Sei sulla pagina 1di 272

Report No.

29506

INDONESIA

EDUCATION IN INDONESIA:
MANAGING THE TRANSITION TO
DECENTRALIZATION
(In Three Volumes) Volume 1

The World Bank


August 2004
TABLE OF CONTENTS
Volume 1

Page

FOREWORD viii
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS ix
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY x

CHAPTER 1: INDONESIA’S EDUCATIONAL PROGRESS AND CHALLENGES 1


Enrollment Expansion 1
Educational Challenges 2
Closing Large Regional Gaps 2
Reducing Inequality across Income Groups 3
Improving the Quality of Education 3
Decentralization: Promise or Peril for Education? 4
Topics for this Review 5
Governance and Management 6
Finance and Public Spending 6
Education Quality 6
Teacher Management 6

CHAPTER 2: GOVERNANCE AND MANAGEMENT 9


Legal Framework and Governance Structures 9
Basic Challenges in Governance and Management 9
Clarifying Governance Functions 10
Rebuilding Management Systems 11
Reframing the Role of the MoNE 13
Building Local Capacity 13

CHAPTER 3: FINANCE AND PUBLIC SPENDING 17


Financing Framework And Structures Under Decentralization 17
Expanding the Resource Envelope for Education 18
Making Education Expenditures Count 20
Spend Locally 21
Differentiate Assistance to Districts and Schools 21
Spend More Resources on Those Most in Need 22
Leverage Governmental Resources – But Consider Consequences of the Poor 24
Track and Monitor Spending 24

CHAPTER 4: QUALITY ASSURANCE AND IMPROVEMENT 27


Two Approaches to Improving Quality 27
Quality Assurance or Control 27
Quality Improvement 29
Policies to Improve the Quality of Education 32
Support National-Programs, District Projects,
and School-Improvements 32
Adapt a Balanced Scorecard Approach to Plan and Manage Support
to Districts and Schools 33
Address Structural Weaknesses of the System 34
Ensure Equity in Quality Improvement 35
Stimulate Demand for and Supply of Innovations and Good Practice
for Improving Teaching 35
From Setting Standards to Meeting Standards 35

CHAPTER 5: TEACHER MANAGEMENT AND PERFORMANCE 37

Management Changes Under Decentralization 37


Responsibility for Teacher Employment and Deployment 37
Responsibility for Setting and Monitoring Teacher Performance Standards 38
Responsibility for Teachers’ Professional Development and
Career Development 39
Teacher Employment and Deployment 39
Teacher Professional Development 41
Teacher Compensation and Incentives 43
Using Teacher Management Systems to Achieve Education Goals 44

CHAPTER 6: THE WAY FORWARD: MAKING DECENTRALIZATION WORK


FOR EDUCATION 47
A Policy Reform Agenda 47
Implementing the Policy Agenda 52
Supply-Side and Demand Led Progress 52
Learning from Past and Ongoing Efforts 53
REFERENCES 61

ii
TABLES IN TEXT

Table 1.1 Rising education enrollment rates at all levels, 1995-2002 1


Table 1.2 Inequality in enrollment rates: wider gaps within than between
provinces, 2002 2
Table 1.3 Education equality at the primary level and increasing equality
at higher levels: Net enrollment rates by income quintile, 1993-
2002 3
Table 1.4 Student performance on mathematics and science tests: ranking
among 38 countries 4
Table 1.5 Some challenges and issues in implementing decentralization in
education 7
Table 3.1 Sources of local revenues, fiscal year 2001 17
Table 3.2 Per capita education spending, 2001-2002 19
Table 4.1 School committees still not fully engaged 31
Table 5.1 Primary teacher absence rate in public schools, 2002-03 39
Table 5.2 A proposed national framework for a teacher management
system 46
Table 6.1 Proposed policy agenda for educational development under
decentralization 54

FIGURES IN TEXT

Figure 1.1 Gross and net enrollment rates in East Asian countries, 2000 1
Figure 1.2 Highest grade completed by 16-18 year olds, by income quintile 3
Figure 2.1 Flows of governance and managerial accountability in
decentralized Indonesia 10
Figure 3.1 Indonesia: Education spending by level of government, 2001 20
Figure 3.2 Relationship between two dimensions of educational
development 22
Figure 4.1 Balanced scorecard to determine appropriate action for each
district/unit 34
Figure 5.1 Districts vary in proportion of primary teachers with minimum
training qualification, percentage of teachers 41

BOXES IN TEXT

Box 2.1 Information systems and management in Brazil and Spain 12


Box 2.2 Transforming the current organizational structure of the
Ministry of National Education 14
Box 4.1 Minimum service standards 28
Box 4.2 Improving the quality of madrasah education 30
Box 5.1 A new teacher deployment scheme in the Philippines 42
Box 5.2 Mexico’s Carrera Magisterial program 43
Box 5.3 Brazil’s FUNDEF program and teacher compensation reform 45

iii
TABLE OF CONTENTS
Volume 2

CHAPTER 1: GOVERNANCE AND MANAGEMENT UNDER DECENTRALIZATION 1


The Situation as Decentralization Gets Under Way 2
The Basic Challenge: Clarifying Governance and Management Functions 7
Are Current Policies Helping? 12
Minimum Service Standards 14
Governance and Management Systems Lacking 15
Governance and Management Development Tasks 20
References for Chapter 1 22
Appendix 1.1 List of Governance and Management Problems 25
Appendix 1.2 List of Interviewees 28
Appendix 1.3 Decentralization Case Studies 30
Appendix 1.4 Citizen Perception and Educational Reality: Insights
from the Governance and Decentralization Survey 37
Appendix 1.5 Organizational Issues for DEPDIKNAS Under Decentralization 47
Appendix 1.6 Minimum Service Standards as Management and
Governance Tools 56

CHAPTER 2: FINANCING EDUCATION UNDER DECENTRALIZATION 65


New Fiscal Structures under Decentralization 65
Public Spending for Education at the National and Local Levels 68
Private Spending for Education Remains Low 71
Equitable Financing in an Unequal World 73
Increasing Efficiency Under Decentralization 76
Summary of Implications for Policy 80
References for Chapter 2 84
Appendix 2.1 Cost Implications of Quality Education for All 86

CHAPTER 3: QUALITY ASSURANCE AND IMPROVEMENT 89

Approach and Rationale 89


Methodology 90
Basic Terms 91
Quality Management 91
Quality Assurance 99
Quality Improvement 104

iv
Conclusions and Summary of Recommendations 111
References for Chapter 3 112
Appendix 3.1: Quality Improvement Projects in Indonesia Since 1990 115
Appendix 3.2: A Quality Management Model 121
Appendix 3.3: A Case Study of Project-Based School Rehabilitation 125

CHAPTER 4: TEACHER MANAGEMENT SYSTEM 127


The Changing Context of Teacher Management in Indonesia 128
Transparent Employment Processes and Conditions of Service 137
School-oriented Performance Standards and Monitoring 146
Career-Long Professional Development 149
Using Teacher Management Systems to Achieve Education Goals 153
References for Chapter 4 156
Appendix 4.1: What Teachers Need to Know and be able to Do 160
Appendix 4.2: Supplementary Information on International Experience 161

TABLES IN TEXT

Table 1.1 Diagnosis of governance, management, and related


decentralized challenges 3
Table 2.1 Public expenditures for education: How does Indonesia compare
with other Asian countries? 69
Table 2.2 Household expenditures on education, by income quintile, 2002 72
Table 2.3 Source of inequality in enrollment rates: Between and within
provinces 73
Table 2.4 Determinants of education expenditures using APBD: Results
from regression analysis 75
Table 3.1 Common uses of national and school-based tests in quality
assurance 97
Table 3.2 Comparing the school effectiveness and school reform
approaches 106
Table 4.1 Teacher management functions for public schools (except
Madrasahs) after decentralization 134
Table 4.2 Average number of hours worked per week 142
Table 4.3 The impact of corrupt practices with the education sector 144
Table 4.4 Comparing two teacher performance evaluation systems in Chile 149
Table 4.5 Potential policy tools for managing the teaching workforce 154

FIGURES IN TEXT

Figure 1.1 Flows of governance and managerial accountability in a


decentralized Indonesia 8
Figure 2.1 Post-decentralization financial structure 66
Figure 2.2 Education expenditures, 2001 71
Figure 2.3 Enrollment rates of children ages 12-15 by province 73

v
Figure 2.4 Inequality in the distribution of 2001 education expenditures
from APBD and APBN allocations 74
Figure 3.1 Diagram of quality management system 92
Figure 3.2 Relationships between standard-setting entities being developed 94

BOXES IN TEXT

Box 1.1 In South Africa, a lack of definition as to who could set


minimum standards, combined with sectoral collusion in teacher
management, led to the emergence of unfunded mandates and
fiscal problems after decentralization 18
Box 1.2 In Brazil and Spain, devising good management information
systems under decentralization was difficult and problematic but
was possible with effort and partnership 19
Box 2.1 Unequal education spending among districts 72
Box 2.2 Brazil’s experience with municipalization 77
Box 2.3 School funding – A gap in financial policy 80
Box 3.1 Hypothetical use of performance information in a school 92
Box 3.2 Information from a national evaluation system changed the
focus of debate in Brazil 98
Box 3.3 Quality assurance of the teaching force 101
Box 3.4 The New Zealand equalization program 108
Box 3.5 School development plans and quality inputs 110
Box 4.1 Cost-effective strategies for raising academic achievement 130
Box 4.2 Permanent or contract teachers? 145
Box 4.3 The importance of teacher quality 147
Box 4.4 International evidence on schooling, resources, educational
institutions and student performance 148
Box 4.5 Teacher education programs that made a difference 151
Box 4.6 Mexico’s incentive scheme for teacher development 153

vi
TABLE OF CONTENTS
Volume 3
Table 1 Highest Level of Education as a Percentage of the Population, by Location 1
Table 2 Net and Gross Primary Enrollment Rates, by Gender 3
Table 3 Net and Gross Junior Secondary Enrollment Rates, by Gender 4
Table 4 Net and Gross Senior Secondary Enrollment Rates, by Gender 5
Table 5 Net and Gross Primary Enrollment Rates, by Location 6
Table 6 Net and Gross Junior Secondary Enrollment Rates, by Location 7
Table 7 Net and Gross Senior Secondary Enrollment Rates, by Location 8
Table 8 Percent of Primary Students Enrolled, by Type of School 9
Table 9 Percent of Junior Secondary Students Enrolled, by Type of School 10
Table 10 Percent of Senior Secondary Students Enrolled by Type of School 11
Table 11 Adult Literacy Rates 12
Table 12 Primary School Classrooms and Teacher Profiles 13
Table 13 Teacher Profile in Junior Secondary Schools 14
Table 14 Teacher Profile in Senior Secondary Schools 15
Table 15 Test Scores of Junior Secondary Students 16
Table 16 Test Scores of Senior Secondary Students 17
Table 17 Average Monthly Household Income 18
Table 18 Education Expenditure as a Proportion of Total Household Expenditure 19
Table 19 National Education Development Expenditure, 2001 20
Table 20 Gross Regional Domestic Product at Current Market Prices, 1998-2000 21
Table 21 Per Capita Provincial Revenues, 2001 22

vii
FOREWORD

Improving the lives of its citizens is at the particular, significant steps have been taken
center of Indonesia’s development to decentralize authority for managing
challenge. Economic growth creates more education to local government and to build
jobs and reduces hunger and poverty, but it partnerships with civil society to improve
is clearly not enough. It is widely the quality of schooling. While we join the
recognized that being literate, more skilled, education community in applauding these
and more knowledgeable about the world steps, we recognize too that many other
also gives people the capacity to control and policies and actions are needed.
to enrich their lives. For this reason, it is
important that Indonesia continues to raise This Education Sector Review discusses the
educational levels, especially for poor and issues and the range of options for policies
disadvantaged people. and actions around the issues of
management and governance, financing,
Schooling will count for more when its teachers, and quality of the education
quality is improved. Indonesia achieved system. It specifically addresses the complex
significant progress in bringing children to and changing nature of the relationships
school during the last 30 years. Enrollment between central and local governments that
rates at the basic levels are high, even as have resulted from Indonesia’s
compared to countries with higher incomes. decentralization process. The Review is a
The key challenge now is to raise the quality collaborative undertaking by Government
of education available to young people so and donors, and its broad consultation
that they are well prepared to participate in process with many of stakeholders at the
Indonesia’s ever more dynamic society and national and local levels gives us also the
economy. Schools must be well managed, perspective of those who are closest to the
staffed with motivated and competent schools and the classrooms and has fuelled
teachers, and supported by a system that profound discussions on the key challenges
both provides resources and requires of the sector. We trust that the reader will
accountability. find this report stimulating and enriching
reading.
Indonesia continues to make important
changes at all levels of education. In

Andrew Steer David Ritchie


Country Director for Indonesia, World Bank Australian Ambassador to Indonesia

viii
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

This report was prepared by a team consisting of Home Affairs, Ministry of Education, and
Audrey Aarons, Luis Crouch, Susiana Iskandar, Ministry of Finance; David Sloper; peer
Jennica Larrison, H. Moegiadi, Fredi Munger, reviewers at the World Bank, Marlaine
Jerry Strudwick, Suheru Muljoatmodjo, and Lockheed, Lant Pritchett, and Haneen Sayeed,
Elizabeth King (Team Leader). It also benefited and other colleagues including Vivi Alatas,
from the helpful advise and generous Michael Borowitz, Deon Filmer, Scott
contributions of a large number of people— Guggenheim, Bert Hofman, Robin Horn,
many national education officials at all levels, Emmanuel Jimenez, Kai Kaiser, Samuel
advisors to the government, regional Lieberman, Jessica Poppele, Fadia Saadah,
government officials, school personnel and other Andrew Steer, and Christopher Thomas for their
stakeholders in various districts outside Jakarta. comments on earlier drafts; Owen Haaga and Ali
For their time, advise, and candor throughout the Subandoro for their very able research
process of preparing this report, we are grateful assistance; Fiona MacKintosh for her editorial
to the national education leaders, Baedhowi, contributions; and Elsa Warouw, Idawati
Secretary General, Ministry of National Harsongko, Dinni Prihandayani, Datty
Education; Boediono, now former Head of Sembodo, Dety Palimbong, Imani Rasheeda
Research and Development, Ministry of Haidara, and Dorothy Judkins for helping the
National Education; Herwindo Haribowo, office processes go smoothly.
Secretary, Research and Development, Ministry
We acknowledge the faithful and vigilant
of National Education; Indra Djati Sidi,
support of the donor community in Indonesia—
Director-General, Primary and Secondary
Asian Development Bank, Australian Agency
Education, Ministry of National Education; Fasli
for International Development, European Union,
Jalal, Director-General, Non-Formal Education;
the Royal Netherlands Government, UNESCO,
Satryo Soemantri Brodjonegoro, Director-
and UNICEF—and especially the funding
General, Higher Education; Ace Suryadi, Senior
assistance given by AusAID and the Royal
Adviser to the Minister, Ministry of National
Netherlands Government for the preparation of
Education; Nina Sardjunani, Director, Education
the report and the subsequent regional and
and Religious Affairs, National Planning
national consultation activities. Lastly, this
Agency; A. Qodri Azizy, Director-General,
report benefited significantly from the comments
Development of Islamic Institutions, Ministry of
of many more leaders and experts who attended
Religious Affairs; Bambang Indriyanto, Head,
the various consultative meetings that were
Policy Research Center, Research and
organized during the preparation of this report.
Development, Ministry of National Education;
and a group of young technocrats in government
who are committed to Indonesia’s educational The Team wishes to honor the memory of Dr. H.
Moegiadi, professor, mentor, colleague, and
development (Hamid Muhammad, Abdul Azis,
friend to many education leaders in Indonesia.
Renani Pantjastuti, Harris Iskandar, Suharti,
Dr. Moegiadi, who was part of the report team
Totok Suprayitno, Ratna Kesuma, Agung
Purwadi, Agus Hariyanto, Yun Widiati, Slamet during his last days, enriched the report with his
Soleh, Husaini Wardi, Ninasapti Triaswati, and vision of educational development in Indonesia
and his experiences in working for that vision
Herry Sukarman). We thank Joel Friedman,
while in government.
Frank Hijmans, Walter McMahon, and Blane
Lewis, technical advisers in the Ministry of
ABBREVIATIONS AND ACRONYMS
Acronym /Term Bahasa Indonesia English Equivalent

ADB Bank Pembangunan Asia Asian Development Bank


AKU Arah Kebijakan Umum General Policy Directions
APBD Anggaran Pendapatan dan Belanja Daerah Provincial or district budget

APBN Anggaran Pendapatan dan Belanja Negara National budget


APPKD Anggaran Penerimaan dan Pengeluaran Kas Desa Village budget
ASEAN Association of South East Asian Nations
AusAID Australian Agency for International
Development
BAPPEDA Badan Perencanaan Pembangunan Daerah Regional Development Planning Board
BAPPENAS Badan Perencanaan Pembangunan Nasional National Development Planning Agency

BAS Badan Akredetasi Sekolah School Accreditation Body

BKN Badan Kepegawaian Negara Civil Service Board


BO Biaya Operasi Sekolah School operation fund
BOMM Bantuan Operasional Manajmen Mutu Operational Assistance for Quality
Management
BP3 Badan Pembantu Penyelenggaraan Pendidikan Parents' association
BPS Biro Pusat Statistik Central Bureau of Statistics
Bupati Head of district
Camat Head of sub-district
CBBEP Community-Based Basic Education Project
CGI Consultative Group for Indonesia
CIDA Canadian International Development
Agency
CLCC Creating Learning Communities for
Children
COPSEP Community Participation in Strategic
Education Planning for School
Improvement (JICA)
DAK Dana Alokasi Khusus Special allocation fund
DAU Dana Alokasi Umum General allocation fund
DBEP Decentralized Basic Education Project
DBO Dana Bantuan Operasional School block grant
DEPDAG Departemen Agama Ministry of Religious Affairs
DEPDAGRI DDN - Departemen Dalam Negeri Ministry of Home Affairs
DEPKEU Departemen Keuangan Ministry of Finance
Desa Village
DFID Department for International Development
(United Kingdom)
DIK Daftar Isian Kegiatan Routine or recurrent budget of a central
ministry
Dinas A Provincial, District, Sub-District Office
with sectoral responsibility
Dinas P & K Dinas Pendidikan dan Kebudayaan Provincial, District, Sub-District Education
Office with responsibility for education
DIP Daftar Isian Proyek Development budget of a central ministry
DISD Directorate for Islamic Schools
Development (MORA)
DPR Dewan Perwakilan Rakyat Legislative Assembly
DPRD Dewan Perwakilan Rakyat Daerah Regional Legislative Assembly
DSSD Capacity Building for Decentralised Social
Services Delivery (ADB)
EBTANAS Evaluasi Belajar Tahap Akhir Nasional National end-of-level examination
(formerly used)
EFA Education For All
ESR Education Sector Review (this Review)
EU Uni Eropa European Union
Gaji Salary and wages
GER Angka Partisipasi Kasar Gross enrolment rate
GOI Government of the Republic of Indonesia
GTZ Gesellschaft für Technische
Zusammenarbeit (Germany)
Guru Teacher
GPN Guru Pegawai Negeri Government teacher
HRD Human Resource Development
IKIP Institut Keguruan dan Ilmu Pendidikan Teachers College
INPRES Instruksi Presiden Presidential Instruction
JBIC Japan Bank for International Cooperation
JICA Japan International Cooperation Agency
JPS Jaring Pengaman Sosial Social safety net program
JSE Pendidikan Lanjutan tingkat Pertama Junior secondary education
JSS SMP – Sekolah Menengah Pertama Junior secondary school
Kabupaten Kabupaten District
Kacab Kepala Cabang Branch Head
Kades Kepala Desa Village Head
Kadin P & K Kepala Dinas P & K (Diknas) Kecamatan Head of the Sub-District Education and
(Diknas) Culture Office
Kecamatan
Kakancam Kepala Kantor Kecamatan Head of Sub-District office of central
Government ministry
Kakandep Kepala Kantor Departemen (Kabupaten) Head of District Office of Central
Government Ministry
Kakanwil Kepala Kantor Wilayah (Propinsi) Head of Provincial office of central
Government ministry
Kakua Kepala Kantor Urusan Agama (Kecamatan) Head of Sub-District Office of Religious
Affairs
Kancam Kantor Kecamatan Sub-District office of central Government
ministry
Kandep Kantor Departemen District office of central Government
ministry
Kandep Diknas Kantor Departemen Pendidikan Nasional (P & District Education Office
K)
Kanin Kantor Inspeksi Inspection Office
Kanincam Kantor Inspeksi Kecamatan Sub-District Inspection Office
Kanwil Kantor Wilayah Provincial office of central Government
ministry
Kecamatan Sub-district
Kelompok Group
Kepala Desa Village head
Kepmen Keputusan Menteri Ministerial Decree
Keppres Keputusan Presiden Presidential Decree
KKKS (K3S) Kelompok Kerja Kepala Sekolah Principal's working group
Kota Autonomous city
KW Kewenangan Wajib (UU 22/99) Obligatory Functions (Law 22/99)
Kyai Veneration title for Islamic religious teacher
or leader
LKGI Latihan Kerja Guru Inti Training program for core teachers
LKMD Lembaga Ketahanan Masyarakat Desa Village community development council
LMD Lembaga Musyawarah Desa Village council
LPMP Lembaga Penjamin Mutu Pendidikan Education Quality Assurance Institution
Lurah Village head (in urban area)
LSM Lembaga Swadaya Masyarakat Non-Government Organization
Madrasah Islamic school
MBBS Manajemen Berbasis Sekolah School Based Management
Menpan Menteri Pendayagunaan Aparatur Negara Ministry of State Personnel
MESA SPPM (Studi Pengembangan Sub- Sektor Madrasah Education Sector Assessment
Pendidikan Madrasah ) study (ADB/AusAID)
MGMP Musyawarah Guru Mata Pelajaran Meeting of Working Group of Subject
Teacher of Secondary Schools
MI Madrasah Ibtidaiyah Islamic primary school
MKKS Musyawarah Kerja Kepala Sekolah Meeting of Principals' Working Group
MOF DEPKEU - Departemen Keuangan Ministry of Finance
MOHA DEPDAGRI - Departemen Dalam Negeri Ministry of Home Affairs

MONE DEPDIKNAS - Departemen Pendidikan Ministry of National Education


Nasional
MORA DEPAG - Departemen Agama Ministry of Religious Affairs
MSS SPM - Standar Pelayanan Minimal Minimum service standard
MTs Madrasah Tsanawiyah Islamic junior secondary school
MPR Majelis Permusyawaratan Rakyat People's Consultative Assembly
Negeri State / national
NER Net enrolment rate
NGO LSM - Lembaga Swadaya Masyarakat Non-Government Organization
NZDA New Zealand Development Assistance
LSM Lembaga Swadaya Masyarakat Non-Government Organization
PAD Pendapatan Asli Daerah Regional own source revenues
Pejabat Functionary, government officer
PERDAS Peraturan Daerah Local regulations
Pesantren Islamic boarding school
PIU UPP - Unit Pelaksanaan Proyek Project implementation unit
PP Peratuan Pemerintah Government Regulation
PROPEDA Program Pembangunan Daerah Regional Development Program
PROPENAS Program Pembangunan Nasional National Development Program
PROPEDATA Program Pembangunan Daerah Tahunan Regional Development Annual Program
RAPBS Rencana Anggaran Pendapatan dan Belanja School revenue and expenditure plan
Sekolah
REDIP Regional Educational Development and
Improvement Program (JICA)
Rp Rupiah Indonesian currency unit
SBM MBBS - Manajemen Berbasis Sekolah School Based Management
SD Sekolah Dasar Primary school

SLTP Sekolah Lanjutan Tingkat Pertama Junior secondary school


SLTP Terbuka Sekolah Lanjutan Tingkat Pertama Terbuka Open junior secondary school
SPM Standar Pelayanan Minimal (MSS) Minimum service standards
SPPM Studi Pengembangan Sub-sektor Pendidikan Madrasah Education Sector Assessment
Madrasah study (ADB/AusAID)
SSA SAB - Standar Analisa Belanja Standard Spending Assessments
SUSENAS Survei Sosial Ekonomi Nasional National Socio-Economic Survey
Swasta Private
TFEA Targeted Funding for Educational
Achievement (New Zealand case )
TPK Tim Pengembangan SLTP Kecamatan Sub-district Junior Secondary School
Development Team
UAS Ujian Akhir Sekolah Final school test (set nationally, marked at
schools)
UNDP United Nations Development Programme
UNESCO United Nations Educational, Scientific, and
Cultural Organisation
UNICEF United Nations International Children's
Fund
USAID United States Agency for International
Development
UU Undang-Undang Law
Walikota Mayor
WB Bank Dunia World Bank
WHO World Health Organisation
WTO World Trade Organisation
Yayasan Private Non-profit Foundation
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Indonesia’s population of school-age children is problem is the failure to provide students with
one of the largest in the world. A sustained the rudiments of instruction—textbooks, a
drive to build schools across the country since blackboard, writing supplies, and a teacher who
the 1970s has resulted in more and more of those has mastered the curriculum and regularly
children attending school every year. This is an comes to class.
impressive accomplishment. But there is a
widespread perception that several critical Because Indonesia’s school system is immense
barriers have prevented Indonesia from and diverse, it will be necessary to understand
achieving its goals of: (i) enrolling all students these problems as they manifest themselves
through to the end of junior secondary level, (ii) across all of the regions of the country and
ensuring that poorer and disadvantaged children across all of its demographic groups, searching
have full and equal access to schools that for factors that explain the low quality of
provide a safe and healthy learning environment education.
and effective instruction, and (iii) providing
education that is of acceptable quality and is Decentralization
relevant to the economy and society.
Indonesia’s ambitious decentralization program
First, behind the impressive increase in is transforming the nature and level of public
enrollment at the national level, wide regional service delivery, including education. How
differences remain, which means that the decentralization applies to the education system
likelihood of reaching junior secondary school is has been defined in Education Law 20/2003,
very different for two young Indonesians, one which transfers the principal responsibilities,
who resides in a well-to-do community in authority, and resources for the delivery of
Yogyakarta and the other in a poor rural area in education to lower levels of government, while
South Sulawesi. And even larger than this some decisionmaking power is transferred to
between-province variation are disparities schools themselves.
among districts within provinces.
There are four key conditions for
Second, although Indonesia’s enrollment decentralization to overcome barriers and
expansion closed the enrollment gap between stimulate educational development: (i) clear
males and females and across income groups, division of responsibilities and power among the
especially at the primary education level, different levels of government, (ii) greater
striking inequalities between richer and poorer decisionmaking power and autonomy to local
children remain at the junior secondary and governments, (iii) greater voice of teachers and
senior secondary levels. While nearly all parents on how schools operate, and (iv)
children enter the early primary grades, those effective accountability mechanisms and
who belong to the poorest income quintile drop financial structures that are consistent with
out first, thus completing much less than full educational goals. By distributing power and
basic education, on average. responsibility more widely throughout the
education sector, decentralization has the
Third, the quality of schooling in Indonesia is potential to increase the efficiency of the system
low and declining, and it is worst in the poorest and its responsiveness to the needs of its
parts of the country. Decades of rapid expansion constituencies. The freedom to experiment is
of enrollment have not produced graduates with another potential benefit from decentralization,
the consistently high quality of knowledge and and locally generated innovations can stimulate
skills needed to build a strong society and continuing improvements in education if a
competitive economy. Underlying the quality region can learn from the experiments carried
out in other regions.

x
However, despite its promising aspects, able to restructure and re-equip themselves to
decentralization is not a policy panacea. undertake their new roles.
Conflicts and inefficiencies can sometimes arise
when the goals of the different levels of Finance and Public Spending. Decentralization
governments contradict each other. And even has shifted the flow and allocation of fiscal
when everyone’s goals are aligned, paternalistic resources from the national government to the
behavior left over from decades of centralistic district governments and from the district
policymaking, on the one hand, and the extreme governments to the schools. Are the fiscal
dependency of some areas, on the other, can be resources for education sufficient? Are these
hard to change simply by edict. Inevitably, there resources being used more efficiently and more
will be lags and variations in implementing equitably than before? How can the use of
decentralization across the country. Thus, the resources be improved? What are the
process of reform is likely to be a slow one, implications of the new fiscal arrangements at
punctuated by bursts of progress and frequent the school level and thus on educational
setbacks that may lead to rising frustration and outcomes?
mistrust among stakeholders if they do not
understand that these are inherent aspects of the Education Quality. Under decentralization,
reform process. improving quality will mean identifying those
institutional arrangements (such as standards,
The Challenges of Implementation structures, and incentives) that will improve
performance and accountability. What then are
Like other countries that have decentralized their the best ways to raise quality in the context of
education system, Indonesia faces many local autonomy? How can performance
implementation challenges. However, most of standards be set, measured, and monitored
these challenges really stem from two throughout the education system?
fundamental problems—unclear, incomplete,
and inappropriate assignment of governance and Teacher Management. In Indonesia, as
management functions and a shortage of the elsewhere, teachers are a critical element in the
management and technical skills needed to process of educational development and,
operate a decentralized education system. reflecting this, their salaries and benefits account
for the bulk of resources spent on education.
Numerous questions about decentralization have How will decentralization affect the incentives
emerged with its implementation. This review faced by teachers, how will it determine
focuses on four broad issues. teachers’ entry into and progression within the
profession, and what management systems are
Governance and Management. Will the shift in likely to be effective in a decentralized context?
authority, responsibilities, and resources from
the central level to district governments and
communities help to achieve the desired A Policy Reform Agenda
education outcomes in Indonesia? This depends
on how certain design and implementation The following set of policy recommendations
issues regarding governance and management emerged mainly from the meetings held by the
systems are resolved. These include how the team that undertook this education sector review
relationships between district governments and with many stakeholders, including officials in
district- and school-level service providers the central agencies, provincial and district
change; what are the functions and roles of the officials, teachers, head teachers, members of
large number of decisionmaking bodies in the school committees (including some parents),
sector; whether local government officials and national education experts, and the staff of aid
school staff have the capacity and skills to fulfill agencies. They are informed also by analyses of
their devolved functions and responsibilities; enrollment, school supplies and public
and whether the central agencies are ready and expenditures data in Indonesia, and by the

xi
lessons from experience of other countries that standard setting, teacher certification,
have decentralized their education system. and school rehabilitation and repair, and
retire any leftover policies and programs
Assign functions clearly and efficiently that undermine the goals under
within the education system and align them decentralization.
with appropriate governance and
management structures and financing x Develop, test, and disseminate new
arrangements at all levels. management and operations systems in
three areas—gathering and reporting
The assignment of governance, managerial, and information, budget and expenditure
financing functions in the education sector tracking, and planning, monitoring, and
remain vague. Similar functions and roles have evaluation of performance—at all levels
been given to different levels of government, of government and at the school level.
which is a recipe for replication, conflict, and
chaos. Also, functions and structures are not x Foster a national education information
aligned (for example, the central Ministry of system consistent with decentralization
National Education is still quite large despite the with financial incentives offered to
transfer of many of its responsibilities to lower districts for reporting information to this
levels of government) and financing national-level education database.
arrangements do not conform to functions (as
illustrated by the many different sources of x Develop management and technical
financing for capital expenditures at the local capacities at all levels and define
level). Moreover, some devolved functions are performance standards and measures for
best left to the national or provincial levels, such all decentralized functions and a
as coordinating the strategic direction of the corresponding checklist of basic
education system and setting education competencies needed to carry them out.
standards. Resolving these issues will require
reviewing and revising the decentralization laws Increase the resources that are available to
to clarify the assignment of functions, to correct the district governments for education.
the misalignments between functions and
structures and between functions and financing To implement their assigned functions under
arrangements, and to follow through with decentralization, local governments should
corresponding structural changes. manage far more educational resources than just
teacher salaries. Only a very small proportion of
Reform the central Ministry of Education the transfers to these governments is available
so that it can articulate and harmonize for non-salary expenditures. The result is either
that schools are starved of much-needed capital
education policies and design an
investments or that capital investments in
implementation program, and an schools are financed in a fragmented and
investment and funding plan for those unplanned way by the central government or aid
policies, while ensuring that local agencies, robbing the districts of the ability to
governments and civil society have a voice manage their education systems. To rectify the
in this process. situation, the central government should expand
the education allocation through the block
The MoNE should be reorganized according to transfer mechanism and should develop and
its new major functions consistent with its disclose a multi-year plan for financial, technical
oversight role in a decentralized education and management assistance to local
system. In particular, the Ministry should: governments. These educational assistance
plans should be developed, in consultation with
x Harmonize and link new education local governments.
policies and programs for example,

xii
Require provincial and district quality standards, especially in poor areas. In
governments to prepare and implement line with this, the central government should
multi-year regional investment and adopt pro-poor education programs to stimulate
financing plans as well as a corresponding demand consistent with the goals of the global
Education for All initiative, and provide
assistance plan for each school in
adequate and timely technical assistance to local
accordance with regional goals and with governments to build the capacity of local
school capacities and needs. governments to carry out their new
responsibilities effectively. As for the central
Giving transfers to lower levels of governments government, the Indonesian government should
is more effective when efforts are also made to adopt a “one policy roof” for all schools, and, as
build local planning skills, to increase a first step, assess all religious and private
transparency in the allocation and use of local schools according to the same national minimum
funds, and to require accountability in return for education quality standards that apply to public
the transfers. Start by replacing the budgeting schools.
process that local governments and schools go
through each year and replace it with a multi-
Establish a teaching service, separate from
year investment plan and an annual spending
plan. In doing so, a clear funding mechanism is
the civil service, that includes a
also needed to transfer resources to schools that transparent, system-wide appointment and
is easy to implement and to monitor. Districts deployment process and a professional
should disclose publicly how much they will be development system that is school-based
giving to each school well before the beginning and performance-led.
of the school year. A periodic financial audit of
schools is an input into the preparation of the Our most critical recommendation is for the
schools’ multi-year assistance plans and makes establishment of a separate teaching service that
the implementation of these plans easier. These involves: merit-based appointments, transfers,
are concrete actions that provincial and district and promotions; school-based performance
governments can take together. evaluations; and professional development that
covers all phases of the teachers’ career
Help all schools to make and implement including their initial training, their induction
decisions that will improve quality, into the teaching profession, school life, and
especially those in poor areas. continuous professional development. This
service would need to be built up over time.
But more resources to schools are not sufficient
to improve them. Making schools the center of Implementing the Policy Agenda
a strategy that is performance based is. The first
step in improving school quality is to bring the Finally, there is the question of how best to
physical and human infrastructure up to implement these recommended actions. Both
minimum standards for accreditation and to supply-side and demand-side approaches will be
ensure that schools are funded at least to the needed to fill existing policy and technical gaps.
minimum necessary for operations and Supply-side investments are needed to
maintenance. This should be accompanied by a strengthen the capacity of central education
periodic audit of schools on the basis of a agencies to make policy, to plan, to set
checklist of standards, require schools to report standards, and to measure the performance of
their own expenditures in a timely fashion, districts and schools. They are also needed to
establish a proposal-based grants program that stimulate the development of new solutions that
would allow schools to request extra resources can be used by local governments. It is vital to
for specific innovations and experiments, and link all of the different supply-side investments
develop a policy for targeting special assistance in one institution-building agenda instead of
to those schools that do not meet the minimum

xiii
undertaking them separately with no Conclusion
coordination.
Many messages have emerged from the review,
However, in the spirit of decentralization and in but the two overarching messages are:
recognition of the great diversity that exists
across Indonesia, demand-side programs are also x Improving education quality across the
needed. First, the central government must system is the key educational challenge
expand its use of block transfers to regional for Indonesia today, and even concerns
governments, rather than move away from them, about equity and serving the poor must
as the channel for education resources, while be couched in terms of universal access
investing urgently in enhancing local capacities to education of acceptable quality.
to manage there resources well. Second, the
national government should establish grants x Decentralization can potentially help to
targeted to the poorest districts to fund projects meet this quality challenge—by
initiated by local schools and communities. To spreading the governance and
encourage districts to collaborate to take managerial responsibility for improving
advantage of economies of scale, the grants better education across different
program could award more money to those stakeholders, by strengthening
proposals that are submitted by associations of accountability mechanisms, and by
districts. Third, as a managerial safety net, the enhancing incentives to innovate.
government should evaluate and support the However, any delays in clarifying and
education management systems being developed rationalizing functions, structures, and
and used in different regions. financing throughout the education
system and any lack of commitment
There is also a need to examine both past and from the government to confronting
ongoing pilot initiatives in education - to build a some difficult implementation issues
body of evidence-based, analytical lessons about could erode the effectiveness of the
how to deliver education services of good reform.
quality in the new decentralized education
system. An integral part of this evaluation effort
must be to establish a mechanism to ensure that
these lessons are widely publicized so that they
can be taken into account in national and local
policymaking and school-based management.

xiv
Chapter 1: Indonesia’s Educational Progress and Challenges

Enrollment Expansion
Table 1.1: Rising Education Enrollment Rates at all Levels, 1995-2002
Indonesia’s population of 1995 1997 1998 1999 2000 2002
school-age children is one Gross enrollment rate
of the largest in the
Primary level 107.0 108.0 107.6 108.0 107.7 106.0
world, but a sustained
Junior secondary level 65.7 74.2 73.4 76.1 77.6 79.9
drive to build schools
across the country since Senior secondary level 42.4 46.6 47.4 48.4 50.2 48.2
the 1970s has resulted in Net enrollment rate
more and more of those Primary level 91.5 92.3 92.1 92.6 92.3 92.7
children attending school
Junior secondary level 51.0 57.8 57.1 59.2 60.3 61.7
every year. This has been
Senior secondary level 32.6 36.6 37.5 38.5 39.3 38.2
an impressive
accomplishment for the Data sources: Pradhan (2001) and calculations using SUSENAS, 2002
country. The primary
school enrollment rate has grown from 62 and to 80 percent in 2002. In 2002, the net
percent in 1973 to nearly universal coverage enrollment rate was 62 percent. The senior
by 1983 and stayed high even through the secondary enrollment rate has been rising
financial crisis of the late 1990s. In 2002, too, though at a much more modest rate.
the gross primary enrollment rate exceeded These enrollment rates, especially at the
100 percent, and net enrollment rate was 93 primary level, compare favorably with
percent (Table 1.1). The gross enrollment enrollment rates in other countries in East
rate for junior secondary education showed Asia with much higher per capita incomes
more marked increases, rising from 18 (Figure 1.1).
percent in the 1970s to 66 percent in 1995

Figure 1.1: Gross and Net Enrollment Rates in East Asian Countries, 2000

120
100
100
80
80
60
60

40 40

20 20

0 0
Indonesia Philippines Thailand Malaysia Korea Indonesia Philippines Thailand Malaysia Korea
($710) ($1020) ($1980) ($3540) ($9930) ($710) ($1020) ($1980) ($3540) ($9930)
Primary Gross enrollment Primary Net enrollment Secondary Gross enrollment Secondary Net enrollment

Notes: GNP per capita data (in parenthesis) are for 2002
Data sources: UNESCO, 2003 and World Bank Edstats (http://www1.worldbank.org/education/edstats)

1
Education Sector Review Volume 1

The financial crisis of the late 1990s in Sumatera Utara. At the junior secondary
threatened to derail the educational progress level, net enrollment rates ranged from 40.9
that Indonesia had made in the previous percent in Nusa Tenggara Timur to 77.2
decade. Enrollment rates faltered percent in Jakarta, and at the senior
immediately after the crisis but have since secondary level, from 24.5 percent in Nusa
recovered. Impressively, large decreases in Tenggara Timur to 58.4 percent in
enrollment rates were avoided even though Yogyakarta.1
real household education expenditures—and
the share of education expenditures in total Even larger than this between-province
household expenditures—declined by about variation are disparities among districts
one-third from 1998 to 2000 (Pradhan, within provinces. Only about one-fourth to
2001). Perhaps this is partly attributable to one-third of the total inequality in
the national pro-poor scholarship and school enrollment rates in primary to senior
grants program that the government secondary education is due to differences
launched at that time to mitigate the adverse between provinces; the rest of the inequality
effects of the crisis (Cameron, 2002 and is due to differences among the districts
Filmer et al, 2001), and perhaps also to a within provinces (Table 1.2). This means
more established demand for schooling in that how education resources are distributed
Indonesia, even among the poor. among districts within each province matters
more than how resources are distributed
Educational Challenges among provinces if equality in education
outcomes is to be realized.
There is a widespread perception that
several critical barriers have prevented
Indonesia from achieving its Education for Table 1.2: Inequality in Enrollment Rates: Wider Gaps
All (EFA) goals of: (i) enrolling all students within than between Provinces, 2002
through to the end of junior secondary level, Source of Junior Senior
(ii) ensuring that poorer and disadvantaged inequality Primary secondary secondary
children have full and equal access to Gross Between
enrollment provinces 30.5 29.2 27.5
schools that provide an appealing learning rates Within
environment and effective instruction, and province 69.5 70.8 72.5
(iii) providing education that is of acceptable Net Between
enrollment provinces 39.2 35.8 29.9
quality and is relevant to the economy and rates Within
society (PROPENAS, 2000-2004 (Jalal and province 60.8 64.2 70.1
Musthafa, 2001). These challenges are Notes: The coefficients of variation for enrollment rates across the
discussed in this section. years are small at the primary level (ranging from 4 to 7 percent
for net enrollment rates), as compared with those at the junior
Closing Large Regional Gaps secondary level (22-28 percent) and at the senior secondary level
(41-46 percent).
Data sources: District-level database for ESR, using data from
Behind the impressive increase in various years of SUSENAS.
enrollment at the national level, wide
regional differences remain. In a country as
large, spread out, and diverse as Indonesia,
differences among regions are to be 1
These comparisons exclude a few provinces where
expected. However, extreme differences the samples tended to be in urban areas. According to
mean that some regions have been lagging the SUSENAS Work Manual (BPS, 2002), “Because
of the unfavorable security situation, in the following
for sustained periods and thus need extra provinces/regencies SUSENAS 2002 is only
help. In 2002, net enrollment rates in conducted in Banda Aceh (Aceh), Ambon (Maluku),
primary education ranged from 83.5 percent Ternate (North Maluku), Sorong (West Irian Jaya),
in the province of Gorontalo to 94.4 percent Timica (Central Irian Jaya), and Jayapura (East Irian
Jaya).”

2
Chapter 1 Indonesia’s Educational Progress and Challenges

Table 1.3: Education Equality at the Primary Level and Increasing Equality at
Higher Levels: Net Enrollment Rates by Income Quintile, 1993-2002
Income Primary Junior secondary Senior secondary
quintile 1993 1997 2002 1993 1997 2002 1993 1997 2002
Poorest 86.7 90.3 91.4 22.6 37.7 45.5 7.0 12.4 17.8
2 90.7 93.0 93.6 37.5 52.2 57.9 15.4 24.4 28.0
3 92.5 93.4 93.8 47.5 60.0 65.1 25.2 34.2 37.9
4 93.3 93.5 93.2 61.3 69.2 72.0 42.3 47.8 49.8
Richest 93.0 92.4 91.4 72.5 75.1 76.9 60.8 60.9 62.0

Q5/Q1 1.07 1.02 1.00 3.21 1.99 1.69 8.68 4.91 3.48
Data source: Calculations based on SUSENAS data, various years. Data exclude East Timor. 2002
exclude most of Aceh and Papua.

was three and a half times that of the poorest


Figure 1.2: Highest Grade Completed by 16-18 year quintile (Table 1.3). While nearly all
olds, by Income Quintile
children enter the early primary grades,
pe rce nt those who belong to the poorest income
100 quintile drop out first, thus completing the
90 richest quintile fewest years of schooling (Figure 1.2).
80 These patterns point to the critical junctions
70
in the school cycle when children from poor
households begin to fall far behind.
60

50 Improving the Quality of Education


second poorest quintile
40

30 There is a common perception that the


quality of schooling in Indonesia is low and
20 poorest quintile
declining and that decades of rapid
10
expansion of enrollment have not produced
0 graduates with the consistently high quality
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
grade of knowledge and skills needed to build a
strong society and competitive economy.
Data source: SUSENAS, 2002. National newspapers periodically comment
on the gap between what schools offer and
the desires of parents for their children to be
Reducing Inequality across Income Groups taught moral and religious rectitude, the
needs of civil society for an engaged
Indonesia’s past enrollment expansion electorate, and the demands of the enterprise
closed the enrollment gap between males sector for employees and entrepreneurs with
and females and across income groups, imagination and problem-solving skills.
especially at the primary education level, but According to the results of the 2002
striking inequalities remain at the junior examinations published on the National
secondary and senior secondary levels. In Examination Center website, the more than
2002, the net enrollment rate in junior 2.2 million students from nearly 20,000
secondary school of the richest one-fifth schools who took the tests averaged scores
(quintile) of the population was 69 percent of 5.79 for math, 5.11 for Bahasa Indonesia,
higher than that of the poorest quintile, and and 5.29 for English, out of a possible 10
their senior secondary net enrollment rate points for each subject area. These confirm
another piece of evidence—that eighth-

3
Education Sector Review Volume 1

graders in Indonesia performed well below Table 1.4: Student Performance on


most of its Asian neighbors on international Mathematics and Science Tests, Ranking
tests in 1999 (Table 1.4). However, this is among 38 Countries
just the tip of the quality problem. National Country Mathematics Science score
averages mask wide variation across score & rank & rank
provinces and across districts. In urban Singapore 604 (1) 568 (2)
Korea 587 (2) 549 (5)
areas alone, government expenditures per Taiwan 585 (3) 569 (1)
school ranged from a minimum of Rp 3,000 Hong Kong 582 (4) 530 (15)
to a maximum of Rp 460,000 in 2001 Japan 579 (5) 550 (4)
(McMahon, 2003). This staggering Malaysia 519 (16) 492 (22)
Thailand 467 (27) 482 (24)
variation defines the starkly different worlds
Indonesia 403 (34) 435 (32)
of students around the archipelago. Philippines 348 (36) 345 (36)
Data source: Trends in International Mathematics
Indonesia’s school system is immense and and Science Study, 1999.
diverse. In 2001/02, there were 28.9 million
primary school students and 1.4 million “If the priorities of South-East Asia’s
primary school teachers in more than politicians are anything to judge by, few
171,000 primary schools across some 400 subjects are more important than
districts and municipalities. At the junior education. … No wonder. Before the
secondary level, in grades 7 through 9, there crash of 1997, education was said to be
were 9.4 million students and about 680,000 propelling South-East Asia’s breakneck
teachers in more than 31,000 schools, growth. Now it is billed as the factor
including general, religious, public, and that could fuel another boom. In fact, the
private schools. Raising the quality of region’s erstwhile tigers still scratch
education in a system this large is not an above their weight in educational terms.
easy task. Underlying the quality problem is … But South-East Asian leaders are
the failure to provide students with the terrified that their countries will lose out
rudiments of instruction—textbooks, a on foreign investment and economic
blackboard, writing supplies, and a teacher growth unless they produce more skilled
who has mastered the curriculum and workers” (Economist.com, 2003).
regularly comes to class. One in six schools
in Central Java and at least one in two Decentralization: Promise or Peril for
schools in Nusa Tenggara Timur are Education?
reported to be in “bad condition,” according
to school survey data from the Ministry of Indonesia’s decision to decentralize its
National Education (MoNE). government was driven primarily by
political considerations—a national call for
The kind of education system that has democracy, the end of the Soeharto regime,
succeeded in expanding enrollment rates is and the failures of the highly centralistic
not necessarily the same kind of system that government, intensified by the financial
can effectively address the kinds of crisis of 1997. Its decentralization laws
challenges related to quality. To find (Law 22 and Law 25 of 1999) are based on
solutions, it is necessary to understand the the principles of democracy, community
problem across all of the regions of the participation, equity and justice, recognition
country and across all of its demographic of the potential and diversity among regions,
groups and to examine the factors that and the need to strengthen local governance.
explain it. A December 2003 article in The This reform is also transforming the nature
Economist emphasized that Indonesia cannot and level of public service delivery,
afford to ignore the challenge of improving including education. How decentralization
education quality: applies to the education system has been
defined in Education Law 20/2003.

4
Chapter 1 Indonesia’s Educational Progress and Challenges

According to this law, the principal lags and variations in implementing


responsibilities, authority, and resources for decentralization across the country. Thus,
the delivery of education are transferred to the process of reform is likely to be a slow
lower levels of government, while some one, punctuated by bursts of progress and
decisionmaking power is transferred to frequent setbacks that may lead to rising
schools themselves. frustration and growing mistrust among
stakeholders if they do not understand that
Can this reform cure what ails Indonesia’s these are inherent aspects of the reform
education system and help to stimulate process.
educational development? If
decentralization changes the distribution of For decentralization’s promise to be realized
accountability among the different in Indonesia, government commitment to the
stakeholders in the education system and reform is necessary but not sufficient in
focuses that accountability on measurable itself. Four key conditions have to be met:
educational outcomes, then the answer is (i) a clear the division of responsibilities and
yes. By distributing responsibility and power among the different levels of
power more widely throughout the government, (ii) real decisionmaking power
education sector, decentralization has the and autonomy to local governments, (iii)
potential to increase the efficiency of the greater voice of teachers and parents on how
system and its responsiveness to the needs schools operate, and (iv) effective
of its constituencies. It also gives the accountability mechanisms and adequate
freedom to innovate. In a large country like financial and technical resources that are
Indonesia, local conditions vary widely consistent with educational goals. Table 1.5
enough to make it rewarding and even lists the supporting conditions that have
necessary to experiment, and locally helped other countries to implement
generated innovations can stimulate decentralization and indicates whether the
continuing improvements in education if a conditions are present in Indonesia.2 Like
region can learn from the experiments other countries that have decentralized their
carried out in other regions. education system, Indonesia faces many
implementation challenges. However, most
However, decentralization also raises of these challenges really stem from two
difficult issues. Despite its promising fundamental problems—unclear,
aspects, it is not a policy panacea. Conflicts incomplete, and inappropriate assignment of
and inefficiencies can sometimes arise when governance and management functions and
the goals of the different levels of a pervasive lack of the management and
governments contradict each other. For technical skills needed to operate a
example, the central government may want decentralized education system.
to allocate public funds in such a way as to
equalize education indicators across the Topics for this Review
country, which might be resisted by a
wealthy district that already has achieved a Numerous questions about decentralization
high education quality level. How to resolve have emerged with its implementation. This
such disparate education goals among review focuses on four broad issues, which
stakeholders in the sector is a permanent are discussed in this section.
challenge under decentralization. And even
when everyone’s goals are aligned,
paternalistic behavior left over from decades
of centralistic policymaking, on the one 2
The information is derived from a series of
hand, and the extreme dependency of some interviews conducted for this report with various
areas, on the other, can be hard to change policymakers, experts on governance and management
issues, and representatives from education boards and
simply by edict. There will inevitably be school committees.

5
Education Sector Review Volume 1

Governance and Management Education Quality

Will the shift in authority, responsibilities, Improving the quality of the education
and resources from the central level to provided in schools has emerged as a high
district governments and communities help priority in the government’s policy and
to achieve the desired education outcomes in issues papers. It has focused on how to
Indonesia? This depends on how certain provide more and better inputs such as
design and implementation issues regarding textbooks and teaching aids to schools.
governance and management systems are Under decentralization, however, improving
resolved. These include how the quality will mean identifying those
relationships between district governments institutional arrangements (such as
and service providers (district and school- standards, structures, and incentives) that
level providers) have changed; what are the will improve performance and
functions and roles of the large number of accountability. What then are the best ways
decisionmaking bodies in the sector; to raise quality in the context of local
whether local government officials and autonomy? How can performance standards
school staff have the capacity and skills to be set, measured, and monitored throughout
fulfill their devolved functions and the education system?
responsibilities; and whether the central
agencies are ready and able to restructure Teacher Management
and reequip themselves to undertake their
new roles. In Indonesia, as elsewhere, teachers are a
critical element in the process of educational
Finance and Public Spending development. No systems for managing the
teaching force have been fully specified in
Decentralization has shifted the flow and either the general decentralization laws or in
allocation of fiscal resources from the the new Education Law. Yet such systems
central government to the district are vital for managing the employment,
governments and from the district deployment, and career opportunities of this
governments to the schools. While very large workforce and to ensure that
Indonesia is no stranger to transfer schools reach a level of performance that is
mechanisms, such as its current block grant consistent with the country’s education
system to districts, it has now become one of goals. How will decentralization affect the
the most decentralized countries in the incentives faced by teachers, how will it
world. Are the fiscal resources for determine teachers’ entry into and
education sufficient? Are these resources progression within the profession, and what
being used more efficiently and more management systems are likely to be
equitably than before? How can the use of effective in a decentralized context?
resources be improved? What are the
implications of the new fiscal arrangements
at the school level and thus on educational
outcomes?

6
Chapter 1 Indonesia’s Educational Progress and Challenges

Table 1.5: Some Challenges and Issues in Implementing Decentralization in Education


Common challenges in Present in Indonesia?
implementing decentralization*
1 Clear and efficient definition and No. Key features and elements of the new institutional arrangements
assignment of roles and responsibilities under decentralization remain unfinished, ambiguous, and controversial.
(function assignment) The law has specified the obligatory sectors for district governments, but
their functions within those sectors have yet to be decided. There are
inconsistent regulations that affect accountability and mismatches
between the functions of and resources available to the different
government levels.
2 Alignment of responsibility and authority Not yet; function assignment is not clear, even in the new Education Law.
3 State or provincial governments sharing No. Provinces do not have overall power relative to districts and schools.
authority with lower levels of
government and with schools
4 Effective management systems and skills No, though highly variable. Many districts do not have the skills to
(generic and system-based) to implement implement education decentralization, though some do. There is no
the reform serious (universal) diagnostic against a complete and detailed function
assignment, partly because function assignments are not clear. Some
samples have been done. Some districts are so small that they may never
have the skills.
5 Community, parent, and private sector Pilot projects suggest interest is high, but few opportunities exist for
participation participation.
6 Organizational and individual No clear mechanisms but there is a proposal for obligatory functions.
accountability
7 Information of high quality and No. Information infrastructure has to be rebuilt and needs to be linked to
information about quality performance.
8 Effective technical support and guidance No. Most instructions and guidelines and the regulatory tradition are
aimed at control rather than support.
9 Equitable educational access, No. There are large variations across districts and schools in indicators of
opportunities, and quality school quality.
10 Efficient and equitable resource No. Funding formulae are inefficient. Spending per student varies
allocation greatly among districts and among schools.
11 Support for decentralization and political Not a serious problem at local levels. Districts are interested in their new
and legal support powers. School-level decentralization has not yet been tested sufficiently
to assess degree of resistance. Some resistance at national level to
decentralization of certain functions, e.g., those related to teacher
management.
12 Project design supports decentralization Does not appear to be a problem. There were decentralization pilot
objectives projects ahead of the legislation and regulation, but there have been
problems in applying lessons from pilot projects to legislation and
regulation.
13 Institutional and political predictability Appears to be a problem; policy vacillates and implementation sometimes
contradicts policy.
14 Form and process of resolving disputes or No.
contested roles and responsibilities
Notes: *As captured by the knowledge management tools at:
http://www1.worldbank.org/education/globaleducationreform/06.GovernanceReform/governace_ref.htm.

7
Education Sector Review Volume 1

8
Chapter 2: Governance and Management

“[there have been] apathies and


Legal Framework and Governance confusion in the process of
Structures decentralization and autonomy in
education as it restructures the ways of
Laws 22/1999 and 25/1999, as well as the thinking, especially in issues related to
newly ratified Education Law 20/2003, have school and community based
firmly established decentralization in management, dichotomy between public
Indonesia, but many important legal and and private schools… and education
implementation issues remain unresolved. management and coordination.” (MoNE,
The Education Law, which takes 2003, p.29).
decentralization a step further from the
district to the school level and which was the
subject of national debate, clarifies but does
Basic Challenges in Governance and
not resolve all these issues. For example, Management
conflicts may arise from the fact that the
central government continues to be in charge Education systems have many different
of setting pay rates for civil servants, decisionmakers, actors, and stakeholders.
including teachers, even while district For decentralization to contribute to
governments have been given the educational development, it must transform
responsibility for hiring and paying teachers the relationships among these various
in all public schools except madrasahs. In individuals and agencies. In Indonesia, this
fact, many districts use their legal means redefining the roles of the MoNE and
prerogative to provide supplementary local governments; increasing transparency
benefits and incentives to the teachers within and accountability at the local level from
their jurisdictions. Also, while initial principals and teachers to parents and
teacher training remains the function of community and from the kepala dinas to the
those universities that are accredited by the DPRD and the education board; opening up
MoNE’s Directorate General of Higher information flows among parents, students,
Education, it is not clear who is responsible and school personnel; and ensuring that
for teachers’ continuing professional local input is taken into account in the
development. learning process. In principle, these changes
in relationships should be facilitated by
Some functions may have been corresponding shifts in the system’s
decentralized too far, leaving district organizational structure.
governments to wrestle with very difficult
managerial and technical tasks that they are Figure 2.1 reflects what is taking place in
unprepared for. It is possible for districts to Indonesia. In the figure, the governance or
collaborate with each other and some are representative line of accountability is
creatively doing precisely that, but there are shown as separate from the management or
hardly any guidelines, principles, or good executive line of accountability. It also
practice examples to inform this type of shows that provincial governments are
collaboration. These conditions have caused essentially missing from the new functional
anxiety among education managers at the structure of basic education.
local level, as the MoNE recognized in a
planning document in 2003:

9
Education Sector Review Volume 1
Figure 2.1: Flows of Governance and Managerial Accountability in Decentralized Indonesia

Governance or Management
Representative Aspect of or Executive Aspect of
Government: Government:
Governance Accountability Management Accountability

President of the
MPR Republic

DPR

MoHA MoF

Depdiknas National
Level
standard-setting report on
(sets standards of reporting organization of
on financial and educational issues) regional government
(accountability is around standards) through MoHA,
reporting to standards

(Provincial Level)

DPRD reporting to standards Regents, Mayors


(Regional People's (Bupati, Walikota)
Representative Kabupaten/
Assembly) Kota
reporting to standards
Education Level
Boards/Councils Head of District
Education Service
(Kepala Dinas
Pendidikan)

reporting to standards

School
Committees Principals
reporting to standards School
Level

Clarifying Governance Functions policies, and regulations that are


independent of the executive or
There are several unexamined or unresolved management line. This could be
issues relating specifically to the governance achieved if local legislatures were to
line. Here we highlight a few. provide research and analysis assistance
to governance bodies, perhaps through
x To make well-informed decisions, consulting services.
governance bodies at each level (in
other words, the DPR at the central x The role of the district education boards
level, the DPRDs at the district level, needs to be revisited. These boards
and the school committees at the school consist of district leaders, including the
level) need regular access to timely and district head, and are supposed to assist
accurate information and to the results the DPRDs in making policy decisions
of technical analyses. Currently, about education. However, the divisions
however, the governance bodies do not of labor between these boards and the
have any systematic mechanisms for DPRDs, between these boards and the
evaluating the soundness of legislation,

10
Chapter 2 Governance and Management

kepala dinas, and between these boards expanded roles. Management systems at all
and the school committees do not appear levels of government that used to operate the
to be effective. education system have broken down or are
now obsolete. New systems that will allow
x As defined by ministerial decree local governments to perform the functions
(KepMen 044/U/2002) and the that have been transferred to them under the
Education Law, the duties and powers of decentralization reform are just beginning to
the school committee need to be made emerge, but there is no national strategy for
clearer and more efficient. In the case encouraging or disseminating good
of financial management, should school practices. There is also some concern that
committees have oversight over all staff at the local levels are not sufficiently
financial matters rather than just the trained and experienced to carry out their
issues related to funds raised by parents? new and expanded roles. Moreover, field
Many of the duties of school committees visits conducted for this review revealed that
appear to require them to enter into there is a great deal of confusion
contracts, but do they have the legal surrounding the functions related to, for
right to do so, and if so, how will this example, teacher management (including
legal status be supported? It would be training, recruitment, deployment,
very inefficient if each of over 400 performance evaluation, human resources
district governments had to resolve these databases, payroll, and redeployment) or to
issues on its own. the allocation of resources to schools. We
highlight a few issues here.
x At the moment, many functions have
been decentralized too far, that is, down x The MoNE stopped receiving regular
to a level that does not have the capacity information through its past data
to perform that function effectively. collection mechanisms because districts,
Having recognized this, some districts now being autonomous, no longer feel
and provinces are coming together to compelled to transmit information
form agencies that can handle certain of upwards. In 2002, the annual school
their functions on a collective basis (as census yielded only a 30 percent
suggested in Law 22/1999). For response rate from schools as compared
example, various districts in East Java with 80 percent in 2000. As shown in
are collaborating on the development of Box 2.1, this has also been the case in
student tests; each district develops the other countries that have decentralized
exam for one academic subject and then their education sectors.
all of the exams are shared across
districts, thereby taking advantage of x The experimentation that follows from
economies of scale. Apart from this, the implementation of decentralization
there are other tasks that are most makes it possible to adapt systems to
usefully undertaken in collaboration— natural variations in local conditions.
but how should collaboration For example, some districts have
agreements be developed? experimented with upgrading their
budgeting and finance systems by
Rebuilding Management Systems setting formulae for district–to–school
funding. One dynamic bupati in Bali
It is clear that the systems that are currently has managed to eliminate certain fees by
in place at the lower levels of government consolidating schools and reducing
are not sufficient to perform the many certain types of expenditure, thus
functions that have been devolved to them. making enough room in the budget to
Nor do the staff at these levels have the eliminate school fees and still cover
necessary skills to carry out those new and costs. The lessons from these various

11
Education Sector Review Volume 1

Box 2.1: Information Systems and Management in Brazil and Spain

In Brazil and Spain, devising good management information systems under decentralization was difficult
and problematic but was possible with effort and partnership between the various levels of government.
Brazil. Until 1995, educational databases in Brazil were outdated and data collection was unsystematic.
Not only was there no up-to-date information available to guide policymaking but there was also no way to
monitor or follow up on policy actions. This caused a huge amount of waste in the use of funds. In the
absence of a standard national system of information and indicators, several states built their own data
gathering and processing systems that were not compatible with each other. As a result, Brazil could not
provide international organizations with consistent national data on education, and the available information
was neither sufficient nor reliable enough to be used as a basis for designing policies.
However, in 1995 the federal government issued guidelines for the creation of evaluation mechanisms to
monitor the country’s education system. Since then, the educational information system has been gradually
reformulated and now has an integrated but decentralized structure that meets the country’s monitoring and
evaluation needs. Several factors have contributed to this successful reorganization - the strong leadership
of the Ministry of Education in constant partnership with sub-national authorities and representatives of the
education sector, growing public support for systematic evaluations of schools and other educational
institutions, and multilateral cooperation in building capacity and disseminating the experiences of other
countries.
Spain. As the decentralization process unfolded in the 1980s, the country needed a planning mechanism to
coordinate the educational policies and programs being developed and executed by Ministry of Education
and the decentralized autonomous communities. One example of why such a coordinating mechanism was
necessary was the fact that soon after the decentralization process began the capacity to gather and
reproduce nationwide educational statistics was lost. Various regions had begun gathering their own data in
ways that could not be aggregated at the national level.
The Education Law of 1985 created the Conference of Counselors, with the Minister of Education and the
autonomous community counselors (chief educational officers) of the seven already decentralized regions as
members. Much of the work of the Conference (which meets at least once a year), is carried out by five
technical sub-committees each focusing on a specific issue (such as personnel, the curriculum, or statistics).
The Conference is an instrument of cooperation and not coordination because none of the decentralized
regions is obligated to carry out the decisions of the Conference when they believe their own statutes of
autonomy are being violated. Also, several autonomous communities worry that the Ministry may use the
Conference to control the actions of the decentralized regions. Another problem is that, even though issues
are brought to the Conference as technical problems, the proposed solutions tend to have heavy political
overtones. After all, the Minister and the Counselors sitting around the table are all appointees of particular
political parties, so political agendas are never far from the surface. Nevertheless, at times the Conference is
capable of reaching important agreements and carrying out complex actions.

Sources: Gumaraes de Castro, 2000 and Hanson, 2000.

experiments, however, have not been to the districts, but if a district takes any
systematically documented at the action that would result in changes in
national level or analyzed to see how the payroll database, it must report this
applicable they might be to other action to the national-level personnel
situations. And even in those districts board, which has the power to veto the
that are experimenting, it is not always action. With unresolved issues about
clear if the evolving financial the assignment of functions, it is not
arrangements are ideal or what functions surprising that districts do not yet have
to decentralize to schools and why. adequate teacher management systems.
x At present, responsibility for personnel
x Increased corruption under
management is nominally decentralized
decentralization has been raised as a

12
Chapter 2 Governance and Management

concern. The argument is that it is more principles of the reform because it must be
difficult to monitor 400 districts than it willing to assume the costs involved in
is to monitor the central government. changing its role in the management of
In principle, however, decentralization education (Box 2.2).
has the potential to reduce corruption.
Corruption can be kept under control if Building Local Capacity
resources are transferred to districts
using transparent allocation formulae, There has not yet been an audit of available
such as a per student funding allocation, local skills covering all of the likely
if all actors know the amount of the functions that would need to be carried out
transferred resources and when the at the district level under a rationalized
funds are transferred, and if a culture of model of decentralization. While districts
public disclosure is engendered at all clearly must be responsible for raising their
levels of government. own skills to the level necessary to carry out
their decentralized functions, the national
Reframing the Role of the MoNE government is responsible for the
maintenance of standards. Therefore, it
Many major responsibilities and powers seems appropriate that the central
now rest with district and provincial government should be responsible for
governments. However, there are some carrying out a nationwide, district-level
important policies and programs that these audit of current management skills and
governments have no incentive to carry out standards. At a minimum, the central
because they cannot fully capture the government should devise an instrument and
returns, because they are unable to perform protocol for doing such an audit and for
them well because of a lack of economies of compiling and communicating the results, as
scale, or because they do not have sufficient having each district devise its own protocol
resources to undertake them. For these would be wasteful. It may be tempting for
reasons, the central government needs to the central government to slow down the
step in if such policies and programs are to pace of decentralization for fear that district
be undertaken. Such policies and programs and provincial governments do not have
include setting goals for and standards of sufficient capacity to carry out their newly
service provision, experimenting when assigned responsibilities effectively.
needed, rewarding innovations from other However, there is greater capacity at the
parts of the system, disseminating local level than most central government
information widely and regularly, policymakers assume. Since few real
establishing a transparent regulatory decisions have had to be made locally
framework and enforcing it, ensuring more before, the actual extent of capacity and skill
equitable education spending, and at these levels has not been put to the test.
motivating districts and schools to adopt As decentralization proceeds, it may be that
national education goals. existing local talents and capacities emerge
naturally, at least in some places. It is clear
Because these may be unfamiliar roles to the that this is already happening in some parts
central education agencies, they may be of Indonesia, as some districts have much
tempted to hold on to their previous roles better and more talented bupatis than others.
rather than to redefine their mission (and The same process will undoubtedly occur
those of their deconcentrated units in the when authority is decentralized to the school
provinces in the case of the MoNE), to level; it will become clear that there are
reorganize themselves accordingly, and to many principals and community leaders
update their own skills. Evidence from other capable of wielding that authority
countries shows that the central government effectively.
has to be politically committed to the

13
Education Sector Review Volume 1

This is not to minimize the importance of process known as “asymmetric”


training and capacity building, particularly decentralization). However, it is important
on the question of inequality. In fact, not to make the criteria that schools must
considerable emphasis is being placed on meet to be given decentralized powers so
this aspect in the various planning and strict that very few can meet them. This has
policy documents as noted above. One happened in some countries (for example, in
possibility is to decentralize authority only Colombia’s asymmetric decentralization
to those schools where capacity already down to the district level) but not in others
exists, while continuing to support those (for example, South Africa’s asymmetric
schools that still need to develop it (a decentralization down to the school level).

Box 2.2: Transforming the Current Organizational Structure of the Ministry of National Education
Since the government of Indonesia has not yet arrived at a final and optimal function assignment and since
organizational form should follow function, it is difficult to suggest improvements for the Ministry of
National Education (MoNE) in any detail. However, judging by the organizational structure of the central
agencies of many countries that are decentralized or effective or both, Indonesia’s MoNE is not optimally
organized to provide support and guidance to lower-level government units and to schools.
The national level of modernizing and decentralizing governments, in other words, those that do not
implement policies but guide their implementation by local governments, is characterized by:
x Less focus on traditional line functions such as early childhood, primary, and secondary education
and more focus on “transversal” support functions such as governance improvement, financial
equalization, and quality control.
x Relatively less focus on supporting the direct execution of projects and hence fewer staff devoted
to the inspection and audit functions of these projects.
x More focus on the procurement not so much of goods and construction services but of analytical
and developmental services.
x The separation of those functions that support narrow issues of human resources or budgeting as
they apply to the MoNE itself and to projects run by the national level from those functions that
apply to the country as a whole.
With regard to size, it should be noted that central authorities in many decentralized countries have very
few staff. One extreme in the developed world is Canada, where the national education body functions
with a staff of only a few dozen, since there is no central authority but only a council of provincial
ministers with a very small secretariat. The United States functions with about 5,000 education staff at the
federal level. Developing countries such as China, Argentina, and South Africa have as few as a few
hundred to little over a thousand national-level staff.
The training and capacity of staff matter much more than the number. The dedication of staff time to
functions that have been appropriately assigned to the national ministry is also key. Staff who are highly
capable and whose actions create considerable leverage—because they are focused on overall direction,
policy, measurement, and comparisons—are much more important than the number of staff at the apex of a
decentralized system.
The proportion of the total budget spent by the national level in decentralized countries varies but is
generally higher than the proportion of staff working at the national level. At the pre-tertiary level in
decentralized countries, this ranges all the way from less than 10 percent (in China, the United States,
South Africa, and Hungary) to as high as 20-40 percent (in Australia, Poland, and Spain). As noted above,
the staff working at the national level in decentralized countries have a great deal more leverage over
resources than similar staff in a centralized system or than similar staff at lower levels of government.

14
Box 2.2: Transforming the Current Organizational Structure of the Ministry of National Education
continued
In sum, a central ministry in a decentralized system does not implement policies or interventions. Instead,
its functions should be to:
x Set standards and measures of performance (ideally related to outcomes rather than inputs) and
ensure that the necessary information systems exist to collect and report them, (including and
engage in goal-setting or minimum service standard-setting, again outcome-oriented
x Focus on institutions of delivery (for example, schools or colleges) rather than “levels” (such as
primary or secondary)
x Ensure competition and emulation between decentralized regions
x Ensure that decentralized units can raise their quality up to the necessary standard through systems
development, teacher training, and sufficient funding
x Ensure that functions with large economies of scale are carried out at a level that takes advantage
of those economies of scale, perhaps by brokering associations between districts or provinces
x Use funding or norming to correct spillovers between regions, for example in specialized areas of
education where one institution could serve more than one district
x Defend equity in funding and outcomes by norming funding equity if possible and, if not, by
persuasion
x Make planning, forecasting, and investment priorities for the whole education system, including
forecasting and analyzing teacher supply and demand
x Encourage experimentation and disseminate any lessons learned from those experiments.

Chapter 1 in Volume 2 of this review contains a more considered discussion of these issues and proposes,
for discussion purposes, an organizational structure for the MoNE that might better suit Indonesia’s needs
than the current one.

15
Education Sector Review Volume 1

16
Chapter 3: Finance and Public Spending

Financing Framework and Structures own-account revenues and shared revenues


under Decentralization for the remaining 30 percent (Table 3.1).3
This significant restructuring of
Decentralization has changed not only the intergovernmental transfers affects what
distribution of authority and responsibilities public resources are available for education
within the education sector but also how and who controls how those resources are
fiscal resources are generated and allocated. spent.
Prior to decentralization, the central
government transferred public funds to the In principle, the DAU allocation is based on
regional governments through the a formula that takes into account differences
Autonomous Government Subsidy (Subsidi in the needs and means of provinces and
Daerah Otonom or SDO) and through districts; in practice, however, the central
Presidential Instruction grants (Instruksi government simply guarantees that a
Presiden or INPRES). Now, province or district will receive an allocation
intergovernmental transfer arrangements at least equal to the amount it received in the
largely consist of block grants given by the past and that will cover its past wage
central government to district governments, obligations. As long as a large part of the
supplemented by an expansion of the block grants are protected under the “hold
districts’ share of the revenues generated harmless”4 components, regional
from local economic activity and natural governments will have little control over the
resources. The new transfer system is a transfers that they receive, nor will they
combination of two grant channels—the have a strong incentive to spend those
General Purpose Fund (Dana Alokasi Umum resources efficiently. This is particularly
or DAU) and the Specific Purpose Fund true in the education sector where the
(Dana Alokasi Khusus or DAK)—and salaries of the teaching force account for
more than 90 percent of expenditures,
Table 3.1: Sources of Local Revenues, Fiscal Year leaving districts only a small fraction of
2001 their budgets to allocate.
Source Rupiah Percent
(Billions) Law 34/2000 has given taxing authority to
Carry-over from previous year 2,157 2.7 district governments. Districts, but not
Own-source revenues 5,233 6.6 provinces, are now allowed to generate their
Transfers from central 69,280 87.2
government
own taxes provided that the taxes are
Of which the DAU allocation 54,401 68.5 authorized by the national government and
Other revenues 2,783 3.5 that they are in accordance with the
Total revenues 79,453 100.0 principles set out in Law 34/2000.5 Since
Source: Ministry of Finance

3
These new financial structures are described in
various revenue-sharing mechanisms. On
greater detail in various studies, including Hofman,
average, the DAU transfers account for Kaiser, and Goga (2003) and Lewis (2001, 2002, and
about 70 percent of the total revenues of 2003).
4
provincial and district governments, and This is to say that the central government is not
responsible if all of the block grant funding does not
reach the regional governments.
5
This is not a new phenomenon, however. Law
18/1997, the previous law on local taxes and levies,
was intended to stop the practice that then prevailed in

17
Education Sector Review Volume 1

being given this authority, district these expenditures (Hofman, Kadjatmiko,


governments have been creating new taxes and Kaiser, 2002). As district governments
aggressively (Lewis, 2002).6 In reality, increasingly exercise their right to borrow, it
district governments have limited capacity will be necessary to improve the framework
to raise taxes from their own resources such of on-lending and on-granting mechanisms
as land, buildings, and natural resources, so that apply to the regions.
these constitute only about 5 percent of their
revenues. Provincial governments have a Expanding the Resource Envelope for
larger own-resource base but must share this Education
with district governments. Moreover, the
revenue bases of provinces and districts are In the past, Indonesia ranked lowest among
highly unequal. For example, the per capita its Asian neighbors in the share of GDP that
non-oil and gas GDP of DKI Jakarta is is spent on education; in the late 1990s,
almost nine times larger than that of the Indonesia spent just 1.4 percent of its GDP
poorest province, East Nusa Tenggara on education compared with 4.7 percent in
(Akita and Alisjahbana, 2002); in 2002, the Thailand and 4.6 percent in Malaysia. Since
richest local government had 32 times the decentralization, the total government
revenues per capita of the poorest one spending for education has increased
(World Bank, 2003b). considerably. According to SIKD estimates,
education expenditures for primary and
To supplement local financial resources, junior secondary education in 2002 were 2.4
district governments are allowed to borrow, percent of Indonesia’s GDP at the district
but are limited in the extent to which they level, totaling about Rp 43 trillion. This
can go into debt. They must get the spending may well have increased close to
approval from the Ministry of Finance in the the EFA cost implications for 2004,
case of foreign loans and none of their loans provided that education spending increased
can be guaranteed by the central by the same projected percentage increase in
government. Law 25/1999 prevents local DAU transfers. (McMahon, 2003). In the
governments from borrowing except for past, Indonesia was able to achieve
projects that will generate a financial return, impressive progress in its basic education
although this clause has been loosened up by enrollment rates, which was due in part to
the implementing regulations. At the the country’s sustained focus on boosting
national level, about half of the development primary education enrollments and in part to
budget (DIP) continues to consist of donor the low cost of doing so.7 A greater focus
project loans, and the central government on education quality requires greater
currently bears the debt-servicing burden on resources and, more importantly, a more
effective use of those resources.
local government of creating a plethora of local
government taxes. Many of these taxes had little Some recent legislation has attempted to
revenue potential but imposed high costs on the secure a greater slice of the country’s
taxpayer and the economy. Law 18 restricted regional revenue pie for education. The new
taxes to a specified list and made any additional taxes Education Law stipulates that a minimum of
conditional upon the approval of the Ministry of Home
Affairs with advice from the Ministry of Finance.
20 percent of the central APBN budget,
6
Property taxes are administered and collected mainly
7
by the national government, although regional Duflo (2001) examined the effect of the large
governments assist with collecting these taxes in both number of schools built between 1973-74 and 1978-79
rural and urban areas. Until recently, the national and concluded that each new school constructed per
government retained 10 percent of total tax revenues 1000 children resulted in 0.12-0.19 year more
for its own use, 9 percent was provided to local tax schooling in Indonesia and 1.5-2.7 percent increase in
offices to assist with collections, 16 percent was given earnings for the first cohort that benefited fully from
to provincial governments, and 65 percent to local the program. This result implies an economic return
governments (Lewis, 2002). to education of 6.8-10.6 percent.

18
Chapter 3 Finance and Public Spending

exclusive of salary costs, and 20 percent of easy to monitor and to implement, is non-
the districts’ APBD budgets, also exclusive discretionary, and depends on just a few key
of salaries, must be allocated to education. measurable criteria. One important step is to
Including salaries, districts now spend on define minimum learning standards that will
average about 40 percent of their APBD be the basis for an agreed level of funding
budgets on education. Excluding salaries, per student. The advantages of this type of
they spend less than 10 percent (assuming funding mechanism are that it makes it
that salaries are a modest 80 percent of easier for local governments and schools to
education spending out of APBD resources) plan ahead because they will know precisely
or less than one-half of what is stipulated in how much funding to expect. It is also more
the Education Law. To double the share of transparent, which ensure accountability.
education spending in APBD net of salaries, One of its disadvantages is that it relies on
districts will need to make significant the availability of accurate and timely local
reductions in the shares of other sectors, enrollment data. If these are not available,
which may or may not be politically then the allocations to schools and districts
possible. may either fall short of what is needed or
fall prey to corrupt efforts to use bloated
Likewise, earmarking 20 percent of the enrollment numbers (Ross and Levaþiü,
APBN when the MoNE is supposed to have 1999). This formula for funding should
devolved most of its functions to local become the routine way to allocate basic
governments may be well-intentioned but education resources in Indonesia, and, in the
has disadvantages. It puts pressure on the process, it will facilitate school-based
MoNE to develop its own spending management by allowing schools to manage
programs in the regions, which would mean assistance in cash rather than in kind.
that most of the capital investments in
education would be outside the control of Table 3.2: Per Capita Education Spending, 2001-
district governments. The experience of 2002
other countries shows that this kind of 2001 (Actual) 2002 (Planned)
earmarking often leads to more spending but Total 134,000 175,058
not better outcomes because these centrally (1,586 – 463,753) (1,193 - 540,479)
initiated interventions guarantee the Routine 126,118 159,460
(998 - 450,789) (1,013 - 539,287)
provision of funds regardless of regional
Development 16,185 21,692
performance and creates multiple (177 - 205,044) (402 - 415,463)
opportunities for corruption. The challenge Notes: Numbers in parentheses indicate minimum and
then is to ensure that central and local maximum values.
education budgets are indeed spent on Source: SIKD, Ministry of Finance
schools and students, that they cover the
basic operating expenses of schools besides There has already been an attempt as part of
the costs of teaching and non-teaching staff the Education for All effort to estimate the
and their career development activities per-student level of spending that would be
(including instructional supplies, the routine consistent with attaining universal
activities of the school committee, the enrollment and improving education quality
maintenance of a school database, the in Indonesia (McMahon, 2003). What needs
dissemination of information to parents and to be done is to open up this proposed
the community, utilities, and light repair of formula to national scrutiny and debate in
the school buildings and other maintenance). order to validate it and to obtain political
support for it. What also needs to happen is
Our principal recommendation about for the funding formula to be applied to the
ensuring adequate resources for districts and local processes of allocating the DAU, not
schools is for the education system to adopt the DAK. Lastly, the funding mechanism
a formula-based funding mechanism that is needs to take into account the extreme

19
Education Sector Review Volume 1

variation in the current per-student are off-budget and local governments often
allocation of the routine and development have no knowledge of them. In 2003, there
budgets in the sector. Clearly, those districts were around 400 different education projects
that are at the lower end of the range will not in operation in Indonesia, but there was little
meet any kind of education standard (Table coordination and information exchange
3.2), so the funding mechanism should be among them. During field visits for this
designed to enable district governments to report, regional education officials in
mitigate specific inequalities among schools. Yogyakarta and Central Java expressed
For example, the funding formula might frustration at not knowing the full extent of
apply only to the per-student level of routine the resources (in kind) available to them.
operational expenditures. Without information and without
transparency, it is very difficult for local
Alternatively, the funding mechanism could governments and schools to plan ahead, to
use a per-school rather than per-student develop coherent and effective educational
resource formula to deploy teachers and programs, and to monitor and assess the
other staff to schools and to determine flow of funds through the system. Another
capital investments. Many schools in significant advantage of using the DAK
Indonesia have urgent development needs,
ranging from staff development to the
Figure 3.1: Indonesia: Education Spending by
construction of a library or science
Level of Government, 2001
laboratory. Richer districts will be able to
undertake these capital investments
Central
themselves, but poorer districts will not, so a LG Capital Recurrent

pro-poor investment program will be Expenditures Expenditures


(APBN)
(APBD)
needed. In fact, because poorer districts 6% 12%
Central Capital
repeatedly find themselves unable to fulfill Expenditures
(APBN) 18%
their responsibility to deliver education of
acceptable coverage or quality (as is evident Province
from the strikingly wide range in the per Recurrent
Expenditures
capita level of education expenditures across Recurrent
(APBD) 1%

districts), in the short-run, direct assistance penditures


(APBD) Province Capital
to schools in the form of cash would be 60% Expenditures
(APBD)
needed even to cover their basic operational 3%
costs, perhaps through a special DAK
allocation.
Source: APBN and APBD data
Notes: LG=Local government
Significant capital investments for education
can also be made through the DAK allocation and minimizing DIP initiatives is
allocation. If there are key areas of that, by increasing the transparency of the
investments that are clearly called for by the distribution of development or capital funds
national education program, the MoNE across regions, this would make it
could consider setting aside a special DAK considerably easier to use the DAU transfers
allocation for those capital expenditures and to increase equity among regions.
inviting local governments to submit
proposals for receiving a share of that
allocation. The advantages of using the Making Education Expenditures
DAK allocation instead of the MoNE’s Count
development budget (DIP) is that local
governments can incorporate their DAK Under decentralization, the impact of
grants into their overall planning and education spending on education goals will
budgeting processes, whereas DIP initiatives depend on how fiscal resources are spent at

20
Chapter 3 Finance and Public Spending

the central and local levels, on whether those government was successful in expanding
resources reach the schools, and, within the enrollment, but has not been effective in
schools, on how those resources are used. raising the quality of education to a
Certain key actions can increase the minimum acceptable standard. The
efficiency of these education resources. financing issue that most affects the quality
of education (the topic of the next chapter) is
Spend Locally whether budgets for schools are sufficient to
cover schools’ basic operation costs, let
There are three important ways to make alone to support their efforts to improve
expenditures more effective. The first way quality. Many junior and senior secondary
is to change the pattern of spending on schools now receive 50 percent or less than
education, especially by district their pre-decentralization budgets
governments. In the system as a whole, (McMahon, 2003).9 Therefore it is important
three-quarters of resources are spent on to ensure that resources find their way to
recurrent items, mostly on salaries and schools and do not get appropriated –
benefits and a small amount on operational whether legally or through corruption – by
costs and pedagogical supplies, and one- the district governments.
quarter is spent on capital outlays (Figure
3.1). This pattern is more extreme at the Differentiate Assistance to Districts and
district level; in 2002, 95 percent of the Schools
routine budgets of district governments was
spent on the salaries of teachers at the When allocating DAK or DIP funds across
primary and junior secondary levels and districts, it is crucial to differentiate among
other personnel.8 Often, even the tiny share districts based on their resources and needs.
left over for development expenditures, Provided that reliable data on districts and
which is supposed to be devoted to building schools are available, the national
new classrooms, repairing school facilities, government should be able to develop an
and teacher training, is occasionally used to assistance program to local governments
cover routine expenditures, especially staff that is based on three indices: (i) an index
salaries. This expenditure allocation is that characterizes educational progress in all
going to have to change if education quality of the 400-plus districts, (ii) a financial
is to improve. Teachers do play the key role needs index, and (iii) an education
in the teaching process, as will be discussed management capacity index that measures
in the next two chapters, but adequate the effectiveness of each district’s
resources need to be devoted not only to performance assessment, information
salaries but also to teacher professional system, and financial processes. All districts
development and classroom supplies. can be ranked in a three-dimensional grid
defined by these indexes and grouped into
It is not a good idea for the central discrete categories that would correspond to
government to step in to fill the capital different packages of assistance from the
expenditure deficits at the local level. The central government.
current system of development projects
designed and controlled by the central For example, those districts with the worst
education index and the poorest financial
8
and management capacities would qualify
Article 49 of the new Education Law states that the
for the highest level of investment and
salaries of teachers and personnel appointed by the
central government will be paid out of the national
9
budget, the APBN. Presumably, the teachers and Districts with high levels of local revenue and
personnel whose salaries were transferred to the districts that are required to maintain particular levels
districts as part of the decentralization reform will of funding to qualify for project funds have
continue to be paid under the local budgets, the maintained or increased their level of financing for
APBD. schools.

21
Education Sector Review Volume 1

test scores. Those


Figure 3.2: Relationship between Two Dimensions of Educational districts that appear in the
Development upper right-hand quadrant
are those that performed
Plot of individual districts by their average test scores and gross the best in both respects
enrollment rate, with the effect of household incomes on test scores and
(enrollment rate and test
enrollment rates netted out
scores), given their
Residual total score variation Linear trendline income levels, while
4 those that appear in the
lower left-hand quadrant
12
11
11 are those that performed
2 3 13 11 11
13
13 the worst.10 Needless to
Residual total score variation

22 11 12 11 11 1312
20 11 12
20 20 11 201117 1333 10
29 17
11
13
11
11 13
13
1113
22
say, those in the upper
2013 12201111 10 1313 311113 1341311
10 10
11
10
20411
11 20
29
13
20
11 11 111311
22
11
16
11
10
10
221123 11
3 13
22
20
2213
17320
13 10
13
273
13
135 right-hand quadrant
13 20 13 13 1013 19 22 113 13 1114 16813 2213
2029131620 13 1917 518 1020
13
419 20
17 11 28 18 20
17213
18 618
4
0 13 13 20
10
203010 16 20
20
31616 10
6 14 19 4
19
19
22
17 10
3
10
17
34
20 10 20 10 4
3162415 302 13 2
4 10 should not be receiving
14 17 14
1610
52 1017416
2015 5 17
1555516
28 24 28
619 4 22224
30
28 24 15 24 24 14
16
191514
27 614
1424 24 62885838 828108248223
2 6 222 5218 2 the kind and level of
24 5
28 24 23 14 21 27
assistance that those in
23 21 21
-2 24
24
23 21 the lower left-hand
17 24 21
2424 quadrant should be. The
24 23
23 chart also shows that, in
-4 6 general, districts that do
-4 -2 0 2
better or worse in one
Residual gross enrollment variat dimension also do better
Residual variation of total score and gross enrollment or worse in the other.
Data source: 2002 EBTANAS test scores for junior secondary schools averaged by district; However, there are
gross enrollment data by district from SUSENAS 2002.
Note: The codes for the plots refer to the provincial affiliation of each district. districts that do well in
one dimension but not the
other, and the type and
technical assistance program for accelerating level of assistance to them should be
educational development. In exchange for a different also.
high level of financial assistance, these
districts would be required to agree to accept Spend More Resources on Those Most in
a correspondingly high level of technical Need
and managerial assistance from the MoNE.
At the other end of the spectrum, those A common concern about decentralization is
districts with the best education index and that the transfer of authority and
the highest capacities would qualify only for responsibilities to local governments
enough assistance to enhance their weakens the central government’s ability to
educational development but would not be close gaps between the richest and poorest
required to take technical or managerial areas of the country and thus inequalities
assistance in exchange for financial help. grow. Districts with the most resources are
The idea behind the varying level of frequently those with higher enrollment
oversight is that districts prefer to have more
autonomy (less technical and managerial 10
support) than less autonomy (more technical Regression analysis was used to identify the
relationship between education outcomes (that is, test
and managerial support), so this acts as an scores or enrollment rates) and the districts’ average
additional incentive for better performance. household income levels. The regression results were
To illustrate, Figure 3.2 portrays the then used to obtain “residual” test scores and
distribution of districts according to two “residual” enrollment rates that could be attributed to
differences in the education systems and other factors
dimensions of educational development –
and not to differences in the economic status of the
school enrollment rates and average student district.

