42 Revocation by Communication From Offeror Received by Offeree


An offeree's power of acceptance is terminated when the offeree receives from the offeror a
manifestation of an intention not to enter into the proposed contract.

R2d §50 Acceptance of Offer Defined; Acceptance by Performance; Acceptance by Promise


(1) Acceptance of an offer is a manifestation of assent to the terms thereof made by the offeree in a
manner invited or required by the offer.
(2) Acceptance by performance requires that at least part of what the offer requests be performed or
tendered and includes acceptance by a performance which operates as a return promise.
(3) Acceptance by a promise: must complete every act essential to the making return promise

12
R2d §54 Unilateral Contract Notification: no notification req’d unless requested; if offeree knows
offeror can’t reasonably find out, offeror duty only when: (1)notification reasonably attempted, (2)
offeror learns of performance, (3)indicates no notification is req’d

R2d §56 Bi-lateral Contract Notification: Notification required for acceptance by promise

Bilateral vs Unilateral Notification: B wants plans + cares about quality of offeree


U – don’t care who, just want it done.

Leval (in Tribune) Test:


 Type I Contract: most, if not all, terms agreed upon. Memorialization is contemplated, but
legally unnecessary. Fully binding agreement.
o Four Factor Test:
 Does language express an intention to be bound?
 “strong presumption against binding obligation with open terms.. and
expressly anticipate future…documents”
 Have all the terms been agreed upon?
 Has there been partial performance?
 Is this type of contract usually committed to written form?
 Type II: leaves many terms open, agree to negotiate in the future to resolve open terms. Binding
preliminary commitment: not a binding contract, but commits them to a duty to bargain in good
faith.
o 5 factor test:
 Intention to be bound revealed by the language
 Context of the negotiations
 Existence of open terms
 Partial Performance
 Necessity of putting the agreement in final form

R2d§27: Agreement that are sufficiently definite can be enforceable even in written memorialization is
contemplated

Ever-Tite Roofing Corp. v. Green COA of LA (1955) p. 252


 Facts: Δ accepted offer for roof-repair from Π in contract that stated it was valid only if signed by
authorized person (never done) or if work is initiated. Π arrives at Δ’s property, but a different
company is doing roofing.
 Holding: Bilateral contract. The initiation of work began with the loading of the truck, not the
arrival at Δ’s property. Further, the time between the acceptance and the initiation was reasonable.
 Contra Proferentum – interpret form against interests of its drafter

Ciaramella v. Reader's Digest Association, Inc 2nd Cir. (1997) POSTPONING ACCEPTANCE
 Facts: During settlement negotiations, Π’s lawyer orally indicated that agreement was reached. Π
had insisted that agreement not valid until signed, and did not sign the agreement that his lawyer had
indicated was complete.
 Holding: Agreement not reached since Π insisted on signature (opting out of R2d § 30, agreement
thru any medium); Not a Type I prelim agreement

13
Revocation

General Rule: Offers are revocable prior to acceptance


Options (§25, §87): Only way to make a promise irrevocable.
2 exceptions
1. Firm Offers (UCC §2-205): Merchant’s signed, written, and explicit promising open offer is not
revocable: during time stated OR (if unstated) for three months
2. Construction Bids:
a. Traynor’s Rule (Drannan) §87(2) / Reliance Option
i. a sub’s promise implies promise: “I will not revoke if you use it in your bid”
ii. Generally adopted (counter arg – I won’t revoke if you don’t bid shop me)
iii. Policy: subs in best position to avoid mistakes in their own bid not GC
iv. Subs bear the risk of their own bid mistake
b. Old Rule (Hand in Baird) – subs offers are like other promises – revocable without
additional consideration.
i. Policy: non-legal reputation factors already compel subs to avoid mistakes, GC can
compare the bid to others and notice mistakes.
ii. GCs bear the risk of subs bid mistake

Revocation of Unilateral Contract: Rules have evolved


 Old rule: revocable at any time before completion of performance
 New Rule (R2d §45): irrevocable once requested performance begins (conditioned on
completion)

Pavel Enterprises, Inc. v. A.S. Johnson Company, Inc. COA of MD (1996)


 Facts: Π computed bid for government contract relying on Δ’s sub-bid. Π lost the contract, and then
regained it when the original winner was disqualified. It then met with Δ, sought further sub-bids,
and then notified Δ that their offer had been accepted. Δ said the bid was in error, and withdrew
their sub-bid.
 Holding: A contract was never formed between the parties. A sub-bid is irrevocable if the sub
should reasonably foresee the prime relying on the sub-bid. Here, the “reasonable time” between
offer and acceptance had lapsed. Π’s behavior (bid shopping) indicates that Π was not relying on
Δ’s offer.

GC / SUB Arguments:
1) Sub’s sub-bid is an offer (Promise), GC’s use of sub-bid is partial performance: §50(2) Acceptance
 Unilateral = Promise + Performance
o Sub’s offer: “we will do the job if you pay us”, they want promise to pay, not use of bid
o Use of bid is not a means of acceptance
2) Sub’s bid is an offer (Promise), Contractor’s use of offer is promissory act (§50(2) Acceptance)
 Bilateral = Promise + Promissory Act/Performance
o The use of the bid is not a promissory act b/c GC doesn’t want to be bound until it wins
bid
o Not acceptable means of acceptance
3) Sub’s sub-bid is an offer (Promise), Contractor mails “acceptance” conditional on final award of
project (Promise)

14
 Offer (Promise) + Acceptance (Promise) = Қ
o GC’s return promise was conditional;
4) 90 Argument: Sub-Contractor’s sub-bid is an offer (Promise), Contractor’s use of sub-bid is
specific reliance
 Promise + Specific Reliance = Қ under §90
a. Sub’s offer is a conditional promise of “I will do the job if you promise to pay”
b. Contractor cannot rely until he makes the return promise to pay

Offer and Counteroffer


Common Law View

Mirror Image Rule:


 Offer and Acceptance must contain identical terms (§38)
 If not identical, acceptance is a counteroffer: original offer terminated (§59)
 Offeree’s power of acceptance terminates upon counter offer. (§39)
Last Shot Doctrine:
 Different written terms, yet performance is rendered and payment is received
 Terms of contract are the terms of the last counter-offer, acceptance by performance/conduct
 Seller friendly

§ 59. Purported Acceptance Which Adds Qualifications


A reply to an offer which purports to accept it but is conditional on the offeror's assent to terms
additional to or different from those offered is not an acceptance but is a counter-offer.

§ 61. Acceptance Which Requests Change Of Terms


An acceptance which requests a change or addition to the terms of the offer is not thereby invalidated
unless the acceptance is made to depend on an assent to the changed or added terms.