22
Chapter 3 Finance and Public Spending

rates and better schools, whereas districts experience with its large scholarship and
with fewest resources are those with lower school grants program, launched at the onset
education indicators. The current formula of the recent financial crisis, can also be an
for the DAU allocations includes poverty as important input into the design of such a
one of its criteria (albeit affecting only a targeted program.
small part of the allocation), but there is no
similar mechanism for ensuring that district One estimate of the cost of raising the
governments themselves use poverty as a education of poor youths is given in the EFA
criterion for funding schools. In addition, costing report for Indonesia (McMahon,
the trend towards local governments raising 2003). The report recommends eliminating
their own resources may widen the gap fees. Currently, fees are charged for
between those districts that have a strong entrance; BP3; examinations; procurement
revenue base and those that are less of textbooks, notebooks, and school bags;
prosperous. Currently, districts receive transport; and so on. Districts and schools
twice as many resources from would have to be able to forego revenues
intergovernmental transfers as from their from these fees while increasing the
own revenues, so if transfers are used enrollment of poor students and without a
equitably, they can be a powerful worsening of education quality. At the
mechanism for reducing regional primary level, eliminating fees would mean
inequalities. foregone revenues of Rp 13,000 per pupil in
2004 (2003 prices), on average. At the
Do district governments consider the same junior secondary level, foregone revenues
factors as the central government does when amount to about Rp 57,000 per pupil.
allocating their funds? When we examined
what factors appear to influence education The report also recommends an additional
spending by districts, using their level of grant for the poorest 18 percent of students
per-student education expenditures (from the to cover the opportunity cost of schooling
2002 APBD allocation), we found that those incurred by their parents and the cost of
districts with greater fiscal capacity make teacher salary supplements in their schools.
larger capital investments in education than The report estimates a student grant of Rp
those districts with lower fiscal capacity. 290,000 per pupil per year at the primary
Also, poorer districts (with the level of level, which is more than doubling the
poverty measured as the proportion of the current grant by the government, and Rp
population below a certain poverty 93,000 per pupil per year at the junior
threshold) do not spend more on education secondary level. It would be advisable to
from their budgets than richer districts initiate pilot tests of these and alternative
despite receiving a larger allocation more grant amounts in order to ascertain the likely
from the DAU. Since the households in responses of poor families across different
poorer districts are less able to spend for parts of Indonesia.
education themselves, both central and local
governments should be willing to Lastly, the central government can influence
compensate for this deficit in order to reduce the allocation decisions of the better-off
inequality among districts. districts, for example, by instituting a reward
system for those districts where the
To make pro-poor policies and programs education indicators of the poorest
financially sustainable, it is important to communities or schools significantly
target them to those who need them most. improve and, conversely, by taxing those
There are valuable lessons to be learned where indicators become worse.
from around the world (for example, from
Bangladesh, Brazil, and Mexico) on how
this can be achieved. Indonesia’s own past

23
Education Sector Review Volume 1

Leverage Governmental Resources – But society that exceed the benefits that they
Consider Consequences for the Poor yield to individuals, there is good reason for
society to subsidize the provision of basic
The total resource envelope for education education. In addition, if the direct and
includes private expenditures as well as indirect costs of education are too high, they
public expenditures. The new Education deter poor children from going to school. In
Law states that the financing of education is the various sites that were visited for this
a responsibility shared by the government study, most schools seem to have granted
and the community (Articles 9, 47, and 54). exemptions to those who could not afford
Indeed, students already pay a variety of the fees, even in cases where the fees were
school fees, including monthly tuition fees, quite low, but this is clearly a situation to
entrance fees for new students, term and watch as practice differs across districts and
final test fees, and extra-curriculum fees, across schools.12
averaging an estimated Rp 213,000 per pupil
in primary and junior secondary schools Track and Monitor Spending
(McMahon, 2003). These fees together
constitute a substantial contribution to the The importance of establishing an effective
income of any school. One study found that, information system has already been
on average, fees consist of about one-third discussed above. Having access to accurate
of schools’ non-salary expenditures, which and timely information helps governments
usually account for about one-fifth to one- to plan and manage the system, and sharing
tenth of a school’s budget (McMahon et al, the information with local stakeholders, such
2001).11 Schools also receive revenues in the as parents, through periodic reports may put
form of BP3 contributions and other pressure on district officials themselves to
donations from parents, private foundations, be more transparent and efficient. The focus
and NGOs. group meetings with teachers, principals,
and district officials undertaken as part of
Should schools be relying on students and this review indicate that decentralization,
the local community for resources? There while mostly a positive change, has created
are opposing views on this. On the one more opportunities for bribery and corrupt
hand, those schools that receive considerable practices (Vanwel, Musthafa and
financing from the local community tend to Miftahuddin 2003). Bribes in money or kind
have greater parental involvement, to are said to be more costly, processes often
operate more efficiently, and to have more take longer than before, and the distribution
successful educational outcomes (Bray, of grants, scholarships, and other school
1997; Jimenez and Paqueo, 1996; and funds is particularly vulnerable to
James, King, and Suryadi, 1996). People corruption. Also, school principals
who pay at least a small amount directly for complained that the lack of transparency
education and other school services come to about budget allocations at the central and
value those services more highly than when district levels prevents schools from
they receive those services for free. On the predicting how much revenue they will
other hand, if schools yield benefits to receive except through fees collected at the
school level and makes it impossible for
11
A similar situation prevailed a decade ago when
public schools obtained 92 percent of their total
12
funding (both salary and non-salary) from government At the beginning of the financial crisis in 1997, the
allocations. However, there was considerable MoNE reminded schools that the school admissions
variation among regions. In Jakarta, public schools fee had been abolished in government primary schools
depended on government resources for only 70 in 1984 and that BP3 payments were voluntary.
percent of their total budget, while in other parts of the School revenues decreased in real terms by as much as
country, public schools depended on the government one-third because of the drop in the real values of fees
for more than 90 percent of their budgets (James, and government subsidies as well as an increase in the
King, and Suryadi, 1996 and King, 1997). non-payment of fees.

24
Chapter 3 Finance and Public Spending

them to do any multi-year improvement Smart, 2002). For Indonesia, this means
planning. These problems are exacerbated requiring local governments to prepare both
by the fact that district governments and an adequate investment plan and an
schools receive funding from a number of adequate maintenance plan. Meanwhile, the
different sources, often too many for them to central government should provide
keep track of, all with different management technical assistance to help local
arrangements.13 Because of the fragmented governments to develop plans, arrange
nature of the funding allocations at the financing, and operate the local education
district level in Indonesia, it is almost system as efficiently as possible. Also,
impossible for the ultimate beneficiary (the financial accounting and reporting processes
school or the student) to know how much should become a standard part of the
funding they are supposed to receive and operating procedures at all levels of
whether the funds have been released. In government and in schools.
this situation, standards and information are
very important in increasing transparency At least as much managerial effort needs to
and compliance with policies, regulations, be spent on accounting and reporting
and laws and in reducing corruption at all processes as is spent on planning and
levels of the system. budgeting. It is already clear that a program
for building the financial management
The experience of countries around the capacity of local officials and school
world shows that better information and personnel is urgently needed. This capacity
greater disclosure are key to maximizing the building program also needs to focus on
effectiveness of decentralization (Bird and reporting responsibilities and techniques.

13
This is not a new phenomenon. It was noted in
World Bank’s report “Education in Indonesia: From
Crisis to Recovery” (World Bank, 1998) that essential
information on the budget is “scattered among five
different ministries,” making the management of the
education system a very difficult task.

25
Education Sector Review Volume 1

26
Chapter 4: Quality Assurance and Improvement

As already mentioned, there is a common Quality Assurance or Control


perception that the quality of schooling in
Indonesia is low and declining. In its final Quality assurance or control refers to
report in 2002, Indonesia’s National processes for guaranteeing that schools meet
Commission on Education expressed particular standards. It has three goals: (i)
concern that the education system does not equivalence – providing a basis for
provide Indonesia’s graduates with the skills comparing the credentials of teachers and
needed to compete successfully in a global school graduates through programs that
knowledge economy (MoNE, 2002a). It include pupil and teacher certification; (ii)
may help to begin this chapter by defining equity – meeting the basic right of even very
education quality, as the term can mean poor children to get a decent education
different things to different people. through programs that ensure districts are
Education quality is typically defined in providing minimum service standards for
terms of its instrumental value in increasing all; and (iii) groundwork – providing a level
student academic performance. In other of material and human infrastructure that is
words, quality is usually defined as that mix equal and high enough for schools and
of inputs, classroom practices, school communities to improve quality as defined
environment, and school organization that by both national and local expectations.
helps students to learn. This definition can
be broadened to include also those inputs Quality control is not new to Indonesia.
and practices that provide children with safe, Indeed, there is hardly any aspect of the
healthy, and pleasant places to learn education system that is not regulated, but
regardless of their impact on learning regulations and guidelines are often not
achievement. followed or implemented as intended for a
variety of reasons, including the
Two Approaches to Improving impracticality of the regulations, a lack of
Quality resources to implement the guidelines, a
lack of incentives to encourage compliance,
In Indonesia, there have been two and an absence of consequences for non-
conceptually related policy approaches compliance. The current national education
towards improving the quality of reform accompanying decentralization aims
education—quality assurance or control and to control quality by specifying standards
quality improvement. Both approaches rely and processes for certifying students,
on standards, measures, indicators of teachers, and schools (Box 4.1). Quality
performance, timely and accurate feedback assurance pertaining to individuals (students
from schools, and strategic implementation and teachers) is administered through
plans, but they use these to achieve different certification programs that are largely
ends. These approaches have been used by examination-based. The incentives for
government and by development agencies compliance with standards are clear, as are
that have supported programs in the sector. the consequences of failing; for example,
However, the absence of a coordinating senior secondary students who do not pass
policy framework to link these various the final national examination are not
efforts has prevented them from being as allowed to graduate, and candidate teachers
effective as they could be. who fail knowledge tests are not certified.

27
Education Sector Review Volume 1

The standardized examinations14 for that are still being discussed are the
competence of candidate teachers, though incentives for compliance, the consequences
far from ideal, are based on specified of non-compliance with minimum standards,
curricular or professional competencies. and the mechanisms for undertaking
performance or process audits of more than
Quality assurance as it pertains to individual 400 districts and 180,000 schools and
schools, or groups of schools as in a district, madrasahs. The development of past
is based on self-assessment against some programs related to quality standards has
normative and some self-determined tended to be ad hoc, which has sent

Box 4.1: Minimum Service Standards


Since 2002, there has been an attempt in Indonesia to reach agreement on a set of minimum service
standards. Despite a rocky start, a model-building group led by the MoHA produced a set of draft minimum
standards for the education sector in 2003. A detailed analysis of these draft education standards
undertaken as part of this review suggests that they have several crucial failings that must be addressed
before they can usefully be applied to the sector’s governance and management.
Numbers. There are nearly 200 standards, which is too many. This will lead to a loss of focus and will
increase, rather than decrease, the transaction costs of accountability.
Type. Most of the existing indicators are not true service standards oriented at improving the delivery of
education (for example, the maximum number of days it should take the school to provide a service to
parents) or at increasing mutual accountability between service units (for example, the maximum number of
weeks it should take the Dinas Pendidikan to supply a school with books).
Motivation. The motivation behind these draft standards is overwhelmingly bureaucratic rather than related
to the need for accountability. The standards also appear to have been structured to protect special or sub-
sectoral interests (for example, sports or teachers’ privileges rather than their rights and responsibilities)
rather than to improve the delivery of general and basic education.
Technical quality. Few of the indicators are measurable, at least as currently specified, either in theory or in
practice.
Level to be reached. For many of these indicators it makes little sense to specify an actual level to be
reached because the initial levels of those that can be measured vary tremendously and thus the rate of
change in levels might be a more sensible metric. Furthermore, those who are drafting these standards do
not appear to have seen the logic of allowing competition to determine the actual level to be reached. For
some key variables, the level should indeed be set centrally (albeit with some local input), but in other cases
there is no theoretical or practical justification for setting an absolute level.
Level at which measured. It would require a special effort to measure too many of the indicators; thus they
contain a built-in disincentive. Under the current system, there are few incentives for local education
managers to report even the most basic variables such as enrollment rates.
Source: See Volume 2, Chapter 1, Appendix 1.6 of this review.

standards rather than on external inspections conflicting messages to districts and schools
against absolute standards as in the past, but regarding minimum standards and
the processes involved are still in the procedures for quality assurance. At
planning phase. Some of the basic issues present, the directorate of the MoNE
responsible for basic education has 54
14 projects providing resources directly from
MoNE technical experts acknowledge that the the central government to schools,
student final examinations (Ujian Akhir
Nasional) are not yet adequately standardized in
weakening the ability of district
terms of test taking, although much progress has governments to fulfill their obligatory
been made in this direction. function to plan, finance, and manage

28
Chapter 4 Quality Assurance and Improvement

education and making it impossible for them them the most. The accreditation document
to monitor centrally funded projects.15 suggests that schools should apply for
accreditation after undertaking their own
In schools, the quality assurance system is in evaluation to determine if their inputs and
its early stages. According to our focus processes meet national requirements and
group discussions with school principals and their own expectations. If schools feel that
teachers in Lampung and Makassar, the they are viable, then they should request a
performance monitoring presently being visit from the local accreditation body.17
done in schools still concentrates largely on Accreditation must be renewed every four
financial matters. The principals and years. It is unclear, however, what will
teachers in the focus groups said that they happen to those schools that do not meet
had not yet discussed setting school minimum accreditation requirements over an
performance standards, and school extended period of time. It is anticipated
supervision and inspection documents that many schools, particularly the numerous
collected during the focus group exercise small private madrasahs that provide
show that the tools used by inspectors in educational services to many poor children,
Lampung and Makassar for supervising especially in remote areas, will fall far short
schools still emphasize administrative issues of the minimum accreditation standards
rather than professional development. (Box 4.2).18 The school accreditation policy
states that the national government will
As set forth in the Education Law and a support and help all non-accredited and low
ministerial decree (KepMen, 087/U/2002),16 ranking schools, but it is not clear from
the post-decentralization model emphasizes where the funding and technical support will
the need for standards. This is evident in the come.
school accreditation process that is currently
being developed and that will apply to all Quality Improvement
public, private, general, and madrasah
schools. Under this system, schools will be Quality improvement is a different approach
accredited as either “viable” or “not viable” that involves upgrading inputs, the learning
by a school accreditation body (SAB). environment, teaching practices, school
Viable schools will be ranked into three organization, and school performance. In
categories, with the lowest category Indonesia, these efforts have tended to be
including schools that meet some absolute limited to particular geographic areas and to
minimum standards. The aim of the system specific supply and/or demand-side
is to raise all schools within a district to the interventions. Past projects have provided
highest category of accreditation by schools with specific inputs (such as teacher
targeting resources to the schools that need training, infrastructure repair, or textbooks)
or have funded processes (such as active
learning methods or continuous assessment)
15
Chapter 2 in Volume 2 of this review contains an
appendix showing the plethora of standard-setting
initiatives that are currently underway. 17
Primary and junior secondary schools will apply to
16
Article 60 of the Education Law stipulates that the the district body for accreditation, while senior
accreditation of schools will be the responsibility of secondary schools will apply to the province.
the government and/or an independent body. The 18
In 2002, according to MoRA data, 5.7 million
KepMen 087/U/2002, which predated the law, children were enrolled in 37,362 madrasahs
established an independent accreditation body (BAS) (ibtidaiyah, tsanawiyah, and aliyah, which correspond
and listed nine school components to be evaluated to the primary, junior secondary, and senior secondary
during accreditation including: the curriculum and the levels of regular schools). Numerous community-
teaching/learning process; school administration and organized madrasah diniyahs also serve a large
management; school/institutional organization, number of children, but no reliable enrollment rates
equipment, and infrastructure; staffing; budgeting; are on record for this type of school. In addition,
teachers and students; community participation; and about 2.7 million children were enrolled in 11,312
the school environment and culture. pesantrens.

29
Education Sector Review Volume 1

Box 4.2: Improving the Quality of Madrasah Education


on the supply side, and social mobilization approaches are appropriate when a lack of
In 2002, according to SUSENAS data in 2002, fewer access
and school quality improvement grants on than 10is percent
the keyof problem in an
all children education
were enrolled in
the demand side. The assumption has been system, as was the case in Indonesia until
madrasahs, except at age 14 when madrasah enrollment exceeds 10 percent. Over the last five years, however,
that, if inputs
enrollment are improved,
in madrasahs has grownthen
fasterteaching theregular
than enrollment in mid-1980s, or when schools have
public schools.
and management processes and, ultimately, physical, material, or teaching conditions
school quality will improve. Supply-side
Enrollment that are and
Rate in Regular Schools below the minimum requirements.
Madrasahs

100
90
Percent of children 80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18
Age

Data source: SUSENAS, 2002

Average student test scores are lower in madrasahs than in regular public schools in 17 out of 26 provinces,
although their overall averages are not very different. Other evidence indicates that madrasahs lack adequate
school facilities, teaching and learning materials, and trained teachers. Those that are registered or accredited
are considered public madrasahs and receive some funding from the Ministry of Religious Affairs; however,
this funding is often not enough to meet their minimal operational and salary needs. Occasional public
subsidies are available also for private madrasahs (in the form of grants, teacher training, the provision of land
and teaching materials, and the secondment of government teachers), but these schools mostly rely on
community contributions and student fees.

Under the decentralization reform, the government is considering treating all schools (whether public, private,
or madrasah) exactly the same according to one policy under the governance of the MoNE at the central level
and of provincial and district governments at the local level. To integrate madrasahs into the regular school
system will mean not only reconciling the governance and funding structures of public and religious schools
but also addressing critical challenges related to quality. Thus, being integrated into the mainstream education
system will bring both benefits and costs to madrasahs. The benefits include the increased ability of madrasah
graduates to transfer to regular public schools and universities and to find employment. Also, they may receive
greater technical and budgetary support from district governments and communities than they now receive from
the national government. However, there is a risk that the opposite will happen – that madrasahs will receive
less support from district governments, partly because they will not be able to compete for resources against
regular public schools. They have to subject themselves to district oversight and of having to adopt the
district’s general curriculum, to hire qualified teachers, to use textbooks, and to build facilities such as
laboratories that are required by the curriculum. Madrasahs will face a double burden in that they must teach
the public school curriculum as well as a religious curriculum. The Islamic State Institutes (IAINs), which
currently produce the majority of the 450,000 graduates who become teachers in madrasahs, will need to be
integrated into the national teacher training system. Also, madrasahs may find it increasingly difficult to deny
admission to non-Muslim students.

Sources: Aziz (2002); Faiqoh (2002); Jalal (2000); Ministry of National Education/Office of Educational Research and
Development (2002).

30
Chapter 4 Quality Assurance and Improvement

Indonesia has experimented with quality Table 4.1: School Committees Still Not
improvement projects for over 30 years, but Fully Engaged
the many lessons from these projects have Percentage distribution by frequency of School
not been integrated into the way in which Committee meetings
teachers teach and principals manage Every week 0.5
Every two weeks 0.7
schools. This is partly because of low Every month 18.3
political willingness at the national level to Every six months 43.7
follow through on successful models and Every year 20.5
partly because there are not enough Only once in awhile 16.3
professionals in the government and in Data source: Bali Impact Crisis Survey, 2003
schools with the competence to implement
these good practices on a wide scale. 20/2003). School-based management (SBM)
is a form of decentralization in which the
Quality improvement projects have followed individual school is the primary unit of
two models – school effectiveness and improvement and the transfer of
school reform in Indonesia. School decisionmaking authority to the school is the
effectiveness models, which have been built primary means through which improvements
on a solid foundation of empirical studies in can be stimulated and sustained (Malen et al,
developed and developing countries, are 1990). Its purpose is to engage people from
about the mix of inputs that define “the the schools’ local communities in planning,
school climate” and about the “enabling monitoring, and improving school quality by
conditions” and “teaching/ learning process” serving on school committees (Article 56
that most effectively produce cognitive Law 20/2003).20
achievement. In Indonesia, these programs
were largely expert-driven and developed at Our findings indicate that school committees
the central level. Very few projects became are in place in Indonesia but are not yet
nationwide programs, and innovations rarely operating as instigators of quality
spread on their own from school to school.19 improvement. For example, a survey of 425
schools in Bali in 2003 revealed that 97
In contrast to school effectiveness models, percent of schools had a school committee,
school reform models are inherently mostly consisting of teachers, parents, and
grounded in management theory, honorary members who might include the
particularly management for change. These bupati. In more than 80 percent of these
models emphasize relationships among schools, however, the committees met at
stakeholders and recommend making most once every six months and played only
decisions based on negotiation, standard a peripheral role in the schools’
measures, comparative and publicly decisionmaking processes (Table 4.1).
available information, and accountability to Similarly, we found in our focus group
achieve school development goals. Under discussions with teachers and principals in
decentralization, this is the key policy that Lampung and Makasar and our meetings
the Indonesian government has adopted for with school committees in Central Java and
improving school quality (Article 51 Law Yogyakarta that there is confusion about the
role of these committees and a high level of
19
skepticism about what they can achieve.
Two exceptions include the active Many principals had not yet discussed
learning/contextual learning projects (CBSA-SPP) that
established communication channels and innovative performance standards or improvement
teaching approaches through local teacher groups and
the new competency-based curriculum. The National
20
Curriculum Center reports that numerous teachers The model has been tested at the junior secondary
from Jakarta’s private schools have requested level (in the BOMM and JSE projects, for example)
materials and have obtained guidance from the and is a component of several large projects (such as
Center’s website. the DBEP, SIGP, and BEP).

31
Education Sector Review Volume 1

planning with school committees, and there information collection and processing
were not enough public funds to sustain the systems; and (vi) circulate information on
committees. This situation has created a good practices to schools to spread effective
financial burden for parents that has led to ideas for school quality improvement as
mistrust between schools and communities. widely as possible.
Nevertheless, the focus group participants
reported that decentralization has Many districts are responding with
empowered teacher and principals and given enthusiasm and initiative to their new
them more confidence in their ability to responsibilities. Having these
manage the teaching/learning process. responsibilities is giving them a much
greater incentive to assess the education
These mixed reviews were further provided within their boundaries. Because
confirmed by a 2003 survey of 36 schools in of the magnitude of the changes involved,
five districts undertaken by the Managing however, the situation at the local level may
Basic Education Project. The survey found be chaotic for a while as institutions redefine
that school committees have been their roles and relationships, debate how
constituted and that they meet two or three best to allocate and manage resources, and
times a year to discuss problems regarding learn to become more democratic and
facilities and fundraising, but the teachers accountable to civil society. In addition,
felt that the committees were not active many districts lack the experience and
enough. knowledge to develop multi-year,
information-based plans that address issues
Policies to Improve the Quality of such as low completion rates, poor learning
Education achievement, and rigid teaching methods.
Inadequate information and obsolete
We recommend the following policies: management information systems also limit
the extent to which districts can plan for the
Support National Programs, District future effectively. In sum, significant
Projects, and School Improvements investment and time will be required before
districts will be able to develop and
As districts and schools begin implementing implement information-based strategies for
both quality assurance and quality educational development.
improvement measures, the role of the
central government needs to be redefined. Everything that is measured, monitored, and
Instead of undertaking new project-based evaluated is aimed in the end at improving
initiatives, the MoNE should: (i) phase out the performance and practices of schools.
any of their policies that inhibit schools Hence, the bulk of investment in the new
from managing their own plans; (ii) crack decentralized education system must be at
down on entrenched behavior like patronage the school level. Likewise, these
and petty corruption that prevents the investments must be planned, managed, and
effective use of resources in the system; (iii) monitored at the school level. Whether they
phase in programs that set standards and are meant to rehabilitate crumbling school
rules but not targets for quality management; buildings or to revise teaching practices, if
(iv) adopt policies that foster quality they do not happen in and for the schools,
improvements, for example, by introducing they simply will not yield the required
regulated market-based incentives to results – better education quality and higher
encourage districts and schools to improve student academic achievement.
their performance; (v) develop the central
government’s capacity to provide needed
services to districts, such as better teacher
training, student assessment mechanisms,

32
Chapter 4 Quality Assurance and Improvement

Adapt a Balanced Scorecard Approach to for textbook approval are germane to


Plan and Manage Support to Districts and this component.
Schools
x Stakeholder satisfaction: This
The balanced scorecard approach is a component includes student
concept that can help education managers to achievement, parent satisfaction, the
plan and monitor performance measures accomplishment of district and national
across multiple elements or components and goals and targets, and the relevance of
to respond appropriately to those results. 21 schooling to the enterprise sector. All
If this approach is adopted by districts and standards, indicators, and targets for
schools, it will streamline the hundreds of student academic achievement, as well
standards and indicators that are currently as targets for district enrollment,
being proposed, into a manageable number transition, and completion rates are
of bell-weather indicators. Specifically, the relevant to this component.
scorecard can have one to four components
that capture the key priorities of the x Governance and management: This
education system and the measures of component includes processes for
performance corresponding to each priority. making policies, regulations, or rules,
Four potential components of the scorecard transparency in decisionmaking,
are : accountability for decisions, and
community participation. Progress in
x Finance: This component includes implementing school-based
human, material, and financial resources management, whether schools and
provided to schools (and districts), and districts comply with governance
the flow of provisions or funds from the procedures, transparency in teacher
point of origin to districts or schools. posting and professional development,
Current MoNE work on minimum per- and other school performance standards
pupil expenditures, formulas for district pertain to this component.
to school transfers, performance-based
accounting procedures, procurement For each of the four components, districts or
protocols, and accountability schools can be positioned along a continuum
requirements through public disclosure of key indicators. This is the basic concept
can be included in this component. behind school accreditation and district
monitoring, but we propose adding a second
x Minimum conditions of learning: This dimension to capture the progress that each
component includes safe and healthy school or district makes in implementing its
school buildings, equipped classrooms, own multi-year quality improvement plan.
and certified and trained teachers. The Taken together, the two dimensions give
MoNE’s work on accreditation four categories of districts or schools: good
standards, teacher certification getting better, good getting worse, bad
standards, teacher licensing, and criteria getting better, and bad getting worse (Figure
4.1). Different interventions can then be
determined for each category of district or
21
school, thus shifting the entire education
An article by Robert Kaplan and David Norton
entitled “The Balanced Scorecard - Measures that
system away from a supply- driven, one-
Drive Performance” in the Harvard Business Review size-fits-all model. This adaptation of the
in 1992 sparked interest in the method, and led to their balanced scorecard approach recognizes that
business bestseller, “The Balanced Scorecard: performance is dynamic and that districts
Translating Strategy into Action,” published in 1996. and schools can get worse as well as better.
Since that time, many businesses, school districts, and
schools in the United States, Australia, and England
have adopted the method for quality management.

33
Education Sector Review Volume 1

Figure 4. 1: Balanced Scorecard to Determine Appropriate Action for Each District or


School
Better than last performance evaluation

B AD SCH OO L S /DISTR IC TS G ETTIN G G O OD


SC HO O LS / DISTRIC TS
B ETTER GETTING BE TTE R

x Look for innovation and best x Block grant financing


practices x Most resourcing through funds
x Eligible for increased funding (rather than materials or in-kind
through block grants services)
x Recognize achievement in public x Eligible for special grants to
forums become “service providers”

Below Standard Above Standard

Min im um Service Standard

B AD SCH OO LS /DISTR IC TS G E TTIN G G O ODSC HO O LS / DISTRIC TS


W OR SE GE TTING W ORSE

x Close attention from higher x Very common in newly decentralized


authority systems
x Earmarked funds x Examine regulatory framework to
x Intensive capacity building remove policies that may be inhibing
x At risk of losing accreditation performance (e.g. financing formula)
x Site visit to d etermine cause for
performance d rop and collaborate on
remediation

Worse than last performance evaluation

Address Structural Weaknesses of the providers of affordable and effective quality


System improvement services for schools (such as
competent financial advisors, teacher
Schools are no longer directly accountable
trainers, program planners, and information
to the MoNE, but the MoNE is still
systems specialists) outside the big cities.
accountable for the performance of the
At present, the central government has a
education system as a whole. Thus, the
near monopoly on teacher training and the
national level needs to change its focus
development of education materials like
away from specific interventions towards
textbooks, and there are not enough
programs that address underlying structural
competent government and university-based
weaknesses such as the vastly uneven
trainers to meet the growing demand for
capacity of districts,22 the fact that there is
such services under decentralization. The
no incentive for improving school
central government can encourage the
performance, and the fact that there are few
development of these service providers by
22
instituting a program of competitive grants
Capacity in this context includes the district that would stimulate a larger supply of
governments’ policies, infrastructure, trainers.
organization, and bureaucratic procedures, as
well as the skills and knowledge of their staff.

34
Chapter 4 Quality Assurance and Improvement

Ensure Equity in Quality Improvement the low attendance rate of children at junior
secondary schools is generally attributed to a
Indonesia has an admirable record of lack of schools of this level, the perceived
adopting pro-poor policies, particularly lack of relevance of secondary education,
during the economic crisis of the late 1990s, and economic hardship. However, another
but these gains could be lost unless a pro- possibility is that these schools are not
poor agenda is built into the national quality providing instructional programs that are
assurance and improvement program. For sufficiently challenging and
example, if poor communities are to be developmentally appropriate for 13- to 15-
expected to share the costs of repairing year-old students.
schools, then there may be a drop in demand
for education among the very poor. Also, if From Setting Standards to Meeting
district minimum service standards are not Standards
pro-poor, then they might have the
unintended effect of pushing poor children Once the standards for minimum service,
out of the system unless the worst accreditation, and certification are set, how
performing schools are improved, they are will they be implemented and what are the
merged with stronger schools or closed, or incentives for implementation? Local
their students are subsidized so they can education officials are now accountable for
afford to enroll in better schools. their performance to two higher authorities –
the local legislature or executive and the
Stimulate Demand for and Supply of central MoNE. It is still unclear what
Innovations and Good Practice for responsibilities the central government has
Improving Teaching towards those districts that fail to meet
minimum standards over a period of time. If
While projects have helped specific districts there are no incentives for compliance or
and schools to improve their management consequences for non-compliance, then the
and teaching practices, there is as yet no standards will not help to assure quality.
systematic way to disseminate successful The critical unresolved issue of what to do
ideas for improving teaching and learning about non-compliant schools is a
practices available across the whole governance issue that should not be left up
education system. Therefore, to encourage to the school accreditation body. Whether
the development of ideas for improving the or not to revoke a non-accredited school’s
quality of teaching and learning, the central right to enroll fee-paying students should be
government should set up a national grant- decided by a policymaking level of
making institution for educational government rather than by an independent
development to provide competitive grants body. Similarly, any decision to provide
to schools or clusters of schools who come targeted resources to unaccredited and low-
up with innovative proposals. This agency performing schools should be backed up by
should also encourage schools to implement a national commitment to provide districts
approaches that have already been proven to with these resources.
improve teaching practices. For example,

35
Education Sector Review Volume 1

36
Chapter 5: Teacher Management and Performance

The level of school performance and student individual schools. At the moment, there
achievement is the result of several factors are several projects in effect that are taking
but perhaps the single most influential factor various demand-driven approaches to
is the quality and performance of the teachers’ in-service training, but no
teaching force. When schools perform well, systematic evaluation has been done of their
it is due to a combination of effective impact on student learning and teacher
teachers and strong leadership by the school performance.
principals. The education and experience of
teachers are all important factors in Management Changes under
improving student performance, but Decentralization
teachers’ freedom to choose their own
methods and books and how much time they When teacher management systems are
spend on tasks such as preparing lessons and changing, this can be a good opportunity to
marking students’ work are also vital implement new ways to achieve education
factors.23 goals. However, during the period of
transition, there can be tensions and
As discussed in the previous chapter, opportunistic behavior at the school and
minimum service standards and district levels in the employment,
accreditation criteria for schools and deployment, and promotion of teachers. The
teachers are currently being developed. implementation of the school-based
However, it is not yet clear how the management approach and the creation of
information from the accreditation and district education boards are changing the
quality assurance processes will be used to nature of teachers’ accountability and their
assist schools and teachers to improve their incentives to perform well. These changes
performance. Nor is it clear where the mean that decisions about a school’s
technical capacities would come from to resources and goals are made by those who
help schools and teachers. The centralized are in the best position to understand the
top-down approach to in-service training is circumstances that prevail at that school,
no longer appropriate as it is supply-driven which is highly desirable. However, they
and is divorced from the goals and needs of also put a heavier burden on teachers, school
principals, school committees, and parents
23
What do we know about teachers in other countries? to work together to improve students’
Researchers in the U.S. have found that teachers’ achievement levels.
higher cognitive skills, as demonstrated in
standardized tests, are associated with better student
outcomes (Strauss and Sawyer, 1986). Recent Responsibility for Teacher Employment
research has also found that on-the-job teacher and Deployment
training is associated with improved student
performance (Angrist and Lavy, 2001). Rewarding At the time of decentralization, large
teachers for what they actually know and do in the
classroom is likely to have a considerable positive numbers of civil servants formerly
impact on student performance (Odden, 2000), but employed by central government agencies
measuring and evaluating what teachers know and do were relocated to district governments along
in the classroom is expensive and far from with budget allocations to cover their
straightforward. Finally, an analysis of junior
secondary school data from the Third International
salaries. The district government became
Mathematics and Science Study (TIMSS) (Woessman, responsible for employing all teachers in
2001) showed how institutional characteristics as well public schools except those in madrasahs.
as teacher characteristics contribute to students’ These include all civil service teachers
academic performance.

37
Education Sector Review Volume 1

(pegawai negeri) in public and private were to rationalize their teacher/student


schools (mostly secondary schools), as well ratios or to adjust to lower enrollment due to
as honorary teachers (guru honor) who were a declining school-age population, or to fire
previously hired and paid for by the central non-performers. Currently, many teachers
government. Also, some districts are feel that they cannot apply for vacancies in a
participating in projects that include contract different district. But whether this is true in
teachers (guru kontrak) paid for by donor the sense that districts may be constrained
loans to the central government. The status by ceilings on civil service budgetary
of the latter group will be reviewed when resources or whether they hold this opinion
these projects close, although attempts to in ignorance of the government’s actual
reach agreement with district governments policy on transfers between districts is not
on exit strategies have been pre-empted by clear.
the central government’s decision to recruit
an additional 190,000 contract teachers, Responsibility for Setting and Monitoring
which it is no longer supposed to do. Teacher Performance Standards

Although district governments are As already discussed, the MoHA has been
responsible for hiring teachers and paying developing minimum service standards,
their salaries, several ambiguities persist. especially as they apply to districts’
For example, those madrasah teachers who obligatory functions, while the MoNE has
are civil servants are still managed by the been developing performance standards that
MoRA, not by districts. Districts, through will affect teachers. The Directorate of
the MoHA, have always been responsible Higher Education has developed standards
for deploying teachers, but with the that must be met by teachers graduating
establishment of school committees, districts from the DII teacher education program (a
might take on a greater role in selecting and two-year post-secondary school teaching
appointing teachers. Three districts in diploma needed to teach in primary schools)
Flores, with the support of AusAID, are and is expecting to extend this exercise for
piloting just such community participation other initial teacher preparation programs
in determining the selection criteria for under its accreditation control (such as the
teachers and head teachers and in the DIII, which is a three-year diploma required
selection process itself. However, district to teach in junior secondary schools, and S1,
governments are bound by a centrally a four-year university degree). These
determined ceiling on the number of standards apply to teacher education
additional civil servants they can recruit (for programs and define in some detail what a
any and all sectors). Hence, if a district graduate teacher should know and be able to
government wishes to hire additional do. Complementary to this, the Directorate
teachers above this ceiling, the district must of Education Personnel is preparing teacher
pay for them from its non-salary resources. competency standards to be used in
assessing teacher performance and
The salary levels and promotional and identifying their professional development
reward systems for civil servants are still set needs. It is expected that these competency
centrally, although many districts provide standards will be used by quality assurance
teachers within their jurisdiction with teams in the provinces acting on behalf of
supplementary benefits and incentives. the MoNE.
While the districts have the option to
dismiss contract and honorary teachers or Besides standards regarding qualification
not to renew their contracts, it is still not and competency, monitoring is also essential
clear whether or not a district government with respect to teacher behavior in school.
can retrench or dismiss civil service Teacher absenteeism is one of the reasons
teachers, as they might want to do if they why students do not learn. A multi-country

38
Chapter 5 Teacher Management and Performance

survey of teacher absences in primary Responsibility for Teachers’ Professional


schools found that Indonesian teachers were Development and Career Development
more likely to be absent from the classroom
than five of the eight countries surveyed Initial teacher preparation programs for
(Table 5.1).24 upgrading teachers’ qualifications remain
the function of universities and teacher
training institutes that are accredited by the
Table 5.1 Primary teacher absence rate
Directorate of Higher Education. There is
in public schools, 2002-03
an ongoing discussion of how to make both
Peru 11 the universities and the associated
Ecuador 14 accrediting board more autonomous and
how to make the process of accreditation
Papua New Guinea 15
more competitive so that teacher education
Bangladesh 16 programs will become more responsive to
Zambia 17 the needs of schools around the country.
Indonesia 19
Who has the responsibility for the
continuing professional development needs
India 25 of teachers is more ambiguous. Most school
Uganda 27 and cluster-based professional development
Source: Chaudhury et al. (2004) activities have been supported in the past by
projects funded by aid agencies or the
The role of these quality assurance teams is MoNE. Now districts are responsible for
still being developed and, as yet, no clear providing in-service training and
guidelines have been developed for district professional support activities, but few have
monitoring activities but it is likely that the resources to do so. Provincial teacher
these will be based on criteria related to the training centers (Balai Pelatihan Guru and
obligatory functions and minimum service Pusat Peninkatan dan Pelatihan Guru) are
standards that are also being developed. deconcentrated branches of the MoNE and
as such are expected to provide both quality
assurance and in-service teacher education
support to districts.

24
Primary teacher absence rate is the percentage of The ways in which the lifelong education of
full-time teachers who were absent from a random teachers relate to teachers’ career,
sample of primary schools during surprise visits. promotion, and incentive structures have not
Enumerators made two to three rounds of been clearly articulated. Districts now are
unannounced visits to each school over a period of taking the initiative to link teacher
weeks or months, to get a more accurate estimate of development programs directly to teachers’
absence and, after verifying workers' schedules, classroom behavior as a way of improving
recorded which of them were absent. The data school quality and are putting a high priority
provide the number of teachers who were supposed to on providing teachers with adequate skills.
be on duty but were in fact absent from the school, Indeed some school committees have been
without regard to the reasons for absence. Many using resources to allow teachers to attend
personnel were absent for valid reasons, such as in-service or other professional development
authorized leave or official duties. Nevertheless, these programs.
absence rates are useful for two reasons: first, because
the reasons for absence given by facility directors
Teacher Employment and
were typically not verifiable; and second, because
even authorized absences reduce the quantity and
Deployment
quality of public services in these primary schools.
The study covered 147 public and private schools in In 2000, there were over 2 million teachers
10 districts in Indonesia (Chaudhury et al., 2004). serving the entire school system in

39
Education Sector Review Volume 1

Indonesia, with 1.3 million in primary teaching load, regardless of the size of the
schools and 600,000 in junior secondary school where they are employed. Even
schools. It was a relatively young teaching when the teacher/student ratio is calculated
force, the majority of teachers (64 percent) using class teachers only, the national ratio
being under 40 years old. More than half is 1:32, which is comparable with other
were employed in primary schools, and of countries in the region.25 At the junior
these, 93.4 percent were civil servants. In secondary school level, the teacher/student
comparison, only 62 percent of teachers in ratios are 1:16 in public schools and 1:10 in
junior secondary schools were civil servants. madrasah schools. At present, teachers at
The large number of teachers who are civil this level expect to teach only one subject,
servants means that districts have a large and regardless of a school’s enrollment,
wage bill inherited from the centralized era each school expects to have at least 18
when teacher-to-school allocation norms teachers.
were extremely, if not extravagantly,
defined. To rationalize teacher salaries and teacher/
student ratios, several districts have been
However, Indonesia’s birth rate is falling, its merging several small schools into one and
primary enrollment rates already high, and redeploying school principals and teachers
the supply of teachers at the primary level to understaffed schools and are discussing
plentiful, so the country is in a position to the relative merits of civil service teachers
reduce the size of the teaching force at the and contract teachers.26 In cases where
district level. This would allow districts to schools have been merged and the number
spend more of their resources on quality of school principal posts have decreased,
inputs and to shift resources to the salaries there is the danger that tensions will arise
of additional teachers at the secondary level. between those who lose out and those who
This does not mean that there are no teacher retain their jobs. As with primary schools,
shortages, but the shortages in the primary many small junior secondary schools could
sector are primarily problems of distribution also be amalgamated to form more efficient
rather than supply. units, and many districts are now doing so.
This implies that junior secondary school
For many districts, the most difficult teachers will need to be able to teach more
questions about increasing access and than one subject, which has implications for
efficiency at the primary and secondary teacher training and teacher development
levels are about changing teacher/student programs. Some small junior secondary
ratios (particularly at the primary school schools are already aiming to recruit
level) and recruiting secondary school teachers who have majors in at least two
teachers who are qualified to teach more teaching subjects.
than one subject. Nationally,
teacher/student ratios are generous at all We recommend that districts develop their
levels, but there are wide differences among own formula for calculating teacher
districts. At the primary level, based on the requirements that takes into account the
total number of teachers including head number of students enrolled in a school
teachers, religion teachers, sports teachers, rather than the number of classes. One
and class teachers, the national teacher/
student ratio is 1:22 in public primary 25
By comparison, the teacher-student ratio is 1:18 in
schools and 1:14 in religious primary
Malaysia, 1:35 in the Philippines, 1:20 in China, and
schools. Only 68 percent of teachers are 1:32 in Korea in 2000 or thereabout (World Bank,
class teachers; of the remainder, 13 percent 2004).
26
are religion teachers and 6 percent are sports These discussions are based on the pilot activities of
teachers. Head teachers, religion teachers, the District Basic Education Project, and the Unit
Fasilitasi, the MoNE, and Basic Education Project
and sports teachers rarely have a full reports.

40
Chapter 5 Teacher Management and Performance

proposal put forward in the past in Indonesia schools. The minimum qualification for
laid out a sliding scale of teacher primary teachers was set in 1989 as a two-
deployment based on school enrollment year post-secondary school teaching
(Somerset, 1997). This scale takes into diploma (DII). Yet in 2002, only one-half of
account the needs of children in lower all primary school teachers in Indonesia held
primary school classes (highly dependent this certificate or a higher qualification. The
learners) that should have fewer students per minimum qualification for teaching in junior
teacher and in upper primary classes (more secondary schools is a three-year diploma
independent learners) that should have more (DIII). By 2002, 67 percent of junior
students per teacher. Small schools where secondary school teachers held this or a
multi-grade teaching is the norm often have higher qualification, while the remaining
fewer students per teacher. To implement one-third had only a two-year diploma (DII).
this sliding scale of teacher allocation, For many teachers, the opportunity to
district planners will need timely and upgrade to the 1989 standard came through
accurate information on the number of participating in Open University part-time
teachers and enrollment rates in each of their distance education programs. However,
schools. Also, the central government will there is very little school-based content and
need complete information on districts’ practice in either the formal full-time
needs as well and on how many students programs or the part-time programs, and
graduates each year from universities and what does exist is poorly executed.27
other institutions in order to broker the
deployment process efficiently. The distribution of those teachers with only
the minimum qualification is uneven across
The MoNE can assist this process by districts and provinces (Figure 5.1). Because
ensuring that adequate information about the many districts operate small school systems
supply and demand for teachers is available and because the pool of qualified teachers is
to local governments, schools, and teachers likely to come from the province as a whole,
themselves. A pilot scheme for identifying these disparities in the distribution of
those schools with too many and too few qualified teachers will need to be addressed
teachers as a guide for deploying contract at the provincial level. Provinces need to
teachers is being implemented as part of the find ways to fund and develop programs for
Basic Education Project. Hopefully, lessons upgrading teacher qualifications that are
from this pilot scheme can be used to inform
efforts to deploy regular teachers as well. A Figure 5.1: Districts Vary in Proportion of Primary
teacher deployment scheme in the Teachers with Minimum Training Qualification,
Philippines also provides valuable Percentage of teachers
experience about how to deploy new
teachers (Box 5.1). Sum atra
Sulaw esi
Teacher Professional Development Papua & Eastern Is
Kalim antan
Java
In the past, teacher quality has been
measured mainly by the level of certification 0 20 40 60 80
rather than performance and classroom
results. This is now changing, as can be seen Notes: The island categories pertain to all provinces in those islands.
Data Source: Ministry of National Education,.
in the efforts of different directorates in the
MoNE to prepare standards for new
graduates from teacher training courses,
27
technical competencies that serving teachers A similar situation prevails in Nigeria where
should meet, and minimum service research has shown that little value is added to a
teacher’s performance if he or she acquires a higher
standards and accreditation criteria for qualification through full-time or part-time study.

41
Education Sector Review Volume 1

Box 5.1: A New Teacher Deployment Scheme in the Philippines

The Philippines is conducting a pilot program to improve its system for deploying new teachers. Using
student-teacher ratios as the principal indicator, disparities in teacher provision at the regional,
provincial and school level were analyzed and the results were displayed in table form, and also through
GIS mapping. A color-coding scheme to identify areas with relatively generous teacher provision and
areas with teacher shortages of varying severity and estimates of a statistical measure of equity in
access to teachers were employed. It was found that while the national distribution of teachers among
regions (clusters of provinces) is fairly equitable, the distribution among provinces within a region and
the distribution within provinces themselves were much less equitable. In fact, there were high-
shortage schools even in provinces that, in aggregate, were relatively well supplied with teachers.
Older schools, especially those in areas of stable or declining population, tend to be generously staffed,
sometimes showing substantial teacher surpluses, while newer schools, many in poor areas, had
deficits.

This scheme was applied in 2002/3 to the deployment process of new teachers that takes place every
two years. In preparation, provincial teams were required to provide teacher-availability data for all
schools under their jurisdiction. These teams attended two-day workshops, conducted by the
Department of Education staff, to acquaint them with a new-teacher deployment request form and to
train them in using computer software designed to prepare data tables and teacher-deployment maps.
All schools complied with requests to provide the necessary data. The color-coded provincial maps
became the basis for all deployment negotiations among provinces, at the level of principals and with
parliamentary representatives who had a say in how education resources are allocated among schools.

As a result of the new system, of a total of 25,000 new teaching positions, 77 percent of elementary
school teachers and 71 percent of secondary school teachers were allocated to the teacher-shortage
areas. There were still wide variations, however. At the elementary level, one region achieved a
targeting proportion of 97 percent, while two others achieved only 31 percent and 54 percent. At the
secondary level, the range was equally wide: between 96 percent in the most effective region and less
than 50 percent in three less-effective regions. Further steps are to be implemented. In particular, it will
be essential to conduct further training to ensure that at all levels of government and the schools, there
is a critical mass of professional and administrative staff who understand the deployment system, know
how to apply it, and feel committed to its maintenance.

qualitatively better than those that currently competency standards for teachers and ways
exist and that are compatible with the to measure their performance against these
principles of school-based management. standards. However, in line with the new
There have been a large number of teacher school-based management model, teachers’
training projects in Indonesia over the past professional development needs to be linked
30 years (Sweeting, 2001). These projects much more closely to the context of the
have had various objectives including to actual classrooms in which they work and to
revise the curriculum in pre-service the monitoring of school performance and
education programs, upgrade the technical standards. Teachers need to be given
capacities of teacher educators and teacher opportunities to continue learning for their
education institutions, and develop in- own self-development, to gain their license
service training and professional support to teach (assuming that such a system is put
systems. While there is considerable in place) or improve their performance, to
experience to build on, it is time to consider enable them to become mentors in induction
a new paradigm that takes school programs, and to enable them to be
performance as the focal point of the career- promoted to posts of responsibility in
long professional development of teachers. schools and/or training programs. This
Indonesia has begun to develop a set of assumes that appropriate reward systems are

42
Chapter 5 Teacher Management and Performance

Box 5.2: Mexico’s Carrera Magisterial Program

Mexico’s decade-old teacher incentive program, Carrera Magisterial, is a teacher compensation reform
program first implemented in 1994. Teachers who voluntarily join the program agree to participate in
annual performance evaluations and to have their annual salary increases linked to the results of these
evaluations. These performance evaluations, totaling 100 points, consist of: the performance peer
review (10 points), teacher subject matter knowledge as measured by the teacher’s test score (28
points); student examination scores (20 points); teachers’ educational attainment (10 points); their
completion of accredited courses to update their skills (17 points); and years of teaching experience (15
points). The wage bonus associated with the program consists of a percentage of the base wage and can
be quite substantial.

Although the program is voluntary, the number of teachers who have joined the program has increased
substantially since 1994—from 39 percent of teachers in its first year, to 49 percent after three years.
As a result, the proportion of students whose teachers are enrolled in the program more than doubled in
the period between 1994 and 1996 and is now around 25 percent of all students. In addition, in 1997
the percentage of all teaching positions that were filled by an individual participating in the program
was close to 50 percent. Of these, 22 percent have received promotions.

The Carrera Magisterial program appears to be having a significant impact on the Mexican education
system as a recent study found that those students whose teachers participate in the program have
higher average test scores than students whose teachers are not in the program.

Source: Lopez-Acevedo, 2001.

in place that recognize teachers’ Teacher Compensation and Incentives


contributions to school performance. It also
assumes that there are institutions available Designing teacher salaries and incentive
to provide such school-based evaluation structures that attract and retain the best and
programs. An example of such a program in the brightest candidates to the teaching
Mexico indicates its potential benefits (Box profession is a complex enterprise. In
5.2). Indonesia, low salaries are often seen as the
main reason why teachers perform poorly,
However, how these teacher development have low morale, and tend to be poorly
programs are to be financed is an important qualified. However, studies have found that
planning problem. Certainly most districts most primary school teachers and junior
probably feel that their current education secondary school teachers have monthly
budgets barely cover their salary earnings equivalent to or higher than those
expenditures and are concerned that teachers of other workers with an equivalent level of
they train may be move to other districts. education.28 Although teachers’ salaries in
For these reasons, districts should not have
to fund teacher development fully. A
mixture of teachers’ own contributions 28
An analysis of labor force data from 2000 (Filmer,
(since they are the key beneficiaries) and of 2002) indicated that teachers with qualifications below
proposal-based grants given by the central the diploma level (about one-third of teachers) have
monthly earnings that are, on average, 22 percent
government to schools and districts to fund higher than the monthly earnings of other paid
specific initiatives to improve teacher and workers with the same qualifications. The differential
school performance is more appropriate. (in terms of monthly salary) is smaller among those
Resources for these grants need to be built with a first or second level diploma (DI/DII) and then
into education expenditure allocations at the becomes negative. In other words, while less qualified
teachers seem to be overpaid relative to others with
district level. the same qualifications, the 10 percent of teachers
with a third-level diploma (DIII) and the 24 percent
with a university degree are underpaid, earning 18 and

43
Education Sector Review Volume 1

Indonesia may be lower than those in other to work, the DAU allocations to districts
countries at a similar level of economic must be disproportionately targeted to
development (such as Chile, the Philippines, poorer districts so they can afford to add
and Thailand), this is partially offset by the sufficient incentives to the basic salaries to
fact that teachers in Indonesia work fewer ensure that teachers will have an incentive to
hours and have smaller classes on average apply for jobs in those districts, even for
(OECD, 2001). MoNE studies of how much vacancies in remote schools. Districts
time teachers spend on instructional tasks should be responsible for determining
indicate that teachers spend only about half appropriate allowances and top-ups for
their time in school actually teaching, teachers working in remote locations or
perhaps because they are not aware of the under difficult conditions. This should not
number of hours of instruction and school be done centrally because if it were, then all
days in a year they are obligated to work. schools would try to be classified as
On a per hour basis, teachers earn more than “difficult” so that their teachers would be
most other workers and have many more paid more. An approach like this has been
days off per year. Indeed, during the 2003 tried in Brazil (Box 5.3).
national recruitment of contract teachers,
there were two applicants per vacancy, In most cases, it would be better to offer
indicating that current salaries do not appear bonuses to supplement teachers’
to be a major deterrent to aspiring teachers. remuneration instead of altering their basic
However, the situation is not the same for all pay scales to reward teachers who take on
teachers, so a review of the entire salary extra responsibilities or duties, to attract
scale is warranted. In particular, teachers better candidates to the teaching profession,
with a university degree (that is, mostly and/or to attract teachers to rural locations
those who teach senior secondary students) where there is a scarcity of applications for
earn slightly less than other workers with an vacant teaching posts.
equivalent level of education.
Using Teacher Management Systems
Under decentralization, it is important to to Achieve Education Goals
ensure mobility in the teacher labor market,
even while decentralizing the employment Decentralization in itself does not
of teachers to, for example, the school level. automatically improve the performance of
The best way to set up teachers’ salary schools and teachers, but effective teacher
scales may be to have a national (or management systems can help to do so.
provincial) pay scale or salary grading Over the longer term, several actions are
system that is based on minimum pay levels needed: (i) to devise strategies to strengthen
agreed between the central government and the professional life of teachers (ii) to
teachers’ unions and professional develop transparent mechanisms for schools
associations but to allow districts and to select their own teachers; (iii) to link
schools to offer supplemental benefits and school performance and teacher
allowances to teachers according to their performance reviews to teachers’ career
own criteria.29 For this topping-up process development and promotion; and (iv) to
37 percent less respectively than other paid workers
with the same levels of education. facilities and materials, longer school days, better
29
After determining the base salary level, a study in management practices, and more skilled teachers, but
India (Kingdon, 1996) suggested that salary structures that investing in smaller pupil-teacher ratios (in urban
for teachers were inefficient, with teacher areas where there is no multi-grade teaching), and
characteristics that improve student learning hardly investing in teacher experience, training, post-graduate
being rewarded while other teacher attributes that have education, and higher across-the-board teachers’
few discernible learning benefits for the students had a salaries may not yield enough benefits to be justifiable
significant salary pay-offs. This suggests that it would in a resource-scarce environment.
enhance school efficiency to spend funds on school

44
Chapter 5 Teacher Management and Performance

Box 5.3: Brazil’s FUNDEF Program and Teacher Compensation Reform

In 1998, Brazil implemented an education finance reform called the Fund for the Maintenance and
Development of Primary Education and Teacher Enhancement (FUNDEF). The main objective of this
fund was to equalize educational opportunities across states and municipalities by guaranteeing a
minimum expenditure per pupil in primary schools throughout the country. Embedded in the reform
was a requirement that at least 60 percent of the additional funds provided by FUNDEF to local
governments must be spent on teachers’ salaries.

The program was expected to improve teacher quality and student outcomes in several ways. First, it
would increase the salaries of existing teachers in regions that, previous to the reform, had had
relatively low teachers’ salaries. This would make teaching a more attractive profession, particularly in
these regions. As a result, it would increase the number of individuals interested in entering teaching
and make teaching an attractive career to more highly skilled individuals, who prior to the reform
would have been likely to choose to enter other professions. Second, local governments could use the
increase in resources for teacher salaries not only to increase the salaries of existing teachers but also to
hire additional teachers, thus enabling them to reduce class sizes, which would probably also improve
student outcomes.

An assessment of the reform in 2002 revealed that regional disparities in teacher pay had been reduced
and that the number of teachers who had at least graduated from secondary school had increased. The
study also showed that the increase in teachers’ compensation and in the number of teachers with at
least a secondary education were positively associated with better student outcomes such as lower
dropout rates and higher pass rates.

Source: World Bank, 2002.

ensure that teachers’ professional obligations for providing basic education of


development covers their initial training, high quality. They should be equipped to
induction into the teaching profession, advise districts on school improvements and
school life, and continuous professional teacher development and to ensure that
development. Teachers should be entitled to teachers are deployed efficiently across
support services and professional districts. District governments should be
development programs. Measures of responsible for the employment and
teachers’ performance need to be based on deployment of teachers across schools and
what they add to the teaching and learning for paying their base salary (the national
processes in their own classrooms as well as minimum) and additional benefits and
their contribution to the professional incentives, for monitoring teacher
education community. performance, and for ensuring that teachers
have regular access to professional
In a decentralized teacher management development programs linked to their school
system, the main role of the central activities.
government should be to set minimum
teaching standards and salary scales and to Table 5.2 illustrates what might be involved
develop guidelines for promotions and in putting a national policy framework for
incentives. The provincial education units teacher management in place and suggests
should be responsible for ensuring that who should be responsible for implementing
districts are able to meet their statutory the various actions and strategies.

45
Education Sector Review Volume 1

Table 5.2: A Proposed National Framework for a Teacher Management System


Enabling Policies Actions/Strategies Responsibilities
Establishing a transparent Teacher registration School – Identify teachers’ needs, review candidates,
teacher appointment process Teacher deployment norms and interview short list, select teachers, inform district
based on efficient deployment Posts of responsibility managers
norms, school vacancies, Administrative procedures for District – Disseminate information on teacher norms
advertisements, selection districts and school for hiring and conditions of employment; prepare initial short
criteria, contractual teachers list of candidates, accept school selection, and
arrangements, and public advertise results
information National – Set guidelines for teacher/student ratios,
posts of responsibilities, minimum qualifications and
experience, conditions of employment; pilot scheme
for identifying teacher-deficit and teacher-surplus
areas and allocating new teachers accordingly
Provincial – Provide quality assurance, facilitate
across-district appointments; assist national
government in piloting deployment scheme
Establish a school Minimum service standards School – Undertake internal self-evaluation
performance evaluation Teacher performance standards processes, feedback to whom? and incentives, school
process that is based on Supervisors, evaluators trained in development program, teacher development needs,
teachers’ collective performance review access resources for school improvement
responsibility and opportunity Professional support activities District – Provide professional support such as
for individual teacher Performance incentives for mentoring by better teachers, budgetary resources for
performance reviews on schools and teachers staff development, information systems on teacher
request for career Evaluation processes and school performance, disseminate best practices
development purposes based Performance review guidelines National – Set minimum service standards and
on their value added to Feedback loops between teacher performance and accreditation standards
education processes and evaluators and teachers Provincial – Provide quality assurance, disseminate
outcomes. Accreditation and information information, identify resource pool for professional
system support
Establish a compensation and Compensation system that District – Assess practice of top-up allowances and
rewards system that is clear, rewards teacher behavior that clarify criteria for allocating allowances
transparent, and guided by improves student achievement National – Pilot and evaluate alternative incentive
considerations of systems for “difficult” areas
qualifications, responsibilities, Provincial – Quantify supply of new teachers
and motivations for teachers’
continuous development
Put in place a teacher School-based initial teacher School – Contribute to practicum, provide feedback
professional development preparation to training institutions and technical resource groups,
system that is school-based Induction to teaching and participate in action research for school development
and performance-led. licensing program that establishes District – Provide feedback to training institutions
partnerships between districts, and technical resource groups; placement of new
schools, and licensing body teachers, support and evaluate candidates, provide
Teacher classroom performance, resources for induction and professional development
value-added opportunities for activities
developing professional interests, Province – Provide quality assurance, technical
pedagogy, subject matter, support resources, disseminate best practices
leadership roles; linked to rewards National – Establish accreditation of teacher
– recognition, financial, and education programs and institutions, respond to
promotion. employers’ and service providers’ needs..

46
Chapter 6: The Way Forward: Making Decentralization Work for
Education
This review of Indonesia’s education sector has system and any lack of commitment
addressed the familiar issues of quality, from the government to confronting
efficiency, and equity but through the special some difficult implementation issues
lens of the current decentralization reform. It could erode the effectiveness of the
has addressed how the country’s key education reform.
goals (reaching universal enrollment in basic
education and improving the quality of Based on the evidence discussed in the previous
schooling) are going to be achieved in a system chapters, this chapter presents a detailed policy
that is supposed to be managed primarily at the agenda that identifies core objectives, specific
district rather than at the central level. The recommendations for action (with a
introduction of decentralization three years ago corresponding assessment of how urgently those
dramatically changed the rules and processes of actions need to be taken), and suggestions on
service provision, and all of the relevant which agencies should implement each action.
stakeholders are still in the process of This agenda is summarized in a policy matrix at
understanding, adapting to, and managing the the end of this chapter (Table 6.1). Many
implications of those changes. With this district governments and schools urgently need
paradigm shift in governance, how education some guidance on the extent of their
services are going to be delivered cannot be decentralized responsibilities and assistance on
“business as usual” for everyone. The review how to carry them out, so the recommendations
has identified areas in the regulatory framework of this review apply to them as much as to the
and implementation processes of the central government.
decentralization reform that need to be clarified,
improved, or corrected. Many messages have A Policy Reform Agenda
emerged from the review, but the two
overarching messages are: The following set of policy recommendations
stem from: (i) the observations and conclusions
x Improving education quality across the of the team that undertook this review of
system is the key educational challenge Indonesia’s education sector, (ii) numerous
for Indonesia today, and even concerns documents produced by donor-assisted projects,
about equity and serving the poor must and (iii) discussions (in the form of meetings
be couched in terms of universal access and interviews) with many stakeholders in the
to education of acceptable quality. system, including officials in the central
agencies, provincial and district officials,
x Decentralization can potentially help to teachers, heads teachers, and members of school
meet this quality challenge—by committees (including some parents), national
spreading the governance and education experts, and the staff of aid agencies.
managerial responsibility for improving In addition, in collaboration with the central
better education across different government, the team launched a much broader
stakeholders, by strengthening consultative process with these various
accountability mechanisms, and by stakeholders in December 2003-January 2004.
enhancing incentives to innovate. The team’s recommendations are as follows.
However, any delays in clarifying and
rationalizing functions, structures, and
financing throughout the education

47
Education Sector Review Volume 1

Establish clear and efficient function Reform the structure and processes of the
assignment within the education system and central Ministry of Education so that it can
align this with appropriate governance and fulfill its core functions of developing and
management structures and financing harmonizing education policies and designing
arrangements at all levels of the system. an implementation program, and an investment
and funding plan for those policies, while
As discussed in previous chapters, the ensuring that local governments and civil
decentralization laws left the assignment of society have a voice in this process.
governance, managerial, and financing functions
in the education sector vague. Similar functions At the moment, the MoNE is not organized in a
and roles have been given to different levels of way that is consistent with its new core function
government, which is a recipe for replication, of quality management and with the spirit of
conflict, and chaos. Also, functions and decentralization. Currently, the Ministry is
structures are not aligned (for example, a large organized by levels of education, which has
central Ministry of National Education continues tended to produce administrative silos and a
to exist despite the transfer of many of its large, unwieldy bureaucracy. There have been
responsibilities to lower levels of government) limited initiatives within the Ministry to fulfill
and financing arrangements do not conform to its functions given under the decentralization
functions (as illustrated by the many different reform, but these initiatives have been assigned
sources of financing for capital expenditures at mainly to an existing unit (for example, the
the local level). Moreover, some devolved Decentralization and Facilitation Unit). What is
functions are best left to the national or needed instead is a fundamental change in the
provincial levels. Some tasks that can most way the Ministry operates. The MoNE should be
efficiently and effectively be carried out at a reorganized according to its new major
level of government higher than the district are: functions, consistent with its oversight role in a
coordinating the strategic direction of the decentralized education system. In particular,
education system, setting education standards, the Ministry should:
developing technical support systems, assessing
best practices, and encouraging the development x Harmonize and link new education
of markets. policies and programs, and retire any
leftover policies and programs that
There are some other issues that need to be undermine the goals under
resolved at a higher level than within the decentralization. Since decentralization,
education sector itself because they also pertain various simultaneous efforts in, for
to other sectors besides education. Resolving example, standard setting, teacher
these issues will require bold steps, including certification, and school rehabilitation
reviewing and revising the decentralization laws and repair have been launched, but it is
to clarify the assignment of functions, to correct vital to coordinate these initiatives to
the misalignments between functions and prevent wasteful duplication and
structures and between functions and financing contradictions. In addition, the MoNE
arrangements, and to follow through with should participate in a permanent inter-
corresponding structural changes. Without these ministerial forum for resolving any
bold changes, education stakeholders will not be policy conflicts that affect different
able to trust the central government’s sectors such as the current civil service
commitment to sharing authority and resources, regulations that are not appropriate for
which will dissipate all of the current impetus managing a decentralized teacher
for reform. service.

48
Chapter 6 The Way Forward

x Develop, test, and disseminate new central government can facilitate this
management and operations systems. collaboration by giving financial
The central government, local incentives for information reporting, by
governments, and schools all urgently reinforcing local pride at being involved
need new systems in three areas— in producing a joint product (such as
information, budget and expenditure standards and definitions developed
tracking, and planning, monitoring, and collaboratively over time), and by
evaluation. The existing system for stressing to weaker districts that
collecting and reporting information on collaboration will enable them to learn
schools has collapsed since from what the stronger districts are
decentralization. Nor is there any doing.
effective system for keeping track of
district-level education expenditures or x Develop management and technical
for determining and tracking the capacities at all levels. Running the
allocation of funding and resources to new management and operations
schools. There are some local systems will require new skills. The
experiments and projects that are biggest bottleneck to implementing
addressing these issues, but these efforts devolved functions is the lack of
are largely sporadic and undocumented. technical and managerial capacity at the
One of the responsibilities of the central local level. Building this capacity must
government is to encourage local begin with the MoNE defining
experimentation, identify good performance standards and measures for
practices, and build on these to create all decentralized functions and a
management and operations systems corresponding checklist of basic
that will be effective in a decentralized competencies needed to carry them out.
context. This checklist can then be used by each
level of government to assess their own
x Foster a national education information current capacity, design a program for
system consistent with decentralization. upgrading that capacity, and fill future
It is worth singling out this function staff vacancies. Such a variety of skills
because having an effective information will be needed that it is highly unlikely
system will be vital for the MoNE to that a single service provider will be
carry out any of its new functions, able to meet all staff development needs.
particularly quality assurance. In order However, since the current supply is
to build an effective information system, limited, the government should take
the MoNE should decide what kinds of immediate steps to expand and diversify
information the database should contain, the supply of service providers.
establish the most effective means for
sharing information between levels of x Develop and disclose a multi-year plan
government, and design and test a for financial, technical and management
simpler data management system for assistance to local governments. During
districts with very little capacity. the consultation meetings for this report,
However, any effective information some local leaders lamented the fact that
system requires reliable and timely capital investments in schools are often
input, so collaboration between the financed in a fragmented and unplanned
MoNE and the regional governments is way by the central government or by aid
essential because the Ministry’s agencies, robbing the districts of the
bureaucratic power alone will not be ability to manage their education
enough to ensure that local governments systems. There are an estimated 400
and schools collect and report projects currently managed by the
information. Under decentralization, the MoNE, accounting for the bulk of the

49
Education Sector Review Volume 1

APBN allocation for education and discretionary and that depends on just a
controlling the capital and quality few key measurable criteria. Besides
improvements investments in the sector. these “operational funds,” the
government should make additional
Require provincial and district governments to funds available through a proposal-
prepare and implement multi-year regional based grants mechanism to cover the
investment and financing plans as well as a costs of, for example, staff development
corresponding assistance plan for each school programs or the construction of a new
in accordance with regional goals and with classroom or laboratory. This funding
school capacities and needs. channel is discussed in greater detail
below. Third, to facilitate school-based
The experience of other countries has revealed management, the government should
that giving transfers to lower levels of give this assistance to schools in cash
governments are more effective when efforts are rather than in kind.
also made to build local planning skills, to
increase transparency in the allocation and use x Disclose publicly the amount of funds
of local funds, and to require accountability in and other assistance that districts will
return for the transfers. For Indonesia, this be giving to each school well before the
means that the central government should: beginning of the school year. This will
give the school committee in each
x Scrap the budgeting process that local school a chance to finalize its own
governments and schools go through spending plan and to raise additional
each year and replace it with a multi- resources if needed. This is complicated
year investment plan and an annual by the fact that the district and school
spending plan. These plans should budget years do not correspond (January
specify the level, source, and type of to December for districts, July to June
resources needed and whether for schools). While it is not necessary to
investment activities would be under the align these budget cycles, local
direct management of the local governments should find a solution that
government or of the school alleviates this problem for schools.
committees.
x Conduct a periodic financial audit of
x Establish a clear funding mechanism to schools as an input into the preparation
transfer resources to schools that is easy of the multi-year assistance plan for
to implement and to monitor. First and each school.
foremost, this means ensuring that
schools receive adequate block grants to x Monitor and evaluate the
cover their basic operating expenses, implementation of school investment
including the costs of teaching and non- plans by means of periodic progress
teaching staff, instructional supplies, reports, field inspections, and
some staff development, the routine evaluations of outcomes. All
activities of the school committee, the investment projects should also be
maintenance of a school database, the audited, and the results of these audits
dissemination of information to parents should be made public.
and the community, utilities, and light
repair of the school buildings and other x Ensure that routine allocation processes
maintenance. Second, to increase are responsive to the needs of the poorer
transparency in the allocation of funds districts and schools by adopting pro-
and to enable schools to plan ahead, the poor education programs to stimulate
size of these grants should be based on a demand consistent with the goals of the
formula-based allocation that is non- global Education for All initiative.

50
Chapter 6 The Way Forward

To achieve these changes, local governments ensure that schools are funded at least to the
need adequate and timely technical assistance to minimum necessary for operations and
build their capacity to develop plans and budget maintenance. Other steps that are needed are to:
processes, arrange financing, operate the local
education system efficiently, and assist schools. x Begin a periodic audit of schools on the
These technical assistance and training programs basis of a checklist of standards,
do not have to be provided by the central produce scorecards on the basis of this
government. In fact, considering the size and audit that rate the overall quality and
diversity of Indonesia’s education system, it performance of each school, and
would be better to encourage the development of develop a protocol for the public
a private supply of technical assistance and disclosure of these scorecards.
training. Specific grants (possibly through the
central government’s development budget – the x Require schools to report their own
DIP – or through the DAK) could be given to expenditures in a timely fashion, but this
the regions to allow them to procure the services will require switching to a multi-year
of national and international experts to help process in order to give schools enough
them to develop their budgeting and planning time to complete their expenditure
skills, to raise their revenues, to track their records before the next planning period.
expenditures, to manage information flows, and
to assess school performance. Ultimately, x Establish a proposal-based grants
regions will be expected to use their own program that would allow schools to
budgets to maintain their planning and request extra resources for specific
management skills and to purchase these innovations and experiments. Some
technical services from an organized schools are going to be much better at
marketplace of suppliers. preparing proposals than other schools,
so this grants program needs to include a
Help schools to make and implement decisions training facility to help build this
that will improve quality, especially those in capacity in those schools that lack it.
poor areas. Several ongoing donor-assisted projects
(for example, the DSSD and the DBEP)
Since the mid-1990s, there has been a trend in have been building similar capacity in
Indonesia towards school quality improvement selected areas of the country so some
projects that are school-planned, school-based, local governments and schools already
and school-monitored. This trend is consistent have the required capability as well as
with Education Law 20, which has empowered the ability to train school personnel.
schools to make decisions regarding their
governance and management. However, as this x Develop a policy for targeting special
review concludes, there is tremendous variation assistance to those schools that do not
in the capacity of schools to exercise the meet the with minimum quality
authority that decentralization has given them. standards, especially in poor areas.
A big challenge over the next few years is to
develop a viable strategy for raising the capacity As discussed above, one significant challenge
of schools to manage resources and programs. for the central and local governments is to make
Another challenge is to ensure that schools meet policies related to education quality that
the minimum requirements for accreditation as embrace all different types of schools. We
defined by the central government and that recommend that the Indonesian government
schools receive sufficient funds to cover their adopt a “one policy roof” for all schools and, as
basic operating expenses. This means that the a first step, should assess all religious and
first step in improving school quality is to bring private schools according to the same national
the physical and human infrastructure up to minimum education quality standards that apply
minimum standards for accreditation and to to public schools. This major task would fill the

51
Education Sector Review Volume 1

information gap left by the collapse of the paying their base salaries (the national
national annual school census and would minimum) and any additional benefits and
underpin subsequent periodic assessments by incentives, for monitoring teacher performance,
local governments. Also, as part of the school and for ensuring that teachers have access to
registration and accreditation processes, local professional development programs. There are
governments should require these (private and also areas where cooperation among the levels
religious) schools to formulate a plan for of government could be highly beneficial. For
bringing their quality standards up to the example, as discussed in the previous chapter,
required level and a timetable of the specific central and provincial governments could
actions and the level of resources that they will increase the efficiency of teacher deployment by
need to do so. Those plans would become helping districts to develop their own formulas
components of a regular accreditation process for calculating their teacher requirements that
for these schools, and their progress in achieving take into account the number of students
its goals could be used as a basis for providing enrolled in a school rather than the number of
them with targeted assistance in the future. classes in the school.

Establish a teaching service, separate from the Educators in Indonesia already feel that there is
civil service, that includes a transparent a need for a new paradigm for the teaching
appointment and deployment process and a profession. Many elements of this new approach
professional development system that is school- are already in place or are being tried out in a
based and performance-led. number of projects. However, developing an
overall framework that defines teachers’
Effective teacher management systems in professional development as a lifelong process
schools are essential for achieving national should be a priority. Many of the elements of
education goals. Table 5.1 in the previous this framework could be tested in simultaneous
chapter lays out a list of appropriate policies, the pilot projects by different institutions and in
kind of actions required to implement these different districts.
policies, and some ideas about who should be
responsible for implementing those actions. The Implementing the Policy Agenda
most critical recommendation is for the
establishment of a separate teaching service with Finally, we return to the question of how best to
the following characteristics: merit-based implement the recommended actions outlined in
appointments, transfers, and promotions; school- this chapter.
based performance evaluations; and professional
development that covers all phases of the Supply-side and Demand-led Programs
teachers’ career including their initial training,
their induction into the teaching profession, Both supply-side and demand-side approaches
school life, and continuous professional are needed to fill existing policy and technical
development. This would need to be built up gaps. Supply-side investments are needed to
over time. strengthen the capacity of central education
agencies to make policy, to plan, to set
In a decentralized teacher management system, standards, and to measure the performance of
the main role of the central government is to set districts and schools. They are needed also to
minimum teaching standards and minimum stimulate the development of new solutions that
salary scales and to develop guidelines for can be used by local governments. These
promotions and incentives. The provincial investments can be made through a national
education units are responsible for ensuring that program or through discrete projects managed
districts are able to meet their statutory by the central agencies. Either way, it is vital to
obligation to provide high-quality education. link all of the different supply-side investments
District governments are responsible for in one institution-building agenda instead of
employing and deploying teachers and for

52
Chapter 6 The Way Forward

undertaking them separately with little or no three decades. Many of these initiatives have
coordination. borne fruit and have provided valuable lessons
about what kind of programs are effective, but
However, in the spirit of decentralization and in many other initiatives have either failed to
recognition of the great diversity that exists produce results or petered out because of a lack
across Indonesia, demand-side programs that of attention from the government or donors.
address the specific needs of provinces, districts, Under decentralization, there is an even greater
and schools should be a cornerstone of education need to learn from these initiatives. Two
policy. As already mentioned earlier, three immediate steps are needed. The first is to cull
measures in particular need to be taken. lessons from past programs. During the
preparation of this review, the team compiled all
x The central government must provide available documents from or about these
adequate block transfers to regional programs and concluded that many types of
governments, especially for those with interventions have been implemented but that
limited local revenues. The larger the share evidence-based, analytical lessons about their
of resources that is directed through this effectiveness or otherwise have seldom been
channel rather than through specific drawn. This review has cited lessons from these
programs, the more it will support the past initiatives whenever they have been
development of local governance and available. It may be impossible to recover
management. lessons from or most of these programs, but it
would be useful for the government and the
x The central government should establish donor community to try.
grants to fund projects initiated by local
schools and communities. These grants will The second immediate step is to identify
have the dual objective of stimulating ongoing and planned programs that should be
innovation and experimentation and of rigorously evaluated. The aim is to build a body
reducing inequality of education quality of evidence-based lessons about how to deliver
among districts. The law allows districts to education services of good quality in a
collaborate in initiating these projects and decentralized setting. It is important to extract
applying for these grants so that they can not just localized lessons but also broad ones
take advantage of economies of scale. To that reflect the wide diversity of contexts in
encourage the formation of this kind of Indonesia. An integral part of this evaluation
association between districts, the grants effort must be to establish a mechanism to
program could award more money to those ensure that these lessons are widely publicized
proposals that are submitted by an so that they can be taken into account in national
association of districts. and local policymaking and school-based
management. Regional meetings held for this
x The central government should evaluate and review suggest that the demand for such lessons
support the education management systems exists.
being developed and used in different
regions.

Learning from Past and Ongoing Efforts

The government of Indonesia and its partners in


the donor community have invested in many
pilot initiatives in education over the past two or

53
Table 6.1. Proposed policy agenda for educational development under decentralization

Policy objectives Specific actions Implementing Comments


agency
(Ź means “For
immediate action”)

A. Core policy objective : To improve governance and management

Ź Finalize PPs for Establish committee of technical and management experts to carry out NG in See Chapter 2 for discussion.
Education Law 20 to analysis and consultations, to review roles for national level and prepare consultation with
provide detailed job descriptions for new national functions. and to determine degree to PG and DG
assignments of which resulting assignments can be mandated Especially in the next three years, will need to
governance and evaluate the assignment continuously to assess
Improve governance standards for Education Boards and School
management functions their appropriateness and effectiveness
Committees, and determine degree of need for national regulation.
to all levels
Ź Align structure of Restructure MoNE along function lines NG (MoNE, with See Chapter 2, Box 2.5, and Volume 2, Chapter
central education collaboration of 1 for discussion.
Launch dissemination activities to inform local governments and schools
authority to functions MoHA)
about this new structure
assigned under
decentralization
Ź Build a national Determine the informational base needed to implement and document the NG in Bureaucratic power alone is not enough to
education information policies at district level collaboration with enforce compliance on information reporting.,
system consistent with PG and DG so (a) rely on incentives (e.g. conditional
Determine the information transmission standards between levels of
decentralization supplementary grants to schools); (b) allow local
government, as information, not as software
officials to work with information professionals
Study already-existing cases of good practice of information use at at central level to develop standards and test
school and district level systems; (c) ensure that product is better than
what is readily available from the market; (d)
Design a prototype default system in a few districts that are weak but
customize local system to capacity of districts,
willing to experiment and improve while ensuring comparability across Indonesia.
Test system and disseminate key findings

54
Policy objectives Specific actions Implementing Comments
agency
(Ź means “For
immediate action”)
All government,
ŹImprove Develop management standards that all government levels, and schools Many ongoing projects (e.g., DSSD, DBEP) do
levels, in
management capacity should meet this, so need to compile lessons, disseminate and
coordination with
throughout the incorporate them into new systems.
Based on function assignments and standards, audit current management each other
education system
systems and capacities throughout the system Where needed and possible, use private
Schools (head providers to conduct audit and systems
Develop plan to restructure organizations and train staff to develop new teachers, teachers, improvements
systems and School
Committees) Process will be ongoing.
Based on standards, develop procedures for local governments and
schools to assess their own management capacity
Develop monitoring and evaluation protocols for capacity development
programs

Establish policy Assess cost-benefit of private provision as it compares with public All levels of
towards private provision government
provision, especially at
secondary and tertiary
education levels
Support capacity of Create funding and selection mechanism to provide legislators with DPR at NG level, Legislative bodies currently have to rely entirely
legislative bodies to demand-led access to academics or consultants to provide studies DPRDs at LG on executive branch for analysis of education
analyze education level policy changes and the state of execution of
Consider funding small technical unit or panel that can be drawn upon
policy policy
repeatedly
Obtain support for Analyze current role of civil society in education, from policy design to NG and LG As democratization and civil society activism
educational goals and policy oversight are relatively new in Indonesia, there are
strategies from civil dangers of misunderstandings and role
Develop training program and materials for government officials on this
society, NGOs, and the confusion.
issue, and train government officials on role of civil society in policy
media
oversight Democratization and decentralization require an
informed citizenry, ideally informed by high-
Improve capacity of the media to analyze and report on education issues,
quality reporting.
by developing training materials for national and regional media and
instituting a yearly award for the best education reporting

55
Policy objectives Specific actions Implementing Comments
agency
(Ź means “For
immediate action”)
B. Core policy objective : To ensure adequate resources for education, improve the improve the efficiency and effectiveness of resource use, and address equity
concerns

Ź Secure adequate Develop and implement per-student funding formula to determine NG in The per-student funding formula is to be cost-
operational budgets for operational education budget at district level consultation with indexed with adjustments for needs of
education at provincial PG and DG disadvantaged groups, using reasonable cost
Develop and implement per-school funding formula to determine staff
and district levels and estimate of enrollment and agreed-upon quality
deployment
in schools standards and geographic-specific prices.
Establish tracking and reporting systems for regular monitoring and
To improve teacher deployment, base staff
analysis of education financing at all levels
deployment on a per-school rather than per-
student basis, with indicative teacher-student
parameters. See section D below.

Ź Secure adequate Evaluate lessons from current development projects throughout the NG in While this should be initiated immediately, the
development resources system, and develop a plan for consolidating or linking, and for scaling consultation with process will take a few years to complete.
for education in regions up those that are effective and terminating those that are not PG and DG
and in schools, esp. for
Audit investment projects for schools and require public disclosure of
poor regions
results of audit; develop monitoring and evaluation protocols for capacity
development programs
Determine which development projects are best undertaken at regional or
national levels

Ź Improve the Develop multi-year plan of financial, technical and management NG in Develop schema for determining level and
transparency and assistance to district governments that is consistent with regional needs consultation with nature of needed assistance to regions:
predictability of and goals PG and DG Categorize districts according to performance
assistance to local level on multiple education indicators, resource
Publish plan so it is broadly known, and establish mechanism for
governments levels, and technical and management capacity
reporting on performance with respect to the plan.
Data requirements: Up-to-date district-level
information on multiple education indicators,
resource levels, and capacity

56
Policy objectives Specific actions Implementing Comments
agency
(Ź means “For
immediate action”)
Ź Improve the Each region to develop multi-year plan of financial, technical and Local Use formula funding mechanisms that are non-
transparency and management assistance to schools governments with discretionary and that depend on a few key
predictability of School Committee criteria; see above.
Publicize assistance plan so it is broadly known; meet with School
assistance to schools in each school
Committees to discuss plans and to disclose expenditures at the end of Up-to-date school-level information on multiple
each year education indicators, resource levels, and
capacity; data should be collected on a regular
basis
Ź Establish on- Initiate a transitional program of assistance to districts with greatest need NG in There is wide variation in revenue levels among
granting mechanism to of support for their education programs and schools but with inadequate consultation with districts. Use DAK mechanism and/or loan
support educational revenues to implement their multi-year educational development plan PG and DG funds to assist poorest districts and their schools
development plans of through on-granting, with matching funds to
Invite these districts to submit well-focused proposals in line with their,
regional governments ensure some additionality.
on condition that these districts will use oversight technical services from
and schools
NG or experts for the duration of the funded project

Ź Develop and Evaluate the pro-poor nature of expenditure patterns at all levels of Local These programs should be owned by districts
implement pro-poor government as part of regular performance audits governments and and provinces, using a DAK allocation.
education programs for schools to inform Additionally, national government might want to
Transition step: Establish a special, finite-term, well-targeted pro-poor
schools and students NG establish a mechanism to reward districts that
national program to supplement district financing for schools and
have achieved larger pro-poor progress.
students in selected areas
Lessons are available from SGP and SIGP of
Districts to launch their own similar program over the long-term how these might be implemented.
C. Core policy objective : To improve education quality

57
Policy objectives Specific actions Implementing Comments
agency
(Ź means “For
immediate action”)

Ź Set standards, Harmonize and link various standard-setting processes for schools and All levels of Separate efforts in MoNE, Civil Service, and
measures and teachers currently underway government MoF have begun efforts to define standards and
monitoring mechanisms measures..
Initialize school mapping and audit of schools on the basis of checklist of
for both institutions and standards, and produce “balanced scorecards” to rate overall quality and Useful to assess also good international practice
individuals governance performance of schools and districts. and Indonesian experiments from other sectors.
Develop protocol for public disclosure of balanced scorecards Some consensus within education agencies
about definition of minimum learning conditions
Develop policy on schools below standards on minimum accreditation
and service standards
Initiate national media campaign to inform people

Ź Set pro-poor x Formalize minimum service standards for local governments in the NG in Separate efforts in MoNE have to define
performance standards area education into appropriate regulation, and harmonize minimum consultation with performance and technical standards and
for districts, provinces service standards developed under MoHA umbrella with standard PG and DG measures.
and the central level setting initiated under new Education Law
District capacities to meet national standards
x Conduct an audit of district performance using the results of school even with flexible timeline is questionable
mapping and school audit activity plus education profiling of district, District capacities to manage standards
to produce “balanced scorecard” for each district monitoring varies widely,
x Set service and performance standards for national level, and audit Risk of increasing inequity unless district
performance of national level against standards standards are pro-poor

Ź Enable and Provide adequate resources for school improvement through proposal Schools and all Risk of increasing inequity unless quality
encourage pro-poor based grants to schools for quality improvements levels of improvement programs are pro-poor
school quality government
Create regulations that empower schools to make decisions that improve Use information on population, status of
improvement school quality education and school mapping to plan for
school rehabilitation, rationalization and system
Locate and disseminate pro-poor good practices, and retire those that are
expansion
ineffective
Stimulate the supply of pro-poor school improvement services
Initiate creation of “one Using quality standards for regular schools, undertake a performance PG and DG in The poorest children are educated in small
regulatory roof” for all audit of all religious and private schools coordination with private schools and Madrasah.

58
Policy objectives Specific actions Implementing Comments
agency
(Ź means “For
immediate action”)
schools School
Require all these schools to formulate a plan of achieving quality
Committees
standards (providing a timetable of specific actions and level of resources
needed) as part of the registration and accreditation processes
Establish a regular accreditation process for these schools using the
standards, and link this requirement to assistance to these schools
D. Core policy objective : To improve teacher management

Ź Establish a new ŹPrepare guidelines on optional teacher deployment patterns NG to set national This system should be compatible with district
system for teacher standards autonomy and the principles of school-based
Establish mechanisms for districts (as employers) to have access to data management, and based on professional
recruitment Districts to work
on graduates from teacher education programs to assist their teacher partnerships among districts (as employer),
supply and demand planning closely with all
schools, and licensing body
levels including
schools
Ź Establish a teacher Ź Accredit teacher education programs and institutions All levels of Depends on the establishment of transparent
professional government to set teacher appointment processes to be successful.
development system national standards
Measure schools and teacher performance and link this to teacher
that is school-based and
development plans DG to work
performance-led.
Establish mechanisms for grant systems to schools for teacher closely with all
development linked to school performance levels including
schools.
Establish licensing scheme and require teachers to be licensed to teach,
i.e., to have approved qualification, have completed an induction period,
and have been assessed as fit to be licensed with periodic review to
renew licensing
Establish a separate Prepare national legal framework for a teaching service cadre outside the NG in conjunction Requires substantial commitment from many
teaching service that regular civil service that identifies the legal employer, defines the with DG (the GoI agencies including MoNE, MoRA, MoHA,
incorporates system- conditions of teacher contracting, and the optional benefits packages that employers) and MoF, BKN, Menpan.
wide transparent would accompany various hiring and deployment strategies PG (the quality
teacher appointment control
Prepare minimum teaching service standards including conditions of
and deployment mechanism)
service salary levels guidelines for career paths and compliance and

59
Policy objectives Specific actions Implementing Comments
agency
(Ź means “For
immediate action”)
processes service, salary levels, guidelines for career paths and compliance and
National consensus on definition of basic
quality mechanisms
competencies required of teachers at different
Establish a National Teaching Commission to oversee the teaching levels of education.
service, including initiating legal actions and defining norms or standards
Determine impact of separate national teaching
service on the existing civil service structure,
civil service regulations.
Deployment norms, career structure, and
employment procedures (that incorporate a
compensation and rewards system that is clear,
transparent, guided by considerations of
qualifications, responsibilities and motivations
for continuous development) need to be simple
to understand, relatively straightforward to
execute and accountable to the community.

Notes:

NG=National government; PG=Provincial government; DG=District government

60
Chapter 6 The Way Forward

61
References For Volume 1

National Summary. Propinsi Kalimantan Timur.


Akita, Takahiro and Armida S. Alisjahbana.
Propinsi Nusa Tenggara Barat. Propinsi
2002. “Regional Income Inequality in Indonesia
Sumatera Utara.
and the Initial Impact of the Economic Crisis,”
Bulletin for Indonesian Economic Studies 38(2): Departamen Pendidikan Nasional. 2001.
201-22. Towards High Quality and Equitable Education.
National Education Commission Report
Angrist, Joshua D. and Victor Lavy. 2001.
Executive Summary.
“Does Teacher Training Affect Pupil Learning?
Evidence from Matched Comparisons in Duflo, Esther. 2001. “Schooling and Labor
Jerusalem Public Schools.” Journal of Labor Market Consequences of School Construction in
Economics, Vol. 19, No. 2, pp. 343-369. Indonesia: Evidence from an Unusual Policy
Experiment,” American Economic Review 91(4):
Aziz, A. 2002. “Madrasah Education in
795-813.
Indonesia: Potential, Problems, and Issues.”
Paper presented at the Symposium on Madrasah Economist.com. 2003. “Banking on education
Education in the Context of a National to propel a new spurt of growth,” Bangkok:
Education System. Sponsored by the Ministry December 11, 2003.
of Religious Affairs and the Asian Development
Faiqoh, Dra. Hj. 2002. “The Development of
Bank. Jakarta, 4 November 2002.
Pondok Pesantrens as a Means of Community
Bird, Richard M. and Michael Smart. 2002. Based Education and Poverty Alleviation.”
“Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers: Some Symposium on Madrasah Education in the
Lessons from International Experience,” World Context of a National Education System.
Development 30(6): 899-912. Jakarta, Indonesia: November 4, 2002.
Bray, Mark. 1997. “Community Financing of Filmer, Deon. 2002. “Teacher Pay in
Education: Rationales, Mechanisms, and Policy Indonesia.” Washington D.C.: The World Bank.
Implications in Less Developed Countries.” In Processed.
Christopher Colclough (ed.), Marketizing
Filmer, D., N. Suwaryani, and B. Indriyanto.
Education and Health in Developing Countries:
2001. “Indonesia’s Primary and Junior
Miracle or Mirage? Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Secondary Schools in a post-crisis environment:
Cameron, Lisa A. 2002. “Impact of the Findings from a follow-up survey of 600
Indonesian Financial Crisis on Children: An schools.” The World Bank. Processed.
Analysis Using the 100 Villages Data.” World
Gumaraes de Castro, M.H. 2000. “Role and
Bank and UNICEF.
Value of International Education Indicators for
Center for Indonesian Legal and Policy Studies, National Policy Development.” Fourth General
The 2002. “A Gloomy Picture of the Attempts Assembly of the OECD Education Indicators
to Eradicate Corruption: Reflection of the Programme (INES). September. Tokyo, Japan.
policies, laws, and institutions of corruption
Hanson, M. 2000. “Democratization and
management in Indonesia, 1969-2001,” in
Educational Decentralization in Spain: A
Holloway, R., ed., Stealing From The Poor,
Twenty Year Struggle for Reform.” Country
Book Four. Jakarta: Aksara Foundation.
Studies. Education Reform and Management
Departamen Pendidikan Nasional, Balan Publication Series. Vol. (3). June 2000.
Penelitan dan Pengembangan (Balitbang). 2002.
Hofman, Bert, Kai Kaiser, and Soraya Goga.
“Studi Kesiapan Propinsi dan Kabupaten/Kota
2003. Decentralizing Indonesia (A Regional
Untuk Melaksanakan Desentralisasi Pendidikan”
Public Expenditure Review). The World Bank,
(“Readiness of Provinces and Districts to
Jakarta.
Implement Education Decentralization.”)

61
Education Sector Review Volume 1

Hofman, Bert, Kadjatmiko, and Kai Kaiser. Smoke (ed.), Intergovernmental Transfers in
2002. “Evaluating Indonesia’s Fiscal Asia. Manila, Asian Development Bank.
Equalization.” The World Bank, Jakarta.
Lewis, Blane D. 2003. “Local Government
Processed.
Borrowing and Repayment in Indonesia: Does
Jalal, Fasli. 2000. “The Role of Madrasah in Fiscal Capacity Matter?” World Development
Basic Education in Indonesia: A Successful 31(6): 1047-1063.
Response of Religious Groups to Educate
Lopez-Acevedo, Gladys. 2001. “Teacher’s
Children of Their Community.” Presented at
Incentives and Professional Development in
Workshop on Public-Private Partnership in
Schools in Mexico.” Washington, DC: The
Education, Tokyo, 29 May – 7 June.
World Bank. Processed.
Jalal, F. and B. Musthafa. 2001. Education
Reform in the Context of Regional Autonomy: Malen, B., R. Ogawa, and J. Kranz. 1990.
The Case of Indonesia. Ministry of National “What Do We Know about School-Based
Education and National Development Planning Management? A Case Study of the Literature- A
Agency, Republic of Indonesia, and the World Call for Research,” in W.H. Clune and J. F.
Bank. Witte, eds., Choice and Control in American
Education, Volume 2: The practice of Choice,
James, Estelle, Elizabeth M. King, and Ace
Decentralization, and School Restructuring.
Suryadi. 1996. “Finance, Management, and
London: Falmer Press.
Costs of Public and Private Schools in
Indonesia,” Economics of Education Review McMahon, Walter. 2003. “Financing and
15(4): 387-398. Achieving ‘Education For All’ Goals.” Final
Report for the Ministry of National Education,
Jimenez, Emmanuel and Vicente Paqueo. 1996.
BAPPENAS and the World Bank, Indonesia.
"Do Local Contributions Affect the Efficiency
Processed.
of Public Primary Schools? " Economics of
Education Review 15(4): 377-86. McMahon, W. with N. Suwaryani, Boediono,
and E. Appiah. 2001. Improving Education
Kaplan, Robert and David Norton. 1992. "The
Finance in Indonesia. Policy Research Center,
Balanced Scorecard - Measures that Drive
Institute for Research and Development,
Performance," Harvard Business Review.
Ministry of National Education, Indonesia,
Kepmen No. 044/U/2002. (Decree of the UNICEF and UNESCO.
Minister of National Education. Republic of
McMahon, W. and Boediono. 2001.
Indonesia. Concerning The Education Council
“Improving Education Funding in Indonesia,” in
and School Committee.)
McMahon, W. with N. Suwaryani, Boediono,
Kepmen No 087/U/2002. (Decree of the and E. Appiah. 2001. Improving Education
Minister of National Education. Republic of Finance in Indonesia. Policy Research Center,
Indonesia. Concerning Accreditation.) Institute for Research and Development,
Kingdon, Geeta Gandhi, 1996. “Student Ministry of National Education, Indonesia,
Achievement and Teacher Pay: A Case Study of UNICEF and UNESCO.
India.” The Development Economics Research Ministry of National Education (MoNE),
Program, London School of Economics and Government of Indonesia. 2002a. “Education
Political Science. DEP No.74 August 1996. for All: Situational Analysis 2002. Indonesia.”
Lewis, Blane D. 2001. “The New Indonesian Draft presented at the National Forum for
Equalization Transfer,” Bulletin for Indonesian Education for All, Jakarta. Processed.
Economic Studies 37(3): 325-43. Ministry of National Education (MoNE),
Lewis, Blane D. 2002. “Revenue-Sharing and Government of Indonesia. 2002b. The Strategic
Grant-Making in Indonesia: The First Two Planning of the Development of Education,
Years of Fiscal Decentralization,” in Paul

62
References

Youth and Sport 2002-2004. Jakarta, Indonesia. Somerset, Tony. 1997. Teacher Supply and
Translated from Indonesian. Distribution Issues in Kabupaten Sukabumi:
Results from a rapid review. Working paper,
Ministry of National Education (MoNE),
World Bank and GOI Basic Education Project
Government of Indonesia. 2002c. The
Preparation. Jakarta.
Existence of Madrasah, Diniyah Education and
Pesantren in the National Education System. Strauss, Robert P. and Elizabeth A. Sawyer.
Office of Educational Research and (1986). “Some New Evidence on Teacher and
Development. Student Competencies,” Economics of
Education Review 5(1): 41-48.
Ministry of National Education/ Office of
Educational Research and Development. 2002d. South Africa, Republic of. 1996. South African
“The Existence of Madrasah, Diniyah Education Schools Act, No. 84 of 1996. Available at
and Pesantren in the National Education http://www.gov.za/acts/96index.html.
System.” Policy Paper. Jakarta, Indonesia.
Sweeting, Elizabeth. 2001. “Booklet for
Ministry of National Education (MoNE), Kabupaten Education Planners.” Background
Government of Indonesia. 2003. “The Strategic paper prepared for MONE and World Bank as
Planning of The Development of Education, part of the Basic Education IV Project
Youth and Sport, 2002-2004.” Limited Draft. Development. Unpublished draft. Jakarta.
National Committee for Education, Sub- Vanwel, Helen, Musthafa and Miftahuddin.
Committee III. 2001. Decentralization of 2003. “Impact of Decentralization on Teacher
Education. Draft Report, June 14. Processed Management: Report on Focus Group
and translated into English. Assessments in Bandar Lampung and
Makassar.” Report for the World Bank’s
Odden, Allan. 2000. “New and Better Forms of
Indonesia Education Sector Review.
Teacher Compensation Are Possible.” Phi Delta
Kappan, Vol. 81, No. 5, pp. 361-366. Woessmann, Ludger. 2001. “Schooling
Resources, Educational Institutions, and Student
Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Performance: the International Evidence.” Kiel,
Development (OECD). 1994. Improving the
Germany: Kiel Institute for World Economics.
Quality of Laws and Regulations: Economic,
Legal, and Managerial Techniques. World Bank. 1998. Education in Indonesia:
OCDE/GD(94)59. Paris. From Crisis to Recovery. Report No. 18651-
IND. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development (OECD). 2001. Teachers for World Bank. 2002. “Brazil. Municipal
Tomorrow’s Schools: Analysis of the World Education Resources, Incentives, and Results.”
Education Indicators. Paris: UNESCO. Policy Report. Washington, DC. The World
Bank.
Pradhan, Menno. 2001. “Welfare Analysis with
a Proxy Consumption Measure, Evidence from a World Bank. 2003a. “Construction Specialist’s
Repeated Experiment in Indonesia,” Working reports on Junior Secondary Education
paper, Free University, Amsterdam. Processed. Projects.”
Pritchett, Lant and Deon Filmer. 1999. “The World Bank. 2003b. “Construction Specialist’s
Effect of Household Wealth on Education reports on Basic Education Projects.”
Attainment: Evidence from 35 Countries,”
World Bank. 2004. “World Development Report
Population and Development Review 25(1).
2004: Making Services Work for the Poor.”
Ross, Kenneth N. and Rosalind Levaþiü (eds.). Washington DC: The World Bank.
1999. Needs-Based Resource Allocation in
Education (Via Formula Funding of Schools).
Paris: UNESCO, International Institute for
Educational Planning.

63
Report No. 29506

INDONESIA

EDUCATION IN INDONESIA:
MANAGING THE TRANSITION TO
DECENTRALIZATION
(In Three Volumes) Volume 2

The World Bank


August 2004
Chapter 1: Governance and Management
under Decentralization
The tools needed for governing and managing thinking, especially in issues related to school
a centralized system are relatively simple – and community based management, dichot-
that is one of the apparent advantages of cen- omy between public and private schools… and
tralism. Decentralization has great potential education management and coordination.”
advantages, but it also requires more skill and (MoNE, 2003). This chapter addresses the
better systems and can, therefore, be a chal- sources of the confusion. It lays out the cur-
lenge. rent challenges facing Indonesia in implement-
ing the governance and management aspects
As is the case in most of Indonesia’s public of a decentralized education system. It offers
sector, Indonesian education has traditionally suggestions for how to move forward.
been quite centralized. Although there have
been some specific moves towards more local The chapter’s main message is that as imple-
management in the past, these have been lim- mentation of decentralization occurred, in
ited to what might better be termed “decon- 2001 and 2002, policy as to who does what,
centration.” Local offices of the national why, and with what legitimacy, appeared quite
Ministry of Education were given manage- confused. The current policy changes, starting
ment responsibilities, but they were not ac- in 2003, are not making things much clearer,
countable to a local legislature or elected and are often technically not the most appro-
politicians, and their ability to set policy was priate. Finally, as ideas do get clearer anyway
limited. The ability of local citizenry to hold (e.g., as practices emerge by default in dis-
officials responsible was, both in theory and in tricts willing to experiment, in spite of, rather
practice, circumscribed. Recently, Laws than because of, clear policy), and appropriate
22/1999 and 25/1999, as well as the 2003 Edu- ideas do emerge, the systems and skills needed
cation Act, constitute a firm thrust towards to implement the new, decentralized ways of
decentralization.1 However, the basic decen- doing things, are often missing or not opti-
tralization laws are vague and the related regu- mized. Furthermore, there are too few good
lations tend to be contradictory and often mechanisms for ensuring the lateral spread of
unrelated to the higher-level Acts. Further- effective practices that emerge in various lo-
more, according to interviews conducted for calities.
this review, some policymakers are discussing
the potential benefits of re-centralization. Fi- To support this basic story-line, the chapter is
nally, there are implementation capacity chal- organized as follows. First, the status of edu-
lenges as discussed in Hickling Indonesia cation governance and management in Indone-
(2001b) as well as in Depdiknas (2002), which sia, and the process of decentralization at its
found uneven capacity across a range of dis- beginning, are analyzed descriptively and in
tricts. This uncertainty has created anxiety, comparative perspective. Second, some of the
which was clearly expressed in a planning sources of confusion are analyzed. A few im-
document issued by the MoNE in 2003: portant current policy changes, such as the
“[there have been] apathies and confusion in 2003 Education Act and the process of setting
the process of decentralization and autonomy minimum service standards, are discussed. It
in education as it restructures the ways of is explained that these might not improve mat-
ters very much, because the basic sources of
confusion are untouched. Third, assuming
1
Furthermore, planning documents such as MoNE some of the basic policy problems can be im-
(2003) endorse the basic principle that the: “spirit of de- proved upon, some “technical” or “systems
centralization and regional autonomy will underline the development” challenges facing Indonesia are
implementation process… the development planning
policy of each region will have a different priority.” p.2.

1
Education Sector Review Volume 2

discussed. Finally, suggestions for improve- been, and there still is, widespread confusion
ment are made.2 as to who does what, and why. This has been
the situation as decentralization gets under
The Situation as Decentralization Gets way.
Under Way
A Comparative Perspective
Detailed governance and management diagno-
ses have already been carried out in the last Table 1.1 presents a list of the most common
few years, both by donors (Greene, 2000; challenges encountered in those countries that
Hickling Indonesia, 2001a and 2001b; and have decentralized their education sectors.3
World Bank, 1998) and by Indonesian schol- The table lists each challenge, indicates
ars (see Sudharto, 2002; Supriyoko, 2002; whether the challenge appears to be relevant to
Widarinata and Mudyahardja, 2002, and oth- the current Indonesian situation, and assesses
ers in the same series). Some of the studies whether the challenge in question seems to
document issues pre-dating the recent laws, impede Indonesia’s decentralization process,
while others focus on the challenges presented and finally whether Indonesian policymakers
by decentralization. They generally agree that appear to be sufficiently aware of this chal-
there is a lack of clarity in the laws and a lack lenge, and how it can be confronted. Whether
of capacity at the local level. Thus, Indonesia Indonesia faces these challenges was assessed
now has to continue its efforts to meet pre- via a series of interviews conducted specifi-
existing goals, such as widening access to cally for this report with various policymakers
education and improving quality, but in the and experts on governance and management
new and complex context of decentralization. issues and with representatives from
Yet, in this section we will show that: a) from Education Boards and school committees.
an international perspective, Indonesia’s de- (See Appendix 1.2 for a complete list of the
centralization process is not yet sufficiently experts interviewed.)
well-embarked; b) based on empirical analyses
of data on local governance and management, Judging by this table, Indonesia’s
there appear to be serious problems, and rely- decentralization is not yet well-embarked.
ing on citizen pressure to solve these problems The experts running the sector are quite aware
will not be easy or automatic; and c) there has of this, but they are often not clear on what to
do about it.

2
“Community participation” is not addressed in
this chapter under that name. However, it is clear
that, in discussing effective community-level gov-
ernance through school committees or the role of
3
civil society in policy definition, we are addressing As captured by the knowledge management tools at
the issues normally covered under the rubric of http://www1.worldbank.org/education/globaleducationreform/
“community participation.” 06.GovernanceReform/governace_ref.htm.

2
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

Table 1.1 Diagnosis of Governance, Management, and Related Decentralization Challenges


Likeli- Clarity
hood to among
impede Aware- experts
decen- ness on how
traliza- among to
Generic Challenge Present in Indonesia? tion experts solve
1. Unclear or inefficient Yes High Yes No
definition and assignment
of roles and responsibili-
ties (function assignment)
2. Misalignment of re- Difficult to say because function assignment High Insuffi- No
sponsibility and authority is not clear but is likely to be a challenge cient
given unclear legislation
3. State/provincial gov- No. Provinces do not have excessive overall Low NA NA
ernment centralism power relative to kabupaten/kota and (poten-
tially) schools.
4. Lack of a) management Yes, though highly variable. Many kabu- High Insuffi- No
systems and b) skills (ge- paten/kota do not have the skills needed to cient
neric and system-based) to implement education decentralization,
implement the reform though some do. No serious (universal) di-
agnostic against a complete and detailed
function assignment has been done, partly
because function assignment is not clear.
Some samples have been done. Some kabu-
paten/kota are so small it is doubtful they
will ever have the skills, or should, since
they handle just a few thousand students.
5. Lack of community, Difficult to say because it has not been tested Medium Yes No
parent and private sector through wide-scale policy. Pilot projects /untested
participation suggest interest could be high.
6. Lack of organizational/ Yes High Yes No
individual accountability
7. Lack of quality Yes. Both a lack of information that is of High Yes No
information high quality and a relative lack of informa-
tion about quality. The former problem is
worse than the latter.
8. Lack of effective tech- Yes. Most instructions, guidelines and tradi- High Insuffi- No
nical support and guidance tion are aimed at control rather than support. cient
9. Inequity of educational Yes. Spending per student varies greatly. High Insuffi- Some
access, opportunities, and See the chapter on finance in this report. cient
quality
10. Inefficient/unequal re- Yes. Funding formulae are inefficient. See High Insuffi- Some
source allocation the chapter on finance in this report. cient
11. Resistance to decen- There appears to be some resistance at na- Medium Some No
tralization and lack of po- tional level to decentralization of certain
litical and legal support functions, e.g., those related to teacher man-
agement. Belief that certain functions
should be re-centralized is not uncommon.
12. Project design does not Does not appear to be a problem. Decen- NA NA NA
support the decentraliza- tralization pilot projects are ahead of the leg-
tion objectives islation and regulation. Actual problem
seems to be rather in making sure the lessons
learned from pilot projects are taken into ac-
count in legislation and regulation.
13. Institutional and po- This appears to be a problem. Policy varies High Yes Some
litical unpredictability and is often unclear.

3
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Most of the current challenges in Indonesia taining to education governance. An analysis


stem from two fundamental problems: (i) the of this survey is presented in Appendix 1.4.
lack of a clear and efficient assignment of Here we summarize the results of the survey.
functions and (ii) a lack of general manage-
ment skills and of the specific management Expert opinions of Dinas Pendidikan officials
skills needed to operate decentralized man- and school officials regarding objective meas-
agement systems.4 ures, such as the time it takes to procure
school books or the time it takes to register a
Almost all other problems derive from these teacher promotion, suggest that the system is
two. For example, the lack of effective tech- slow and poorly managed. According to the
nical support and guidance is part of the more opinions of principals, it seems to take about
generic problem of the absence of manage- 7.4 months to fulfill a school’s book requisi-
ment systems aligned with the new functions tion and 5.8 months to register a teacher pro-
and with the lack of operational skills. motion. Interestingly, the opinions on how
long it takes to accomplish these tasks differ
Empirical Evidence from the Governance significantly between the school level and the
and Decentralization Survey Dinas Pendidikan. The former estimate the
same tasks to take some 40 percent longer
The final goal of decentralization is to increase than the latter. This in itself is suggestive of a
transparency and accountability at the local management problem and serious disconnects
level, from principals and teachers to parents in perception.
and community, from Kepala Dinas to the
DPRD and the Education Board; to improve Both citizens and NGOs perceive education, in
information flows about what clients want general, to be among the most corrupt and
from schools; and to increase local input into poorly executed of services in Indonesia, and
schooling production process and input costs. DPRD members suggest that they receive
What is the evidence on the current situation? more complaints about education than about
any other service. This may be a biased view,
The Governance and Decentralization Survey of course, in the sense that education is a ser-
(GDS) carried out by the Center for Popula- vice that touches citizens’ lives every day and
tion and Policy Studies (CPPS) at the Univer- in which perhaps the largest proportion of citi-
sity of Gajah Mada, with World Bank funding, zens participates on a daily basis. Thus, one
is an opinion survey that was applied to many may be more likely to complain about educa-
levels of Indonesian society. The survey was tion than about other services. Finally, DPRD
taken in 2002. It contains a few questions per- members perceived that only in about 28 per-
cent of the cases is the sector regulated at dis-
trict level—a year after decentralization is
4 supposed to have taken effect.
In Indonesia, there is little historical precedent for
a style of governance that emphasizes self-
regulation and accountability to citizens at the local Yet, if one asks citizens or parents about their
level. Historically, Indonesia transited from a po- subjective satisfaction with their children’s
litical style that could be characterized as feudal schooling, some 80 percent of parents are sat-
before colonization, to colonization under the isfied on issues such as fees, discipline, and
Dutch, which did not foster accountability to the quality of learning.5 The range of satisfaction
average person, and, after 1948, to a national lib- opinions across districts is extremely narrow:
eration centralist government typical of 20th Cen- parents seem to respond very uniformly and
tury post-colonial societies. This explains partly
why there is little natural or instinctive understand-
ing of how to develop policies and procedures that
5
are clear and lead to local self-governance. How- The phrasing of the question varied between “are
ever, in this chapter we start with more proximate you satisfied” and “are you unhappy.” The per-
causes. centages were roughly the same in either case.

4
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

always slightly positively. Furthermore, par- “help” with some function that belongs to
ents’ opinions vary much less than principals’ level Y. For example, according to PP
opinions about management problems, and are 25/2000, the education Dinas at the province
uncorrelated with the expert opinions on ob- level is supposed to “help” with providing
jective problems. Thus, in districts manage- textbooks or to “help manage” higher educa-
ment tasks are particularly slow, for example, tion. It is difficult to interpret such regula-
parents’ opinions of the system are about the tions, and it is possible that such language
same as in other districts. might exacerbate jealousy and turf battles
rather than alleviate them.
All of these factors taken together suggest that
the sector is indeed poorly managed and gov- Functions are assigned vaguely. For example,
erned but that citizens have fairly low expecta- “books” (without specifying which aspect) are
tions and uniformly so. This presents obvious the responsibility of the province. Some ex-
problems for decentralization, in terms of the perts advocate that this function should be
degree to which one can use citizens’ expecta- given to the districts, but nobody specifies
tions to pressure for improvements in service precisely how the textbooks should be funded,
provision. Possible solutions might include purchased, and distributed. For example,
introducing a public information campaign Wiradinata and Mudhyahardja (2002) recom-
about the education system or encouraging (or mend that: “At least in the medium term, some
requiring) comparative ranking of schools us- authorities of the Province (for example, book
ing systems such as school or district score- supply) should be given to Kabupaten/Kota.”
cards. Culturally appropriate methods of Yet even though the law now stipulates that
making citizens aware of their rights and of “books” are no longer the responsibility of the
the level of service they are entitled to expect central government, DEPDIKNAS still in-
need to be developed. This is discussed fur- cludes the provision of books in its planning.
ther below in the context of Minimum Service
Standards (SPMs in the Indonesian acronym). In fact, most education planning at the na-
tional level still includes functions that are (or
“Who Does What, and Why” Unclear logically ought to be) assigned to lower gov-
ernment levels. However the MoNE seems to
The various laws, decrees, and guidelines pro-
spend little on the functions that are logically
pose conflicting and overlapping functions at
nationwide functions like those involving
the most fundamental level. In one example, a
standard-setting, policy monitoring, training,
MoNE report (MoNE, 2002) states on page 17
and research. Thus, for example, while MoNE
that “Education Boards and School Commit-
(2003) explains that decentralization is being
tees control educational management or out-
taken into account, most of the activities that it
put.” However, other pages in the same
proposes to undertake seem to involve con-
document (as well as in Kepmen 044/U/2002)
struction or materials procurement, which are
describe the functions of these bodies as being
not appropriate activities for a national minis-
quite limited and as not really being to control
try in a country as big as Indonesia, and with a
or manage educational output. In another ex-
decentralized education system. 6
ample, according to PP 39/2001, the education
Dinas at the province level is responsible for
“providing education and training in Kabu- 6
For example, the activities in the basic education
paten/Kota” (Wiradinata and Mudyahardja, area (MoNE, 2003, Table III.4) include: construc-
2002) but this is contradicted by Law 22/1999. tion of junior high school (SLTP) buildings, con-
Similarly, Keppres No. 165/2000 appears to struction of additional classrooms, renovation of
contradict Law 22/1999 with regard to the SLTP buildings, construction of laboratory rooms,
level of status it accords to the MoNE. It is construction of library rooms, supply of sport and
quite common to find, in the regulations, musical instruments, supply of teaching aids for
statements such as that level X is supposed to mathematics, supply of teaching aids for pure sci-
ence, supply of books for main subjects, and sup-

5
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Furthermore, some experts and policymakers place at district level since it involves inter-
are still proposing function assignments that district spillovers.
seem to run counter to the spirit of decentrali-
zation, as was noted by several of the experts Heads of the Education Boards/Councils often
whom we interviewed. This spirit is also evi- do not yet have clear mandates or clear job de-
dent in occasional proposals to re-centralize scriptions, even in districts that are, by reputa-
(or to keep central) certain aspects of teacher tion, well-managed and are embracing
management. “Next to teacher supply, teacher decentralization. As became clear in our in-
rotation needs to be nationally and intensely terviews, many heads of Education Boards,
managed” (Djohar, 2002, p. vii). As reported while dynamic, curious, and eager to help,
by our interviewees, many aspects of teacher seemed unclear about what role they were ex-
management are still centralized, including pected to play in the new decentralized educa-
personnel database management, the registra- tion system.
tion of personnel actions, and the transmitting
of this information to the payroll system, even Although the central government, in principle,
when many of these aspects are decentralized is empowered to set standards, it has been
in theory. For example, personnel manage- timid about setting governance standards, in
ment and the payroll function take place at the particular in defining clear roles for districts’
district level, but the recording of such actions, Education Boards and School Committees.
in order for the action to trigger the payroll, is Similarly, there are no national standards for
still centralized. school funding. This can be seen in Kepmen
No. 044/U/2002.
No means have yet been found to avoid par-
ticularism (meaning, for example, each district On the other hand, the central government has
wanting its own teacher training institution or retained those functions whose role and pur-
wanting to appoint only local teachers) while pose in a decentralized system are not clear or,
staying within the spirit of decentralization. if clear, not ideal. For example, the role of the
Several interviewees gave us evidence of in- central inspectorate in the decentralized sys-
creasing particularism. This is a reflection tem is not clear. In the view of senior Indone-
within the education system of a tendency that sian analysts, the fact that the central
can be seen in society at large, such as districts government is holding on to such functions is
creating fisheries rights for themselves and not necessarily in the public interest and may
creating local nuisance taxes. Finding a solu- have more to do with either inertia or personal
tion to these problems is part of the process of interest.
clarifying function assignments. It will re-
quire both technical skills and consultations, There are no clear national standards for han-
and it is hard to imagine that this can take dling and reporting information or, if they are
clear, they are not being followed, since re-
ply of books for libraries. While the MoNE’s Stra-
porting is very poor. As a result, the education
tegic Plan contains a chapter that refers to man- authorities of the central government have in-
agement development under decentralization, the sufficient information even on basic issues
activities that it proposes are not really activities such as enrollment. At this point, for example,
but are re-statements of goals or of the findings of it seems as if basic Education Management In-
studies or seem unrealistically limited. For exam- formation System (EMIS) data on some 90
ple, the Plan states as one of its aims: “to develop a percent of the schools at the primary level are
system and mechanism of educational planning and missing from the national computer files,
budgeting and also to describe the annual targeting meaning that only about 10 percent of schools
and budgeting,” but this receives no more descrip- are reporting their data (or districts are for-
tion than is contained in this quotation and is
scheduled only as one activity (not described) per
warding the data) to the central government.
year in the Plan. However, it does indicate that the At the secondary level, it might be as high as
MoNE is at least aware of the issues. 25 percent, but this is still far from ideal.

6
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

ting out the highest-order “functional” division


Schools can receive funding (for either recur- of labor: that between governance and man-
rent or capital expenditures), projects, and in- agement. The distinction between ideal gov-
puts from any one of three government levels: ernance and management roles is not a precise
the district, the province, and the national gov- science and the distinctions are often muddled
ernment. There do not seem to be clear, func- in most societies. But it is clear that the con-
tioning protocols that would prevent a fusions in Indonesia are more fundamental
proliferation of procedures and orders and to than in most other societies with serious
ensure that funding goes through a simple growth ambitions. It will be difficult to make
management chain and is received by local much progress unless there is some consensus
managers as single sources. (Though some on such basic organizational issues. Outlining
local managers have created “virtual” single- in diagrammatic form how the sector should
source funding by internally consolidating the function, along these two “lines,” may seem
funding sources. However, this requires con- risky and too prescriptive. However, the lack
siderable skill.) of clarity is a real problem. Thus, to achieve
clarity, sooner or later such diagrams will need
The absence of clear definitions of functions, to be created, and it is important that, when
the vacillation and tendencies to re-centralize, they are created, they reflect a clear vision.
tend to cause widespread anxiety (“apathies The fact that there is confusion at present is
and confusion” as expressed in a MoNE evident in various documents. For example, a
document), expressed not only by respected MoNE report (MoNE, 2002b, p. 16) shows an
Indonesian education experts but also by in- informal diagram of a section of the govern-
ternational donors (Wiradinata and Mudya- ance structure that implies that Bupatis are ac-
hardja, 2002, pp. vii-viii; Sudharto, 2002, pp. countable to the DPRDs (or vice versa)
2-3; Supriyoko, 2002, pp. vii, 18, 19, 26; and through the district-level Education Boards. It
World Bank, 2002b, p. 25). is not clear that this is what Kepmen
044/U/2002 intended, nor is it clear that this
The Basic Challenge: Clarifying would be a sensible arrangement.
Governance and Management
Functions In various proposals it is suggested (or as-
sumed) that School Committees be account-
The preceding section provides evidence that able to district-level education boards. Thus,
the decentralization process is still quite con- basic confusion around governance and man-
fused, and that management and governance agement hierarchies that could work is quite
of the sector are weak. This section turns to common.
the basic causes of confusion. As noted
above, two key challenges need to be ad- Figure 1.1 represents a best attempt to inter-
dressed before any others: (i) the lack of clar- pret the law and to reflect what is taking place
ity about the different governance “functions” at the district level based on our interviews. It
and (ii) the lack of clarity about the manage- also represents a good organization of func-
ment improvements needed to implement tions and responsibilities for a country of In-
those functions. We now look closely at each donesia’s size and complexity.7 An advantage
of these questions in turn. of diagramming these basic functions is that
this can clarify the differences between the
Unclear Sectoral Organization for governance functions and the management
Management and Governance functions. For now, we present this diagram
It emerged during our interviews with experts as merely a work in progress. Clearly, a better
that there is as yet no clear agreement on a ba-
sic organizing diagram of the sector (not just
7
in Depdiknas but in the sector as a whole) set- Particularly at the school level, since at this level
the regulations are still not finished.

7
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Figure 1.1 Governance and Managerial Accountability in a Decentralized Indonesia

Governance or Management
Representative Aspect of or Executive Aspect of
Government: Government:
Governance Accountability Management Accountability

President of the
MPR Republic

DPR

MoHA MoF

Depdiknas National
Level
standard-setting report on
(sets standards of reporting organization of
on financial and educational issues) regional government
(accountability is around standards) through MoHA,
reporting to standards

(Provincial Level)

DPRD reporting to standards Regents, Mayors


(Regional People's (Bupati, Walikota)
Representative Kabupaten/
Assembly) Kota
reporting to standards
Education Level
Boards/Councils Head of District
Education Service
(Kepala Dinas
Pendidikan)

reporting to standards

School
Committees Principals
reporting to standards School
Level

picture will emerge as a result of the discus- ity is strongly “horizontal” as be-
sions that this report will stimulate. fits a truly decentralized system.

For the sake of simplicity, the diagram skips 2. The whole notion of a governance
the provincial and sub-district levels. The fol- “line” is unfamiliar in the Indone-
lowing aspects should now be clear: sian context. Given the nature of
public sector management in the
1. There is a clear governance “line” past, the governance and man-
that runs vertically down the left- agement lines were essentially one
hand side of the graphic and a and the same, with governance be-
clear management “line” running ing largely vertical, hierarchical,
down the right side. Accountabil- and indistinguishable from man-

8
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

agement. In Law 22/1999 passed should ideally be not more than


in 1999, it was stipulated that one management and one govern-
there should now be a governance ance entity per level. Making
line and that it should be non- Education Boards and School
hierarchical and should have a Committees play an advisory role
strong “horizontal” accountability – a loose form of governance –
(for example, Bupati to DPRD). might make the most sense. Note
Yet, the distinctions between the that this is quite different from the
governance and management lines role suggested for School Com-
are not clear in this law or in sub- mittees both in Figure 1.1 and in
sequent regulations, nor do they various policy documents, such as
seem to be clear in the minds of the new Education Act (at least if
officials as reflected in conflicting one interprets it in that direction—
or confused viewpoints in various interpretation is key, as the Act
official documents and interviews tends to be vague). The suggested
conducted for this review. Further role for School Committees is in-
policy dialogue and analyses will deed a true governance role with
be needed to clarify how this respect to schools.
change can work in practice.
6. Because there are no vertical lines
3. The diagram makes it clear that at on the governance side, it is clear
each level of government there is that there is no hierarchy in the
one (and ideally only one) gov- governance of the decentralized
ernance entity and one (and ide- education system. It is also clear
ally only one) management entity. that those in the management line
report to those in the governance
4. The diagram highlights the role of line because.
Depdiknas as a national standard-
setting body. However, there are This diagram is not meant to be a prescription.
other important but non- It is a good interpretation of what the basic
hierarchical roles that Depdiknas laws require, and of what best international
could or should perform, such as practice suggests. It also points out the impor-
disseminating best practices and tance of parental voice at the local level, via
creating a training facility for up- horizontal accountability of schools to parents.
grading management skills. Yet it is meant only to suggest that Indone-
sians ought to try to achieve diagrammatic
5. The governance line represents clarity of this type in this area.
the political entities that are clos-
est to the citizen – the representa- The Roles Assigned to the Central
tives of the electorate. This Government are not Optimal
includes the DPR, DPRDs, and
School Committees. Note that the Aside from making clear distinctions between
Education Boards play an inter- the governance line and the management line,
mediate and (for now) ambiguous it is also important to make sure that different
role and, therefore, straddle the levels in the management line play roles ap-
two lines. The diagram makes it propriate to a system where governance is
clear that the concept of an Educa- horizontal and non-hierarchical. At the top of
tion Board is not entirely clear and the system, in Indonesia, this has not yet
that thinking of it as either a gov- started to take place. The lack of determina-
ernance or management entity is tion of a clear and appropriate role for the cen-
likely to create problems as there ter of the system blocks the emergence of

9
Education Sector Review Volume 2

clear and appropriate roles for other levels, has been much discussion on the issue (see
because one of the key roles the center is not Jalal and Musthafa, 2001).
performing well is precisely to help determine
an appropriate (appropriate to a non- The Current Internal Organization and
hierarchical governance line) assignment of Size of Depdiknas Should be Improved.
functions for other levels.
Given that the role or task of Depdiknas is still
The central government has not yet adapted to not truly appropriate, the internal organization,
being at the apex of a decentralized system it follows, is also not appropriate. Since the
rather being than the sole decision-maker as in government of Indonesia has not yet arrived at
the past. The impulse of central politicians a final and optimal function assignment and
and civil servants is to make things happen, since organizational form should follow func-
for example, by building schools or ordering tion, it is difficult to prescribe improvements
them to be built. It has not become second na- for Depdiknas in any detail. However, judg-
ture to them to steer and support, to set norms ing by the organizational structures in the na-
and regulate wisely and unobtrusively, to re- tional-level education ministries of many
search and disseminate, to encourage innova- countries that are decentralized or effective or
tion, and to provide technical advice to the rest both, it can be stated that Indonesia’s Depdi-
of the system rather than actually to do the knas is not optimally organized to provide
“direct” work of education, such as managing support and guidance to lower-level govern-
teacher deployment or textbook design and ment units and schools.
procurement.
The national level of modernizing and decen-
This is partly because central government staff tralizing ministries is characterized by:
do not yet have the skills to perform their new
functions, and they are understandably wary of x Less focus on traditional “level”
performing functions for which they do not line functions such as early child-
have the requisite skills. It is also possible hood, primary, and secondary, and
that there are fewer rent-seeking opportunities more focus on “transversal” sup-
for them in their new functions than there port functions such as governance
were in their old roles, and therefore they are improvement, financial equaliza-
resisting abandoning their old ones, which tion, and quality assurance. The
were more profitable. It is also likely that cen- latter functions have more staff
tral government staff lack the process man- and more status, in a decentralized
agement and substantive skills not only to do or modern ministry, relative to the
their new jobs well but to finalize the defini- “level” functions.
tion of decentralization. (For example, it takes
a combination of process management skills x Relatively less focus on support-
and substantive knowledge of public manage- ing direct execution of projects
ment to arrive at solutions that are consen- and hence less staff devoted to in-
sual—and hence likely to be implemented—as spection and audit functions, and
well as technically sound.) This is logical. these functions tend to carry less
Since decentralization, at least in initial design status.
aspects, is a one-off event, most staff naturally
have not had practice in designing decentrali- x If there is procurement, focus is
zation processes. As an example, the critical on the procurement not so much
issue of teacher management, and which as- of goods and construction services
pects of this function should be relatively de- but of analytical and developmen-
centralized or centralized is still unresolved; tal services.
there is also uncertainty about whether it will
be re-centralized, despite the fact that there

10
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

x A separation of functions between cial ministers with a very small secretariat.


organizational units supporting The United States, a country about 25 percent
narrow issues of human resources larger than Indonesia, has around 5,000 educa-
or budgeting as they apply to the tion staff at the federal level. Some develop-
national ministry itself and to pro- ing countries, such as China, Argentina, or
jects run by the national level and South Africa, have as few as a few hundred or
support functions that apply to the not much more than a thousand staff at the
country as a whole. For example, federal or national level. However, this is not
in a modernized ministry, human a problem because the training and capacity of
resource management, as it ap- staff matter much more than their numbers.
plies nationwide to, for example, How much time that staff spend on highly lev-
teacher evaluation, deployment, eraged task on appropriately assigned func-
and development, is quite separate tions at the national ministry is also key. Staff
from human resource manage- who are extremely capable and who focus
ment as it applies to the staff of their work on the overall direction of the edu-
the ministry itself. However, it is cation sector, policy, measurement of outputs,
important for the ministry units and comparisons between schools and be-
working on policy issues to main- tween sub-national governments, are much
tain practical links with units more important than sheer numbers at the apex
working on internal issues, be- of a decentralized system. Sheer numbers
cause the latter tend to have more simply do not make up for a lack of ability in
experience with practical adminis- the tasks that are required in a central ministry
trative matters (such as the han- in the context of a decentralized system. So
dling of personnel databases). If Indonesia faces the prospect of having too
the units dealing with national large a staff, most of whom are not trained to
policy on, for example, teacher operate in the decentralized system. This not
management, do not have experi- only consumes resources needlessly but also
ence with the practical issues, they creates a built-in interest group that has an in-
tend to become too theoretical. centive to maintain things as they always have
Thus, it is a good idea for the been. This is a serious problem that must be
units making policy on the financ- confronted. The size of the central bureauc-
ing of schools, for example, to racy is not just a technical problem, but one
collaborate with the units super- that can politically slow down decentraliza-
vising the financial execution of tion.
nationally run projects and to un-
derstand the policies and proce- Size is also an issue when it comes to spend-
dures used in this execution. ing power. The proportion of the total educa-
tion budget spent by the national level in
Appendix 1.5 contains a fuller discussion of decentralized countries varies but in general is
these issues and presents, for discussion pur- higher than the proportion of staff working at
poses, an organigram for Depdiknas that might national level. This is because the staff work-
better suit Indonesia’s needs than the current ing at national level in decentralized countries,
organigram. as noted above, have a great deal more lever-
age over resources than similar staff in a cen-
With regard to size, it should be noted that na- tralized system or than similar staff at the
tional-level ministries in many decentralized lower levels of government in a decentralized
countries have very few staff. One extreme in system. Spending by central education minis-
the developed world is Canada, where the na- tries as a percentage of total spending at the
tional education level in fact functions with a pre-tertiary level in decentralized countries
staff of at most a few dozen, since there is no ranges all the way from less than 10 percent
national ministry but only a council of provin- (in China, the US, South Africa, and Hungary)

11
Education Sector Review Volume 2

to as high as 20-40 percent (in Australia, Po- ple, not to educational substance), effective
land, and Spain). law should, among other things:

Are Current Policies Helping? x Make the rights and responsibilities of


specific actors (as people with the ca-
The problems described above were common
pacity to delegate) clear. For exam-
as Indonesian decentralization got under way
ple, the law should say “The Minister
in 2002. We have seen that the division of la-
has the responsibility to…” or “par-
bor between levels and branches of govern-
ents have the responsibility to…”
ment is not as clear and productive as it could
be, and that central government has not re- x Specify responsibilities in terms of
structured itself, yet, to fully support decen- governance procedures (for example,
tralization. But policy-making has not stood procedures for electing governing
still. Are the more current policies likely to bodies to govern schools) as well as
fully resolve these problems? In this section substantive tasks (the actual duties of
we examine two recent policies or policy governing bodies).
trends, namely the recent Education Act and x Deal as much as possible with con-
the process of setting Minimum Service Stan- crete institutions, such as “schools,”
dards. We find that the problems are not rather than with abstractions, such as
likely to be fully resolved by these initiatives, “education.”
at least as they stood as of this writing. How- x Not give the same responsibilities to
ever, the currently evolving policies do often more than one actor.
point in an appropriate general direction. For x Specify processes for resolving con-
example, the Education Act does begin to lay tradictions and differences between
a better legal basis for school-based manage- actors.
ment or autonomy. Similarly, the notion of x Deal with observable behavior, not at-
defining standards is, at heart, a good one, titudes or beliefs.
even though the specifics are not yet imple- x Be as specific as possible, leaving
mented as well as they could be. only truly technical details to be de-
fined by subsequent regulations, and
The Education Act as an Instrument of no detail should be postponed until
Governance Design regulation merely because it presents a
difficult policy problem or social is-
During the course of this Education Sector sue.
Review, a new law to shape all of Indonesia’s x Duties and prerogatives as actions that
education system was produced by the Minis- key actors must take, as opposed to
try of Education and passed by the legislative those that the actors may take, should
assembly, the DPR. The result is Act No. be specified. This makes the obliga-
20/2003, the Act on the National Education tion to act clearer when the action is
System (English version Gazette No. 78, something that an actor must do (an
2003). An effective education law can be of obligation, responsibility, or duty), but
considerable assistance in clarifying rights and the right to act is also clearer, when it
responsibilities (or duties and powers) in an is something the actor may do (a right,
education governance system. Naturally, an or power). Thus, both rights and re-
effective law is a necessary but far from suffi- sponsibilities are spelled out.
cient condition for an effective education sys-
x Ensure that definitions are clearly a
tem. Examples of countries with clear
matter of clarifying a concept and are
education legislation include South Africa,
not mixed with statements of intent or
Singapore, and Malaysia. Judging from such
belief or with the specification of ac-
examples (and noting that these pointers refer
tions.
exclusively to process and governance princi-

12
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

As the process of legal drafting proceeded, the tion system is the responsibility of the
bill noticeably improved in several of these Minister” (article 50). Though again,
dimensions. However, the law that was even- the word “management” is vague and
tually signed by the President in July of 2003 open to interpretation, because spe-
is still far from ideal. For example: cific rights and duties are not dis-
cussed.
x There are at least 35 calls for further x Key aspects of the way in which the
regulation in areas that require major system functions are regulated
policy decisions rather than technical vaguely on the one hand but over-
details, thus glossing over key matters. regulated on the other. Just to take
All of the further regulations appear to one example, the vital issues of stan-
be the duties or rights of the national dard-setting, certification, evaluation,
government. Should there be regula- and minimum standards is covered in
tions issued by a regional government at least five different articles (or more
that contradict the Act, it is not clear depending on how one interprets the
which regulation should prevail. law) that define duties that are likely
x Rights and responsibilities too often to seriously overlap or duplicate each
devolve on more than one actor (as in other (articles 35, 59, 60, 62, and 66).
“the [national] government and the re-
gional government must guide and It may seem that all these issues can be re-
develop educational staff”). This solved in later regulations. This is certainly
phrase appears about 15 times, often true in principle and happens in all countries.
in crucial contexts. However, in Indonesia there are two problems
x The nature of the actors is left vague, with this.
so that the Act often specifies that it is
“the government” that has a responsi- First, the whole legal and regulatory approach
bility, not the Kepala Dinas, or the has been characterized by a lack of specificity,
Bupati/Walikota, or the national Min- with the resolution of important problems al-
ister. ways being deferred to a later date. Also, once
x The language used in the law is often the problem has eventually been specifically
quite vague, saying that some level of addressed, it is often open to a very wide mar-
government will “coordinate” or “fa- gin of interpretation. Thus, for example, if the
cilitate” or “guide” or “assist” or “su- law appears to create overlaps (for example, as
pervise” some function that another noted above where five different articles of the
level is actually in charge of deliver- Education Act deal with standard-setting and
ing. Language such as “manage” or quality control), this will simply not be re-
“coordinate” or “facilitate” is often solved during the regulation drafting stage,
used without any apparent substance because those who are drafting the regulation
behind the language or without distin- work in separate groups, and thus have often
guishing what might be meant by the lost sight of the overall context.
different versions of the same concept.
x The law seems to attempt to take back A second problem with delaying the resolution
many functions that one would as- of important problems to a subsequent regula-
sume to be the prerogative of local tion is that this regulation is unlikely to be
government, based on previous gov- taken as seriously as a fully fledged law
ernment legislation and regulations. passed by the DPR. This means that there are
One example would be the issue of more opportunities for mistakes, uninformed
teacher management and employment, actions, a lack of transparency, and self-
and another would be the notion that interested actions on the part of the executive
“the management of national educa- branch (since it is this branch that drafts regu-
lation), and other governance failures is much

13
Education Sector Review Volume 2

greater than if the regulation was clearer to in no small measure to a lack of clarity in the
begin with. In any case, in drafting the secon- legislation, including the definition of termi-
dary regulation, it would be wise to follow the nology (see Donor SPM Working Group,
principles of good education regulation, which 2002, also GTZ-Support for Decentralization
are similar to the principles of good education Measures et Al, 2003). (This problem is com-
legislation as listed above (while bearing in pounded by the Education Law, No. 20/2003,
mind that they refer to process and legal prin- as noted in other sections of this chapter.)
ciples, rather than educational substance). In However, in spite of a rocky start, the process,
particular, it would be a positive development under a MoHA-led “model-building” exercise,
if the secondary regulation were sufficiently had produced a set of draft minimum stan-
specific not to require a third regulation to dards for the education sector by mid-2003
clarify its details. (Departemen Pendidikan Nasional/Unit Fasili-
tasi Desentralisasi Pendidikan, 2003).
In spite of the above problems with the Act, it
is important to note that it does make positive In gauging the likely impact of minimum
contributions. It, for example, lays out the le- standards on decentralized governance, it is
gal basis for notions of school autonomy and important to note that there is no accepted
school-based management for the first time at body of theory or practice that can be used as
this high level. (In practice there are many pi- a solid basis for guidance (see Ferrazzi, 2002).
lot experiments taking place, but they have lit- However, minimum standards can also be ap-
tle high-level legal basis.) proached from the point of view of more gen-
erally accepted practical and theoretical
Minimum Service Standards notions of decentralization and intergovern-
mental public finance (see Smoke, 2002 and,
Minimum Service Standards (Standar Pelaya- for interesting similarities to a very different
nan Minimal–SPM) are a potentially useful sector with salutary lessons for education, see
tool of management and governance. How- Baker and Trémolet, 2000). It also makes
ever, if misapplied, they can be a hindrance or, sense to anchor the discussion of SPMs in the
worse, can actually undermine decentralized specific context of the overall process of de-
governance. This section tackles the issue of centralization in Indonesia. If one then adds
whether SPMs in Indonesia, as the situation what little international evidence does exist,
currently stands, are likely to be more of a one has some basis for judging the current
help than a hindrance. A more detailed dis- state of affairs with regard to education SPMs
cussion is presented in Appendix 1.6. in Indonesia according to the certain criteria.
A detailed analysis (contained in Appendix
The basic decentralization law, No. 22/1999, 1.6) of the current draft education SPMs sug-
is silent on the issue of minimum standards. It gests the following:
is Government Regulation No. 25/2000 that
calls for the preparation of guidelines for de- x Numbers: There are too many, nearly
termining SPMs that must be “implemented” 200. This leads to a loss of focus and
by local governments. Other recent regula- increases rather than decreases the
tions, such as Government Regulation 105 of transaction costs of accountability.
2000, have specified that local government Reducing the numbers should be
budgets should be performance-oriented, strongly considered.
based on minimum standards that measure
x Type: Most of the existing indicators
performance. Government Regulation 108 of
are not true service standards aimed at
2000 also calls for minimum standards in the
improving service to citizens, such as
evaluation of local government performance.
the number of days it takes the school
In response to these various regulations, Indo-
to provide a service to parents, or mu-
nesia began in 2002 to devise some SPMs
tual accountability between service
with some false starts and some confusion due
units, such as the number of weeks it

14
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

takes the Dinas Pendidikan to supply a x Level at which measured: Too many
school with books or to get a teacher of the indicators have little practical
promoted. Serious work should be manifestation at the level of the unit of
done to include more true service delivery and/or data on these indica-
standards. tors are often not routinely collected
x Motivation and use: The motivation and reported upward by the actual
for adopting SPMs is too often the de- service unit (for example, schools or
sire for bureaucratic reporting along districts). Thus, it requires special ef-
the management line rather than citi- fort to collect these data—a special ef-
zen accountability along the govern- fort that may be in no one’s inherent
ance line. There is insufficient interest, even under a good system of
realization at the national level of the horizontal accountability. Thus, they
usefulness of indicators in a decentral- will tend not to be collected or re-
ized and democratic system as tools ported. These sorts of indicators need
whereby horizontal accountability can to be reduced or eliminated. Note that
be monitored. There also appears to the current system is barely capable of
be a motivation to protect special or reporting upward even such basic in-
sub-sectoral interests (such as sports dicators as enrollment data, or rather
or teachers’ privileges rather than their there is a lack of incentive to do so.
rights and responsibilities as profes-
sional agents) via the setting of SPMs, It would appear that a large amount of work is
with a consequent loss of focus on the still needed on the education SPMs before
most important issues, such as the de- they can be an effective element of the sec-
livery of general and basic education. tor’s governance and management. Standards
x Technical quality: The technical qual- are necessary, in principle, however, and a
ity of a few of the indicators is low. start has been made.
They are non-measurable, at least as
Governance and Management Systems
currently specified, either in theory or
in practice. Lacking
x Level to be reached: For many of the So far this chapter has noted that policies have
indicators, it makes little sense to been confusing and often inappropriate, that
specify an actual level to be reached. there are objective, measurable problems in
Furthermore, the logic of setting up an the governance of the sector. The more recent
indicator framework and allowing policies have attempted to clarify, and do help
competition and emulation to deter- in some ways, but they still need much work.
mine the actual level to be reached In particular, practical ways to implement cur-
appears not to be understood, or, if rent policies are needed. Furthermore, many
understood, utilized in the standard- progressive districts have proceeded to im-
setting exercise. For some key vari- plement in innovative ways, under the flexibil-
ables, in a country with as little ex- ity allowed by decentralization. In any case,
perience with competitive electoral pilot projects, often donor-funded, have been
processes as Indonesia and with poor experimenting with techniques such as school-
horizontal accountability mechanisms, based management and more transparent
the level should be set by the central school budgeting for many years. However,
government (albeit with a locally de- this experimentation has thus far taken place
termined speed of approach to the without the education system as a whole
goal), but in other cases there is no evaluating and learning from these experi-
theoretical or practical justification for ences, at a central level (but not necessarily by
setting a level.

15
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Depdiknas)8, and then spreading them through ized management but instead on random ideas,
better norming and standardization around tradition, and the experience of other countries
good practices. Also, because experimenta- that ignores their different historical and po-
tion and pilot testing has been largely up to litical contexts. For example, some experts
donors and innovative Bupatis, progress has are suggesting that the Education Boards
tended to be a hit-or-miss affair. To improve should have the same functions as similar
on this, systematization of good practice is boards in other countries, despite the fact that
needed. As central policy also improves, sys- the Indonesian context is very different and
tems for implementing the improved regula- that, even in those other countries (such as the
tion will be needed. This section lays out US and Japan), the boards are controversial
some of these systems needs, as “technical and are still evolving.
challenges,” first in governance and then in
management. Again, this is because of the absence of a
management and governance framework
Technical Challenges in Governance within which these roles could be defined. At
the moment, it seems that each district is being
There are several important issues relating
left to design these roles largely on its own.
specifically to the governance “line.” For ex-
(There are some donor projects working in
ample, the governance bodies at each level
these areas, but the lessons provided by these
have no way to evaluate the educational ap-
projects do not seem to become part of the
propriateness of legislation, policies, and regu-
mainstream.) This is not a healthy approach to
lations independently of the executive branch.
decentralization. It leaves the lower levels of
The lack of access by governance bodies to
government to wrestle with difficult concep-
technical analysis is a reason often given for
tual tasks that may be beyond their capacity,
placing personnel appointed from the execu-
while taking away from them some of the ac-
tive branch of government in governance or
tual management tasks, such as teacher man-
legislative-like bodies. However, it would be
agement, that they may be more than capable
far better to develop research and analysis
of handling. In a sense, the wrong functions
mechanisms for governance bodies or to pro-
are decentralized.
vide legislatures with research and analysis
consultants rather than to continue setting up
The duties and powers of School Committees
bodies with both elected and appointed mem-
are a crucial matter to define clearly, and with
bers from the executive branch.
a view to autonomy and real school-based
management. Current legislation does not do
The current role of Education Boards in the
this. Current viewpoints, both in general and
kabupaten/kota is not necessarily efficient.
relative to school principals, are not clear or
Specifically, the division of labor between
efficient, at least as they are currently defined
Education Boards and DPRDs, between Edu-
either in Kepmen 044/U/2002 or in legislation
cation Boards and kepala dinas, and between
such as the 2003 Education Law. For exam-
Education Boards and School Committees
ple, their roles in finance and teacher man-
does not appear to be effective. Much of the
agement as outlined in existing regulations
ongoing discussion in Indonesia on this issue
and legislation are not clear, conflict with each
is not based on sound principles of decentral-
other, and may be too demanding in certain
areas and not demanding enough in other ar-
8 eas. The fact that the Committees should, ide-
In Brazil’s CONSED, for example, it is the state educa-
tion secretaries manage the organization, not the national ally, have oversight rights over all financial
minister of education. And, as noted elsewhere in this matters, not just the issues related to parent-
report, Canada does not even have a national Ministry, raised funds, is not made clear. The relation-
but this does not mean national functions are not per- ship between the old BP3s and the School
formed. There are many ways to perform national func-
Committees, and the question of whether BP3s
tions via bottom-up association, delegation to non-
governmental entities, etc. should even exist after School Committees are

16
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

in power, is not clear. The separation between exam for one academic subject for madrasah
the governance and the professional manage- schools and then all of the exams are shared
ment of the pedagogical process is not clear. by all of the districts, thus taking advantage of
The legal status of the School Committees, economies of scale. However, no one has yet
relative to their duties, is also not clear. Many researched the ideal features of this kind of
of their duties appear to require them to enter collaboration, such as what kinds of tasks
into contracts with providers (e.g., for minor would most usefully be performed in collabo-
physical plant improvements), but it is not ration and how to develop effective collabora-
clear whether they have the legal right to enter tion agreements.
into contracts, and if so, how this will be sup-
ported with legal assistance to schools, should Technical Challenges in Management
they require it. Again, each district could
In terms of management, it is clear that the
simply be left to determine its own issues and
systems that are currently in place at lower
design its own solutions, but this would be in-
levels of government are not sufficient to per-
efficient.
form the many functions that are being allo-
cated to these levels in the decentralization
To study such issues and determine optimal
process. It is also clear that the staff at these
solutions would require a considerable degree
levels do not have the necessary skills to carry
of technical skill, which is unlikely to be
out their new and expanded roles.
available at the local level. Also, this kind of
organizational research is subject to econo-
Some districts have conducted interesting ex-
mies of scale, meaning that leaving each one
periments in improving their budgeting and fi-
of around 390 district governments to carry
nance systems. For example, projects such as
out its own research and design would be quite
the DSSD have experimented with setting
inefficient. Since there is plenty of interna-
formulae for district–to–school funding and
tional experience on these issues, it would
with simplifying budgeting formats. The ex-
make sense for Indonesia to draw on that ex-
perimentation allowed or encouraged by de-
pertise at the highest level and for the gov-
centralization will also allow natural variations
ernment to ensure that effective norms or at
in practices (e.g., budgeting systems) to
least examples of best practices are developed
emerge. For example, one dynamic Bupati
and made available to districts. Deriving these
has managed to eliminate certain fees by con-
lessons and making sure that good practice
solidating schools and reducing certain types
spreads is a central function, but not one that
of expenditure, thus making room in the
need be performed by Depdiknas.
budget to eliminate fees and still cover costs.
However, the lessons from these various ex-
It is not yet clear how to organize the decen-
periments have not been systematically docu-
tralized governance of religious and/or private
mented at the national level or analyzed to see
schools without unduly affecting their inde-
how applicable they might be to other situa-
pendence. Various interviewees highlighted
tions. Also, even in those districts that have
the need to resolve this issue carefully.
been experimenting, it is not always clear that
their evolving financial arrangements are
At the moment, many functions have been de- ideal. For example, it is not clear how much
centralized too far, in other words down to a authority is really being devolved to schools,
level that does not have the capacity to per- even in these districts. It emerged during our
form that function effectively. Having recog- interviews that personnel at the district level
nized this, some districts and provinces are were not always clear about what functions to
coming together to form agencies that can decentralize to schools and why. Newer dis-
handle certain of their functions on a collec- trict-to-school funding approaches that were
tive basis (as suggested in Law 22/1999). For called “block funding” were not really block
example, various districts in East Java are col- funding and seemed to be just as cumbersome
laborating so that each district develops the

17
Education Sector Review Volume 2

and intrusive as previous approaches. The There has not yet been a universal (all dis-
current laws and regulations often seem to tricts, not just a sample) audit of skills at the
give away authority with one hand but take it district level covering all functions that would
back with the other, leaving the system more probably need to be performed at that level
complicated than before and no more decen- under a rational model of decentralization.
tralized. While districts must be responsible for raising
their own skills to the necessary level to carry
There is a great deal of confusion surrounding out their decentralized functions, the national
the allocation of functions related to teacher government is responsible for the maintenance
management (including training, recruitment, of standards. Therefore, it seems appropriate
deployment, performance evaluation, human that the national government should be re-
resources databases, payroll, and redeploy- sponsible for carrying out a nationwide, dis-
ment). For example, at present, even though trict-level audit of current management skills
responsibility for personnel management is and standards. At a minimum, the central
nominally decentralized to the districts, any government should devise an instrument and
personnel actions that would result in changes protocol for carrying out such an audit and for
in the payroll database must still be communi- compiling and communicating the results, as
cated to the national level BKN. Because having each district devise its own protocol
there are still tensions and unresolved issues in would be a waste of resources. Current infor-
the assignment of functions, it is not surprising mation systems at the district level do not
that districts do not yet have adequate teacher seem to be capable of reporting reliable statis-
management systems in place. It is vital to re- tics on basic, fundamental issues such as en-
solve the issue of who is responsible for which rollment to the central level. As is shown in
teacher management functions because any in- Box 1.2 and in Appendix 1.3, Case 5, this has
appropriate assignment of these functions (for also been the case in other countries where
example, if the assignment is bureaucratically education functions have been decentralized.
unclear, if it sets up a conflict between bu- This is a problem that needs to be addressed.
reaucracies, or if it is technically unsound) can
lead to financial and other problems. A case
study is shown in Box 1.1, and in Appendix
1.3, Case 2.

Box 1.1 In South Africa, a lack of definition as to who could set minimum standards, combined with
sectoral collusion in teacher management, led to the emergence of unfunded mandates and fiscal prob-
lems after decentralization.

[After decentralization] all provinces experienced similar over-spending, in large part due to implementing
nationally determined policies. This included the nationally negotiated salary agreement and new policies in
the education, health, and welfare sectors. Much of this problem was due to the lack of co-ordination be-
tween policymaking and budgeting, and the rapid creation of a decentralized system compounded this prob-
lem. The implementation of nationally agreed policies was not necessarily an unfunded mandate, however.
Such policies (in education, health, and welfare) were implemented with the full support of provincial line
function departments, who were also involved in developing the policies.

Sectoral collusion to secure more funds for a sector proved to be a far stronger factor in overspending than
unfunded mandates. Intergovernmental forums in education, health, and welfare developed national policy
[especially on standards] without taking into account budgetary resources. Many departments adopted an
aggressive policy to address backlogs in deprived black areas. For instance, differences in teacher-pupil ra-
tios were reduced between black and white schools. The increase in personnel expenditure squeezed out ex-
penditure in non-personnel inputs like textbooks, undermining the attainment of the desired outputs.

From: Momoniat, I. No date. “Fiscal Decentralisation in South Africa: A Practitioner’s Perspective”


http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/publicfinance/documents/South%20Africa.pdf

18
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

Box 1.2 In Brazil and Spain, devising good management information systems under decentralization
was difficult and problematic but was possible with effort and partnership.

Brazil

Until 1995, Brazilian education data were outdated and unsystematic. Since there was no recent information
available, directing government policies in that area was a challenge as difficult as flying a plane in the midst
of a storm with no guiding instrument on board. Not only did the lack of up-to-date information jeopardize
the decision-making process, but it also caused huge waste in the allocation of funds. Furthermore, in the
absence of a standard nationwide system of information and indicators, several states had their own data
gathering and processing systems, which were not compatible with each other. For this reason, Brazil could
not even provide international organizations with consistent data on education.

By the beginning of 1995, the latest school census that was available dated back to 1989, and the last fin-
ished survey had been carried out in 1991. Therefore, there was not enough information available to inform
the design of actions aimed at improving the education system. From that year on, the Brazilian educational
information system has gradually undergone a complete reformulation into an integrated, decentralized and
comprehensive structure, which provides all levels and types of education, from early childhood to tertiary
education and more advanced programs.

Gumaraes de Castro, M.H. 2000. “Role and Value of International Education Indicators For National Policy Develop-
ment.” Fourth General Assembly of the OECD Education Indicators Programme (INES). 11 - 13 September - Tokyo,
Japan.
http://www.inep.gov.br/download/internacional/idioma/Role%20and%20value%20of%20international%20indicators%2
0for%20national%20policy%20development.pdf.

Spain

As the decentralization process unfolded in the 1980s, the country needed a planning mechanism that would
coordinate the educational policies and programs being developed and executed by the MEC and the decen-
tralized autonomous communities (de jure). One reason why such a coordinating mechanism was necessary
was that, soon after the decentralization process began, the capacity to gather and reproduce nationwide edu-
cational statistics was lost because various regions had begun gathering their own data using formats that
were not comparable and thus could not be aggregated at the national level.

From Hanson, M. 2000. “Democratization and Educational Decentralization in Spain: A Twenty Year Struggle for Re-
form.” Country Studies. Education Reform and Management Publication Series. Vol. 1, No. 3, June 2000.
http://www1.worldbank.org/education/globaleducationreform/pdf/hanson.pdf.

The possible increase in corruption under de- tion. On the other hand, having too many
centralization has been brought up in the dis- funding and provisioning channels into
cussions held as a part of this review. In schools creates great opportunities for corrup-
principle, decentralization has the scope either tion or at least for waste. Funding and provi-
to increase or to reduce corruption – the key is sioning that is discretionary and not based on a
the actual design of institutions and systems. simple formula also creates opportunities for
For example, ensuring that resources flow as corruption, waste, and patronage. However,
per capita grants, ensuring that all actors know having too many controls could make systems
the amount of the grants to which they are en- too cumbersome. Therefore, extreme care
titled and when the funds will arrive, and en- needs to be taken in the design of such sys-
suring that actors have oversight over each tems. What is crucial is to bear the potential
other (parents can check what the principal for corruption in mind when designing decen-
does, and the principal can check what parents tralized systems and to create the appropriate
do) can all help to limit the scope for corrup-

19
Education Sector Review Volume 2

checks and balances without paralyzing flows proving and clarifying function definition can
of resources. be informed by emerging practice, in any case,
and because it will help further clarify and
There is considerable inequality within dis- validate experimentation.
tricts in terms of both funding and education
achievement in Indonesia already, and it is not Step 2: Thoroughly inventory existing man-
clear that there are any effective mechanisms agement systems, skills stocks, and innovation
for reducing this source of inequality in the capacity at the local level. Based on how
education sector. As we noted above, asym- functions are assigned in step 1, the next step
metric decentralization of governance and should be to carry out thorough inventory
management, along with funding targeted to- management systems at all levels, particularly
wards the poorest districts and populations in the areas of finance, the management of
within districts, may be one way to reduce ex- personnel (particularly teachers), procurement,
cessive inequality. and information management. This search
should be conducted by means of nationwide
Governance and Management consultations with both system users and sys-
Development Tasks tem developers at all levels or by means of
empirical research. An integral aspect of this
As this chapter makes clear, certain actions stocktaking exercise should be to recommend
need to be taken to clarify the roles and func- improvements and to develop a time-phased,
tions of the various levels of government in demand-led plan for improving management
the governance and management of the new systems. Another important aspect of the ex-
decentralized education system. These actions ercise should be to carry out an audit of the
are listed here, starting with the most impor- current management skills of personnel at
tant and urgent. It is important to note that every level of governance and to map the na-
these steps are not equal in costs or in time. tion’s lack of and need for these skills. The
exercise should go on to suggest ways to de-
Step 1: Clarify and assign functions. This is velop a system (possibly run by outside pro-
the step that must, in principle, be taken before viders) for upgrading skills and a facility for
all others because, without a clear assignment continuously assessing both systems develop-
of functions, nothing else can be clarified. ment and the skills upgrading system, includ-
This can be done through a set of well-guided, ing a yearly or twice yearly repetition of the
specific technical consultations. In other nationwide consultation process. The proposed
words, it is possible to have a technically in- approach should constitute a program that is
formed yet consultative process that leads to a flexible enough to be able to receive funding
solid conclusion; it need not be left up to from a variety of donors without each of these
chance, pure politics, or relatively non- donors having to develop a separate project
technical “least-common denominator” con- that would be expensive and time-consuming
sultations. Furthermore, it is important that to design.
the consultation process yields conclusive rec-
ommendations on the assignment of fairly de- Of all the existing systems and skills, perhaps
tailed sub-functions. This consultative process the most crucial one that needs to be further
(which should last from about six months to a strengthened, documented, and fed into a sys-
year) can be seen as a preliminary form of dis- tem (not necessarily central) of lesson-
semination of the conclusions reached as a re- spreading, is the set of relations of account-
sult of the consultations, but true ability between schools and parent commu-
dissemination should be a separate and ongo- nity. This will not be an easy task, as many
ing process. In practice it may not be possible parents themselves may have lowered expecta-
to be fully sequential, and to take this step tions, conditioned by years of centralism.
first. Districts are moving ahead in any case.
However, it is still worth doing, because im-

20
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

Step 3: Upgrade systems and skills. This step tice, it might be wise to set a five-year time-
will be the most costly and long-lasting by far. frame for completing the systems development
In theory, it could go on forever, but in prac- and skills upgrading process.

21
Education Sector Review Volume 2

References For Chapter 1

Abdillah, M. 2002. “The Existence of Ma- Untuk Melaksanakan Desentralisasi Pendidi-


drasah, Diniyah Education, and Pesanteren in kan” (“Readiness of Provinces and Districts to
the National Education System.” Policy Pa- Implement Education Decentralization.”) Na-
per. Ministry of National Education. Office tional Summary. Propinsi Kalimantan Timur.
of Educational Research and Development. Propinsi Nusa Tenggara Barat. Propinsi Su-
Jakarta. matera Utara.

Abdulhak, I. 2002. “Pre-School Education, Departamen Pendidikan Nasional. 2001. To-


Primary School and Out-of-School Educa- wards High Quality and Equitable Education.
tion.” Policy Paper. Ministry of National National Education Commission Report Ex-
Education. Office of Educational Research ecutive Summary.
and Development. Jakarta.
Djohar. 2002. “The Teacher and Teacher
Aziz, A. 2002. “Madrasah Education in Indo- Education.” Policy Paper. Ministry of Na-
nesia: Potential, Problems, and Issues.” Paper tional Education. Office of Educational Re-
presented at the Symposium on Madrasah search and Development. Jakarta.
Education in the Context of a National Educa-
tion System. Sponsored by the Ministry of DSSD–Capacity Building for Decentralized
Religious Affairs and the Asian Development Social Services Delivery. 2002a. “Draft
Bank. Jakarta, 4 November 2002. Analysis No. 1 On District Results.” Asian
Development Bank ADB TA 3042-INO.
Azra, Azyumardi. 2001. “Civil Society and
Democratization in Indonesia: Transition dur- DSSD–Capacity Building for Decentralized
ing President Wahid’s Rule and Beyond.” Re- Social Services Delivery. 2002b. “Draft
fleksi. Vol. III, No. 3, 2001. Analysis No. 2 On District Financing of
Schools.” Asian Development Bank ADB TA
Baker, B. and S. Trémolet. 2000. “Regulation 3042-INO.
of Quality of Infrastructure Services in Devel-
oping Countries.” NERA. Paper given at the DSSD–Capacity Building for Decentralized
conference on Infrastructure for Development: Social Services Delivery. 2002c. “Draft
Private Solutions for the Poor, London, UK, Analysis No. 3 On School Results.” Asian
31 May – 2 June. Word processed. Development Bank ADB TA 3042-INO.

Bedi, A., and A. Garg. 2000. “The Effective- DSSD–Capacity Building for Decentralized
ness of Private versus Public Schools: the Social Services Delivery. 2002d. “Draft
Case of Indonesia.” Journal of Development Analysis No. 4 On School Integrated Financial
Economics. Vol 61, pp. 463-494. Management System.” Asian Development
Bank ADB TA 3042-INO.
Center for Indonesian Legal and Policy Stud-
ies. 2002. “A Gloomy Picture of the At- Ferrazzi, G. 2002. “Obligatory Functions and
tempts to Eradicate Corruption: Reflection of Minimum Service Standards: A Preliminary
the Policies, Laws, and Institutions of Corrup- Review of the Indonesian Approach,” GTZ-
tion Management in Indonesia, 1969-2001,” in SfDM, Jakarta: Word processed.
Holloway, R., ed., Stealing from the Poor.
Book Four. Jakarta: Aksara Foudation. Filmer, D., N. Suwaryani, and B. Indriyanto.
2001. “Indonesia’s Primary and Junior Sec-
Departamen Pendidikan Nasional, Balan Pene- ondary Schools in a Post-crisis Environment:
litan dan Pengembangan (Balitbang). 2002. Findings from a Follow-up survey of 600
“Studi Kesiapan Propinsi dan Kabupaten/Kota

22
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

Schools.” The World Bank, pre-publication Lewis, B. 2002. “Revenue-Sharing and


version. Grant-Making in Indonesia: The First Two
Years of Fiscal Decentralization.” Word
Furqon and S. Surapranata. 2002. “Evalua- processed. Research Triangle Institute.
tion, Examination, and Assessment of Educa-
tion.” Policy Paper. Ministry of National Malaysia. 1997. Educational Act 1996.
Education. Office of Educational Research
and Development. Jakarta. Mas’udi, M. 2002. “Corruption Through the
Perspective of Culture and Islamic Law,” in
Greene, D. 2000. “Decentralization and Edu- Holloway, R., ed., Stealing from the Poor.
cational Reform in Indonesia.” Consultant’s Book Four. Jakarta: Aksara Foundation.
Report, Word processed. The World Bank
and Asian Development Bank. McMahon, W. with N. Suwaryani, Boediono,
and E. Appiah. 2001. Improving Education
Hickling Indonesia, PT. 2001a. “Education Finance in Indonesia. Policy Research Cen-
Decentralization Policy Recommendations: ter, Institute for Research and Development,
Human Resources.” Development Planning Ministry of National Education, Indonesia,
Assistance Project. Final Report SP-16H. UNICEF and UNESCO.
March.
McMahon, W. and Boediono. 2001. “Im-
Hickling Indonesia, PT. 2001b. “Towards proving Education Funding in Indonesia,” in
Participatory Governance of Education in In- McMahon, W. with N. Suwaryani, Boediono,
donesia. A Report on Regional Consultations and E. Appiah. 2001. Improving Education
in West Sumatra on the Use of School Boards Finance in Indonesia. Policy Research Cen-
and School Committees.” Prepared for Bap- ter, Institute for Research and Development,
penas in collaboration with the Ministry of Ministry of National Education, Indonesia,
Education and The World Bank. Draft 2. UNICEF and UNESCO.

Hum, F. 2002. “Development of Pondok MONE (Ministry of National Education).


Pesanterens as Means of Community-Based 2002. “Education for All: Situational Analysis
Education and Poverty Alleviation.” Paper 2002. Indonesia.” Draft Presented at the Na-
presented at the Symposium on Madrasah tional Forum for Education for All, Jakarta.
Education in the Context of a National Educa-
tion System. Sponsored by the Ministry of MONE (Ministry of National Education).
Religious Affairs and the Asian Development 2003. “The Strategic Planning of The Devel-
Bank. Jakarta, 4 November 2002. opment of Education, Youth and Sport, 2002-
2004.” Limited Draft.
Ikshan, M. 2002. “Measuring the Economic
Costs of Corruption in Indonesia,” in Hollo- Musa, I. 2003. “Reforming the Indonesian
way, R., ed., Stealing from the Poor. Book Education Act.” Background report for Edu-
Four. Jakarta: Aksara Foudation. cation Sector Review 2003. The World Bank.
Unicef Special Service Agreement.
Jalal, F. and B. Musthafa. 2001. Education (SSA/IDSA/2003/00000199-0). January.
Reform in the Context of Regional Autonomy:
The Case of Indonesia. Ministry of National Organisation for Economic Cooperation and
Education and National Development Plan- Development (OECD). 1994. Improving the
ning Agency, Republic of Indonesia, and the Quality of Laws and Regulations: Economic,
World Bank. Legal, and Managerial Techniques.
OCDE/GD(94)59. Paris.
Kepmen No. 044/U/2002. (Decree of the
Minister of National Education. Republic of Said, S. and N. Suhendra. 2002. “Corruption
Indonesia. Concerning The Education Coun- and Indonesian Society,” in Holloway, R., ed.,
cil and School Committee.)
23
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Stealing from the Poor. Book One Jakarta: School Improvement Grants Program.” Draft
Aksara Foudation. May 17. Word processed.

Singapore, Republic of. 1957. Education Act. The World Bank. 2002b. “Decentralizing In-
Ordinance 45 of 1957. Available at donesia.” A Regional Public Expenditure Re-
http://www.lawnet.com.sg/. view. Overview Report. East Asia Poverty
Reduction and Economic Management Unit.
Smoke, P. 2002. “Expenditure Assignment Draft June 15, 2002.
under Indonesia’s Emerging Decentralization:
A Review of Progress and Issues for the Fu- The World Bank. 2002c. “Decentralizing In-
ture.” Prepared for conference on “Can De- donesia. Kota Sukabumi.” A Regional Public
centralization Help Rebuild Indonesia?” Expenditure Review. Overview Report. East
Andrew Young School of Policy Studies, Asia Poverty Reduction and Economic Man-
Georgia State University, Atlanta, Georgia, agement Unit. Draft June 15, 2002.
USA. May 1-3. Word processed.
The World Bank. 2002d. “Decentralizing In-
South Africa, Republic of. 1996. South Afri- donesia. Lombok Timur.” A Regional Public
can Schools Act, No. 84 of 1996. Available at Expenditure Review. Overview Report. East
http://www.gov.za/acts/96index.html. Asia Poverty Reduction and Economic Man-
agement Unit. Draft June 15, 2002.
Sudharto. 2002. “The Improvement of Edu-
cational Supervision System in the Regional The World Bank. 2002e. “Decentralizing In-
Autonomy Era.” Policy Paper. Ministry of donesia. North Sumatra.” A Regional Public
National Education. Office of Educational Expenditure Review. Overview Report. East
Research and Development. Jakarta. Asia Poverty Reduction and Economic Man-
agement Unit. Draft June 15, 2002.
Supriyoko, K. 2002. “Towards the Improve-
ment of Quality and Equity of Secondary Edu- The World Bank. 1998. “Education in Indo-
cation in Indonesia.” Policy Paper. Ministry nesia: From Crisis to Recovery.” Education
of National Education. Office of Educational Sector Unit. East Asia and Pacific Region.
Research and Development. Jakarta.
Warta/CIMU. 2000. Special Issue: History
Syarief, H. 2002. “Madrasah Education: Ac- and Review of the Scholarship and Grants
cess, Quality, Finance, Governance.” Paper Program. August.
presented at the Symposium on Madrasah
Education in the Context of a National Educa- Wiradinata, R. and R. Mudyahardja. 2002.
tion System. Sponsored by the Ministry of “Decentralization and Management of Educa-
Religious Affairs and the Asian Development tional Programs and Activities within the
Bank. Jakarta, 4 November 2002. Framework of Decentralized Service Pat-
terns.” Policy Paper. Ministry of National
The Center for Indonesian Legal and Policy Education. Office of Educational Research
Studies. 2002. “A Gloomy Picture of the At- and Development. Jakarta.
tempts to Eradicate Corruption: Reflection of
the Policies, Laws, and Institutions of Corrup- Woodhouse, A. 2001. “The dynamics of Ru-
tion Management in Indonesia, 1969-2001,” in ral Power in Indonesia: Fighting Corruption in
Holloway, R., ed., Stealing from the Poor. a Community Development Project.” Novem-
Book Four. Jakarta: Aksara Foudation. ber. Word processed report, Kecamatan De-
velopment Project (KDP), The World Bank.
The World Bank. 2002a. “An Assessment of
the Scholarships and Grants Program and

24
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

Appendix 1.1. List of Governance and Management Problems


In a discussion document of limited length, it a ministry. For example, several districts
is not possible to list in detail all of the impor- could get together to create a multi-district
tant issues that still need to be resolved. For agency to carry out a certain task. In some in-
that reason, the following table contains a stances, a ministry or some other agency may
more comprehensive catalog of such issues have undertaken tasks on behalf of a district,
than was possible in the main text but without which is why the list for the “national” level is
a full discussion of each one. Only a few are longer than the list of issues at the local level.
discussed in greater detail in the main text to We are not advocating a large role for the cen-
give the reader a sense of the nuances in- tral government under decentralization. Nev-
volved in some of the most important cases. ertheless, clearly the national or provincial
governments could play an important role by
In the table below, “national” does not neces- taking advantage of economies of scale in
sarily pertain to a bureaucratic or organiza- helping districts to develop management sys-
tional entity. Some of these functions are tems. Finally, note that province-level issues
indeed functions that need to take place at the are not fully explained because, in large part,
MoNE, but others can be performed by some function assignment itself is not finished and,
other national ministry. Still others could be while the roles for the national and district
performed by a national-level organization (or levels are relatively obvious and easy to sug-
any organization at a level of government gest based on logic, this is not so much the
higher than the district) but not necessarily in case for the province level.

Governance and Management Issues


Management “Line” Governance “Line”
National 1. Increase the MoNE’s abil- 11. Develop clearer sense and acceptance
level ity to assess decentralized best at the MoNE of its national role in a decentral-
practice by improving its monitor- ized setting. This needs to be done with more
ing and evaluation functions/roles. technical proficiency and depth than has been
2. Change the nature of the done thus far.
Inspectorate towards evaluating 12. Finalize implementing rules and pro-
whether sub-national levels are fol- cedures for Education Law
lowing general standards. 13. Resolve governance standards for
3. Set up permanent facility Education Boards as well as School Committees,
for evaluating and improving stan- while making sure these align with the
dards. forthcoming law. Standards should be
4. Assess skills profile mandatory. If not, then DEPDIKNAS should
needed to carry out assigned func- offer more than one non-mandatory model with
tions at all system levels. clear reasons for preferring one over another
5. Carry out systematic backed up by good research.
management and governance skills 14. Develop criteria for asymmetric decen-
audit against assigned governance tralization, since not all schools are likely to be
and management functions and the ready to take on new powers at the same time.
skills required. 15. Resolve issue of decentralization of re-
6. Create, fund, and manage ligious and/or private education. Come up with
a facility for upgrading manage- feasible district-level governance model that is
ment and governance capacity and standard across districts.
skills at sub-national levels accord- 16. Finalize initial standards and dissemi-
ing to demand. Evaluate feasibility/ nate this information.
requirements of outsourcing if this 17. Convene panel of experts to finalize
is an option. function assignment in detail.

25
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Governance and Management Issues


Management “Line” Governance “Line”
7. Begin formal and in- 18. Ensure the DPR has access to good,
depth process of “re-educating” independent, technical advice.
MoNE staff in their roles and func- 19. Increase capacity of the media to re-
tions in a decentralized setting. port accurately on education issues for example
8. Inventory (in all districts) by training education reporters and instituting a
the existing financial management prize for the best education reporter of the year.
systems, personnel (teacher) man- 20. Produce “map” of civil society, includ-
agement systems, and educational ing NGOs, to educate government officials on
materials procurement systems. this nature of NGOs and civil society. Develop
Evaluate problems, assess interest- training materials and protocols for government
ing experiments developed under officials on this theme.
decentralization, develop approach 21. Develop approach for ensuring sub-
to funding, and develop systems stantive discussion of education issues in the
usable by districts according to 2004 elections.
demand. 22. Develop “scorecard” system for rat-
9. Assess and reproduce ing/ranking districts, Bupatis, etc., in their per-
methods whereby lower-level gov- formance of education functions.
ernments can collaborate to create 23. Develop approach for improving pol-
“agency” bodies to take advantage icy dialogue about education in government (ex-
of economies of scale. ecutive and legislative, at national and possibly
10. Improve management district level), in civil society, and between the
and governance systems to reduce two.
corruption under decentralization. 24. Train staff of lower levels to learn
from governance experience elsewhere as a
means of raising their own performance to stan-
dard.
District 25. Require districts to assess 31. Apply processes for determining dis-
level their own management and gov- trict-specific standards as well as socializing na-
ernance skills against their as- tional standards.
signed functions 32. Ensure that DPRDs know how to hold
26. Start demand-led skills Bupati/Walikota accountable for their education
upgrading by creating and using responsibilities.
capacity-building facility 33. Develop and apply better norms and
27. Require districts to assess guidelines to the functioning of Education
their practices against standards Boards and School Committees, or apply na-
and start reporting according to tional ones.
standards, both up the management 34. Apply system for dissemination and
line (to Bupati/ Walikota) and reporting on school-specific performance against
horizontally to the DPRD standards. Ensure that Education
28. Develop or apply nation- Board/Councils, DPRDs, schools and School
ally developed systems for provid- Committees know about this system.
ing team-based, school-oriented (as 35. Train staff of lower levels in the mean-
opposed to problem-oriented all- ing of new laws and regulations. Train them to
school)response to schools not learn from governance experience elsewhere as a
coming up to performance stan- means of raising their own performance to stan-
dards. dard.
29. Collaborate with each
other and with national or provin-
cial governments in developing fi-
nancial, personnel, procurement,
and information systems.
30. Apply systems as devel-
oped.

26
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

Governance and Management Issues


Management “Line” Governance “Line”
School 36. Require districts to assess 41. Apply governance guidelines on
level their management and governance School Committees.
skills against their assigned func- 42. Train staff of lower levels to learn
tions from governance experience elsewhere as a
37. Start demand-led skills means of raising their own performance to stan-
upgrading by creating and using dard.
capacity-building facility 43. Train School Committees in assessing
38. Require districts to assess their own schools.
their performance against stan- 44. Train School Committees in finances
dards and start reporting according and personnel management.
to standards, both up the manage- 45. Train School Committees on how to
ment line and horizontally to the receive and use information about how to raise
School Committee educational quality up to standard.
39. Apply models for inter-
acting with School Committee
40. Apply decentralized fi-
nancial, personnel, procurement,
and information systems

27
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Appendix 1.2. List of Interviewees


Experts and Policymakers on Governance and Senior researcher, Indonesian Institute of
Management Issues Sciences (LIPI).Sumarno M.A., Ph.D., Drs.
Vice-Director, School of Graduate Studies,
Asshidiqie, Prof. Dr. Jimly. Faculty of Law, Universitas Negeri Yogyakarta.
Universitas Indonesia. Center for Electoral
Reform. Supriyoko, Prof. Dr. Ki. Majelis Luhur
Taman Siswa. National Education Com..
Azra, Prof. Dr. Azyumardi. Rektor, IAIN
Syarif Hidayatullah. Suyanto, Prof. Rektor, Universitas Negeri
Yogyakarta.
Djemari, Prof. Mardapi. Director, School of
Graduate Studies, Universitas Negeri Tobing, Drs. Jacob. Member of Parliament.
Yogyakarta. Commission A on Constitutional
Ammendments to 1945 Constitution.
Madjid, Prof. Dr. Nurcholish. Rector,
Universitas Paramadina. Lecturer, Post-
graduate Faculty, IAIN Syarif Hidayatullah.

Representatives of Education Boards and of School Committees


We selected key members of Education Boards and School Committees in four rural and four urban
areas, yielding 34 interviewees.The urban districts chosen were Benkulu City and Mataram City
(classified as low income) andYogyakarta City and Banjarmasin City (classified as middle-income).
The rural districts included Wonosobo and Lamongan (classified as low income) and Bekasi and
Gianyar (classified as middle income).