Dataserv Equipment, Inc. v. Technology Finance Leasing Corp. MN (1985)


 Facts: “Indepth installation clause”. Π makes offer, Δ counters; initially rejected by π, π later
attempts to accept. ∆ stated it was too late and offer was revoked.
 Holding: Π initial rejection of Δ offer eliminates their ability to accept an offer. Since subsequent
counter-offers by Π were never accepted by Δ, a contract was never formed.
UCC §2-207

Battle of the Forms:


Route 1: First Clause of 2-207(1) + buyer friendly
a. Acceptance not expressly conditional on assent and contains additional or different terms
b. Different terms are EITHER (courts undecided):
i. UCC governs (knock-out both parties): Scott says majoritarian
ii. Dropped out – leaving offeror’s terms govern
c. Add’l Terms
i. Merchants (§2-207(2)) Additional terms become part of the contract UNLESS
o offer expressly limited expressly to the terms of original offer

15
o they materially alter the contract (most terms mat. Alter)
o offeror objects to them within a reasonable time
ii. For Consumers: terms are just proposals – fall out.
Route 2: Second Clause of 2-207(1)
a. Acceptance expressly conditional and contains add’l/diff. terms, AND
b. Offeror expressly agrees to the additional and different terms of the counteroffer
c. Seller’s terms dictate – both different and additional terms.
Route 3: §2-207(3) + buyer friendly
a. Acceptance includes different and/or additional terms but the contract is initiated through
performance (writings disagree, w/ no express assent to new/different terms).
 All different and additional terms are discarded via the Knock-Out Rule
 Contract terms: those agreed upon + defaults of the UCC
 Comment 6: when terms directly conflict, assumed that both parties disagree to their use

Additional terms v. Different Terms - §2-207(2): Some courts interpret this to mean that “different
terms” are not covered by this section. Scott believes otherwise drafting error.
 Primary means of dealing with this is to apply Knock-Out Rule, (both sets of different terms
knock each other out, leaving §2-207(3)-style contract.)
UCC Default Terms:
- delivery at buyer’s place of business (§2-310)
- delivery in “reasonable time” (§2-308)
- Specific Performance (§2-716)
- Seller pays buyer’s incidental and consequential damages (§2-715)

Step Saver Test of conditional acceptance:


1. States a term that materially alters deal solely to offeror’s disadvantage
2. Contains key words or phrases (only terms upon which we are willing etc.)
3. Demonstrate an unwillingness to proceed without term

Ionics, Inc. v. Elmwood Sensors, Inc. 1st Cir. (1997)


 Facts: “Battle of the forms”. Π and ∆ had conflicting forms. Dispute involving liability for
exploding radiator
 Holding Last Shot Doctrine doesn’t apply; UCC 2-207(3) governs as forms directly conflict. Terms
= agreed to terms + UCC provisions. Conduct or silence are not a means of accepting a
counteroffer’s terms (can accept offer’s terms that way, Gateway)

Step-Saver Data Systems, Inc. v. Wyse Technology, Inc. 3rd Cir. (1991)
 Facts: Π purchased copies of Δ’s software via telephone. The software contained a box-top
warranty disclaimer.
 Holding: Order = Acceptance. Delivery = performance. The box-top disclaimer was an additional
term brought after the parties had contracted over the phone. The box-top doesn’t meet the test for
conditional acceptance as the parties had an ongoing history of transactions that indicated the seller
was willing to proceed even without some express warranty terms as part of the transaction. 2-207
Route 1 contract, terms materially alter contract, fall out.

Hill v. Gateway 2000, Inc. 7th Cir. (1997)

16
 Facts : Π charges racketeering against Δ for product defects. Δ tried enforcing arbitration clause
contained in List of Terms delivered with computer.
 Holding: Transactional efficiency dictates that order = offer, delivery = conditional acceptance. The
contract here was formed upon Π’s receipt and acceptance of the computer, and Π are thus bound
by the arbitration clause.
 NOTE: UCC 2-207 applies only where there are multiple writings.

Rolling Contracts: initial transaction


a. Consumer-friendly
i. Phone conversation/submission is the offer
ii. Acceptance is delivery
1. If shipment is expressly conditional on customer’s acceptance, then the
conflicting terms are knocked out, and the UCC governs the void
2. OR, if the shipment is not expressly conditional, than the buyer’s terms
prevail
iii. Less transactionally efficient, but supported by Autonomy and consumer choice
b. Business-friendly (Easterbrook in Gateway)
i. Phone conversation is invitation to negotiate
ii. Shipment is an offer. Acceptance is promissory act. Previously “add’l” terms are
part of initial offer and stay in contract.
iii. Transactionally efficient: avoids having to read entire contracts over the phone

17
Relational Contracts
Uncertainty

Relational Contract: parties are incapable of finalizing contract terms due to uncertainty and
complexity. Few default rules exist.

Filling Gaps + Open Price Terms


 Enforcement is common if there’s intent to contract and agreement on a basic minimum terms
 UCC §2-204 (3) open terms are okay if parties had sufficient intent
 UCC §2-305: Open Price Terms

The Puzzle of Incomplete Contracts – Parties often leave incomplete terms because:
1. Costs of complete contract are onerous:
a. Negotiations + writing costs
b. Cost of identifying all contingencies
2. Maintain asymmetrical information private (not worth telling them a business secret)

Why write incomplete K’s? (1) too remote to be worth dickering (2) failure to foresee (3) might block
negotiation (4) assume courts will fill gap in its favor (5) intention to rely on non-legal mechanisms

Why is P time of delivery, not time of agreement? Maintains pre-contract price risk on part of B + S.

R2d §33: Manifestation of intention to offer = contract only if terms are reasonably certain
 (2) Requires basis to determine existence of breach + remedy
 (3)Open/uncertain terms may = no intention to make an offer/acceptance
 No agreements to agree
 Bright line rule

UCC
 Broad, flexible standard based on intention to be bound
 Examines context: prior dealings + custom (2-208, 1-205)
 Provides default rules to fill in open terms

§2-204 Formation in General


(1) A contract for sale of goods may be made in any manner sufficient to show agreement, including
conduct by both parties which recognizes the existence of such a contract.
(2) An agreement sufficient to constitute a contract for sale may be found even though the moment of
its making is undetermined.
(3) Even though one or more terms are left open a contract for sale does not fail for indefiniteness if
the parties have intended to make a contract and there is a reasonably certain basis for given
appropriate remedy.
§2-305: Open Price Term – filled in as “reasonable at time of delivery”
§2-309: Absent time of deliver – default is “reasonable time”

18
§2-310: Absent time of payment – default is payment upon delivery

Varney v. Ditmar
 Facts: Employer and employee verbal agree that employee will receive a bonus of a fair and
reasonable share of profits.
 Holding: Terms must be definite enough for court to enforce. Parties must be certain and explicit so
that their full intention my be ascertained to a reasonable degree of certainty for K to be enforced.
“Fair and reasonable share” of profits = too uncertain.

J. Martin, Jr. Delicatessen v. Schumacher NY (1981)


 Facts: Π leased retail space space from Δ; renewal clause stated that renewed rental price would be
“agreed upon” at time of renewal. Δ would only do so at higher than market value price. Π sought
specific performance at appraised market value.
 Holding: The agreement to agree is unenforceable

Slammit v. Badshot
 Facts: Badshot signs purchase order for fixed number of gut-stringed rackets from Slammit at
“price to be determined.” Before delivery, the price of gut triples. Was there a contract?
 Holding: Badshot did not intend to be bound unless the price were fixed or agreed (under §2-
305(4)). Prior dealings show that neither party had intention to be bound to pay the price at
delivery if the price of gut string had shifted markedly since the time of order. Prior dealings can
give meaning to open terms and ambiguous contract terms

DR Curtis Co. v. Mathews ID (1982)


 Facts: ∆ sold grain promised to Curtis to another after failure to agree on price term. “Protein basis”
was left open for future agreement.
 Holding: Under UCC §2-305, 2-204(3), contract without price term is still valid as long as both
intended to enter into the contract. Court had reasonable market price to substitute.
Preliminary Negotiations

Can §90 be used to enforce representations made during Prelim Negotiations? Generally NO.
 Need a promise + calculated inducement. Most often fails due to lack of a promise (R2d §2)
 Scott: Typically need clear definite and unambiguous promise for enforcement
 Policy – Over-enforcement = activity level effect on prelim negotiations; encourages cheap talk
o Already usually truthful + in both parties best interests not to lie;
o Usually fails due to a lack of intent to be bound due to uncertainty

Coley v. Lang AL (1976)


 Facts: Δ-Coley sent a letter to Π-Lang stating agreement to terms of stock purchase. Δ backed out,
and Π brought suit for specific performance based on reliance. Δ argued that the letter was part of
negotiations and it contained incomplete terms.
 Holding: The letter agreement is unenforceable since it lacked materials terms (court found
indefinite agreement to agree, but more appropriate that there was no intent to contract.) It was
unreasonable for Π to have relied on it. Waiting to be bound