Interviewees from Education Boards/Councils

District/City Name of Respondent Position

Yogyakarta City H.M. Wasul Widyo Pranoto, B.A. Member/Chief, Public


Drs. Asmuni Relations Section
Member, Infrastructure
and Facilities Section
District of Bekasi, H. Hanafi Ali Vice-Chairman
West Java Noupal Al Rasyid Secretary
H. Rimin. Member
District of Gianyar, Drs. I Made Susila Secretary I
Bali I Wayan Sudamia, SH Secretary II
Mataram City, H. Adnan Muchsin, Ssi Chairman
Nusa Tenggara Barat Drs. M. Tajuddin, M.Si Secretary
Bengkulu City Drs. Sutrisno, S.A. Chairman
Djajadi Aliamar, B.A. Vice-Chairman
Drs. Z. Fauzi Hamid Secretary
Banjarmasin City, Drs.H. Sultani Secretary I
South Kalimantan
District of Wonosobo, Central Slamet Rahardjo Budi Chairman
Java Drs. Slamet Witoro Secretary II
District of Lamongan, East Drs. Tsalist Fahami, MM Chairman
Java K.H. Abdul Fatah Vice Chairman
Ir. Suhandoyo, SP Secretary

28
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

Interviewees from School Committees

Name of School Name of Respondent Position

SMU Negeri I, Ir. Sagoro Wedy, MM Chairman


Yogyakarta City Drs. Helly P. Soetjipto, MA Member
SD Negeri Jatimulya 04 Tam- Bambang S. Chairman
bun, Bekasi Mirsod Member
West Java

SLTP Negeri I Gianyar, I Pande Ketut Sutara Chairman


Bali
Chairman
SMU Negeri I Gianyar, Bali I Dewa Ketut Alit Budiana
SD Negeri 13 Ampenan, Drs. Sugiyarno Chairman
Mataram, NTB
SLTP Negeri I Bengkulu H. Sukiman, SE Vice Chairman
Herlina Tobing Secretary
SD Negeri Teluk Dalam 4, H. Iskandar Chairman
Banjar-masin, South Kaliman- Yadi ES Vice Chairman
tan Suratno Secretary
SLTP Negeri I, Leksono, Wo- H. Pudjonartojo Chairman
no-sobo, Central Java Kidjo DH Member
SMK Negeri I Lamongan, H. Gholib Kastoer Chairman
East Java Arifin Secretary

In addition, we interviewed representatives of the Bupati and the Dinas Pendidikan Office in the
Jembrana District.

29
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Appendix 1.3. Decentralization Case Studies


Case 1. Mexico: broad decentralization educational governance has not been success-
success but a lack of definition and top- ful.
down implementation has led to insufficient
gains in local governance.  From: Ornelas, Carlos. No date.
“The politics of the educational
Despite erratic policies and political conflicts,
decentralization in Mexico.” At
the decentralization of education in Mexico is
http://www1.worldbank.org/educat
on the move. Whereas it does not represent a
ion/globaleducationreform/pdf/orn
complete devolution to the states—having
elas.pdf.
transferred significantly more management
functions but not full responsibility for cur-
Case 2. South Africa: minimum standards
riculum content, academic evaluation, and
and sectoral collusion in teacher manage-
quality assessment—the states are assuming a
ment has led to unfunded mandates and fis-
large measure of influence over education, and
cal problems.
this is getting larger.
[After decentralization], all provinces experi-
[However,] Chapter VII of the General Law of enced similar over-spending, in large part be-
Education (GLE) provided the basis for creat- cause they were implementing nationally
ing Councils of Social Participation in Educa- determined policies. This included the nation-
tion. These councils were designed to exist at ally negotiated salary agreement and new poli-
every level of the education system in a pyra- cies in the education, health, and welfare
mid fashion from the bottom up, with councils sectors. Much of this problem was due to the
operating in every school, county, and state in lack of co-ordination between policymaking
the nation including representatives from each and budgeting, and the rapid pace of decen-
state council, plus outstanding teachers and tralization compounded this problem. The
scholars, and other distinguished representa- implementation of nationally agreed policies
tives of society. The GLE stated that parent was not necessarily an unfunded mandate,
associations should not be involved in the de- however. Such policies (in education, health,
tails of school management but instead should and welfare) were implemented with the full
concentrate on larger issues. support of education departments at the pro-
vincial level, who were also involved in de-
The SNTE (teacher’s union) leadership did not veloping the policies.
formally oppose the creation of such councils,
but some groups of teacher foresaw the inter- Sectoral collusion to secure more funds
vention of “extraneous” people in school af- proved to be a far stronger factor in over-
fairs, which they considered their exclusive spending than unfunded mandates. Intergov-
terrain. In their Educational Congress of ernmental agencies on education, health, and
1994, foreseeing a threat to weaken the teach- welfare developed national policy [especially
ers’ monopoly in school management, the on standards] without taking into account
SNTE’s national leadership ruled that at least budgetary resources. Many departments
half of the members of such councils must be adopted an aggressive policy to address back-
teachers (Sindicato Nacional de Trabajadores logs in deprived black areas. For instance, in-
de la Educación, 1994). Finally, in September equities in teacher-pupil ratios were reduced
1999, the SEP (the national Ministry of Edu- between black and white schools. The increase
cation) organized the national council with in personnel expenditure squeezed out expen-
many as members but without defining its diture in non-personnel inputs like textbooks,
specific functions. So far, the use of councils undermining the attainment of the desired out-
as a means of instituting wider participation in puts.

30
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

The national government was forced to inter- educators to schools. These new national
vene. It solved the problem of a lack of co- guidelines specified a learner: educator ratio
ordination by creating joint intergovernmental of 1:40 in primary schools and 1:35 in secon-
forums between the Treasury and the relevant dary schools. However, because decisions
national line ministries. For example, a com- about educator numbers and salaries were
mittee was set up comprising the national made at national level [in a process led by the
Ministers of Finance and Education together education authorities] while implementation
with their counterparts in provinces, and this took place at provincial level [with budgets
met at least twice a year to co-ordinate poli- determined by financial authorities], these
cymaking, budgeting, and implementation. agreements were often unaffordable at provin-
These structures are supported by a range of cial level.
large and small technical forums of officials
from national and provincial treasuries and The national process of educator provisioning
line function departments. These forums en- was abandoned, and it was decided that each
sure that budgets and national policy are province would have its own target learner:
aligned and that provincial departments adhere educator ratio [with affordability driven from
to their budgets. It has also reduced the the budget side determining the number of af-
budget games played in such sectors. fordable teachers in a province], but a nation-
ally negotiated post-provisioning model would
The implementation of these simple but criti- guide its application in individual schools.
cal measures helped to turn around provincial The attempt at equitable distribution of educa-
finances dramatically. They ran a R500 mil- tors has not been ruined, however, since pro-
lion surplus in 1998/99 compared to a R5.5 vincial education departments became
billion deficit a year earlier. Provinces stabi- responsible for the process. The latest statis-
lized their personnel expenditures and began tics released by the Department of Education
shifting funds towards non-personnel budgets suggest that provinces have moved closer to
and the payment of debts. The implementa- each other in terms of learner: educator ratios.
tion of a multi-year budget [MTEF] from 1998
onwards also helped provinces to prepare  Lange, M. 1998. “Opening Re-
more realistic budgets. Provinces have run marks,” Seminar on Democratic
surpluses every year since 1998 and had paid Transformation of Education,”
off their debt by the end of the 2000 financial Konrad Adenauer Foundation Jo-
year. This has put them in a strong position to hannesburg, at
focus on the micro reforms necessary to im- http://www.kas.org.za/Publications
prove the quality of spending in education and /Semi-
health and on increasing their infrastructure narRports/Democratictransformati
budgets. onofeducation/lange.pdf.
Case 3. USA and Japan: School Boards, an
 From: Momoniat, I. No date. old tradition—but sometimes a controver-
“Fiscal Decentralisation in South sial one.
Africa: A Practitioner’s Perspec-
USA
tive,” at
http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/pub
From San Francisco to New York City, may-
licf-
ors and state legislatures are contesting local
nance/documents/South%20Africa.
school boards for control over classrooms.
pdf
It's a flat-out challenge to one of the deepest
In 1994, gross inequalities in learner: educator
traditions in American public education:
ratios were also identified as an important ob-
schools being run by boards that are anchored
stacle to equity, and plans were made to de-
in the community.
velop national norms for the provision of

31
Education Sector Review Volume 2

While both mayoral candidates in last year's


The United States has long had the strongest election campaigned to keep control of the
system of local control in the industrialized schools in City Hall, opinion polls show a ma-
world, and critics of the current takeover trend jority of voters want to go back to an elected
worry that communities - and especially racial board.
minorities - are being disenfranchised.
Indeed, the US tradition of local control runs
But pressure for change, driven by sagging deep. Across the country, some 15,000 local
student achievement and education's growing school boards handle everything from repair-
role in state budgets, is formidable. Some 23 ing gutters to setting educational goals. Of the
states have passed laws authorizing state or 95,000 people on these boards, 96 percent are
city takeovers of school districts in crisis. elected.

"Mayoral control is a new phenomenon in That system is now under siege in many urban
troubled urban school systems, and the early centers. Early takeovers in cities like Boston
signs in the cities that have moved this way (1991), Chicago (1995), Cleveland (1998),
look promising enough for others to follow and Detroit (1999) were prompted by a melt-
suit," says Ted Sanders, president of the Den- down of school finances or governance. In
ver-based Education Commission of the Baltimore (1993) and Philadelphia (2001), the
States. state engineered the takeovers.

Last week, San Francisco Mayor Willie In some cases, elected school boards con-
Brown called for returning that city to a spicuously mismanaged funds - overspending
mayor-appointed board, after 30 years with an credit cards or bungling millions in funding
elected board. The change would result in for school construction. In others, petty
more qualified people on the board and im- squabbles and erratic behavior spilled out onto
provements in public schools, he said. the front pages of local newspapers, undermin-
ing public confidence in the capacity of local
Meanwhile, New York City's new mayor, Mi- boards.
chael Bloomberg, wants to abandon an ap-
pointed board in favor of a commissioner who More recently, pressure for change is coming
reports directly to the mayor. And last month, down to the central issue of student achieve-
New York Gov. George Pataki (R) called for ment.
putting mayors in charge of schools in the
state's six largest cities, including Albany and Most students in urban public schools aren't
New York City. doing well. And with new state and federal
testing regimes, such failures are becoming
But current moves to center more control on more and more conspicuous…
City Hall are already generating a backlash
from critics. They argue that the shift from "The basic problem is that school boards are a
elected boards will distance poor and minority 19th century idea that made sense when most
voters from decisionmaking. communities were small and self-governing,
and people tended to grow up and live and die
Cleveland - now starting a $1 billion school- in the same place.... That has all changed
construction project - is gearing up for a vote now," says Chester Finn, president of the
this fall on whether to return to an elected Thomas B. Fordham Foundation and an ad-
school board after three years of control by viser to GOP presidents…
City Hall. Mishandling of a $60 million bond
issue was one reason the state turned control  From Chaddock, G.R. 2002.
of schools over to the mayor in 1998. “Mayors, States, Push School
Boards Aside,” Christian Science

32
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

Monitor, February 26, 2002 at lage school superintendents is an example. If


boards of education in neighboring villages
http://www.csmonitor.com/2002/0 form liaison committees and share staff and
226/p01s01-ussc.html budgets, they would find it easier to pursue
bold policies.
Japan: School Boards—an unfinished agenda
The concept of a board of education was origi-
Editorial: School Boards Can Work nally an organization to solicit opinions from
those in a community with children in school
The forum, properly used, can inspire educa- and an interest in education. If parents and
tion. Many boards of education seem to be lit- residents use the forum wisely, the board of
tle more than a pipeline for carrying education can continue to be very useful.
instructions from the education and science
ministry to the schools…  From The Asahi Shimbun, Nov.
26, 2002), at:
Many boards of education seem to be little http://www.asahi.com/english/op-
more than a pipeline for carrying instructions ed/K2002112700673.html.
from the education and science ministry to the
schools. Education board secretariat officials Case 4. Brazil, Spain: Decentralization and
in many municipalities set the agenda and good management information—difficult
education board members are just figureheads. and problematic but possible with effort
and partnership.
It is not surprising that some critics say boards
of education have no value. Some even say Brazil
they should be eliminated and the mayor
should take over the administration of public The implementation of education reforms in
education. They also say that voters should Brazil, where education systems are character-
determine whether the mayor has performed ized by political-institutional decentralization,
satisfactorily. necessarily requires sound mechanisms for
monitoring and following-up on ongoing ac-
Those critics have a point. If the mayor ap- tions and policies. Such managerial instru-
points teachers on political grounds, however, ments help observe how reforms are
it would cause confusion in schools. A mayor progressing and, more importantly, help iden-
should instead challenge and make better use tify the positive points and those needing ad-
of a board of education. justments. Those mechanisms also provide
unquestionable social gains that may be meas-
But some points require extra attention. Mem- ured both in terms of greater efficiency and ef-
bers of a board of education must be drawn fectiveness, and in terms of the desirable
from a wide spectrum, including parents, edu- assurance of transparency and equity in gov-
cation specialists, people in business and ernmental programs.
young people. Those with an interest in edu-
cation should be drawn upon to discuss their The use of information in educational man-
perspectives and solicit their suggestions. agement complies, therefore, with two basic
principles of democracy: accountability -
It is also useful to have nonprofit organiza- through the wide dissemination of results ob-
tions as full-time assistants to the board mem- tained in surveys and assessments - and per-
bers and get them involved in policymaking. manent social control. Last, but not least,
educational evaluation and information sys-
And it is important to have cooperation among tems play a strategic role in the planning and
members of boards of education in neighbor- prospective design of scenarios, for they con-
ing communities. The annual meeting of vil- tribute in no small way to the formulation of

33
Education Sector Review Volume 2

new policies and programs that may provide Several factors have contributed to the refor-
answers for new trends. In order to fulfill mulation of the educational evaluation, statis-
these multiple purposes, information systems tics and indicators systems in Brazil. In the
must count on uniform and scientifically based domestic context, the strong leadership of the
methodologies and survey instruments, up- Ministry of Education should be pointed out,
dated and reliable databases, as well as agile driving this initiative forward in constant part-
and precise dissemination mechanisms. nership with sub-national authorities as well as
with representatives of the education sector.
[But] until 1995, Brazilian education data Growing public opinion support to the sys-
were outdated and unsystematic. Since there tematic evaluations of the educational institu-
was no recent information available, directing tions has also been an extremely relevant
government policies in that area was a chal- factor. In the international context, the impor-
lenge as difficult as flying a plane in the midst tance of multilateral cooperation should also
of a storm having no guiding instrument on be stressed, for the purposes of acquiring
board. Not only did the lack of updated in- knowledge, capacity-building, sharing experi-
formation jeopardize the decisionmaking ences and comparisons with other countries.
process, but it also caused a huge waste in the
allocation of funds. Furthermore, in the ab-  Gumaraes de Castro, M.H. 2000.
sence of a national standard system of infor- “Role and Value of International
mation and indicators, several states had their Education Indicators For National
own data gathering and processing systems, Policy Development.” Fourth
not compatible to each other. For this very General Assembly of the OECD
reason Brazil could not even provide interna- Education Indicators Programme
tional organizations with consistent data on (INES). 11 - 13 September - To-
education. kyo, Japan, at:
http://www.inep.gov.br/download/i
By the beginning of 1995, the latest school nterna-
census available dated back to 1989, and the cional/idioma/Role%20and%20val
last finished survey was that of 1991. The in- ue%20of%20international%20indi
formation available was, therefore, inadequate ca-
to provide support for the design of actions di- tors%20for%20national%20policy
rected at improving the education system. %20development.pdf.
From that year on, the Brazilian educational
information system has gradually undergone a
Spain
complete reformulation, having acquired an
integrated, decentralized and comprehensive
As the decentralization process unfolded in the
structure, which includes now all levels and
1980s, the country needed a planning mecha-
types, from early childhood to tertiary educa-
nism that would serve to coordinate the educa-
tion and more advanced programs.
tional policies and programs being developed
and executed by the MEC and the decentral-
This process was based on government guide-
ized autonomous communities (de jure). An
lines for the creation of evaluation mecha-
early experience signaled why such a coordi-
nisms to monitor the country's education
nating mechanism was necessary; soon after
systems. As a matter of fact, nowadays all
the decentralization process began the capacity
programs and projects carried out by the Min-
to gather and reproduce nation-wide educa-
istry of Education are based on diagnoses and
tional statistics was lost. Various regions had
recommendations derived from statistical sur-
begun gathering their own data using formats
veys and assessments on basic and higher edu-
that could not be aggregated at the national
cation.
level.

34
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

The Education Law of 1985 created the Con- ion/globaleducationreform/pdf/han


ference of Counselors, with the Minister of son.pdf
Education and the autonomous community
Counselors (chief educational officers) of the Case 5. The United States: Data compli-
seven already decentralized regions as mem- ance in a large federal republic.
bers. Much of the work of the Conference
(which meets at least once a year), is carried The United States is the second largest federal
out by five technical subcommittees each fo- republic in the world after India. Compared to
cusing on a specific issue (for example, per- unitary republics, the federal level in the US
sonnel, curriculum, and statistics). has relatively little control over education and
relatively little power to enforce or mandate
[It has been pointed out that] de facto the Con- standards. It provides only a small amount of
ference is an instrument of cooperation and funding, historically considerably under 10
not coordination because none of the decen- percent of total education funding in the coun-
tralized regions is obligated to carry out the try. However, this does not mean that it is im-
decisions of the Conference when they believe possible to develop some uniformity of data at
their own statutes of autonomy are being vio- the federal level. (Description of these data
lated. Rather, the Conference operates as a can be found at the Web site on the Common
mechanism that brings together the chief edu- Core of Data—CDD—of the National Center
cators of the decentralized regions and the for Education Statistics—NCES,
Ministry of Education and Science to discuss http://nces.ed.gov/ccd/aboutCCD.asp.) And,
common problems and to search for possible given that control even in unitary republics
avenues of collective action. Interviews with may be more illusory than real (generating
observers of and participants in the Confer- only the illusion of compliance), some of the
ence of Counselors reveals two underlying lessons from the US might be of interest, par-
problems that limit its effectiveness as a major ticularly to large, unitary republics undergoing
integrating force. The first problem is a ge- serious decentralization (to the degree that
neric distrust on the part of several autono- some call them quasi-federal), such as South
mous communities that the Conference may Africa or Indonesia.
be used by the MEC to control the actions of
the decentralized regions. The second prob- In the US, uniformity and compliance by
lem is that even though issues are brought to states in the submission of data to the federal
the Conference as technical problems, the pro- level has been accomplished via a variety of
posed solutions tend to have heavy political tactics.
overtones. After all, the Minister and the
Counselors sitting around the table all re- x Least important is any form of man-
ceived their appointments as representatives of date or obligation: these are the least-
a particular political party, thus political agen- used means of ensuring compliance
das are never far from the surface. Having and uniformity.
said that, it should be noted that at times the x The federal level does rely on the fact
Conference is capable of reaching important that each state (generally, though it
agreements and carrying out complex actions. varies) does have power to ensure
compliance from schools. Thus, the
 From Hanson, M. 2000. “Democ- federal level is mostly concerned with
ratization and Educational Decen- communicating with 50 states, not
tralization in Spain: A Twenty some 18,000 districts, or hundreds of
Year Struggle for Reform.” Coun- thousands of schools.
try Studies. Education Reform and x Some compliance is required in feder-
Management Publication Series. ally funded programs; standard data
Vol. 1, No. 3, June 2000, at: object definitions are published. But
http://www1.worldbank.org/educat

35
Education Sector Review Volume 2

most of the data gathered at federal x The federal level tries to make it as
level does not fall under this category. easy as possible to submit data, ac-
x Another incentive is that, as the qual- cepting a wide variety of computer
ity of data have improved over time, formats.
the federal government does use the x The system has evolved. Over the
data in initial planning and indicative past 15 years, the federal level has
resource allocation. The states know emphasized networking, the build-up
this, and thus there is an incentive to of professional relations, allowing par-
improve. ticular States to show off their best
x A major incentive is maintenance of practices to the other states, etc. This
close professional and personal rela- has been a great help.
tions between the data groups at fed-
eral level and each of the states. In short, a decentralized system can assure a
x There are technical statistical working considerable degree of data compliance. The
groups that are cooperative in nature, key lessons are that it takes time, professional-
but exist on a permanent basis. These ism, nurturing of relationships, and, of course,
groups generate awareness of the need some sustainable budgetary allocations to en-
for standards, agree on definitions, sure that the effort does not flag once it starts.
etc. The most important example is
the National Forum on Education Sta-  Compiled by Luis Crouch
tistics (http://nces.ed.gov/forum/), from personal communica-
which brings together public sector of- tions with the CDD and
ficials from education and other re- NCES.
lated sectors, but also from teacher
unions, and others concerned with
education. The forum is funded by
the federal government, which gener-
ates sustainability, but is not a gov-
ernment office. Importantly, the
forum provides training, guidebooks
on definitions, etc. It meets twice per
year, though some sub-committees
meet more often.

36
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

Appendix 1.4. Citizen Perception and Educational Reality: Insights from


the Governance and Decentralization Survey
The Governance and Decentralization Survey Second, when the few objective indicators of
(GDS) was a random sample survey carried out quality of services that could be found were ana-
in 2002 in a large number of Indonesian dis- lyzed, it was found that service standards are ac-
tricts. It asked both citizens and officials for tually fairly poor—schools claim it takes some
their opinions about the quality of various ser- seven months to fulfill book orders, for example.
vices, including the effects of decentralization, Furthermore, opinion from school-level stake-
their perceptions of corruption, and other impor- holders (principals) about these more objective
tant issues related to the governance and man- service standards varies a great deal more (some
agement of service delivery. Most of the 10 times more) among districts than citizen’s
questions elicited subjective opinions based on a perceptions of quality, confirming that citizens
scale. A few questions asked for objective in- tend to have a range of opinions about quality
formation such as the number of days required that is narrower than more objective indicators
by delivery systems (for example, education) to or that they simply responded positively out of
perform a certain task (for example, to promote politeness or because they thought this may be
a teacher). what the enumerator wanted to hear. There is
also evidence that citizens place more value on
Based on the results of the survey, which col- physical and business infrastructure than on
lected data on purely subjective opinions, citi- education, confirming the suggestion that per-
zens appear to be fairly happy with their haps their standards with regard to education
education services and seem to believe that these might not be very high.
services have improved since decentralization.
Third, when “objective” observers were asked
This could have two quite opposite interpreta- about their perceptions of corruption and citi-
tions. First, if there was some sort of objective zens’ general complaints, education regularly
correlate that suggested citizens have reasonably fared worse than other sectors.
high standards and are good judges of quality,
then this result would be a positive thing. Fur- Finally, less than a third of districts seemed to
ther improvements would always be possible, of have had norms regarding education, at least in
course. However, a second, more negative in- the opinion of DPRD members, at the time the
terpretation would be that if there are some ob- survey was taken. All of these findings taken
jective indications, even within the survey itself, together suggest that improving governance and
that services leave a good deal to be desired, management in the sector will require not just
then the fact that citizens appear somewhat increasing citizens’ capacity and incentives to
complacent makes the task of improving educa- press for better services but also the harder (and
tion seem even harder than it might otherwise chronologically prior) tasks of a) developing
be. This is because in addition to delivering on demanding but reasonable standards and em-
improvements, it may be necessary to overcome bodying them in norms, regulations, or guide-
existing complacency. This second interpreta- lines, b) ensuring that citizens know what
tion appears the most likely for two reasons. standards they have a right to expect, and c) en-
suring that, either through some form of man-
First, when citizens were asked about their per- dates or moral persuasion and dialogue, local
ception regarding education, there is some evi- areas give education the degree of local prioriti-
dence that their range of response was very zation it deserves. These tasks are more in-
narrow. Citizens seem to have responded in a volved—conceptually—than those involved
tight and marginally optimistic fashion, without with simply training citizens to press for better
much deviation towards the negative or the posi- services. They also, as noted, need to be tackled
tive. before raising citizens’ expectations, both logi-

37
Education Sector Review Volume 2

cally and chronologically. However, they are d. Officers of the Dinas Kesehatan
not much more labor-intensive. (141)
e. Officers of the Dinas Pendidikan
Basic Facts about the Survey (141)
f. Members of NGOs (563)
The Governance and Decentralization Survey g. Members of the media (422)
(GDS) carried out by the Center for Population h. Lawyers (133)
and Policy Studies (CPPS) at the University of i. Officers of Puskesmas
Gajah Mada, with World Bank funding, was an j. Officers of schools (857)
opinion survey that was applied to many levels k. Citizens or households (8579)
of Indonesian society.9 The survey was carried l. Representatives of private sector
out in 2002. The survey has the following rele- (562)
vant characteristics:
3. The list of districts where the overall survey
1. It is largely an opinion survey, based on was carried out is shown in Table 13 (This
scales, with only a few objective indicators table is shown at the end of this appendix as
or judgments by enumerators trained to it is quite long.) Sixty households were in-
evaluate a process or situation. The lack of terviewed in each district. (In one or two of
objective measurements (or judgment of these districts both the kota and the kabu-
processes by trained enumerators) makes it paten were sampled, for a total of 120 inter-
difficult to assess the objective quality of views.) It would be tedious to show the
governance. It also makes it difficult to cor- geographical distribution of every type of
roborate opinions by seeing whether they are respondent, so only the list of districts is
correlated with the objective measurements. shown.
Thus, the absolute value of the opinions is
not of very much interest. However, opin- Initial Results and Puzzles
ions can be compared with each other a)
across sectors and issues, to see whether A logical place to begin, given the aim of this
opinion about governance in some sectors or appendix, is to see what the most “basic” or “fi-
issues is better or worse than in others and nal” respondents, namely parents and citizens
b) for a given sector or issue across localities think about the quality of services and govern-
and actors to see whether these opinions cor- ance of the education sector, both at present and
relate with each other. over the past few years.

2. The following actors—numbers of each in The following observations can be made from
the database are shown in parentheses— the survey. First, the proportions of citizens
were interviewed: who thought, at the time of the survey, that ser-
a. Officials in Bupati/Walikota’s office vices were at 3 (or 4) or better on a scale of 1 to
and other general local government 5 (where 5 is best) is as shown in Table 1.
(741) Given the standard errors, differences between
b. Members of regional legislature or proportions of more than .015 are generally sig-
DPRD (567) nificant at the 5 percent level. The data have
c. Practitioners in the justice system— been sorted from the “worst” service to the
judges and district attorneys (259) “best.”

9
For a fuller description of the survey see:
http://lnweb18.worldbank.org/eap/eap.nsf/2500ec5f1
a2d9bad852568a3006f557d/f342ce243175816d4725
6c1a0015a2a0?OpenDocument.

38
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

Table 1. Proportion of citizens scoring quality of services


as “medium” or better (3 or higher on a 1 to 5 scale)10
Proportion scoring the service Proportion scoring the service Std Error of
Service 3 or better 4 or better Column 1
Police 0.722 0.324 0.005
Head of Sub-district office 0.844 0.488 0.004
Public Senior High School 0.859 0.574 0.004
Doctor of Puskesmas 0.878 0.542 0.004
Village Midwife 0.884 0.590 0.003
Public Junior High School 0.886 0.592 0.003
Public Elementary School 0.905 0.599 0.003
Puskesmas 0.915 0.508 0.003
Posyandu 0.927 0.649 0.003
Head of Kelurahan/village
Office 0.931 0.575 0.003

Generally, education falls in the middle of the A majority of citizens think that services
range. A very large majority of citizens seems have not changed, but far more think that
to think services are either “ok” (3) or better, services have gotten better than think they
with the numbers thinking services are “better have gotten worse (the middle category of “no
than ok” (4 or higher) being a small majority change” is the rest). Again, differences be-
(except for in the police and sub-district cate- tween services of more than about 0.015 in the
gories). It would be hard to argue that in static “better” column and of more than 0.003 in the
terms, and in terms of subjective opinion, edu- “worse” column are statistically significant. It
cation services are failing, either compared to is true that the largest proportion of citizens
other services or in purely subjective absolute who think services have gotten worse is in
terms. education, but 6.1 percent, while statistically
significantly different from the value for the
Second, citizens seem to think not only that other services, is not striking from a social or
things are not bad, but also that services ap- economic point of view. It is interesting to
pear to be improving under decentralization, if note that, regarding education, fewer citizens
one goes just by citizens’ subjective opinions, are in the middle and fewer are without an
as shown in Table 2. opinion.

Table 2. Proportion of citizens who think services have Third, when citizens were asked to say
gotten better or worse since decentralization whether they were happy with particular
Don’t aspects of education, on average, across
Better Worse
Service Know most sub-aspects, about 80 percent said
School 0.396 0.061 0.045 they were happy, and there is not much
Health 0.403 0.030 0.066 variability across sub-aspects.11 This is
Village 0.397 0.026 0.032 shown in Table 3.
Sub-District 0.318 0.017 0.142
District 0.264 0.021 0.298 All this presents a puzzle. The experts
seem to think that the Indonesian educa-
tion sector is in trouble, yet citizens appear not
to think so. One possible explanation is that

10 11
The source for all tables is our analysis of the The phrasing of the question was altered between
GDS itself. The source for each individual table is “are you satisfied” and “are you unhappy.” The
therefore not listed. percentages were roughly the same in either case.

39
Education Sector Review Volume 2

the experts are wrong, that they are rent- technically reasonable. Thus, this suggests a)
seeking in promoting a sense that education the need not only for School Committees and
has problems (because if they promote a sense other citizen groups to articulate demands and
of crisis, there will be a higher demand for ex- hold service providers to account but also for
pert services). This may mean that the situa- ambitious but reasonable standards of per-
tion is in fact truly better than subjective formance and b) citizens to realize what stan-
Table 3. Percentage of citizens satisfied dards they have a right to expect.
with various sub-aspects of education
School fees 71 If the second explanation is true, this means
Uniform prices 78
that parents and communities will tend to un-
School achievement 82
der-invest in education, which means that cen-
School discipline 87
tral budgetary pressure of some sort (some
School learning process 86
earmarking or even mandates), as well as
PTA management 83
training and moral persuasion, will be neces-
sary to ensure that citizens recognize the na-
Extra-curricular activities 81
tion’s needs as well as their own. Again, this
opinions would suggest or there may be at is likely to be a difficult task. We now turn to
least two other explanations. the task of sorting out whether these two hy-
potheses might be true.
One possible explanation is that citizens told
the enumerators what they thought they Sorting out the Puzzle
wanted to hear and thus responded fairly posi-
tively to most questions even though they may The first hypothesis, that there is some bias to
have thought otherwise, or citizens may sim- the positive middle, can be tested in at least
ply have had very low expectations. If one one simple way. We took all the responses to
takes into account noise and randomness, then the question on the degree of happiness with a
there is some variation around a generally variety of services (the question underlying
positive, but somehow “standardized ok” out- Table 2). The range of judgment as to the
look. The lack of many objective correlates to quality of services can go from 1 to 5, with 5
the opinion questions makes it hard to assess being the best. We averaged the valid re-
whether this is the case. sponses for all services in each district. We
then ranked all of the 142 districts. The dis-
Another possible explanation is that citizens trict falling at the boundary of the 1st and 2nd
genuinely perceived things to be going fairly quintiles (the average of the 35th and 36th) had
well in education, but there was a gap between an average of 3.51. The district falling at the
what they perceived and what is in the na- boundary of the 4th and 5th quintiles (the aver-
tional interest—in other words, the survey as- age of the 106th and 107th) had an average of
sessed individual or local satisfaction rather 3.69. The very worst district of the 142 had an
than collective need. Since the effects of edu- average rating of 3.23, nearly half-way be-
cation are perhaps 50 percent external to the tween “fair” and “good,” and the very best
family and to a considerable degree external to only 3.95, not quite “good.” The total range
a village, it makes sense that villagers would from 3.23 to 3.95 is 0.72 or only 18 percent of
tend to under-invest in education and/or over- the total range of variation possible (4 points),
estimate the degree to which it is provided at a and the inter-quartile range is only 4.7 percent
“good-enough” level compared to the national of the total possible range of variation.
need.
All this strongly suggests a pre-disposition to
If the first explanation is true, then citizens respond with a bias towards the slightly posi-
need to be educated to have higher expecta- tive above neutral. It is true that averaging out
tions. However, their expectation must also be all services produces an artificial uniformity
bias that may not be present in the responses.

40
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

Table 4. Time it takes to perform certain tasks (in months)


Dinas Pen- Percentage
Task didikan School difference
Changing the status of a position (promoting a position) 3.0 5.1 68%
Promoting a teacher 3.7 5.8 58%
Approving a student movement 2.0 2.2 9%
Fulfilling book procurement proposal of the school 5.7 7.4 30%

Thus, taking specific services one at a time, and of the schools. The services concerned
the actual range of total variation between the were:
worst and best district is, on average, 24 per- 1. Changing the status of a position
cent of the possible range of variation, and the (promoting a position)
inter-quartile range, service by service, is 6.3 2. Promoting a teacher
percent of the possible range. Finally, the 3. Approving a student movement
worst service, policing, got an average rating 4. Fulfilling the school’s book procure-
of 3.1, and the best, Posyandu, got an average ment proposal.
of 3.8, with the difference between the two be-
ing 16 percent of the possible range. This The responses were in ranges (1 to 3 months,
confirmed the notion of a restricted range of 4 to 7, etc.). Giving the middle value of the
variation that sits right above the average. range to each range, the approximate time in
The idea that this restricted range might be months taken to carry out each of these tasks
“natural” still has to be dealt with—there is, from the points of view of the Dinas Pendidi-
after all, no reason why citizens’ ratings would kan and the school is shown in Table 4.
have to be uniformly distributed or distributed
in any particular way. If the quality of ser- This table is significant for various reasons.
vices really is very tightly controlled by gov- First, taking 3.7, or even 3 months, to promote
ernment and kept within a certain range, it is a teacher, or taking 5.7, or even 5 months to
entirely possible that the citizens’ reactions fulfill a procurement order, is a very low stan-
might simply reflect this fact. We will return dard, and yet this is the perception of the Di-
to this when we have a way to test it. nas Pendidikan. The perception of the school
is that the tasks take, on average, some 30 to
Another way to test the notion of positive bias 70 percent longer (44 percent on average), as
due to a lack of objective scaling is that there much as 7 months to fulfill book procurement
were at least some governance and manage- orders or 5 to 6 months to get a teacher pro-
ment questions that were a) based on an objec- moted. One has to remember that “2” in the
tive scale (though not independently table above really means 1 to 3 (months), so
measured) and b) asked of more than one type one has to interpret the results cautiously.
of respondent. There was a question about Nonetheless, these are poor performance lev-
how long it took the Dinas Pendidikan office els. When this is juxtaposed with parental
to process a certain type of action. The same opinion, then, parents seem to have a bias to-
question was asked of the Dinas Pendidikan wards the positive or to have low expectations.
Second, the difference in perspective between We can now turn to the issue of whether the
the Dinas Pendidikan and the schools is clear range of citizens’ rating of services might be
and strong: 44 percent on average. The one “natural,” in other words, might reflect the
exception to this divergence of perception is true range of objective variation in quality. To
the time it took to approve a student move- check this, we assessed the coefficient of
ment. Schools’ estimates of the time required variation between district averages of the time
for certain actions is much longer than those it takes to perform various services as above.
of officials. These results are shown in Table 5.

41
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Table 5. Coefficient of inter-district variation


in time it takes to perform certain tasks and in citizen rating of various services
Dinas Pen-
didikan School per- Citizen per-
Task perception ception ception
Changing the status of a position (promoting a position) 0.68 0.38 NA
Promoting a teacher 0.88 0.40 NA
Approving a student movement 0 0.12 NA
Fulfilling book procurement proposal of the school 0.77 0.42 NA
Average across all tasks 0.46 0.24 NA
Citizen rating of basic education services NA NA 0.042

Interestingly, the averages as perceived by the limited than the “real” range of quality as de-
Dinas Pendidikan are wider even than those noted by officials’ reported range of variation
perceived by the schools. However, this is in a few objective indicators of service quality.
due to the fact that within many districts the
Dinas Pendidikan officials answered simply Another way of assessing whether citizens are
by choosing the lowest possible level (the “right” is to assess the correlation between
range 1-3). A few, however, appear to have citizens’ opinion on the subjective scale and
admitted that things take longer. This yielded the opinions of both Dinas Pendidikan offi-
a wide range—a range greater than that re- cials and school principals on an objective
ported by schools, which would otherwise measure of the time it takes to perform tasks.
seem unlikely. The hypothesis suggests itself Some simple correlations between citizens’
that perhaps Dinas officers have been exag- opinions on various services were added as a
gerating at the low end. In any case, it is clear benchmark to allow us to judge whether citi-
that citizens’ range of expressed evaluation of zens’ opinions, themselves, might be mere
quality is much more restricted—by about noise. The results are shown in Table 6.
four-fifths—than the variation in this one ob-
jective indicator of quality of services as re- Note that citizen’s opinions do not seem to be
ported by the schools or—by nine-tenths—by mere noise. Opinions on the quality of differ-
the Dinas Pendidikan. ent levels of schooling are highly correlated to
each other and are highly correlated to the
This strongly suggests that citizens’ range of opinions of village heads on educational qual-
perceptions of service quality is much more ity (last row, third panel of the table).

While citizens’ opinions may not be mere


Table 6. Simple correlations between household opinions on school quality scale and officials’ opinions on
time it takes to carry out basic tasks for schools
Variables Correlation
Dinas Pendidikan, Schools Opinions on Task Time 0.23
Households’ Opinion on Primary Schools, Dinas Pendidikan Opinion on Task Time 0.05
Households’ Opinion on Primary Schools, Schools’ Opinion on Task Time -0.08
Households’ Opinion on Junior Secondary Schools’, Dinas Pendidikan Opinion on Task Time 0.03
Households’ Opinion on Junior Secondary Schools’, Schools Opinion on Task Time -0.10
Households’ Opinion on Senior Secondary Schools’, Dinas Pendidikan Opinion on Task Time -0.02
Households’ Opinion on Senior Secondary Schools’, Schools Opinion on Task Time -0.07
Households’ Opinion on Primary Schools and Opinion on Junior Secondary Schools 0.88
Households’ Opinion on Primary Schools and Opinion Senior Secondary Schools 0.86
Households’ Opinion on Junior Secondary and Opinion Senior Secondary Schools 0.94
Households’ Opinion on Primary Education and Opinion on Head of Village 0.74

42
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

noise, they are not very correlated with offi- also interesting that education is listed fourth
cials’ opinions regarding the time it takes to but a fairly distant fourth: the drop from third
perform certain tasks. This suggests that one to fourth place is from 18 to 9 percent. This
should be cautious when using task perform- suggests, but only vaguely, that citizens might
ance time as a measure of quality or taking be thinking of education in terms of its private
subjective quality perceptions too seriously. and local returns and that therefore they tend
to put a relatively low priority on education.
Interestingly, while the correlation between Improved health services are also given a rela-
the Dinas Pendidikan officials’ and the school tively low priority. It is likely that here too
principals’ opinion on task time is statistically citizens tend to think not so much about public
positive, 0.23 is low in substantive terms. health measures as about measures that apply
Our second hypothesis is that parents’ or citi- to themselves as individuals or perhaps as a
village.
Table 7. Investment priorities of citizens upon receipt of large
fiscal windfall for their municipality
Poverty alleviation 23% What Do More “Objective”
Local physical development (means/ infrastructure) 19% Observers Say?
Increasing existing business capital 18% One way to assess relative qual-
Improving education service quality 9% ity of services, even without ob-
Agricultural development 7% jective measurements, is to see
Other 5% what other “objective” observers
Improving health service quality 5% (other than parents since, as we
Improving other public service quality 4% have seen, their range of reactions
Distributed to the people 4% seems biased towards the posi-
Financing manpower intensive projects 2% tive) might have to say. NGOs
Developing industrial factories 2% are not likely to be truly objec-
Increasing salary 0% tive, in that NGOs, as is the case
Increasing the number of staff 0% with most policy and service de-
livery analysts and advocates,
zens’ opinions reflect a private or local view presumably benefit from the maintenance of a
of education that naturally tends to under- perception that problems and crises exist.
estimate its importance and thus overestimate (However, it is hard to imagine reasons why
the degree to which delivery is sufficient or of they would tend to be more alarmist about one
adequate quality. sector than another; it would seem logical that
they would be about equally biased in all ar-
One possible way to test this is to assess the eas.) The proportion of NGO respondents
degree to which citizens would want to invest who said that in each of the areas shown there
in education as opposed to other items if their were few or no complaints against local ser-
municipality were to receive a fiscal windfall. vice providers is shown in Table 8.
The results are not an uncommon local priori-
tization: invest in economic assets that do
Table 8. Proportion of NGO respondents who report no com-
not move. The results are as shown in
plaints or hardly any complaints, by sector or office
Table 7.
Program and project development and implementation 0.45
Education service 0.48
The top responses, if taken together,
Health services 0.54
suggest that citizens tend to want to in-
vest in activities of fairly direct economic Regulation of informal economy 0.61
benefit and that apply to fixed assets. Land or building disputes 0.64
Notably, interest in direct investment in Human rights violations 0.65
work schemes or in investment projects Discipline violations in public service 0.68
Labor conflict 0.77
appears not to be high. In any case, it is

43
Education Sector Review Volume 2

The only area “worse” than education appears Table 10. Proportion of DPRD members or offi-
to be general program and project develop- cials who reported no complaints, by sector
ment. All services whose low-complaint pro- Education 0.19
portions are statistically different from Program and project development 0.21
education at the 5 percent level are shown in Health 0.25
italics. The number of low complaints in the Land/building certification 0.37
area of program and project development is Identity card 0.61
not statistically different from education. Amount of land/building tax 0.66
Thus, education is, in a sense, the sector
against which there are most complaints or is Again, education is at the bottom and indistin-
equivalent to the worst. guishably so from program and project devel-
opment. Note that the perceptions on this
It may well be that there are more complaints score are similar to NGO perceptions. And, it
against education simply because this is the is noteworthy how different these numbers are
social service that touches most people on a from citizens’ own responses about problems
daily basis. This cannot be tested. and levels of satisfaction. The same idea, with
some refinement, is shown in Table 11. The
To look at this issue further, we narrowed the results are the same, placing education at the
focus of management or governance com- bottom.
plaints down to the issue of corruption. The Table 11. Proportion of DPRD members
results are shown in Table 9. Sectors statisti- or officials who report few or very few
cally different from education at the 5 percent complaints (within those who report some
level are shown in italics. complaints), by sector
Education 0.23
Table 9. Proportion of NGO respondents who reported
low or very low levels of corruption, by sector or office Program and project development 0.24
Health 0.27
Head of District Office 0.23
Land/building certification 0.32
Local Parliament 0.23
Identity card 0.39
Land Certification Agency 0.21
Amount of land/building tax 0.41
Education Department 0.34
Health Department 0.34
Sub-district 0.4 Does Regulation Exist?
Village 0.46 The DPRD members were asked whether
regulation exists, for some key areas and
The absolute numbers above are of some in- their opinion of what regulation does exist.
terest: if 34 percent of the respondents were The results are shown in Table 12.
reporting little or no corruption, then 66 per-
cent were reporting some or more. This has This is a Table 12. Proportion of DRPD
positive implications for the drive towards de- somewhat ob- respondents saying regulation ex-
ists, by area
centralization below the district level, as advo- jective meas-
cated in the Education Act, as the village level urement, and it Poverty alleviation 0.1
is seen as the least corrupt. is of some Education 0.28
concern that Health 0.53
Similarly, whereas the DPRD might be biased only 28 per- KKN 0.05
in some general direction, it is hard to hy- cent of re-
pothesize that they would have particularly spondents seem to believe that the education
strong sectoral biases. Thus, their perception sector at the local level has been regulated.
of citizens’ complaints is of interest. This is This could be mere perception, but nonethe-
shown in Table 10. less it is the perception of the regional legisla-
ture, so it should be regarded as an important
issue.

44
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

Table 13 Districts Sampled


Alor, Nusa Tenggara Timar Ciamis, Jawa Barat
Asahan, Sumatera Utara Cilacap, Jawa Tengah
Badung, Bali Cirebon, Jawa Barat
Balikpapan, Kalimantan Timur Dairi, Sumatera Utara
Bandung, Jawa Barat Denpasar, Bali
Banggai Kepulauan, Sulawesi Tengah Depok, Jawa Barat
Bangkalan, Jawa Timar Donggala, Sulawesi Tengah
Banjar, Kalimantan Selatan Dumai, Riau
Banjarbaru, Kalimantan Selatan Flores Timur, Nusa Tenggara Timar
Bantaeng, Sulawesi Selatan Gianyar, Bali
Bantul, D I Yogyakarta Gowa, Sulawesi Selatan
Banyuwangi, Jawa Timur Gresik, Jawa Timur
Batam, Riau Hulu Sungai Tengah, Kalimantan Selatan
Bekasi, Jawa Barat Hulu Sungai Utara, Kalimantan Selatan
Bengkalis, Riau Indragiri Hulu, Riau
Berau, Kalimantan Timur Indramayu, Jawa Barat
Bima, Nusa Tenggara Barat Jember, Jawa Timur
Binjai, Sumatera Utara Jepara, Jawa Tengah
Blitar, Jawa Timur Kampar, Riau
Blora, Jawa Tengah Kapuas Hulu, Kalimantan Barat
Bogor, Jawa Barat Karang Asem, Bali
Bojonegoro, Jawa Timur Karawang, Jawa Barat
Bolaang Mengondow, Sulawesi Utara Karimun, Riau
Bone, Sulawesi Selatan Kebumen, Jawa Tengah
Boyolali, Jawa Tengah Kediri, Jawa Timur
Buton, Sulawesi Tenggara Kendal, Jawa Tengah
Kendari, Sulawesi Tenggara Rembang, Jawa Tengah
Klaten, Jawa Tengah Rokan Hilir, Riau
Klungkung, Bali Rokan Hulu, Riau
Kota Baru, Kalimantan Selatan Sambas, Kalimantan Barat
Kudus, Jawa Tengah Sampang, Jawa Timur
Kutai, Kalimantan Timur Sanggau, Kalimantan Barat
Labuhan Batu, Sumatera Utara Sangihe Talaud, Sulawesi Utara
Lahat, Sumatera Selatan Semarang, Jawa Tengah
Lampung Tengah, Lampung Sidenreng Rappang, Sulawesi Selatan
Lampung Utara, Lampung Sinjai, Sulawesi Selatan
Landak, Kalimantan Barat Situbondo, Jawa Timur
Lima Puluh Koto, Sumatera Barat Sleman, D I Yogyakarta
Lombok Timur, Nusa Tenggara Barat Solok, Sumatera Barat
Luwu Utara, Sulawesi Selatan Soppeng, Sulawesi Selatan
Madiun, Jawa Timur Sukoharjo, Jawa Tengah
Magelang, Jawa Tengah Sumba Barat, Nusa Tenggara Timur
Majalengka, Jawa Barat Sumbawa, Nusa Tenggara Barat
Malang, Jawa Timur Sumedang, Jawa Barat
Manado, Sulawesi Utara Tana Toraja, Sulawesi Selatan
Manggarai, Nusa Tenggara Timur Tanah Datar, Sumatera Barat
Maros, Sulawesi Selatan Tanggamus, Lampung

45
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Table 13 Districts Sampled


Mataram, Nusa Tenggara Barat Tapanuli Tengah, Sumatera Utara
Medan, Sumatera Utara Tapanuli Utara, Sumatera Utara
Metro, Lampung Tapin, Kalimantan Selatan
Muara Enim, Sumatera Selatan Tarakan, Kalimantan Timur
Muna, Sulawesi Tenggara Tegal, Jawa Tengah
Ngada, Nusa Tenggara Timur Temanggung, Jawa Tengah
Nganjuk, Jawa Timur Timor Tengah Selatan, Nusa Tenggara Tim
Nias, Sumatera Utara Timor Tengah Utara, Nusa Tenggara Timur
Ogan Komering Ulu, Sumatera Selatan Toba Samosir, Sumatera Utara
Pacitan, Jawa Timur Toli-Toli, Sulawesi Tengah
Padang Panjang, Sumatera Barat Tuban, Jawa Timur
Padang Pariaman, Sumatera Barat Tulungagung, Jawa Timur
Palembang, Sumatera Selatan Ujung Pandang, Sulawesi Selatan
Palu, Sulawesi Tengah Wajo, Sulawesi Selatan
Pangkajene Kepulauan, Sulawesi Selatan Way Kanan, Lampung
Pasaman, Sumatera Barat Wonosobo, Jawa Tengah
Pasir, Kalimantan Timur Yogyakarta, D I Yogyakarta
Payakumbuh, Sumatera Barat
Pekalongan, Jawa Tengah
Pemalang, Jawa Tengah
Pematang Siantar, Sumatera Utara
Pesisir Selatan, Sumatera Barat
Pinrang, Sulawesi Selatan
Ponorogo, Jawa Timur
Pontianak, Kalimantan Barat
Probolinggo, Jawa Timur

46
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

Appendix 1.5. Organizational Issues for Depdiknas under


Decentralization
Since function assignment is still being de- The South African Department of Education
bated and since form should follow function, employs only some 500 employees in a
it is difficult to be exactly prescriptive about country with some 350,000 teachers and a
bureaucratic form for Depdiknas and other little less than one-third as many students as
national-level bodies such as MoRA, where Indonesia. The rest of the country’s educa-
the assignment of basic decentralization tion personnel are employed by the decen-
functions is even less clear. However, based tralized provinces. Argentina has a little less
on the logic of decentralization that Indone- than one-fifth as many students as Indonesia
sia has set out for itself as embodied in vari- and about 1,200 national employees. Even
ous laws and based on international decentralized countries can have fairly large
experience, a few pointers can be set out. It staffs at the central level if they can afford it
needs to be noted that there is no necessary and depending on the degree of true decen-
correspondence between organizational tralization.
structure and performance, just as there is no
necessary connection between decentraliza- Spending Size
tion and educational performance. How-
Spending by central ministries as a percent-
ever, there are organizational structures for a
age of total spending at the pre-tertiary level
national ministry that make more sense than
in decentralized countries ranges all the way
others in a decentralized or decentralizing
from less than 10 percent (in China, the US,
education system. This section covers two
South Africa, and Hungary) to as high as 20-
issues: a) size (which is subdivided into dis-
40 percent (in Australia, Poland, and Spain).
cussions of personnel and budget) and b)
Spending at the central level is usually
structure.
higher as a proportion of total spending than
Size staffing at the central level. This is because
much national spending in decentralized
Personnel Size countries takes the form of grants, transfers,
Judging from international practice, for the or project support of various types to lower-
national level to have less than one in one level governments as opposed to the direct
thousand of the total pre-tertiary education purchase of inputs (including labor) into in-
staff in the country would be too few. At struction or school administration.
one extreme, Canada has no national Minis-
try, so in a sense it has zero staff (though it Structure
has a council of provincial Ministers with a
secretariat of 40 or so) at the national level. Indonesia’s education system is far from be-
A more realistic illustration might be China, ing effectively decentralized yet. Decen-
a nation with approximately six to seven tralization is not only new, but in its early
times more pre-tertiary students than Indo- days, it has not been well-defined. Decen-
nesia, which has only some 700 professional tralization is a process that has taken some
employees at the central ministry level. This 20 years in Spain, and some 15 years in
is the case even though China has one of the Chile. South Africa started decentralizing in
lowest ratios of central to sub-national per- 1994, reached some degree of fiscal stability
sonnel in the world across all governments in 1998 or so, and began reaping some qual-
and though its education system is not nec- ity improvements in 2001 or so. In a sense,
essarily an efficiently decentralized one. decentralization is never finished, as can be
South Africa’s national education workforce seen in the constant re-design and re-
is still lean but not at the Chinese extreme. assessment of the systems in the United

47
Education Sector Review Volume 2

States after 200 years as a decentralized so- mies of scale, perhaps by bro-
ciety (for example, the ongoing debate as to kering associations between dis-
whether district education boards should be tricts or provinces.
elected or appointed or whether they, or 6. Use funding or norms (such as
mayors, should control education in a mu- requiring districts to enroll chil-
nicipality—see Case 3 in Appendix 1.3). dren from outside the district,
The functions that a ministry in a decentral- and then funding them to do so)
izing country should perform are different to correct spillovers between re-
from those the same ministry might perform gions, for example, in special-
in a country that is already effectively de- ized areas of education where
centralized. Thus, looking at international one institution could serve more
examples of countries that are already de- than one district.
centralized (such as the UK, Spain, and the 7. Keep up funding levels and en-
US) is of limited, but some value. Looking courage local levels to pursue
at decentralizing cases is more interesting, equity in outcomes by creating
but there is a danger that one may try to regulation on the internal distri-
learn lessons from countries that are con- bution of funding within dis-
stantly decentralizing but getting there only tricts if possible, and by moral
slowly (Colombia). Chile, South Africa, persuasion if direct regulation is
Argentina, and Hungary are examples of deemed too intrusive into dis-
countries that have “achieved” some degree trict affairs.
of effective decentralization but are still suf- 8. Carry out overall system plan-
ficiently dynamic that there is an ongoing ning, forecasting, and invest-
decentralization process for the national ment prioritization, including
level to support. Judging by these cases, a forecasting and analyzing
central ministry in a decentralizing system teacher supply and demand.
should not implement education but instead 9. Encourage experimentation and
should: disseminate lessons learned
from that experimentation.
1. Set standards and measures of
performance, ideally outcome The organizational structure corresponding
measures rather than input ones; to such a “modern” set-up can be seen in the
ensure that these indicators are organigrams for two very different Minis-
measured and reported (includ- tries of Education: 1) Korea, an Asian uni-
ing information systems); set tary republic where students score extremely
goals and/or minimum service well in international comparative assess-
standards, again outcome- ments (Figure 1), and 2) Argentina, a Latin
oriented. American federal republic with an education
2. Focus on institutions of delivery system of medium effectiveness by middle-
(schools, colleges) rather than income country standards (Figure 2).12 It
“levels” (primary, secondary). would be possible to produce organograms
3. Ensure competition and emula- for strongly decentralizing developed coun-
tion between decentralized re-
gions.
4. Ensure that decentralized units 12
can come up to standard through Note that, since the focus of this ESR is pre-
systems development, training, tertiary education and education as such rather
and by advocating for effective than culture, science, sports, and other ancillary
functions often assigned to Ministries of Educa-
funding. tion, we have glossed over the details in the parts
5. Perform, or ensure performance, of the organigrams that correspond to such func-
of functions with large econo- tions.

48
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

tries such as Spain or unitary developed most modernizing and/or decentralizing


countries that are still experimenting such as ministries seek to do.
the UK, as the organizational lessons are
almost exactly the same. As noted, it should It should also be noted that some countries
not be inferred that causality can be ascribed have quite a good decentralization structure
to any particular type of structure. The point in terms of the relations between schools,
is simply that, in modernizing and decentral- districts, or provinces (or some other inter-
izing countries, the bureaucratic structure at mediate level) and the national level, but the
the center tends to have certain functions, internal organization of the national-level
but it should not be assumed that institu- ministry may still not be as good as it could
tional reorganization at the center of the sys- be. A good example of this is South Africa,
tem will necessarily have a direct and where the structure of decentralization, in
predictable impact on the quality of educa- terms of the relations between national, pro-
tion. What ultimately matters is incentives vincial, and school levels, is well thought-
and behavior at the classroom and school through and very close to international best
levels, but there are ways to organize levels practice, but the internal organization struc-
higher than the school so that they are opti- ture of the national Department of Education
mized to support schools. This is what is old-fashioned and not optimally suppor-
tive of the decentralized structures under it.

49
Figure 1. Structure of Ministry of Education, Republic of Korea

Minister

Information Technology Planning


Vice-Minister
Audit Information Technology Support
International Cooperation
Inspector General and Information
Technology Internatinoal Cooperation
Inspection

Lifelong and
Planning and School Policy Human Resources Local Education
Vocational University Affairs General Affairs
Management Development Services
Educaiton

Planning and
Teacher Policy
Budget

Administrative Various subunits


Management School
Teacher Policy
Policy

Legal Affairs
Curriculum Teacher Education
Policy and Development
Education
Facilities
Asessment and Teacher
Evaluation Welfare
Women's
Education

Emergency
Planning

50
Figure 2. Structure of Federal Ministry of Education, Argentina

Minister of Education

Secretary for
Secretary for Secretary for
Science, Technology,
Education University Policy
and Innovation

Subsecretary for Subsecretary for Various subunits


Administrative Quality and Equity
Coordination

National
National
DG DG National Directorate:
DG Directorate:
Finance and International Directorate: Curriculum and
Legal issues Information and
Management Funding Targeted Funding Teacher
School Quality
Development

Directorate: Directorate:
Directorate:
Accounting and Human
Budget
Finance Resources

51
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Based on these considerations, Depdiknas is and more prominent than the units
not currently optimized to support the performing such functions internal
decentralization process or a decentralized to the national ministry itself and
system. The following are suggestions for should be quite separate from them.
ways in which it could be reorganized to In a sense, these units should be
make it more supportive of a decentralized considered “line function” units just
education system: as important as traditional line units
such as “basic” or “tertiary” or “vo-
1. In a largely non-implementing min- cational.” The structure of the Ko-
istry there is no obvious need for a rean ministry is a good example in
large Inspectorate. This is not to say this regard. At a minimum, such
internal audit functions and the audit units should be headed by a Director
of sub-national units in charge of General (and not the Secretary Gen-
projects should be neglected, but the eral) such as a Director General for
unit performing internal and special Policy and Planning, who would
project audit, while strong and well- cover not only the traditional policy
staffed, need not be very large. The and planning issues but also these
internal audit function should be issues related to administrative and
part of the internal ministry staff governance support to regions.
function, in other words, organiza- 4. However, incentives should be cre-
tionally it should be placed in a ated for staff working in such units
manner similar to that of Korea. to work in tandem with the internal
2. A distinction needs to be made be- Depdiknas staff because the latter
tween the “staff” working on func- often have practical know-how,
tions that are internal to the ministry such as how the personnel databases
(generally associated with some- operate. Without such practical
thing like a Secretary General), such know-how, staff in such a Policy
as human resources, budget, pro- and Planning Directorate General
curement, on the one hand and sup- will tend to be seen by their regional
port to decentralized regions counterparts as “mere theoreti-
carrying out those same functions cians.” Some of these key support
on the other. functions would be:
a. The offices performing a. Funding and developing fi-
functions internal to the nancial norms, such as
ministry can be fairly small. model funding norms for
b. The technical focus of these districts to fund or provision
functions will need to schools.
change. For example, pro- b. Developing models and
curement expertise should tools for personnel (teacher)
shift from materials to tech- management.
nical assistance and re- c. Improving procurement of,
search and development for example, books.
contracts. This will also re- d. Developing information
quire better links between systems.
technical staff and central e. Continuing governance and
staff. It is likely to require management development.
the retraining of some staff. 5. The Directorate General for Policy
3. Units providing assistance to sub- and Planning should be divided into
national governments in functions two (or more) broad areas, to handle
such as human resources, budgeting, a) these financial, administrative,
and procurement should be bigger and governance support functions

52
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

and b) the traditional curriculum, nance and Analytical Services.13


accreditation, and examination func- Note the focus on Schools (as insti-
tions. Alternatively, there could be tutions) rather than on “education”
two Directorate Generals, one for as an abstraction, and note that only
these “systems” issues and another one of the DGs, if that, is focused on
for the more traditional educational traditional “line” functions and the
ones. others deal with analytical and sup-
6. Given that the functions of Depdi- port functions. This makes sense,
knas will be evolving towards pro- given that the goal of the Depart-
viding support and technical ment is “only” to: “develop and im-
assistance to lower levels, most of plement policies and programs – by
its job descriptions will have to setting the framework of standards,
change. In fact, thinking in terms of accountability, devolution, and cus-
describing jobs that exist to support tomer choice for each phase of edu-
regions in the decentralization proc- cation.”
ess is a fairly good way to establish x South Africa’s Department of Edu-
the new functions, since the new cation has only one Director Gen-
functions are not to be performed by eral and four Deputy Directors
the institution as an abstraction but General: three for line functions
by people. (higher, general, and techni-
cal/vocational) and one for policy
The following aspects of various existing and planning. The latter takes on
decentralized education systems around the tasks such as setting norms for how
world illustrate the suggestions listed above. provinces fund their schools and
There is naturally no perfect system, and all providing technical assistance in the
of the systems below are simply compro- development of school-based gov-
mises where the solutions to certain prob- ernance and information. The pol-
lems have created other problems. icy and planning “branch” works
directly with the provinces when it
x The higher-level organization chart comes to implementation but also
(as specified by decree) for Argen- sees the “line” branches as its clients
tina’s national Ministry of Educa- when developing norms or policies.
tion, Science, and Technology does Traditional functions such as cur-
not even refer to traditional lines riculum development are embedded
such as “primary” or “secondary.” It in the line functions. Staff functions
has a Sub-Secretariat for Quality, are performed within the policy and
with Directorates for Information planning “branch,” but that has been
and Assessment, Equity Programs, an uncomfortable compromise. As
and Curriculum and Teacher train- noted above, this is a relatively old-
ing; it also has a Directorate for fashioned approach, and while
Technical-Administrative Assis- South Africa has a highly regarded
tance. This is the case in Korea as system of inter-governmental rela-
well. Note that in both cases the tions, it is not clear that the internal
emphasis is on supporting functions structure of the national Department
and institutions, not traditional “lev-
els.”
x In the UK’s Department for Educa-
tion and Skills, there are five Direc-
tors-General for Schools, Youth, 13
Not shown, but available at
Corporate Services and Develop- http://www.dfes.gov.uk/deptreport2002/pdf/01-
ment, Lifelong Learning, and Fi- Prelims.pdf.

53
Education Sector Review Volume 2

of Education is optimal.14 The main “line” headings in Korea’s


x Organizational models such as those organization are: 1) Planning and
suggested here are not unique to Management, 2) School Policy, 3)
geographically decentralized coun- Human Resources Development, 4)
tries. Korea’s education system is Lifelong and Vocational Education,
effective, but it is not decentralized 5) University Affairs, 6) Local Edu-
in a geographical manner similar to cation Services, and 7) General Af-
those of countries discussed above. fairs. The functions such as audit
Nevertheless, Korea’s Ministry of and inspection are to the side of the
Education is organized entirely main headings to the main headings
without the traditional line functions (they are not line functions).
that usually exist in an
“implementation” ministry, similar Bearing all of the foregoing in mind, Figure
to those of, say, the UK. 3 on the following page sketches a possible
organizational structure for Depdiknas.

14
In South Africa, the Ministry as such is very
small and exists only to support the Minister as a
political appointee. The Department, which con-
tains most of the employees, runs all of the bu-
reaucratic and operational affairs and is headed
by a single technical appointee on contract who
answers to the Minister.

54
Figure 3. One possible organizational structure for Depdiknas

Minister

Inspector General
(focus on financial and Secretary General
audit issues only)

HR Internal to
Ministry
Policy and Planning General education Lifelong education Higher education

Budgeting and
Financial Controls of
Institutional Finance Ministry and
(Funding formula Curricular analysis, Nationally-Run
support, norming, development, norming, Various subunits Programs
policy; budget dialogue) and support

Other functions
Teacher policy on internal to Ministry
Information systems and or nationally-run
evaluation, in-service
data gathering programs
training, pay,
deployment

Institution (schools.
colleges, universities)
measurement and quality
assurance

Governance and
management norming
and support to districts
and schools

Research and policy


analysis on structural
issues, coordination of
policy support to
Minister

55
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Appendix 1.6. Minimum Service Standards as Management and


Governance Tools
Minimum Service Standards (Standar Pelaya- sector with salutary lessons for education, see
nan Minimal–SPM) are potentially a useful Baker and Trémolet, 2002). It also makes
governance and management tool. However, sense to anchor the discussion of SPMs in the
if misapplied, they can be a hindrance or, specific context of the overall process of de-
worse, can actually undermine decentralized centralization in Indonesia. If one then adds
governance. This Appendix tackles the issue what little international evidence does exist,
of whether SPMs in Indonesia, as the situation one has some basis for judging the current
currently stands, are likely to be more of a state of affairs with regard to education SPMs
help than a hindrance. in Indonesia according to the following crite-
ria:
The basic decentralization law, No. 22/1999, is
silent on the issue of minimum standards. It is x Numbers: Are there too many or too
Government Regulation No. 25/2000 that calls few? Are the numbers, by sub-issue
for the preparation of guidelines for determin- or sub-function, appropriate to the im-
ing SPMs that must be “implemented” by local portance of the issue or sub-function?
governments. Other recent regulations, such x Type: True service standard or aggre-
as Government Regulation 105 of 2000, have gate indicator?
specified that local government budgets should x Motivation and use: Vertical reporting
be performance-oriented, based on minimum or horizontal reporting? Accountabil-
standards that measure performance. Gov- ity to citizens or to politicians and bu-
ernment Regulation 108 of 2000 also calls for reaucratic management?
minimum standards in the evaluation of local x Technical quality: Are the SPMs well-
government performance. In response to these specified and measurable?
various regulations, Indonesia began in 2002 x Level to be reached: Are the levels of
to devise some SPMs with some false starts the indicators to be reached too high
and some confusion due in no small measure or too low?
to a lack of clarity in the legislation, including x Level at which measured: Are the dis-
the definition of terminology (see Donor SPM trict-level indicators based on school-
Working Group 2002, also GTZ-Support for level or unit-level indicators? Are
Decentralization Measures et. al. 2003). (This they measurable as a by-product of
problem is compounded by the Education unit-level managerial needs?
Law, No. 20/2003, as noted in other sections
of this chapter.) However, in spite of a rocky Before applying these criteria to the draft edu-
start, the process, under a MoHA-led “model- cation SPMs in Indonesia, it is useful to ex-
building” exercise, had produced a set of draft pand a little on these concepts, based on
minimum standards for the education sector by decentralization and public finance theory and
mid-2003 (Departemen Pendidikan Na- practice and on what little international evi-
sional/Unit Fasilitasi Desentralisasi Pendidi- dence does exist. Thus, in each case below,
kan, 2003). we discuss first a little of the “theory” and then
apply the “theory” to the Indonesian education
In gauging the likely impact of minimum stan- case.
dards on decentralized governance, it is impor-
tant to note that there is no accepted body of
Numbers
theory or practice that can be used as a solid
basis for guidance (see Ferrazzi, 2002). How- Certainly, it is better to have few standards
ever, minimum standards can also be ap- than to have none. The usual reason given for
proached from the point of view of more the desirability of standards is circular: stan-
generally accepted practical and theoretical dards are assumed to be self-evidently good
notions of decentralization and intergovern- because no one would argue for things to be
mental public finance (see Smoke, 2002 and, sub-standard. But the more fundamental rea-
for interesting similarities to a very different son for having standards is that they lower the

56
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

transaction costs involved when social or eco- tention away from the more central and gen-
nomic agents hold each other accountable. eral interests, such as basic general education,
Thus, the criterion by which to judge whether that have less organized defenders. Setting
an appropriate number of standards is being minimum standards and obligatory functions
used is whether the number of standards really and maintaining a strong central role in poli-
helps agents to hold each other accountable, cymaking can prevent this sort of “whip-
whether standards are in fact lowering transac- sawing” of local governments.15 However, as
tion costs or increasing them, or whether the will be seen below (where undue attention is
transaction costs they avoid are worth the cost sometimes given to sports education or to
entailed in tracking the standards. Further- teachers in general), at the moment the central
more, clearly those sectors where policymak- government in Indonesia seems more likely to
ers believe that accountability is most abet special interests than to control them.
important (perhaps because they require a
higher proportion of the national budget) In Indonesia, as the draft minimum standards
should have more standards. Having too many document currently stands, it appears that
standards can actually reduce accountability if there are simply too many standards, or, indi-
the number gets to the point where it is unreal- cators, and that they are grossly out of propor-
istic to expect so many to be monitored. tion to the importance of the areas in question.
Worse, a proliferation of standards, especially The draft contains 197 indicators, all with ap-
if they are set too high or if their numbers are parently equal priority. True, many of them
out of proportion to the intrinsic importance of are repetitive, since, for example, the draft re-
the area in question, can be a signal that spe- quires that data on enrollment rates be col-
cial interest groups are trying to capture budg- lected at the primary, junior secondary, and
etary resources, by mandating, say, that senior secondary levels. Nonetheless, to ex-
schools or districts must have teachers teach- pect managers to agree to be held accountable
ing in specialized areas. Finally, the appropri- for 197 indicators, without any real sense of
ate number of standards will also depend on prioritization among them, seems either naïve
the type of standards in question. (See below or cynical. Few competent managers would
for a discussion of types.) If the standards be- agree to be truly held politically accountable
ing set are of the consumer-satisfaction or citi- for that many indicators. Furthermore, the
zen-rights type, it is likely that the optimal numbers are out of all proportion to their in-
number may be fairly high. If standards are trinsic importance. While there are only 18
for purposes of bureaucratic or political ac- indicators related to primary schooling, there
countability and diagnosis, the optimal number are 22 indicators related to sports education,
is likely to be much smaller. and while there is an indicator that induces
better reporting of sports statistics, there is no
One reason to prefer more, rather than fewer, similar indicator inducing the reporting of
indicators, is that having a clear set of indica- educational statistics. This is not necessarily
tors allows local governments to stick to their to suggest that the latter should be added; it is
core mission. If DPRD members are seen as more to suggest that the former is excessive.
venal or not very capable and local citizens are
prey to populist illusions such as “fiscal illu- The clear impression is that tracking this many
sion” (the belief that resources that come from indicators will increase rather than lower the
a central level are “free”—see Dollery and
Wallis 2001), they can easily fall prey to spe-
cial interests who try to force local govern- 15
“Whip-sawing” is a style of collective bargaining
ments to compete with each other in providing in which a powerful union negotiates with more
non-essential services. By the logic of collec- than one employer, pitting one employer against
tive action, it is naturally the less “general” in- another and forcing each employer in turn to meet
terests that are able to steer public funding or exceed the agreement that the union previously
towards their favorite cause. Hence, it is pos- made with a different employer. The same applies
to special interests pitting local governments
sible that special interests could start races be-
against each other and to any sort of negotiation in
tween local governments in providing services general. A whip-saw is a saw operated by two
or sub-services that are of more special interest people, where the cutting requires a back-and-forth
such as sports or music, drawing managers’ at- motion.

57
Education Sector Review Volume 2

transaction costs related to accountability and gated data as the gross or net enrollment ratios
runs the risk of skewing accountability by that risk being too general to be useful at the
forcing managers and governors to concentrate local level. Of the indicators that we re-
equally on essential and non-essential items. viewed, only one or two would be of any in-
Both the absolute numbers of indicators and terest to a particular parent, such as the
proportionality between them needs to be seri- proportion of students who pass a given exam.
ously revisited. Few parents are likely to care whether the
gross enrollment rate is 70 percent or 90 per-
Type, Motivation, and Use cent as long as his or her child is enrolled in
school. Nor do the SPMs focus on workers
Across the world, the overwhelming majority within the system and the accountability of
of “minimum service standards” are con- system units to each other. Similarly, they do
sumer-level or citizen-level standards of direct not contain any service indicators such as the
service delivery. Some examples of these in- time it would take the Dinas Pendidikan to ful-
clude citizens being notified more than 24 fill a school’s book order or how long it would
hours in advance of any planned interruption take to register a teacher’s promotion and no-
in service or specifying that parents will be in- tify the payroll system, and for the teacher’s
formed of their children’s end-of-year test promotion to be reflected in his or her pay.
scores within four weeks or that a local educa- The whole ethos of providing parent-oriented
tion office will respond to any query from a service indicators or indicators of mutual ac-
school within forty-eight hours or that parents countability is absent from Indonesia’s current
have a right to know the average test scores of draft SPMs.
all the schools in the district. These standards
can be set irrespective of political ideology or As noted above, when indicators focus on di-
whether one regards the subject of service as a rect service provision, it may optimal to have
“client” or “consumer” in a “marketized” ap- rather more indicators than when indicators are
proach or as a “citizen” with rights in a “hu- used for upward accountability or horizontal
man-rights” approach. Thus, institutions but political accountability. The reason for this
advocating quality improvements from a is because each individual client is likely to
rights-oriented viewpoint emphasize the indi- want to hold service providers accountable ac-
vidual-level service standards (see Theis, cording to the indicator that interests him or
2003) as much as traditional corporatist insti- her and because indicators bearing on direct
tutions. (For a discussion of the changes in service delivery are likely to be more immedi-
perspective and ideology involved in the ate to the actual process and characteristics of
“Charterist” or MSP approach in the UK, service delivery and to the everyday tasks of
which applies fairly generally, see Falconer, the service delivery agents. Furthermore, in-
no date, or Wallis and Dollery, 2002.) dividual clients are less likely than system
managers to act as interest groups engaged in
If not at the level of direct service provision, rent-seeking; their actions are more likely to
indicators should at least refer as much as pos- be consistent with actual welfare. Thus, if in-
sible to outputs of the system rather than in- dicators are oriented towards making service
puts. In cases like governance, where process providers accountable to clients, then there is
is in effect the output, it is vital to have proc- likely to be little loss of focus from having a
ess indicators, such as ensuring that govern- few more indicators.
ance bodies (such as School Committees) are
working to norm, e.g., have the right number One suggestion would be for Indonesia to con-
of parents as opposed to teachers, and have sider replacing many of its current aggregate,
followed proper nomination procedures to top-down indicators, with citizen-level and
elect the members. unit-level indicators that will enable both hori-
zontal and reverse accountability. (Reverse ac-
At present, the draft Indonesian SPMs are de- countability means, for example, Dinas
signed to make schools and districts account- Pendidikan being accountable to schools for
able to the central education ministry rather book delivery, not just schools being account-
than to clients or citizens. They are very often able to the Dinas Pendidikan for the quality of
input-oriented and tend to cover such aggre- their education services.) Furthermore, the

58
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

overall number of indicators should be re- teach and which are not weighted in
duced and those that remain should mostly be any way.
indicators of output rather than inputs.
x Many districts in Indonesia are quite
Technical Quality small. Measurement of such key vari-
ables as dropping out or moving up to
To be useful, it is self-evident that SPMs have a higher education level will therefore
to be measurable. Yet, according to the cur- generally be extremely unreliable. In
rent draft of the education minimum standards, small and generally under-supplied
a minority (but a fairly large minority) of the districts, transition rates will probably
Indonesian indicators are not measurable or appear to be very low. In large, well-
are specified too poorly to be measurable. For supplied districts that are situated next
example: to smaller and less well-supplied ones,
the transition rate to higher levels of
x There are indicators that specify that education (junior or senior secondary)
systems will exist to allow teachers appear to be higher than 100 percent
access to certain levels of training, and because children are migrating, either
the indicator is set at, say, 50 percent, on a day-to-day basis, or sent to live
without specifying whether this means with relatives, to take advantage of
that the systems should be 50 percent educational opportunities. This will
operational, whether 50 percent of dis- make indicators such as dropping out
tricts should have operational systems, and transition rates extremely difficult
or whether the systems should reach to measure—in fact impossible, in
50 percent of the teachers. practice.
x Similarly, there are indicators for such It does not do any good to wish these matters
vague things as the percentage of away: they are fundamental measurement
youths taking part in training that im- problems, and attempting to measure the un-
proves their character and attitude, measurable creates, rather than reduces, social
without specifying how one might and bureaucratic tension, and makes citizens
measure whether a program helps im- lose respect for the state. In short, there are
prove attitude or character, or whether quite a few indicators in the draft document
in fact the students’ character and atti- that have simply not been well designed.
tude have in fact been improved. The
issue of self-selection (youths of fairly In the case of some of the indicators, even
good character are more likely to join though measurement is possible in theory, in
such programs) needs to be taken into practice it will turn out to be very difficult be-
account. In principle, one could cer- cause there are no actual delivery units on
tify certain courses as being “charac- whom it makes administrative sense to gather
ter-improving” and then count those, the data. One example would be the proposal
but this would require the onerous task to track the number of youths participating in
of certifying just about every course of an economically meaningful activity. (See be-
any kind available to students and still low on the importance of data being a by-
avoids the fundamental measurement product of administrative practice.) It would
issue. be possible in principle to use random sample
surveys to measure this indicator, but note that
x On a more important point that refers random sample surveys are no good for track-
to basic educational delivery, there is ing the data needed for accountability except
an attempt to measure “teachers’ at the very highest and most aggregated level.
readiness to teach,” and a standard is This is a much more serious problem than the
set at 90 percent. But the indicator re- problem of the theoretical inadequacy of the
fers to a number of extremely complex indicator.
variables for which there is little em-
pirical evidence about their effective-
ness in measuring actual readiness to

59
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Level at which Indicators are Set, Level invest. Finally, in situations where horizontal
to be Reached accountability mechanisms (accountability of
local government to DPRD or citizens, for ex-
In a competitive market or in a democracy, ample) are still weak, it is justified for higher-
government (in the case of markets) or higher- level government to set levels of key indica-
level governments (in the case of governance) tors, not just the indicator framework as such.
need not in principle set the levels of any per-
formance standards. The role of the govern- But the cases where specific levels are stated,
ment, for example, should be limited to in Indonesia, are excessive, as they go beyond
establishing the whole system of weights and the above-stated justifications. Even if, as
measures as a standard and ensuring that all appears to be the case, the policy is that the in-
merchants sell in kilograms rather than some dicators can be reached at different speeds by
in kilograms and others in pounds and others different governments, having the same termi-
in bushels (thus creating transparency for con- nal point still does not make sense, in many of
sumers). However, the government should not the indicators. For example, it is not clear why
tell merchants how much to sell or at what every local government should value sports
price. Similarly, in a competitive political en- the same (and it is difficult to argue that sports
vironment where local bureaucrats and politi- represent a serious externality) or why the
cians have to compete for votes and taxes, fight against HIV/AIDS or drug abuse should
higher levels of government should ensure that be fought at exactly the same level of intensity
lower levels of government can be judged in every district, when it is well-known that
against a common set of standards but need both HIV/AIDS and drug abuse tend to happen
not necessarily set a level for those standards. in geographical clusters. Yet the SPMs are ex-
In either case, competition and emulation will tremely detailed regarding sports indicators
set the optimum level at which transactions (for example, something to the effect that 15
take place, in other words, the level that con- percent of athletes in every location should be
sumers want and at which producers can af- winning or should be competing at the highest
ford to produce. This will vary from place to organized level!), yet totally silent on many
place and from person to person because eve- other areas of education for life, such as art or
ryone and every local government has differ- music. Perhaps some local governments
ent needs and different capacities. Setting a would rather have less sports education and,
fixed level is by definition sub-optimal, unless say, more gamelan education. Yet music or
every citizen has exactly identical preferences arts education is not at all covered. This is not
and every firm and local government has ex- to say that arts and music education should be
actly identical technology, natural resources, covered; it is to say that the current coverage
and capital, which is never the case. of areas such as sport is extremely excessive.
And, this is only one example—there are quite
In situations of monopoly, however, the gov- a few other such cases. One could argue that
ernment does set the actual level of expected this imbalance already represents a “capture”
service provision, as is the case in the devel- of local government by special interests,
opment of service standards for either public though in this case with the connivance of cen-
or private public utilities that are “natural” tral government. It is clear that this is not
monopolies. These standards are, or should likely to be the intent, but it is nonetheless the
be, contained in the licensing of new utilities, practical effect—hardly an optimal role for
such as cell phone or cable television licenses. central government to be playing.
Similarly, in situations where local govern-
ments affect each other in non-measurable The level (and the numbers) at which the indi-
ways (“externalities,” as in the case where citi- cators are set might also “set up” local gov-
zens with secondary education are likely to ernment for failure, which would be an excuse
migrate from the areas where they were edu- for the central level to “re-centralize.” Few
cated, thus benefiting the receiving areas with central organizations give up the privileges of
services they did not pay for) it makes sense centralization willingly, so it is logical that
for government to mandate certain levels of they would try to reassert control, and one way
provision that assure the national interest— to do so is to set the goals very high so that lo-
otherwise the local area has a disincentive to cal governments fail. Even if the motivation

60
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

were not so undesirable, a moment’s reflection ministratively within the delivery units them-
will suggest that the national government ap- selves, and, furthermore, the administrative
pears to want to hold local governments ac- recording should be such that it directly helps
countable with a degree of specificity and at a the unit itself do a better job of delivering its
level that it did not hold itself effectively ac- services.
countable to citizens during the period of cen-
tralization. The fact that the standards One solution that has been proposed to the
suddenly appear higher when it is someone problem of under-reporting by schools is that
else (local governments) that is being held ac- schools be supplied with the data that are
countable should be cause of some concern re- compiled by the central Education Manage-
garding the sincerity of motivation in the ment Information System (EMIS), so that they
SPMs, and is likely to be noted by local au- see what is done with the data. But this is not
thorities as a questionable intention on the part likely to be very motivating, except initially,
of central government. as a novelty. Another idea that is similarly
unlikely to be effective is the idea that schools
Finally, it should be noted that, with only one supply the EMIS with data and that the EMIS
exception to our knowledge (Lewis, 2003), no somehow makes the information available
one is estimating the costs of the levels at back to the school for management purposes
which the indicators are being set. It is not as a way of creating an incentive for them to
just a matter of financial cost—that is the easy continue collecting and reporting data. This is
part. In many cases, the financial cost is lower also likely an unworkable proposition, as any
than the opportunity cost of scarce manage- data useful for management will be out-of-date
ment talent, because the rationing of labor and by the time it makes the round trip from the
the allocation of labor to tasks, and in particu- school to the EMIS and back to the school. In
lar scarce high-level management talent, in the the end, the most effective means of ensuring
public service is not very efficient and the hu- adequate reporting from schools and districts
man resource implications of meeting the lev- is a combination of a) data reporting as a by-
els of the various indicators are not being product of routine administrative recording by
calculated either. This suggests that much the delivery units and b) sheer bureaucratic
more emphasis should be put on using the in- pressure from the center within a strengthened
dicators as a framework of accountability in administrative system. On the first score, the
which the level is not determined by fiat but is idea is to make sure schools are directly ac-
determined through emulation and competi- countable for certain services and feel pressure
tion, for example through the issuance by cen- to be so accountable, to make sure that they
tral government of comparative score-cards on understand what data helps them discharge
service performance of local governments. that accountability well, and to make sure that
the system for reporting data towards higher
Level at which Measured levels of government mostly use the same data
as are needed at the local level, and which are
Indicators and minimum standards should therefore reported as a by-product of good
lower the transaction costs involved in agents’ administrative practice at the school level.
holding each other accountable, but they
should do so without imposing complex bu- In Indonesia’s draft education SPMs, some of
reaucratic requirements and measurement cost. the indicators are indeed a byproduct of good
One way to do so is to make sure that the indi- administrative practice. The gross and net en-
cators are measured as much as possible as the rollment indicators, for example, are the result
by-product of administrative systems that as- of data that good schools should keep and use
sist the actual delivery units (such as schools) in management in any case, such as records of
in the delivery process. Clearly, indicators student numbers by grade and age (as well as
that are aimed at ensuring the quality of direct by gender). However, a few are difficult to
service delivery to the client will accomplish track because there are no units that currently
this more or less automatically (which is an- provide the services being tracked and in
other advantage of such indicators), but that is whose interest it is to track the variable in
only one way. In general, the indicators question. For example, there is an indicator
should be measurable as much as possible ad- that refers to activities aimed at increasing

61
Education Sector Review Volume 2

awareness of the value of education. That is a livery units already exist that have an
fine sentiment and lofty goal, but the indicator interest in measuring these indicators
is set at 80 percent, without specifying what for their own administrative purposes
this means. It is not clear what the numerator (if they are well-managed).
and denominator should be, nor in whose in- x set more indicators as direct service
terest it is to track this, nor what classifies as delivery indicators, both for service
such an activity. delivery to parents and students and
service delivery from unit to unit, and
Conclusion set much fewer indicators of upward
bureaucratic or political accountabil-
In summary, the education SPM exercise may ity.
be a good beginning. However, before these
x limit the use of indicators that are not
indicators can be activated, very serious work
measurable as an essential element of
should be done to:
the administrative capacity of service
x radically shorten the list of indicators. delivery units.
x reduce the number of the input indica-
tors in particular. If this is not done, the indicators are likely to
x not set actual levels for many indica- add more to transaction costs than they will
tors and instead use score-cards and save in transaction costs, and on top of that,
other means of stimulating informed they are likely to increase measurement and
competition so as to allow “natural” bureaucratic costs. In that case, the natural re-
levels to be found. action of local government and delivery units
x keep levels as quantitative goals in a will likely be to ignore the indicators, even if
few key output indicators. they initially agreed to collect them. This will
x think through the technical problems tend to make enforcement costs very high, and
and costs of gathering the indicators, cause the effort to wither.
including their definition, ways to
measure them, and whether local de-

References For Appendix 1.6

Baker, B. and S. Trémolet. 2000. “Regulation mum Service Standards: A Proposal for Con-
of Quality of Infrastructure Services in Devel- ceptual Development and Implementation,”
oping Countries.” NERA. Paper given at the Jakarta: Word processed.
conference on Infrastructure for Development:
Private Solutions for the Poor, London, UK, Falconer, P. No date. “Public Administration
31 May – 2 June. Word processed. and the New Public Management: Lessons
from the UK Experience.” Department of Law
Departemen Pendidikan Nasional/Unit Fasili- and Public Administration, Glasgow Caledo-
tasi Desentralisasi Pendidikan. 2003. “Kewe- nian University, Glasgow, Scotland, UK:
nangan Wajib Dan Standar Pelayanan Minimal Word processed.
Bidang Pendidikan, Pemuda dan Olahraga.”
Jakarta: Word processed. Ferrazzi, G. 2002. “Obligatory Functions and
Minimum Service Standards: A Preliminary
Dollery, B. and J. Wallis. 2001. “A Taxo- Review of the Indonesian Approach,” GTZ-
nomic Analysis of Government Failure in Lo- SfDM, Jakarta: Word processed.
cal Government.” School of Economics,
University of New England, Armidale, Austra- GTZ-Support for Decentralization Measures,
lia. Working Paper Series in Economics No. USAID-Perform, USAID-MSH, ADB-Basic
2001-7. Word processed. Education, The World Bank-WBDTFID.
2003. “Draft Laporan Sintesa – Kegiatan
Donor SPM Working Group. 2002. “Local Model Building Kewenangan Wajib Dan
Government Obligatory Functions and Mini-

62
Chapter 1 Governance and Management under Decentralization

Standar Pelayanan” Minimal, Jakarta: Word Theis, J. 2003. “Rights-based Monitoring and
processed. Evaluation.” Save the Children: Word proc-
essed.
Lewis, B. 2003. “Minimum Local Public
Service Delivery Standards in Indonesia: Wallis, J. and B. Dollery. 2002. “Styles of
Fiscal Implications and Affordability Con- Policy Leadership and Local Government Re-
cerns.” Draft version. Research Triangle In- form.” University of Otago Economics Dis-
stitute International, Research Triangle Park, cussion Papers No. 0206. Dunedin, New
North Carolina, USA: Word processed. Zealand.

Smoke, P. 2002. “Expenditure Assignment


under Indonesia’s Emerging Decentralization:
A Review of Progress and Issues for the Fu-
ture.” Prepared for conference on “Can De-
centralization Help Rebuild Indonesia?”
Andrew Young School of Policy Studies,
Georgia State University, Atlanta, Georgia,
USA. May 1-3. Word processed.

63
Education Sector Review Volume 2

64
Chapter 2: Financing Education under Decentralization

Indonesia’s decentralization laws have not classrooms, then education outcomes will de-
only profoundly changed the distribution of teriorate under the new regime. Finally, the
authority and responsibilities among different chapter offers policy options for improving al-
levels of governments but also how fiscal re- location mechanisms at all levels of govern-
sources are generated and who controls them. ment, for aligning resources and financial
The old transfer system, which was character- management with the goals of the Indonesian
ized chiefly by earmarked grants from the cen- education sector, and for ensuring that schools
tral government budget to provincial and receive adequate resources.
district governments, has been replaced by one
that consists largely of general grants from the New Fiscal Structures under
central government budget to local govern- Decentralization
ments with expanded revenue sharing. Unlike
earmarked grants that have to be spent for Prior to decentralization, the national govern-
specified purposes, how the general grants are ment transferred public funds to the regional
used is left up to the discretion of the recipient governments through the Autonomous Gov-
government. Also, the laws now allow re- ernment Subsidy (Subsidi Daerah Otonom or
gional—that is, provincial and district— SDO) and through Presidential Instruction
governments to retain an increasing share of grants (Instruksi Presiden or INPRES). For
the revenues generated from local economic more than 30 years before 2001, the SDO was
activity and natural resources. By the time de- the basic grant mechanism for recurrent ex-
centralization has been fully implemented, to- penditures, while general- and special-purpose
tal regional government expenditures are INPRES transfers were the vehicle for devel-
expected to account for about 10 percent of opment grants. The SDO financed almost the
GDP or more than 40 percent of total govern- whole bill for the salaries and allowances of
ment spending (Hofman, Kaiser, and Goga civil servants in regional governments, includ-
2003). ing the pay of primary school teachers. It also
covered routine expenditures such as those to
This fiscal and financial restructuring is likely fund the operation and maintenance of school
to affect how much public money will be spent buildings and administrative expenditures.
on education and also how efficiently those re- Meanwhile, INPRES grants, which began as a
sources will be spent, although many of the simple block grant mechanism in the late
specifics of these fiscal structures have yet to 1960s, evolved into a diverse array of grants
be defined or clarified. This chapter discusses with at least 15 different specific-purpose
the implications of these new financial ar- transfers, including those for primary schools,
rangements and identifies important issues that primary health care, roads, and agricultural ex-
should be addressed by policymakers. The tension among others (Silver, Azis, and
chapter begins by briefly contrasting the old Schroeder, 2001 and Lewis, 2002). A lot of
and new fiscal structures and the old and new the progress made in human development in
relationships between the central government the regions has been attributed to the INPRES
and the regional governments, and then goes grants,16 but this mechanism is said to have
on to discuss the likely consequences of these been characterized also by excessive central
changes for the financing of education. Be- control, a lack of transparency in its allocation
cause financing education involves not only procedures, and a lack of regional autonomy.
increasing the amount of resources available
but also improving how those resources are
spent, the discussion covers both efficiency 16
and equity concerns. One important issue is Duflo (2001) estimates that the INPRES program
raised the probability that a child would complete
what happens within districts and within
primary school by 12 percent, and thus increased
schools. If regional governments fail to allo- the average years of schooling by 0.25 to 0.40 year
cate adequate resources to schools or if those for the cohort of children during the period 1974-
resources somehow do not reach schools and 78.

65
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Figure 2.1 Post-Decentralization Financial Structure

DAU/Shared Revenues
Central
Government
DAK
Ministry of Ministry of
Religious National General Flows
Affairs Education APBD

Earmarked Flows
ABPD
Provincial
government

APBN APBN

Dinas District Dinas


Education Government Education
Spending Spending

Public Schools
Religious Schools

Source: Hoffman, Kaiser and Goga, 2003.

Under decentralization, resource transfer ar- DAU Allocations


rangements have changed. The new transfer In FY2002, DAU grants from the central gov-
system is a combination of two grant chan- ernment accounted, on average, for more than
nels—the General Purpose Fund (Dana Alo- 70 percent of the revenues of provincial and
kasi Umum or DAU) and the Specific Purpose district governments. In principle, these grants
Fund (Dana Alokasi Khusus or DAK)—and are allocated according to a formula that takes
shared revenues from natural resources (Sum- into account differences in local needs and in
ber Daya Alam or SDA) (Figure 2.1).17 Prov- local means. In practice, however, the for-
inces receive 10 percent of the total amount of mula-based part of the grant is only a fraction
DAU transfers, while district governments re- of it. The formula continues to evolve, but in
ceive 90 percent (Hofman, Kaiser, and Goga, 2002 the total allocation to each provincial or
2002). In addition to these grant mechanisms, district government comprised three parts,
the central government is able to expand the namely, a lump sum amount, a fiscal gap
resources available in the regions directly by amount, and a balancing factor amount (Silver,
channeling funds from its own national budget Azis, and Schroeder, 2001; Lewis, 2002; and
(anggaran pendapatan dan belanja nasional Brodjonegoro and Martinez-Vazquez, 2002).
or APBN) to public schools (through the
MoNE) and to madrasahs (through the In 2002, the lump sum component for any par-
MoRA). The regional governments’ routine or ticular district was 10 percent of the total DAU
recurrent budgets (Daftar Isian Kegiatan or amount divided by the total number of dis-
DIK) pay for civil service expenditures, recur- tricts. The fiscal gap component was allocated
rent materials and the cost of goods, and sub- to each district based on the size of the dis-
sidies (such as for fuel and electricity) in trict’s fiscal gap relative to the country’s total
schools, while their development budgets fiscal gap, with the fiscal gap being defined as
(Daftar Isian Projek or DIP) are spent on capi- the difference between estimated expenditure
tal projects such as school construction. needs and fiscal capacity. This component
was designed to take the expenditure needs of
each district into account when determining
the level of its transfer. This formula for the
fiscal gap component, which was based on ac-
17
By law, the annual DAU allocation is a minimum tual expenditure amounts in the previous year
of 25 percent of the central government’s total do- as given by the total regional government
mestic revenues minus any revenues shared with budget (anggaran pendapatan dan belanja
regional governments.

66
Chapter 2 Financing Education under Decentralization

daerah or APBD) and an allocation factor, has civil service wage bill. The fiscal gap ac-
been criticized for being mechanistic rather counted for 50 percent rather than the 40 per-
than based on the real expenditure needs of re- cent that was the case with the allocation to
gional governments.18 districts.

The third component, the balancing factor or DAK Allocation


“hold harmless” factor, was meant to ensure
The DAK is a special-purpose transfer that is
that no district would receive less than it had
supposed to finance capital expenditures that
received the previous year. In FY2001, this
cannot be predicted or accommodated using
amounted to 50 percent of the total DAU allo-
cation, and the amount going to each district the common allocation formula as well as
was a function of the district’s share of the to- those that are national commitments or priori-
ties. By law, this grant cannot be used for ad-
tal civil service wage bill for the country. It
was supposed to cover the costs incurred by ministrative costs or for the training and travel
of staff and other such costs. It has two com-
districts in taking on the additional
responsibility for paying civil servants as a ponents: one is based on national reforestation
result of decentralization. In FY2002, this measures, which stipulate that 40 percent of
component funded 77 percent of each district’s state reforestation levies on forestry companies
should be returned to the district of origin for
wage bill on average.
exclusive use in reforestation activities; and a
The provincial DAU allocations were derived second is the “real” special-purpose grant for
using a formula similar to the one used for the financing national priority infrastructure in-
districts, except that the lump sum and balanc- vestments that are outside the scope of DAU
ing factor components were based on 20 and funding. The latter, designed as a matching
30 percent respectively of the total provincial grant, requires that a region’s contribution to a
DAU budget (Lewis, 2002). In FY2002, each project be at least 10 percent of total project
province received a lump sum allocation of Rp expenditures and is designed to provide dis-
46.8 billion and funding for 31 percent of their tricts with incentives to build infrastructure
that meets national standards. In the past two
years, the DAK allocation has remained mini-
mal compared with the DAU allocation.
18
Since about 70 percent of regional expenditures are fi- However, the central government has reiter-
nanced through intergovernmental transfers, it makes ated its intention to use targeted DAK grants
sense to examine the formula according to which these
transfers are allocated. The allocation criterion is an ex- to districts as a mechanism for ensuring equal-
penditure needs index for each district that is based on ity among them and transparency in their op-
four characteristics of the district – population, area, erations (DSEF, 2002). This grant mechanism
poverty, and a cost index (Lewis, 2002). The 2002 for- continued to evolve in 2003.
mula for expenditure needs was: EN = APBD [0.4
RPop + 0.1 RArea + 0.1 RPovGap + 0.4 Rcost ], where
Rpop, Rarea, RpovGap, and Rcost represent the ratios of Raising Own Revenues
a district’s population, land area, poverty gap, and cost
index to the total values for the country. These factors In Indonesia, Law 34/2000 has given taxing
were specified in Law 25/99; in 2001, they were given authority to district governments. Districts,
equal weight. Local fiscal capacity is defined as the sum but not provinces, are now allowed to generate
of potential own-source revenues and shared revenues their own taxes through local by-laws under
from property taxes, personal income taxes, and natural
resource taxes. Of the four factors in the formula, popu-
the condition that the taxes should be author-
lation size and poverty together measure the potential ized by the national government and that they
demands on the public education system. This formula- should be consistent with the principles men-
based allocation is similar to those used in several other tioned in Law 34/2000.19 Since being given
countries (Bird and Smart, 2002). For example, Japan,
Brazil, Nigeria, and Austria use similar systems in which
local governments receive a fixed share of national taxes,
and the resulting total is then distributed according to a 19
formula that takes into account such factors as population
This is not a new phenomenon, however. Law
and community size. In the Philippines, most funds 18/1997, the previous law on local taxes and levies,
transferred to local governments come from a pre- was intended to stop the practice that then pre-
determined share of national taxes and are allocated ac- vailed in local government of creating a plethora of
cording to population, area, and an equalizing factor. local government taxes. Many of these taxes had
little revenue potential but imposed high costs on

67
Education Sector Review Volume 2

this authority, district governments have been increasingly exercise their right to borrow, it
creating new taxes aggressively (Lewis, will soon be necessary to improve the frame-
2002).20 The reality, however, is that district work of grants and on-lending mechanisms for
governments have limited capacity to raise the regions.
taxes from their own resources such as land,
buildings, and natural resources, which consti- In the future, provincial and district govern-
tute only about 5 percent of their revenues. ments will be increasingly expected to mobi-
Provincial governments have a larger own- lize their own resources in addition to their
resource base but must share this with district transfers from central government in order to
governments. Moreover, there are large ine- finance their expanded responsibilities.21 This
qualities in the revenue bases of the different may make public spending more efficient.
provinces and of the different districts. For ex- When people have to spend some of their own
ample, the per capita non-oil and gas GDP of money on providing services, they are more
the richest province, Jakarta, is almost nine likely to want to see the whole allocation spent
times larger than that of the poorest province, wisely and frugally. Also, local governments
East Nusa Tenggara (Akita and Alisjahbana, may be able to spend money more effectively
2002). The DAU allocation formula includes than the national government because they
a poverty measure and thus provides a means have more access to critical information about
of targeting those districts that are most in local needs, inputs, and providers and because
need and for equalizing the potential resources they can (and are more motivated to) closely
that are available to districts. monitor service provision.

A final point on local financial resources is Several questions arise with respect to the im-
that district governments are allowed to bor- pact of the new fiscal structures on education.
row, although their borrowing is limited by a Will the district governments’ expanded re-
formula that restricts the extent to which they sponsibility for education increase or decrease
can go into debt, that requires approval by the the amount of resources available for educa-
MOF in the case of foreign loans, and that tion? Will the current transfer formula make
cannot be guaranteed by the central govern- regions more or less equal in terms of their
ment. Law 25/1999 also restricts these gov- ability to meet national standards of provision?
ernments to borrowing only for projects that Are district governments allocating sufficient
will generate a financial return, but this clause resources to schools? The next section takes a
has been loosened up by the implementing macro view of these questions.
regulations, which explain that this financial
return can either be direct or indirect. At the Public Spending for Education at the
national level, about half of the development National and Local Levels
budget continues to be financed by donor pro-
ject loans, and the national government cur- One commonly used method for assessing the
rently bears the debt servicing burden on these level of government spending is to compare
expenditures (Hofman, Kadjatmiko, and Kai- numbers across different countries. Based on
ser, 2002). However, as district governments 1998-2000 data from several countries, Indo-
nesia ranked second lowest among its Asian
neighbors in terms of its share of education
the taxpayer and the economy. Law 18 restricted expenditures in GDP (Table 2.1) with only
regional taxes to a specified list and made any addi-
tional taxes conditional upon the approval of the
Ministry of Home Affairs with advice from the
21
Ministry of Finance. With the transfer of authority and management to
20
Property taxes are administered and collected regional governments in Indonesia, “it is hoped that
mainly by the national government, although re- the local governments are capable of obtaining
gional governments assist with tax collection in ru- more funds in their regions and in managing them
ral and urban sectors. Until recently, the national more efficiently and effectively. It is expected that
government retained 10 percent of total tax reve- the local governments are able to use or exploit the
nues for its own use, 9 percent was provided to lo- sources of funds in the regions, such as the private
cal tax offices to assist with collection, 16 percent sector and other education stakeholders, in funding
to provincial governments, and 65 percent to local education” (National Committee for Education,
governments. (Lewis, 2002). Sub-Committee III, 2001).

68
Chapter 2 Financing Education under Decentralization

Table 2.1 Public expenditures for education: How does Indonesia compare with other Asian countries?
Per student primary ex- Percent of education
Education expenditures penditures as a percent expenditures in total
as percent of GDP [a] of GDP per capita [b] public spending [c]
China 2.2 6.58 13.0
Indonesia 2.8 4.21 9.6
Vietnam 2.8 7.26 7.4
India 4.1 12.72 13.7
Singapore 3.1 7.00 23.4
Philippines 3.5 12.69 20.6
Japan 3.5 21.41 10.5
South Korea 4.1 12.30 17.5
Thailand 5.4 17.21 20.1
Malaysia 6.2 12.88 25.2
Notes: [a] From EdStats (http://www1.worldbank.org/education/edstats), World Bank; data from 2000 or latest two years, ex-
cept for China, 1998, Vietnam, 1997 and Singapore, 1995; data are originally from UNESCO; [b] From EdStats and World
Development Indicators, World Bank; data pertain mostly to 2000, except for China, 1998 and Vietnam, 1996, Singapore and
Korea, 1997, or latest two years; [c] From EdStats; and UNESCO, 2000.

China ranking lower; however, Indonesia was Estimates of the level of transfers that were
well behind China in regard to per student made to district governments in 2002 suggest
primary expenditures as a percentage of GDP that, on average, districts have more resources
and education expenditure as a percent of total at their disposal than in the past, and the recent
public spending. Indonesia’s education spend- trend in education spending suggests that dis-
ing was 2.8 percent of GDP, as compared with tricts are spending more of those resources on
4.7 percent for Thailand and 4.6 percent for education. Important questions are whether
Malaysia. As a share of total government these higher educational budgets are sustain-
spending, Indonesia’s education spending was able in the future and also whether they are
slightly higher than Vietnam’s 7.4 percent but adequate for meeting the current responsibili-
was far lower than Thailand’s 20 percent. ties of districts for delivering services.
Perhaps because Indonesia maintained its fo-
cus on getting more children in primary The block grant system, which gives district
schools and perhaps because the cost of inputs decisionmakers latitude to pursue their local
was relatively low, it was able to raise enroll- goals with funds that are not restricted to one
ment rates with relatively meager resources. particular use, offers no guarantees. Local
decisionmakers may choose to spend most of
In FY2001, total government (actual) expendi- their transfers and own revenues on those
ture for education was Rp 41 trillion, of which budget items that are likely to have a quicker
about one-half was part of the APBD alloca- and more stimulating effect on the local econ-
tion. In FY2002, the APBD expenditures in- omy than on education. Indeed, this desire of
creased to Rp 25.5 trillion. In FY2003, total local politicians to obtain quick returns for
government expenditure was expected to reach public spending, coupled with the inability of
Rp 370 trillion, of which nearly Rp 77 trillion districts, being limited labor markets, to cap-
will make up the DAU transfer to regions and ture fully the human capital benefits of educat-
less than Rp 3 trillion will make up the DAK ing their children, may make investing in
transfer. The total government budget repre- educational development unappealing to them.
sents a 13-percent increase over actual expen- On the other hand, local leaders may be driven
ditures in FY2002, and total transfers to to invest in education by the desire of local
regions have increased by 14 percent. If edu- voters for more and better schools or by the
cation expenditures increased by as much, then fact that schools provide local employment or
districts’ spending for education have reached that schools can be a source of prestige for the
about Rp 50 trillion in FY2003, with about Rp community and its leaders. In a decentralized
30 trillion coming from the APBD. setting, the outcome of these factors is uncer-
tain, since the allocation is the result of a mix-
ture of allocation formulae and procedures

69
Education Sector Review Volume 2

and, in very large part, on the willingness of as a way of anticipating issues that may arise
the regions to invest in education. also in Indonesia. In Brazil, the “municipali-
zation” of education resulted in a net loss of
Recent legislation attempts to secure a greater $2.7 billion in total public education spending.
slice of the country’s revenue pie for educa- Between 1988 and 1991, spending on educa-
tion. Education Law 20/2003 stipulates that a tion at the federal level dropped by about one-
minimum of 20 percent of the central APBN half, state-level spending remained approxi-
budget, exclusive of salary costs, and 20 per- mately the same, and spending in municipali-
cent of the districts’ APBD budgets, also ex- ties rose by one-third but not by enough to
clusive of salaries, must be allocated to compensate for the decline in federal spending
education. Including salaries, districts now (Workman, 1997 cited in Behrman, Deola-
spend on average about 40 percent of their likar, and Soon, 2002). In contrast, in Argen-
APBD budgets on education. Excluding sala- tina, total spending on education increased
ries, they spend less than 10 percent (assuming with decentralization, but in Mexico, it did
that salaries are a modest 80 percent of educa- not. Given the educational challenges facing
tion spending out of APBD resources) or less Indonesia, a reduction in education spending
than one-half of what is stipulated in the Edu- in the next few years, especially in the wake of
cation Law. To double the share of education the financial crisis, would certainly set the
spending in APBD net salaries, districts will country back with respect to educational de-
need to make significant reductions in the velopment.
shares of other sectors, which may or may not
be politically possible. So besides the earmarking stipulated by Edu-
cation Law 20/2003, what policies would en-
Earmarking 20 percent of the APBN when the courage the regions to keep up education
MoNE is supposed to have devolved most of spending? Given that DAU allocations are the
its functions to local governments may be dominant means of transferring resources, the
well-intentioned but has disadvantages. It puts key challenge is to encourage provinces and
pressure on the MoNE to develop its own districts to spend these block grants in a par-
spending programs in the regions, which ticular way (in other words, on education)
would mean that most of the capital invest- without relying on earmarking restrictions that
ments in education would be outside the con- can undermine the autonomy of provincial and
trol of district governments. The experience district governments. Chapter 1 of this volume
of other countries shows that this kind of ear- discussed the intention of the central govern-
marking often leads to more spending but not ment to enter into agreements with provincial
necessarily better outcomes because these cen- and district governments on their obligatory
trally-initiated interventions guarantee the functions and on minimum service standards
provision of funds regardless of regional per- as a way of influencing the expenditure
formance and creates multiple opportunities choices of local leaders. There have been sig-
for corruption. A big challenge is to ensure nificant developments and some pilot projects
that earmarked national and local education related to these agreements in the past year;
budgets are indeed spent on schools and stu- within the MoNE, the unit charged with this
dents, that they cover the basic operating ex- responsibility is Unit Fasilitasi. But these
penses of schools besides the costs of teaching compacts are not enforceable unless the central
and non-teaching staff (such as instructional government has enough information to moni-
supplies, the routine activities of the school tor the financial choices that provincial and
committee, the maintenance of a school data- district governments make, and such an infor-
base, the dissemination of information to par- mation system has not yet been built.
ents and the community, utilities, and light
repair of the school buildings and other main- Another option for ensuring that regional gov-
tenance) and their career development activi- ernments spend enough on education is for the
ties. central government to make transfers condi-
tional on the money being spent on basic edu-
It is useful to review some evidence from cation services. The DAK allocation, which
other countries about what happens to the level requires matching funds, has a lot of potential
of funding for education after decentralization for stimulating essential education investments

70
Chapter 2 Financing Education under Decentralization

if the central government uses it to leverage Figure 2.2 Education Expenditures, 2001
capital expenditures that will yield high bene- Central
Recurrent
fits for education. LG Capital
Expenditures
Expenditures
(APBN)
(APBD)
12%
In sum, legislation has expanded the revenue- 6% Central Capit
raising ability of district governments, and Expendit ure
(APBN) 18%
regulations are allowing them to determine
their own financial management, accounting, Province
Recurrent
and procurement systems within broad guide- Expendit ures
lines. That district-level spending now domi- LG Recurrent (APBD) 1%
Expendit ures
nates the country’s education expenditures is (APBD) Province Capital
seen in Figure 2.2. These are reforms that are 60% Expenditures
(APBD)
fully consistent with the goal of devolving de- 3%
cisionmaking authority and accountability to
regional governments. However, the effects of Source: Ministry of Finance, SIKD data.
this new authority are undermined by the fact
that the funding system remains too diverse estimate, fees contribute as much as one-third
and fragmented, with separate agencies admin- of total primary school revenues that are not
istering the relevant budgets at the national allocated to salaries (McMahon and Suwary-
level. During field visits made for this report, ani, 2002).23
regional education officials in Yogyakarta and
Central Java expressed some degree of frustra- Education expenditures in households that
tion at not having a clear sense of the total have children of school age, on average, ac-
level of resources that are actually available counted for 3.4 percent of these households’
for education or of the total amount actually total expenditures and 8.5 percent of their non-
being spent per pupil. Without information food expenditures in 2002 (Table 2.2).24 On
and without transparency, it is very difficult to average, these households spent Rp 341,654
plan ahead, to develop coherent and effective that year. However, there was a wide differ-
educational programs, and to monitor and as- ence in such expenditures between poor and
sess the flow of funds through the system.22 non-poor households. Households in the
poorest quintile (with young children) spent
Private Spending for Education
1.8 percent of their total expenditures (or 6.4
Remains Low percent of their non-food expenditures) on
Households, communities, and private organi- education, while those in the richest quintile
zations spend out of their own pockets to fi- spent 4.6 percent (or 9.0 of their non-food ex-
nance education in Indonesia in addition to the penditures) on average.
resources spent by governments. Schools re-
ceive revenues in the form of BP3 contribu- To what extent should school finance depend
tions and other donations from parents, private on students and the local community for sup-
foundations, and NGOs. Students pay a vari- port? There are opposing views on this. On
ety of school fees, including monthly tuition the one hand, there is some evidence that those
fees, entrance fees for new students, term and
final test fees, and extra-curriculum fees.
These fees together constitute a substantial
contribution to the income of any school, pri- 23
A similar situation prevailed a decade ago when public
marily to its non-salary expenditures, which schools obtained 92 percent of their total (salary and non-
usually account for about one-fifth to one- salary) funding from government allocations. However,
tenth of a school’s budget. According to one there was considerable diversity among regions. In Ja-
karta, public schools depended on government resources
for only 70 percent of their total budget, while in other
parts of the country, public schools depended on the gov-
22
This is not a new phenomenon. It was noted in World ernment for more than 90 percent of their budgets (King,
Bank, 1998 (Education in Indonesia: From Crisis to Re- 1997).
24
covery) that essential information on the budget is “scat- Moreover, this pattern is similar to the situation that
tered among five different ministries,” making the prevailed in 2000 when education accounted for 1.9 per-
management of the education system a very difficult cent of households’ total expenditures and 7.1 percent of
task. their non-food expenditures (SUSENAS data).

71
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Table 2.2 Household expenditures on education, by income quintile, 2002


Income quintile Mean annual Coefficient of % share in total % share in household non-
expenditures variation household consump- food consumption
(Rp) tion

All 341 654 1.90 3.4 (1.2) 8.5 (2.5)


Poorest 75 656 4.43 1.8 (2.1) 6.4 (5.8)
2 126 713 1.67 2.1 (2.8) 7.3 (7.5)
3 195 455 1.48 2.5 (3.2) 8.0 (8.4)
4 325 833 1.38 3.0 (3.8) 8.7 (8.9)
Richest 1021 451 1.30 4.6 (5.2) 9.0 (10.1)

Notes: Data from the 2002 SUSENAS; standard deviations in parentheses.


schools that rely more on parental or other lo- of education can deter poor households from
cal sources of finance are more likely to oper- sending their children to school. During the
ate efficiently (Bray, 1997; Jimenez and recent financial crisis, school revenues de-
Paqueo, 1996; and James, King, and Suryadi, creased in real terms by as much as one-third
1996). People who pay at least small amounts because of the drop in the real values of fees
of their money directly for services come to and government subsidies as well as an in-
value those services more highly than when crease in the non-payment of fees (Jones and
the services are given away free. Hagul, 2001). In the various sites that were
visited for this study, it seemed common for
On the other hand, schools produce benefits to schools to exempt those who could not afford
society that are wider than the private benefits the fees, even in cases where the fees were
that accrue to the local community, so there quite low.
are good reasons for society as a whole to sub-
sidize at least some of the costs of local
schools. In addition, direct and indirect costs

Box 2.1 Unequal Education Spending among Districts

How can an effective and equitable financing system be created within the prevailing legal and regulatory frame-
work in Indonesia? A component of the technical assistance project Capacity Building for Decentralized Social
Services Delivery (DSSD) of the Asian Development Bank has been studying alternatives for improving the allo-
cation of resources to schools in three pilot districts. In these districts, the project has established a School Opera-
tion Fund (Biaya Operasion Sekola or BOS) to consolidate all resources available for financing school operations
from the district APBD and from central programs (DSSD, 2002). This is a mechanism for addressing a key
shortcoming of the current grants system—extremely fragmented sources of funds. The project stressed the impor-
tance of elaborating a formula to allocate the total BOS funding to schools and to use APBD funds to “balance” all
other funds. The rationale behind this approach is that, when schools are funded from national-level programs,
there is more likely to be a mismatch between the needs of individual schools and the “one-size-fit-all” approach
of the central programs and a lack of coordination that may result in some schools repeatedly receiving resources
while others are excluded from all schemes.
The three pilot districts for the project – Magelang, Purworejo, and Lampung Barat – are very diverse with respect
to financing, as shown by their per capita education budget using their APBD allocations. Purworejo, which allo-
cates 52 percent of its APBD grant to education, has a per capita education budget that is less than one-half of Ma-
gelang’s which devotes 37 percent of its APBD grant to education. Lampung Barat, which allocates 41 percent to
education, has an even lower budget. And since regions do not control civil service pay, it is important to look at
the proportion of their education allocation devoted to development and non-salary routine expenditures over
which they do have discretion. The disparities among the three districts are even more pronounced in this respect:
Purworejo’s discretionary education budget is one-third that of Lampung Barat and only one-fifth that of Mage-
lang’s. In all three districts, however, an overwhelming share of the education grant (79 percent to 94 percent) is
spent on salaries. Lastly, another critical statistic is the fraction of the non-salary education expenditures that
reaches schools directly. As a share of the total education allocation from APBD, this is miniscule, less than 5 per-
cent in Magelang, 6 percent in Lampung Barat, and less than 2 percent in Purworejo.

72
Chapter 2 Financing Education under Decentralization

Equitable Financing in an Unequal Figure 2.3 Enrollment Rates of Children Ages 13-
15, By Province
World
The trend towards local resource mobilization, Yogyakarta
Jakarta
as discussed above, risks widening the dispari- North Sumatera
East Kalimantan
ties between those districts that have a strong West Sumatera
Riau
revenue base and those that are less prosper- Lampung
Bali

ous. (An example of such wide disparities is Central Java


Jambi
given in Box 2.1.) Consider an extreme hypo- East Java
Bengkulu
thetical case in which district governments Central Kalimantan
SE Sulawesi
must depend entirely on their own revenues West Java
West Kalimantan
and do not receive any intergovernmental North Sulawesi
South Sumatera
transfers. In such a system, there would be no N.T. Barat
South Kalimantan
mechanism for the national government to nar- N.T. Timur
Central Sulawesi
row disparities among districts. Even if dis- South Sulawesi

tricts themselves were to adopt equalizing 60 70 80 90 100

policies within their areas, this would elimi- Source: Susenas 1998 and 2002
nate only within-district disparities and not be- Notes: Figure reflects provincial divisions in 1998; the prov-
tween-district disparities. Currently in inces of Aceh, Irian Jaya, Maluku and North Maluku have
Indonesia, districts receive twice as many re- been excluded because their sample sizes in 2002 were very
sources from intergovernmental transfers as much smaller and limited than in 1998.
from their own revenues, so if transfers are
used judiciously, they can be a powerful Table 2.3 Source of inequality in enrollment rates:
Between and within provinces
mechanism for reducing regional inequali-
Junior sec- Senior sec-
ties.25 Source Primary ondary ondary

Between 46.0 34.9 27.4


Enrollment rates vary widely across Indone- 1997
Within 54.0 65.1 72.6
sia’s provinces, with as much as a 25- percent-
age point difference between Yogyakarta and Between 43.0 31.6 25.6
1998
South Sulawesi (Figure 2.3). Yet an even lar- Within 57.0 68.4 74.4
ger variation exists among districts throughout Between 38.5 33.5 28.6
the country. Looking back over data covering 1999
Within 61.5 66.5 71.4
the past six years, the source of inequality has
Between 31.8 30.6 25.4
shifted towards within-province rather than be- 2000
tween-province variation (Table 2.3). Indeed, Within 68.2 69.4 74.6
especially at the basic education levels, there Between 27.1 27.3 27.3
was a notable jump in within-province ine- 2001
Within 72.9 72.7 72.7
quality after 1999. In the case of junior sec- Between 30.5 29.2 27.5
ondary education where the coefficient of 2002
Within 69.5 70.8 72.5
variation of enrollment rates ranged from 22 to Source: Various years of SUSENAS.
28 percent, the variation was increasingly due
also to differences within provinces. This pat- tern of educational inequality suggests that, if
the current formula for allocating transfers to
districts were able to redress the inequalities
25
There are dangers to watch out for, however. Taken to among districts, then it would have a major
an extreme, a system with intergovernmental transfers (a impact on equalizing educational development
centralized system being one) creates its own problems
in that, if richer regions are taxed high enough and a
across the country.
large proportion of those tax revenues are transferred to
poorer regions, it could induce both the rich and the poor How then are education resources distributed
to migrate to the more lightly taxed, more highly subsi- across districts? To illustrate the need for
dized jurisdictions, thus causing overcrowding in those
policymakers to devote more attention to eq-
areas” (Prud’homme, 1995). The conclusion from most
analytical and empirical research is that “any reduction in uity concerns, Figure 2.4 presents two concen-
the importance of national budgets relative to those at the tration curves for the distribution of APBD
subnational level … increases interjurisdictional dispari- and APBN expenditures for education among
ties by reducing the impact of national policies designed
to correct regional inequities” (Prud’homme, 1995).

73
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Figure 2.4 Inequality in the distribution of 2001 education expenditures


from APBD and APBN allocations

Expenditure Concentration Curves


Districts Sorted by Mean Income
100%

80% Education
Development from
APBD by Kabupaten,
Cum % Budget

2001
60%

Education
40% Development from
APBN, 2001

20%

Education
Development from
0% APBN, 2001 without
0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100% Jakarta
Cumulative Percent of Population

Expenditure Concentration Curves


Districts Sorted by 2001 Junior Secondary Enrollment

100%
Education
Development from
80% APBD by Kabupaten,
2001
Cum % Budget

60%
Education
Development from
40% APBN, 2001
including Jakarta

20% Education
Development from
APBN, 2001
0%
0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100%
Cumulative % population

Note: Note that perfect equality would be represented as a 45 degree line.

74
Chapter 2 Financing Education under Decentralization

Table 2.4 Determinants of Education Expenditures using APBD: Results from Regression Analysis
% share of education ex-
Total per student Per student routine Per student devel- penditures in total DAU
Variables expenditures [a] expenditures opment expenditures allocation
Fiscal capacity (Rp tril) 0.798 (1.84) 0.334 (0.77) 0.554 (7.33) 364.19 (1.83)
Population (mil) -0.566 (-4.22) -0.429 (-3.22) -0.143 (-6.77) 60.04 (0.98)
Land area (sq km) -4.169 (-0.88) -7.817 (-1.66) 3.582 ( 4.25) -2189.21 (-1.03)
Poverty [b] 407.43 (1.36) 378.72 (1.27) 22.76 (0.46) -1498.56 (-0.01)

Notes: t-values are in parentheses. [a] Education data used pertain to APBD routine and development expenditures,
2002. A fixed-effects model was estimated to take into account unobserved sources variation within each province. [b]
Poverty as measured by the size of the population with incomes below a poverty threshold. Regressions using GDP per
capita, 1999, as an indicator of poverty yield similar results.
Source: Population data for 2000 from BPS website.

districts in 2001.26 These curves were obtained this equalization scheme, regardless of which
by ranking districts from lowest to highest ac- measure of expenditure needs is used, the
cording to their mean income levels and ac- variation in potential revenues was lower after
cording to their junior secondary education total DAU allocations were incorporated
enrollment rates and then plotting their APBD (Lewis 2001). Those district governments
and APBN education shares against their share with more land and more poverty tend to re-
of the country’s population. The diagonal line ceive higher per capita DAU transfers,
is the line of equality—a line showing that any whereas those with larger populations tend to
given proportion of the population receives receive smaller per capita transfers, perhaps
exactly that share of education resources. because large economies of scale are likely.
There is no such formula telling districts how
The estimated concentration curves indicate much of their revenues should be allocated to
that the district and central education expendi- education, only the aforementioned earmark-
tures, exclusive of spending in Jakarta, are un- ing established by legislation. But do district
equally allocated with respect to income governments nevertheless use similar factors
levels, but that APBN expenditures, exclusive as the central authority to determine their
of Jakarta spending, are more equally distrib- budget allocation for education?
uted than APBD expenditures. With respect
to enrollment rates, both types of expenditures For this report, we estimated a statistical rela-
are fairly equally distributed among districts, tionship to examine the factors that affect dis-
with a slight concentration in districts in the trict-level education spending. Using different
middle of the enrollment distribution. When measures of education spending (from the
APBN expenditures in Jakarta are taken into 2002 APBD allocation) as the dependent vari-
account, expenditures are overwhelmingly able in a multivariate regression analysis and
concentrated in Jakarta, as shown by the factors similar to those used in the DAU for-
curves that are farthest from the diagonal line. mula, we obtain the following results (Table
2.4): (i) Districts with a larger population tend
As already mentioned, the DAU transfer for- to have smaller per capita allocations for edu-
mula takes into account the fiscal capacities cation, which suggests also economies of scale
and needs of district governments. Because of in the provision of services; this result is statis-
tically significant. (ii) Districts with greater
fiscal capacity tend to make larger per-student
capital investments in education. (iii) Districts
26
Concentration curves plot the proportion of total ex- with more (or less) poverty, as measured by
penditures that is received by a given proportion of the
population. The 45-degree line is the line of equality, in-
the proportion of the population below a cer-
dicating, for example, that 10 percent of total expenditure tain poverty threshold, do not have larger (or
is received by 10 percent of the population, that 20 per- smaller) per-student education allocations than
cent of total expenditure is received by 20 percent of the other districts. This result suggests that, al-
population, and so on. The farther away a concentration though poorer districts may receive a higher
curve is from the 45-degree line, the more unequal is the
distribution of expenditure. DAU allocation by virtue of the DAU transfer

75
Education Sector Review Volume 2

formula, the same districts do not necessarily What can the central government do to engen-
spend a larger proportion of it on education. In der local capacity? It can: (i) Disclose the
a decentralized setting, central mandates be- amount of funds and other assistance that re-
come less and less effective, and so the central gional governments can expect to receive well
government must turn to powerful incentives before the beginning of each school year to
to compel local governments to behave in a give them a chance to finalize their spending
desired manner. Brazil provides a good ex- plans and to mobilize additional resources, as
ample of this (Box 2.2). needed. (ii) Give local governments more of
their resources through block transfers, rather
In sum, the inequalities among districts pre- than through centrally-initiated and centrally-
date decentralization, but decentralization managed projects. Indeed, the greater the
could exacerbate them. Transferring fiscal re- share of resources that are coursed through this
sponsibilities to local areas and a growing reli- channel rather than through specific programs,
ance on local resources and expertise is likely the stronger the support for developing local
to widen educational gaps between those areas capacity for governance and management.
that have a strong revenue base and those that There is some concern that local governments
are less prosperous, while weakening the cen- and schools, lacking experience and skills in
tral government’s ability to close education managing considerable discretionary funds,
gaps between the richest and poorest areas. will use those funds inappropriately.
Extreme regional differences signal the need to
establish an effective equalization mechanism. It is feared that corruption and fraud in the ab-
sence of effective controls and audits will
Increasing Efficiency under waste valuable resources and thus erode past
Decentralization educational gains.27 These problems are exac-
erbated by the fact that district governments
Enhance Local Capacity to Manage and schools receive funding from a number of
Financial Resources different sources, often too many for them to
While resources are important to sustain the keep track of, all with different management
educational progress achieved by Indonesia, arrangements.28 Because of the fragmented
higher spending alone does not guarantee bet- nature of the funding allocations at the local
ter education outcomes. A critical bottleneck level in Indonesia, it is almost impossible for
in implementing the decentralized functions of the ultimate beneficiary (the school or the stu-
regional governments is often a shortage of dent) to know how much funding they are
sufficient technical and managerial expertise. supposed to receive and whether the funds
In addition, the lack of viable and coordinated have been released.
management systems that link the operations
of central agencies to local governments and These are legitimate concerns, but the appro-
schools exacerbate the problems that arise priate response is not to re-centralize financial
from weak local capacity. With the new func- management. Rather, they call for establish-
tion assignments under decentralization, all ing better accountability mechanisms —
levels of government are effectively mandated
to train (or retrain) staff in financial planning
and budgeting, personnel management, infor- 27
Focus-group meetings with teachers, principals, and
mation collection and communication, among district officials undertaken as part of this report indicate
others. Given the collective inexperience with that decentralization, while mostly a positive change, has
created more opportunities for bribery and corrupt prac-
decentralized management, these skills are
tices. Bribes in money or kind are said to be more costly,
likely to be acquired not only through formal processes often take longer than before, and the distribu-
training but also through learning-by-doing tion of grants, scholarships, and other school funds is
within an enabling environment. For instance, particularly vulnerable to corruption.
local capacity for financial management is 28
challenged and stimulated by changing the This is not a new phenomenon. It was noted in World
Bank’s report “Education in Indonesia: From Crisis to
manner in which funds are provided to the dis- Recovery” (World Bank, 1998) that essential information
tricts. on the budget is “scattered among five different minis-
tries,” making the management of the education system a
very difficult task.

76
Chapter 2 Financing Education under Decentralization

Box 2.2 Brazil’s Experience with Municipalization

During the period of 1996-1998, the Government of Brazil carried out a comprehensive educational policy
reform. A new national educational law, enacted in 1996, laid out new roles and responsibilities for all levels
of government, and introduced a simple mechanism that links resources to student enrollment, thus creating a
powerful incentive for schools to raise enrollments. This financing mechanism, called the Fundo de
Manutenção e Desenvolvimento do Ensino Fundamental e de Valorização do Magistério (FUNDEF), revolu-
tionized the financing mechanism for sub-national governments by addressing the divergence between re-
source needs and revenue availability for education. The 1988 Constitution tied 25 percent of state and
municipal government expenditures to education, but a constitutional amendment in 1996 raised this to 60
percent for basic education (grades 1-8). In addition, it created a new mechanism to distribute tax collection
among states and municipalities. Each state, then, has its own FUNDEF, which corresponds to 15 percent of
revenue collection from specific tax and transfer sources. The total revenue collected within a given state, in-
cluding tax revenue from the state and its municipalities, is divided according to the total population of stu-
dents enrolled in that State within the previous academic year. The amount per student is then multiplied by
the current number of students enrolled within each sub-national government and distributed accordingly.
According to this new financing mechanism, each sub-national government contributes a certain amount of
resources to FUNDEF based mainly on their tax revenue per student, but receives a different amount based
on the current number of students they have enrolled in their respective basic education systems.

State and municipal governments are obligated to contribute a certain earmarked proportion of their revenues
to the FUNDEF fund for each state; the resources are then distributed to the state and each of the municipal
governments in that state on the basis of the number of primary education students enrolled by the respective
education systems managed by the sub-national entities. As each sub-national government contributes to
FUNDEF but receives money from the fund only according to its number of enrolled students, the new legis-
lation created an incentive for sub-national governments to enroll as many primary education students as pos-
sible.

Some municipalities have done much better than others in making use of the additional resources that they
have received. These municipalities have invested adequately in upgrading and rationalizing school infra-
structure, instituted transportation services for children, improved the quality of teachers, and provided them
with greater administrative and pedagogical support. At the same time, some municipalities still lack a coher-
ent educational policy, and learning is poor. Municipalities that have received additional resources due to
FUNDEF have maintained their own contributions to educational expenditures. The fungibility of resources
means that municipalities may reduce their own expenditures when they receive additional transferred re-
sources. However, the opportunities for such reductions have been limited because municipalities have faced
increased expenditure requirements for pre-school education, which does not benefit from FUNDEF re-
sources. Pre-school education suffered a temporary setback as states stopped spending on this level of educa-
tion as enjoined by the constitutional amendment of 1996 that established the FUNDEF mechanism.
However, municipalities have since picked up the reduction in state enrollments, leading to increase in the
coverage of pre-school education.

Among its significant contributions, FUNDEF created new administrative and teaching incentives within the
basic education system. Most importantly, it promoted an increase in enrollment pervasive across sub-
national governments. “As each sub-national government contributes to FUNDEF, but obtains receipts from
the fund only to the extent that is has enrolled students, the new legislation created an incentive to sub-
national governments to enroll as many primary education students as possible” (World Bank, 2002). In addi-
tion to the administrative incentive to expand access, legislation also specified that states and municipalities
spend a minimum of 60 percent of their FUNDEF funds on the payment of salaries of teachers and others in-
volved in the provision of educational services. Ultimately, this centrally-driven policy helped improve re-
gional disparities in terms of teacher salaries and subsequently of teacher profiles.

Source: World Bank 2002. “Brazil. Municipal Education Resources, Incentives, and Results.”

defining performance standards and measures, Standards and information are very important
developing checklists of basic standards and in increasing transparency and compliance
competencies, auditing current capacity and with policies, regulations, and laws and in re-
performance on the basis of those checklists. ducing corruption at all levels of the system.

77
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Having access to accurate and timely informa- resources that are spent on the actual opera-
tion helps district governments to plan and tions and maintenance of schools tend to be
manage the system, and sharing the informa- very limited. Often, even the tiny share left
tion with local stakeholders, such as parents, over for development expenditures, which is
through periodic reports may press district of- supposed to be devoted to building new class-
ficials to be more transparent and efficient. rooms, repairing school facilities, and teacher
The government has promulgated several key training, is used to cover routine expenditures,
regulations governing information flows under especially staff salaries.
decentralization. The PP11/2001 on Regional
Financial Information provides for a compre- With such a minute share of education re-
hensive information system to be developed to sources going to development expenditures, is
link national and district decisionmakers. It it possible to achieve needed improvements in
obliges sub-national governments to submit the quality of education? Teachers do play the
specified information to both the MoF and the key role in the teaching process, as is dis-
MoHA, thus giving national agencies the nec- cussed in the next two chapters, but adequate
essary data to develop a nationwide perform- resources need to be devoted not only to sala-
ance and financial monitoring system. A ries but also to teacher professional develop-
further regulation is needed to require schools ment and classroom supplies.
to feed data back to district governments.
With improved accountability, it is possible to Spend Locally
use the potential ability of district govern-
ments and schools to use public funds where The impact of the current reform will depend
they are most needed and where they can have ultimately on how much of the fiscal resources
the greatest educational impact. allocated to education actually reach the
schools and, within the schools, how those re-
Spend Productively sources are put to use. Some issues are:

Improving the efficiency of the education sys- First, the level of funds available for education
tem requires spending educational resources within a district needs to be predictable and
where they are most productive. This is not in assured and should be closely linked to educa-
any way a concern that is unique to the decen- tion plans and standards at the national level
tralized reform. However, with responsible that have been discussed and negotiated with
parties spending more autonomously than be- local stakeholders. It is also important to have
fore, it has become more difficult to coordi- clear, well-understood rules for allocating
nate the balance in the composition of these funds to schools so that schools know
expenditures throughout the education system. the level of funding to expect each year from
the government at the beginning of each
Consider that in the system as a whole, three- school year. (Box 2.3) Schools in Indonesia
quarters of resources are spent on recurrent receive funding from a number of sources, of-
items, mostly on salaries and benefits and a ten too many for the schools to keep track of
small amount on operational costs and peda- them all. These sources include public monies
gogical supplies, and one-quarter is spent on from as many as seven channels, all with dif-
capital outlays (Figure 2.2 above). This pat- ferent management arrangements. During fo-
tern is more extreme at the district level, where cus-group meetings for this report, school
governments spend more than 90 percent of principals complained that the lack of trans-
their education budgets on routine expendi- parency about budget allocations at the central
tures; in 2002, 95 percent of their routine and district levels prevents them from predict-
budgets was spent on the salaries of teachers at ing how much revenue they will receive ex-
the primary and junior secondary levels and cept through fees collected at the school level
other personnel (McMahon and Suwaryani, and makes it impossible for them to do any
2002 and Clark et al, 1998).29 In contrast, the
tral government will be paid out of the national budget,
the APBN. Presumably, the teachers and personnel
whose salaries were transferred to the districts as part of
29
Article 49 of the new Education Law states that the the decentralization reform will continue to be paid under
salaries of teachers and personnel appointed by the cen- the local budgets, the APBD.

78
Chapter 2 Financing Education under Decentralization

multi-year improvement planning. In several dance later in the year. It is also essential to
countries, the amount of funds allocated to track how much of each school’s allocation is
schools is based on the number of students ex- actually received by the school and how much
pected to enroll in the school by means of an goes astray. If schools provide appropriate
agreed-upon cost-indexed per student alloca- and timely information to the various levels of
tion. This per-student cost is defined on the government, this will help government per-
basis of delivery of an acceptable standard of sonnel to plan and administer schools. Schools
service, which directly links the subsidies that should also provide this information to local
the school receives to its educational quality stakeholders such as parents, who can then use
and performance. The alternative, allocating this information to press district officials to be
equal resources to each school regardless of more transparent and efficient.
the number of pupils, gives schools no incen-
tive to achieve cost-effective pupil-teacher ra- Third, the capacity within schools for devel-
tios.. A formula-based allocation is equitable opment planning, budget preparation and exe-
in that every student is allocated an equal cution, and accounting also determines how
amount of cost-indexed funds, but does not well they are able to use the decentralized fis-
preclude MoNE or the district governments cal structure to their advantage and how effi-
from establishing mechanisms for mitigating ciently they are able to spend the resources
specific inequalities among communities and allocated to them. The largest single subsidy
schools.30 This compensatory or equalizing to schools is in the form of teacher and staff
role is essential since communities are not salaries, which means that schools’ discretion-
equal in their ability to mobilize extra re- ary budgets are often quite limited.
sources for their schools and schools are not
equal in the educational challenges that they As districts and communities mobilize greater
have to face every day. District governments resources to cover non-salary expenditures that
should target these additional grants to schools improve schools, they will need the skills nec-
that are unable to mobilize sufficient resources essary for preparing and implementing school
to meet minimum quality standards, but the improvement plans. Past studies have sug-
government should do so only in conjunction gested that the benefits of decentralization are
with greater supervision of those schools and more likely to emerge when school councils
performance evaluation against agreed-upon are able to exercise some autonomy over ad-
indicators of progress. ministrative and financial matters related to
the school (Reithwood and Menzies, 1998,
Second, there must be a free exchange of in- Jimenez and Sawada, 1999 and King and
formation between the levels of government Ozler, 2000). School Committees in Indonesia
and schools, and the data that are exchanged have yet to be given clear functions and have
must be accurate. Obviously, accurate enroll- yet to take advantage of their supposed greater
ment numbers are essential. Many students autonomy. As school “governors,” these
who will drop out tend to do so soon after the Committees will need to make the hard deci-
start of the school year, so school subsidies sions about how to spend school revenues.
must be based not on enrollment at the begin-
ning of the year but on average daily atten-

30
In the U.S., under most equalization programs, poor
school districts experience increased spending, but some
poor school districts actually receive lower per-pupil
school spending under equalization programs that at-
tempts to level spending down a lot (Hoxby 2001).
Hoxby suggests that it is possible to minimize the nega-
tive effects of school finance equalization by combining
elements of categorical aid with property taxes. This
could mean redistributing grants among school districts
on the basis of their characteristics such as mean house-
hold income, poverty rate, and/or demographic variables,
such as the proportion of children who live in single-
parent families.

79
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Box 2.3 School Funding – A Gap in Financial Policy


The mechanisms of finance under decentralization are still faulty, confusing, or absent (see McMahon and
Boediono, 2001). One critical gap has to do with school funding. The simplest possible school funding sys-
tem would disburse all of the resources to each school on a per student basis rather than just providing it with
inputs. In such a funding system, as most of the funding would be given on a block basis, the tasks of finan-
cial management would be relatively simple, and keeping track of the funding would be relatively easy.
However, such a system may not be possible for a long time in Indonesia, at least for all schools. There may
be valid reasons not to adopt such a system at this point, and there may also be other reasons that are related
to inertia and tradition. A compromise would be to introduce this system on an “asymmetrical” basis, in
other words, only in those schools that already have financial planning capacity.
In the absence of such a system, there are likely to be various different sources of funding at the school level,
many of them earmarked, and some of the funding will take the form of providing inputs rather than money.
In this situation, the main task would be to develop a set of accounting tools and tracking systems at the na-
tional level that can follow (both budgeted and actual) expenditures down to the school level and can aggre-
gate all forms of expenditure, including inputs, for each school. Two or three months before the beginning of
any school year, each district government should inform each school of the school’s total expenditure in the
most recent year available (there should be enough time to close the books so that final expenditure figures
could be reported), its estimated expenditure in the previous year, and its allotted budget for the current year.
This report should be as detailed as possible and should include a breakdown of items into those that were
merely inputs and those that were an actual financial transfer to the school. The report should also inform the
school (and its committee) of its per student expenditure and those of similar schools so the school can com-
pare its expenditure with that of others. If the school’s per student spending is far above that of its peers,
then the district should make it clear that this cannot continue.
The national government can contribute by crafting a set of standards for financial management and then al-
lowing various suppliers to develop competing financial management packages for schools and districts to
purchase, as long as their software meets the functionality requirements developed by the government. Even
if only one-tenth of schools successfully computerize their financial management systems, this would still
represent an attractive market that would be difficult for software vendors to ignore. It is unlikely that gov-
ernment or donor-based financial software development would be as successful as independent software de-
velopment, but the software would be built to specified standards. One of the standards that such packages
would have to meet is complete manual-to-machine inter-operability and compatibility. The government
could then require schools to hand over the manual to other schools, thus forcing better-off schools to subsi-
dize the development of the simpler manual package for the poorer schools and making it easy for schools to
change from manual systems to computer systems without having to change their service provider.

Summary of Implications for Policy generation, allocation, and use of funds. Three
key messages on financing education are:
This chapter began with the proposition that
establishing appropriate resource allocation
Ensure that total education expenditures are
and accountability systems for the manage-
adequate to maintain educational develop-
ment of those resources in Indonesia’s educa-
ment and increase the efficiency of resource
tion sector is key to increasing its effectiveness
use.
and attaining the country’s educational goals.
This message would have applied even if In- This task requires strong leadership from the
donesia had not embarked on its “big bang” central government, both in crafting an effec-
decentralization, but under decentralization, tive funding mechanism that is easy to monitor
the ways and forms in which these challenges and to implement and in building political
can be met have changed. Decentralization support for that mechanism among provincial
has shifted the relative roles of different levels and district leaders. Earmarking the central
of governance, from the central government and local budgets for education, as the Consti-
down to the regional governments and the tution and the Education Law have done, goes
School Committees. At the same time, the only part of the distance to ensure that ade-
success or failure of the decentralization will quate resources are allocated to the schools
rest partly on how well these governance lev- where they can make a difference. The real
els use their discretion and autonomy over the challenge is to ensure that earmarked national

80
Chapter 2 Financing Education under Decentralization

and local education budgets are indeed spent fulfill their responsibility to deliver education
on schools and students, that they cover the of acceptable coverage or quality. This is evi-
basic operating expenses of schools besides dent in the strikingly wide range of per-capita
the costs of teaching and non-teaching staff levels of education expenditures across dis-
(such instructional supplies, the routine activi- tricts. However, a “sunset clause” should be
ties of the School Committee, maintaining a included in this special DAK allocation that
school database and disseminating information would ensure that it ended once the DAU
to parents and the community, utilities, and mechanism had been improved.
light repairs of the school buildings and other
maintenance), and their development activi- In addition to a national investment plan for
ties. Together with efforts to define a mini- education, Indonesia needs a multi-year educa-
mum standard of provision, it is possible to tion development plan for each region (prov-
design a formula-based allocation that is non- ince and/or district) that would spell out the
discretionary and that depends on just a few education goals and the implied resource re-
key measurable criteria. quirements of those goals for each region.
This is not the same as the yearly budgeting
The Education For All effort is already an at- process to arrive at an annual budget for the
tempt to estimate the per student level of sector. What is needed is a resource plan that
spending that would be consistent with attain- is more closely linked to the educational de-
ing universal enrollment and improving educa- velopment goals of the region than is the case
tion quality in Indonesia (McMahon, 2003). with the yearly budgeting process, that is the
What needs to happen is to open the proposed product of a broad consultation with school
formula to national scrutiny and debate in or- stakeholders, that specifies clear performance
der to validate it and to obtain political support indicators, that identifies the different intended
for it. What also needs to happen is to apply sources of funds and required management
the funding formula to the local processes of and technical skills, and that is widely publi-
allocating the DAU rather than the DAK. This cized among the various stakeholder groups in
formula funding mechanism should become the regions. In turn, there should be a re-
the routine way to allocated education grants gional (provincial and/or district) multi-year
in Indonesia and, in the process, it will facili- resource plan that would specify all planned
tate school-based management by allowing investments in the improvement of all schools
schools to manage assistance in cash rather within the control of the regional government,
than in kind. including investments that go beyond the con-
struction and repair of facilities. These multi-
The funding formula mentioned above should year assistance plans to schools would not just
apply only to the per student level of routine be expenditure plans but also financial, staff-
operational expenditures. However, a per- ing, and management plans. To formulate the
school rather than per-student funding formula assistance plans to schools and, consequently,
is more appropriate in deploying teachers and the regional resource plan, what is needed is a
other staff to schools. In addition, many funding allocation formula that is based on a
schools in Indonesia have urgent development cost-indexed, per-pupil basis and consensual
needs, including staff development and the quality standards and region-specific prices.
construction of libraries or laboratories.
Richer districts will be able to undertake these It is important to have an equivalent and paral-
capital investments themselves, but poorer dis- lel process of planning at the level of the cen-
tricts will not, so a pro-poor investment pro- tral government. The regional plans can be
gram will be needed. In fact, in the short run aggregated to formulate a multi-year plan of
(that is, until the DAU mechanism is fixed), assistance for educational development, and
schools are likely to need direct cash assis- this can be achieved using the different in-
tance, perhaps through a special DAK alloca- struments available to the national government
tion, to cover even their basic operational in the new decentralized context. Because the
costs. This is because the current DAU alloca- sum of regional demands is likely to exceed
tions are not equalizing the distribution of lo- the resources available to the national gov-
cal resources, which means that poorer ernment, districts should be categorized ac-
districts repeatedly find themselves unable to cording to their performance on multiple

81
Education Sector Review Volume 2

education indicators, their resource levels and an adequate maintenance plan. Second,
(transfers as well as own resources), and their the communities or schools that receive trans-
technical and management capacity. This cate- fers should be selected based on both their
gorization would make it possible for the na- needs and their capacity as well as of the eco-
tional government to prioritize the level of nomic viability of the project in question.
assistance that it provides to provinces or dis- Third, the central government should make
tricts. In recognition of the fact that resource adequate technical assistance available to local
levels and technical capacities vary across dis- governments to help them to develop plans, ar-
tricts in Indonesia, adjustments would have to range financing, and operate the local educa-
be made in the allocation amounts that are cur- tion system as efficiently as possible. Fourth,
rently given to the disadvantaged areas. Using the central government should monitor and
this categorization, it would be possible to de- evaluate the implementation of the investment
termine the notional level and nature of assis- plans by requiring periodic progress reports
tance for each region. This notional level of and by making field inspections and formal
assistance could then be the basis for the an- evaluations of outcomes. Finally, all regional
nual transfers to the regions, particularly the governments that receive a transfer should be
DAK allocations. required to testify about the condition of the
infrastructure on which the resources are to be
Another important aspect of using perform- spent to enable the central government to
ance-based or results-based funding schemes make an adequate assessment of the future
to ensure that resources are used more effi- needs of local governments.
ciently is that this holds regional governments
and schools ultimately accountable for meas- Because of the fragmented nature of the fund-
urable indicators of progress within their juris- ing allocations at the district level in Indone-
dictions. For the central government, this sia, there are numerous opportunities for
means imposing a hard budget constraint on corruption and leakage in the current system.
regional governments, refusing to bail out Information plays a critical role in improving
those that miss their goals because of bad de- the quality of decisionmaking by policymak-
cisions or poor implementation. At the same ers. Information flows are likewise important
time, the central government should help local for improving the implementation of policies
governments to build their capacity for effi- and investment programs. They help to in-
cient planning, budgeting, and fiscal manage- crease transparency and compliance with poli-
ment and to train provincial and district cies, regulations and laws and to reduce
officials to use data to target assistance and to corruption at all levels of the system. The re-
measure impact. There have been several ef- gional education investment plans discussed
forts in the past at improving the planning and above should be based on regular, systematic,
budgeting processes in schools and districts, and purposive collection and analysis of edu-
such as the DSSD program. Although these cation data. Local governments are likely to
have been fragmented efforts, and often only spend transfers for capital investments more
pilot programs, some lessons can still be effectively if they know in advance how much
learned from these efforts that can be used to they are going to receive so they can devise a
guide a country-wide effort to formulate edu- coherent development strategy.
cation investment and assistance plans at all
levels. Similarly, it is important for schools to know
accurately and in a timely manner the size and
Increase the productivity and effectiveness of nature of the resources that they will be receiv-
resources spent on education at the provin- ing so they can plan accordingly. This is diffi-
cial, district, and school levels. cult under the current system in which public
resources flow through many different chan-
There are lessons from the experience of coun-
nels, some of which are completely unpredict-
tries around the world about how to increase
able or subject to being diverted by local
the effectiveness of transfers that might be
politicians. A formula-based allocation that is
useful to Indonesia (Bird and Smart, 2002).
non-discretionary and that depends on a few
First, regional governments should be required
key—and simple—pieces of information helps
to prepare both an adequate investment plan
to make allocations more transparent. When

82
Chapter 2 Financing Education under Decentralization

school committees know in advance how First, as mentioned above, the DAU mecha-
much of a subsidy they are due to receive from nism needs to be improved so that it can help
the regional government, they can compare to equalize the wide disparities in educational
that amount with what they actually receive, outcomes across regions. Second, the central
which thus serves as an effective check on cor- education authority should support targeted,
ruption in local public spending. pro-poor education programs, perhaps through
a DAK allocation. Indonesia’s past experience
Focus education resources on those who with its large scholarship and school grants
need them most. program, launched at the onset of the recent
financial crisis, can inform the design of a tar-
In Indonesia, as in many other developing geted program. To make such a program fi-
countries, a more pressing concern than effi- nancially sustainable, what is needed is the
ciency is often the inability to meet the de- political will to keep it well targeted to those
mand for services, especially the demand from who need it most. There are valuable lessons
the poor and disadvantaged. Districts that from around the world (for example, Bangla-
have higher enrollment rates and better quality desh, Brazil, and Mexico) on how this can be
are frequently those with more resources, achieved. Third, the national government can
whereas districts that have low education indi- use incentives to influence the allocation deci-
cators are typically also the districts with sions of the better-off districts, for example, by
fewer resources. To improve education out- rewarding those districts that are able to make
comes in Indonesia, it is imperative to serve large improvements in the education indicators
the needs of those districts that are in greater pertaining to the poorest communities or
need and to tailor the type of assistance pro- schools within their jurisdiction and, con-
vided to the type of need manifested. Under versely, by taxing those with worsening indi-
decentralization, whether or not adequate re- cators. Indonesia is very capable of doing this
sources are allocated to pro-poor services de- type of monitoring because of its longstanding
pends on the priorities of local leaders and experience with fielding large household sur-
communities. This is one of the dangers of veys, such as the SUSENAS.
decentralization.

83
Education Sector Review Volume 2

References For Chapter 2

Akita, Takahiro and Armida S. Alisjahbana. Duflo, Esther. 2001. “Schooling and Labor
2002. “Regional Income Inequality in Indo- Market Consequences of School Construc-
nesia and the Initial Impact of the Economic tion in Indonesia: Evidence from an Unusual
Crisis,” Bulletin for Indonesian Economic Policy Experiment,” American Economic
Studies 38(2): 201-22. Review 91(4): 795-813.
Hofman, Bert, Kai Kaiser, and Soraya Goga.
Alm, James, Robert H. Aten, and Roy Bahl.
2003. Decentralizing Indonesia (A Regional
2001. “Can Indonesia Decentralize Success-
Public Expenditure Review). Washington
fully? Plans, Problems, and Prospects,” Bul-
DC: The World Bank.
letin for Indonesian Economic Studies 37(1):
83-102. Hofman, Bert, Kadjatmiko, and Kai Kaiser.
2002. “Evaluating Indonesia’s Fiscal
Behrman, Jere R., Anil B. Deolalikar, and
Equalization.” Washington DC: The World
Lee-Ying Soon. 2002. Promoting Effective
Bank. Processed.
Schooling through Education Decentraliza-
tion in Bangladesh, Indonesia, and Philip- Hoxby, Caroline. 2001. “All School Fi-
pines. ERD Working Paper Series No. 23, nance Equalizations Are Not Created
Asian Development Bank. Equal,” Quarterly Journal of Economics.
116(4) : 1189-1231.
Bird, Richard M. and Michael Smart. 2002.
“Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers: Some Jalal, Fasli and Bachrudin Musthafa. 2001.
Lessons from International Experience,” Education Reform in the Context of Regional
World Development 30(6): 899-912. Autonomy: The Case of Indonesia. Ministry
Brodjonegero, B. and J. Martinez-Vasquez. of National Education and National Devel-
2002. “An Analysis of Indonesia's Transfer opment Planning Agency, Republic of Indo-
System: Recent Performance and Future nesia, and the World Bank.
Approaches.” Can Decentralization Help
James, Estelle, Elizabeth M. King, and Ace
Rebuild Indonesia, Stone Mountain Park,
Suryadi. 1996. “Finance, Management, and
Atlanta, Georgia, Georgia State University.
Costs of Public and Private Schools in Indo-
Bray, Mark. 1997. “Community Financing nesia,” Economics of Education Review
of Education: Rationales, Mechanisms, and 15(4): 387-398.
Policy Implications in Less Developed
Countries.” In Christopher Colclough (ed.), Jimenez, Emmanuel and Yasuyuki Sawada.
Marketizing Education and Health in Devel- 1999. "Do community-managed schools
oping Countries: Miracle or Mirage? Ox- work? An evaluation of El Salvador's
ford: Clarendon Press. EDUCO program." World Bank Economic
Review (International) 13(3): 415-41.
Clark, D. et al. 1998. Financing of Educa-
tion in Indonesia. Asian Development Bank Jimenez, Emmanuel and Vicente Paqueo.
and the University of Hong Kong. 1996. "Do Local Contributions Affect the
Efficiency of Public Primary Schools? "
Decentralized Strategy for Education Fi- Economics of Education Review 15(4): 377-
nance (DSEF) Project. 2002. Education Re- 86.
form in the Context of Decentralization
Jones, G. W. and P. Hagul. 2001. “School-
(Strategy and Action Plan for Decentralized
ing in Indonesia: Crisis-Related and Longer-
Financing of Education). January 29 Draft
Term Issues,” Bulletin for Indonesian Eco-
Report. Processed.
nomic Studies 37(2): 207-231.
Decentralized Social Services Delivery
King, Elizabeth M. 1997. “Who Really Pays
(DSSD). 2002. “Draft Analysis No.2 on
for Education? The Roles of Government
District Financing of Schools,” Asian De-
and Families in Indonesia,” in Colclough,
velopment Bank.
Christopher, ed., Marketizing Education and

84
Chapter 2 Financing Education under Decentralization

Health in Developing Countries: Miracle or tion Finance in Indonesia. Policy Research


Mirage? Oxford: Clarendon Press. Center, Institute for Research and Develop-
ment, Ministry of Education, Indonesia, and
King, E. and B. Ozler. 1998. “What’s De-
UNICEF and UNESCO.
centralization Got to Do with Learning?
The Case of Nicaragua’s School Autonomy Ministry of National Education, Government
Reforms.” Paper presented at the Annual of Indonesia. 2002. The Existence of Ma-
Meeting of the American Educational Re- drasah, Diniyah Education and Pesantren in
search Association held in San Diego, CA the National Education System. Office of
referenced in World Bank 2003. Educational Research and Development.
Leithwood, K. and T. Menzies. 1998. National Committee for Education, Sub-
“Forms and Effect of School-based Man- Committee III. 2001. Decentralization of
agement: A Review.” Educational Policy Education. Draft Report, June 14. Proc-
summarized in World Bank, 2003. essed and translated into English.
Lewis, Blane D. 2001. “The New Indone-
sian Equalization Transfer,” Bulletin for In- Prud'homme, Remy. 1995. "Dangers of
donesian Economic Studies 37(3): 325-43. Decentralization." World Bank Research
Observer (International) (10): 201-20.
Lewis, Blane D. 2002. “Revenue-Sharing
and Grant-Making in Indonesia: The First
Two Years of Fiscal Decentralization,” in Silver, Christopher, Iwan J. Azis, and
Paul Smoke (ed.), Intergovernmental Trans- Larry Schroeder. 2001. “Intergovern-
fers in Asia. Manila, Asian Development mental Transfers and Decentralization in
Bank. Indonesia,” Bulletin for Indonesian Eco-
nomic Studies 37 (3): 345-62.
McMahon, Walter. 2003. “Financing and
Achieving ‘Education For All’ Goals.” Fi- The World Bank. 1998. Education in Indo-
nal Report for the Ministry of National Edu- nesia: From Crisis to Recovery. Report No.
cation, BAPPENAS and the World Bank, 18651-IND. Washington, DC: The World
Indonesia. Bank.
McMahon, Walter and Nanik Suwaryani. The World Bank. 2002. “Brazil. Municipal
2002. “Improving Education Funding Education Resources, Incentives, and Re-
Methods in Indonesia,” in Walter W. sults.” Policy Report. Washington, DC.
McMahon, Nanik Suwaryani, Boediono and The World Bank.
Elizabeth Appiah (eds). Improving Educa-

85
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Appendix 2.1. Cost Implications of Quality Education for All

The Education for All (EFA) goals are to in- BP3, examinations; procurement of
crease net enrollment rates at both primary textbooks, notebooks, and school bags;
and junior secondary education levels, transport; and so on. At the primary
reaching out even to the poor and disadvan- level, eliminating fees mean foregone
taged populations, and to improve the qual- revenues of Rp 13,000 per pupil in 2004
ity of education available. The cost (2003 prices), on average, increasing to
implications of these goals have been calcu- Rp 38,000 per pupil in 2008. At the jun-
lated by Professor McMahon (McMahon, ior secondary level, the amount is about
2003). A key concept for his costing is ade- Rp 57,000 per pupil.
quacy, or “what it takes in terms of text- x In addition, a student grant of Rp
books, teaching materials, teacher abilities 290,000 per pupil per year for 18.2 per-
and qualifications, school libraries, and so cent of all primary school students,
forth to produce an educationally adequate which is more than doubling the current
education for each child” (McMahon 2003). grant by the government, will cover the
McMahon’s estimates, developed on a per- opportunity costs borne by parents and
pupil basis, are based on the following as- for teacher supplements and BP3. The
sumptions, among others: corresponding grant is Rp 93,000 per
pupil per year.
x The EFA goals are to achieve 100 per-
cent net enrollment rate by 2008 in pri-
mary education and 95 percent in junior Table 1. Cost estimates for EFA
secondary education by 2008, and to as- Primary Secondary
sure that this education is of acceptable 2004/5 2008/9 2004/5 2008/9
quality. Per-pupil cost (Rp thousands)
Incremental cost 179 209 509 834
x A recently conducted survey of schools of EFA
provide data on what schools are actu- Current cost 966 966 1,449 1,449
Total 1,145 1,175 1,958 2,283
ally spending. These data provide the Total cost (=Per-pupil cost x students enrolled)
current or base cost of schools. (Rp billions)
x What the “best practice” schools are cur- Incremental cost 5,061 5,702 5,331 10,245
of EFA
rently spending is the measure of what Current cost 27,255 26,397 15,476 18,049
inputs are needed and “most cost effec- Total 32,316 32,099 20,807 28,418
tive” to improve learning in schools. The Source: McMahon (2003)
“best practice” schools, those that have Note: All estimates are in 2003 prices.
experienced increases in EBTANAS test
scores, have been found to have more The estimates per pupil for 2004/5 indicate
books and teaching materials for every that the incremental costs associated with
pupil, and salary supplements for teach- EFA would be 18 percent of the current
ers are larger. For example, in expendi- (2004) per-pupil cost at the district level for
ture terms, the average schools is primary education and 35 percent for junior
estimated to spend Rp 15,000 per pupil secondary education (Table 1). These repre-
on teaching aids while the “best practice sent a significant increase in per-pupil
schools” spend Rp 21,745 per pupil, on spending. Primary and junior secondary
average. education costs would total Rp 53 trillion in
x The corresponding cost estimate for jun- 2004. According to SIKD estimates, educa-
ior secondary education is 1.5 times the tion expenditures in 2002 were 2.4 percent
cost above for primary education. of Indonesia’s GDP at the local level, or to-
x To increase the enrollment rate of the taling about Rp 43 trillion. This spending
poor and disadvantaged population re- may well have increased close to the EFA
quires additional resources, largely for cost estimates by 2004 if education spending
the purpose of eliminating fees. Cur- increases by the same percentage as the pro-
rently, fees are charged for entrance, jected percentage increase in DAU transfers.

86
Chapter 2 Financing Education under Decentralization

Thus, while the EFA cost implications as es- Lastly, there are several ways to improve the
timated by McMahon (2003) will mean a existing EFA cost estimates while maintain-
significant rise in education per-pupil spend- ing the basic principles of McMahon’s esti-
ing, the implied total expenditure is not far mation model. Examples are: Improve the
off from the total education expenditures al- reference used for the level of spending per
ready being made at the district level. pupil needed to raise quality. The assump-
tion used was that the “best practice”
Is EFA by 2008 guaranteed then? No, by no schools are not able to reduce their cost per
means is EFA guaranteed without the neces- pupil without quality reductions (thus, that
sary accompanying changes in the manage- they are at optimal efficiency). To what ex-
ment of schools and the education system as tent this is true would require more studies
a whole. Costing EFA is an important step on the gains and cost of increasing school ef-
in understanding what is required to fulfill ficiency. And improve the estimate of what
this national commitment, but more re- is needed to raise the enrollment of poor
sources are not enough. The changes for youths. Impact evaluations of the national
better quality are discussed in Chapter 3 of scholarship program initiated in the late
this volume. 1990s would be able to inform this.

87
Education Sector Review Volume 2

88
Chapter 3: Education Quality Assurance and Improvement

The biggest challenge in the development of of secondary education beginning in the


national education is enhancing the quality 1980s (Jones, 2001). Unemployment among
and relevance of education (MoNE, 2001a). high school graduates is also high and re-
mained so even during the 1990s, a time of
Expectations for the basic education system unprecedented growth in the labor market.
are high. Parents want the system to prepare In 1996, BAPPENAS published data col-
their children for productive employment lected since 1990 on unemployment rates
and a moral life, while the state wants among general secondary school graduates.
graduates who can contribute to a growing At that time, 25.47 percent of high school
economy with high productivity, particularly graduates were unemployed, despite a
the types of productivity gained through par- growth of 13.4 percent in employment op-
ticipation in the knowledge economy portunities for people with that level of edu-
(MoNE, 2000). The state also wants the so- cation (BAPPENAS quoted in Soedijarto,
cial benefits associated with education – 2003). Business leaders interviewed as part
lower birth rates, better health practices, and of the district consultation process for this
more active participation of citizens in a sector review commented that it takes high
democratic civil society (Republic of Indo- school graduates about six months before
nesia, 2003). Achieving these goals requires they are able to complete the most basic
two things: that children have access to edu- workplace functions, such as coming to
cation, preferably by attending formal work on time or following instructions
schools, and that the education they receive (SAGRIC, 2004).
is of acceptable quality. Volume I reports
that the net enrollment rates for Indonesia in Furthermore, what quality improvements
2002 were 92.7 percent for primary school- there have been so far appear to be inequita-
ing and 61.7 percent for junior secondary ble. In Chapter 2 on finance, we reported
schooling up from 91.5 and 51.0, respec- that public spending on education barely
tively, in 1995. With these gains in enroll- covers teachers’ salaries and the routine op-
ment levels, Indonesia is now at the erating expenses of public schools. Parents
historical point where countries start to em- fill this financing gap through various school
phasize quality as much as continued growth fees both in public and private schools.31 As
in access. In Indonesia, two forces shape the pointed out in Chapter 2 on financing, ine-
quality agenda: the increasing demand for qualities in per-pupil spending are high, both
quality improvement from journalists and within districts and between districts. In
policymakers and the political pressure of practice, this means that the schools that
the decentralization agenda. serve poor children get worse and the
schools that serve higher-income children
Most official reports on educational quality get better (ADB, 2000).
in Indonesia, such as the Education for All
Situational Analysis (Education for All,
Approach and Rationale
2002a), express dissatisfaction with the cur- The previous chapters discussed the risks
rent level of quality and cite as evidence the and benefits inherent in decentralization and
poor showing of Indonesia in the 1999 raised general issues about the basic educa-
Trends in International Mathematics and tion governance, management, and finance
Science Study. Out of the 38 countries in- systems that are currently being debated or
cluded in this study, Indonesia ranked 34th in put into place in Indonesia. Implicit in those
mathematics and 32nd in science. An Indo- chapters was the notion that the principles of
nesian report in the mid-1990s stated that the decentralization, if applied to the reform of
quality of the typical upper secondary
graduate declined to a level that was proba-
bly equivalent to lower secondary education
31
before the beginning of the rapid expansion For affiliated private schools and madrasahs, foun-
dations sometimes provide additional support.

89
Education Sector Review Volume 2

education system management, governance, make it difficult to improve quality in the


and finance, will enable Indonesia to meet sector. Second, the lack of technical capac-
its goal of providing all children with nine ity at the district and school levels to imple-
years of high-quality basic education. This ment and sustain quality assurance and
favorable result is not expected to derive quality improvement programs, as evidenced
automatically from decentralization. Some failures to sustain or mainstream the major-
research warns of a decline in general qual- ity of good practices developed under pro-
ity or an inequitable rise in quality after de- jects.
centralization (Galiani and Schargrodsky,
2001), while other studies report a general Methodology
improvement in school quality (King and
The methodology for this chapter consisted
Ozler, 1998).
of a review of documents on educational
quality such as newspapers, strategic and
In this chapter, we propose a break with past
annual action plans, laws, decrees, guide-
approaches to quality management that re-
lines, background papers, policy documents,
lied on centrally managed projects. Instead,
conference presentations, and the text of
we propose an approach that: (i) links qual-
speeches from the Minister and Directors
ity assurance and quality improvement, (ii)
General of Education to capture a sense of
clearly allocates functions to specific levels
the national government’s strategic inten-
of government, (iii) incorporates quality im-
tions on the issue of quality management.
provement and assurance into the routine
Interviews with officials in the top two eche-
operations of the central government, dis-
lons of the MoNE provided us with guidance
tricts, and schools, and (iv) uses projects ju-
on how policymakers are conceptualizing
diciously as part of an overall development
future quality control and quality improve-
plan for district education. We then review
ment efforts. In additional interviews with
the quality assurance and quality improve-
the national staff and consultants responsible
ment efforts that are already in place or are
for managing the quality improvement pro-
proposed under the policy framework cur-
jects funded by the central government, we
rently being prepared by the MoNE. At the
learned about the difficulties that they face
school level, this is school-based manage-
in mainstreaming lessons learned from pro-
ment, while at the district level, it is per-
jects.
formance-based budgeting. Details on how
school-based management can be modified
We conducted two kinds of activities at the
to address the quality issue more directly
school and district levels. On field visits to
appears in Appendix 3.2. Throughout this
selected districts and schools, we inter-
chapter, we include a few international com-
viewed officials and held group discussions
parisons to illustrate how other countries
with school committee members and school
have managed the issue of improving quality
heads to gain insights into the challenges
under decentralization. The chapter con-
that they face in trying to raise quality at the
cludes with a summary of recommendations
local level under decentralization. We also
for taking a program approach to quality
organized a series of focus groups at the
management.
school and district levels to provide us with
insights into how schools and districts carry
The rationale for this program approach is
out quality control and teacher management.
that the quality of education in Indonesia is
This process included three half-day consul-
not improving for two reasons. First, the
tations with groups of 8 to 10 bupatis from
lack of political will at the central and dis-
rural and urban areas in the same province.
trict levels to tackle the quality problem as
evidenced by: the low level of public financ-
Finally, we solicited comments on an earlier
ing of schools and of the sector overall, the
draft of this chapter from Indonesian offi-
absence of formal systems of incentives for
cials at the National Evaluation Center, the
improving quality and of consequences for
Directorate for Junior Secondary Education,
not meeting minimum quality standards, and
the Basic Education Planning Division of the
an organizational structure of the MoNE and
Directorate for Primary and Secondary Edu-
personnel policies of local governments that

90
Chapter 3 Quality Assurance and Improvement

cation, and from consultants working on grams is to improve school conditions and
project evaluation and management. These raise school performance.
inputs have been incorporated into the text.
Quality assurance refers to processes for
Basic Terms guaranteeing that schools and districts meet
particular standards. The quality assurance
This chapter uses several terms that are open
activities in Indonesia have three compatible
to interpretation and have no universally ac-
goals: (i) equivalence – ensuring a basis for
cepted definition. These “terms of art” are
comparing the credentials of teachers and
briefly described below, and more complete
school graduates throughout the archipelago
explanations are given later in the chapter.
through programs that include examinations
Quality is typically defined in terms of its and certification; (ii) equity – meeting the
instrumental value in increasing students’ basic rights of even very poor children to re-
academic performance. In other words, ceive basic educational services that meet
quality is usually defined as that mix of in- minimum service standards through a pro-
puts, classroom practices, school environ- gram that holds districts accountable to na-
ment, and school organization that adds tional standards for their performance; and
value to student learning. This chapter ex- (iii) groundwork – ensuring that schools
pands that definition to include an additional have a basic minimum amount of material
intrinsic dimension to the definition of qual- and human infrastructure that is both large
ity. We take the position that children have and equitable enough to improve quality.
a basic right to attend schools that meet the Under the new Education Law (No.
minimum conditions of learning as stipu- 20/2003), the mechanisms for achieving
lated in the Education Law and that any in- these ends consist of accrediting schools,
vestments in improving the quality of certifying teachers, and setting graduation
unsafe, unhealthy schools staffed by un- requirements for post-primary students.
qualified teachers to minimum standards are
by definition investments in educational Quality Management
quality regardless of their impact on chil-
Quality management means linking quality
dren’s academic performance. Expanding
improvement and quality assurance through
the definition to include the health, safety,
a common set of standards and measures.
and welfare of students aligns this definition
Under this approach, information from peri-
of quality with Indonesia’s Education Law
odic performance evaluations guide both
and its commitment to educational quality
quality assurance and quality improvement
for all (Education for All, 2002b) as both a
activities, as illustrated in Figure 3.1 and de-
basic human right and an instrument for
scribed in Box 3.1. The new Education Law
economic and social development.
provides part of the framework for quality
assurance by establishing a body that will set
Quality improvement simply means upgrad-
national standards and evaluate perform-
ing inputs, learning environments, teaching
ance. However, the law does not specify the
practices, school organization, and school
relationship between national standards and
performance to bring them closer to the ex-
quality improvement at the district or school
pectations of both the state and parents. In
levels. In this section, we discuss progress
Indonesia, recent quality improvement pro-
and issues in setting national standards and
jects have involved training and managing
measures and in establishing a nationwide
teachers, revising curricula, providing text-
system for reporting on performance.
books, rehabilitating classrooms, supporting
school-based management, and promoting
packaged inputs both on specific subjects
(for example, the Science Education Quality
Improvement package or SEQIP) and on
modern teaching methods (for example, the
Creating Learning Communities for Chil-
dren’s “joyful learning” package or CLCC).
The purpose of quality improvement pro-

91
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Figure 3.1 Diagram of Quality Management System


QUALITY
ASSURANCE
COMPONENT

Uniform Standards Uniform Measures

Recognition for Positive


Result Correction for Negative
Result
Positive PERFORMANCE Negative
EVALUATION

Monitoring
Results Information
Based Planning
QUALITY
IMPROVEMENT
COMPONENT

Milestones Improvement
Mobilizing Resource, Plan
Implementing Plans

Box 3.1 Hypothetical Use of Performance Information in a School

A hypothetical school is evaluated by an accreditation body and is performing just at the minimum
standard level. On the quality assurance side, the school receives an incentive for performing up to
minimum standards, in this case a certificate of accreditation that carries with it certain privileges.
This certificate qualifies the school to send representatives to an annual conference of accredited
schools offered by the district. On the quality improvement side, the school uses the performance
evaluation to prepare a school improvement plan and at regular interval checks to see if it is on
course to achieve these milestones. In this case, the school evaluation shows that many grade 4
students are not able to read at the 4th grade level; so the school introduces a daily program of
30minutes of sustained silent reading for students in grades 2 and 3. Teachers from grades 4 and 5
agree to monitor the progress of the children every two months. If the program works well, the
school will make 30minutes of sustained silent reading part of their daily teaching practice.

Need for Common Ground standards will be the conceptual link between
the quality assurance and quality improvement
A quality management approach requires a set systems, for example, by aligning school per-
of standards and measures to serve as common formance evaluation (quality assurance) with
ground for quality assurance and improve-
school development planning (quality im-
ment. The standards and measures must be provement) to the same set of national stan-
uniform across the education system, although dards. Second, the national standards will
performance targets can vary to take into ac- coordinate the activities of different agencies
count differences in conditions between dis-
operating at the same levels, for example, by
tricts or schools. For example, the standards focusing independent accreditation bodies and
of teacher competence must be the same in,
district school inspectors on the same set of is-
say, Mataram, East Java and Kupang, NTT. sues or by focusing public and private provid-
Likewise, the instruments used to measure ers of teacher training services on the same set
teacher competence, such as public examina- of competencies. Finally, as the function of
tions on subject matter plus observed teaching
quality management has been allocated to
practice, must be the same in both places. more than one level of government, the na-
However, the scores that teachers must receive
tional standards will help to ensure that all
to be certified or promoted can vary depending these different agencies carry out these quality
on the needs and resources of each district. functions towards the same end. For exam-
ple, while the central government will be re-
A single, well-considered set of national stan- sponsible for setting minimum standards for
dards is seminal in several ways. First, these
tests of basic student competencies, districts or

92
Chapter 3 Education Quality Assurance and Improvement

independent bodies will be responsible for de- 1. The school accreditation body (BAS) is
veloping tests that meet those standards. setting minimum standards for the ac-
creditation of schools and is defining a
Under decentralization, the central government process for monitoring and improving
is responsible both for setting national stan- school quality.
dards and measures and for evaluating the per- 2. The decentralization facilitation unit
formance of the education system overall. The (UFD) is working under the MoHA um-
MoNE is currently undertaking several parallel brella to develop minimum performance
standard-setting activities, and Figure 3.2 on standards for the districts.
the following page contains a diagram of the 3. The national evaluation center is devel-
standard-setting activities begun in 2003. The oping standards and tests of students’
most important of these standard-setting exer- mastery of basic competencies and the
cises are the National Education Standards for general and subject knowledge of trainee
schools, Minimum Service Standards for dis- teachers.
tricts, and Teacher Performance and Certifica- 4. The national curriculum center is defin-
tion Standards. Each is being developed by a ing basic competencies in all subject ar-
different working group, and, as yet, there is eas.
no standing body to coordinate their activities. 5. The textbook and academic publications
The absence of a steering body on standards center is defining technical standards for
has two dangers: first, that the cumulative print and graphic teaching materials.
number of standards may be too many to man- 6. The teacher training department is de-
age and, second, that the standards being de- veloping teacher competency standards.
veloped may not be compatible and may
therefore send different messages to teachers, Until this body is established, we highly rec-
schools, and districts about what they need to ommend forming a steering committee for
achieve. The Education Law mandates the harmonizing standards.
formation of a standardization and evaluation
body that will, among other duties, specify na-
tional education standards.32 Among its other
duties, this new body will have to coordinate
the following standard-setting activities:

32
Law No. 20/2003 Chapter IX, Article 35 and Chapter
XIV, Articles 57-59.

93
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Figure 3.2 Relationships between Standard-setting Entities being Developed or in Effect

UNDER DEVELOPMENT OR REVISION BY CENTER


IN EFFECT
Technical Standards for Inputs
Including:
School Accreditation - Textbooks
Body (BAS) KepMen MSS (MoHA)
PP/25/00 - Local Curricula
87/U/02 School Inspection
PP/108/00 - Infrastructure
KepMen 39/O/03 KepMen20/U/98
Various KepMen

Provincial Quality Im-


provement Institutes Student Certification
KepMen 114/U/01 MSS (MoNE)
Teacher Certification (LPMP)
KepMen 87/O/03 KepMen 11/U/02 KepMen053/U/01

District Education Systems


School
Committees
KepMen
44/U/02

Public and Private General Schools and Madrasah

Students and Teachers

94
Chapter 3 Quality Assurance and Improvement

Standards school performance. The national education


standards are not at present formally linked to
Chapter 4 of this report on teacher manage-
the district minimum service standards that are
ment discusses the standards currently being currently in draft form. The reason for this
developed for initial teacher certification and lack of connection is structural; the Education
their subsequent performance evaluations and Standards will be developed by an independ-
how these can be used in a career-long teacher
ent body and formalized as Ministerial Decree,
management and development program. In while the Minimum Service Standards are be-
this section, we discuss the National Education
ing developed by MoNE technical staff under
Standards for schools and Minimum Service the auspices of the Ministry of Home Affairs.33
Standards for districts. In 2001, a Ministerial Decree34 established a
set of standards for kindergartens, primary
Legal and Regulatory Basis schools, and junior secondary schools. These
The 2003 Education Law devotes an entire standards will be retired when the independent
chapter (Chapter IX) to the issue of national body formulates the new national education
education standards. That chapter mandates standards. The current standards have not
that standards be developed and codified for been effective for several reasons, principally,
educational content, process, graduation com- because there are too many categories (eight)
petencies, teaching force, infrastructure, man- and indicators (30-40) and because the guid-
agement, budgeting, and evaluation. It also ance for their implementation is burdensome.
calls for these national standards to be the ba- Because the central government has not pro-
sis for developing curricula, the teaching force, vided schools with adequate funds for training
educational infrastructure, management, and their administrators and teachers in the use of
budgeting. Among the 14 regulations cur- these standards and because the central gov-
rently being prepared is a draft regulation ernment has no statutory authority to compel
(RPP) that addresses the articles in the Educa- districts to use them, the existing national edu-
tion Law on national education standards. The cation standards have not been enforced. It is
draft RPP does not contain standards per se not clear whether the independent standardiza-
but states that national standards should be de- tion body that will manage the school stan-
veloped, implemented, reported on, and evalu- dard-setting process will also oversee the
ated by an independent educational district minimum service standards.
standardization and assurance body that re-
ports to the Minister of Education and this in- Minimum Service Standards for Districts
dependent body will organize standardization
Since decentralization, quality control in Indo-
and certification nationwide (RPP, 2003). In
nesia has been moving towards adopting a per-
the interests of public accountability and
formance-based type of management and
transparency, the law requires that citizens be
establishing quality control systems that are
given an opportunity to comment on these
transparent, equitable, and collaborative and
draft regulations at public hearings. This are consistent with the quality improvement
process of public hearings will begin in mid-
agenda. This progress can be seen in the
2004, and the independent education stan-
work of a special Decentralization Facilitation
dardization and assurance body is not likely to
Unit (DFU) within the MoNE, which under
be constituted before 2005. Therefore, there is
the guidance of the MoHA, has undertaken a
an ample timeframe for the government to
model-building exercise for setting district
recommend standards and standard-setting minimum service standards. The Unit has
processes for consideration.
been conducting pilot studies in three prov-
inces (West Java, East Java, and NTB) and
Education Standards for Schools
The independent body mentioned above will
set standards for schools and oversee school 33
Although there will be an umbrella Presidential Decree
quality assurance. Under the legal framework, authorizing Minimum Service Standards for several sec-
these education standards will be used as the tors, the standards themselves will be set by the Minister
basis for both a school accreditation system concerned through Ministerial Decrees, in this case the
and as a sector evaluation system based on Minister of Education.
34
Ministerial Decree 53/2001.