19
 Note: Discussions were too definite for Type II Leval contract; could instead make a ‘subject-to’
deal.

Hoffman v. Red Owl WI (1965) p. 204


 Facts: Π and Δ held negotiations for a franchise, but did not reach final agreement. Δ promised that
if Π met certain requirements, he would receive a franchise. Π relied on those representations, and
realized damages when Δ failed to award franchise without further conditions.
 Holding: Δ is liable for restitution damages because injustice would result, court found definiteness
of promise less strict for §90 than §71. Only restitution (not profits) available under promissory
estoppel.
 Note: case is outlier, better explanation is under quasi-contract. Hoffman conferred benefit (info on
business acumen) retention by red owl is unjust

Citigroup v. Wachovia & Wells Fargo:


 Reliance = interest on $5B loan
 Expectation = none, no obligation
 Quasi-Contract = best argument to obtain some of the $13B price increase due to the week loan
Binding Preliminary Agreements

Leval Test: Modern standard for determining nature of preliminary negotiations (see ~pg. 13)
 Typical context: MOUs, LOIs

Damages under Type II contract: Reliance expenditures are the appropriate damages to compensate
a party where counterparty has violated “good faith” bargaining (strategic bargaining delay)
 Policy – discourages strategic delays and promotes contractual investments

Brown v. Cara (US CC 2005)


 Facts: ∏ Developer had a MOU with ∆ property owner to develop property and reach formal
agreement. After investments + rezoning, ∆ refused to negotiate with ∏.
 Holding: The MOU induced performance and reliance. There was a binding Type II preliminary
agreement.

Output/Requirements/Exclusive Dealings

2 primary Relational contract purposes:


1. Thick Market - “smooth the bumps” – volatile market can have spillover effects on business
 Goal is to keep both parties ‘above water’ but offer flexibility
 Tools: Price index, Quantity discretion, exit opportunities
2. Specific (relationally specific) Investment
 Party wants to invest in contract to make it more valuable to both
 No opportunity to redeploy investments in other business ventures
 Goal is to provide framework that promotes investment and avoids “holdup” problem

UCC § 2-306: Output, Requirement and Exclusive Dealings

20
a) Requirements/Output Contract (Reasonable Quantity Demanded aka good faith)
b) Exclusive Dealings (Best Efforts)
UCC § 2-103(1)(b): Good Faith in the case of a merchant means honesty and the observance of
reasonable commercial standards of dealing in the trade.

R2d §205: Good faith required in all contracts


Output/Requirement

Thick Market “Smooth the Bumps” Contracts:


 UCC § 2-306(a): Requires “good faith”, no requirements “unreasonably disproportionate”
 Custom can be a barrier to ‘bad faith’ attacks
 Tools: Peg contract price to a price index/escalator with:
 a backup price escalator/index
 AND a circuit breaker / price ceiling / price floor

UCC §1-203: Obligation of Good Faith

Can requirements = 0? Posner thinks yes! Only if done in good faith. With fungible goods, always
have market buyers to dispose of excess. Not supported by language of UCC §2-306. Can use prior
dealings, industry practice to support/protect decreased requirements.

Good Faith: Typically requires exogenous variable dramatically altering business plan. (≠ reallocation
of capital). Must be more than re-evaluation of merits of deal.

Eastern Airlines v. Gulf Oil Corp. USDC, SD of FL (1975)


 Facts: Embargo induced breakdown of contractual price index and leads to Π receiving oil at below
market price from Δ, who demanded Π pay a higher price than that contractually stipulated. Π then
brought suit for breach of contract.
 Holding: The contract between the parties is a valid requirements contract enforceable under UCC
§2-306; not too indefinite; and thus is judged on the basis of “good faith” by the parties. Π had
acted in good faith, “fuel freighting” was consistent with course of dealings and wasn’t “bad faith”

Orange & Rockland Utilities v. Amerada Hess Corp (p. 330)


 Facts: Δ supplied oil to Π, for whom it became more profitable to sell the oil than to use it for the
intended purpose. Π attempted to purchase double the estimated requirement, and Δ ceased
delivery.
 Holding: Π’s demands were “unreasonably disproportionate” to the estimates in the contract.
 Factors for “unreasonably disproportionate:”
a. Requirements exceed estimate by how much?
b. Whether seller had reasonable basis on which to anticipate this increase
c. Amount by which the market price increased contract price
d. Was increase fortuitous?
e. Reason for the increase: “Middlemen to the world?”

Empire Gas Corporation v. American Bakeries Company 7th Cir. (1988)

21
 Facts: Requirements contract where Δ would buy “approximately 3,000” propane gas tanks and all
accompanying propane from Π. Δ ordered none, prompting suit. Gave no evidence of reason for
reduction of order.
 Holding: A buyer in an options contract can reduce his requirements to zero only if acting in good
faith. Δ, which failed to provide any justification for its zero requirement decision, did not act in
good faith.
o Buyer may not overdemand but may underdemand if in good faith
 Probably not supported by text of UCC 2-306. If estimate provided, it’s a “center”
 Problem of underdemand: buyer will find substitute goods that work just as well,
violate exclusivity
o Contractual purpose: “Off the shelf indicates requirements contract, non-fungible indicates
specific investment

Exclusive Dealings Contracts

Purpose: Capture additional marginal utility by taking advantage of one party’s relative advantage in
distribution/marketing etc.

P P1: Marginal Cost

P1+P2: Marginal Cost

Marginal Revenue
Q
QP1 QP1+P2
Exclusive Dealings: Encourages relationally specific investment by distributor; by preventing
“freeriding” by competing distributors who don’t participate in investment(the “Karl Problem”)

UCC §2-306(2): requires “best efforts in exclusive dealings to maximize joint value (optimal sales
level if same entity owned both production and distribution rights

Thick Market “Specific Investment” Contracts: Options for K structure


1) Explicit, fully defined K
 Has firm numbers for Q(units) and P($)
 No way to know optimal P/Q ahead of time; limits flexibility; generally contextually
inappropriate
2) Net Profits (Woods v. Lucy)
 Parties split profits according to agreed upon rate. Aligns parties’ interests.
 Problem = distributors with multiple products can spread costs amongst many products and
distort actual profits (Hollywood example)
 Works best: distributor w/ single product; easier to monitor costs.

22
3) % of Gross Revenue (Bloor v. Falstaff):
 Avoids distortion from net profits
 Problem = royalty shifts optimal level of sales compared to other products with no royalty;
distributor may not be motivated to sell your product (dist. Max profit ≠ seller max profit)
 Solutions: Incentives! Publishing - advance stimulates party to recover sunk initial costs

∆PRoyalty

Q
QP2 QP1
4) Benchmarking (McDonald’s):
 Operate a few vertically integrated outlets, to which all franchises are compared; franchise
agreements have mechanism to terminate in the event of trailing benchmark
5) Full Vertical Integration (Starbucks):
 Own outlets so there is no spread in incentives
6) Extra-Legal Enforcement:
 Parties are interested in goodwill and continued business

Wood v. Lucy Lady Duff-Gordon NY (1917)


 Facts: Δ entered into Exclusive Dealings contract with Π, who alleges Δ broke the agreement by
dealing with others. Π charges the contract is invalid since it obligates Π to nothing.
 Holding: An implied promise to act in good faith has been made by Π. Therefore, the contract is
valid. Implied promise to act in the best interest of the parties as an aligned unit in exclusive
dealing

Bloor v. Falstaff Brewing Corp. 2nd Cir. (1979)


 Facts: Π entered into Exclusive Dealing contract with Δ. Π alleges that Δ violated good faith clause
in agreement by reducing sales and marketing of Π’s beer. Δ maintains that it need not do anything
to market Π’s beer that would result in substantial losses.
 Holding: Δ violated best efforts. After saving company from financial peril, Δ was obligated to at
least consider sales and marketing options for Π’s beer that wouldn’t have incurred bankrupting
financial losses. Compared sales to comparable fully integrated beer producers.
Reducing Conflicts of Interest

Agency Costs: costs of hiring someone else to do business and sharing in profits; potential for moral
hazard (agent acts in own best interest, not in mutual interests). 2 options for limiting:
 Supervision: ensures agents act in your best interests; works well for routinized work (assembly
line). Costly, not appropriate for many high skill/service jobs
 Bonding: Agent provides performance guarantee to reduce need for supervision
o Termination Clause
o Covenants not to Compete

23
Termination Clauses

At will employment: provides bond for employee performance


 At-will: Low monitoring costs, incentivizes employee performance + productivity, no adverse
selection problem (avoids attracting lazy employees)
 For Cause: employee morale, more employee dialogue, non-salary benefit lower labor costs

Common Law: Can terminate at will for any reason or no reason; not a bad reason, violation of public
policy (failure to violate public policy, whistle blowing)

Employee handbook: If termination procedure is listed, must disclaim ability to deviate from
procedures. Be explicit, make it conspicuous, get initials!

Wagenseller v. Scottsdale Memorial Hospital (AZ 1985)


 Facts: At-will employee fired after failing to violate statute (mooning!)
 Holding: Absent a contractual provision, an at-will employee can be fired for good or no reason,
but not bad reason. Since the termination violated public policy and was bad faith. There are
implied in fact and in law contract terms. Good faith and fair dealing are implied.

Consumers International v. Sysco Corporation (AZ 1997)


 Facts: Distribution at-will contract. ∆ terminated without “good cause”. Π argued similar to
franchisee relationship with severe bargaining imbalance (some courts found “good faith” = “ good
cause” in that context)
 Holding: both parties were aware of the termination clause and had access to counsel and had
bargaining power. No evidence of bad cause. No cause need not be for good cause, autonomy
theory, free to make contracts.
Covenants not to Compete

Purpose: Protect specific investment in employee’s skill/knowledge


 Courts prefer incentives rather than limits b/c of autonomy, competition + consumer choice

‘Blue Line’ Rule: Court may strike objectionable terms while keeping others enforceable.

R2d §188 + 205: Restraints on Competition + Duty of Good Faith

Limits to Covenants to not Compete (from Gaglardi):


1) Existence of consideration
 ≠ continued employment
 must involve a change of status
2) Reasonable in time and place (too long, too broad?)
3) Related and supplemental to the employment contract
4) Necessary to protect interests

Gagliardi Bros. Inc. v. Caputo: USDC, Eastern. D. of PA (1982)


 Facts: Π alleges violation of Δ’s non-compete clause. Steak-ums manufacturer

24
 Holding: The non-compete clause is unenforceable since (1) it is not supported by consideration,
(2) was not reasonably limited in time & space, and (3) unnecessary to protect Π. Subsequent
employees not under same obligations

Amtech v. Harkness Hypo: How to avoid “did someone try hard enough” litigation?
1. Montoring
2. Benchmark/deliverables
3. Incentivize:
a. Stock options (combined with fee or not)
b. Termination clause

Modification of Existing Agreements

Hold-up Problem w/ Relational K: Strategic behavior to compel renegotiation in monopolistic or


specific investment situation (“over a barrel”);
 Re-allocate the pie instead of grow the pie

Pre-existing duty rule (common law): no modification to a contract is binding unless it is supported
by fresh consideration; can’t get more for the same duties. no obligation to renegotiate. 2 ways around:
 Fresh consideration (risks sham consideration)
 Rescind initial contract prior to entering new contract

Good Faith/Fair + Equitable (UCC§2-209 + R2d §89): all good faith modifications are enforceable
without without requiring separate consideration.
 Verifiability issues in proving “bad faith” (Emmitt Smith, wants to retire early or more money?)

Rules v. Standards:

Alaska Packers' Ass'n v. Domenico 9th Cir. (1902)


 Facts : Δs demanded modification of existing contract (flat rate + royalty per catch) claiming faulty
nets; Π accepted, no other options due to isolated work camp.
 Holding: The modification to the contract had no new consideration since Δs new deal had identical
duties. Trial Ct found nets were sufficient.

25
Regulating the Bargaining Process
3 Requirements of Expanded Choice + Contract Theory:
1. Voluntary
2. Informed
3. Mentally competence

Autonomy: Must have free will in decision


Instrumentalist:
 Without 3 req’s, can’t assume that parties are making a socially beneficial exchange
 Society shouldn’t subsidize bad behavior
 Denying enforcement allows parties to avoid excessive precautions that reduce total social gain

Line drawing problem: encourage “cheap talk” while protecting against negative behavior

Duress

Proto-Typical cases:
1. Ex-ante Duress (’48 Morgan): “Hard Bargaining” ≠ duress
 Simply stating price and sticking to it isn’t duress, even if other party is desperate
 Poor choices are better than no choices!
 No good faith required
2. Ex-post Economic Duress: (§176(1)(d)) (Wolf +Austin)
 Good faith required once a contract exists
 Games of chicken
3. Ex-ante Economic Duress (Mojave Dessert Hypo)
 Exploiting perilous situation ≠ duress unless ∆ creates peril
 Why? Poor choices are better than no choices! We want to incentivize services to those in peril.
 Need a rule; uncertainty of standard would deter service providers
 Situational monopoly
Elements § 175:
1. Improper threat (§176(1))
 Commit a crime or tort
 Criminal prosecution
 Bad faith civil action
 Breach of good faith once under a contract (ex-post economic duress)
2. Induce Assent
3. No reasonable alternative
 Subj/ Obj: Would a ‘reasonable’ person with those subjective chars. act that way?

Efficient breach in Ex-Post Econ. Duress context: Must show no hold-up + no a game of chicken
 Rationale: Cost of performance > Damages (≠ duress per UCC §2-209(c2); production cost)
 Efficient renegotiation: (Value of Performance > Damages)

26
 Value of Performance > Damages: often due to lack of recovery for goodwill losses, legal costs etc.

Wolf v. Marlton Corp. Superior Court of NJ, App. Div. (1959)


 Facts: Π sues to recover deposit on house they claim they were ready, willing and able to purchase
at all times prior to breach. Δ says breach was due to duress by Π’s lawyer, who threatened to ruin
Δ’s career.
 Holding: If Π can be shown to have made a threat reasonably likely to induce duress, then Δ may
recover from any damages resulting from the breach of the contract. Threat of sale to undesirable =
bad faith, no reason besides to induce assent, bad motivation.
 If a party causes duress to other side, it has breached the contract.

Austin Inst., Inc. v. Loral Corp. NY (1971)


 Facts: Π sought recovery for payment owed on a subcontract that Δ claims was accepted in duress
caused by Π.
 Holding: Π’s threat (to withhold delivery of materials under the first contract unless Δ accepted
higher prices in the 2nd contract) constituted duress.
 Scott disagrees and felt it may be covered under §2-209 (good faith)

Chouinard v. Chouinard 5th Cir(1978)


 Facts: Owner(π) desperately needs loan during ownership dispute, at bank’s insistence buys out
partner at high price
 Holding: Duress was caused by π’s mismanagement, ex-ante economic duress≠apply; hard
bargaining by co-owner

Post v. Jones: Admiralty doctrine of salvage should’ve applied to “auction sale” by salvaging boat. No
common law equiv.