95
Education Sector Review Volume 2

five districts (Cianjur, Cirebon, Kota Sura- control quality and put district educational au-
baya, Kota Malang, and Lombok Timur). The thorities in a difficult position.
piloting began in the provincial capitals with
discussions with local government officials Lead and Lag Indicators
about the concept, function, and types of stan-
Quality management systems are most effec-
dards. The process continued at the district
tive if they are based on standards that include
level where various interest groups came to-
both “lead” and “lag” indicators.” Lag indica-
gether to discuss standards for 10 obligatory
tors describe what has been accomplished so
functions and 24 types of services. This
far. At the school level, for example, the
model-building exercise defined about 173
number of qualified teachers is a lag indicator,
minimum service standards for education (ex-
while the number of teachers sent for special-
cluding higher education), with each service
ized training is a lead indicator. At the district
type having as many as 19 or as few as two
level, the participation rate is an example of a
performance indicators (Hijmans, 2003). The
lag indicator, while the number of “at risk”
set of standards that are currently being devel-
children receiving scholarships is an example
oped include access, equity, and quality indi-
of a lead indicator. We recommend that the
cators such as enrollment rates, dropout and
standards for schools and districts contain a
completion rates by gender, students’ aca-
mixture of lag and lead indicators.
demic performance, and the percentage of the
APBD directed to the basic education sector
excluding teacher salaries. These are a mix of
Measures
input (technical) and output (performance) Setting standard measures for quality indica-
standards. The minimum service standards for tors is also an important element of a nation-
districts are critiqued in Chapter 1 on govern- wide quality management system. For quality
ance and management in this volume. management systems, the most important per-
formance measure is student learning. There
Local Targets – National Standards are many approaches to measuring student
learning, some being appropriate for quality
The national education standards were origi-
assurance and others for quality improvement.
nally intended to be set in an open process in
Each approach has specific advantages and
which the central government and the regions
disadvantages for Indonesia. For quality as-
would negotiate region-specific targets on the
surance, many countries use standardized tests
basis of indicators set by the central govern-
at the end of an educational cycle as one of the
ment. However, the MoNE now plans to have
factors that determine whether students have
national targets but flexible timelines for
learned enough to qualify for diplomas or cer-
achieving those education targets. Setting tar-
tificates of completion. In a large decentral-
gets at the national level is problematic for
ized system, equivalence among various
several reasons. First, it impinges on the pre-
private or public providers of examinations
rogative of local governments to chart their
can be assured by accrediting the testing insti-
own course. Second, it makes local education
tutions based on the rigor of their test devel-
officials accountable for their performance to
opment process, the reliability of the
two higher authorities, not only the local legis-
instruments that they prepare, and the validity
lature/executive but also the central MoNE.
of their test administration and scoring proto-
This is less troubling if all of these authorities
cols. Another alternative is to use sample-
have the same performance expectations but
based national assessments early or in the
can be problematic if the national and local
middle of an education cycle to measure stu-
performance expectations are very different.
dents’ performance against national standards.
Third, it is unclear what responsibilities the
Table 3.1 below shows how different types of
central government will have towards those
standard learning assessments can be used in a
districts that fail to meet minimum standards
quality management system.
over a period of time. If there are no incen-
tives for compliance or consequences for non-
compliance, then the standards do not help to

96
Chapter 3 Quality Assurance and Improvement

Table 3.1 Common Uses of National and School-based Tests in Quality Assurance
Norm Referenced Competency Referenced
Nationwide or Regional
High Stakes: Filtering: Rank students in per- Qualifying: Determine which
x Determine future oppor- centiles to determine which stu- students obtain diplomas or cer-
tunities for test takers dents may pass to favored tificates.
x Tied to performance in- schools at the next level
centives/ corrections
systems for schools Formerly used in Indonesia Currently used in Indonesia
x Expensive to develop (EBTANAS) (UAN)
and implement
x Prone to corruption
Middle Stakes Comparative ranking of schools Diagnostic: Used to recommend
x Tied to performance in- or districts: Used to rank order specific quality improvement in-
centives/ corrections schools or districts to determine puts for particular schools
system for schools which schools are eligible for
x No consequences for benefits, remediation or correc-
test takers tion Not yet used in Indonesia but can
x Expensive to develop be used in conjunction with ac-
and implement Not used in Indonesia in educa- creditation system or Provincial
x Somewhat prone to cor- tion sector, (an analogy can be Quality Improvement Institutes
ruption drawn with the Human Resource (LPMP)
Index which is used to rank dis-
tricts to determine welfare eligi-
bility)
Low Stakes Informational ranking of schools Informational for district or
x Information for plan- or districts school planning purposes only.
ning purposes only
x Not tied to performance Not used in Indonesia in educa-
incentives/ corrections tion sector, (an analogy can be
system for schools drawn with rankings on Human
x No consequences for Resource Index
test takers
x Expensive to implement
x Not prone to corruption
Sample-based International tests, such as Assessment of overall system ef-
x Information for plan- TIMSS, used to rank countries fectiveness for policy and pro-
ning purposes only for informational purposes gram planning
x Not tied to performance
incentives/ corrections Used in Indonesia Not yet used in Indonesia
system for schools
x No consequences for
test takers
x Relatively inexpensive
to implement
x Not prone to corruption
School-based
High Stakes Competitive ranking of pupils for Qualifying: Determine which
x Expensive to develop purposes of screening admissions students obtain diplomas or cer-
or awarding prizes or benefits. tificates.
x Open to corruption Entrance exams are used in In-
donesia to screen applicants. Used in Indonesia (UAS)

Low Stakes Informational ranking of students Information on individual student


x Not expensive to de- performance
velop or implement Not used in Indonesia
x Very demanding of Used in some classrooms
teachers
Note: EBTANAS = Evaluasi Belajar Tahap Akhir Nasional, UAN = Ujian Akhir Nasional, and UAS =
Ujian Akhir Sekolah.
97
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Box 3.2 Information from a National Evaluation System Changed the Focus of Debate in Brazil

Brazil is a large, decentralized country like Indonesia. Its decentralized structures and systems are heterogeneous to
the point where there are almost as many different education systems as there are states and cities. In such a system,
information is especially critical.

The evaluation system introduced in the 1990s has three components: a school census, a national assessment, and
public examinations at the end of the basic education cycle. Brazil has built up a very useful professional expertise
on the application of sample-based standardized student assessment tests that bring educational quality into the fore-
front of policy formulation and implementation. The active dissemination of test results, together with results about
resources and school operating standards, are fuelling competition among municipalities to improve their schools.
This practice puts a high value on the importance of establishing feedback mechanisms for ensuring that information
is shared across and within sub-national entities and community organizations.

Information derived from the evaluation tools focused the educational debate in Brazil on equity in the distribution of
public resources and conditions of instruction, the quality of instruction at various levels and in the various school
systems, teacher training, school autonomy, and management models. More specifically, after the census revealed
financing inequities among districts, the government redistributed about $10 billion among all public schools in dif-
ferent localities, which benefited 30 million students throughout the country. As a result of the national assessment,
policymakers introduced accelerated learning programs for students who were at least two grade levels behind their
age group and a training and certification program for teachers. Also, introducing a requirement that students had to
pass public examinations to graduate from secondary school created a standardized credential that is useful to both
higher education institutes and employers.

Source: World Bank, 2002.

Although information from standard tests can targets. Brazil has a large, decentralized edu-
be used to devise and implement improve- cation system in which performance informa-
ments within schools, most systems rely on tion is used to inform policymakers’ decisions.
school-based tests or continuous classroom as- A brief description of how pupil assessment is
sessment to monitor and upgrade the progress managed in Brazil is provided in Box 3.2.
of individual pupils. These methods require a
great deal of time and attention from teachers. Recommendations
We make the following recommendations in
Information
the area of quality management.
We discuss the need for a robust information
system in Chapter 1 on governance and man- x Under a decentralized program ap-
agement. At its most basic, the information proach to quality management, a
system must collect information relative to the permanent capacity for reviewing
national standards using the standard metrics. standards and measures is required.
One critical function of the information system The national Education Law (No,
is to provide reports to all levels  schools, 20/2003) requires the establishment
districts, provinces, and the central govern- of an independent body reporting to
ment. For quality management purposes, in- the Minister of Education that is re-
formation on performance is most useful if it sponsible for standardization and
includes three types of information  each evaluation. Until such a body is es-
school or district’s performance relative to na- tablished, we recommend that the
tional standards, their own past performance, MoNE appoint a standardization
and the performance of other districts or steering committee to oversee the
schools. In this way a district or school can several parallel standard-setting proc-
monitor changes in its performance over time. esses that are already underway.
Although the results of performance assess-
ments can be reported as a single number by x In the interest of imposing discipline
using a formulated index, if the results are dis- and rigor on the standard-setting
aggregated by topic, this can help districts and process, we recommend that staff
schools to meet specific quality improvement who are qualified, experienced, and

98
Chapter 3 Quality Assurance and Improvement

empowered to make difficult deci- pendent institution. Further, it speci-


sions actively participate in or steer fies that the community and/or
the standard-setting body. In Indone- professional organizations can form
sia, policies are not set by law or independent bodies to undertake those
even by decree, which are often evaluations of learning outcomes.
vague and contradictory. Rather, the x The article on accreditation (Chapter
policies are embodied within opera- XIV, Article 60) stipulates that the
tional guidelines written by mid- government and/or independent bodies
ranking professionals or even inde- will accredit programs and schools in
pendent bodies. In a sense, the diffi- the interests of public accountability.
cult job of policymaking has been Furthermore, the law states that ac-
delegated to a level of staff who are creditation will be based on “open cri-
not sufficiently qualified, experi- teria” that are not further explained.
enced, or empowered to set policies. x The article on certification (Chapter
XIV, Article 61) states that certifica-
x We recommend an international peer tion will be in the form of “diplomas”
review through a seminar and follow- (ijazah) and certificates of compe-
up workshops before the national tency. Diplomas will be awarded to
education standards and minimum students in acknowledgement of their
service standards are finalized. Host- learning achievement and/or their
ing international seminars has raised completion of a level of study after
awareness within the MoNE that passing an examination organized by
standard-setting activities are instru- an accredited school. Schools and
mental to assuring and improving training institutes will give compe-
educational quality. The MoNE has tency certificates to learners and
recently completed drafts for both community members in recognition of
kinds of minimum service standards x their competency to undertake specific
but would benefit from additional in- work after passing competency tests
put before codifying those drafts into organized by an accredited school or
regulation. certified institution.

Quality Assurance In theory, these stipulations will be clarified


This section describes the status of quality as- through government regulations (RPPs), Min-
surance in the education sector using examples isterial Decrees, and procedural manuals.
from current practices. The link between the The Education Law mandates the preparation
quality assurance organizations is not clear, of 14 Government Regulations (RPPs), and the
and there is potential for them to produce con- drafting of one additional law on the legal
flicting messages and for there to be duplica- status of schools (BHP). As we discussed in
tion in their efforts. the section on standards above, a draft RPP is
currently being prepared that addresses both
Legal and Regulatory Framework Chapter IX on National Education Standards
and Chapter XIV on evaluation, accreditation,
The New Education Law (No. 20/2003) de- and certification summarized above.
votes an entire chapter to the issues of evalua-
tion, accreditation, and certification (Chapter Current Practices
XIV, Articles 57-59).
Currently, there are several quality assurance
mechanisms practiced in Indonesia. These can
x The law calls for the evaluation of
be organized into two groups: mechanisms
learners, institutions, and programs.
that apply to individuals (students and teach-
Although the law is vague and some-
ers) and mechanisms that apply to institutions
what contradictory, it seems to stipu-
(schools and local government). The mecha-
late two kinds of learner evaluation:
nisms are falling short of expectations due to
continuous assessment by teachers and
issues such as tension between the center and
the periodic evaluation of learners,
districts regarding roles and responsibilities for
schools, and programs by an inde-

99
Education Sector Review Volume 2

quality assurance and technical matters like the and replaced at the junior and senior secondary
lack of capacity to implement policies pertain- levels only with the Ujian Akhir Nasional
ing to school and district educational quality (UAN) and the Ujian Akhir Sekolah (UAS).
assurance. The UAN covers three core subjects (Bahasa
Indonesia, Mathematics, and English) and
Students and Teachers draws the multiple-choice items from the same
item bank for schools nationwide. The items
At the present time, quality assurance pro-
on the UAN still mostly require only factual
grams for students and teachers are examina-
recall and rarely measure competencies, espe-
tion-based, routine, and structured as part of
cially in subjects like Indonesian in which lan-
the normal course of doing business. There
guage competency is the core of the
are clear incentives for students and teachers
curriculum. The UAS is the test for all na-
to comply with standards, as there are clear
tional subjects other than Bahasa Indonesia,
consequences for failing (for example, senior
Mathematics, and English as well as local con-
secondary students who do not pass the final
tent chosen by the districts and can include es-
national examination are not allowed to gradu-
says, portfolios, laboratory work, and other
ate and candidate teachers who fail knowledge
assessment methods. However, at this stage,
tests are not certified). The standard examina-
the UAS also mainly relies on multiple-choice
tions for measuring student achievement and
questions. Tests can be, and often are, set by
the competency of candidate teachers, though
individual schools or, in some cases, as the re-
far from ideal, are reasonable. Technical ex-
sult of agreements among groups of teachers at
perts at the MoNE acknowledge that students’
the district (junior and senior secondary) or
final examinations are not yet adequately stan-
sub-district (primary) level.
dardized, although much progress has been
made in this direction.
The parliament decided to permit the 2004
public examinations to go ahead but stated its
Student Diplomas. In Indonesia, academic intention to discontinue allocating public funds
quality is monitored through students’ end-of- for that specific purpose in the future. As a
level examinations. School certificates are newly elected parliament will be responsible
granted or withheld on the basis of the stu- for appropriations in 2005, it remains to be
dents’ examination scores. These certificates seen whether the 2004 public examinations
grant, but do not guarantee them access to the are, indeed, the final finals.
next level of study. In the 1980s, the Evaluasi
Belajar Tahap Akhir Nasional (EBTANAS) Teacher Certification. Teachers are the single
was introduced as a national test. Originally most important determinant of students’
intended as a tool to assess and control the performance and school quality, and teacher
quality of the education system, the tests issues are discussed in depth in the next
quickly became high-stakes public examina- chapter. Therefore, the management of the
tions that determined which students would be supply of this most critical “input” must be the
able to continue their education and the kind first step in ensuring that the teaching
of school to which they could hope to gain workforce meets the country’s minimum
admission.35 Due to widespread criticism of standards of quality through the process of
expense, corruption and lack of usability of the certification. There are currently four types of
public examination system, the EBTANAS teachers in Indonesia (see Box 3.3), two of
was abolished by ministerial decree in 2002 which are certified. Teacher certification is
managed by an appointments procedure,
which takes into account their performance on
35
Although the EBTANAS was a nationwide public ex- standardized tests.
amination, it did not meet the standard for a standard-
ized test. Provinces were sent alternative questions and
could choose easier or harder questions to suit the ability For the last six years, graduates of accredited
of students in their region. The formula to work out the institutions of higher education who wish to
final score also varied by region to make sure that any become junior or senior secondary teachers or
differences in final scores between regions were not too contract teachers must take a public
great, although in practice the differences in scores be-
tween provinces were considerable.
examination, which tests their general

100
Chapter 3 Quality Assurance and Improvement

Box 3.3 Quality Assurance of the Teaching Force

x Public teachers are civil servants and have minimum teaching qualification (for a new SD teacher, D2,
two year degree and post SMU, for new SMP/SMU teachers, this is S1, a four year university degree).
x Contract teachers are fixed term contract teachers, normally engaged as part of education projects but
with the same qualifications as public teachers.
x Permanent teachers are engaged by foundations to teach in private schools. Those in better schools
have to have all of the required minimum qualifications described above, but in poorer schools, many
have less qualifications.
x Temporary teachers are employed in all kinds of schools (private and public) to fill shortages and are
normally paid by the scholl committee or a foundation. These teachers vary widely in their
qualifications, some have only the minimum qualification and many in poorer schools lack even the
minimum. Their wages are often very low, sometimes less that Rp. 100,000 per month.

knowledge,36 subject mastery, and scholastic school accreditation body (BAS), listed the
aptitude. As of this year, 2004, primary key aspects of accreditation, and stated that the
teachers will also take the examinations. Due new ranking will be used to provide guidance
to the large numbers of candidates taking the on quality improvement to schools. The
tests each year (in 2003, 500,000 candidates accreditation procedure itself involves seven
took the examination as part of the application steps. The first step involves each school
process for advertised junior secondary doing a self-assessment of whether it meets the
education positions), a test of teaching national requirements. If the school feels that
competencies has not been included. The it is in compliance with the standards, then it
results of six years of testing will provide a requests an audit from the local accreditation
rich resource for future research into the body.38 If the school passes the audit, then it
specific strengths and weaknesses of the receives accreditation for a four-year period.
current teaching workforce. It has not yet been decided what will happen to
those schools that do not meet the minimum
Schools and Local Government accreditation requirements over an extended
period of time. It is anticipated that many
School Accreditation. In the future, school-
schools, particularly the numerous small
level quality will be maintained and improved
private madrasahs that provide educational
through an accreditation system established
services to many poor children especially in
under the new Education Law. This
remote areas, will fall far short of the
accreditation system will apply to all schools,
minimum accreditation standards.
whether public, private, general, or madrasah.
Accredited schools will be ranked into three
The accreditation system is an interesting ap-
categories, and the lowest category will
proach to quality assurance but tough policy
include schools that meet the absolute
issues remain unresolved. To ensure that dif-
minimum standards. Thus far, the ranking of
ficult policy decisions are aligned with na-
schools under the new system is not much
tional priorities, policymakers rather than the
different from the existing system for ranking
independent accreditation body need to make
schools. A Ministerial Decree (KepMen
some difficult decisions about which incen-
087/U/2002)37 has established an independent
tives and sanctions to put in place for those
schools that do and do not meet the minimum
accreditation standards. As the policy reads
36
General knowledge tests include Bahasa Indonesia, now, the purposes of accreditation are twofold:
civics, public policy, English, and mathematics. (i) to ensure that even disadvantaged children
37
Article 60 of the Education Law stipulates that the ac-
creditation of schools will be the responsibility of the
attend schools that meet the minimum condi-
government and/or an independent body. The KepMen
087/U/2002, which predated the law established an inde- structure; staffing; budgeting; teachers and students;
pendent accreditation body (BAS), lists nine school community participation; and the school environment
components to be evaluated during accreditation includ- and culture.
38
ing: the curriculum and the teaching/learning process; Primary and junior secondary schools will apply to the
school administration and management; district body for accreditation, while senior secondary
school/institutional organization, equipment and infra- schools will apply to the province.

101
Education Sector Review Volume 2

tions of learning and (ii) to provide continuing Institutional Framework


guidance to schools to help them to improve
There are several bodies that will be responsi-
their quality. Assigning two technically de-
manding functions to bodies that have not yet ble for implementing the new quality assur-
been established needs further consideration. ance mechanisms.
The guidance concept is appealing, but unless
it is accompanied by a serious commitment of National Agencies
financial and technical resources, this guidance The task of coordinating the quality assurance
will have little effect. The responsibility for system is, under the Education Law, assigned
schools has clearly been assigned to the dis- to a quality assurance and standardization
tricts, but no legislation or regulation defines body, to be known as the National Standardi-
how districts can be persuaded to spend scarce zation Body. As mentioned previously, the
resources on programs to ensure that schools government regulations associated with that
meet national minimum accreditation stan- article of the law are currently being prepared,
dards. Furthermore, there is no explanation of and the particular institutional framework for
where the local accreditation bodies will find managing quality assurance has not yet been
the human and financial resources required to formalized.
conduct audits of every school and madrasah
every four years and to provide them with con- There is no provision for a national center to
tinuing guidance. set nationwide public examinations as a means
for quality assurance under the Education
Districts Law. This has opened debate about the future
existence of the National Evaluation and Test-
At present there is confusion about what
ing Center, which until now has been respon-
mechanisms apply for ensuring the quality of
sible for setting, overseeing, and managing the
education services managed by districts. As
marking of the current high-stakes public ex-
mentioned above, minimum service standards
aminations at the end of the basic and secon-
for education are being prepared, along with
dary cycles.
standards for other decentralized sectors.
Eventually, these service standards will be-
Prior to the passage of the Education Law, the
come part of the government’s performance-
Ministry of Education established an Educa-
based budget procedures described in Law
tional Quality Assurance Institution (Provin-
17/2003. This law requires district and na-
cial Lembaga Penjamin Mutu Pendidikan or
tional budgets to be prepared based on activi-
LPMP) by Ministerial Decree (KepMen
ties that are justified against performance
87/O/03). This decree transformed 30 provin-
standards. It is not yet clear how central fi-
cial teacher training centers into 30 branches
nancing for districts will be tied to their ac-
of the LPMP. The core functions of these
tions or their performance against standards.
branches are to support school and teacher
Nor is it clear if districts will need to justify
quality assurance including:
funding items in terms of their actions or past
performance. The education sector is increas-
x Measuring and evaluating the imple-
ingly using the DAK mechanism for financing
mentation of basic and secondary edu-
national education priorities such as the Edu-
cation.
cation for All initiatives. DAK financing is
proposal-based, and the central government x Building models, including teach-
could require districts to use service standards ing/learning models, that will help
as a basis for those proposals. By using per- schools to meet national quality stan-
formance standards to justify both block and dards.
earmarked grants, the national government can x Assisting teachers in measuring and
use financing as a quality assurance tool. evaluating the outcomes of learning.
Once national policies on district level ac- x Helping teachers to manage educa-
countability for educational quality are clari- tional resources for quality improve-
fied, mechanisms for quality assurance at the ment.
district level can be refined and coordinated.

102
Chapter 3 Quality Assurance and Improvement

The LPMP is not mentioned in the Education School Committees


Law, and the law assigns most of the 40 tasks
included in the LPMP’s terms of reference to The national policy on school-based manage-
the National Standardization Body and to the ment includes the function of quality assur-
district governments. It is not clear whether ance at the school level. The Education Law
the LPMP will be continued after the accredi- specifies this function assignment and, in Arti-
tation bodies and district quality evaluation cle 51, stipulates that school management must
bodies have been formally established. be based on minimum service standards and
on the principle of school-based management
Continuing the LPMP and its branches might (Law No. 20/2003, Chapter XIV, Article 51,
be beneficial if the institution does not actually paragraph 1).
set standards but limits its activities to provid-
The school-level body responsible for evalua-
ing performance evaluation services under the
tion and quality assurance is the school com-
direction of the school accreditation body
mittee; these committees are discussed in
(BAS). The overlap of its functions with those
Chapter 1 on governance and management.
of the districts might be more problematic.
Teachers are assigned the responsibility for
The following list highlights a few of the over-
quality assurance through classroom practices
lapping tasks:
such as continuous assessment.
x Assessing the competency of and cer-
tifying educational institutions and
Recommendations
staff in the provinces. School-level quality control under decentrali-
x Undertaking EMIS services including zation is shifting from a system dependent on
data collection and school quality external inspections against absolute standards
mapping, and maintaining the data- to a system reliant on self-assessment against
base for and disseminating informa- national, local, and school-based standards
tion on primary and secondary backed up by occasional external audits. In-
information to schools. deed, there are far too many schools to be
x Supervising and evaluating primary monitored entirely through a system of exter-
and secondary education in the prov- nal inspections. Ideally, the results of both the
inces. schools’ self-assessments and occasional ex-
x Certifying educational quality in the ternal audits will serve as inputs to the process
provinces. of improving school quality, thereby linking
the quality control and quality improvement
School Inspectors efforts. Towards this end we make the follow-
ing recommendations:
At present, districts still use a system of circuit
inspections for quality assurance. Primary
school inspectors operate out of sub-district x We recommend that the MoNE de-
offices, while junior secondary school inspec- velop a model for enabling citizens to
tors operate out of district government offices. participate in preparing and refining
Although school inspectors are supposed to regulations. The model-building exer-
provide feedback and guidance to schools on cise could be implemented by : (i) or-
teaching practice, most school principals and ganizing information campaigns about
teachers who participated in our focus groups government regulation aimed at all
described the inspections as focusing almost education sector stakeholders, (ii)
entirely on administrative matters. Inspectors conducting public hearings, and (iii)
visit schools only infrequently, particularly updating and finalizing the govern-
those schools located far from the sub-district ment regulations.
offices. In the past, many school inspectors
were retired teachers, but recently younger x Indonesia lacks a standardized test of
people have been recruited who have been learning to provide geographically
trained in modern teaching practices and who comparative information on students’
are physically more able to get to remote academic performance. While there
schools. are one or two internationally compa-
rable tests, there are no domestic ones

103
Education Sector Review Volume 2

that give an accurate picture of the claim that the certification process is
state of learning within Indonesia. We not transparent and that the extortion
recommend introducing a periodic na- of sums of money by officials in
tional assessment of learning, particu- exchange for favorable appointments
larly at the lower grades, which would is a common practice. Indeed, the
yield useful information about the practice is so widespread that poor
overall performance of the education parents of junior high students feel
system. that the teaching profession is closed
to their offspring as they cannot afford
x Although some progress has been the illegal payments (World Bank,
made in establishing a system for 2001). However, once these anti-
school accreditation, many difficult is- corruption activities are implemented,
sues are left unresolved. For example, the quality of the teaching force will
at present there is no incentive system no longer be undermined by corrupt
with rewards and corrections for en- practices like these.
couraging schools and districts to
comply with national standards. Nor Quality Improvement
does the policy include a process for
This section places quality improvement in the
resolving disagreements over accredi-
context of Indonesia’s experiments with qual-
tation or monitoring results. Also
ity improvement, the current legal and regula-
lacking is a system for gathering data
tory framework governing quality
on quality indicators to be used for
improvement. We then tie failures to improve
quality control and resource allocation
quality to underlying structural issues such as
purposes. Until the specifics of the
inadequate sector finance and absence of a
compliance and implementation proc-
system for sustaining quality improvement that
esses are sorted out, the new accredita-
is integrated into routine sector management
tion system is not likely to serve its
practices.
purposes. We recommend an interna-
tional peer review of the proposed ac-
The Indonesian Experience in School
creditation system through an
international conference and a series Quality Improvement
of follow-up workshops with policy Indonesia has been experimenting with quality
makers to resolve difficult issues. improvement for over 30 years. During this
time, public support for quality improvement
x Assuring quality in districts and has been project-based and channeled from the
schools through minimum service central government while private support has
standards is still in the planning phase. been school-based and channeled through
We recommend that quality assurance school fees and other household contributions.
be linked to annual performance-based Remarks made by school committee represen-
budgets prepared by schools and dis- tatives and school principals during the district
tricts. In this way, the quality assur- consultation process during the preparation of
ance system will become a routine part this report revealed that the dynamic that pro-
of financial planning and performance pels schools to improve quality is market-
reviews. based; better public and private schools can
charge higher fees for services. Two factors
x Indonesia is currently planning some limit the effectiveness of the market dynamic:
comprehensive anti-corruption the limited supply of quality improvement
activities that will include monitoring goods and services and the modest purchasing
independent from the government. We power of even the most successful schools.
recommend that anti-corruption Indonesia has been expanding the supply of
activities be considered part of the government-provided goods and services
quality assurance process. The Social through centrally funded projects for over 30
Assessment for the Basic Education years. Since the 1990s, Indonesia has been
IV Project reports that many teachers experimenting with giving government grants
to schools for quality improvement. Donors

104
Chapter 3 Quality Assurance and Improvement

have been active in the sector guiding and in- Research Underlying Quality
vesting in many publicly financed projects that Improvement Projects
fund school rehabilitation, textbooks, libraries,
teacher training, technical advice, and other The quality improvement projects over the last
inputs.39 With all this experience, donor guid- decade have been based on practices derived
ance, and investment, why has the quality of from two main research areas – school effec-
education overall not improved? tiveness and school reform.

Researchers have built up a foundation of lon-


Project Approach
gitudinal, quantitative, and empirical studies in
The problem is structural in that quality im- developed and developing countries about
provements are project-based and not part of a what mix of inputs into “the school climate,”
school’s or a district’s routine operations. Pro- “enabling conditions,” and “the teaching/
ject-based interventions such as cluster-based learning process” influence students’ cognitive
in-service training, library construction, or achievements. Unfortunately, the results of
proposal-based grants for quality improvement these studies have not yielded a sequenced list
are sometimes successful during the life span of investments guaranteed to improve per-
of the project, but nearly all prove to be unsus- formance. School reform research is grounded
tainable in the long run due to high unit or in management theory, particularly manage-
high recurrent costs. In addition to a short life ment for change, and is primarily based on
span, quality improvements are seldom evalu- qualitative research and case studies. School
ated in terms of their impact on school per- reform emphasizes improving the within-
formance and they rarely spread spontaneously school decisionmaking process, enhancing
to those schools that were not project benefici- school/community relations, encouraging the
aries. One approach that has not yet been ap- generation of ideas from within schools about
plied in Indonesia is to incorporate quality how to improve quality, and in-house capacity
improvement into the routine operations of building. Unfortunately, research into the im-
schools or districts by: (i) including quality pact of school reform on school performance
improvement activities in a consolidated is not conclusive. Indonesia has experimented
budget for school financing that is transferred with projects derived from each of these re-
from districts to schools either as part of the search areas. Table 3.2 compares the attributes
school’s block grant or as earmarked funds of the school effectiveness approach and
depending on the school’s capacity for plan- school reform approach.
ning and accounting, and (ii) using a perform-
ance-based budgeting system that holds
districts accountable for schools’ minimum
service standards.

39
A summary of 25 donor-supported projects appears in
Appendix 1.

105
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Table 3.2 Comparing the School Effectiveness and School Reform Approaches
School Effectiveness School Reform
Research area Cognitive science (theory into Management science (practice
practice) into theory)
Research thrust Teaching and learning process Managing for quality improve-
ment
Classroom teaching practices
Managing for change
Allocation of production func-
tions
Research variables Inputs School control over resources

Classroom processes School governance structures

Learning achievement School management processes


Research methods Longitudinal, quantitative, and Qualitative studies to explain the
empirical studies highly context-specific nature of
quality improvement
Rigorously designed sequential
studies Evaluations of individual im-
provement initiatives
Methodologically complex analy-
sis using statistical techniques
such as multi-level modeling to
large data sets
Examples of projects/programs in SPP-CBSA COPLANER
Indonesia SSEM Cosep
(Some have elements of both: the PEQIP BOMM
projects are categorized by their SEQIP REDIP I and II
major thrust and intention) PJSE DSSD
B&R DBEP
BEP (MoRA) CLCC
BEP (MoNE) MBE
PGSD
PGSM
CLCC
Major inputs Pre and in-service teacher training School and kecamatan manage-
ment capacity building
Educational materials School Improvement Grants

School rehabilitation
Weaknesses Limited demand for quality im- Limited supply of quality im-
provement services in non-project provement services
schools

Does not explain how to make in- Does not explain how to improve
effective schools effective quality of teaching and learning

Defines effectiveness in terms of


cognitive and academic outcomes
rather than social and effective
ones
Key findings from research Influence of student background Management of change
on performance
Improvement as a process at sys-
Importance of “proximal” factors tem, school, and classroom levels
over “distal” ones
Descriptive analysis of in-school
Differential effectiveness within cultures and power relationships
schools

106
Chapter 3 Quality Assurance and Improvement

School Effectiveness School Reform

Interaction of factors within


schools
Interventions Technical and professional Decentralized decisionmaking
Centrally defined, standard pack-
age of inputs
Support for changing practices
External pressure to change prac- that can be sustained by the
tices to meet technical or profes- school over the long term
sional standards
Note: A brief description of each project featured in this table appears in Appendix 3.1.

Current Legal and Regulatory The legal obligations of the central govern-
Framework for Quality Improvement ment in school financing are limited to paying
teachers’ salaries through the wage transfer
Unlike quality assurance, there is no chapter in portion of the DAU formula. Although the
the Education Law that specifically addresses constitution and the Education Law (No.
the issue of quality improvement. However, 20/2003) stipulate that 20 percent of the na-
quality improvement is mentioned several tional budget and 20 percent of the block
times, both as a general agenda item and as the grants to districts must be spent on education,
specific goal of several statutes. For example, there is no regulation that establishes a funding
in Article 56 on education boards and school floor for schools. Indeed, there is no national
committees, the law stipulates that the role of law that regulates within-district transfers of
the community in improving quality in schools APBD funding to schools. If the government’s
should include planning, monitoring, and appropriation to the education sector does not
evaluation. Prior to decentralization, the rou- increase to the level stipulated under the con-
tine management of the primary school system stitution and the decentralization laws, quality
was assigned to local governments, and re- will not improve equitably. Channeling qual-
sponsibility for educational quality improve- ity improvements through the DAK mecha-
ment was assigned to the central government. nism could ensure that funds allocated for
Under decentralization law 22/1999, these education are spent for schools and by schools.
functions were reunited and districts were This chapter on quality recognizes but does
given responsibility for the education sector not address the issues of the 7 to 15-year-old
overall. A national policy of school-based children who do not attend school. Under the
management through school committees and law, they are entitled to receive their fair share
district education management by education of public spending on education, but in prac-
boards was formalized by a Ministerial Decree tice this already disadvantaged group receives
(KepMen 44/U/02). Under this policy um- far less than the young citizens who are en-
brella, schools are responsible for improving rolled in school.
the quality of education while districts are re-
sponsible for improving the quality of the Project preparation documents for the World
management of educational services.40 Bank’s Basic Education IV project under-
Whether this transfer of authority translates scored the need for quality improvement in
into a transfer of assets or of liabilities de- early childhood and early grade education.
pends upon two things: (i) the condition of the Background papers reported that teachers
schools and the capacities of the district and spend most of their classroom time in grades 4
(ii) the amount of the public budget allocated and above on remedial teaching rather than on
to education. helping students to master grade-level skills.
This pattern will continue unless the govern-
ment adopts programs that prepare children for
schooling and strengthen the early childhood
component of basic education.

107
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Financing the Quality Improvement of Box 3.4 The New Zealand Equalization Pro-
Schools gram
What kind of value is the Indonesian state and There is a tendency in decentralized education
are Indonesian families getting for what they systems for differences in quality to increase be-
spend on basic education? The Education for tween wealthier and less wealthy areas unless ex-
All (EFA) task force has estimated that com- plicit corrective measures are taken. In New
pulsory academic fees for primary and junior Zealand, the original design of the school-based
secondary average about Rps 213,000 per pu- management reforms did not include mechanisms
pil. These fees are used to cover schools’ op- to ensure the equitable financing of schools. In
erating expenses and improvements in the response to this absence, the government created
the Targeted Funding for Educational Achieve-
quality of its physical assets, teachers’ salaries,
ment (TFEA) as a component of schools’ operat-
schoolbooks, learning materials, and equip- ing grants. The TFEA is targeted to specific
ment. This implies that public spending on schools to enable them to overcome the barriers
these basic conditions of learning is inade- to students’ learning that are associated with so-
quate. At the district level where education cioeconomic disadvantage. All schools are
personnel constitute over half of all public ranked by decile, and per-student funding in-
employees, up to 60 percent of the routine and creases as the school’s decile declines.
development district budget (APBD) is spent
on education, primarily on routine expenses
such as teachers’ salaries. Educational facili- Organizational Systems for Sustaining
ties constitute more than half of the assets held Quality Improvement
by many local governments. The central gov- In this section, we discuss the organizational
ernment has no formula for equalizing district frameworks for sustaining quality improve-
expenditures on quality improvements and no ment, namely school-based management and
means to ensure that districts allocate their district development planning. School-based
education resources equitably. The current management is not only a policy of the MoNE,
practice of channeling quality improvement but is also mandated under Law 20, article
inputs to schools directly through centrally 51(1). District development planning is re-
funded projects exceeds the two-year time quired under Law No. 17/2003 on perform-
limit for direct transfer of resources that was ance-based budgeting. Although neither of
set in Law 25/1999. these systems deals directly with the quality
issue, both systems have some potential for
In Chapter 2 on financing, we pointed out that sustaining quality improvement. District de-
Indonesia is spending less on education than velopment planning is discussed in Chapter 1
might be expected given its per capita income on governance and management. In the sec-
level. The introductory chapter showed that tion below, we focus on school-based man-
Indonesian children perform worse on stan- agement.
dardized international tests than children in
neighboring countries but better than children School-based Management
in some countries that spend about the same
proportion of public money on education. In Indonesia, the strategy that has been
Taken together, the data show that Indonesian adopted to improve schools over the long term
parents and the state have been getting reason- is school-based management (SBM). The in-
able value for their expenditure compared with tention behind school-based management is to
other countries; in other words, they spend lit- engage the wider local community through
tle and get little. Furthermore, Chapter 2 on school committees in planning, monitoring,
financing revealed that spending on education and improving school quality (Article 56 Law
in Indonesia is inequitable, resulting in un- 20/2003). Very preliminary findings from our
equal access and quality. Box 3.4 describes consultations with district-level officials indi-
New Zealand’s approach to equalizing quality cate that school committees have been set up
in a decentralized system.

108
Chapter 3 Quality Assurance and Improvement

but are not yet active in the area of quality im- Background papers on school-based manage-
provement.41 ment written for this report acknowledge that
participatory management and adequate school
School-based management does not guarantee resources are a necessary but not sufficient
quality improvement. International research condition for improving student achievement.
reveals that the link between SBM and quality They also recognize that schools require,
improvement is inconclusive. According to a among other elements, performance informa-
recent review of 83 studies of SBM programs tion (through both school profile statistics and
around the world, there is no universally posi- self-assessments) and accountability systems
tive relationship between school-based man- (Umaedi, 1999). Although the MoNE has dis-
agement and school performance or school seminated guidelines to schools for carrying
quality improvement (Leithwood and Menzies, out performance self-assessments that incorpo-
1998). In fact, the authors conclude that SBM rate these concepts, none of the schools in-
fails to improve students’ academic achieve- cluded in the focus groups mentioned using
ment or to reduce dropout and repetition rates, them.
even though SBM does increase parents’ and
communities’ say in decisionmaking, teachers’ In response to studies indicating that school ef-
participation in developing school improve- fectiveness inputs are not always used and
ment plans, and administrative efficiency in al- maintained,42 Indonesia has been experiment-
locating scarce resources effectively. Other ing with pilot programs that require schools to
research indicates that it is not school-based prepare improvement plans designed to im-
decisionmaking per se that improves learning; prove teaching and learning. Since 2000, many
rather, it is the type of decisions that schools quality improvement programs have been pro-
are entitled to make for themselves. Schools’ viding small grants to schools to implement
autonomy in making personnel decisions, their school development plans. These plans
teachers’ autonomy in choosing which teach- reveal much about the gap between the priori-
ing methods to use, and teachers’ involvement ties of education professionals and the priori-
in procurement decisions are particularly in- ties of school managers. Box 3.5 contains a
fluential (Woessmann, 2001). description of the typical content of most
school development plans.
Despite several well-known shortcomings,
SBM is the best method available in Indonesia However, there are many steps that can be
for making quality improvement a part of rou- taken that move beyond the limited scope of
tine school operations. Thirty years of pro- most school improvement plans. One such step
jects have yielded insights into what involves package-based improvement grants.
methodologies work best in classrooms to in- In Indonesia, under the SIGP program of
crease student achievement and to make 2001-2002, the central government gave a
schooling a pleasant experience for both grant package to all schools that met all of the
teachers and students (for example, active and necessary requirements and conditions. SIGP
contextual learning). Unfortunately, systemic funds could only be used for seven purposes:
and structural barriers, such as a lack of ac- buying books and stationery, hiring teachers,
countability, insufficient human and technical purchasing teaching aids, renovating build-
resources, and widespread corruption, prevent ings, repairing classrooms and library furni-
good practices from spreading spontaneously. ture, installing water and sanitation facilities,
and introducing school-based teacher training.
Each school received a set amount depending
41
Focus group discussions with teachers and principals
in Lampung and Makasar as well as meetings with
42
school committee members in Central Java and Yogya- For example, staff from the MBE project in East Java
karta revealed that many principals have not yet dis- and Central Java reported that several of the libraries in
cussed performance standards or improvement planning the 36 schools that they visited appeared to be unused
with school committees. Some focus group members judging by the dust on the books and the records. Also,
also commented that the performance monitoring pres- staff from the JBIC team on field visits to recently con-
ently being conducted by school committees, an essential structed junior secondary schools in 2002 reported that
element in sustaining quality improvement, concentrates over half of the new school stock was not being regularly
only on financial matters. maintained.

109
Education Sector Review Volume 2

on its level of poverty, the condition of its x The absence of knowledge and infor-
physical plant, and safety considerations. Dis- mation about education quality im-
trict committees selected the schools and de- provement at the district level is a
termined the amount of the grant. REDIP also major inhibiting factor. Projects such
used a menu of restricted choices for school as the DBEP that used proposal-based
grants and required schools to produce simple grants in an attempt to enhance dis-
proposals written to a template. Packaged tricts’ ability to improve school qual-
grants require less planning capacity on the ity have shown that districts lack the
part of schools than SBM but remove respon- experience and knowledge to develop
sibility from the school and community for multi-year programs to improve edu-
self-assessment and program development. cation quality. We recommend mak-
Box 3.5 School Development Plans and ing a significant investment in
Quality Inputs building the technical and managerial
capacity of districts to improve qual-
There has been no research published yet on the ity.
comparative results of school reform projects.
Anecdotal evidence provided by field workers x The supply of competent government
from the Managing Basic Education (MBE) Pro- and private sector trainers and con-
ject indicates that the school development plans sultants is a compounding and binding
from participating schools are confined largely to constraint. Therefore, we recommend
physical conditions such as rehabilitating build- making a significant investment in de-
ings and providing more books. A recent visit by
veloping the capacity of public and
MBE project teams to REDIP sites in Central
Java found little change in teaching as a result of
private providers of quality improve-
the program. Likewise, a review of DBEP school ment services. Indeed, knowledge
improvement proposals confirmed that schools about how to improve school quality
tend to request the rehabilitation of their facilities already exists in Indonesia; the bottle-
and the provision of more library books and other neck is that there are not enough high
material inputs rather than teacher training. The quality “service providers” (such as
focus on physical inputs is partly the result of the competent and informed teacher train-
lack of teacher trainers. The demand is there, but ers) to apply this knowledge in every
there is no supply to meet it. The CLCC project school. Centrally planned quality im-
is slightly different in that it focuses on SBM in provement projects are often well-
order to improve teaching and directly tackles the conceived packages that, in their pilot
training issue by increasing the supply of trainers.
phases, are usually successful in
achieving their objectives. In the pilot
Recommendations test phase of such projects, project
If simply providing inputs improved quality teams generally provide services to
and school performance, then district educa- schools directly, but it is impractical to
tional planning would simply be a question of extend this pilot approach to all of the
channeling inputs to schools. Unfortunately, one and a half million teachers in In-
the link between specific inputs such as teach- donesia’s 180,000 schools. To over-
ers’ salaries or textbooks and particular out- come this challenge, we recommend
puts such as better student test scores is not using some variation of a cascade
straightforward, and process functions can ei- model, in which the people who best
ther enhance or inhibit progress towards that understand the intervention (project
goal. The use of textbooks, for example, is designers) train others who then train
nearly as important as their availability; nor is teachers, which means that there can
the availability of particular teaching materials be as many as three or four layers of
as significant in raising learning achievement training in between the project team
as teachers having a say in which materials are and individual teachers. If anyone in
procured (Woessmann, 2001 and Pritchett and the chain does not fully understand the
Filmer, 1999). intervention or training methods, this
can result in poor performance further
down the chain. As a result, there are
few examples of improvements lasting

110
Chapter 3 Quality Assurance and Improvement

beyond the life of the project or of Whether the expense is borne by parents or by
good practices spreading spontane- the public is a matter for policymakers. Sec-
ously to other schools.43 ond, schools must receive funds based, at least
in part, on a transparent, per-student formula
x Schools are asymmetrical in their abil- that factors in enrollment or attendance rates
ity to implement quality improvement. as recommended in Chapter 2 on financing
Also, school performance can deterio- and in the EFA Summary Report.
rate as well as improve under decen-
tralization. Therefore, we recommend Third, schools must receive their share of sec-
taking into account the performance of tor development money in cash rather than in
schools relative to national standards kind, either through an earmarking or pro-
and to their own past performance posal-based budgeting process. In terms of
when formulating school or district sustainable improvements, schools must have
budgets and education development some discretion to choose the quality im-
plans. One such approach, an adapta- provement interventions that they are willing
tion of the “balanced scorecard” is and able to implement. This will require that
presented in Appendix 3. 2. they have a supply of proven quality im-
provement packages from which to choose,
Conclusion and Summary of cadres of competent providers of quality im-
Recommendations provement services, and a flexible system for
determining the relative ability of each school
We conclude that the reason why the quality to implement independent planning and block
of education overall has not improved in re- grant financing.
cent years lies deep within the sector’s struc-
tural and financing systems and that quality Finally, we recommend that the effort to en-
must be addressed by changing the sector’s sure education quality be seen holistically as
organizational structure, financing, and opera- an enterprise consisting of both assurance and
tional systems. improvement functions linked by a common
set of simple standards and measures.
Some of the required changes in the area of
sector finance are not under the sole control of
the MoNE. To improve quality, Indonesia
must first spend more and spend wisely.

43
Several projects have experimented with this system in
reverse, with school-based interventions shared among
clusters of several local schools, which are also shared
with local government school supervisors and so forth up
the chain of command via workshops. Occasionally, as
with the CBSA, this leads to an adjustment in national
policy and the innovation becoming an established part
of the education sector.

111
Education Sector Review Volume 2

References For Chapter 3

Asian Development Bank (ADB). 2003. Sta- Fasli Jalal and Bachrudin Musthafa. 2001.
tistical Tables compiled for Review of the “Education Reform in the Context of Decen-
Madrasah System. Jakarta, Unpublished. tralization.” Ministry of National Education
(MoNE), the National Development Planning
Asian Development Bank (ADB). 2000. Staff Agency, and the World Bank.
Appraisal Report on the Decentralized Basic
Education Project. Ford, Daryl. 2003. “Choosing a good school
for you,” Jakarta Post, 27 April.
Aziz, Drs. H. Abdul. 2002. “Madrasah Educa-
tion in Indonesia: Potential, Problems, and Is- Galiani and Schargrodsky. 2001. “Evaluating
sues.” Symposium on Madrasah Education in the Impact of Education on School Quality.”
the Context of a National Education System. http://www.utdt.edu/departamentos/empresaria
Jakarta, Indonesia. 4 November 2002. l/cif/pdfs-wp/wpcif-072001.pdf.

Berita Indonesia. 2003. “Four Government Government of Indonesia. 2003. RPP Standar
Regulations on Education will be Finalized Nasional Pendidikan, draft 29, October 2003.
Before 2004,” Newspaper article posted on the
Internet. In Indonesian. Hijmans, Frank. 2003. “Unit for Facilitation
of Education Decentralization” descriptive
Bond, Linda. 1996. “Norm and Criterion- synopsis. Word processed: Jakarta.
referenced Testing.” Retrieved October 2003.
http://www.mcg.net/Articles/norm/htm Hong, Yao. 1997. “What Investments Raise
School Outcomes: Improving School Quality
Bush, Kenneth, and Diana Salterelli. 2000. or Increasing School Quantity?” Unpublished
The Two Faces of Education in Ethnic Con- manuscript.
flict: Towards a Peacebuilding Education for
Children. Florence, Italy: UNICEF/Innocenti Jones, Gavin. 2001. “Education, Equity, and
Research Centre. Exuberant Expectation: Reflections on South-
East Asia.” FEA Working Paper.
Education for All. 2002a. “Situational Analy- http://www.cassey.com/fea2000-1.pdf.
sis.” Ministry of National Education (MoNE),
Photocopy of draft chapter on quality. Kellaghan, Thomas and Vincent Greaney.
2001. “Using Assessment to Improve the
Education for All. 2002b. “Education for Quality of Education.” IIEP Unesco. Paris.
All.” Ministry of National Education (MoNE),
Photocopy of draft main report. Kim, Gwang-Jo. 2001. “Education Policies
and Reform in South Korea.” Paper prepared
Education for All. 2003. “Per Pupil Costs of as part of a World Bank consultancy for Mau-
Achieving Each EFA Dakar Commitment” ritius.
Handout at EFA costing presentation.
King, E. and B. Ozler. 1998. “What’s Decen-
Educational Psychology Interactive. 1996. tralization Got to Do with Learning? The
“Measurement and Evaluation: Criterion- Case of Nicaragua’s School Autonomy Re-
Versus Norm Referenced Testing.” forms.” Paper presented at the Annual Meet-
http://chiron.valdosta.edu/whuitt/col/measeval/ ing of the American Educational Research
crnmref.html Association held in San Diego, CA referenced
in World Bank 2003.
Faiqoh, Dra. Hj. 2002. “The Development of
Pondok Pesantrens as a Means of Commu- Leithwood, K. and L. Earl. 2000. “Educa-
nity-based Education and Poverty Allevia- tional Accountability Effects: An International
tion.” Symposium on Madrasah Education in Perspective,” Peabody Journal of Education,
the Context of a National Education System. 75(4) 1-18.
Jakarta, Indonesia. 4 November 2002.

112
Chapter 3 Quality Assurance and Improvement

Leithwood, K. and T. Menzies. 1998. “Forms MoNE. 2000. Guidelines for Evaluating
and Effect of School-based Management: A School Performance (Junior and Senior Sec-
Review.” Educational Policy summarized in ondary). In Indonesian. Directorate of Pri-
World Bank, 2003. mary and Secondary Education. Jakarta.

Malen, B., R. Ogawa, and J. Kranz. 1990. Monitoring and Evaluation Team, Ministry of
“What Do We Know about School-Based National Education. 2002. Executive Sum-
Management? A Case Study of the Literature- mary. “Project to Raise the Quality of Junior
A Call for Research,” in W.H. Clune and J. F. Secondary Schools.” In Indonesian.
Witte (eds.) Choice and Control in American
Education, Volume 2: The practice of Choice, O’Meas, Mavis. 2003. Notes from presenta-
Decentralization, and School Restructuring. tion at national conference on obligatory func-
London: Falmer Press. Cited in Governance tions and minimum service standards. Jakarta.
Reform.
Pradhan, Menno. 2001. “Welfare Analysis
McMahon, Walter W. 2003. “Financing and with a Proxy Consumption Measure, Evidence
Achieving Education for All Goals.” Paper from a Repeated Experiment in Indonesia,”
distributed at presentation. Indonesia. Working paper, Free University, Amsterdam.

Moegiadi. 1976. Indonesia: Quality of Basic Pritchett, Lant and Deon Filmer. 1999. What
Education. Jakarta: Balitbang Dikbud. education production functions really show: a
positive theory of education expenditures.
MoNE. 2003a. “The Strategic Planning of Economics of Education Review 18 (1999)
The Development of Education, Youth, and 223-239.
Sport, 2002-2004.” Limited Draft.
Republic of Indonesia. 2003. Rencana Pem-
MoNE. 2003b. “Quality Assurance Institute: bangunan Tahunan (REPETA) Tahun 2004,
Organization, Administration, Tasks, Func- 2003, 2002, 2001, 2000. Jakarta: Annual De-
tions, and Task Management.” Pamphlet in velopment Plans for 2000-2004. In Indone-
Indonesian. sian.

MoNE. 2002a. Proyek Peningkatan Mutu Se- Republic of Indonesia. 2003. National Educa-
kolah Lanjutan Tingkat Pertama: Ringkasan tion System Law.
Eksekutif. Jakarta: Project Report.
SAGRIC. 2004. Summary Repot on District
MoNE. 2002b. “The Existence of Madrasahs, Consultation. June 2004.
Diniyah Education, and Pesantren in the Na-
tional Education System.” Policy Paper. Office Said, S. and N. Suhendra. 2002. “Corruption
of Educational Research and Development, and Indonesian Society,” in R. Holloway (ed.),
Jakarta. Stealing From The Poor. Book One, Jakarta:
Aksara Foundation.
MoNE. 2001a. National Report on the Devel-
opment of Education, Country: Indonesia. Ya- SAPS team for JBIC. 2002. “Final Report on
karta. Special Assistance for Project Sustainability
the Junior Secondary School Building Con-
MoNE. 2001b. “Pedoman Penyusunan Standar struction Project in Indonesia.” Project Re-
Pelayanan Minimal Penyelenggaraan Perseko- port.
hahan Bidang Pendidikan Dasar dan Menen-
gah” Keputusal Mendiknas 053/U/2001, April Soedijarto, M.A. 2003. Kebijakan Nasional
19. Tentang Akreditasi Sekolah. MONE Policy
Paper.
MoNE. 2001c. “Toward Quality and Equity in
Basic Education: Report of the National Somerset, Tony. 1994. “Some Basic Number
Commission on Education.” In Indonesian. Skills in Twelve Primary Schools: An Ex-
ploratory Study.” Processed.

113
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Suryadi, A. 1989. Improving the Educational UNESCO, UNICEF, MoNE. No date. “Creat-
Quality of Primary Schools. Jakarta: Balitbang ing Learning Communities for Children: Im-
Dikbud. proving Primary Schools through School-
based Management and Community Participa-
Sweeting, Elizabeth. 2001. “Booklet for Ka- tion” Pamphlet. Jakarta.
bupaten Education Planners.” Background
paper prepared for the MoNE and World Bank World Bank. 2003. Decentralization and
as part of the Basic Education IV Project De- SBM Resource Kit.
velopment. Unpublished draft. Jakarta.
World Bank. 2001a. “Social Assessment Pilot
Umaedi. 1999. “School-based Quality Im- Activity Basic Education IV.” Draft report.
provement Management.” In Indonesian. Jakarta.
MoNE (Ministry of National Education).
World Bank. 2001b. “Early Childhood and
USAID. 2003. “Managing Basic Education Early Grades Education” Draft report, Jakarta.
Project Initial District Surveys Phase 1 Dis-
tricts.” Project report. World Bank. 1996. Background Paper to
Textbook Project. Mimeographed.

Woessmann, Ludger. 2001. Schooling Re-


sources, Educational Institutions, and Student
Performance: The International Evidence.
Kiel, Germany: Kiel Institute of World Eco-
nomics.

114
Chapter 3 Quality Assurance and Improvement

Appendix 3.1. Quality Improvement Projects In Indonesia Since 1990

In Indonesia during the 1990s, the government The project provided teacher training in sci-
and donors spent hundreds of millions of dol- ence, mathematics, Indonesian, English and
lars on over 25 projects to improve the quality social studies, helped districts to initiate clus-
of primary and junior secondary education. ter-based training for teachers, provided fund-
Various lessons can be learned from these pro- ing for science equipment, and helped to
jects, and these are summarized below. develop a national test item bank and provin-
cial-level teams to improve the testing of stu-
dents.
SPP-CBSA/ALPS
Active Learning through Professional Support
to Teachers (1979-1994). UK Government Management capacity was strengthened by
through Balitbang. conducting studies to establish EMIS to help
the MoNE with school data collection and
Areas: One district each in West Java, NTB, management training workshops.
North Sumatra, South Sulawesi, East Java,
Lampung, South Kalimantan, Central Java, Follow-up projects include the JSE and the
South Sumatra, and Jakarta. BEPs.

The purpose of the SPP-CBSA was to enhance COPLANER


the quality of teaching and learning in primary Community Participation in Planning and
schools by promoting active learning and a Management of Educational Resources (1991-
professional development system based on 1995). UNDP/UNESCO. Through the MoNE
teachers’ working groups. The design used a and BAPPENAS.
bottom-up approach that viewed teachers as
the main stakeholders of change. The design Areas: East Java, South Sumatra, North Su-
recognized that teachers do not work in isola- lawesi, and NTT (24 kecamatan total)
tion from: (i) how they were trained, (ii) the
curriculum that they teach, (iii) the financial The objective of COPLANER was to improve
and administrative conditions under which the quality and increase the relevance of edu-
they work, and (iv) the support that they re- cation by piloting a model of community sup-
ceive from principals, supervisors, parents, port for and participation in bottom-up
and the local educational administration. education planning and school resources man-
agement within a supportive structure at the
sub-district (kecamatan) level. COPLANER
SSEM was built upon a prior UNDP/UNESCO/GoI
Second Secondary Education and Manage- project that had the same objectives but was
ment Project (1990-1997) World Bank through implemented only at the province and district
the MoNE’s Division of Junior Secondary levels. COPLANNER was an exploratory pro-
Education. ject to discover how to do bottom-up planning
at the school, community, and sub-district lev-
Areas: National but most activities focused in els.
West Java, Yogyakarta, Central Kalimantan,
South Sulawesi, and NTB. Follow-up projects have included the REDIP
and the CLCC, which have both used kecama-
The objectives of the SSEM were to improve tan-level community participation in planning.
the quality of secondary education and to
strengthen management capacity in secondary PEQIP
schools. Primary Education Quality Improvement Pro-
ject (1992-1999). World Bank through the
MoNE’s Division of Primary Education.

115
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Areas: Aceh, West Sumatra, Yogyakarta, and Activities included giving fellowships in cur-
Bali NTT riculum development and teacher training as
well as providing some facilities and equip-
The project’s objectives were to improve the ment for the MoNE’s national-level curricu-
quality of primary education through improved lum center.
teaching and learning activities, to increase
districts’ capacity to manage a quality im- The follow-up consists of the SJSE in the five
provement program, and to provide special as- provinces considered to be most in need.
sistance to poor, remote, and under-served
schools through block grants. The PEQIP had
SEQIP
too many sub-components and relied too much
Science Education Quality Improvement Pro-
on the cascade model for teacher training. The
ject (1994-ongoing). Germany through the
legacy of the PEQIP is the school cluster ap-
MoNE’s Division of Primary Education.
proach.
Areas: Jakarta, Central Java, East Java, South
No follow-up projects.
Kalimantan, NTB, South Sulawesi, and West
Papua
PGSD
Primary School Teacher Development Pro- The SEQIP’s purpose is to improve the quality
gram (1992-1999). World Bank through the of science teaching in primary school grades 3
MoNE’s Division of Higher Education. and 6. This is being accomplished through a
package of inputs that addresses all factors af-
Areas: Nationwide through teacher training fecting classroom activities simultaneously.
colleges The logic is that sustainability at the classroom
level is ensured by a package approach. The
The project’s objective was to enhance the package includes: in-service training for se-
teaching/learning process in primary schools lected teachers in active learning methods, in
through a new higher education teacher di- lesson planning, and in using a SEQIP science
ploma course (D2) for both pre-service and in- kit; training for principals and school supervi-
service training. sors so they can support the teachers, science
kits for teachers and students, and a system for
The new pre-service primary teacher education kit maintenance; teachers’ guides on how to
curriculum for D2 is used by all teacher train- use the kits in lessons and guidelines on using
ing colleges. new pupil textbooks; improved end of term
test items to match the new emphasis in sci-
ence teaching; and a project monitoring sys-
JSEP tem.
Junior Secondary Education Project (1993-
1998). Asian Development Bank through the
MDLCC
MoNE’s Division of Junior Secondary Educa-
Managing the Delivery of Local Content Cur-
tion.
riculum (1995-1997). UNDP through the
MoNE’s Division of Junior Secondary Educa-
Area: Nationwide but emphasizing un-served
tion.
and under-served areas and disadvantaged ur-
ban areas in Sumatra and Java.
Areas: Lampung
The project’s goals were to support the gov-
The purpose of the project was to develop
ernment in the delivery of compulsory educa-
policies and strategies to enable junior secon-
tion by improving academic supervision and
dary schools to attract and retain pupils and to
student assessment processes, implementing
develop links between post-primary education
Curriculum 1994, and strengthening the insti-
and income-generating opportunities.
tutional capacity of the MoNE and the MoRA.
Project activities included designing and refin-
ing management for local content delivery and

116
Chapter 3 Quality Assurance and Improvement

producing case studies on difficulties encoun- CJ-JSE


tered in delivering local content to primary Central Java Junior Secondary Education
levels. Project (1996-2002). World Bank through the
MoNE’s Division of Junior Secondary Educa-
tion.
PJSE
Private Junior Secondary Education Project
Area: Three districts in Central Java and all
(1995-2001). Asian Development Bank
districts in Yogyakarta
through private junior secondary schools.
All of the World-Bank-financed JSE projects
Areas: Lampung, Jakarta, South Kalimantan,
had the same objectives: to expand access to
and South Sulawesi.
junior secondary education in a cost-effective
and equitable way; to improve the quality of
B&R junior secondary education; and to strengthen
Book and Reading Development Project management capacity at the school level. For
(1996-2001). World Bank through Sarana. each JSE project, priorities and needs were de-
fined at the provincial level along with the in-
Area: National stitutional capacity to implement chosen
interventions. All stakeholders at the prov-
The objectives of the project were to improve ince, district, parent association, school, and
the quality of education by improving the pro- foundation levels (for private schools) were
duction and distribution of textbooks and by involved in developing project proposals
helping teachers to use textbooks in a more ef- within each province.
fective way.
Access was expanded through a school con-
The project’s activities included supplying struction and furnishing component, the hiring
textbooks to all junior secondary schools in all of contract teachers for remote areas, expand-
EBTANAS subjects and teachers’ guides in ing the open junior secondary program by
non-examined subjects; establishing the Na- supplying books and reference materials and
tional Textbook Evaluation Commission in the by covering its operating costs, and the provi-
Book Center to evaluate the quality of private sion of scholarships to needy students. Qual-
junior secondary books; holding workshops on ity was improved through in-service training at
writing textbooks for publishers: producing the district level, cluster-level teacher support
guidebooks for teachers; and developing a groups, and the supply of teaching materials
media campaign to promote reading. and libraries to rural schools. Training was
provided to province- and district-level staff
PGSM on managing information systems to enable
Secondary School Teacher Development Pro- them to analyze trends and identify problems.
ject (1996-2001). World Bank through the At the school level, training was provided in
MoNE’s Division of Higher Education. school-based management and professional
support to teachers.
Area: National
The economic crisis and mid-term review
The project’s objectives were to strengthen caused resources to be redirected to scholar-
pre- and in-service teacher education and the ships and school grants.
links between teacher training colleges and
secondary schools. S-JSE
Sumatra Junior Secondary Education Project
The project’s activities included improving the (1996-2002). World Bank through the
curriculum, procuring science equipment, de- MoNE’s Division of Junior Secondary Educa-
veloping textbooks, establishing student sup- tion.
port centers, and providing scholarships to
needy teachers to upgrade to S1. Area: Aceh, West Sumatra, Jambi, Lampung,
and South Sumatra

117
Education Sector Review Volume 2

EI JSE quality improvement activities focused on the


Eastern Islands Junior Secondary Education subject knowledge and teaching skills in core
Project (1996-2002). World Bank through the non-religious subjects of madrasah teachers
MoNE’s Division of Junior Secondary Educa- and introduced a six-month certification proc-
tion. ess and in-service program through cluster-
based training. Equitable access was increased
Area: East Java and NTT by rehabilitating schools and funding scholar-
ships for the poor, particularly girls. MoRA
COSEP management was strengthened at all levels.
Community Participation for Strategic Educa- School accreditation, management, and super-
tion Planning for School Improvement (1997- vision were improved by the production and
ongoing). JICA through the MoNE’s Division provision of training and manuals. The MoRA
of Junior Secondary Education. also used a model approach in which selected
schools were upgraded to provide model ma-
Areas: North Sulawesi and Central Java drasahs that demonstrated good teaching prac-
tices and good school management.
The objective of this project is to improve the Upgrading involved the rehabilitation of
quality of education by strengthening bottom- schools and the provision of materials such as
up planning skills and processes to promote libraries, laboratories, and extra classrooms.
community participation and school-based
management. CCP
Curriculum Capacity Project (1998-2000).
Activities include holding planning meetings UK through Balitbang.
and facilitator workshops, establishing an edu-
cation planning committee in each participat- Area: Central MoNE and Jakarta
ing kecamatan, holding workshops on local-
level quality improvement planning, and de- The objective of the CCP was to develop staff
veloping kecamatan basic education im- capacity in the MoNE to manage, develop, and
provement plans. evaluate the curriculum.

BEP (MORA) Activities included short training courses, both


Basic Education Project – Ministry of Reli- in-country and overseas, research and field
gious Affairs. Asian Development Bank studies to improve the curricula in core sub-
(1997-2002). jects, and the development and implementa-
tion of a curriculum evaluation and
Areas: West Java, Central Java, East Java, development cycle.
Lampung, NTB, and South Kalimantan
SJSE
The objective was to upgrade the quality of all Second Junior Secondary Education Project
madrasahs serving primary and junior secon- (1997-2003). Asian Development Bank
dary students to provide better education, par- through the MoNE’s Division of Junior Sec-
ticularly to girls and the poor. This was the ondary Education.
first donor project to focus solely on ma-
drasahs. Previously only about 10 percent of Areas: East Kalimantan, South Kalimantan,
donor resources were channeled to madrasahs and Central Sulawesi
through MoNE projects.
The objectives of the SJSE were to increase
This project had three components: improving junior high school enrollment, to upgrade gen-
quality, promoting equitable access, and insti- eral junior high schools and madrasahs, and to
tutional strengthening. The project was de- build institutional capacity.
signed to help the madrasahs adjust to their
new task. Up until 1994, madrasah education Activities included strengthening school man-
had focused solely on religion. After 1994, agement and supervision by providing block
many madrasahs used both the MoNE curricu- grants (BOMM) to 1,000 junior secondary
lum and the MoRA curriculum. The project’s schools, providing in-service training to teach-

118
Chapter 3 Quality Assurance and Improvement

ers and administrators, and enhancing re- BEP II


sources such as libraries, science laboratories, Sumatera Basic Education Program (1999-
textbooks, and teaching materials. The project 2004). World Bank through the MoNE’s Di-
also trained district and provincial managers to rectorate of Primary and Secondary Education
monitor the provision of junior secondary edu- Areas: North Sumatra, Riau, and Bengkulu
cation.
The objectives and activities of the BEP II are
WJBEP the same as for the BEP I as described above.
West Java Basic Education Project (1998-
2003). World Bank through the MoNE’s Di- BEP III
rectorate of Primary and Secondary Educa- South Sulawesi and Eastern Islands Basic
tion. Education Program (1999-2004). World Bank
through the MoNE’s Directorate of Primary
Areas: Selected sub-districts within all districts and Secondary Education.

The goals of the project were to improve the Areas: South Sulawesi and Maluku
quality of primary education, to expand access
to the JSE in poor and remote areas, and to The objectives and activities of the BEP III are
strengthen planning and management of the the same as for the BEP I as described above.
education system at all levels. The project was
the first to focus on decentralization and im- REDIP
plementation to the district level with support Regional Educational Development and Im-
from the province. Primary-level quality im- provement Project (1999-2001). JICA
provement activities focused on rehabilitation, through Balitbang.
school consolidation, and teacher re-
deployment; training for teachers, principals, Areas: Central Java and North Sulawesi
supervisors, and community leaders; the pro- (seven districts, 15 sub-districts in the pilot
vision of books, teaching aids, and materials; phase)
scholarships for poor students; and fellowships
to upgrade teachers’ credentials. The objectives of this project are to improve
the quality of junior secondary education by
Activities to improve quality in junior secon- building the capacity of local education ad-
dary schools included school construction us- ministration and schools and by increasing
ing a community-managed approach, contract community awareness of and participation in
teachers, in-service training for teachers, prin- education.
cipals, supervisors and community leaders,
and the provision of books and scholarships to The project’s activities included two compo-
poor children. nents: (i) the development of the capacity of
sub-district committees and (ii) a choice of one
Management was strengthened at the district from five school-level interventions such as
and province level through school mapping, cluster-based training, textbooks, block grants,
the integration of all ministries’ activities in and parent council development. The school
basic education, an assessment of staff capac- grants that were introduced under the REDIP
ity, and administrative retraining of staff at the are managed at the kecamatan level and are
district and province level to enable them to the same for all schools in the kecamatan. The
manage the project. sub-district committee plans all kecamatan-
level activities and writes and costs proposals
DPAP for funding with the help of project consult-
Development Planning Assistance Project ants. The committee then provides technical
(1998-2001). Policy Studies. CIDA through assistance to the grantees to support the im-
BAPPENAS. plementation of grants.

CLCC
Creating Learning Communities for Children
(1999-ongoing). UNESCO/UNICEF through

119
Education Sector Review Volume 2

the MoNE’s Directorate of Primary and Sec- the MoNE’s Directorate of Primary and Sec-
ondary Education ondary Education.

Areas: Central Java, East Java, and South Su- Areas: NTB and Bali
lawesi
The objectives of the DBEP are to create a
The objective of the CLCC is to develop mod- model for increasing equitable access to nine
els to improve the quality of primary schools years of basic education for all children by
through active teaching and learning as well as making proposal-based grants to schools for
school-based management and community rehabilitation and quality improvement, mak-
participation. ing grants to districts for education develop-
ment and improvement, and creating a unit
Activities include providing models for child- within the MoNE to track the impact of decen-
friendly schools, assessing school-based tralization on school quality and on the provi-
training trainers in active learning, providing sion of education services at the district level.
packages of training, grants, and other inputs
to participating schools, and conducting a
community mobilization media campaign to
raise awareness of the importance of educating
children.

DBEP
Decentralized Basic Education Project (2003-
ongoing). Asian Development Bank through

120
Chapter 3 Quality Assurance and Improvement

Appendix 3.2. A Quality Management Model


The balanced scorecard is a concept that helps the language arts portion of future examina-
managers at all levels to monitor results in tions.
their key areas of responsibility. An article by
Robert Kaplan and David Norton entitled "The The Balanced Scorecard
Balanced Scorecard - Measures that Drive Per-
Standards should be set and measured in di-
formance" in the Harvard Business Review in
1992 sparked interest in the method and led to mensions that capture the values and priorities
of the education system. For example:
their business best selling book, The Balanced
Scorecard: Translating Strategy into Action,
published in 1996. Since that time, many x Finance: Including the human, mate-
businesses, school districts, and schools in the rial, and financial resources that are
United States, Australia, and England have provided to schools (and districts), the
adapted this method for quality management. flow of provisions/funds from the
Basically, the balanced scorecard is a method point of origin to schools, and public
of designing, organizing, and communicating accountability for expenditures.
performance measures across three to five di- x Basic Rights: Minimum conditions of
mensions utilizing both short- and long-term learning to which every child has the
time horizons. right such as safe and healthy school
buildings and certified and trained
For each dimension, there are a set of mini- teachers.
mum service standards and associated key per- x Stakeholder Satisfaction: Student
formance measures that include both “lead” achievement, parental satisfaction with
and “lag” indicators. In brief, “lag” indicators the results of their children’s school-
describe what has been accomplished so far. ing, and the accomplishment of district
For example, students’ scores on Indonesian and national goals and targets.
language tests are a lag indicator. “Lead” in- x Governance and Management: Proc-
dicators predict future performance. For ex- esses for making policies/regulations/
ample, time spent by students on reading rules, transparency in decisionmaking,
improvement programs such as “sustained si- accountability for decisions, and
lent reading” or “writing across the curricu- community participation.
lum” is a predictor of their improved scores on

121
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Table 1 Indicative Indictors for Education System Balanced Scorecard


Finance Basic Rights: Stakeholder Satisfaction: Governance and Man-
agement:
Lag indi- Lead Indica- Lag Lead Indica- Lag indica- Lead Indica- Lag indi- Lead Indica-
cators tors indicators tors tors tors cators tors
District (ser- % APBD Proportion Numbers Number of Numbers of Number of Timely Number of
vice man- actually of school fi- of class- community out-of- community delivery public ac-
agement) spent on nance pro- rooms in- based school school chil- forums to of goods count-ability
non-salary vided by stead of rehabilitation dren discuss edu- and ser- forums
education funds repair efforts cation con- vices to
cerns schools
District
Proportion Proportion Number of Student per- Number of Leakage education
of schools of unquali- teachers par- formance on “good prac- of funds service
receiving fied teach- ticipating in standardized tices” and intended structure
minimum ers teacher train- tests local innova- for edu- appropriate
per student ing programs tions identi- cation for current
costs fied units functions

Perform- Numbers of Teachers Appropriate


ance-based schools ac- Proportion paid on payroll and
budget for credited of un- time and teacher
district edu- accredited in the management
cation ser- schools with correct system
vice. school im- amount
provement
plans

School (ser- Proportion Integrated Minimum Plans for Student Numbers of School Attendance
vice provi- of school school conditions school im- achievement teachers par- rules en- records by
sion) finance budget of learning provement to on tests of ticipating in forced teachers and
provided met MCL basic skills teacher train- students
by funds ing

Minimum School- Teachers


per stu- based quality and stu-
dent costs improvement dents
received program provided
on time such as with
and in full “writing needed
amount across the materials
curriculum” and sup-
or remedial plies on
program for time
failing stu-
dents

Standards and the Balanced Scorecard


Minimum service standards and associated ment. The targets can be set nationally or ne-
“lag” indicators can be set for each of the four gotiated with districts.
dimensions by the national level. The districts
and/or education units themselves should set For each dimension, districts or schools can
the “lead” indicators linked to the “lag” indica- then be positioned along a continuum based on
tors. Each dimension should have no more their performance on the key “lag” indicators.
than three standards each with one or two key This is the basic concept behind Indonesia’s
“lag” performance indicators. The service current school accreditation and district moni-
standards, indicators, and measures should be toring programs
standardized and set by the national govern-
.

122
Chapter 3 Quality Assurance and Improvement

Figure 1 The Balanced Scorecard Continuum

Below Standard Above Standard

Minimum Service Standard

By adding a second dimension for perform- and getting better, good and getting worse, bad
ance on lead indicators, each school or district and getting better, and bad and getting worse.
can be described using the grid in Figure 2. Different interventions can then be determined
Their performance can be reported and veri- for each category of district or education unit,
fied as part of each funding cycle. Taken to- which illustrates how the entire education sys-
gether, the two dimensions yield four tem has moved further away from the supply-
categories of districts or education units: good driven, one-response-for-all model.

123
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Figure 2 Using the Balanced Scorecard

Better than last performance evaluation

BAD SCHOOLS/DISTRICTS GETTING GOOD SCHOOLS/DISTRICTS GETTING


BETTER BETTER

x Look for innovation and best x Block grant financing


practices x Most resourcing through funds
x Eligible for increased funding (rather than materials or in-kind
through block grants services)
x Recognize achievement in public x Eligible for special grants to be-
forums come “service providers”

Below Standard Above Standard

Minimum Service Standard

BAD SCHOOLS/DISTRICTS GETTING GOOD SCHOOLS/DISTRICTS GETTING


WORSE WORSE

x Close attention from higher au- x Very common in newly decentralized


thority systems
x Earmarked funds x Examine regulatory framework to re-
x Intensive capacity building move policies that may be inhibiting per-
x At risk of losing accreditation formance (e.g. financing formula)
x Site visit to determine cause for per-
formance drop and collaborate on
remediation

Worse than last performance evaluation

124
Chapter 3 Quality Assurance and Improvement

Appendix 3.3. A Case Study Of Project-Based School


Rehabilitation

Table 1 Number of Classrooms Needing Rehabilitation 2000/2001


Light Moderate Heavy Total
Type and Level of school Num % Num % Num % Num %
Primary Level
PS public and private 377,198 41.6 316,915 35 212,280 23.4 906,393 100
MI public 6,005 59 2,752 27 1,430 14 10,187 100
MI private 56,348 48.4 38,365 33 21,675 18.6 116,388 100
Total Primary Level 439,551 358,032 235,385 1,032,968
JS Level
JS public and private 157,753 87.5 16,415 9.1 6,118 3.4 180,286 100
MTs public 9,360 73.6 2,221 17.5 1,135 8.9 12,716 100
MTs private 28,183 60.8 12,902 27.8 5,280 11.4 46,365 100
Total JS Level 195,296 31,538 12,533 239,367
Source: ADB MESA report (ADB, 2003).

Primary schools in Indonesia are not in good Kerusuhan) spent a portion of Rp 241.23 bil-
condition. According to an inventory of assets lion on rebuilding and rehabilitating class-
conducted by the MoNE in 2000, more than rooms. Several donor-financed projects have
half of all public general school classrooms also included a classroom rehabilitation com-
(530,000) were in fair or bad condition, and ponent since 2000 (see Table 2).
about 14 percent of the junior secondary class-
rooms (22,600) needed moderate or heavy re- Taken together these massive efforts have re-
pairs (see Table 1). habilitated about 30 percent of the classrooms
that needed the heaviest repairs or about 13
The government responded to the findings of percent of the classrooms that needed heavy or
the 2000 survey with a two-pronged strategy, moderate repairs. According to figures pro-
which, according to the Education for All draft vided by the government and donors, 82 per-
costing tables, aims to complete the rehabilita- cent of the junior secondary classrooms that
tion of classrooms by 2015 through a series of needed moderate to heavy rehabilitation were
projects. In 2001, Rp 3.55 trillion44 was spent repaired. The huge repair bill is due primary
on the school rehabilitation component of the to two factors  sub-standard construction
Bantuan Khusus Sekolah (BKS) program, and no routine maintenance. Future repair
which also expended a considerable sum on bills can be lowered somewhat by including
scholarships. In addition, the centrally funded maintenance costs in the formula for calculat-
Imbal Swadaya program provided Rp 267 bil- ing a school’s operating budget. Indeed, if
lion in 2003 for both new school construction minimum maintenance is not carried out, the
and classroom rehabilitation (Rp 30,000 in 75 classrooms will require massive rehabilitation
percent matching grants to 8,900 schools). about every 10 years. Sub-standard construc-
Also in 2003, a significant DAK transfer (Rp tion is due in part to a lack of competent con-
625 billion) was made specifically for school struction engineers and construction workers
rehabilitation. In addition, a centrally funded and to corruption in various forms, such as
program aimed at remote and conflict areas contractors billing for materials that meet con-
(Daerah Tertinggal Bencana Alam dan struction specifications but substituting infe-
rior materials on site.

44
Rp1.144 trillion from the oil subsidy money was
used in 2001, with another Rp 2.41 trillion coming
from other sources in 2003.

125
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Table 2 Classrooms Rehabilitated by Government and Donors, 2000-2003


Primary Classrooms Rehabili- Junior Secondary Classrooms
Donor/Project tated Rehabilitated
GoI Projects
BKS (2001,2003) 32,000 18,000
Imbal Swadaya (2003) 8,900 8,900
Pemberdayaan Di Daerah 6,220 2,775
Tertinggal (2001,2002,2003)
ADB
MoRA (1996-2002) 1,210 920
RNG
SIGP I (2001, 2002) 8,865 1,250
SIGP II( (2002) 8,000 1,200
World Bank
Basic I, II, III 12,000
JSE (1998-2003) 3,340
TOTALS 77,195 36,385
Sources: ADB Project Completion Report BDP Project, BKS implementation Unit, Ibdal Swadaya Implementation
Unit, SIGP Implementation Unit, JSE Implementation Unit, Basic I, II, and III monitoring reports, JBIC Evaluation Re-
port, MoNE Proyek Pemberdayaan Pendidikan, Didaerah Tertinggal, Benchana Alam dan Rerusuhan Jakarta year end
summary reports.
Note: This assumes two primary and two JSS classrooms per school.

Transition from Projects to Program competence to sustain and propagate the inno-
vations have cost more than Indonesian politi-
The advent of the new planning period pre- cians have been willing to spend. Projects still
sents policymakers with a historically unique have a vital role to play in trying out new
opportunity to change the country’s quality
ideas for improving teaching, for pilot testing
improvement strategy from the current series
school quality management models on a small
of discrete and disconnected projects into a
scale, for determining the management and
cogent and comprehensive quality manage-
technical capacity required to implement par-
ment program that integrates quality control ticular quality control approaches, and for in-
and quality improvement into the routine op- creasing the supply of quality improvement
erations of schools and districts.
service providers. The projects approach is
simply not up to the job of improving the qual-
Quality improvement projects have accom-
ity of this enormous and varied education sys-
plished a great deal in a few areas, but the unit tem overall.
costs and the need for high levels of technical

126
Chapter 4: Teacher Management System
Teachers are the most important asset in Indo- creasing the qualifications and technical ca-
nesia’s education system, both because they pacities of teachers and head teachers as a way
are the primary determinant of school per- of increasing the professionalism and improv-
formance and because their salaries consume ing the welfare of teachers, enabling them to
most of the public spending on education. In implement a new curriculum that aims to
this chapter, we argue that a new paradigm for make students more creative and to make
teacher management is necessary to ensure teaching more efficient and effective.” In or-
that Indonesia derives maximum value from der to “achieve the education goals, these
its teachers in terms of the academic achieve- strategies are to be supported by evaluation
ments of their students while adhering to the mechanisms that will function as a quality
principles and legal requirements of decen- control system and by increased supervision of
tralization. schools and accountability for school perform-
ance.” In 2003, the MoNE began working in
The Indonesian debate about teachers, teach- collaboration with line agencies (such as the
ing, and teacher management predates decen- MoHA, the MoF, the BAKN, and the MoRA)
tralization by at least three decades and many to develop a clear regulatory framework for
of the teacher management concerns discussed teacher management, including assigning re-
in this chapter are not new, nor do they all sponsibilities for hiring teachers as civil ser-
arise directly from the post-decentralization vants or as contract teachers.
forms of education governance, management,
and financing discussed in previous chapters. We believe that the regulatory framework,
Some persistent issues that need to be resolved standards, and monitoring systems currently
in the era of decentralization include teachers’ being developed by the MoNE, though ambi-
remuneration, incentives, career structure and tious, do not go far enough. This chapter iden-
promotion, their recruitment and deployment, tifies several key teacher management issues
their education and competence, their career and recommends three systemic actions that
development and in-service training, and their need to be taken: (i) setting teacher profes-
empowerment in the context of school-based sional standards and performance monitoring
management. Indeed, the empowerment of criteria that are based on their classroom and
schools and district governments under decen- school performance; (ii) developing a new
tralization provides a welcome opportunity to paradigm of career-long teacher professional
revisit long-standing issues and to examine development that is school-based and class-
how introducing a new paradigm into teacher room performance-led and (iii) de-linking the
management can contribute to improving management of teachers and their conditions
teaching and school performance. of employment from the civil service and cre-
ating a teaching service that reflects the needs
Since decentralization went into effect in of the educational system and the development
2000, the MoNE has been employing a two- of teaching as a profession. The aim of these
part strategy for improving the quality of recommendations is to encourage the devel-
teachers and teaching. The first part sets stan- opment of a professional teaching force that is
dards for teachers and head teachers and de- consistent with school-based management and
velops quality assurance monitoring systems; improves school performance, and students’
the second part builds the capacity of provin- learning outcomes.
cial institutions and district governments to
carry out their new roles relating to teacher This paper draws heavily on the work of sev-
management. This approach was described in eral teacher policy reform groups that existed
the Government of Indonesia’s Strategic Plan from 1999 onwards. The proposals from these
for Education 2002-2004 and relies on “in groups are reflected in the National Commis-

127
Education Sector Review Volume 2

sion on Education’s 2001 report called “Edu- Finally, we propose some policies and strate-
cation Reform in the Context of Regional gies and outline the kind of timeframe that is
Autonomy: The Case of Indonesia” and in the likely to be required to implement the pro-
Government of Indonesia’s Strategic Plan for posed policies.
Education 2002-2004. The analysis of teacher
management issues in this chapter uses the The Changing Context of Teacher
principles of decentralization and school- Management in Indonesia
based management systems to review progress
to date, to identify areas of concern, and to At the time of the decentralization reform, dis-
propose some possible ways forward. It dis- trict governments inherited a school system
cusses the information, incentives, and ac- that operated according to centrally deter-
countability systems relating to teachers that mined rules governing the employment and
will be needed to support decentralized man- deployment of teachers, the curriculum, teach-
agement systems and the goals to improve ers’ education, school inspections, teachers’
school quality. performance, and information systems. The
system was designed and structured in such a
The analysis in this chapter is based on: (i) a way that districts and provinces fed education-
review of Indonesia’s laws, regulations, policy related information upwards to the central
documents, implementation guidelines, project government (without receiving any informa-
reports, statistics, and media surveys; (ii) an tion in return. In turn, the central government
international literature review; (iii) interviews made all decisions pertaining to the procure-
with key stakeholders and focus group re- ment and distribution of all education inputs
search in Jakarta, Bandung, Makassar, and such as school buildings, books, teachers, and
Bandar Lampung (with additional focus in-service training.
groups to be conducted in three rural districts
by the end of November); and, (iv) a forum However, the situation was more complex
held by the Government of Indonesia and its than this summary might indicate. For exam-
development partners and feedback on early ple, public primary schools (sekolah dasar)
drafts of this chapter from experts in Indonesia were managed by the MoHA at the district
with extensive knowledge and field experience level; specifically, the local government was
of the education system. The chapter reviews responsible for the 3Ms (manpower, money,
proposed strategies, current practices and rele- and materials) for primary schools, while the
vant international experience to construct a ca- curriculum and quality issues were managed
reer-long teacher development and by the MoNE representative at the district or
management framework. Some elements of province level. On the other hand, the MoNE
this framework are already being discussed by managed public secondary schools. Public
the MoNE and various districts, while others schools in the madrasah system were, and
represent a major departure from the current continue to be, centrally managed by the
and proposed teacher management systems. MoRA. Public teachers were, and still are,
civil servants (pegawai negri) who taught and
The chapter is organized in the following way. still teach in public, madrasah, and private
First we look at some key characteristics of schools. In addition, there were contract
schools and teachers in the changing context teachers (mostly employed through central
in Indonesia. Second, we review the main projects financed by donors and “voluntary”
changes in teacher management arising from teachers who were paid an honorarium (guru
decentralization and education laws, stake- honor) from the parents’ contribution to their
holders’ perceptions of these changes, and the children’s school or through the school’s
initiatives being taken by district governments. foundation (yayasan). Contract teachers
Third, we discuss the main issues related to mostly taught in public schools, while volun-
teacher management in Indonesia and look at tary teachers could be found in both public
some lessons from international experience. and private schools.

128
Chapter 4 Teacher Management System

Then, as now, there is a wide variation among cruiting teachers to remote schools, and to de-
districts in their capacity to meet national tar- velop school support systems to meet the
gets and to provide a supportive environment needs of small schools in isolated areas or
for teachers and for schools. Variations in conflict plagued environments. Districts in
population density, financial resources, admin- these situations may not have enough techni-
istrative capabilities, and progress in meeting cal and financial resources to meet the needs
the national education goal (nine years basic of large numbers of remote schools, although
education for all) make it impossible for cen- the districts within any given province often
tral policymakers to develop an effective one- vary considerably in the amount of resources
size-fits-all formula for teacher development that they have available to provide incentives
and management. For example, some districts to teachers (according to provincial economic
are experiencing periodic civil disturbances data from The MoNE’s Research and Devel-
(these include not only Aceh but also districts opment Center (Balitbang). On the other
in Central Sulawesi, Maluku, and parts of hand, in other parts of the country, there are
Papua), thus making it difficult for them to large urban districts where land is scarce and
employ and retain teachers. In other districts, past policies created multiple primary schools
where most of the population lives in accessi- on a single site, each with its own administra-
ble areas, it is relatively easy to provide tive system. Most of these local governments
enough schools, to staff them adequately, and are now streamlining these schools into a sin-
to give teachers regular professional support. gle institution and teacher management sys-
However, many districts have low population tem, thus reducing the numbers of head
densities and limited infrastructure, which teachers, administrative staff, and specialist
makes the task of teacher deployment much teachers as well as rationalizing the use of
more difficult.45 various physical resources.