Fraud

R2d §164: 4 prongs


1. Misrepresentation of fact
 §168: Opinion = expression of belief/judgment w/out certainty as to a fact
 §169: Justification for relying on opinion
i. Special relationship of trust
ii. Reasonable belief in special skill/judgment/objectivity
iii. Π particularly susceptible to misrepresentation of the type involved (Borat woman)
2. Fraudulent
 §162 (1): knowingly/recklessly
o knows/believes to be false
o does not have confidence stated/implied
o knows to not have basis stated/implied
 Courts are split on ‘material’ misrepresentation; §162 (2). Don’t use as reason in this class.
3. Induces Assent
 §167 – not ‘but-for’ causation, ‘substantially contributes’
4. Justifiably relied upon – (collapsed subjective/objective test)

27
 Would a ‘reasonable’ person with those subjective characteristics have acted that way

“Fraud vitiates Contracts”: Strong general policy preference against fraud due to social costs

Contracting around Fraud: Can get around policy with specific disclaimer combined with
merger/waiver clause, Danann & Borat

Can lose ability to rescind K without prompt action in the event of discovery of fraud (Snyder p. 425)
Willfull + Negligent

Spiess v. Brandt MN (1950)


 Facts: Π purchased resort, relying on Δ’s claims of profitability. Didn’t make money, Δ canceled
the contract as Π fell behind on payments.
 Holding: Π relied on Δ claims of previous revenues (resort success and past revenues), justifiable
b/c seller didn’t turn over books. “especially susceptible” to Δ claims b/c of their special
relationship (“trust and friendship”)
 Dissent: ∏ failed to prove damages; sale price was fair and youth does not constitute a valid
excuse. Should’ve checked the books!

Danann Realty Corp. v. Harris NY (1959)


 Facts: Π relied on misreps of op costs by Δ and signed lease. K included a disclaimer that Π hadn’t
relied on any representations by Δ in entering into the contract.
 Holding: Language of disclaimer was sufficient to bar recovery for fraud misrepresentations by Δ.
 Dissent: Fraud vitiates agreement and ∆ should not be protected by contractual terms.
 Notes: contract was between businesses; oral representations

Streit v. 20th Century Fox


 Borat lawsuit, while π was particularly susceptible to misrepresentations, specific disclaimer +
merger/waiver sufficient
 Misrepresentation was in written contract itself, not previous discussions, wrongly decided?
Disclosure + Concealment

Concealment (§160): party taking affirmative action that makes it harder to discover the defect
(papering over walls etc.) = concealment/assertion (Obde).

Duty to Disclose – (§161)


(a) Prevent previous assertion from being fraudulent, a misrepresentation or material
(b) Other party mistake; 3 parts:
1) Correcting a mistake (defect)
2) That is a basic assumption of the other party (material); Market conditions ≠ basic assumption
(§152 comment b)
3) Failure to do so is a breach of good faith + reasonable standards of fair dealing
 Good faith = latent, true facts are hard to discover
(c) Correct a mistake in the writings
(d) Special trust relationship

28
Why compel disclosure? reduce contracting costs; More efficient to have buyer disclose than to have
buyer pay for all possible inspections
Why no disclosure for extrinsic info? Proprietary: encourage private research + gives property
interest in information that is acquired. General info: speeds dissemination of proper pricing info
(Disney orange groves)

Caveat Emptor – common law rule of “Buyer Beware”; opposes concealment + duty to disclose
 Policy: disclosure risks info overload and invites false claims of disclosure for all disappointed π’s

Obde v. Schlemeyer WA (1960)


 Facts: Π bought a termite-infested house from Δ, took only superficial remedial actions and didn’t
disclose to Π.
 Holding: Damage was latent, undiscoverable defect posing a safety risk to Π. Δ had a duty to
disclose.

Reed v. King COA, CA (1983)


 Facts: Π purchased a home, site of a mass-murder. Δ did not disclose this fact, and took positive
action to prevent disclosure by neighbours(moderately discounted).
 Holding: Sellers have a duty to disclose material facts about real estate. A jury could find that the
occurrence of the murders is a material fact, and summary judgment is thus reversed.

Stambovsky v Ackley
 Facts: ∆ promoted perception that her house was haunted, sold to π without disclosure of
 Holding: Seller creating a material condition that is peculiarly within its knowledge has a duty to
disclose

Laidlaw v. Organ
 Facts: ∆ negotiated with π’s agent (Girault) for purchase of tobacco. π unaware of news that prices
were up, asked ∆ if aware of any news affecting prices, ∆ declined to answer and purchased for half
price.
 Holding: no obligation to disclose extrinsic circumstances

Unconscionability

Pre-conditions of ability to promise: (1) Voluntary (precludes duress), (2) informed (precludes fraud)
and (3) rational (precludes infancy)

Unconscionability: extension of fraud doctrine. Contracts are unenforceable if (both req’d):


1. Procedural: Absence of meaningful choice (absence or inequality of bargaining power)
- No opportunity to bargain on terms, or understand terms of K
- Leads to disclaimers, conspicuous terms + initialing
- Doesn’t just mean poor vs. rich or no one would contract w/ poor people
2. Substantive: Unreasonably favorable terms
- “Shocks the conscience” compared to standard business practice

29
- Can be used as evidence of procedural (who would ever sign that?); burden shifting
to ∆ to show procedure was acceptable

UCC §2-302: if a court finds a portion of a contract unconscionable it may not enforce a portion or
entire contract

Should a substantively unconscionable but fully disclosed clause be enforced?


YES. (1) Free choice + autonomy, don’t limit options, (2) Would drive up price and exclude some
buyers, (3) Too paternalistic, don’t tell people what to do.
NO. (1) we tell people what to do all the time, especially when there are spillover social costs (think
motorcycle helmet laws), (2) Cognitive error, people underestimate likelihood of their own default.

 Unconscionability is broadly defined but narrowly applied by courts

Williams v. Walker-Thomas Furniture (I) DC COA (1964)


 Facts: Π-Williams entered into installment-plan contract for items purchased from Δ. The contract
maintained a balance that aggregated all subsequent purchases so that ownership of all purchases
remained with Δ until last payment by Π. Π defaulted, and appellee filed a complaint in replevin.
Contract signed within the home.
 Holding: Π’s failure to read contract (unilateral mistake) was not ground for preventing
enforcement. However, court found that contract was unconscionable, but that it lacked statutory
power to prevent enforcement.

Williams v. Walker-Thomas Furniture (II) USCOA, DC Cir. (1965)


 Holding: Citing UCC, court finds that lower court was able to prevent enforcement of contract if
determined unconscionable. Case remanded (not enough facts in record to determine
unconscionability).

Statute of Frauds

Formal defense where ∆ can keep trial from jury and avoid judgment on merits
Common Law:
1. Sales of land
2. Suretyship (answering for others debts)
3. Contracts that cannot be performed within a year of signing
4. UCC §2-201 – Sales of goods for an amount >$500

R2d §131: General requirements of writing sufficient to surpass barrier of SoF


1) Identifies subject matter
2) Indicates a contract has been made b/w parties
3) States w/ reasonable certainty essential terms

Requirements for enforcement:


1. Writing
2. Signed; §1-201(39): broad definition
3. Needs quantity term (UCC only)

30
a. Doesn’t need to be accurate but recovery is limited to terms stated, sufficient to indicate
a contract has been made
4. ≠ contract has to be in writing; but provide solid evidence of the existence of a contract

Exceptions:
1. Reply doctrine§2-201(2):
a. Two merchants where one party fails to reply to a letter within 10 days
2. Special or custom-made goods §2-201(3)(a)
3. Admissions (in court etc.)§2-201(3)(b)
4. Partial Performance §2-201(3)(c); limited to goods received

Partial Performance: substantial partial performance in common law not limited to amount performed
 Lower bar than UCC

Policy for SoF: Encourage deliberation and preserve evidence in “significant” contractual matters
 Public subsidy of litigation costs creates undervaluation of reducing litigation cost (facilitating
adjudication by providing more evidence); SoF mandates considering those costs

Predominant purpose test – to classify ‘mixed’ contract (sale of goods + service/distribution rights),
look to “predominant purpose of transaction”

Monetti, S.P.A. v. Anchor Hocking Co. (US CC 1991)


 Facts: Π entered into discussions to sell itself to ∆. Two writings existed which are not signed by
both parties but embodied their verbal agreement. ∏ took actions in preparation for sale
 Holding: The writings anticipate a contract and agree to the offeree’s terms, so they satisfy the
UCC/IL statute of frauds requirements. Both the UCC and IL statute apply, and the partial
performance supports the existence of a contract.
 Writings before executing contract can satisfy SoF.

31
Identifying + Interpreting Terms
Goal: Find interpretation that the parties intended a court to reach in the event of dispute (subjective +
prospective)

2 Questions of interpretation:
1. What are the terms of the contract?
2. What is the meaning of those terms?

Parol Evidence Rule: prevents a party to a written contract from presenting oral evidence that
contradicts or adds to the written terms that have been agreed to.

Identifying Terms

Step 1: To what degree were contractual terms committed to language, what is level of integration?
 Unintegrated: no evidence of agreement or intent to commit terms to language; any evidence is
admissible to prove if a term is or isn’t part of the contract.
 Partially Integrated: Parties agree to some but not all terms. Writing is final to those terms (PER
bars evidence to the contrary); however, evidence allowed for other terms
 Totally Integrated: Intention for writing to be final and exclusive. No external evidence
allowed under PER. Intention = explicit (merger clause) or implied (certain/natural omission)
Step 2: What do terms mean? Contextual vs. Textual.
Common Law: Hard Parol Evidence Rule

“Four Corners” presumption: If document looks facially complete, presumption of total integration

Natural Omission Doctrine: Exception to four corners, evidence of additional terms allowed if parties
would have naturally omitted them.

“Plain Meaning” rule: Words interpreted by plain, unambiguous meaning, independent of the context.
Uses “majoritarian language”. Extrinsic evidence only allowed if meaning is ambiguous or vague.

 Hard PER = Textual interpretation, New York

Policy Hard PER: Ease of adjudication; encourages summary judgment; foster business transaction

Policy: Why shift transaction costs Ex-ante by requiring explicit contracts through PER? (NY State)
 Parties know their purposes + intrinsic values better than a court ex-post.
 Reduce litigation costs by facilitating use of summary judgment at trial.
 You can opt-out of hard PER rules to softer standards, but very difficult opt-into hard PER

UCC: Soft Parol Evidence Rule

32
R2d§209+210: Level of integration; rejects four corners.

UCC §2-202: Abandons many common law rules (four corners, natural omission, plain meaning) for
contextual approach to interpretation.

Partial Integration - 2-202(b): Additional terms may not contradict, and allowed if consistent
 Hunt: Consistent = doesn’t directly contradict (apply same test: D only barred if D =≠C)
 Snyder: Consistent = in reasonable harmony (term allowing unilateral cancellation ≠ harmony)

Contextual meaning: UCC (2-202 comment 1(b)+(c)) and R2d (§212) reject “plain meaning” and
allow contextual evidence (usage of trade, course of dealings, subject matter, preliminary negotiations)

Certain Omission: Evidence supporting terms under UCC allowable unless the parties would have
certainly included the terms in the writing. Increases barrier to proving integration (2-202 comment 3).

 Soft PER = Contextual interpretation; UCC, R2d, California


Mitchill v. Lath NY (1928)
 Facts: Δ sold property to Π through contract. Purchase was conditioned on ∆ oral agreement to
remove shed on adjacent property. Δ refused to remove shed after sale of property.
 Holding: An oral agreement may vary the terms of a written contract when (1) collateral, (2) oral
terms don’t contradict written terms, (3) term would not naturally be embodied in agreement. Due
to close connection to sale of land, this deal doesn’t meet 3rd requirement. Evidence should be
excluded
 Dissent: Four corners inappropriate, shed removal was a collateral contract.

Masterson v. Sine CA (1968)


 Facts: Π sold property to Δ in contract containing repurchase clause. Π went bankrupt, and the
trustees sought to repurchase the ranch. Δ objected, saying there had been an oral agreement that Π
wanted the ranch to stay in the family.
 Holding: Unsophisticated buyer, natural to exclude “family” term in written contract. Partially
integrated contract & terms don’t contradict the written terms, the trial court should’ve allowed
parol evidence about the family term.
 Dissent: Decision deprives creditors and undermines the doctrine, and the agreement contradicts the
written contract by severely reducing the value (can only be sold to family members)

Hunt Foods & Industries v. Doliner SCNY, App. Div. (1966)


 Facts: Following an offer by Π in negotiations to enter into a contract, Π stated that a recess could
be taken provided that they be given option to purchase stock(to prevent leveraging negotiations
into 3rd party deal). This was agreed to in writing, with an oral agreement that option only exercised
if Δ sought outside bids. Negotiations ended, Π moved to purchase stock.
 Holding: Stipulation did not contradict or negate a term in the writing, and was not one that
certainly would have been put into writing had the parties agreed to it. Consistent = does not
contradict.

33
Mistake + Excuse
Performer’s Risk Rule: Promisee should bear all risks of performance b/c generally best suited to
reduce risks as they have most control; cheaper K-default insurance policy, benefits social welfare
 Tries to recreate the ex-ante bargain that would’ve occurred

Exceptions: Excuse for impossibility when a specific performance with no substitute (paint a portrait,
specific crop, specific theatre)
Information Forcing Policy: Foreseeable events (people die, floods, bldgs. burn down) compels
promisee to disclose subjective value and consequences of breach (value of specific oranges)
General Policy: Unallocated risks (not part of the bargain!) should fall on promisee, as they should
stay where they would be borne were it not for the contract
 Autonomy: no voluntary assent to shift burden to promisor
 Instrumentalist: perhaps that party is cheapest cost avoider because they typically bear it?

Stees v. Leonard MN (1874)


 Facts: Δ contracted with Π to erect building on Π’s property. The building collapsed twice during
construction, and Δ abandoned the job. Π brought suit. Δ charged that (1) collapse occurred due to
soil, (2) Π had duty to ensure adequacy of soil, and (3) Π failed to honor oral agreement to keep soil
drained.
 Holding: The party entering into a contract is responsible for losses incurred during the
performance for which he contracted; could have contracted around liability.
 Difficulty in performing a contract not valid grounds for voiding

Mistake
Mistake: Discharge of party’s performance due to incorrect belief about endogenous fact, not
contemplated by the agreement material affects the contract.

Mistake – R2d § 151: A belief not in accord with the facts


Mutual Mistake - R2d §152:
1) Mistake
2) By both parties
3) Basic Assumption (Corbin: “No Risk” attributed to it)
4) Material effect = “adversely affects party”
5) Risk not Allocated (R2d§154) to party asserting mistake
a. Expressly allocated by parties (or by necessary implication, ALCOA arguments)
b. Speculative: limited knowledge/conscious ignorance, treats knowledge as sufficient
(gambling)
c. Default allocation = reasonable in the cicumstance

Unilateral Mistake - R2d §153: Mistake by only by one party. Add’l requirements:
1. Enforcement = Unconscionable, OR
2. “Last clear chance”: Other party had reason to know of the mistake or caused the mistake

34
Double precautions at the margin: encourages both sides tot to take care; promisee with last clear
chance will inform or bear risk; promisor doesn’t know whether promisee is in position to bail out.

Last Clear Chance Policy: Autonomy ~ “harm principle”, one ought not to exploit others
Instrumentalist: seller would have to take costly ex-ante precautions to avoid all such mistakes

Aluminum Co. of America v. Essex Group, Inc. (USDC 1980)


 ∏ - §152 (Mutual mistake)
o Mistake by both parties: WPI ≠ reflect production costs w/in reasonable bound
o Not allocated; too remote to be worth adding floor
 ∆ – (no mistake; if mistake, not mutual; if mutual allocated to ∏)
o Not endogenous fact, no mistake
o Only assumption was that escalator would set price, not that it wouldn’t fail
o No material effect ($9M profit)
o Allocated = expressio unis + contra preferentum; by accepting a contract with an
escalator, they expressly assumed risk of no floor; should be interpreted against them as
drafting party
Holding: In favour of ∏; court can renegotiate the contract terms.