Decentralization provides an opportunity for Some districts are beginning to reorganize


each district to create a teacher management their teacher management systems to align
and development system that meets its unique them with the newly decentralized decision
needs, but few districts have the financial or making structure by adopting information sys-
technical capacity to do so. For example, in tems that are more open to the public by in-
the province of East Kalimantan, some dis- volving local communities in education
tricts are able to equip their schools and to decision making, and by setting staffing and
provide teachers with financial incentives and performance targets that are appropriate to
access to professional support systems even in their particular circumstances. Now that they
remote areas, but other districts do not have have greater control over their budgetary re-
the same level of local resources to draw upon. sources, district governments are becoming
There are many rural, remote districts such as more aware of inefficiencies that were inher-
those in the eastern islands and in mountain- ent in many previous policies. For example,
ous environments such as in Papua, Java, Ka- in the past, primary schools were expected to
limantan, and Sulawesi that have difficult employ a minimum of nine teachers regardless
decisions to make about how best to spend of the number of students that were enrolled,
scarce resources, to provide incentives for re- while in junior secondary schools, teachers
were often employed to teach only one subject
regardless of the school’s size and need.
45
Some districts are already distributing and us-
Although four provinces have population densi- ing teachers more efficiently in their schools.
ties between 500 to 1000 people per square kilome-
ter, more than half of the provinces have Indonesia is not alone in struggling with
population densities of fewer than 100 people per
square kilometer. The extremes are Papua with five
teacher management issues under
people and DKI Jakarta with 12,645 people per decentralization. A group of education
square kilometer. planners in several Latin American countries
assessed the impact of different policies to

129
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Box 4.1 Cost-effective Strategies for Raising Academic Achievement

A group of education planners from a number of Latin American countries examined the cost-effectiveness
of about 40 policy interventions that aimed to raise students’ academic achievement. The group measured the
cost-effectiveness of the interventions according to the estimated impact of the intervention on academic
achievement (as measured by a standardized test of mathematics and reading at the primary grade 6 level),
the probability of the intervention being properly implemented, and the estimated cost of implementing the
intervention. Of the 40 policy interventions examined, the top five most cost- effective interventions were
(starting with the best): (i) assigning the best teachers to the first grade, (ii) enforcing the official length of
the school year, (iii) not switching classroom teachers during the school year, (iv) testing 10 percent of grade
4 students annually and distributing the results to teachers, and (v) decentralizing school management. The
first three of these interventions are not very costly but greatly increase teachers’ productivity and school per-
formance.

The group found that four policy interventions had the greatest possible impact on improving school quality
and learning achievement. These were (starting with the most effective): (i) providing teaching and learning
materials and training teachers to use them, (ii) providing self-directed learning materials to teachers without
any accompanying teacher training, (iii) providing a package of interventions to at-risk schools including
self-learning materials, training in active and cooperative learning, hands-on workshops on modern teaching
methods community involvement in school decisionmaking, school-based management, formative evaluation
of the intervention package, and systematic testing and feedback, of student learning, and (iv) paying teach-
ers higher salaries to work in rural areas and assigning the best teachers to the first grade of primary school.
All of these interventions have costs attached, and the probability of them being fully implemented is lower
than the chance that the five most cost-effective interventions above will be implemented.

Source: Schieflebein et al, 1998.

impact of different policies to improve school tricts to produce some school-age population
quality that the governments of these countries projections (say, for 10-15 years ahead) and
had introduced over time (Schieflebein et al, then to match these to projections of primary
1998). The education planners ranked the im- school enrollment rates and to the qualifica-
pact of these policies on student achievement, tions and age group profiles of the existing
taking into account the cost and degree of dif- population of certified teachers.
ficulty of introducing each innovation. Sev-
eral of these have implications for teacher The decentralization legislation clearly allo-
management. The results of this exercise are cates the responsibility for teacher manage-
summarized in Box 4.1. ment to the districts. Given the vast range of
different types of schools and of varying dis-
One of the key challenges in teacher manage- trict capacities, the national and provincial
ment is estimating the number of teachers that governments will have to continue to play an
will be needed in the future. Districts may important role in teacher management and de-
require financial and technical assistance from velopment in the medium term. For example,
higher levels of government so that they can the provincial quality assurance institute de-
build their capacity to gather information scribed in Chapter 3 on quality can help dis-
about the supply of and demand for teachers in tricts to build their capacity to monitor
the future. The demographic shift caused by teachers’ performance so that this monitoring
declining birthrates and rising primary and system can contribute to the lifelong profes-
junior secondary school enrollments implies sional development of teachers and head
that there is likely to be a decrease in the de- teachers.
mand for primary school teachers and an in-
crease in the need for secondary school
teachers in the future. The central and provin-
cial governments might consider helping dis-

130
Chapter 4 Teacher Management System

Allocation of Teacher Management Changes in Teacher Management


Functions Systems as a Result of Decentralization
When teacher management systems are chang- The implementation of the decentralization
ing, this can be a good opportunity to imple- laws is changing how civil servants, including
ment new ways to achieve education goals. teachers, are managed. At the time when de-
However, during the period of transition there centralization was introduced, large numbers
can sometimes be tensions and opportunistic of civil servants who up until then had been
behavior at the school and district levels in the employed by central line agencies, such as the
appointment, deployment, and promotion of former Department of Education and Culture,
teachers. Because of the magnitude of the were reassigned to district and provincial edu-
changes that have been taking place since cation units along with budget allocations to
2001, there is likely to be a certain amount of cover their salaries. A freeze and budgetary
confusion and upheaval as local governments ceiling on civil service recruitment (including
redefine their roles and relationships, debate public teachers) have been in place ever
how best to allocate and manage resources, since.47 The government has begun to intro-
and learn to become more democratic and ac- duce civil service reforms in line with the de-
countable to civil society. We look at some of centralization of governance and management
these changes in this sub-section through the structures, including revisions to salary scales.
lenses of the regulations that govern the man- It is also reviewing some teacher management
agement of teachers, the perceptions of stake- systems, especially those relating to perform-
holders, and the experiences of district ance standards and recruitment and deploy-
governments. ment. Because of ambiguities in the
decentralization law and regulations regarding
In a decentralized teacher management sys- the assignment of some key teacher manage-
tem, the main role of the central government ment functions, there is still some overlap and
should ideally be to develop a national teach- duplication between the districts and those
ing service that sets minimum teaching stan- agencies who were previously responsible for
dards and minimum salary scales and develops carrying out those functions in the pre-
guidelines for promotions and incentives. The decentralization era.
provincial education units would be responsi-
ble for ensuring that districts were able to The implementation of the school-based man-
meet their statutory obligations for providing agement of education and the creation of dis-
basic education of a sufficiently high quality.46 trict education boards is changing the nature of
They would also be equipped to advise dis- teachers’ accountability and their incentives to
tricts on school improvement and teacher de- perform well. These changes mean that the
velopment and to ensure that teachers could be decisions about a school’s resources and goals
deployed across districts if and when required. are made by those who know are in the best
District governments would be responsible for position to understand the circumstances that
the employment and deployment of teachers prevail at that school, which is a highly desir-
and for the payment of their base salary (the able outcome. However, they also put a heav-
national minimum) and any additional benefits ier burden on teachers, school principals,
and incentives, for monitoring teacher per- school committees, and parents to work to-
formance, and for ensuring that teachers had gether to assess the school’s performance and
regular access to professional development to achieve better student learning outcomes.
programs linked to their school activities. A number of projects are currently helping

46 47
This proposal should be vigorously debated as it However, the recruitment of contract teachers is
does not conform to the principles of decentraliza- a special case. This is discussed later in the chap-
tion in Indonesia. ter.

131
Education Sector Review Volume 2

teachers, head teachers, and school supervisors benefits and incentives. While the districts
to develop the necessary capacity to meet the have the option to dismiss contract teachers48
requirements of school-based management or not to renew their contracts, it is still not
and to improve school performance. District clear whether or not district governments can
education managers are receiving technical reduce the teaching force by dismissing some
support and training under ongoing MoNE civil service teachers, as they might want to do
projects (such as the DBEP, the BSE, the JSE, if they were to rationalize their teacher/student
and the Unit Facilitasi in areas of school map- ratios or to adjust to lower enrollment due to a
ping), teacher deployment, and quality im- declining school-age population. Currently,
provement planning to help them to fulfill many teachers are under the impression that
their new obligatory functions. However, they cannot apply for vacancies in a different
there are over 420 district governments in In- district, but this may be because districts want
donesia with very different capacities, and not to retain the civil servants whom they already
all of these activities are taking place in all employ. Nor are there any good mechanisms
districts, which means that progress is very by which schools and districts can advertise
uneven. teaching vacancies beyond district boundaries
to recruit those teachers who may be best
Responsibility for the Employment and suited to that particular school.
Deployment of Teachers
Although district governments are responsible
Under the decentralization laws, the district for hiring teachers and paying their salaries,
government is responsible for employing all some ambiguities remain in the system. For
public school teachers except those in ma- example, madrasah teachers who are civil ser-
drasah schools. This includes all the civil ser- vants are still managed by the MoRA which,
vice teachers (pegawai negeri) in public and unlike the MoNE, has not been decentralized.
private schools (mostly secondary schools) Districts, through the MoHA, have always
who were previously hired and paid for by the been responsible for deploying teachers, but
central government. Wages for public teach- with the establishment of school committees
ers are transferred to the districts’ budgets and education boards, schools and districts
(APBD) as part of their block grant (DAU) may take on a bigger role in selecting and ap-
from the central government. There are also pointing teachers, especially head teachers.49
districts that have hired contract teachers District governments are bound by the central
(guru kontrak) as part of projects funded by government’s zero recruitment policies for the
loans made by donors to the central govern- civil service, which have been implemented
ment. The salaries of these teachers do not over the past few years. This applies as much
appear in the district budget but are funded by to teachers as to other civil servants. For ex-
these MoNE-managed projects through the ample, if a district government wishes to hire
DIP mechanism. The status of these contract any additional teachers, the district must pay
teachers will be reviewed when these donor- for them from their own resources. The Min-
funded projects end, although attempts by do- istry of Finance will not grant districts any in-
nors to design an exit strategy have been pre-
empted by the central government’s decision
to recruit an additional 190,000 contract
teachers, which it is no longer supposed to do.
48
Contract teachers are not civil servants. They are
The salary levels and promotional and reward contracted to the MoNE for a period of three years
systems for civil servants are still set centrally, at fixed rates.
49
although many districts provide teachers Three districts in Flores, with the support of
within their jurisdiction with supplementary AusAID, are piloting just such community partici-
pation in determining selection criteria for teachers
and head teachers and in participating in the selec-
tion of teachers and head teachers.

132
Chapter 4 Teacher Management System

creases in their budget allocations to recruit Responsibility for Teachers’ Professional


additional civil servants (see Chapter 2). Development and Career Development
Responsibility for Setting and Monitoring Initial teacher preparation remains the function
of universities and teacher training institutes
Teacher Performance Standards
that are accredited by the MoNE’s Directorate
As discussed in Chapter 3 on quality, the of Higher Education. This applies also to pro-
MoNE is developing minimum service stan- grams for upgrading teachers’ qualifications
dards for districts’ obligatory functions and and to further education courses for teachers.
education standards for schools through sev- There are ongoing discussions about how to
eral different parallel processes. Associated make both the universities and the accrediting
with these activities (or independently of them board more autonomous and how to make the
in some cases), different units of the MoNE process of accreditation more demanding and
are developing performance standards that will competitive so that teacher education pro-
affect teachers. grams in universities will become more re-
sponsive to the needs of schools (the service
The Directorate of Higher Education has de- providers) and district governments (the em-
veloped standards that trainee teachers must ployers). Where the responsibility rests for the
meet to be allowed to graduate from the DII continuing professional development of teach-
teacher education program (a two-year post- ers is more ambiguous. Most school-based
secondary school teaching diploma needed to and cluster-based professional development
teach in primary schools) and is expecting to activities carried out in Indonesia (for which it
continue this exercise for the other teacher has a well-earned reputation) were supported
preparation programs under its accreditation in the past by projects funded by donors or by
control (such as the DIII, which is a three-year the MoNE. Now districts are responsible for
diploma required to teach in junior secondary providing in-service training and professional
schools, and S1 or undergraduate degree). support activities, but few have the resources
These graduating standards apply to the ac- or the motivation to do so. Provincial teacher
creditation of teacher education programs and training centers (Balai Pelatihan Guru and
define in some detail what an Indonesian Pusat Peninkatan dan Pelatihan Guru) are de-
graduate teacher should know and be able to concentrated branches of the MoNE and, as
do. Complementary to this, the Directorate of such, are expected to provide both quality as-
Education Personnel is preparing teacher surance and in-service teacher education sup-
competency standards for serving teachers to port to districts.
be used in assessing their performance and
identifying their professional development The ways in which the lifelong education of
needs. teachers relates to their career, promotion, and
incentive structures have not been clearly ar-
It is expected that these competency standards ticulated in the past. This needs to be ad-
will be used by quality assurance institutes in dressed, especially in the context of decen-
the provinces acting on behalf of the MoNE. tralization. We will look at these issues in
The role of these quality assurance institutes is more detail later in the chapter.
still being developed, and, as yet, no clear
guidelines have been developed for their Table 4.1 summarizes the changes in teacher
monitoring activities, but it is likely that these management functions for public general
will be based on criteria related to the obliga- schools (not madrasahs) resulting from decen-
tory functions and minimum service standards tralization.
that are also being developed.

133
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Table 4.1 Teacher Management Functions for Public Schools (except Madrasahs)
after Decentralization
Decisionmaker Decisionmaking Process
Management function Pre-decentralization Post-decentralization
Teacher employment, deployment Public teachers: By local govern-
x Selection Public teachers: By central ment under national civil service
x Appointment authority deconcentrated to guidelines
x Deployment provincial government.
x Transfer Process governed by civil Contract teachers: Unchanged
x Promotion service regulations and uses
x Conditions of service (salary credit point system Permanent teachers: Unchanged
scales, incentive systems)
Contract teachers: Through Temporary teachers: Unchanged
x Dismissal/rehiring
centrally funded projects,
not subject to civil service
regulation

Permanent teachers: By
private foundations, not sub-
ject to civil service regula-
tion

Temporary teachers: By
schools, not subject to civil
service regulation
Teacher performance Primary Primary
x Standards setting Public Teachers: By the Public Teachers: By districts and
x Performance monitoring MoNe and monitored by dis- schools
x Sanctions and remediation trict circuit inspectors based
in sub-districts Contract Teachers: Unchanged

Contract Teachers: By cen- Permanent teachers: Unchanged


trally funded projects
Temporary teachers: Unchanged
Permanent teachers: By
foundations and foundation
inspectors

Temporary teachers: By
schools

134
Chapter 4 Teacher Management System

Decisionmaker Decisionmaking Process


Management function Pre-decentralization Post-decentralization
Junior secondary Public Junior secondary
Teachers: By the MoNE and Public Teachers: By districts
monitored by national circuit
inspectors working out of Contract Teachers: Unchanged
the provincial MoNE offices
Permanent teachers: Unchanged
Contract Teachers: By cen-
trally funded projects moni- Temporary teachers: Unchanged
tored by projects and by
circuit inspectors

Permanent teachers: By
foundation

Temporary teachers: By
school
Teacher professional development Public teachers: By centrally
x Initial preparation accredited teacher training Public Teachers: Unchanged
x Induction institutions, through public
x Continued professional develop- examinations, by individual Contract Teachers: Unchanged
ment opportunity through credit
system Permanent teachers: Unchanged

Contract teachers: By cen- Temporary teachers: Unchanged


trally accredited teacher
training institutions, through
public examinations, by in-
dividual opportunity through
project

Permanent teachers: By
school

Temporary teachers: By
school

held that brought all teachers, head teachers,


Stakeholder Perceptions of Teacher and supervisors together. The focus group fa-
Management cilitators then discussed the findings of all of
As part of the consultative processes of the the group sessions with a representative group
World Bank’s Education Sector Review, a of district managers. The district education
number of focus group meetings were held to officers in Bandar Lampung and in Makassar
learn about the experiences and perceptions of chose which teachers and head teachers would
key stakeholders regarding decentralization participate in the focus groups on the basis of
and its impact on teacher management issues. sampling criteria agreed between them and the
Two initial sets of meetings were held in Ban- ESR team. These teachers were representative
dar Lampung and in Makassar over the course of primary and junior secondary schools in the
of a week. Separate focus groups of teachers, public, private, and madrasah sectors and in-
head teachers, and school supervisors all dis- cluded both public servants and contract
cussed the characteristics of good teacher teachers as well as equal numbers of male and
management. In addition, one meeting was female teachers. The district managers were

135
Education Sector Review Volume 2

represented by local government personnel cess by the results of the students’ final
from the district parliament and education and examination and by how many children
planning offices (Dinas Pendidkan, Dinas are accepted by the secondary school of
Agama, Pemda, and Komisi A). their choice. Teachers who have bene-
fited from performance monitoring
Here are a few highlights to illustrate the pointed out that at least now this is done
views that emerged from the focus group ex- at the district level and not far away in
ercise: Jakarta, which they saw as an advantage.
On the other hand, the school supervi-
x Since decentralization, teaching vacan- sors, who were formerly accountable for
cies are advertised in the local media. school monitoring, felt that the district
These advertisements provide the public government was now taking over this re-
with information about the position and sponsibility, leaving them with less of a
location of the job and invite interested role in supervising schools and teachers.
teachers to apply. However, since de-
centralization, it has become more diffi- x Except for teachers in schools that are
cult for teachers to apply for transfers or part of ongoing projects (such as the
promotions out of their original districts. BSE, the JSE, and the DBEP) funded by
The teachers and head teachers in the fo- the national government, there are few
cus groups were concerned about this. resources or opportunities for teachers to
They also expressed considerable con- participate in any kind of professional
cern about the lack of transparency in- development programs (such as in-
volved in the appointment, transfer, and service training or workshops). Educa-
promotion of teachers under decentrali- tion managers themselves said that dis-
zation and about the high cost to indi- trict education budgets are not large
viduals arising from the ”fees” (bribes enough to fund teacher development ac-
and other payments to facilitate results) tivities on a regular basis.
that they have to pay to assist these
processes. In many cases, these pay- Further focus group meetings of education
ments (in cash or kind) are beyond the stakeholders are planned over the next few
means of teachers who might otherwise months in a wider range of districts, including
be eligible for a position. The teachers districts in rural and island areas and districts
claimed that this kind of rent seeking has with different levels of prosperity and with
become worse since decentralization. different population densities and numbers of
schools. As the first two sessions were held in
x Although this is not a specific impact of urban districts, it is planned to include rural
decentralization, teachers were con- and remote districts in the next round to get a
cerned about the infrequency of per- balanced perspective.
formance evaluations and the poor
quality of performance monitoring (by District-led Initiatives
head teachers or district school supervi-
Many districts are responding with enthusiasm
sors). They considered supervision to be
and initiative to their new responsibilities,
too focused on administrative aspects
which are giving them a much greater incen-
and not sufficiently on giving teachers
tive to examine the quality and efficiency of
feedback about their teaching methods.
the education provided within their bounda-
However, as the teachers also pointed
ries. Because resources are now allocated by
out, there are few opportunities for pro-
democratically elected district parliaments, the
motion or any other incentives for either
district planning office is taking a greater role
school managers or teachers to justify
in both preparing budget proposals and de-
more frequent performance evaluations.
fending the allocation of resources.
Parents tend to measure a teacher’s suc-

136
Chapter 4 Teacher Management System

These days, education initiatives often origi- instead are buying books and learning materi-
nate within district governments (in other als.
words, within the leadership of the Bupati
through the Bappeda to the Dinas units), espe- Need for a New Teacher Management
cially as they examine ways to use their re- Framework
sources more efficiently. Several districts have
been merging several small schools into one, Good governance and management require in-
redeploying school principals and teachers to formation, accountability, and incentives.
understaffed schools based on more efficient From the examples given above, it can be seen
student/teacher ratios, and are discussing the that districts and schools now have much
relative merits of civil service teachers and greater incentives to make use of information
contract teachers.50 that formerly was only passed up to the central
education authorities. For example, many dis-
In cases where schools have been merged and tricts are seeing that the analysis of these data
the number of school principal posts have de- can help them to use their resources more effi-
creased, there is a danger that tensions will ciently. Now that elected local governments
arise between those who lose out and those are making decisions about budget allocations
who retain their jobs. District governments and schools have a greater say in how they are
are finding ways to deal with these situations – managed, there is increasing evidence of both
for example, school principals who had previ- better planning and greater accountability to
ously been evaluated and had lost their jobs the community. However, the central gov-
due to poor performance as administrators ernment still has an important role to play in
have been asked to return to teaching. In advertising examples of good practice and in
some cases, natural attrition by retirement providing incentives and technical support to
solves the problem; in other cases, school district governments who wish to try out inno-
principals may have chosen to retire or to seek vative ideas and who need to develop the ca-
other work. School committees in some well- pacity to do so.
developed areas have been using their re-
sources to allow teachers to attend in-service Most of the key issues on the subject of
or other professional development programs teacher management are the same after decen-
(as is happening in several districts in East tralization as they were before. The relevant
Java under the UNESCO/UNICEF project). In question is how these issues have been altered
many cases, this builds on practices begun un- by decentralization and how to create an effec-
der such projects as the Junior Secondary tive teaching service within the context of
Education and Basic Education projects. autonomous district governments and of
school-based management systems. We pro-
Districts now are taking the initiative to focus pose a new teacher management framework
directly on teachers’ classroom behavior as a consisting of three teacher management sub-
way of improving school quality rather than systems: teachers’ employment and conditions
relying solely on physical inputs such as of service, teaching performance standards
school buildings. The teacher is seen as being and performance monitoring, and teachers’
central to this goal, and thus districts are put- professional development. These are dis-
ting a high priority on ensuring that they have cussed in the next three sections.
adequate skill levels. For example, some dis-
tricts have put a temporary embargo on fund- Transparent Employment Processes
ing physical infrastructure programs and and Conditions of Service
Advocates of decentralization contend that the
more that school managers and teachers can
50
Based on the pilot activities of the District Basic participate in making the decisions that affect
Education Project, Unit Facilitasi, the MoNE, and their schools, the more likely it will be that
the Basic Education Project. those decisions will meet the needs of their

137
Education Sector Review Volume 2

students. Similarly, if school managers (as teachers and 6.2 percent are sports teachers.
opposed to higher-level education authorities) Head teachers, religion teachers, and sports
can make the decisions regarding the hiring teachers rarely have a full teaching load, re-
and firing of teachers in their schools, then gardless of the size of the school where they
they will be able to build a strong teaching are employed. When the student/teacher ratio
force. Some of the burning questions being is calculated using class teachers only, the na-
considered at all levels of government revolve tional ratio is 32:1, which is still reasonably
around who determines the number of teachers low compared with countries at a similar level
that are required, who determines how much of economic development.
teachers should be paid and why, and what
elements should comprise their pay. We have As in primary schools, the national stu-
two policy recommendations: (i) establishing dent/teacher ratios for junior secondary
a transparent teacher appointment process schools are 16:1 in public schools and 10:1 in
based on efficient deployment norms, school madrasahs.51 Junior secondary school teachers
vacancies, advertisement, selection criteria, expect to teach only one subject52 and, no mat-
contractual arrangements, and public informa- ter how small the school, each school expects
tion and (ii) establishing a compensation and to have at least 18 teachers. The mean en-
rewards system that is clear, transparent, and rollment size of public junior secondary
guided by considerations of teachers’ qualifi- schools (SMP) is 358 students, and in reli-
cations, responsibilities, and motivations for gious junior secondary schools (madrasah
continuous development. Implementing these tsanawiyah), 182 students. At the primary
policies would require a dramatic shift from a school level, 93.4 percent of teachers are na-
focus on numbers of schools to numbers of tional civil servants. The remainder are volun-
students and from teachers’ credentials to tary teachers (guru honor) or teachers
classroom practices. employed by the school. Compared with pri-
mary school teachers, only 62 percent of jun-
Student-based Teacher Allocation ior secondary school teachers are permanent
Formula civil servants (who, like primary school teach-
ers, are employed by the district govern-
Indonesia uses a formula for teacher allocation ments), which means that a much higher share
and deployment that is based on the number of of these teachers are employed by the schools
schools not on the number of students. As a or as contract teachers than in primary
result, nationally, average class sizes and the schools.
ratio of students to teachers are both low at all
levels of education, although there are differ- The introduction of decentralization has cre-
ences among districts and between schools in ated an opportunity to link teacher manage-
rural areas and those in urban areas. Based on ment to local education priorities. Past
the total number of teachers in primary policies on teacher recruitment and deploy-
schools (including head teachers, religion ment are being revisited as local governments
teachers, sports teachers, and class teachers), try to balance their allocations of resources to
the national student/teacher ratio is 22:1 in the budget for teachers’ salaries and to the
public primary schools (sekolah dasar) and
14:1 in religious primary schools (madrasah
ibtidaiyah). These low ratios are not an effi- 51
The MoRA has pointed out that many teachers in
cient use of resources, especially when there madrasahs are part-time teachers, and it is not clear
are few resources available for other quality that this estimate is based on full-time teaching
inputs (such as textbooks, library books, equivalents. The Madrasah Education System As-
equipment, and in-service training for teach- sessment (MESA) team is investigating this fur-
ers). However, in public primary schools, ther.
52
only 68.4 percent of teachers are class teach- Also, in junior secondary schools, there may be
ers. Of the remainder, 12.9 percent are religion differences in the availability of teachers of differ-
ent subjects.

138
Chapter 4 Teacher Management System

budget for other quality inputs to schools. For students and total number of teachers to man-
many districts, the most difficult questions in- age). Planners might consider a sliding scale
volved in widening secondary school access so that smaller schools have more generous
and increasing efficiency at both the primary student/teacher ratios than larger schools. In
and secondary school levels are likely to be India, each community with 40 children is en-
about changing student/ teacher ratios (at the titled to one teacher per school, and schools
primary school level particularly) and recruit- are allowed one extra teacher with every 40
ing secondary school teachers who are quali- additional children enrolled.53 The principle
fied to teach more than one subject. behind a sliding scale is that small schools
where multi-grade teaching is the norm should
For example, at the primary school level, there have fewer students per class (and thus per
may be a justification for locating schools as teacher) than bigger schools where the teacher
close as possible to where children live. In only has to teach one grade level.
many districts, this would result in a large
number of small schools (sekolah kecil), espe- Teacher Surplus. Up until the 1990s, the
cially in the eastern islands, Papua, central Ka- struggle was to maintain parity between the
limantan, and other rural districts throughout supply of teachers and the growing numbers of
Indonesia. This would mean a policy change schools. At this juncture, however, it is neces-
in that teachers would have to be recruited on sary to re-examine the commonly held as-
the basis of a school’s enrollment rate rather sumption among policymakers that Indonesia
than its number of classes as is presently the suffers from a shortage of teachers. We con-
case. Small schools often require teachers tend that this assumption is false and that gaps
who are trained to teach multi-grade classes in coverage are due to inefficient teacher dis-
and need to be supported with learning materi- tribution rather than to a teacher shortage.
als that enable students to work in groups. This apparent teacher shortage is a result of
Therefore, there is likely to be a significant the allocation formula used to calculate the
need for incentive schemes and professional number of teachers required in each district.
support services to encourage teachers to ac- Indonesia’s annual population growth is 1.6
quire the necessary skills for teaching in small percent (compared with 1.1 percent in East
rural schools. Asia and the Pacific as a whole), and the birth
rate is falling. Of course, this does not mean
Many existing small junior secondary schools that there are no gaps in coverage in Indone-
could also be amalgamated to form more effi- sia, but the gaps in the primary sector are
cient units. If this is to happen, then junior problems of distribution rather than supply. In
secondary school teachers will need to be able many parts of the country, there are pockets of
to teach more than one subject, which has im- teacher shortages alongside pockets of sur-
plications for teacher training and teacher de- pluses. In one district in West Java, for exam-
velopment programs. ple, shortages range from an extreme of 173 in
an isolated rural school far from public trans-
We recommend that district planners consider
a new formula for calculating teacher re-
quirements. This formula should be based on 53
One proposal put forward in the past in Indone-
the number of students enrolled in a school sia (Somerset, 1997) laid out a sliding scale based
rather than the number of classes. In addition, on school enrollments for calculating the provision
all teachers (including sports and religion of teachers, which would be more efficient than the
teachers) should have a full teaching load and present formula. Small schools with fewer than
be included in the formula on that basis. Head 130 students would be eligible for one teacher for
teachers, especially in small schools, should every 30 children, larger schools with between 130
and 200 students would be eligible for one teacher
also be class teachers with amounts of non- for every 35 children enrolled, and schools with
teaching time to be calculated on the basis of over 200 students would be eligible for one teacher
the school’s size (that is, the total number of for every 40 children enrolled.

139
Education Sector Review Volume 2

portation and other services to only 9.4 in a throughout the country. There was no short-
small school in a peri-urban area near the dis- age of applicants – over 400,000 people ap-
trict’s center. This is not uncommon as will plied. Teachers will be contracted to the
be seen in the discussion below. In the past, central government for four years and will re-
the MoNE assumed that all primary schools ceive Rp. 460,000 as monthly base salary from
needed one teacher per grade level plus two the central government, with any additional
additional full-time teachers, one for physical benefits expected to be funded by the district
education and health and one for religion as governments.
well as a non-teaching head teacher. The
MoNE continued to use this formula in its re- The role of the central government in recruit-
cent recruitment drive for contract teachers. ing teachers has become a sore point for many
This formula substantially overestimates the districts, especially those that are themselves
number of teachers needed in schools, espe- in the process of rationalizing schools and re-
cially in small schools. For example, in one examining the formula by which teachers are
school in a district in Java with a stu- appointed to schools (Weston, 2003). These
dent/teacher ratio of 9:4, the average class new teacher appointments have been spread
consists of only 11 children, with 66 pupils across districts but are not based on actual
distributed among only six classes (Weston, need. Seven districts in Java and Sulawesi
2003). This school currently has seven teach- that do not have large shortages of teachers are
ers, but according to the MoNE’s teacher for- all due to receive between 300 and 800 con-
mula, the school still “needs” an additional tract teachers, and another district, which can
teacher, which would give it a student/teacher only be described as having a potential surplus
ratio of 8:3. If the formula is applied to all of teachers, is to receive 399 contract teachers.
schools in the district and all these teachers
were supplied, the student/teacher ratio for Donor-funded education projects are also sup-
that district would drop to about 13:1, which is porting the salaries of contract teachers. Un-
even lower than in the most developed coun- der project-related agreements between district
tries of the world. governments and donors, contract teachers
hired under these projects are supposed to be
With high enrollment rates and an already employed by the districts directly while the
plentiful supply of teachers, Indonesia is in a donors guarantee their salaries. However, the
position to rationalize and upgrade the teach- central government has by-passed these ar-
ing force at the primary school level. This rangements by going ahead and recruiting
would allow districts to channel more of their contract teachers directly and paying them
resources into quality inputs and to fund the from the national budget.
salaries of the additional teachers that will be
required at the secondary level, which is The district governments surveyed by Weston
where the education system will be expanding (2003) would like teachers to be selected and
in the future. employed at the district or even the school
level, with the central government having no
Centrally Recruited Teachers. Despite the de- power to select or employ teachers. This is
centralization of education management to the compatible with the intention of Indonesia’s
district level, the MoNE is still funding and decentralization laws and the purposes of the
managing the appointment of contract teachers general allocation funding to districts. A new
across the country. The MoNE is testing ap- system is needed for selecting, appointing, and
plicants, determining who can be employed, transferring teachers based on student/ teacher
issuing their contracts, and paying their sala- enrollment needs and other criteria related to
ries. The MoNE has recruited 190,000 con- the need for multi-grade teaching in small
tract teachers in 2003 to be deployed across all schools. Also, the rules governing the em-
levels of the school system, 20 percent of ployment, deployment, and transfer of teach-
whom are to be employed in private schools ers need to be sufficiently flexible to allow

140
Chapter 4 Teacher Management System

schools to hire teachers from outside their own cult” so that their teachers would be paid
districts and for teachers to be able to transfer more. If each district has the power to set top-
to other districts when appropriate. up allowances for its own schools in a trans-
parent way, then this would be an efficient
Performance-based Compensation and way to attract teachers to rural areas. Brazil
Rewards has tried such an approach, and the results are
included in Appendix 4.2 on relevant interna-
Designing teacher salaries and incentive struc- tional experience.
tures that attract the best and the brightest to
the teaching profession and retain them is a Policy decisions about teacher salaries also
complex enterprise. In Indonesia, low salaries need to be informed by research about the
are often seen as being an important contribut- most effective way to spend resources on edu-
ing factor to poor teacher performance, low cation inputs. Research on education expendi-
teacher morale, and the low quality of entrants ture allocations (Pritchett and Filmer, 1999)
into the teaching profession, but is this actu- has shown that the marginal benefits per dollar
ally so? Research from Indonesia indicates of inputs that are not associated with teachers’
that teacher salaries are not low compared salaries are commonly 10 to 100 times higher
with other professions and international re- than those of direct inputs to teachers’ welfare
search draws no correlation between teacher (that is, their salaries and incentives). This
salary increases and improvements in teaching implies that too much is generally spent on in-
performance. puts that provide direct benefits to educators
(like teachers’ wages) relative to the amount
We recommend that under decentralization, spent on other inputs that contribute directly to
teachers’ salary scales should have a national learning such as books or instructional materi-
base and then districts should be allowed to als.
top up salaries. This topping-up process
would need to be monitored by the central Recent research shows that most Indonesian
government to ensure that the DAU alloca- primary school teachers and junior secondary
tions to districts are made sufficiently pro- school teachers have earnings equivalent to or
poor so poorer districts can afford to add suf- higher than those of other workers with an
ficient financial incentives to retain teachers, equivalent level of education. Teachers with a
especially if many of these are posted to re- university degree (that is, mostly those who
mote schools. Care should be taken not to in- teach in senior secondary schools) may earn
crease teachers’ base salaries to unsustainable slightly less than other workers with an
levels. Where material incentives seem to be a equivalent level of education. However,
useful policy tool, it would be better to offer teachers earn more per hour than most other
bonuses to supplement teachers’ remuneration workers and have many more days off per
instead of altering their basic pay scales. Such year.
bonus systems could also be used to reward
teachers who take on extra responsibilities or An analysis of labor force data from 2000
duties, to attract better candidates to the teach- (Filmer, 2002) indicated that teachers with
ing profession, to encourage schools to im- qualifications below the diploma level (about
prove their performance, and/or to attract one-third of teachers) have monthly earnings
teachers to rural locations where there is a that are, on average, 22 percent higher than the
scarcity of applications for vacant teaching monthly earnings of other paid workers with
posts. Districts should be responsible for de- the same qualifications. The differential (in
termining appropriate allowances and top-ups terms of monthly salary) is smaller among
for those teachers who work in remote loca- those with a first or second level diploma and
tions or under difficult conditions. This should then becomes negative; in other words, the 10
not be done centrally because, if it were, then percent of teachers with a third level diploma
all schools would try to be classified as “diffi- and the 24 percent with a university degree

141
Education Sector Review Volume 2

earn 18 and 37 percent less respectively than schooling earn 61 percent more per hour,
other paid workers with the same levels of teachers with first and second level diplomas
education. earn 32 percent more, and those with third
level diplomas earn 5 percent more than other
Hourly earnings follow a different profile workers with the same levels of schooling.
since teachers tend to work fewer hours but However, among workers with a university
are typically paid more per hour than other degree, teachers earn 19 percent less than oth-
workers. Teachers consistently work fewer ers.
hours than other workers, regardless of their
level of education. Teachers in the study re- Hence, after controlling for individual charac-
ported working about 34 hours per week while teristics and the respondents’ region of resi-
other paid workers with similar levels of edu- dence, the study found that teachers earn 7.9
cation reported working between 43 and 46 percent less per month than other paid work-
hours per week (see Table 4.2). Not only do ers, but at the same time they earn 18.9 per-
teachers work a shorter week than other paid cent more per hour than other workers. See
workers, but they also have more holidays per Table 4.2 for a comparison of the hours
year. Thus, teachers with senior secondary worked by different types of teachers.
Balitbang of time spent on instructional tasks
The above-mentioned labor force study also indicate that teachers may spend only about
noted regional differences in teachers’ earn- half of their time in school actually teaching.
ings. For example, in West Sumatra, the study
found that teachers earn 7.3 percent less per Table 4.2 Average Number of Hours Worked per
month than teachers in West Java (controlling Week
for age, gender, urban residence, and educa- Not a Teacher
tional attainment). Other workers in West Su- Teacher
matra, however, earn 32.3 percent more than All workers (SAKERNAS 34.0 (8.5)
workers in West Java do. Other places where 2000) 44.7 (13.1)
the differentials are large are Riau (20.7 per- Public school teachers (IFLS
cent), South Sumatra (19.3 percent), DKI Ja- 2000)
karta (28.2 percent), and Central and South Primary schools -- 33.6 (7.4)
Kalimantan (24.3 and 35.3 percent). These
Junior secondary schools -- 24.1 (7.9)
are provinces where teachers earn substan-
tially less than other workers. The same Private school teachers (IFLS
places have large differentials in terms of 2000)
hourly earnings as well. Conversely, there are Primary schools -- 29.6 (10.3)
two provinces where teachers earn substan- Junior secondary schools -- 21.8 (9.8)
tially more per month than other workers –
Source: Filmer, 2002.
NTB (35.7 percent) and Central Sulawesi
Notes: Data derived from SAKERNAS 2000 and from the
(16.3 percent). In the case of hourly earnings, Indonesia Family Life Survey (IFLS) 2000.
two additional provinces make the list –
Yogyakarta (20.9 percent) and West Kaliman-
To compensate for this, managers need to be
tan (20.6 percent).
concerned about teachers’ productivity, and
teachers need to be aware of the statutory
Indonesian primary teachers have salaries that
numbers of hours of instruction and school
are comparable to those paid to other workers
days in a year that they are obligated to work.
but are lower than the salaries paid to teachers
School managers should be able to hold
in other countries. However, this is partially
schools and teachers accountable for their
offset by the fact that they have smaller
productivity. For example, it is common in
classes, although they may work longer hours
many secondary schools for students to attend
than teachers in other East Asian countries
(OECD, 2002). However, studies by the

142
Chapter 4 Teacher Management System

school only part-time in the last three weeks of money against their future earnings. The in-
the term and to spend the rest of that time on centive to meet these payments is, of course,
“home study” to prepare for the end-of-term the increased salary and benefits of the promo-
tests. After taking the test, the students might tion, but it also has to do with the increased
not be required to attend school for up to one opportunity to generate additional income
week while their teachers mark their test pa- from, for example, fees for after-school tuition
pers. In return, school managers should be and examinations and commissions on the sale
able to ensure that teachers are deployed effi- of textbooks and school uniforms. Any study
ciently so that no teacher is burdened with of teachers’ earnings and salaries should take
very large classes while others have small into account the high cost to teachers (and to
classes. District governments (and supporting the credibility of the whole education system)
institutions at the national level) need to con- of these kinds of “fees” and other rent-seeking
sider these points as they try to balance their activities.
expenditures on salaries with their expendi-
tures on other valuable and complementary Transparent teacher management systems
inputs to schools. need to be put in place, and mechanisms must
be developed to address grievances. Indonesia
The research findings reported in this section is not alone in recognizing the damage done to
raise questions about the relationship between the education system by poor teacher man-
teachers’ productivity and earnings. If the agement practices. Issues of transparency (in-
number of applicants for vacancies is anything formation, accountability, and incentives) and
to go by, the recent national recruiting exer- what rights teachers have to receive redress for
cise for contract teachers had a ratio of two their grievances about poor teacher manage-
applicants per vacancy, which seems to indi- ment processes are being faced by a number of
cate that teachers’ salaries are not a deterrent countries. At the UNESCO International
to applicants. Institute of Education Planning in Paris in
2002, meetings were held on the subject of
The Impact of Corrupt Practices on corruption in education in which several
Teachers and Teaching countries admitted to having this problem.
For example, in Mexico, the high cost to
What Indonesian teachers earn and what
society of corruption was estimated to be
wages the teachers actually receive are not al-
around 15 percent of GNP. In Ghana and
ways the same. The ESR focus groups in
Nigeria, corruption abounds in school admis-
2003 found that teachers face high transaction
sions, the payment of teachers’ salaries, and
costs in the form of bribes during the process
the leak of examination questions to students.
of, for example, being employed, transferred,
In South Africa and Pakistan, public resources
promoted, or selected for in-service training.
were being diverted to fictitious schools,
A recent small survey of 70 schools with 130
teachers, and pupils as a result of poor data
teachers in eight provinces (Keluarga Sekolah
monitoring and mis-reporting.
Indonesia, 2003) indicated that 80 percent of
teachers do not receive the full amount of their
Hong Kong has been addressing corruption in
pay and that 30 percent or more of their pay is
society in general. It established an anti-
unofficially deducted by the education office
corruption commission in 1973, which has a
or by their school principals beforehand.
sub-committee on education that deals, in par-
ticular with inappropriate allocations of funds
In some cases, teachers seeking to be pro-
and with teachers’ inadequate professional
moted to a head teacher position have had to
practices. Table 4.3 summarizes some of the
pay the equivalent of six to twelve months of
main ways in which corrupt practices in
their salary to the education officials responsi-
teacher management affect quality, equity, and
ble for appointments in order to win the post.
ethical standards in the education sector.
Many teachers use their savings or borrow this

143
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Table 4.3 The Impact of Corrupt Practices within the Education Sector
Corrupt practices/ opportuni- Elements of education systems
Area of management involved ties for corrupt practices most affected
Recruitment, promotion, and ap- x Irregular recruitment and Quality
pointment of teachers (including unjustified allocations
systems of incentives) x Unjustified promotions
x Training and scholarship
allocation by criteria
based on passing
x Payment of salaries and
allocations to ghost teach-
ers
x Ignoring posting and
transfer criteria for teach-
ers
(arising from favoritism, nepo-
tism, bribes and pay-offs,
by-passing criteria)
Conduct of teachers x Teaching hours paid for as Access
opposed to the number Quality
really delivered Equity
x Ghost teachers Ethics
x Bribes and pay-offs (for
school entrance, for the
assessment of children,
etc)
x Use of fees requested from
pupils
Allocation of specific allowances x Favoritism Access
(compensatory measures, fellow- x Nepotism Equity
ships, subsidies to the private sec- x Bribes and pay-offs
tor etc) x By-passing criteria
Examinations and diplomas x Selling information Equity
x Favoritism Ethics
x Nepotism
x Bribes and pay-offs
x Academic fraud
Supply and distribution of equip- x Closed processes in public Equity
ment, food, and textbooks tendering
x Embezzlement
x By-passing criteria
Building of schools x Closed processes in public Access
tendering Equity
x Embezzlement
x School mapping
Source: Hallak and Poisson, 2002 (adapted).

144
Chapter 4 Teacher Management System

Box 4.2 Permanent or Contract Teachers?

Ibu Guru [the teacher’s real name has been changed] has been a primary school teacher for nine years. She
trained as a religion teacher. She was locally hired and is employed and paid directly by the school. Her
monthly pay is Rp. 100,000 and she teaches grade 1. She uses up-to-date pedagogic approaches and
achieves excellent results with her students. Her outstanding performance as a teacher came to the atten-
tion of education managers, and she was recruited to train teachers in other districts and provinces.

Most madrasahs and many primary and junior secondary schools rely on locally hired teachers who may be
paid in the range of Rp. 50,000– Rp. 125, 000 per month compared to the Rp. 500,000 and more per month
paid to teachers who are civil servants.

District managers (from 30 districts in 10 provinces) have acknowledged their reliance on locally hired
teachers and on the professionalism of many of these teachers. However, they have pointed out that, when
these teachers become members of the civil service, their performance often deteriorates.

The managers expressed the view that hiring new teachers on limited-term contracts would place them on a
similar basis to many private sector employees. Under-performing teachers could be more easily made re-
dundant – good teachers need never fear redundancy. It would also mean that teachers could be placed in
schools as and when they are needed and the level of their wages tied to working in a particular school.

Source: Weston, 2003.

Teacher Motivation and Incentives We recommend the creation of a teaching ser-


What motivates teachers to enter and remain vice that links the licensing of teachers, their
in the profession is not solely related to their professional rights and obligations, their con-
salary levels. Other aspects of professional ditions of employment, and their career incen-
life matter as well, including recognition from tives and promotional paths to the needs of
the local community and from their peers, op- schools and classrooms. Under the new sys-
portunities to share their experiences and to tem, teachers’ unions and associations would
learn from others, access to continuous profes- protect teachers’ rights and thus empower the
sional development, and pride in their stu- members of this hitherto powerless profession.
dents’ achievements (see Box 4.2 below).
It is important to preserve a flexible teaching
force and a national teacher labor market as
De-linking Teachers from the Civil much as possible. This would require putting
Service mechanisms in place to allow teachers to ap-
ply for vacancies in any district and for
The majority of school teachers are civil ser- schools to have a say in the selection of their
vants. However, a civil service exists to con- teachers. Districts need to be able to meet
trol and operate a bureaucracy, and it can be supply and demand in more flexible ways than
argued that school teaching is not a bureau- is currently possible. The functioning of the
cratic activity. The teachers’ unions and other teacher labor market may well need a certain
professional associations are already discuss- degree of central direction and management
ing how best to establish a separate teaching (in the form of standards and licensing) to en-
service. The benefits of having such a service sure that it stays national, but the responsibil-
would be that it would better meet the profes- ity for allocating teachers to vacant posts in
sional needs of teachers by developing spe- schools can be decentralized. This would be
cific criteria for teachers’ professional career the best of both worlds. There should be a na-
development and reward systems rather than tional pay scale or salary grading system based
using administrative criteria as happens now. on pre-set minimum pay levels, with districts
and schools having the option, as discussed

145
Education Sector Review Volume 2

above, to provide their teachers with supple- School-oriented Performance Standards


mentary benefits and allowances according to and Monitoring
criteria determined at the district or school
level. The minimum pay scales and condi- When schools perform well, it is due to a
tions of service should emerge from a collec- combination of effective teaching and of
tive bargaining process between the national strong professional leadership by the school
government and teachers’ unions and profes- principal. Under decentralization, school
sional associations. Through such a process, a committees and district governments expect to
better balance could be struck between na- hold schools and teachers accountable for
tional and district priorities and the needs of learning outcomes, but the way in which
teachers than is currently the case. school performance is currently measured is
not always based on the most value-added in-
The Indonesian Teachers’ Association (Per- puts, as became clear from the focus group
satuan Guru Republik Indonesia or PGRI) discussions discussed above.
represents the vast majority of teachers in In-
donesia (1.4 million) and is naturally protec- Teaching is a complex operation. As summa-
tive of its members. Since decentralization, it rized by Brophy and Everston (1976), effec-
is learning (with the support of the ILO) to act tive teaching requires the ability to implement
in the interests of its members. The national a very large number of diagnostic, instruc-
teachers’ association now has greater freedom tional, managerial, and therapeutic skills, with
to act as a labor union with collective bargain- teachers having to tailor their behavior in spe-
ing rights. Most teachers would probably re- cific situations to the needs of the moment
gard salary increases as a higher priority than while still performing effectively in the class-
other professional issues such as performance room. Indonesia’s current standards for
monitoring or access to in-service training. evaluating teachers rely heavily on their cre-
The PGRI was founded on November 25, dentials and years of experience, even though
1945 and for several decades was a New Or- research has demonstrated that having a more
der organization representing teachers as civil educated and experienced teacher does not
servants and Golkar party members rather than necessarily lead students to learn more or bet-
a trade union. Newly founded independent ter (Woessmann, 2001). However, research
teachers’ unions cannot compete in size or has also shown that what teachers know and
match the PGRI’s infrastructure, which it are able to do does improve the academic per-
holds from its pre-trade union existence (for formance of their students. For example, re-
example, 17 out of 29 PGRI provincial com- searchers in the U.S. have found that the
mittees have their own buildings and many greater a teacher’s cognitive skills as demon-
have teacher training institutes). The demand strated in a standardized test, the better his or
for increases in salaries comes mainly from her students perform academically (Summers
teachers who, with the advent of local democ- and Wolfe, 1977; Strauss and Sawyer, 1986;
racy and their newly unionized teachers’ asso- and Ferguson, 1990). Thus, rewarding teach-
ciation, are an increasingly powerful lobby. ers for what they actually know and do in the
However, teachers and their unions are self- classroom is likely to have a much greater im-
interested and are not always able to see the pact on student performance than rewarding
public interest of the nation and to accept the them for their academic credentials and years
most efficient use of resources. Teachers tend of experience (see also Darling-Hammond,
to assume that the two are the same thing, but 1997).
they are not.

146
Chapter 4 Teacher Management System

Box 4.3 The Importance of Teacher Quality

A review of the literature indicates that a range of factors relating to teacher quality affects stu-
dent performance (see OECD, 2002). However, the literature also reveals the limitations of the
information provided by the more measurable characteristics of teachers. Researchers have often
found it hard to isolate the effect of characteristics such as knowledge of subject-matter,
qualifications, academic ability, pedagogical knowledge, or teaching experience on student
outcomes. The evidence predominantly shows that all of these teacher characteristics have a
positive impact on student learning but to a lesser extent than might have been expected. One
possible explanation is that research studies looking at individual school systems with relatively
uniform teacher characteristics have not been able to observe sufficient variation in such factors
to be able to measure the difference that they make. In addition, for most of these characteristics,
a “threshold effect” is likely to apply; teachers need a certain level of qualifications or experience
to be effective, but further attainments beyond those levels may have progressively less of an
impact on student performance.

A further possible explanation is that the teacher characteristics that are typically measured in re-
search studies may explain less of the variation in teacher quality than other characteristics that
are more difficult to measure. Such characteristics may include the ability to convey ideas in clear
and convincing ways, to work effectively with colleagues and the school community, to use a
wide range of teaching strategies appropriate for students’ needs, and enthusiasm, creativity, and
commitment to the students’ success. The literature reviewed in OECD (2001) includes recent
studies that point to the importance of such variables in influencing student learning. This sug-
gests that policymakers need to take account of the potentially substantial variation in quality that
exists among teachers whose easily measured characteristics are similar.

Source: OECD, 2002.


We recommend that Indonesia should establish a classrooms also remains to be accomplished.
process for evaluating school performance that is Also, the teacher competencies and the school
based on individual teacher performance reviews performance measures that are currently being
that assess their value added to education proc- developed are too centrist in their approach.
esses and outcomes.
The OECD has analyzed what teacher charac-
Furthermore, we recommend that those who teristics have the greatest effect on improving
define the criteria for effective teaching in Indone- quality (see Box 4.3), and this analysis pro-
sia (currently the MoNE) should more widely re- vides a good example of meaningful teacher
present the key stakeholders in education. These performance standards for a decentralized
recommendations are based on our assessment that education system. However, Indonesia has
current standards and performance assessment begun to develop a career-long set of compe-
practices have failed to improve the quality of tea- tency standards for teachers and ways to
ching in Indonesian schools. International best measure their performance against these stan-
practices provide strong support for this recom- dards. Research from elsewhere in the world
mendation as will be seen in Box 4.4.
has indicated which teacher characteristics and
behavior contribute the most to improving the
The definition of effective teaching in the di-
academic performance of students. An analy-
verse environments of Indonesia’s schools is
sis of junior secondary school results from the
still far from clear in the context of the new
Third International Mathematics Survey
decentralized education system. Designing
(Woessman, 2001) gave some illustrations of
monitoring tools and training inspectors in
teacher characteristics and behavior at the
how to assess the many aspects of teaching in
school level that seem to improve students’

147
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Box 4.4 International Evidence on Schooling, Resources,


Educational Institutions and Student Performance

x Students of female teachers score higher than students of male teachers in both mathematics and sci-
ence.
x School autonomy in the purchase of supplies is associated with good academic performance by stu-
dents.
x Students in schools that were responsible for hiring their own teachers performed significantly better
in mathematics and science; thus school autonomy in personnel management seems highly conducive
to good student performance.
x When individual teachers can choose which teaching method to use on the basis of what they think
would be best for their students, this helps students to learn more. Positive effects on students’ test
scores were also observed when individual teachers could influence how the curriculum was taught
in the school and when teachers were responsible for the purchase of supplies.
x The longer the instruction time that students have in school, the better their academic performance.
x Centralized examinations (that is, tests and examinations set independently of the school) that make
students’ learning efforts more visible to external observers were shown to have a positive impact on
students’ educational achievement.
x The more time that class teachers spend outside the formal school day on preparing or grading their
students’ work, the higher their students’ test scores in mathematics.
x It seems that assigning homework less often but on a more ambitious scale is particularly conducive
to students’ learning.

Source: Woessmann, 2001.

performance (see Box 4.4). These characteristics to protect the interests of teachers. In Indonesia,
are a good place to start in devising ways to meas- the processes of democracy are still being devel-
ure how teachers perform in terms of meeting oped, and much of the standard-setting of the re-
teaching and learning standards. cent past has been centrist and from the top
down. Education stakeholders at the local level
The international literature provides several promis- have not yet had much opportunity to discuss,
ing models for setting standards and monitoring adapt, or reject the standards and performance
teacher performance. The best known of these, the monitoring guidelines that are being developed.
UK school inspection system (Ofsted, 2003), is A study (Avalos, 1998) reviewed the battle for
described in Appendix 4.2. Recently, Chile has been and against the performance evaluation of mu-
developing new models for evaluating teacher per- nicipal teachers in Chile. (A summary of the dif-
formance, although these have been complicated by ference between the proposed evaluation system
long negotiations between the municipalities that as it was set out in the government statutes and
employ teachers and the teachers’ unions that exist the final negotiated system is in Table 4.4.)

148
Chapter 4 Teacher Management System

Table 4.4 Comparing Two Teacher Performance Evaluation Systems in Chile


Evaluation System The Statute System The New Agreed System
Purpose To assess teacher’s “functionary” or contractual Teaching performance, not contractual obliga-
performance. tions
Who is to be evalu- All teachers who have been employed for at least Gradually to cover all teachers in municipal
ated six months schools with one or more years of service, over a
period of four years.
Frequency of evalua- Once a year Every four years
tion
Content of the evalua- x Professional and contractual responsibility Specified in the National Set of Criteria: Frame-
tion x In-service courses taken and evidence of work for Good Teaching.
self-improvement (research or publica- It covers four domains:
tions) x Preparation for teaching
x Performance indicators including student x Developing an appropriate classroom envi-
results according to contexts ronment
x Exceptional evidence such as design of x Classroom teaching
school or classroom improvement projects. x Professional responsibilities beyond the
classroom
Each domain has four or five standards or crite-
ria to guide the assessment.
Procedures Ratings in a “evaluation record” and evidence x Portfolio with evidence of teaching and as-
from the teacher’s “life-history record.” sessment materials (may include a video)
x Self-evaluation sheet
x Structured interviews
x Head teacher report form
Rating scheme A point-scheme from 1 (deficient) to 5 (excel- Four categories based on ratings from examined
lent) evidence: outstanding, competent, basic, and un-
satisfactory.
Who evaluates A committee composed of the school head or Experienced teachers who are specifically
municipal head, a teachers’ representative, and a trained and checked for inter-rater reliability
municipal representative
Who decides The above committee A municipal evaluation committee on the basis
of the evaluators’ reports.
Right of appeal A committee including the municipal Mayor, the Not specified
Head of the Municipal Education Corporation,
and a school representative.
Effects Teachers deemed “unsatisfactory” in two con- Teachers deemed “basic” or “unsatisfactory”
secutive evaluations may be dismissed. Highly will be offered support to improve and will be
rated teachers may be eligible for in-service assessed up to twice more before being dis-
courses and funding of innovation projects. missed. Highly rated teachers will be offered ex-
tra opportunities for professional growth.
Coordination of the Municipalities x A national system under the Ministry of
system Education.
x A three-party technical committee: the
teachers’ union, municipalities, and aca-
demic institutions.
Funding Municipal budgets A national fund equivalent to 1% of teacher sala-
ries to pay for in-service provision organized by
municipalities.
Source: Avalos, 1998.

There are lessons from Chile that Indonesia Career-Long Professional Development
might want to consider. Avalos (1998) points
There have been a large number of teacher
out that the most important difference between
education and training projects in Indonesia
the two systems lies in the fact that the new
over the past 30 years (Sweeting, 2001).
system has a well-developed set of criteria or
standards against which to compare teaching These have aimed at revising the curriculum in
behavior, which the statutory system did not pre-service education programs, upgrading the
technical capacities of teacher educators and
have. These standards can also form the core
teacher education institutions, and developing
competencies for a career-long professional
in-service training and professional support
development system.
systems based on concepts of school cluster-
ing and teacher mentoring. However, there are
still many complaints about the fact that most

149
Education Sector Review Volume 2

in-service training does not improve teacher ance in the classroom or add value to their
quality, which reinforces the public’s opinion students’ learning.
that the quality of most teachers in Indonesia
is low (Sweeting, 2000). Initial Preparation of Teachers
The minimum qualification for primary teach-
We recommend a new paradigm for teacher
ers was set in 1989 as a two-year post-
training in Indonesia, one that takes as its
secondary-school teaching diploma (DII). Yet
starting point the career-long professional de-
in 2002, only one-half of all primary school
velopment of teachers. This would cover
teachers in Indonesia held this certificate or a
teachers’ initial training, their induction into
higher qualification. For junior secondary
school life, their professional registration, and
schools, the minimum teaching qualification is
their continuing professional development.
a three-year education degree (S1), and in
This continuum of professional development
2002, only 50.7 percent of teachers held this
needs to be linked directly to the actual class-
or a higher qualification. Research consis-
rooms and schools in which teachers work.
tently indicates that the most successful
This means that colleges and universities need
teacher education programs require trainee
to be much more responsive to the demands of
teachers to spend a high proportion of their
schools and of the district governments that
time in teaching and other practical and intern-
employ teachers. They also need to be respon-
ship experiences in schools (see Box 4.5 be-
sive to the professional demands of teachers
low).
who wish to deepen their experience and
knowledge of teaching to add value to what
International research indicates that:
they do in classrooms and in collegial activi-
ties with their colleagues (for example, men-
toring newly licensed teachers). The notion of x The most competent teachers are
teacher preparation is now being redefined to those who have a good mastery of
include reflective teaching approaches and the subject to be taught and have
classroom-based action research collaboration also studied Education.
among teachers, effective communication, and x Teachers with more training in
other characteristics that contribute to lifelong teaching methodology are more ef-
professional development (see Appendix 4.1 fective than those with less.
for a fuller version of what teachers should x Teachers who have spent more
know and be able to do). time studying pedagogy are better
teachers, especially when it comes
While there is constant discussion about re- to encouraging higher-order think-
quiring higher levels of certification for teach- ing skills in their students and ca-
ers, there are issues that need to be addressed tering for their individual needs.
beforehand about the kind of teachers that x How well trainee teachers perform
schools need and the relationship between in well-assessed practice teaching
formal qualifications like the DII or S1 and the is the best predictor of their future
actual lives of teachers. These issues include success in the classroom.
how to organize learning in multi-grade
schools, what are the most appropriate meth- The main implication of these findings for ini-
ods for teaching literacy to young learners, tial teacher preparation and for continuing pro-
and how to approach teaching in multilingual fessional development programs is that
environments. There also needs to be more training institutions will need to send trainee
discussion about whether or not resources teachers to practice in schools in a wide range
spent on constantly upgrading teachers’ quali- of different environments.
fications will actually improve their perform-

150
Chapter 4 Teacher Management System

Box 4.5 Teacher Education Programs that Made a Difference

Research on teacher education programs in the USA has shown that the most effective programs have these
characteristics:

x A common vision is expressed in the coursework and in the clinical experiences or practice teaching
sessions.
x They set well-defined standards of practice and performance.
x Graduates are expected to know content-specific pedagogy, child development, learning theory, and
student assessment methods.
x They provide extended clinical experiences (lasting a total of 30 weeks in a four-year degree pro-
gram).
x They have strong partnerships with universities and schools.
x They make extensive use of case methods, teacher research, performance assessments, and portfolio
evaluations.

Source: Darling-Hammond, 2000.

censing boards with responsibility for initial


Induction of New Teachers into School teacher licensing and for performance moni-
Life and Classroom Teaching toring at the renewal stages. In Ireland, for ex-
There is currently no formal school induction ample, a Department of Education Inspector
process for newly graduated teachers even assesses each new teacher for certification
though this is an important stage in their pro- purposes during an initial probationary period
fessional development. Most professions have following his or her appointment to a full-time
internship systems that lead to registration and teaching post. Most new teachers complete
entry into the profession. It provides an impor- the certification requirements within two and a
tant link between the employer, the service half years of their graduation. Malaysia and
provider, and those who educate and train pro- Australia also have systems that require teach-
fessionals. An induction process also provides ers to register after completing their initial
a supportive environment for new teachers teacher education programs (Acedo, 1998).
when they are first being held fully account-
able for a class of children and their learning A major unsolved problem in teacher licensing
to parents and colleagues. Looking at the in Indonesia is that no criteria exist for deter-
OECD’s extended list of what teachers should mining when a prospective teacher is fully
know and be able to do (see Appendix 4.1), it ready to take responsibility for teaching a
is obvious that no new graduate could possibly classroom full of students. In most countries,
have all of these characteristics at the start of teachers simply have to pass all of the courses
his or her career. The Directorate of Higher in an approved teacher education program.
Education at the MoNE is currently identify- However, because Indonesian policymakers
ing what new graduates are expected to know did not believe that this route necessarily
and be able to do and what beginning teachers demonstrated that prospective teachers were
should know and be able to do in order to be fit to practice, they imposed additional tests of
licensed. basic skills, subject matter, and pedagogy on
trainee teachers.
Introducing an induction stage into teacher
development in Indonesia would require estab- The Indonesian system consists of paper and
lishing an internship system that links poten- pencil tests with mainly multiple choice ques-
tial employers, schools, and licensing boards, tions in standardized tests of basic skills, sub-
developing mentoring systems for interns, ject matter, and pedagogical knowledge as
providing incentives for employers and well as classroom observation sessions in
schools to support interns, and establishing li- which candidate teachers are assessed against

151
Education Sector Review Volume 2

a checklist of designated kinds of teaching be- x Teaching is a function of both


havior. Neither the standardized tests nor the content and pedagogical knowl-
observations based on the checklist adequately edge.
reflect the extent of a candidate’s knowledge x Combining support and assess-
base and, thus, improve the quality of candi- ment is essential to the evaluation
dates’ preparation for teaching. Similar tests in of teachers’ professional compe-
the USA were abandoned in the mid-1980s in tence.
favor of performance-oriented assessments x The tasks in the assessment must
because of the following problems: represent authentic exhibitions of
teacher-related activities.
x Only 10 percent of the questions x Professional judgment and exper-
actually asked about the candi- tise are key dimensions in assess-
dates’ knowledge about teaching ing teacher performance
and learning. (Pecheone and Carey, 1990).
x Over 40 percent of the questions
were so poorly specified that they
either had no clearly defensible Continuous Professional Development
right answer or had an answer
based solely on ideology rather In many areas of Indonesia, teachers act as
than on knowledge of research mentors to other less experienced teachers ei-
(Darling-Hammond, 1986). ther in professional development activities at
x The tests did not allow candidates the school or through teachers’ meetings at the
to demonstrate their knowledge, school cluster level or in district in-service
judgment, and skills in the kinds training workshops. However, reports indicate
of complex settings that character- that in many cases this system breaks down
ize real teaching. because mentoring does not provide the men-
tors with any opportunity to deepen their pro-
x They represented a narrow behav-
fessional experience nor are the resources
ioristic view of teaching that over-
available for them to do so (Nielsen 1996).
simplifies the nature of teachers’
The main sources of funding for professional
decision making.
development activities in the past have been
x The exceedingly brief statements
externally funded projects or the central gov-
of professional problems failed to
ernment’s project funding. When these
represent the complexity of teach-
sources are not available, there are only lim-
ers’ decision making processes or
ited resources available to pay for any school-
the full range of their professional
based professional development activities. To
knowledge base.
date, few district governments have allocated
x The questions failed to provide any budgetary resources to in-service training
sufficient information about the activities. Some teacher training institutions
context for and goals of teaching and universities, again with project funding,
decisions to allow candidates to have established applied research activities in
give sensible answers. schools in which teachers have been able to
participate, and reflect on their practice, and
We recommend that Indonesia develop per- develop ideas for improving teaching prac-
formance-oriented assessments for teachers tices at their schools. Some schools have used
grounded in four assumptions about teaching project money to pay for experts to work with
and learning: them on specific teaching and learning issues,
but these examples are not common.

152
Chapter 4 Teacher Management System

Box 4.6 Mexico’s Incentive Scheme for Teacher Development

Mexico’s Carrera Magisterial (CM) Program, first implemented in 1994, ties teachers’ compensation to their
professional development. Teachers who voluntarily join the program agree to participate in annual perform-
ance evaluations and to have their annual salary increases linked to the results of these evaluations. These per-
formance evaluations consist of the following components: teacher performance evaluations (composed of a
combination of self-assessments and peer reviews); an annual written examination of the teacher’s professional
skills; written student examinations; educational attainment; the completion of accredited courses to update
skills; and years of teaching experience.

Although the program is voluntary, the number of teachers enrolled since 1994 has increased substantially, be-
ginning with 38 percent of the total number of teachers and rising to 49 percent after just two years. Indeed,
the proportion of students whose teachers were enrolled in the program more than doubled during that period,
reaching around 25 percent of all students. In addition, in 1997, the percentage of all teaching positions that
were filled by teachers who were participating in the CM program was close to 50 percent. A recent study
found that students whose teachers are in the CM program have higher average test scores than students whose
teachers are not in the program. Thus, after 10 years, the CM program has already had a considerable impact
on the Mexican education system.

Source: Lopez-Acevedo, 2001.

The existing credit point system that is used to Using Teacher Management Systems to
assess whether teachers are ready for promo- Achieve Education Goals
tion needs to be revamped to create more in- Educators in Indonesia probably already feel
centives for teachers to upgrade their skills that there is a need for a new paradigm for the
and update their knowledge on a regular basis. development of the teaching profession. Many
Also, universities and other education institu- elements of this new approach are in place or
tions need to be more responsive to teachers’ are being tried out in a number of project-
professional needs by providing them with related activities. However, developing an
short vacation courses and flexible modular overall framework that incorporates these ac-
courses that would allow them to deepen their tivities into a lifelong perspective on teachers’
knowledge and widen their experience without professional development should be a priority.
necessarily committing themselves to long-
term, full-time academic programs. Teachers’ Having effective teacher management systems
professional development programs should be in place in every school is essential for achiev-
linked to school and teacher performance ing Indonesia’s national education goals. The
monitoring. There is much work to be done in policy framework that we are proposing aims
this area, but there is also a lot of Indonesian to improve schools by creating a professional
experience to build on. Also, other countries, teaching service with the following character-
such as Mexico (see Box 4.6 below), have also istics: merit-based appointments, transfers,
been experimenting with tying teachers’ com- and promotions; school-based performance
pensation to their professional development evaluations; and career-long professional de-
and providing teachers with professional su- velopment. These characteristics mirror three
port. This professional support can consist of longer-term policy goals: (i) creating a teach-
peer mentoring within schools, opportunities ing service in which the professional life of
to work alongside experienced teachers in teachers is central to the management system
their own or other schools, visits to other good and in which schools select their own teachers
practice schools and classrooms, or bringing a in a transparent way; (ii) linking the monitor-
teacher-designated “expert” to the classroom ing of schools and teachers by adding per-
to encourage teachers to reflect on their teach- formance reviews as part of teachers’ career
ing behavior and to try new approaches. development; and (iii) developing the various

153
Education Sector Review Volume 2

phases of teachers’ professional development their teachers’ performance, which would be


including initial preparation, induction into the evaluated in terms of the value that the teacher
teaching profession, school life, and continu- adds to student learning in the classroom, to
ous professional development. the professional life of the school, and to the
wider educational community. These attrib-
These policy tools are based on some assump- utes would be the basis of any recognition,
tions about how schools would benefit. For promotion, or rewards given to the teacher as
example, under a school-based management well as of the renewal of their contracts and of
system that involves the local community in the provision of assistance in improving their
making decisions about how the school is classroom performance. Teachers at the start
managed, the school should have the right to of their careers would be expected to exhibit
choose its teachers. This would result in im- these attributes in order to be hired. In return,
plicit contractual agreements between the the school would have an obligation to provide
school that selected the teacher and the teacher the teacher with professional development op-
who selected the school. Schools and districts portunities.
would have specific expectations regarding

Table 4.5 Potential Policy Tools for Managing the Teaching Workforce
Demand-side tools Supply-side tools Matching process tools
Class size Attractiveness of the profession Bargaining mechanisms
Monetary incentives Set of mechanisms for bargain-
Teaching loads -relative salaries ing: setting of salaries, pay differ-
-career structure and salary scale entiation to account for shortages,
Required learning time for stu- -other (e.g. merit-based awards, opening of profession to interna-
dents signing bonuses, differentiated tional markets.
pay, housing subsidies, childcare,
Use of teaching assistants and income tax credits) Level of centralization of bar-
other support staff gaining
Non-monetary incentives Degree of autonomy of schools
Use of technology and distance -vacation time, flexibility to take regarding recruitment, selection
learning leave and assignment of teachers; and
-working conditions: opportuni- setting of incentive structure.
Structure of curriculum and edu- ties for collaboration and decision
cational programmers making, school safety and student Recruitment and selection
discipline, class size, working processes
Starting and ending age of com- loads, quality of facilities and in- Organization; definition of quali-
pulsory education structional materials fication requirements; delegation
of authority to recruit; select and
Academic standards defining re- Teacher education and certifi- assign teachers; methods for
quirements for graduation cation screening candidates; emergency
Teacher initial education and pro- recruitment programs.
fessional development: supply,
structure, content, and accredita-
tion of teacher education pro-
grams; incentives to engage in
teacher education; induction and
mentoring programs; provision of
professional development activi-
ties.

Certification of teachers: defini-


tion of certification standards; al-
ternative certification programs.

Source: OECD, 2002.

154
Chapter 4 Teacher Management System

The most critical point in our proposals is the in putting in place such a teacher management
establishment of a separate teaching service. framework, we have given some examples in
This would need to be built up over time. It is the matrix below of appropriate policies to
also essential to examine how teacher salaries adopt, the kind of actions required to imple-
depend upon districts’ budgets and how this ment the policies, and some ideas about who
affects the degree to which schools can recruit should be responsible for implementing them.
teachers. To illustrate what might be involved

155
Education Sector Review Volume 2

References For Chapter 4

Acedo, Clementina, 1998. “Teacher Supply, of State Policy Evidence,” Education Policy
Training, and Professional Development: Analysis Archives, 8(1) January 2000.
Lessons on Teaching Assessment Derived
from the American Practice of Teacher Educa- Darling-Hammond, Linda, 1997. The Right to
tion” from Robert Folden, “The Need of New Learn. A Blueprint for Creating Schools that
Assessment in Teaching.” Prepared for World Work. San Francisco, Jossey-Bass.
Bank Seminar on Education System Reform
and Management, September 9. Darling-Hammond, Linda, 1986. “Tuition
Tax Deductions and Parents School Choice.”
Acedo, Clementina, Mitsue Uemura, Christo- Rand Corp.
pher J. Thomas, Yoko Nagashima and Kathy
Li Tow Ngow, 1999. “Education Indicators Delannoy, Francoise, 2000. “Brazil: Teachers
for East Asia and the Pacific.” The World Development and Incentives: A Strategic
Bank, Washington. Framework.” Report No. 20408-Br., Latin
America and Caribbean Regional Office.
Avalos, Beatrice, 1998. “School-based Washington: The World Bank.
Teacher Development.” Teaching and Teacher
Education 14, (93) 257-271. Farrell, James B., 2003. “Teacher Manage-
ment.” Unpublished report for the World
Bray, Mark and Thomas R. Murray, eds, 1998. Bank’s Indonesia Education Sector Review.
Financing of Education in Indonesia. Asian Jakarta.
Development Bank and the University of
Hong Kong Comparative Education Research Farrell, Joseph P. and Joao B. Oliveira, eds,
Centre. 1993. “Teachers in Developing Countries:
Improving Effectiveness and Managing
Brophy, Jere and Carolyn Everston, 1976. Costs.” Economic Development Institute of
Learning from Teaching: A Developmental the World Bank. Washington.
Perspective. Boston: Allyn & Bacon.
Ferguson, Ronald, 1990. “Teacher Salaries,
Burgess, Simon, Bronwyn Croxson, Paul Teacher Quality, and Student Performance:
Gregg, and Carol Propper, 2001. The Intrica- Texas Schools in the Mid-1980s.” Working
cies of the Relationship Between Pay and Per- Paper, Malcolm Weiner Center for Social Pol-
formance for Teachers: Do Teachers Respond icy, John F. Kennedy School of Government,
to Performance-related Pay Schemes? The Harvard University.
Centre for Market and Public Organisation
Working Paper No. 01/035. University of Filmer, Deon, 2002. “Teachers’ Pay in Indo-
Bristol Department of Economics. nesia.” Unpublished paper, World Bank, Sep-
tember.
Craig, Helen J., R.J. Kraft, and J. du Plessis,
1998. Teacher Development: Making an Im- Filmer, Deon and David Landauer, 2000.
pact. USAID Basic Education and Literacy “Does Indonesia Have a “Low Pay” Civil Ser-
Project and World Bank, Human Development vice?” Unpublished paper, World Bank, Sep-
Network, Effective Schools and Teachers. tember.
Washington.
Gaynor, Cathy, 1998. “Decentralization of
Darling-Hammond, Linda, 2000. “Teacher Education. Teacher Management.” Directions
Quality and Student Achievement: A Review in Development, The World Bank, Washing-
ton.

156
Chapter 4 Teacher Management System

Glewwe, Paul, Nauman Ilias, Michael Kremer, search Program, London School of Economics
and Sylvie Moulin, 2001. “Teacher Incentives and Political Science. DEP No.74, August.
and Student Outcomes: Evidence from a Ran-
domized Evaluation in Kenya.” Draft. Lindauer, David L., 2000. “Paying Indonesia’s
Civil Servants.” Unpublished paper World
Gordon, Nora and Emiliana Vegas, 2004. Bank/Wellesley College, August 24.
“Education Finance Equalization, Spending,
Teacher Quality, and Student Outcomes: The Lopez-Acevedo, Gladys, 2001. “Teacher’s
Case of Brazil’s FUNDEF.” The World Bank. Incentives and Professional Development in
Processed. Schools in Mexico.” World Bank, Washing-
ton D.C. Processed.
Hallak, Jaques and Muriel Poisson, 2002.
“Ethics and Corruption in Education.” Policy McLure, Maureen and Ninasapti Triaswati,
Forum No. 15. IIEP/UNESCO. Paris. 2001. “Strategy of Educational Reform within
the Context of Fiscal Decentralization” Work-
Halliday, Ian and Joe Hogan, 1994. Develop- ing paper for the Ministry of National Educa-
ing a Database for Teacher Management. tion, The British Council, and The World
The Management of Teachers. IIEP Research Bank. Development of Strategies for Educa-
and Studies Program. Paris, UNESCO Interna- tional Finance.
tional Institute for Educational Planning.
McMahon, Walter, 2003. “Financing and
Hayes, Denis, 1999. “Opportunities and Ob- Achieving Education for All Goals” Ministry
stacles in the Competency-based Training and of National Education, Bappenas, The World
Assessment of Primary School Teachers in Bank. Working paper, April.
England.” Harvard Education Review, April
1999. McMahon, Walter, 2001. Improving Educa-
tion Finance in Indonesia. Policy Research
Heneveld, Ward and Helen Craig, 1996. Center, Institute for Research and Develop-
“Schools Count: World Bank Project Designs ment, Ministry of National Education, UNI-
and the Quality of Primary Education in Sub- CEF, and UNESCO. Jakarta.
Saharan Africa.” World Bank Technical Pa-
per Number 303. Washington. Mingat, Alain and Jee-Peng Tan, 1999a.
“Management of Teacher Deployment and
Huberman, M. and T. R. Guskey, 1995. “The Classroom Processes.” A two-part training
Diversities of Professional Development” in module. World Bank, Washington, DC.
M. Huberman and T. R. Guskey (eds). Profes-
sional Development in Education. New Para- Mingat, Alain and Jee-Peng Tan, 1999b. “As-
digms and Practices. New York: Teachers’ sessing Policy Options for Teacher Training
College. and Pay.” A two-part training module. World
Bank, Washington, DC.
Jalal, Fasli and Bachuradin Musthafa, eds,
2001. Education Reform in the Context of Re- Ministry of National Education, 2002a. The
gional Autonomy: The Case of Indonesia. Strategic Planning of the Development of
Ministry of National Education and National Education, Youth, and Sport 2002-2004.
Development Planning Agency,and the World
Bank. Ministry of National Education, 2002b. Indo-
nesia Educational Statistics in Brief
Kingdon, Geeta Gandhi, 1996. Student 2001/2002.
Achievement and Teacher Pay: A Case Study
of India. The Development Economics Re- Ministry of National Education, 2002c. Stan-
dar Kompentensi Guru Kelas SD-MI.

157
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Ministry of National Education, Office of Organization for Economic Cooperation and


Educational Research and Development. Development (OECD), 2002. Education Pol-
2002. “The Teacher and Teacher Education.” icy Analysis. Paris.
Policy paper. Jakarta.
Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Ministry of Education and Culture, 1997a. Development (OECD), 2001. Teachers for
“JSE Handbook: In-service Training Program Tomorrow’s Schools: Analysis of the World
for SLTP Teachers.” Technical Report No. Education Indicators. 2001 edition. UNESCO
13. Institute for Statistics. Paris.

Ministry of Education and Culture, 1997b. Pecheone, R.L and N.B. Carey, 1990. “The
“JSE Science Handbook: In-service Training Validity of Performance Assessments for
Program for SLTP Teachers.” Teacher Licensure: Connecticut’s Ongoing
Research.” Journal of Personnel Evaluation in
Ministry of Education and Culture, 1996a. Education, 3, 115-142.
“Secondary Education in Indonesia: Strength-
ening Teacher Competency and Student Pritchett, Lant and Deon Filmer, 1999. “What
Learning.” Technical Report No.1a. Education Production Functions Really Show:
a Positive Theory of Education Expenditures.”
Ministry of Education and Culture, 1996b. Economics of Education Review 18 (1999)
“English Diagnostic Survey with recommen- 223-239.
dations for Inservice Training Program for
SLTP Teachers.” Technical Report No. 8a. Schiefelbein, Ernesto, Laurence Wolff, and
Paulina Schiefelbein, 1998. “Cost-
Ministry of Education and Culture, 1996c. effectiveness of Education Policies in Latin
“JSE Mathematics: Diagnostic Survey of Ba- America: A Survey of Expert Opinion.” Tech-
sic Number Skills.” Technical Report No. 12. nical Study. Inter-American Development
Bank, Sustainable Development Department,
Moleong, Lexy J., 2003. “Survey of Media Education Unit, Washington D.C.
Articles on Education Decentralization.” Un-
published report for the World Bank’s Indone- Somerset, Anthony, 1997. “Teacher Supply
sia Education Sector Review. Jakarta. and Distribution issues in Kabupaten Suka-
bumi: Results from a Rapid Review.” Work-
Nielsen, H. Dean, 1998. “Reforms to Teacher ing paper for Government of Indonesia/World
Education in Indonesia. Does More Mean Bet- Bank’s Basic Education project preparation.
ter?” Asia Pacific Journal of Education. Jakarta.

Nielsen, H. Dean, 1996. “A Review of In- Strauss, Robert P. and Elizabeth A. Sawyer,
service Teacher Education Programs in Indo- 1986. “Some New Evidence on Teacher and
nesia.” Report prepared for the World Bank’s Student Competencies.” Economics of Educa-
Indonesia Basic Education program. October- tion Review 5(1) 41-48.
November.
Summers, Anita A. and Barbara L. Wolfe,
Office for Standards in Education (Ofsted), 1977. “Do Schools Make a Difference?” The
2003. Inspection reports on state primary and American Economic Review 67(4): 639-52.
secondary schools, teacher training, and local
government authorities. Sweeting, Elizabeth, 2001. “Basic Education
http://www.ofsted.gov.uk. Projects in Indonesia since 1990: A Study in
Sustainability.” March. Working paper for the
Ministry of National Education/World Bank
Basic Education IV project preparation.

158
Chapter 4 Teacher Management System

Sweeting, Elizabeth, 2000. “West Java Basic World Bank, 2000b. “Implementation Com-
Education Project: Teacher Training Study for pletion Report (34960,3496A, 3496S). Pri-
the Project Supervision Mission.” Processed mary School Teacher Development Project.”
report to the World Bank.
World Bank, 1999. “Mid-term Review of the
Thair, M. and D.F. Treagust, 2003. “A Brief Secondary School Teacher Development Pro-
History of a Science Teacher Professional De- ject.” Loan 3979-IND.
velopment Initiative in Indonesia and the Im-
plications for Centralized Teacher Ministerial decrees
Development.” International Journal of Edu- Number 034/U/2003 Auxiliary Teachers, The
cation Development 23 (2003) 201-213. Minister of National Education
Van der Werf, Greetje, Bert Creemers, Rob Number 013/U/2002 Credit Units in
De Jong, and Elizabeth Claver, 2000. Teacher’s Functional Position, The Minister of
“Evaluation of School Improvements through Education
an Educational Effective Model: The Case of
Indonesia’s PEQIP Project.” Comparative Number 123/U/2001 Guidelines for the Ap-
Education Review 44(3): 329-55. pointment of Teachers, The Minister of
Education
Vanwel, Helen et al 2003. “Impact of Decen-
tralization on Teacher Management: Report on Number 84/1996 Functional Position of
Focus Group Assessments in Bandar Lampung Teacher and its Credit Points, State Minister
and Makassar.” Report for the World Bank’s for Apparatus Reform
Indonesia Education Sector Review.
The Basic Concept of Determining the Obliga-
Vanwel, Helen et al 2001. “Social Assessment tory Function and Minimum Service Standard,
Pilot Activity.” Working paper for Indonesia The Ministry of Home Affairs.
Basic Education IV project preparation. Min-
istry of National Education/ The World Bank, Management and Development of Teaching
December. Staff in the Era of Regional Autonomy
(MoNE?)
Voluntary Service Overseas (VSO), 2002.
What Makes Teachers Tick? A Policy Re- Presidential decrees
search Report on Teachers’ Motivation in De-
veloping Countries. London. Number 3 Year 2003 Teaching staff allow-
ances, President of the Republic of Indonesia
Weston, Stuart. 2003. “Exploding Myths.” Number 9 Year 2003 Authority to appoint,
Background Paper for the World Bank’s Indo- relocate and dismiss civil servants, President
nesia Education Sector Review. Unpublished. of the Republic of Indonesia

Woessmann, Ludger, 2001. Schooling Re- Laws


sources, Educational Institutions and Student Numbers 22 and 25, 1999 on decentralization.
Performance: the International Evidence. In-
stitute of World Economics, Kiel, Germany. Number 20, 2003 on National Education System.
January.

World Bank, 2000a. “Implementation Com-


pletion Report. Indonesia Primary Education
Quality Improvement Project.” Loan 348-
IND.

159
Education Sector Review Volume 2

Appendix 4.1. What Teachers Need to Know and Be Able to Do

Content knowledge:
x Understanding subject matter deeply and flexibly to help students to create cognitive maps, link
ideas, and address misconceptions
x Seeing how ideas connect across fields of knowledge and to life
x Making ideas accessible to others and understanding the perspective of the learner

Learner knowledge:
x Knowledge of child and adolescent development and how to support cognitive, social, physical, and
emotional growth, to interpret learners’ statements and actions, and to shape productive learning ex-
periences
x Understanding of and respect for differences in culture, family experience, forms of intelligence, and
approaches to learning and the ability to teach in a way that connects with students
x Inquiring sensitively, listening carefully, looking thoughtfully at student work, and structuring situa-
tions to allow students to express themselves

Motivating students:
x Understanding what individual students believe about themselves, what they care about, and how to
give them encouragement

Knowledge about learning:


x Deciding which type of learning is most appropriate in specific circumstances and which materials to
use when and for what purpose
x Ability to use different strategies for teaching, evaluating students’ knowledge, and assessing their
learning
x Capacity to understand the strengths of individual students
x Capacity to work with disabled students
x Understanding of how students acquire language (the gateway to learning) to build their skills and
create accessible learning experiences

Knowledge about curriculum resources and technologies:


x Allowing students to explore ideas, acquire and synthesize information, and frame and solve prob-
lems

Knowledge about collaboration:


x Structuring student interactions for shared learning
x Collaborating with other teachers
x Working with parents to learn more about their children and to shape supportive experiences at
school and home

Capacity to reflect:
x Assessing their own teaching practices and how to refine and improve them
x Continuously evaluating students’ progress and reshape lesson plans accordingly.

Source: OECD, 2002.

160
Chapter 4 Teacher Management System

Appendix 4.2. Supplementary Information on International Experience


This appendix provides supplementary infor- result, it would increase the number of indi-
mation on international experiences in the ar- viduals interested in teaching and make teach-
eas of teacher salaries and teacher ing an attractive career to more highly skilled
performance standards. individuals who, prior to the reform, would
have been likely to choose to enter other pro-
Teacher Salaries fessions. Second, local governments could
use the increase in resources for teacher sala-
A number of countries have begun to link
ries not only to increase the salaries of existing
teachers’ pay directly to measures of student
teachers but also to hire additional teachers,
outcomes, but this has become highly conten-
thus enabling them to reduce class sizes,
tious in many cases. Chile has the most exten-
which would probably also improve student
sive program of performance-based teacher
outcomes.
compensation, while other countries such as
Colombia and Mexico have smaller, experi-
An assessment of the reform that was carried
mental programs. However, giving perform-
out in 2002 revealed that regional disparities
ance-based salary incentives to individual
in teacher pay had been reduced and that the
teachers within a school can have negative ef-
number of teachers who had at least graduated
fects. These can inhibit teamwork among
from secondary school had increased. The
teachers in a school, which is a core principle
study also showed that the increase in teach-
involved in improving the overall quality of
ers’ compensation and in the number of teach-
education provided. It can also create unpro-
ers with at least a secondary education were
ductive competition between teachers within
positively associated with better student out-
the same school. Education policymakers in
comes such as lower dropout rates and higher
Brazil, India, and Kenya have considered
pass rates (Gordon and Vegas, 2004).
compensation and performance issues. Their
experiences are described below.
India
Brazil A study of teacher salaries in India found that
the salary structures for teachers were ineffi-
In 1998, Brazil implemented an education fi-
cient, with those teacher characteristics that
nance reform called the Fund for the Mainte-
have few discernible learning benefits for stu-
nance and Development of Primary Education
dents being rewarded in salary terms whereas
and Teacher Enhancement (FUNDEF). The
those that improve student learning were not.
main objective of this fund was to equalize
The study suggested that spending more
educational opportunities across states and
money on school facilities and materials,
municipalities by guaranteeing a minimum
longer school days, better management prac-
expenditure per pupil in primary schools
tices, and more skilled teachers would enhance
throughout the country. Embedded in the re-
school efficiency but that investing in smaller
form was a requirement that at least 60 percent
pupil-teacher ratios (in urban areas where
of the additional funds provided by FUNDEF
there is no multi-grade teaching), in teacher
must be spent on teachers’ salaries.
experience, training, and post-graduate educa-
tion, and higher across-the-board teachers’
The program was expected to improve teacher
salaries may not make sense in a resource-
quality and student outcomes in several ways.
scarce environment. Moreover, it suggested
First, it would increase the salaries of existing
that more emphasis should be put on the qual-
teachers in regions that, previous to the re-
ity of teachers’ education (in other words,
form, had had relatively low teachers’ salaries.
their knowledge of subject matter and their
This would make teaching a more attractive
cognitive skills) when selecting and remuner-
profession, particularly in these regions. As a

161
Education Sector Review Volume 2

ating teachers than on their years of schooling, ensure that his or her students perform
training, and experience, since these inputs well academically. This is a measurable
were not significant in explaining variations in task – through student test scores, for
school outcomes. These findings are also example. However, another of their ob-
likely to apply to education in Indonesia jectives is to ensure that students are so-
(Kingdon, 1996). cially and emotionally well adjusted.
This objective is not easily measurable.
Kenya Therefore, if an incentive is based on the
measurable objective, teachers will tend
Kenya has pilot-tested a performance-based
to focus on that task above all others and
incentive system that would reward all teach-
may neglect the other non-measurable
ers in a given school based on improved stu-
but equally important tasks.
dent performance in grades four to eight in
that school. There were two ways in which x Fourth, teachers object to being judged
schools could distinguish themselves in this based solely on their students’ academic
performance-based scheme – either by having performance if they are teaching a diffi-
the highest test scores of all of the schools in cult or disadvantaged population, per-
their district or by having the most improved haps because the school is located in a
test scores of all of the schools in their district. poor community where student perform-
ance has historically been weak. In this
The pilot project set out to measure the impact case, it would not be fair to have teach-
and cost-effectiveness of this performance- ers in better-off communities judged by
based incentive system that rewarded all the same criteria as those teaching in
teachers in schools whose performance had disadvantaged communities.
improved. The program was designed to take x Fifth, basing teacher incentives on stu-
note of five important criticisms of perform- dents’ test scores can cause teachers to
ance-based incentive systems in which per- neglect or force out weaker students in
formance is judged by student outcomes: order to concentrate on those students
who will perform well on the tests
x The first objection is that teachers are (Glewwe et al, 2001).
not solely responsible for the academic
performance of their students. In order to Teacher Performance Standards
produce good student outcomes, teachers
in a school need to cooperate with each The United Kingdom
other, and it is important that they do so The United Kingdom (UK) school inspection
rather than competing against each other. system sets performance standards and, on
x The second objection to performance- school visits, its inspectors ask questions such
based incentives is that a teacher’s per- as: How high are standards in the school
formance is largely unobservable, and, (based on the school’s results and achieve-
even when it can be observed, it is diffi- ments)? How well are the pupils taught?
cult to verify objectively. What consti- How good are the curricular and other oppor-
tutes good performance by a teacher is tunities offered to pupils? How well does the
not simple or easily quantifiable; there- school care for its pupils? How well does the
fore it is difficult to compensate teachers school work in partnership with parents? How
based on their performance. well is the school led and managed? What
x The third difficulty in establishing per- should the school do to improve further? The
formance-based incentives is that a Office of Standards in Education (Ofsted) pre-
teacher’s job involves many different pares detailed inspection reports and sets pri-
tasks, some of which are easily measur- orities for school and teacher development
able and some of which are not. For in- programs. The key question asked in review-
stance, one objective of a teacher is to ing classroom teaching is: How well are pupils

162
Chapter 4 Teacher Management System

taught? The assessment is based on classroom quality of education. During the school
observations of teaching; interviews with par- observations conducted for the Indonesian
ents, teachers, school principals, and students; Primary Education Quality Improvement
and reviews of teachers’ and students’ portfo- Project, many management-related prob-
lios of work. The kind of suggestions that in-
lems appeared, such as frequent teacher
spectors make are reflected in this extract from
and student absenteeism, inefficient use of
a school report (available on the Ofsted web-
site, www.ofsted.gov.uk): instruction time, and under-qualified or
unmotivated teachers. The principals of
x Review the curriculum (as the project schools focused too much on
taught), ensuring that it has ap- administrative tasks (for example, keeping
propriate breadth and balance records of students’ test results and finan-
and that the required coverage is cial tasks) rather than on educational lead-
provided for subjects other than ership tasks. An evaluation of the project
the core subjects of English, as well as international research into edu-
mathematics, and science. cational effectiveness has shown that ef-
x Improve and broaden the range fective principals generally undertake the
of teaching approaches that are following activities: sitting in on class-
often adopted in the non-core
rooms to observe the quality of teaching;
subjects, particularly where
teachers feel constrained by the creating conditions for teachers to improve
detail of the lesson plans. their teaching skills; selecting high-quality
x Improve the quality of assess- teachers, guiding less able ones, and re-
ment in the non-core subjects. placing those who do not improve; rein-
x Give more attention to educating forcing teachers’ motivation; ensuring that
pupils for life in a multi-cultural school time is used efficiently; preventing
society. teacher and student absenteeism; control-
x Ensure that training is provided ling the implementation of the curriculum
for staff in child protection and in all grades; promoting an orderly and
in health and safety issues (Of- friendly school climate; and getting par-
sted, 2003). ents and the community involved effec-
tively in school matters. These aspects of
Indonesia effective educational leadership should be
included in management training for prin-
Management at the school level is the cipals, which will mean changing current
most important factor for improving the training methods and content(Van der
Werf et al, 2002).