Modern Excuse of Impracticability


Excuse: Discharge of party’s performance due to exogenous risk, not contemplated by the agreement
renders performance impossible, impracticable, or pointless. “not on the table” when deal was made

R2d §261 Supervening Impractability:


1) Performance is made impractical
 Must be “severe disappointment”: magnitude speaks to unforeseeability, party wouldn’t
have taken such a risk
2) Without the party’s fault (exogenous event)
3) By the occurrence of an event (causation)
4) Non-occurrence was a basic assumption of both contracting parties (unforeseeable)
 Continuing financial markets aren’t a basic assumption

R2d §263 – Destruction of Necessary Item which was a basic contractual assumption
 Excuse if a necessary item is destroyed or doesn’t come into existence

UCC §2-615 Supervening Impractability:


1) Performance is made impractical
2) Without the party’s fault (exogenous event)
3) By the occurrence of an event
4) Non-occurrence was a basic assumption of both contracting parties

Doctrine of frustration: focuses on a party’s severe disappointment which is caused by circumstances


which frustrate a party’s principle purpose for entering the contract

R2d §265: Frustration of Purpose Requires:

35
1) Performance is substantially frustrated (becomes worthless)
2) Without the party’s fault(exogenous event)
3) Caused by the occurrence of an event
4) Non-occurrence was a basic assumption of both contracting parties

Taylor v. Caldwell King’s Bench (1863)


 Facts: Δ entered into contract Π to rent music hall for a concert. Hall was destroyed by fire, an
event which Π and Δ did not anticipate or plan for.
 Holding: Π and Δ are excused from contract. Performance impossible.

Eastern Airlines (Pt. II): events in Middle East and price regulation by government were foreseeable
 Majority Rule

ALCOA v. Essex (Pt. II)


 ∏ - §261 (Service contract)
 Severe Impractability - lose $60 million in performance
 OPEC embargo + EPA policies led to higher costs: Confluence of events = unforeseeable
 Both parties confirmed escalator against history to ensure it would work
 ∆ – no excuse
 No severe disappointment ($9M profit)
 Many foreseeable factors could’ve caused price to rise (inflation = 16%); burden on ∏ to prove
causation
o Excuse would grant ∏ the benefit of factors that were already allocated in price
(inflation etc.)
 Parties predicted variation, potential extreme increase was foreseeable to Essex = circuit
breaker
 Court finds for ALCOA, but reset the price terms to cost +
 Court, with the benefit of hindsight, is well suited to replicate the initial purpose of the parties
(Cost +)
 Issues: courts confuse ends with means; parties never would’ve agreed to that approach
 Parties should be able to choose b/w rules + standards for optimal contract, judge infringed on
autonomy

36
Remedies
Basic Remedies

Seller Breach

Preconditions for Buyer damages availability – § 2-711:


1. Failure to Deliver
2. Repudiation
3. Buyer rightfully rejects or justifiably revokes acceptance on a substandard good

Options for Breaching Seller:


1. Perform + lose
a. Internal Performance:
b. Cover with Market substitute (includes expending
2. Breach + Pay: Buyer’s options and potential damages below

Options upon Seller’s breach:


1. Specific Performance - §2-716: Appropriate if:
a. Unique good (one of a kind – i.e. real estate, NFL teams)
b. Other proper circumstances: Thin markets - inability to cover or “great expense, trouble loss
or delay”, Sedmak
2. Expectation Damages
a. Cover – §2-712: reasonably purchase goods in substitution without unreasonable delay.
Damages = (Pcover – Pcontract) + incidentals (§2-715(1)) + consequential damages (§2-715(2))
b. Market Damages – §2-713: Damages = (Pmarket - Pcontract) + incidentals (§2-715(1)) +
consequential damages (§2-715(2)
Thick Market: Seller would breach if: (Costs of Cover Seller) >(Costs of Cover Buyer)

Buyer Breach

Options:
1. Perform + Lose
2. Breach: Triggers seller decision below
Options for Seller upon Buyer Breach:
1. Specific Performance - §2-709: Action for the Price
2. Expectation Damages:
a. Market Damages - §2-708: Damages = (Pmarket - Pcontract) + Incidentals (§2-710)
b. Resell - §2-706: Good faith and commercially reasonable resale; Damages = (Pcover –
Pcontract) + incidentals (§2-710)
i. Consequential damages not available b/c money should be available in liquid
market.

Malign Theory: Breacher seeks to take advantaged of situation that could force the other party to settle
for less than full expectancy damages.

37
Benign Breach: “Cry for help. Breacher determines that it would be cheaper to breach and pay π for
the breach than it would be to perform and suffer losses.
Compensation
3 types of Damages:
1. Expectation (R2d §344 (a) + §347): damages = put Π in the position had Δ performed
 Factors why damages are worse than actual performance (non-ideal)
o Damages must be calculable to “reasonable certainty” for compensation (Freund)
o Mitigation – breaching party takes steps to cut promisee’s damages (Globe)
o Foreseeability: consequential damages limited to those foreseeable (Hadley)
o Cost of litigation born by promisee
o Time spent finding cover is often hard to calculate and uncompensated.
2. Reliance (R2d §344 (b) and §349): Undo harm of reliance, same position as if party had never
entered into contract.
 Position of next best option to contract
 Thick market: expectancy = reliance
 Often speculative inquiry into what promisee would have done
3. Restitution (R2d §344 (c) + §371): Value of the performance in terms of the benefits the promisee
has already conferred on the promisor in order to secure the broken promise.
 Fact-specific
 Only option for quasi-contract

Liquidated Damages(R2d §356 / UCC §2-718): opt-out for damages default rules, must be reasonable

Theory of Efficient Breach: promisors will breach if fewer losses or greater profits than performance
 Rules don’t compel performance, instead assure performance, or equivalent compensation
 Flaws: assumes no transaction costs

Globe v. Landa Cotton Oil US (1903)


 Facts: Π contracted to buy 10 tanks cars of cotton oil from Δ. Π sent cars to Δ’s facility in
Kentucky, but the cars were turned away. Other cotton oil plants were in the area, but the cars
instead returned empty.
 Holding: (Holmes) Π entitled to difference between market price contracted for and current market
price, but not for costs of transporting. This best replicates the parties theoretical bargain.

Freund v. Washington Square Press NY (1974)


 Facts: Π entered into contract for hardcover publication of proposed book. Π delivered manuscript
as promised and received advance. After book rejection period had passed, Δ was acquired by
another publisher who stopped publishing hardcover books.
 Holding: Trial court erred in assessing damages as costs of performance to Δ rather than value of
contract to Π. Π’s expectation interest in the contract was the advance and the royalties. The
advance had already been received, and royalties are speculative for awarding damages.
 Courts rarely assign value to lost goodwill, Too hard to calculate/speculative.
 NOTE : Freund’s best option would have been to find another publisher ASAP – to fix the value of
royalties – and then sue for expectancy damages, using the royalties as a barometer.

38
Expectation Damages: Cost to Complete vs. Diminution of Value

Market Damages: Preferred means of measuring expectancy damages in thick market situation

Economic Waste Problem: Courts typically apply diminution in market value when costs to complete
>> ∆ market value.
 Scott: Often ignores and undercompensates for prepaid services (often shadow price)
 Functionally a “mandatory” rule, as ‘penalty doctrine’ (UCC§2-718; R2d§356) threatens liquidated
damage clauses that insure idiosyncratic valuation

Perfect Tender (UCC § 2-601) vs. Substantial Performance (R2d §237) – stds of performance
 PT – buyer can reject goods for any defect no matter how minor
o Goods are typically fungible, avoiding unfairness on seller
 SP – if failure of performance is immaterial, difference in value is sufficient
o SP + damages (difference in value) = Performance
o Default for construction contracts b/c cost of ensuring perfect completion to
idiosyncratic standard would drive up prices

R2d §237 (Dependent Promises) – performance only required if there has been Substantial
Performance (no material failure) by other party
R2d §241 – factors of material failure: deprivation of benefit, inadequate compensation, likelihood of
forfeiture, likelihood of curing failure, degree of good faith/fair dealing
UCC § 2-601 – buyer’s rights on improper delivery (perfect tender)

R2d §348: Alternatives to Loss in Value of Performance


 Unfinished construction with uncertain loss in value allows damages in the form of:
o (a) the diminution in the market price of the property caused by the breach, or
o (b) the reasonable cost of completing performance or of remedying the defects if that cost is
not clearly disproportionate to the probable loss in value to him.

Jacobs & Young v. Kent NY (1921)


 Facts: Π built house for Δ. Near completion of the job, it was discovered that Π used a type of pipe
other than that specified in the contract (equal quality and price). Δ refused to pay the balance owed
to Π, prompting suit.
 Holding: Innocent/trivial deviation in the performance of contract does not justify forfeiture of
payment when the difference in value between the specifications and deviations is minimal and is
far exceeded by the burden of remedying the deviation. Court order payment by Δ, minus the
difference in value of the pipe (damages). Cost of completion would result in economic waste. Opt-
out clause was too boiler plate and not specific enough.

American Standard v. Schectman (NY 1981)


 Facts: Demolition company failed to remove underground structures (K- ∆ paid $275K for salvage
+ demo) resulting in a $110,500 cost of completion but a $3000 diminution in value.
 Holding: The diminution in value measure of damages (ie Jacob & Youngs v. Kent) is only
appropriate where it was an unintentional mistake occurred which is unremediable without

39
substantially tearing down the structure (if no “undoing” duty must be incidental to contract). ∆
chose to not perform solely for economic interest, must pay cost of completion.
 Note: no idiosyncratic value, solely for resale. Wrongly decided?

Peevyhouse v. Garland Coal and Mining (OK 1962)


 Issue: Whether diminution in value or cost of completion is an adequate measure of damages for a
failure to fully perform a part of the contract that was bargained for especially by the plaintiffs?
 Court: Plaintiff’s behavior here is economically irrational. Relative economic benefit is the
consideration here. The agreement to repair the land after mining was incidental to the contract and
the cost is grossly disproportional to the cost of the contract itself.
 Dissent: This was a bad faith breach. The defendants are depriving the plaintiffs of their value of
the contract. Should determine how the contractor values the performance.
Specific Performance

R2d §359: Damages inadequate to protect expectation interest


R2d §360: “Inadequate” factors:
 A difficulty of proving damages with reasonable certainty
 Difficult of procuring suitable substitute performance via damages
 Likelihood that an award of damages could not be collected

UCC §2-716: Unique or “other proper circumstances” – intentionally liberalizes CL standard


UCC §2-709: Seller SP: “unable after reasonable effort to resell at reasonable price”

Market Thickness:
 Thick: availability of substitutes and ease of proving reasonability of “cover”; no SP
 Thin: buyer vulnerable in proving “reasonableness” of cover; exposed to undercompensation;
o More likely to be “other proper circumstance”, even if property is not unique
o Limited as court doesn’t like to supervise performance of services

Klein v. Pepsico 4th Cir. (1988) p. 113


 Facts: Δ breached a contract for the purchase by Π of a jet owned by Δ. Π sought specific
performance of the contract.
 Holding: UCC allows specific performance where (1) the good is unique, or (2) “in other proper
circumstances.” This case was neither since many like models of the plane were available for
purchase. Failed to argue risk of undercompensation.
 Note: π buying for resale and not end use; factor?

Sedmak v. Charlie’s Chevrolet, Inc. (MO 1981)


 Facts: Contract for limited edition Corvette. Δ appeals from order of specific performance.
 Holding: Market is sufficiently thin to present undue hardship to Π if they were forced to cover.

Limitations on Compensation

R2d §350: Duty to mitigate; cannot recover for losses that could be reasonably avoided
R2d §351: Foreseeability limitation of damages.

40
 Flow in ordinary course, or if ∆ had reason to know of special circumstance
 Trends: abandon “tacit agreement”; “ reason to know” not meeting of the minds
 Universal opt-out of this rule by sellers. Not effective insurer against loss of buyer profits
 Repair + replace clause: 1. disclaim all warranties (2-316); 2. express warranty; 3. explicit remedies
 Means to attack: 1. No means of effective repair §2-719(2); 2. Unconscionable

R2d §352: Uncertainty limitation on damages; need reasonably certain evidence

UCC §2-715(2): Incidental damages include any losses from needs that other party had reason to know
at time of K. Uses “reason to know” instead of CL rule of “communication” or “tacit knowledge”

R2d UCC§2-719(2): Courts unclear as to whether lack of effective repair creates liability for (a) full
consequential damages or (b) loss of bargain
Certainty

New Business Profits: Common Law rule against profits for new business due to speculative nature
 New view (Drews): Not a per se bar to recovery, evidentiary presumption, overcome with:
o Market study, Compelling expert; ≠ give gross receipts and state expected profits.

Old Approach to Foreseeability: Limits the extent of damages recoverable


 Special/unique circumstances only iff party was aware of the circumstances at the time of Қ
 Encourages information sharing to make other side aware of idiosyncratic values

Redgrave v. BSO: exception to lack of recoverability for loss of goodwill, court found sufficient
evidence of loss of professional opportunities (appellate court greatly reduced initial award)

Drews Co. v. Ledwith-Wolfe Associates, Inc. (SC 1988)


 Facts: New business (contractor) seeks lost profits due to delay in construction of a restaurant
 Holding: Profits should not be automatically unavailable if π can provide sufficient proof. Π didn’t
meet evidentiary burden to establish certainty.

Hadley v. Baxendale Court of Exchequer (1854)


 Facts: Π sent mill crankshaft to Δ for repair. The repair was delayed because of neglect, and Π’s
mill remained shutdown as a result for longer than anticipated. Π sued for recovery of lost profits.
 Holding: Damages arising from contractual breach should be either (1) costs arising from the
breach, or (2) costs that are foreseeable to both parties given their knowledge at the time of entering
contract; not reasonably foreseeable.
 Note: two distinctions above have disappeared.
Duty to Mitigate

Duty to Deal with Breachertac: Typically doesn’t exist in thick markets; thin markets may exist but
not if different or inferior (employment context)

Rockingham County v. Luten Bridge Co. (US CC 1929)

41
 Facts: Bridge builder(∆) kept building a bridge after county decided not to build road connecting
bridge π attempted to limit damages to costs incurred prior to breach
 Holding: ∆ cannot pile up damages, should have desisted further work, failed to mitigate damages

Parker v. Twentieth Century-Fox Film Corp. CA (1970)


 Facts: Δ breached movie contract with play-or-pay clause; offered part in different film; π declined,
∆ claims failure to mitigate by seeking other employment.
 Holding: Π under no obligation to accept “inferior” employment; duty to mitigate, but only with
“substantially similar” work. Further, as a general rule, a breached against party is under no
obligation to mitigate by working with the breaching party.
 Dissent: Similarity of roles is a factual matter for jury, summary judgment inappropriate.
 Note: Court likely applied wrong doctrine. Did π have any duty to mitigation with play-or-Pay
clause?

ADD
Factors from Reed v. King

ACCEPTANCE UCC Provisions??

WHAT TO CITE FOR BREACH

Can you use mistake etc. in UCC

42

Potrebbero piacerti anche