163
Education Sector Review Volume 2

164
Report No. 29506

INDONESIA

EDUCATION IN INDONESIA:
MANAGING THE TRANSITION TO
DECENTRALIZATION
(In Three Volumes) Volume 3

STATISTICAL ANNEX

The World Bank


August 2004
Table 1. Highest Level of Education as a Percentage of the Population, by Location

Less than Primary School Primary School Junior Secondary School


1995 1998 2000 2002 1995 1998 2000 2002 1995 1998 2000 2002
Province Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural
Aceh 10.54 33.18 11.40 28.46 4.84 24.25 38.45 23.18 39.09 12.76 16.83 12.17 18.81 14.23 14.29
North Sumatera 21.74 43.55 15.15 29.55 11.66 29.21 9.77 20.98 24.83 31.79 25.45 37.65 24.53 35.65 23.21 38.42 21.04 13.94 19.51 18.23 19.93 18.78 22.33 21.65
West Sumatera 17.49 43.45 12.25 40.21 14.57 37.18 12.29 32.93 22.65 30.33 21.51 30.10 20.22 29.48 19.35 29.95 14.71 11.09 17.90 12.24 15.75 14.69 17.68 16.95
Riau 14.54 37.76 10.51 30.41 11.60 33.94 6.55 21.71 24.57 40.09 25.05 43.95 22.69 38.51 21.25 48.40 20.80 11.21 20.04 14.48 19.28 15.08 20.10 15.46
Jambi 15.45 42.96 15.83 36.76 15.27 35.96 11.16 27.90 29.86 38.11 26.38 37.80 24.15 36.46 27.37 43.29 18.13 9.09 18.44 11.25 18.81 15.15 17.49 14.54
South Sumatera 24.74 47.57 18.03 40.00 18.97 32.82 12.36 31.85 28.81 36.75 30.03 39.02 26.77 44.13 29.59 47.64 14.21 8.04 17.36 10.77 17.08 11.87 16.85 11.76
Bengkulu 14.23 40.79 11.05 38.82 10.55 37.34 9.88 31.68 22.95 34.38 22.70 36.17 20.86 37.40 19.08 39.56 17.23 9.88 17.83 10.60 19.16 10.90 18.71 13.91
Lampung 26.53 48.79 21.61 39.23 17.25 42.02 17.04 31.39 24.56 33.17 26.91 40.50 27.42 36.59 26.36 41.17 14.80 8.34 14.65 9.48 16.22 10.82 17.58 15.41
Bangka Belitung 19.94 35.23 33.29 49.78 17.29 7.85
Jakarta 10.79 8.34 9.05 6.70 26.72 22.77 23.10 21.27 18.53 18.25 17.61 18.15
West Java 21.56 43.27 16.99 35.11 15.38 34.87 14.58 28.68 31.19 44.62 31.59 49.83 32.57 49.20 33.02 55.82 14.13 5.82 15.61 7.04 15.77 8.01 15.70 8.20
Central Java 25.13 42.79 20.63 37.82 19.06 33.71 19.60 32.03 32.76 42.35 33.30 45.27 33.96 46.84 33.05 48.24 14.18 6.70 14.97 7.76 15.69 9.51 15.43 10.06
DI Yogyakarta 20.09 31.11 16.55 29.17 16.86 25.52 13.29 21.28 26.19 40.28 25.38 39.94 25.07 39.37 22.91 42.89 14.62 11.71 14.91 12.63 16.40 14.53 16.18 15.16
East Java 24.65 47.00 16.86 38.74 15.96 34.98 16.33 32.01 29.20 37.11 30.17 42.36 30.50 43.33 31.36 47.43 14.99 7.15 17.18 8.82 18.32 10.62 17.06 10.46
Banten 10.64 36.11 21.74 46.64 18.47 10.33
Bali 17.51 32.10 14.46 25.82 10.39 26.61 12.00 22.39 30.44 40.57
27.91 43.95 28.60 41.18 27.79 42.57 11.22 7.10
11.63 9.70 12.85 10.39 12.40 12.89
West Nusa Tenggara 27.03 46.89 26.40 43.18 30.09 38.91 24.15 34.89 23.59 31.49
23.87 30.54 22.45 30.95 26.46 36.14 12.36 8.10
12.12 9.37 13.65 10.89 12.80 12.50
East Nusa Tenggara 21.48 42.96 17.34 38.70 16.41 40.42 12.67 36.28 24.02 38.26
22.29 40.66 21.37 40.93 21.97 43.69 15.35 6.74
13.39 7.84 15.08 7.43 14.97 8.80
West Kalimantan 28.19 56.88 14.38 28.40 20.16 42.76 17.99 37.02 26.52 26.87
23.83 24.86 23.16 32.98 24.10 36.99 13.67 6.8717.15 14.73 17.48 13.40 16.97 14.04
Central Kalimantan 15.45 30.82 22.05 46.63 12.49 21.20 10.26 21.82 29.25 43.45
21.21 30.33 28.15 47.71 27.29 46.23 15.99 14.57
16.70 10.50 21.53 17.60 19.35 19.49
South Kalimantan 26.32 48.94 11.64 27.85 20.70 42.25 15.64 37.80 27.95 33.60
29.37 44.56 26.16 36.21 27.90 39.15 14.24 7.28
15.51 15.19 15.99 9.67 16.44 11.75
East Kalimantan 19.20 39.86 19.75 43.77 15.08 32.15 11.11 22.92 25.23 33.00
26.81 34.42 22.94 39.08 23.21 41.05 14.38 11.26
15.78 8.72 17.86 14.49 19.08 17.40
North Sulawesi 17.87 35.17 17.30 33.02 14.34 30.21 11.76 24.35 24.80 34.12
23.40 34.42 23.36 36.87 18.25 38.21 17.52 13.01
17.14 13.28 21.35 16.46 19.39 17.25
Central Sulawesi 14.95 36.84 15.90 32.34 11.15 29.66 9.26 22.09 24.25 40.61
21.75 35.57 21.88 41.17 23.09 47.75 15.55 9.73
17.61 14.63 15.66 13.40 16.11 14.81
South Sulawesi 17.31 38.21 13.63 30.48 14.64 31.74 12.56 29.45 24.44 35.96
20.71 41.88 20.11 34.96 20.84 37.39 12.89 10.59
14.79 12.11 14.69 13.41 14.45 14.84
Southeast Sulawesi 19.20 35.10 14.95 35.03 10.08 25.87 10.99 23.82 19.74 35.89
23.14 34.17 19.45 36.51 18.88 36.92 11.97 11.09
14.76 12.37 16.47 16.61 15.89 17.50
Gorontolo 17.35 26.58 22.08 44.20 22.82 38.75 24.72 36.12 14.18 14.65 16.32 9.71
Maluku 11.88 34.93 7.78 29.35 2.06 1.35 26.07 42.94 24.88 45.28 18.27 52.70 16.21 11.97 19.16 11.98 17.90 12.83
North Maluku 13.56 12.82 19.05 56.37 20.63 14.52
Irian Jaya 15.18 36.66 8.96 32.77 8.06 34.87 1.88 2.21 18.85 36.71 20.25 37.28 27.54 41.88 13.85 53.32 18.46 11.09 17.83 12.62 19.12 11.78 17.71 24.46
INDONESIA 20.44 43.15 15.86 36.25 15.2 34.4 13.9 30.1 28.6 38.6 28.24 42.06 28.7 42.4 28.10 45.90 15.6 8.25 16.6 9.93 16.9 11.2 16.91 12.17
Source: SUSENAS, several years
Notes: Population defined as over 24 years old
Missing values due to civil unrest or governmental changes (as several provinces developed post 1999)
Sample size for all individual SUSENAS data: 1995 - 873,647; 1998 - 879,936;2000 – 780,141; 2002 – 862,210

1
Table 1. Highest Level of Education, cont.

Senior Secondary School Higher Education


1995 1998 2000 2002 1995 1998 2000 2002
Province Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural
Aceh 36.41 12.91 35.39 14.78 44.99 11.97 3.29 11.22 3.45 23.12
North Sumatera 25.40 9.54 31.99 13.08 34.71 14.62 35.55 16.77 6.99 1.18 7.90 1.49 9.18 1.74 9.14 2.18
West Sumatera 33.27 12.77 34.77 14.20 34.45 15.39 34.79 15.57 11.87 2.36 13.57 3.25 15.01 3.26 15.89 4.60
Riau 32.54 9.45 35.24 9.75 36.73 11.14 42.41 12.56 7.55 1.50 9.16 1.41 9.70 1.34 9.68 1.87
Jambi 28.00 8.95 29.92 11.95 31.14 10.68 33.39 11.52 8.56 0.89 9.42 2.25 10.62 1.75 10.59 2.75
South Sumatera 25.70 6.82 28.04 8.84 26.80 9.98 31.71 7.68 6.53 0.82 6.53 1.37 10.38 1.19 9.49 1.06
Bengkulu 34.35 13.20 36.66 12.97 38.29 12.21 37.09 12.70 11.25 1.74 11.77 1.43 11.14 2.16 15.24 2.15
Lampung 24.36 8.44 26.10 9.64 30.39 9.26 28.48 10.25 9.74 1.26 10.74 1.14 8.72 1.33 10.54 1.78
Bangka Belitung 24.14 5.52 5.34 1.63
Jakarta 33.22 37.36 36.04 36.78 10.73 13.29 14.20 17.10
West Java 25.60 5.64 27.17 6.49 28.12 6.64 27.31 5.60 7.53 0.66 8.63 1.54 8.16 1.28 9.38 1.70
Central Java 22.00 6.92 23.37 7.43 23.53 8.19 22.35 7.44 5.93 1.25 7.72 1.72 7.76 1.74 9.57 2.24
DI Yogyakarta 28.67 14.43 29.72 14.85 29.73 16.11 32.10 16.48 10.43 2.46 13.45 3.42 11.94 4.46 15.52 4.20
East Java 23.88 7.30 27.63 8.26 27.32 9.15 26.07 7.99 7.28 1.44 8.16 1.82 7.90 1.92 9.19 2.11
Banten 35.08 6.18 14.07 0.74
Bali 30.85 16.08 32.56 16.65 35.61 18.14 33.03 17.66 9.98 4.15 13.45 3.88 12.56 3.68 14.79 4.50
West Nusa Tenggara 25.54 11.65 28.24 13.47 26.92 15.45 27.11 14.06 11.48 1.87 9.38 3.45 6.88 3.80 9.47 2.41
East Nusa Tenggara 28.05 9.73 35.74 10.76 36.55 9.30 36.69 9.08 11.09 2.31 11.24 2.03 10.58 1.92 13.70 2.16
West Kalimantan 27.03 8.62 33.33 27.70 28.70 9.64 30.24 10.25 4.59 0.76 11.31 4.31 10.50 1.23 10.69 1.70
Central Kalimantan 29.05 10.26 29.92 11.06 29.61 12.27 32.89 10.69 10.26 0.91 10.13 1.47 8.21 1.23 10.22 1.77
South Kalimantan 24.94 9.06 32.55 11.44 29.32 10.49 29.95 8.81 6.55 1.12 10.93 0.96 7.82 1.39 10.07 2.50
East Kalimantan 31.61 14.33 28.84 11.44 34.87 13.01 36.83 16.00 9.59 1.56 8.81 1.66 9.24 1.27 9.77 2.64
North Sulawesi 31.88 15.01 32.62 16.65 33.14 14.16 39.86 17.83 7.93 2.69 9.53 2.63 7.81 2.29 10.74 2.36
Central Sulawesi 32.12 11.40 34.90 14.44 37.88 14.03 38.15 12.90 13.13 1.42 9.84 3.02 13.43 1.74 13.39 2.45
South Sulawesi 32.54 12.71 36.44 12.97 37.13 16.39 37.92 14.61 12.81 2.52 14.42 2.56 13.43 3.50 14.22 3.72
Southeast Sulawesi 33.80 15.71 34.02 15.30 39.54 18.33 38.18 17.75 15.29 2.21 13.14 3.13 14.46 2.68 16.06 4.01
Gorontolo 33.35 17.08 29.51 7.73 12.31 2.93 7.36 2.24
Maluku 36.17 9.20 38.32 11.36 45.34 27.72 9.68 0.95 9.85 2.04 16.43 5.40
North Maluku 36.82 15.43 9.93 0.86
Irian Jaya 35.04 12.97 42.62 14.05 36.35 10.02 50.37 15.56 12.47 2.57 10.33 3.27 8.93 1.44 16.19 4.45
INDONESIA 27.11 8.57 29.76 9.81 29.72 10.16 30.03 9.65 8.27 1.42 9.58 1.94 9.41 1.85 11.05 2.20
Source: SUSENAS, several years
Note: Population defined as over 24 years old.
Missing values due to civil unrest or governmental changes (as several provinces developed post 1999)

2
Table 2. Net and Gross Primary Enrollment Rates, by Gender

Net Primary Enrollment Gross Primary Enrollment


1995 1998 2000 2002 1995 1998 2000 2002
Province Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female
Aceh 91.43 92.55 93.23 93.12 91.49 92.42 106.25 104.53 106.72 106.09 97.88 96.62
North Sumatera 93.75 93.90 93.87 93.77 94.47 93.97 93.99 93.59 109.02 109.25 111.32 108.79 110.32 108.99 107.71 106.89
West Sumatera 91.84 92.64 92.57 92.45 92.86 92.44 92.38 92.22 107.66 107.09 107.92 107.33 110.40 107.59 104.11 103.91
Riau 95.31 93.15 94.12 94.31 94.11 93.77 94.16 94.29 112.27 109.58 108.19 108.92 108.46 107.40 107.88 106.88
Jambi 90.86 91.12 91.34 90.61 92.52 93.05 93.70 92.43 106.75 104.04 106.14 104.66 108.67 109.74 108.79 106.87
South Sumatera 89.20 89.74 91.16 91.75 92.48 92.07 91.84 91.19 104.82 104.81 107.35 105.52 108.28 105.42 108.45 107.49
Bengkulu 92.20 90.55 91.97 92.12 91.82 91.20 92.44 92.54 110.57 106.55 111.65 106.28 109.14 105.24 107.37 107.50
Lampung 91.25 92.57 93.08 91.94 93.56 92.80 92.91 93.26 105.88 108.54 107.03 106.84 113.45 110.15 106.54 105.42
Bangka Belitung 92.49 94.39 108.56 107.60
Jakarta 93.56 92.75 93.01 92.47 91.28 91.62 89.96 91.62 110.00 107.28 108.75 108.12 105.72 108.59 102.85 105.99
West Java 90.36 91.37 92.53 93.11 92.35 92.97 93.59 94.07 103.14 103.75 105.22 105.60 105.09 104.39 104.34 104.58
Central Java 94.27 93.63 94.31 94.30 93.98 93.74 94.46 93.70 111.37 109.19 110.80 110.75 111.80 110.22 108.54 107.79
DI Yogyakarta 95.25 95.75 92.91 95.20 93.49 95.25 93.41 93.03 115.02 111.04 110.32 110.48 109.93 110.69 106.36 103.06
East Java 93.44 92.49 93.07 91.55 92.24 92.43 93.15 93.24 110.28 107.80 110.41 106.52 108.32 107.03 107.15 107.30
Banten 92.49 93.74 103.27 105.26
Bali 93.67 93.33 94.03 93.06 93.68 93.01 93.28 90.98 106.45 107.23 110.77 110.76 108.55 109.50 106.48 103.31
West Nusa Tenggara 87.38 89.74 90.69 91.52 88.19 91.65 92.70 93.77 100.82 102.38 101.63 101.54 102.10 102.32 102.20 104.72
East Nusa Tenggara 84.71 86.67 86.52 88.74 87.96 90.00 86.59 87.59 104.97 108.51 109.89 111.34 110.88 110.50 106.45 107.02
East Timor 72.93 70.64 70.68 69.55 93.83 92.34 90.19 90.21
West Kalimantan 84.65 84.53 88.02 89.09 90.02 89.04 89.95 88.94 106.69 108.09 112.51 111.06 107.73 111.54 110.53 107.18
Central Kalimantan 94.39 94.39 94.68 93.00 93.77 94.83 94.23 93.78 110.10 114.92 116.55 113.23 111.17 113.65 110.39 112.54
South Kalimantan 92.07 91.70 93.17 92.12 92.15 92.77 90.92 92.53 109.22 107.66 110.35 107.23 108.43 107.73 103.58 104.55
East Kalimantan 93.19 91.10 92.93 92.09 90.83 92.15 92.21 91.57 114.03 113.26 113.18 110.15 108.50 114.51 108.29 107.90
North Sulawesi 87.64 87.94 90.06 90.86 90.04 90.79 87.67 87.74 105.00 105.04 109.95 111.64 109.05 107.66 101.64 105.85
Central Sulawesi 89.46 92.95 90.04 89.74 90.60 91.59 89.81 90.49 104.28 110.16 108.08 108.59 106.80 110.96 104.88 106.94
South Sulawesi 85.46 87.75 85.75 88.33 88.13 89.08 88.84 89.11 100.45 100.86 98.98 103.08 102.65 103.90 100.60 100.40
Southeast Sulawesi 88.74 88.43 89.93 90.49 88.57 90.43 90.60 88.77 106.64 107.04 106.22 106.65 103.90 103.00 104.20 102.83
Gorontolo 78.15 83.84 88.13 98.17
Maluku 92.07 92.33 90.77 91.53 87.42 86.42 112.84 112.95 106.88 108.25 98.52 109.51
Irian Jaya 81.17 77.69 79.16 79.77 81.03 82.77 95.46 94.33 103.35 97.61 98.45 97.58 104.30 101.41 106.29 107.40
North Maluku 94.53 90.59 116.07 103.92

INDONESIA 91.38 91.53 92.05 92.11 92.13 92.45 92.65 92.75 107.31 106.67 107.95 107.22 108.03 107.30 105.98 105.98
Source: SUSENAS, several years
Note: Missing values due to civil unrest or governmental changes (as several provinces developed post 1999)

3
Table 3. Net and Gross Junior Secondary Enrollment Rates, by Gender

Net Junior Secondary Enrollment Gross Junior Secondary Enrollment


1995 1998 2000 2002 1995 1998 2000 2002
Province Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female
Aceh 53.59 50.85 58.89 57.65 76.37 83.93 67.65 63.67 74.90 69.68 98.17 101.81
North Sumatera 61.80 60.06 61.29 65.28 66.47 68.02 67.94 70.21 77.84 74.85 83.32 82.51 82.78 85.02 87.19 88.97
West Sumatera 52.91 62.19 59.17 65.02 59.47 66.59 62.15 69.77 73.85 79.34 77.37 85.40 81.02 87.11 85.01 93.84
Riau 52.69 48.97 57.03 60.72 61.03 64.54 63.67 64.07 68.20 63.92 72.53 73.61 80.35 85.94 85.02 81.67
Jambi 46.68 47.03 53.35 52.25 56.04 56.92 61.88 60.18 61.54 59.93 77.17 71.90 80.23 77.08 80.36 79.10
South Sumatera 45.55 43.24 54.95 54.46 58.34 60.85 53.81 53.33 60.86 57.02 73.46 68.16 76.70 75.44 72.25 72.27
Bengkulu 48.58 51.98 46.74 55.33 55.89 58.87 58.72 59.57 65.61 67.38 64.46 71.37 74.78 77.15 76.59 78.01
Lampung 52.33 54.56 56.22 57.55 57.04 61.89 60.74 64.93 69.27 67.78 74.54 77.06 73.67 82.11 79.88 84.20
Bangka Belitung 42.33 48.24 58.33 61.07
Jakarta 72.98 71.04 76.86 75.01 79.34 74.90 79.46 75.54 97.62 93.43 101.57 95.74 102.93 93.11 104.39 96.76
West Java 47.61 47.57 53.01 56.21 56.73 58.78 60.98 60.57 61.64 58.16 66.33 68.38 71.83 72.36 75.87 76.09
Central Java 50.63 53.86 59.51 62.34 60.60 64.62 62.99 66.50 64.85 68.19 76.23 77.46 79.70 81.30 81.68 83.74
DI Yogyakarta 66.06 72.16 69.72 72.56 72.31 78.74 75.53 77.71 86.83 89.36 89.29 89.77 90.30 93.25 100.80 100.10
East Java 52.28 52.19 58.78 59.15 62.07 64.68 62.49 64.87 68.11 65.43 75.58 75.27 83.58 83.21 83.38 83.77
Banten 61.20 60.30 75.26 73.53
Bali 66.15 58.08 71.22 64.18 74.85 65.52 69.24 67.53 87.22 70.09 91.17 81.98 91.58 78.18 90.28 88.36
West Nusa Tenggara 40.46 38.74 48.94 50.22 58.63 57.77 59.51 55.81 52.62 48.33 61.99 61.55 77.81 69.39 74.33 69.03
East Nusa Tenggara 29.43 27.24 31.97 34.53 32.02 36.59 37.12 40.23 44.45 38.91 47.84 50.30 48.55 54.63 57.04 61.68
East Timor 29.37 24.58 33.50 34.41 52.84 45.86 57.26 52.69
West Kalimantan 33.98 34.19 39.61 42.23 49.09 44.95 43.33 46.79 49.58 53.86 61.25 60.37 68.10 64.16 62.82 64.01
Central Kalimantan 49.96 50.58 46.09 46.60 59.58 62.07 54.07 51.41 64.95 67.89 64.46 63.89 78.48 79.23 66.85 70.27
South Kalimantan 44.64 46.66 51.96 52.65 50.02 53.73 56.33 55.39 57.16 56.50 70.23 69.62 63.61 67.16 75.15 75.32
East Kalimantan 53.96 59.05 60.59 56.88 62.11 58.56 59.26 65.84 71.08 76.77 76.83 77.14 85.42 78.30 85.65 89.16
North Sulawesi 47.65 54.26 54.38 56.15 61.68 64.69 66.27 67.13 62.15 72.31 68.02 69.48 78.88 80.36 87.34 87.84
Central Sulawesi 44.13 42.50 45.79 50.86 48.70 48.40 49.21 53.51 55.84 50.65 63.14 62.08 66.38 60.78 69.85 72.11
South Sulawesi 43.56 45.52 48.69 48.20 50.62 54.26 51.44 54.97 56.91 57.01 62.75 59.78 66.12 69.07 65.58 71.95
Southeast Sulawesi 48.28 48.68 55.22 56.99 56.91 64.63 55.21 61.64 60.66 65.52 71.78 76.07 76.12 81.59 74.37 83.47
Gorontolo 42.97 41.85 59.99 56.59
Maluku 46.19 46.00 57.92 56.06 70.94 74.29 63.84 63.09 79.41 73.38 95.95 101.75
Irian Jaya 40.43 38.92 40.76 44.88 31.45 39.77 82.10 83.20 65.32 55.47 64.55 64.53 50.53 59.35 96.24 100.53
North Maluku 66.88 77.64 84.72 98.27
INDONESIA 50.70 51.24 56.25 58.04 59.06 61.56 60.92 62.51 66.34 64.94 73.31 73.38 77.24 78.02 79.35 80.41
Source: SUSENAS, several years
Note: Missing values due to civil unrest or governmental changes (as several provinces developed post 1999)

4
Table 4. Net and Gross Senior Secondary Enrollment Rates, by Gender

Net Senior Secondary Enrollment Gross Senior Secondary Enrollment


1995 1998 2000 2002 1995 1998 2000 2002
Province Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female
Aceh 32.01 29.20 37.19 35.90 77.39 76.77 44.05 37.04 46.94 45.16 90.48 94.12
North Sumatera 43.05 41.86 45.20 49.40 49.58 52.98 49.31 48.88 57.20 53.61 57.54 62.08 65.00 65.91 60.87 61.30
West Sumatera 36.05 44.89 44.37 51.05 44.36 53.33 45.60 51.89 47.95 56.44 54.18 64.65 61.82 68.24 59.39 66.02
Riau 27.37 27.05 32.94 34.24 38.80 40.33 39.28 42.10 36.91 35.09 42.40 43.32 53.35 50.92 52.44 51.26
Jambi 24.91 26.90 26.43 31.14 36.13 35.99 36.42 35.00 36.24 34.41 34.65 40.42 44.61 43.80 44.81 44.39
South Sumatera 23.34 28.09 32.29 33.26 35.43 39.63 33.88 34.76 32.11 36.61 41.54 41.79 46.06 51.25 46.15 45.56
Bengkulu 29.01 38.15 34.77 40.37 35.01 44.63 29.77 43.95 40.86 47.70 45.39 50.57 48.04 57.31 38.66 57.93
Lampung 29.92 30.71 30.31 28.76 31.79 30.74 30.55 31.49 38.70 38.14 38.80 40.42 42.99 40.01 38.20 39.13
Bangka Belitung 36.92 33.82 50.06 45.90
Jakarta 60.99 47.99 67.96 60.80 60.85 56.93 65.39 50.56 83.12 62.54 88.36 76.43 81.04 72.77 79.37 62.18
West Java 28.80 25.69 34.97 33.71 35.93 36.05 35.24 30.66 37.52 32.24 44.81 41.26 45.83 42.65 44.07 36.00
Central Java 34.12 30.21 35.05 35.60 38.09 38.63 38.97 37.36 43.57 36.73 43.96 42.79 49.79 47.09 49.65 47.19
DI Yogyakarta 52.48 56.79 56.82 57.46 58.91 63.09 56.45 60.85 76.99 70.42 75.36 69.71 76.54 75.46 72.90 78.41
East Java 35.11 30.67 38.22 36.82 39.65 41.41 39.03 38.80 45.62 38.45 48.23 45.46 51.49 50.59 50.77 48.30
Banten 38.17 37.36 46.75 46.07
Bali 49.72 40.88 53.40 47.33 53.00 54.82 55.27 46.09 63.77 52.44 64.44 57.99 66.41 69.56 68.93 57.21
West Nusa Tenggara 27.78 24.02 30.54 24.12 33.80 36.64 36.44 35.37 39.36 29.44 36.10 29.64 45.03 49.29 41.85 40.43
East Nusa Tenggara 17.76 16.12 23.18 21.51 20.57 20.39 20.10 23.50 30.65 24.60 36.18 29.77 30.92 29.07 30.78 31.74
East Timor 18.26 17.86 19.48 23.65 43.38 36.70 41.42 37.45
West Kalimantan 21.15 18.75 24.90 26.11 20.75 26.50 23.22 26.18 30.68 26.04 35.99 35.02 28.37 37.40 31.86 34.66
Central Kalimantan 31.30 32.27 23.57 29.95 34.25 33.36 30.11 30.56 38.90 38.80 30.73 40.58 43.86 42.22 40.10 41.64
South Kalimantan 24.07 26.91 30.83 30.26 30.53 31.57 28.76 27.21 33.74 34.03 38.62 37.70 40.20 37.02 35.65 33.30
East Kalimantan 39.08 39.71 44.39 42.66 44.92 39.57 41.57 48.30 51.45 48.84 57.74 58.05 67.89 55.02 59.40 63.65
North Sulawesi 28.94 32.88 35.85 38.76 41.15 38.20 39.50 47.98 38.82 44.71 46.88 49.70 50.86 49.44 51.24 63.06
Central Sulawesi 26.40 29.10 24.88 30.56 29.43 31.68 25.49 28.31 33.98 37.62 34.93 37.98 39.72 38.54 35.97 38.55
South Sulawesi 28.19 32.86 33.59 32.37 34.60 35.44 35.88 33.28 40.16 41.33 43.89 40.27 46.01 47.05 44.62 41.26
Southeast Sulawesi 35.21 35.32 36.93 36.96 35.60 41.14 32.50 39.61 46.60 44.70 47.53 49.87 44.46 53.33 44.83 44.78
Gorontolo 19.31 27.01 27.21 39.31
Maluku 34.28 36.53 39.25 44.23 71.69 63.78 44.67 51.26 52.73 54.95 93.63 83.92
Irian Jaya 23.75 26.75 29.73 32.92 28.61 31.93 74.81 78.28 38.35 38.00 45.04 42.82 45.47 39.80 95.10 95.09
North Maluku 70.94 69.66 88.24 88.89
INDONESIA 33.47 31.70 37.46 37.45 38.63 40.07 38.79 37.68 44.60 40.21 48.08 46.78 50.66 49.76 49.39 46.89
Source: SUSENAS
Note: Missing values due to civil unrest or governmental changes (as several provinces developed post 1999)

5
Table 5. Net and Gross Primary Enrollment Rates, by location

Net Primary Enrollment Gross Primary Enrollment


1995 1998 2000 2002 1995 1998 2000 2002
Province Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural
Aceh 92.38 91.90 92.23 93.43 91.91 105.42 105.39 108.02 105.99 97.30
North Sumatera 94.06 93.69 92.60 94.62 93.86 94.47 93.31 94.11 107.12 110.27 109.88 110.25 107.57 111.05 106.12 108.10
West Sumatera 92.04 92.27 93.10 92.33 91.85 92.92 90.82 92.92 109.12 106.92 109.08 107.19 107.10 109.69 101.89 104.89
Riau 96.23 93.39 93.58 94.50 93.99 93.92 94.31 94.17 112.21 110.40 109.45 108.11 106.89 108.59 107.10 107.61
Jambi 91.72 90.76 91.69 90.74 89.33 93.74 90.38 94.14 107.31 104.85 107.35 104.75 105.12 110.32 103.78 109.46
South Sumatera 89.42 89.49 91.22 91.53 90.43 93.10 89.70 92.43 106.40 104.25 109.68 105.31 106.04 107.24 106.62 108.65
Bengkulu 92.50 91.10 90.67 92.48 93.24 90.89 89.84 93.57 109.21 108.44 107.25 109.60 106.30 107.48 103.49 109.05
Lampung 92.58 91.77 92.45 92.54 93.86 93.05 94.21 92.79 109.81 106.72 108.39 106.69 108.19 112.75 104.64 106.34
Bangka Belitung 89.88 95.35 103.34 110.68
Jakarta 93.17 92.75 91.45 90.73 108.69 108.45 107.13 104.31
West Java 91.45 90.46 93.60 92.20 92.74 92.58 93.15 94.53 104.82 102.55 107.52 103.80 105.90 103.76 104.92 103.96
Central Java 93.92 93.98 94.26 94.33 93.25 94.21 93.27 94.67 110.47 110.24 110.23 111.02 109.80 111.73 106.79 109.13
DI Yogyakarta 96.48 94.54 92.47 95.59 94.50 94.16 93.31 93.14 114.17 111.99 106.25 114.72 109.09 111.52 104.48 105.10
East Java 93.89 92.61 93.36 91.84 93.69 91.48 93.46 93.02 108.77 109.19 108.43 108.56 108.38 107.26 107.16 107.27
Banten 94.07 92.11 105.95 102.49
Bali 93.10 93.70 93.24 93.76 92.10 94.30 91.80 92.58 109.71 105.53 111.09 110.59 108.41 109.43 105.68 104.28
West Nusa Tenggara 91.07 88.08 92.47 90.80 87.13 91.13 94.12 92.74 102.92 101.35 104.25 101.05 99.51 103.45 105.41 102.37
East Nusa Tenggara 90.60 85.00 90.73 87.18 89.80 88.80 89.89 86.59 108.90 106.39 111.81 110.44 106.82 111.31 106.43 106.77
East Timor 83.40 70.88 89.98 68.11 111.27 91.60 110.84 88.09
West Kalimantan 92.28 82.94 88.56 88.53 91.36 89.03 90.18 89.25 116.46 105.36 110.39 112.14 110.93 109.29 107.27 109.42
Central Kalimantan 90.54 95.30 92.74 94.09 93.99 94.34 91.46 94.90 103.70 114.33 114.12 115.05 108.68 113.41 105.82 113.36
South Kalimantan 92.97 91.47 91.78 93.02 91.37 92.92 91.40 91.86 107.77 108.71 106.45 109.79 105.88 109.06 102.64 104.80
East Kalimantan 92.11 92.23 91.88 93.14 91.37 91.50 91.56 92.33 110.12 116.81 108.27 114.99 111.70 110.83 106.56 109.99
North Sulawesi 90.06 87.06 87.60 91.35 88.93 91.03 85.75 88.75 111.68 102.91 107.33 111.85 109.96 107.71 106.41 101.95
Central Sulawesi 91.59 90.90 89.78 89.94 90.59 91.19 86.97 90.78 108.39 106.59 104.98 109.25 104.76 109.68 103.72 106.29
South Sulawesi 90.78 85.25 89.05 86.24 88.52 88.60 88.83 89.02 106.10 98.93 101.24 100.79 101.53 103.84 100.01 100.69
Southeast Sulawesi 89.35 88.41 89.09 90.54 89.29 89.50 90.33 89.60 108.28 106.49 106.78 106.32 103.51 103.46 103.83 103.48
Gorontolo 85.95 79.06 101.19 89.96
Maluku 91.35 92.36 88.57 91.82 86.73 87.76 114.42 112.57 103.85 108.51 104.73 100.04
Irian Jaya 87.48 77.58 93.16 75.63 91.24 79.10 95.92 81.14 103.56 100.00 107.42 95.48 105.66 102.15 108.14 87.38
North Maluku 90.99 100.00 110.43 107.99
INDONESIA 92.64 90.90 92.85 91.69 92.49 92.16 92.55 92.80 107.88 106.59 108.29 107.24 107.19 107.97 105.54 106.30
Source: SUSENAS, several years
Note: Missing values due to civil unrest or governmental changes

6
Table 6. Net and Gross Junior Secondary Enrollment Rates, by Location

Net Junior Secondary Enrollment Gross Junior Secondary Enrollment


1995 1998 2000 2002 1995 1998 2000 2002
Province Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural
Aceh 69.16 48.70 69.15 55.39 80.19 88.62 60.89 92.53 66.94 100.01
North Sumatera 69.81 55.95 67.61 60.33 74.10 62.95 73.96 65.50 87.45 70.15 91.61 77.08 95.10 76.90 96.10 82.28
West Sumatera 70.72 53.61 72.15 58.53 70.03 60.78 73.50 62.93 97.89 70.24 93.83 76.96 95.09 80.52 100.23 85.04
Riau 70.67 41.77 71.86 52.79 73.32 56.08 76.57 56.12 91.58 54.39 90.93 64.77 95.35 75.33 98.18 74.39
Jambi 73.39 36.93 68.78 45.84 72.90 50.82 73.72 55.97 94.45 48.18 97.10 64.78 100.87 70.87 100.37 71.49
South Sumatera 62.47 36.21 68.35 48.35 67.19 55.80 70.72 44.89 82.95 48.07 89.77 61.94 88.96 69.57 99.65 58.39
Bengkulu 70.53 43.63 68.69 44.71 70.00 52.23 68.50 55.14 91.59 58.25 94.20 58.58 90.46 70.06 94.41 69.98
Lampung 65.79 51.07 69.77 54.36 66.09 57.53 69.70 61.07 80.59 66.24 94.28 72.17 86.42 75.29 93.00 79.22
Bangka Belitung 64.16 30.96 87.27 39.01
Jakarta 71.99 75.89 77.01 77.49 95.48 98.52 97.78 100.55
West Java 64.44 35.25 67.84 43.08 68.15 48.12 70.08 50.05 81.34 44.19 83.82 53.07 86.67 58.71 89.45 60.39
Central Java 63.54 46.91 69.60 56.19 69.60 58.22 70.28 60.76 81.01 59.70 87.43 71.12 89.92 74.60 90.92 76.84
DI Yogyakarta 72.89 65.38 78.06 63.26 78.85 71.46 78.55 74.26 92.05 84.27 97.95 79.94 96.44 86.26 100.50 100.39
East Java 66.37 45.13 72.03 51.91 74.15 55.88 73.42 56.68 82.58 58.89 92.06 66.47 94.97 75.44 96.19 74.56
Banten 76.51 44.00 91.40 56.33
Bali 68.76 59.02 75.14 63.68 73.77 68.10 73.18 63.66 89.87 73.43 92.63 83.48 91.93 80.34 99.18 79.55
West Nusa Tenggara 53.92 36.63 55.22 48.32 59.83 57.31 61.82 54.97 70.68 46.34 68.10 60.34 78.95 70.59 77.81 67.72
East Nusa Tenggara 64.45 21.48 64.21 27.00 68.17 27.21 68.19 32.68 90.74 32.40 89.89 40.83 94.98 42.50 95.99 51.90
East Timor 40.05 25.73 56.06 31.47 73.01 47.03 88.13 51.34
West Kalimantan 61.13 26.08 56.05 36.77 66.65 40.13 66.50 37.97 86.09 41.38 86.45 53.87 90.81 57.46 93.21 53.66
Central Kalimantan 73.68 43.77 63.42 41.47 71.99 56.99 66.74 47.87 99.53 57.18 88.55 57.22 91.30 74.69 92.00 60.10
South Kalimantan 65.61 37.47 67.53 45.52 66.08 44.80 72.51 48.38 80.44 47.10 90.10 60.96 83.22 56.54 97.12 65.34
East Kalimantan 72.28 43.12 70.53 47.05 65.43 53.45 67.77 56.63 93.14 57.61 90.56 63.48 87.78 73.92 95.23 78.40
North Sulawesi 63.15 47.35 66.52 50.97 74.24 58.44 70.76 64.23 86.36 61.59 87.05 61.84 97.08 72.20 96.23 82.39
Central Sulawesi 69.60 35.59 66.37 42.71 66.57 43.96 67.14 47.52 85.50 43.69 84.25 55.95 82.35 58.82 96.88 64.70
South Sulawesi 61.10 38.83 64.71 41.66 62.58 48.53 66.27 48.04 75.80 50.48 80.29 53.33 79.69 62.97 88.48 60.95
Southeast Sulawesi 70.33 42.00 61.84 53.98 66.32 59.22 76.08 53.91 88.25 55.53 83.56 70.35 91.17 75.75 99.80 73.59
Gorontolo 61.42 34.50 79.99 49.32
Maluku 69.41 38.79 76.66 50.62 73.15 71.37 94.46 53.76 105.41 67.21 96.83 109.37
Irian Jaya 68.10 30.73 73.70 31.66 66.69 24.57 84.50 57.22 95.30 49.77 103.17 50.96 103.84 37.91 97.40 114.60
North Maluku 68.10 30.73 72.74 68.87 93.66 75.15
INDONESIA 66.51 42.65 69.74 49.63 70.53 53.44 71.90 54.13 85.19 55.21 89.44 63.78 90.82 68.83 93.53 69.74
Source: SUSENAS, several years
Note: Missing values due to civil unrest or governmental changes

7
Table 7. Net and Gross Senior Secondary Enrollment Rates, by Location

Net Senior Secondary Enrollment Gross Senior Secondary Enrollment


1995 1998 2000 2002 1995 1998 2000 2002
Province Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural
Aceh 57.13 23.44 55.77 30.49 77.11 75.23 31.17 74.86 36.98 92.13
North Sumatera 55.62 32.70 60.55 36.12 63.55 42.34 58.42 41.02 71.02 43.86 76.77 45.50 81.39 53.87 73.34 50.42
West Sumatera 57.59 33.30 66.94 38.86 67.50 40.34 65.26 41.02 74.98 42.56 82.20 49.01 88.61 54.30 87.10 51.41
Riau 51.47 15.52 55.30 22.42 61.41 25.12 58.35 28.30 69.72 19.77 71.24 28.25 81.43 32.75 73.60 36.63
Jambi 58.07 13.32 55.10 15.99 63.13 23.11 58.84 25.30 78.83 18.38 70.88 21.34 77.52 28.25 73.83 31.43
South Sumatera 47.74 14.42 55.33 20.11 58.65 23.99 59.52 18.02 63.64 19.40 71.36 25.03 78.11 29.82 81.79 22.65
Bengkulu 62.18 22.41 63.82 25.38 66.86 27.00 59.32 24.55 77.43 31.36 82.32 32.14 86.18 36.93 78.90 31.52
Lampung 57.65 23.78 51.85 23.42 58.50 23.24 47.54 25.79 69.06 31.15 66.37 32.14 79.11 30.53 62.45 31.16
Bangka Belitung 57.49 12.41 78.76 16.03
Jakarta 53.87 64.21 58.83 57.44 71.86 82.12 76.76 70.15
West Java 42.27 14.01 49.52 18.87 49.17 20.50 45.12 17.64 54.25 17.85 62.70 23.03 62.02 23.54 55.10 21.17
Central Java 46.28 24.19 50.45 26.09 50.62 29.17 48.98 29.31 58.25 29.98 62.60 31.69 64.58 36.33 63.87 35.78
DI Yogyakarta 58.05 49.79 61.81 50.67 64.40 54.81 63.23 50.67 80.39 63.85 78.45 64.29 79.27 70.02 82.62 63.53
East Java 49.74 22.69 56.07 25.32 58.64 26.86 53.80 26.73 63.30 29.19 70.82 31.09 73.95 33.85 69.17 33.53
Banten 58.06 15.72 70.98 19.70
Bali 62.57 34.82 64.52 40.25 62.92 45.15 61.31 38.00 77.70 46.28 81.17 46.88 80.15 56.12 75.90 47.81
West Nusa Tenggara 47.26 18.52 41.65 23.21 49.19 27.07 48.33 27.94 62.84 24.29 51.42 27.56 71.07 33.23 55.96 31.64
East Nusa Tenggara 53.86 8.40 58.32 10.49 59.85 9.97 62.19 10.33 88.66 13.44 82.24 16.59 86.63 14.91 85.21 15.90
East Timor 35.98 15.82 43.91 17.36 72.04 36.16 74.32 33.45
West Kalimantan 51.77 10.07 50.96 15.96 48.41 12.38 49.21 15.96 73.27 14.38 72.71 21.59 66.89 17.42 64.10 22.27
Central Kalimantan 61.74 18.33 54.74 15.32 62.90 20.32 54.01 18.95 77.67 21.48 70.42 21.42 78.53 26.60 72.98 25.44
South Kalimantan 50.03 15.46 52.80 18.67 50.48 19.97 44.89 18.05 70.04 19.28 64.83 23.93 62.51 24.94 53.40 23.36
East Kalimantan 56.37 20.70 59.80 24.32 57.10 19.77 56.09 29.06 72.26 25.62 78.26 33.86 80.52 32.72 75.60 41.55
North Sulawesi 50.05 24.82 50.33 31.22 52.85 34.13 56.58 34.59 65.55 34.19 69.47 38.50 66.76 43.05 76.97 43.07
Central Sulawesi 60.76 16.39 60.13 14.58 58.06 20.61 58.52 18.02 77.28 21.52 77.75 19.93 77.59 25.28 80.65 25.11
South Sulawesi 54.80 19.82 54.87 21.76 53.61 26.34 53.49 25.21 73.99 25.94 71.23 27.07 73.95 33.72 66.91 31.07
Southeast Sulawesi 63.71 23.02 61.19 25.31 66.62 27.03 65.48 27.14 82.45 29.76 77.89 34.65 81.76 35.63 80.98 33.41
Gorontolo 44.85 13.42 65.16 18.92
Maluku 65.79 21.25 73.42 24.54 73.85 43.84 90.09 28.35 91.87 33.13 98.20 51.80
Irian Jaya 54.91 12.61 60.65 15.09 58.48 14.82 79.55 37.39 82.57 19.62 83.36 22.00 83.71 20.08 98.46 49.85
North Maluku 73.48 44.64 93.19 50.22
INDONESIA 50.01 20.86 55.48 24.20 55.15 26.36 52.95 25.41 65.12 27.13 70.65 30.36 71.05 33.15 67.10 31.64
Source: SUSENAS, several years
Note: Missing values due to civil unrest or governmental changes

8
Table 8. Percent of Primary Students Enrolled, by Type of School

Primary School Students Enrolled Primary School Students Enrolled


Public School Private School Public Madrasah Private Madrasah
Province 1995 1998 2000 2002 1995 1998 2000 2002 1995 1998 2000 2002 1995 1998 2000 2002
Aceh 87.47 91.16 76.70 0.91 1.78 4.73 10.18 6.02 18.58 1.44 1.04 0.00
North Sumatera 86.25 86.39 85.40 87.22 11.21 11.85 13.55 11.50 0.97 0.91 0.57 0.94 1.58 0.85 0.48 0.33
West Sumatera 96.14 96.57 96.51 96.00 2.02 2.54 2.90 2.96 1.03 0.54 0.39 0.88 0.82 0.35 0.20 0.15
Riau 95.92 91.60 91.34 92.79 2.01 5.24 7.28 5.25 0.61 0.94 0.28 1.45 1.46 2.22 1.10 0.51
Jambi 97.30 95.56 96.64 96.09 1.57 2.13 1.91 1.99 0.97 1.20 0.96 1.36 0.16 1.10 0.48 0.57
South Sumatera 93.10 93.82 93.49 92.27 2.47 4.44 4.38 5.72 1.26 0.59 0.41 1.18 3.17 1.15 1.73 0.83
Bengkulu 96.19 98.20 97.26 96.23 0.39 1.00 1.78 1.29 1.00 0.63 0.81 2.20 2.42 0.17 0.15 0.28
Lampung 91.74 93.97 91.25 90.55 1.65 3.25 3.49 4.56 2.51 0.79 0.66 1.27 4.09 1.99 4.61 3.62
Bangka Belitung 91.54 4.35 3.92 0.19
Jakarta 79.13 78.16 79.49 80.69 13.11 17.09 17.54 16.31 2.04 0.99 0.65 1.27 5.72 3.76 2.32 1.73
West Java 91.40 90.65 92.38 91.61 2.22 3.79 3.09 3.03 1.99 1.04 0.83 1.32 4.39 4.52 3.70 4.03
Central Java 87.41 87.03 87.22 87.47 1.68 3.56 3.57 3.51 2.92 0.99 1.23 1.53 7.99 8.43 7.99 7.48
DI Yogyakarta 81.60 83.80 82.73 85.31 4.59 14.73 16.55 13.08 2.32 0.82 0.30 0.82 11.49 0.65 0.42 0.79
East Java 81.67 80.56 82.76 81.52 3.14 5.54 4.61 4.96 3.09 0.94 1.36 1.63 12.09 12.96 11.27 11.89
Banten 89.22 6.03 1.36 3.39
Bali 94.53 96.15 94.65 94.49 3.72 3.26 4.10 4.09 0.85 0.24 0.91 0.65 0.90 0.36 0.34 0.78
West Nusa Tenggara 91.89 92.96 91.72 95.53 0.30 1.14 0.96 1.33 1.87 0.55 0.98 0.90 5.94 5.35 6.35 2.24
East Nusa Tenggara 56.24 57.76 61.08 59.84 15.16 40.10 38.15 38.19 3.11 0.43 0.21 0.91 25.49 1.72 0.56 1.06
East Timor 89.34 85.94 3.39 13.40 2.90 0.27 4.37 0.39
West Kalimantan 93.12 89.68 90.95 89.83 3.91 5.25 6.39 6.34 1.05 0.64 0.58 1.06 1.91 4.43 2.08 2.76
Central Kalimantan 94.77 92.40 93.83 95.98 1.96 2.51 2.40 1.21 1.26 1.10 0.51 1.22 2.02 3.99 3.27 1.59
South Kalimantan 85.06 85.20 88.22 88.30 1.47 3.75 2.42 2.25 4.13 3.60 3.95 4.25 9.35 7.45 5.41 5.21
East Kalimantan 91.95 93.08 93.77 93.78 5.88 5.57 5.05 4.29 0.54 0.86 0.36 1.12 1.63 0.49 0.82 0.80
North Sulawesi 82.86 78.33 79.78 74.55 5.54 20.72 19.58 23.65 2.70 0.33 0.38 1.28 8.90 0.62 0.26 0.52
Central Sulawesi 95.14 94.84 96.82 94.84 2.35 4.39 2.38 3.83 0.70 0.57 0.49 0.87 1.81 0.20 0.32 0.46
South Sulawesi 95.15 95.23 95.09 96.17 1.61 2.52 2.22 1.82 1.91 0.94 0.82 0.73 1.33 1.32 1.87 1.28
Southeast Sulawesi 97.20 97.76 98.15 97.15 1.12 0.82 0.80 0.88 1.27 0.86 0.91 1.22 0.42 0.57 0.14 0.75
Gorontolo 95.77 1.09 1.51 1.63
Maluku 81.45 78.74 89.67 14.23 19.14 7.01 1.34 0.56 1.85 2.97 1.56 1.47
Irian Jaya 66.12 63.43 68.36 84.44 19.42 35.81 30.94 13.29 5.43 0.63 0.49 0.65 9.04 0.13 0.21 1.63
North Maluku 90.75 8.54 0.71 0.00
INDONESIA 87.73 87.38 88.23 88.43 3.91 6.59 6.30 5.81 2.34 1.04 0.90 1.37 6.02 5.00 4.56 4.39
Source: SUSENAS, several years
Note: Missing values due to civil unrest or governmental changes

9
Table 9. Percent of Junior Secondary Students Enrolled, by Type of School

Junior Secondary School Students Enrolled Junior Secondary School Students Enrolled
Public School Private School Public Madrasah Private Madrasah
Province 1995 1998 2000 2002 1995 1998 2000 2002 1995 1998 2000 2002 1995 1998 2000 2002
Aceh 80.59 89.21 89.22 4.03 3.94 0.90 11.14 6.04 8.98 4.25 0.81 0.90
North Sumatera 54.36 53.81 59.13 58.62 33.02 37.08 31.37 31.60 2.67 1.45 1.92 1.79 9.95 7.66 7.58 7.99
West Sumatera 75.40 78.62 80.17 79.51 4.26 5.13 4.69 3.81 13.26 11.84 10.88 12.21 7.07 4.42 4.26 4.47
Riau 72.35 68.76 67.97 74.99 9.25 15.24 18.32 12.10 7.88 5.11 4.26 3.81 10.52 10.90 9.44 9.10
Jambi 76.09 74.22 72.13 70.08 8.27 8.42 7.63 10.24 9.77 13.54 12.52 10.80 5.87 3.83 7.72 8.89
South Sumatera 63.57 62.92 69.07 71.56 21.99 28.88 21.76 20.50 5.09 2.33 3.03 3.60 9.34 5.86 6.15 4.34
Bengkulu 90.36 91.83 89.53 87.41 3.16 4.10 5.42 4.31 4.51 2.61 4.13 6.09 1.97 1.45 0.92 2.20
Lampung 50.34 49.65 52.33 60.29 29.69 35.30 30.59 26.62 6.56 4.07 3.70 3.26 13.40 10.97 13.39 9.84
Bangka Belitung 71.11 19.90 0.79 8.20
Jakarta 64.00 63.03 65.57 64.20 27.65 32.32 31.35 32.13 2.96 0.55 0.98 1.27 5.39 4.11 2.11 2.41
West Java 62.78 61.94 65.14 66.04 19.64 23.54 20.61 21.05 6.55 2.75 3.05 3.12 11.03 11.77 11.20 9.78
Central Java 62.30 62.11 65.15 63.85 14.74 21.74 19.29 19.47 7.01 3.32 3.49 3.58 15.95 12.83 12.08 13.10
DI Yogyakarta 51.50 63.02 69.04 77.32 22.82 30.98 26.31 20.15 7.54 4.44 4.22 1.75 18.14 1.55 0.44 0.78
East Java 54.93 54.52 60.13 60.57 20.30 25.87 20.57 19.04 7.20 4.38 5.33 5.01 17.57 15.23 13.97 15.37
Banten 58.14 24.05 3.25 14.57
Bali 75.32 74.82 79.74 78.20 21.34 23.61 19.17 21.02 0.87 1.45 1.02 0.62 2.47 0.11 0.07 0.16
West Nusa Tenggara 65.96 70.80 72.21 76.12 4.17 3.49 2.96 4.85 6.64 4.36 3.58 5.10 23.23 21.36 21.24 13.93
East Nusa Tenggara 53.57 63.84 63.76 65.97 21.61 34.91 34.24 31.54 7.95 0.77 1.10 1.51 16.88 0.48 0.90 0.98
East Timor 84.77 84.00 6.69 16.00 3.62 0.00 4.92 0.00
West Kalimantan 67.62 65.61 61.95 69.52 21.07 24.29 27.80 23.43 4.68 2.81 4.78 1.68 6.63 7.29 5.46 5.38
Central Kalimantan 81.22 71.61 82.87 85.51 8.42 10.70 8.08 5.04 7.60 7.31 3.59 3.08 2.77 10.37 5.46 6.37
South Kalimantan 52.12 53.11 58.22 59.85 7.83 8.66 6.37 4.49 18.55 20.96 21.21 20.42 21.51 17.27 14.20 15.25
East Kalimantan 68.97 70.99 74.19 80.75 18.99 19.67 17.04 14.03 4.26 3.33 3.05 1.54 7.77 6.01 5.72 3.68
North Sulawesi 81.39 78.49 81.80 82.46 7.97 18.85 16.04 16.54 4.32 1.20 1.05 0.48 6.32 1.46 1.11 0.52
Central Sulawesi 75.55 83.21 83.79 84.48 8.34 6.33 5.61 6.92 5.19 3.68 4.13 3.65 10.92 6.79 6.47 4.95
South Sulawesi 76.27 80.59 83.04 85.35 9.42 11.43 9.33 8.48 7.07 3.17 2.88 2.35 7.24 4.82 4.75 3.82
Southeast Sulawesi 84.46 88.49 90.63 88.91 4.97 2.02 3.80 2.26 5.67 3.63 3.44 5.28 4.90 5.87 2.12 3.55
Gorontolo 91.01 0.00 5.85 3.14
Maluku 77.64 77.47 93.27 14.79 15.53 5.88 5.01 2.47 0.85 2.56 4.53 0.00
Irian Jaya 83.07 82.63 86.20 94.27 7.32 16.32 12.43 5.73 3.95 0.33 1.01 0.00 5.66 0.72 0.36 0.00
North Maluku 92.39 5.95 1.67 0.00
INDONESIA 63.37 63.54 66.29 67.05 18.42 22.99 20.22 19.55 6.46 3.69 3.91 3.84 11.76 9.77 9.58 9.56
Source: SUSENAS, several years
Note: Missing values due to civil unrest or governmental changes

10
Table 10. Percent of Senior Secondary Students Enrolled, by Type of School

Senior Secondary Students Enrolled Senior Secondary Students Enrolled


Public School Private School Public Madrasah Private Madrasah
Province 1995 1998 2000 2002 1995 1998 2000 2002 1995 1998 2000 2002 1995 1998 2000 2002
Aceh 83.01 87.12 86.08 7.21 5.96 4.64 7.71 5.72 8.51 2.07 1.20 0.77
North Sumatera 42.39 45.99 48.95 45.58 47.38 46.43 44.26 46.88 2.16 1.67 1.87 1.80 8.06 5.90 4.92 5.74
West Sumatera 75.06 71.94 77.05 76.53 14.39 16.07 14.26 11.61 6.14 8.65 5.44 8.08 4.41 3.34 3.24 3.79
Riau 70.36 66.07 72.27 77.07 18.26 18.04 19.38 15.25 7.92 7.24 3.66 4.46 3.47 8.65 4.69 3.22
Jambi 70.78 70.63 70.78 62.47 15.39 15.55 13.96 20.15 10.54 7.99 9.55 9.63 3.29 5.84 5.71 7.75
South Sumatera 51.43 48.14 45.75 54.36 37.97 48.02 47.83 41.96 3.08 1.40 3.08 1.32 7.52 2.44 3.35 2.36
Bengkulu 78.46 81.05 81.98 81.73 13.34 14.57 11.14 12.35 3.58 3.34 6.43 5.92 4.62 1.05 0.45 0.00
Lampung 53.27 45.82 53.60 53.54 36.50 43.15 39.38 37.38 3.79 4.98 2.18 2.70 6.44 6.05 4.85 6.37
Bangka Belitung 53.01 37.88 1.99 7.12
Jakarta 52.18 47.17 45.58 48.58 41.33 50.66 52.14 48.06 1.93 0.71 0.47 1.05 4.57 1.46 1.80 2.30
West Java 52.75 51.56 56.70 55.75 38.78 38.83 36.75 34.44 2.70 3.33 2.26 3.77 5.77 6.28 4.29 6.04
Central Java 49.58 52.70 51.79 52.41 33.09 37.06 38.10 35.89 4.41 3.64 3.67 4.16 12.92 6.59 6.44 7.55
DI Yogyakarta 44.75 51.92 50.36 57.73 30.56 43.27 42.72 36.93 3.86 4.29 6.03 3.65 20.82 0.52 0.89 1.69
East Java 42.68 45.22 45.23 43.83 41.90 41.94 38.81 38.42 4.07 4.06 6.31 5.34 11.35 8.78 9.65 12.42
Banten 41.72 40.37 7.17 10.74
Bali 51.47 56.06 56.38 57.17 47.25 43.45 42.15 42.36 0.11 0.48 1.12 0.47 1.17 0.00 0.35 0.00
West Nusa Tenggara 68.21 61.34 59.73 65.30 8.91 13.62 13.44 12.96 7.96 6.92 9.52 9.22 14.92 18.12 17.31 12.52
East Nusa Tenggara 49.33 62.01 61.92 58.83 25.61 37.41 36.88 40.31 6.18 0.46 1.20 0.86 18.88 0.12 0.00 0.00
East Timor 81.30 80.68 12.18 19.17 1.79 0.00 4.73 0.15
West Kalimantan 58.85 59.29 56.61 56.40 36.05 36.07 36.53 36.12 1.94 2.13 2.34 3.12 3.16 2.51 4.52 4.36
Central Kalimantan 78.11 79.76 85.15 82.25 14.11 13.15 8.73 9.65 4.52 3.74 4.63 4.72 3.26 3.34 1.50 3.39
South Kalimantan 55.84 52.15 64.35 55.58 20.40 18.33 9.56 13.95 13.39 16.59 17.57 19.13 10.38 12.93 8.52 11.34
East Kalimantan 59.61 60.81 68.03 70.03 32.70 32.76 23.72 25.68 2.15 3.36 5.10 2.18 5.55 3.07 3.15 2.11
North Sulawesi 83.57 83.22 90.75 77.54 6.49 14.75 7.55 21.87 4.81 1.90 1.62 0.12 5.13 0.13 0.08 0.47
Central Sulawesi 80.21 82.56 86.16 84.60 11.00 10.48 5.70 6.99 5.36 2.78 3.66 2.82 3.44 4.18 4.48 5.59
South Sulawesi 71.07 76.85 75.22 79.45 21.06 16.66 19.11 14.44 4.05 3.60 2.54 3.75 3.82 2.88 3.13 2.36
Southeast Sulawesi 89.30 89.09 86.96 87.40 5.45 4.41 8.99 5.51 3.51 1.87 2.49 3.30 1.74 4.63 1.56 3.79
Gorontolo 78.96 0.47 10.96 9.60
Maluku 76.92 72.95 84.59 15.73 21.67 13.37 4.52 3.40 2.03 2.83 1.98 0.00
Irian Jaya 74.59 72.08 77.45 91.68 11.30 27.50 22.33 8.32 2.33 0.22 0.22 0.00 11.78 0.20 0.00 0.00
North Maluku 88.13 6.78 2.54 2.54
INDONESIA 54.67 55.45 56.38 55.96 33.65 35.84 34.85 33.58 3.79 3.48 3.64 4.11 7.90 5.23 5.13 6.35
Source: SUSENAS, several years
Note: Missing values due to civil unrest or governmental changes

11
Table 11. Adult Literacy Rates

1995 1998 2000 2002


Ages Ages Ages Ages Over Ages Ages Over Ages Ages Over
Province 15-24 25-54 Over 55 Overall 15-24 25-54 55 Overall 15-24 25-54 55 Overall 15-24 25-54 55 Overall
Aceh 97.70 89.56 64.74 89.03 98.54 92.86 71.58 91.97 99.79 98.47 84.05 97.34
North Sumatera 99.02 95.68 74.92 93.93 99.14 97.33 80.59 95.65 99.41 97.51 83.23 96.21 99.15 97.66 82.56 96.11
West Sumatera 98.18 93.10 74.14 91.27 98.84 95.48 80.86 93.81 98.93 96.86 83.19 94.99 98.77 96.55 84.67 95.15
Riau 97.54 92.31 72.75 92.11 99.00 95.89 81.21 95.36 99.33 96.45 81.34 95.80 99.07 96.79 85.42 96.56
Jambi 97.87 89.43 65.27 89.59 98.60 93.09 76.63 92.77 99.38 95.74 74.84 94.43 98.96 95.88 77.65 94.71
South Sumatera 97.92 91.75 65.14 90.42 98.53 94.59 72.93 93.06 98.49 95.61 76.46 93.98 98.85 95.69 75.40 94.11
Bengkulu 98.33 91.62 65.78 90.77 98.55 93.76 71.38 92.55 98.79 93.06 65.33 91.54 98.59 95.07 68.93 93.04
Lampung 98.55 90.97 56.27 89.07 99.09 93.52 59.18 90.51 99.05 93.67 62.25 90.91 98.91 94.99 70.81 93.00
Bangka Belitung 97.52 94.40 66.88 91.74
Jakarta 99.67 96.81 82.19 96.41 99.57 98.42 90.23 97.99 99.75 98.20 87.74 97.56 99.57 98.74 90.89 98.23
West Java 98.46 89.28 60.15 87.85 99.21 93.53 70.95 92.09 99.25 94.25 70.65 92.49 99.45 95.28 72.64 93.11
Central Java 98.33 84.37 43.41 80.23 98.87 89.09 51.19 84.23 99.04 90.34 53.26 85.63 99.17 91.19 51.33 85.66
DI Yogyakarta 99.06 87.21 41.63 80.37 99.05 90.18 41.74 81.17 98.50 90.82 41.69 80.51 99.36 92.84 48.13 83.81
East Java 96.78 79.02 39.36 75.75 97.40 84.63 48.24 80.78 97.97 86.17 47.90 81.74 98.46 87.83 49.80 83.19
Banten 98.81 94.73 73.53 93.84
Bali 97.45 81.49 36.90 78.31 98.22 87.59 47.49 83.33 98.49 88.93 49.36 84.23 97.65 89.29 50.44 84.19
West Nusa Tenggara 91.38 61.73 30.30 65.81 93.54 71.88 39.04 73.72 94.91 75.15 42.70 76.32 95.72 76.73 45.31 77.87
East Nusa Tenggara 93.54 77.70 42.11 76.90 95.11 84.08 48.45 81.57 95.25 85.76 50.39 82.83 95.86 88.04 51.04 84.13
East Timor 74.13 37.29 9.42 45.56 76.58 42.31 9.39 47.29
West Kalimantan 94.48 75.14 41.42 77.44 97.47 83.13 53.82 84.14 97.12 85.26 53.57 85.24 97.12 87.53 56.77 86.75
Central Kalimantan 98.64 93.98 74.18 93.48 98.98 95.61 80.83 95.11 98.97 96.19 81.17 95.68 99.47 97.33 79.99 96.32
South Kalimantan 97.91 90.26 66.05 89.77 98.47 93.90 71.13 92.45 98.98 93.37 71.77 92.21 98.47 94.65 73.77 93.29
East Kalimantan 98.31 91.18 62.60 90.92 99.10 93.18 69.80 92.87 98.99 94.58 68.93 93.73 99.23 96.17 74.78 95.19
North Sulawesi 98.07 97.03 90.00 96.37 98.95 98.07 93.37 97.64 99.00 98.57 94.65 98.10 99.40 99.02 96.96 98.79
Central Sulawesi 97.03 90.96 63.55 89.90 98.30 93.35 72.46 92.71 98.37 93.74 74.56 92.89 98.57 94.52 73.39 93.32
South Sulawesi 94.96 78.64 42.63 78.35 95.71 84.59 50.92 82.56 96.10 86.27 51.96 83.64 95.29 86.57 51.96 83.47
Southeast Sulawesi 96.53 83.17 44.29 83.01 97.34 88.12 55.29 87.35 98.03 89.81 56.81 88.76 96.99 90.31 54.36 88.24
Gorontolo 96.81 96.25 86.49 95.21
Maluku 97.52 94.60 75.73 93.13 98.84 95.94 80.53 94.74 99.30 99.62 99.48 99.50
Irian Jaya 85.07 65.45 53.14 70.24 82.85 67.31 60.89 71.47 80.13 66.59 61.37 70.11 100.00 98.81 87.00 97.93
North Maluku 99.80 97.13 93.73 97.74
INDONESIA 95.83 84.18 55.94 83.72 96.81 88.57 64.08 87.37 97.59 90.95 66.05 89.15 98.47 93.94 71.94 92.05
Source: SUSENAS, several years
Note: Missing values due to civil unrest or governmental changes

12
Table 12. Primary School Classrooms and Teacher Profiles

Classrooms Teachers Degree Held by Teachers

Number of Good Fair Poor Total SLTP SMU SMU non


Province classes condition condition condition Number Civil Non-Civil SLTP teaching teaching teaching DII DIII Above DIII
Jakarta 27,494 18,426 3,268 821 36,597 73.1% 26.9% 1.4% 2.9% 61.4% 2.2% 18.5% 5.1% 8.6%
West Java 207,618 58,370 63,698 43,204 190,633 90.8% 9.2% 0.8% 1.1% 63.2% 2.6% 26.6% 2.0% 3.8%
Central Java 163,506 72,779 59,164 20,554 194,261 92.6% 7.4% 1.5% 2.4% 72.4% 2.6% 15.8% 2.2% 3.1%
DI Yogyakarta 16,289 7,243 6,626 1,969 21,276 97.4% 2.6% 1.8% 2.0% 59.8% 0.1% 26.9% 4.8% 4.6%
East Java 172,542 81,319 56,568 22,021 210,017 82.1% 17.9% 3.6% 3.1% 58.5% 6.7% 13.2% 4.7% 10.3%
Aceh 25,972 11,741 7,330 3,608 28,832 96.1% 3.9% 0.8% 2.0% 75.2% 1.0% 16.8% 1.6% 2.7%
North Sumatera 69,864 30,566 22,491 8,926 80,176 90.7% 9.3% 1.4% 2.0% 87.8% 1.9% 3.4% 1.5% 2.1%
West Sumatera 29,183 11,696 10,263 3,628 31,852 96.8% 3.2% 0.5% 1.3% 73.4% 1.0% 20.3% 1.4% 2.1%
Riau 28,647 9,421 7,589 4,690 30,486 87.4% 12.6% 1.3% 1.5% 76.7% 4.6% 12.1% 1.2% 2.6%
Jambi 20,173 7,922 5,925 3,134 22,504 86.4% 13.6% 2.1% 1.3% 78.5% 1.3% 14.1% 1.1% 1.7%
South Sumatera 44,873 16,236 11,620 7,093 50,649 87.4% 12.6% 3.4% 3.0% 76.0% 3.8% 11.0% 1.0% 1.9%
Lampung 42,132 15,493 11,102 5,579 48,431 87.3% 12.7% 1.8% 3.3% 71.4% 3.1% 14.0% 2.1% 4.2%
West Kalimantan 27,157 7,070 8,419 5,076 29,055 95.9% 4.1% 1.2% 0.5% 86.4% 1.0% 8.1% 1.6% 1.3%
Central Kalimantan 11,941 3,531 3,085 3,499 13,315 93.2% 6.8% 0.7% 1.2% 80.4% 2.3% 13.1% 1.2% 1.1%
North Kalimantan 22,172 7,950 7,862 4,506 26,553 88.6% 11.4% 1.5% 1.6% 69.4% 3.4% 21.3% 0.9% 2.0%
East Kalimantan 16,608 5,836 4,881 2,558 19,129 95.4% 4.6% 0.7% 2.1% 76.0% 1.7% 13.6% 1.2% 4.8%
North Sulawesi 20,107 10,705 6,169 2,728 25,255 97.8% 2.2% 0.8% 0.6% 90.6% 0.3% 5.5% 0.7% 1.4%
Central Sulawesi 18,094 5,204 5,453 4,447 18,044 97.9% 2.1% 1.1% 0.4% 85.6% 0.9% 10.0% 0.4% 1.5%
South Sulawesi 53,964 22,464 15,772 7,908 59,117 98.2% 1.8% 0.7% 1.1% 78.6% 0.7% 10.8% 3.1% 5.0%
Southeast Sulawesi 12,482 3,965 3,854 2,714 13,605 99.4% 0.6% 0.6% 2.9% 81.0% 0.5% 12.4% 0.4% 2.2%
Maluku 17,067 5,181 4,155 4,642 16,152 96.4% 3.6% 0.5% 2.0% 84.7% 1.0% 10.4% 0.4% 0.8%
Bali 16,882 8,710 5,739 2,722 22,756 97.3% 2.7% 0.1% 2.5% 69.5% 0.4% 18.0% 1.4% 8.1%
West Nusa Tenggara 22,544 10,284 6,296 2,431 27,133 90.4% 9.6% 0.3% 1.6% 73.6% 4.6% 12.9% 2.6% 4.5%
East Nusa Tenggara 28,596 8,797 8,559 9,284 28,247 94.7% 5.3% 1.3% 5.3% 83.7% 0.7% 7.4% 1.1% 0.5%
Irian Jaya 15,915 6,708 3,113 2,835 16,649 95.7% 4.3% 0.9% 0.8% 93.7% 0.9% 2.0% 0.5% 1.2%
Bengkulu 10,339 3,873 3,387 1,713 12,362 97.6% 2.4% 0.7% 1.5% 74.9% 0.6% 19.6% 1.0% 1.7%
INDONESIA 1,142,161 451,490 352,388 182,290 1,280,798 90.36% 9.64% 1.60% 2.10% 71.71% 2.86% 15.04% 2.34% 4.36%
Source: 1999 MoNE School Survey
Sample Size: 172,457 schools

13
Table 13. Teacher Profile in Junior Secondary Schools

Years of Teacher Work Experience

Total Civil Non-Civil


Province Teachers Servants Servants Under 5 5-9 10 - 14 15 - 19 20 - 24 Over 25
Jakarta 2,413 3% 97% 11% 11% 17% 34% 19% 7%
West Java 7,613 5% 95% 24% 16% 23% 22% 8% 7%
Central Java 6,900 4% 96% 19% 10% 25% 26% 10% 10%
DI Yogyakarta 580 7% 93% 13% 7% 16% 30% 18% 17%
East Java 8,446 3% 97% 22% 12% 29% 24% 7% 6%
Aceh 1,249 2% 98% 14% 10% 25% 36% 12% 3%
North Sumatera 1,050 2% 98% 18% 13% 25% 28% 10% 6%
West Sumatera 582 1% 99% 9% 12% 30% 32% 11% 6%
Riau 776 4% 96% 21% 15% 24% 27% 10% 3%
Jambi 533 2% 98% 21% 13% 32% 23% 8% 3%
South Sumatera 2,284 2% 98% 27% 18% 25% 20% 7% 4%
Lampung 984 5% 95% 20% 20% 28% 20% 9% 2%
West Kalimantan 754 4% 96% 27% 12% 27% 24% 9% 2%
Central Kalimantan 57 2% 98% 48% 18% 23% 10% 1% 0%
North Kalimantan 147 6% 94% 15% 10% 28% 35% 8% 3%
East Kalimantan 252 13% 87% 26% 20% 33% 16% 3% 2%
North Sulawesi 318 25% 75% 16% 8% 23% 34% 14% 5%
Central Sulawesi 152 5% 95% 21% 19% 26% 25% 6% 2%
South Sulawesi 473 21% 79% 18% 14% 25% 27% 9% 7%
Southeast Sulawesi 50 16% 84% 21% 21% 22% 24% 9% 3%
Bali 330 4% 96% 12% 9% 23% 35% 15% 6%
West Nusa Tenggara 1,226 8% 92% 21% 21% 23% 25% 8% 3%
East Nusa Tenggara 570 4% 96% 26% 12% 23% 26% 12% 1%
Irian Jaya 287 16% 84% 25% 27% 28% 12% 5% 3%
Bengkulu 264 2% 98% 24% 22% 26% 21% 1% 2%
Source: 1999 MoNE School Survey
Sample size: 8793 public schools

14
Table 14. Teacher Profile in Senior Secondary Schools

Years of Teacher Work Experience


Total Civil Non-Civil
Province Teachers Servants Servants Under 5 5-9 10 - 14 15 - 19 20 - 24 Over 25
Jakarta 1,480 3% 97% 5% 15% 29% 27% 17% 7%
West Java 1,853 14% 86% 7% 22% 36% 23% 7% 6%
Central Java 2,829 6% 94% 9% 14% 36% 21% 13% 7%
DI Yogyakarta 523 10% 90% 24% 12% 22% 17% 13% 12%
East Java 3,341 4% 96% 6% 14% 40% 25% 10% 5%
Aceh 519 10% 90% 15% 17% 34% 22% 9% 4%
North Sumatera 571 10% 90% 14% 18% 29% 21% 12% 6%
West Sumatera 396 2% 98% 10% 18% 34% 23% 10% 4%
Riau 264 4% 96% 24% 24% 28% 15% 6% 3%
Jambi 209 3% 97% 58% 13% 15% 9% 4% 1%
South Sumatera 826 4% 96% 34% 22% 25% 11% 5% 3%
Lampung 225 11% 89% 40% 25% 22% 8% 4% 1%
West Kalimantan 201 12% 88% 53% 15% 19% 6% 4% 2%
Central Kalimantan 6 0% 100% 96% 2% 2% 0% 0% 0%
North Kalimantan 136 22% 78% 62% 9% 17% 7% 4% 2%
East Kalimantan 139 8% 92% 59% 19% 13% 7% 2% 0%
North Sulawesi 160 11% 89% 27% 17% 29% 13% 8% 5%
Central Sulawesi 26 4% 96% 47% 18% 21% 9% 3% 2%
South Sulawesi 171 19% 81% 11% 18% 39% 18% 9% 6%
Bali 168 7% 93% 22% 13% 31% 17% 10% 7%
West Nusa Tenggara 472 9% 91% 35% 27% 22% 9% 5% 2%
East Nusa Tenggara 171 10% 90% 50% 17% 19% 10% 3% 1%
Irian Jaya 86 9% 91% 67% 20% 9% 2% 1% 1%
Bengkulu 76 9% 91% 55% 18% 17% 7% 2% 0%
Source: 1999 MoNE School Survey
Sample size: 2385 public schools

15
Table 15. Test Scores of Junior Secondary Students

MATH LANGUAGE TOTAL SCORE

25th 75th 25th 75th 25th 75th


Province Total Students percentile percentile Mean percentile percentile Mean percentile percentile Mean
Jakarta 135,221 4.37 5.13 4.87 4.8 5.77 5.30 27.84 32.6 30.57
West Java 446,250 4.48 4.93 4.77 4.72 5.28 5.01 28.15 30.8 29.67
Central Java 484,636 4.5 5.02 4.83 4.96 5.72 5.34 28.76 32.01 30.58
DI Yogyakarta 48,346 4.49 5.255 4.94 4.93 5.73 5.33 28.945 33.1 31.23
East Java 465,770 4.53 4.97 4.82 4.8 5.45 5.14 28.34 31.2 30.00
Aceh 62,888 4.78 5.18 5.01 5.58 6.09 5.85 31.78 34.09 33.02
North Sumatera 217,434 4.46 4.89 4.71 4.31 4.81 4.58 27.01 29.75 28.50
West Sumatera 75,150 4.42 4.87 4.68 4.76 5.44 5.09 28.39 31.18 29.89
Riau 68,585 4.55 4.96 4.79 4.59 5.17 4.88 27.98 30.545 29.33
Jambi 34,377 4.42 4.83 4.58 4.35 4.95 4.57 26.98 29.84 27.96
South Sumatera 98,558 4.47 4.91 4.62 4.4 4.99 4.60 27.25 29.84 27.89
Lampung 110,017 4.37 4.68 4.57 4.45 4.91 4.70 27.12 29.11 28.27
West Kalimantan 45,637 4.43 4.7 4.60 4.44 5.03 4.74 27.25 29.49 28.45
Central Kalimantan 19,783 4.36 4.92 4.64 4.59 5.07 4.81 27.645 30.16 28.76
North Kalimantan 35,296 4.66 4.94 4.82 4.65 5.12 4.88 28.17 30.3 29.25
East Kalimantan 36,303 4.53 4.9 4.72 5.05 5.52 5.28 29.01 31.28 30.05
North Sulawesi 25,116 4.53 5.32 4.89 4.51 5.09 4.78 28.4 31.73 29.85
Central Sulawesi 26,058 4.5 5.1 4.81 4.47 5.06 4.74 27.76 30.73 29.13
South Sulawesi 103,330 4.51 5.45 5.02 4.55 5.25 4.91 28.27 32.27 30.32
Southeast Sulawesi 29,119 2.7 4.02 3.46 4.06 4.94 4.49 23.12 28.48 25.69
Maluku
Bali 43,478 4.62 5.12 4.89 4.74 5.5 5.09 28.29 31.94 30.14
West Nusa Tenggara 8,306 2.47 3.98 3.22 3.67 5.04 4.48 20.99 27.21 24.77
East Nusa Tenggara 43,943 2.93 4.47 3.87 4.35 5.07 4.70 24.5 28.54 26.47
Irian Jaya
Bengkulu 4.55 4.87 4.72 4.45 5.11 4.76 27.345 29.835 28.57
North Maluku 11,123 3.29 4.86 4.11 4.32 5.44 4.89 25.2 30.72 27.98
Gorontalo 7,896 4.62 5.08 4.86 4.4 4.98 4.67 27.41 30.31 28.93
Banten 107,108 4.27 4.64 4.54 4.37 4.94 4.71 26.67 29.01 28.24
Bangka Belitung 12,795 4.58 5.07 4.84 4.79 5.53 5.15 28.19 31.79 29.85
INDONESIA 2,802,523 4.65 4.90 4.70 4.69 5.26 4.99 28.54 30.50 29.44
Source: EBTANAS 2001/2002 school year
Note: Individual Subjects scores out of a possible 10; total scores out of a possible 60 points; missing figures due to lack of reporting
Sample Size: 2,802,523 students

16
Table 16. Test Scores of Senior Secondary Students

Natural Sciences Track Language Track Social Sciences Track

Low High Average # of Low High Average # of Low High Average


Province # of students score score score students score score score students score score score
Jakarta 28,399 24.03 41.61 31.93 1,324 23.04 39.58 31.68 52,642 18.93 36.27 27.46
West Java 57,720 20.51 37.34 27.75 4,021 21.27 36.23 29.13 91,417 16.50 33.05 24.34
Central Java 54,530 24.35 41.17 31.51 4,021 24.23 39.24 31.87 96,588 19.26 36.40 27.48
DI Yogyakarta 10,112 22.46 38.23 29.21 15,904 18.43 34.74 26.37
East Java 64,066 30.70 5,656 30.86 106,301 24.90
Aceh 15,839 29.13 41.57 34.90 14,476 24.65 35.13 29.46
North Sumatera 44,162 21.87 37.61 28.56 515 19.70 35.48 27.55 49,782 19.96 35.89 27.23
West Sumatera 10,828 21.42 36.53 26.66 1,020 21.06 36.36 28.30 23,706 17.15 32.76 23.54
Riau 7,394 21.30 37.39 28.26 529 19.17 36.65 27.89 19,760 16.89 32.41 23.85
Jambi 4,082 20.61 33.79 26.31 505 17.52 31.81 23.85 10,298 14.80 28.36 20.92
South Sumatera 13,997 19.96 34.53 26.41 99 23.55 38.11 30.53 29,256 14.52 28.09 20.78
Lampung 10,982 18.87 34.43 25.22 221 18.06 37.06 27.49 23,065 14.74 30.51 21.65
West Kalimantan 3,929 20.46 37.42 27.38 347 19.70 34.58 26.14 13,183 15.69 32.02 22.84
Central Kalimantan 2,719 19.41 33.02 25.31 391 18.43 33.80 25.67 5,299 14.72 28.19 20.65
North Kalimantan 3,675 29.36 1,663 17.67 34.78 25.63 9,479 16.17 32.78 23.69
East Kalimantan 5,371 20.87 34.89 26.80 238 19.69 33.55 26.70 9,171 16.12 30.27 22.39
North Sulawesi 4,390 21.34 32.99 26.88 1,782 18.04 31.32 24.35 6,392 17.04 29.34 22.88
Central Sulawesi 3,420 24.09 35.37 29.07 807 19.41 35.02 26.19 7,131 17.51 29.60 22.94
South Sulawesi 19,349 31.83 2,214 20.88 32.99 26.81 25,087 18.23 31.43 24.66
Southeast Sulawesi 38,924 21.43 34.07 28.21 7,095 19.02 33.58 25.89 62,559 16.63 30.27 22.87
Bali 6,884 24.61 39.95 31.70 4,942 21.47 37.28 29.37 10,433 17.67 33.90 25.39
West Nusa Tenggara 6,838 18.57 33.72 24.87 3,534 17.00 32.06 23.89 15,715 13.91 29.90 20.74
East Nusa Tenggara 3,430 17.07 26.15 21.03 2,420 15.76 27.15 20.99 11,659 13.57 24.87 18.45
Bengkulu 26.82 26.11 24.07
North Maluku 2,304 23.10 43.26 29.59 350 19.85 33.34 25.51 3,396 18.81 37.33 24.87
Gorontalo 974 23.02 34.66 28.26 470 18.21 30.60 24.32 1,901 17.39 31.42 23.81
Banten 20,430 21.28 35.55 27.04 11,716 18.45 32.09 25.03 43,104 16.27 31.48 22.89
Bangka Belitung 1,594 22.73 39.22 29.98 3,841 17.93 32.57 24.74
INDONESIA 446,342 17.07 43.26 28.27 55,880 17.5 39.58 26.87 761,545 13.57 37.33 23.78
Source: EBTANAS 2001/2002 school year
Note: Total Scores out of a possible 60 points,
Missing figures due to lack of reporting
Sample Size: 1,263,767 students

17
Table 17. Average Monthly Household Income
(Rupiah)

1995 1998 2000 2002


Province Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural Urban Rural
Aceh 307,000 186,000 424,000 278,000 1,161,000
North Sumatera 299,000 185,000 422,000 286,000 701,000 466,000 1,049,000 634,000
West Sumatera 311,000 203,000 460,000 297,000 768,000 546,000 1,081,000 707,000
Riau 346,000 236,000 583,000 349,000 961,000 584,000 1,395,000 781,000
Jambi 290,000 189,000 444,000 267,000 654,000 449,000 868,000 592,000
South Sumatera 288,000 177,000 370,000 245,000 691,000 440,000 984,000 506,000
Bengkulu 267,000 180,000 394,000 251,000 636,000 445,000 863,000 553,000
Lampung 276,000 170,000 401,000 213,000 599,000 382,000 793,000 521,000
Bangka Belitung 968,000 766,000
Jakarta 456,000 738,000 1,050,000 1,998,000
West Java 323,000 185,000 445,000 269,000 656,000 414,000 970,000 537,000
Central Java 218,000 142,000 315,000 213,000 507,000 358,000 756,000 505,000
DI Yogyakarta 239,000 156,000 361,000 248,000 508,000 360,000 922,000 555,000
East Java 269,000 142,000 350,000 204,000 520,000 340,000 798,000 494,000
Banten 1,272,000 635,000
Bali 310,000 218,000 484,000 316,000 768,000 582,000 1,244,000 812,000
West Nusa Tenggara 205,000 145,000 323,000 213,000 493,000 397,000 677,000 497,000
East Nusa Tenggara 295,000 145,000 392,000 215,000 703,000 373,000 889,000 462,000
East Timor 267,000 163,000 393,000 212,000
West Kalimantan 360,000 211,000 527,000 281,000 878,000 480,000 1,219,000 621,000
Central Kalimantan 313,000 210,000 458,000 317,000 708,000 510,000 944,000 698,000
South Kalimantan 300,000 174,282 444,000 278,000 705,000 441,000 973,000 610,000
East Kalimantan 390,000 227,000 537,000 337,000 803,000 512,000 1,231,000 758,000
North Sulawesi 251,000 163,000 366,000 240,000 632,000 418,000 954,000 646,000
Central Sulawesi 303,000 177,000 442,000 233,000 716,000 445,000 977,000 588,000
South Sulawesi 275,000 161,000 402,000 247,000 698,000 434,000 950,000 564,000
Southeast Sulawesi 305,000 158,000 315,000 251,000 679,000 435,000 948,000 590,000
Gorontolo 659,000 409,000
Maluku 309,000 170,000 424,000 243,000 1,103,000 754,000
Irian Jaya 364,000 151,000 504,000 231,000 733,000 314,000 1,076,000 1,116,000
North Maluku 1,104,000 721,000
INDONESIA 308,000 167,000 441,000 243,000 666,000 405,000 1,043,000 554,000
Source: SUSENAS, several years
Notes: Figures rounded to nearest thousand
Missing values due to civil unrest or governmental changes (as several provinces developed post 1999)
Sample size for all household SUSENAS data: 1995 - 201,421 households; 1998 - 207,645; 2000 – 189,339; 2002 – 212,646

18
Table 18. Education Expenditure as a Proportion of Total Household Expenditure

1995 1998 2000 2002

Province Mean Std dev Mean Std dev Mean Std dev Mean Std dev
Aceh 3.79 9.39 2.57 5.09 4.08 12.61
North Sumatera 4.37 9.23 3.46 7.48 2.82 7.08 2.24 4.96
West Sumatera 3.61 7.54 3.29 8.42 2.59 8.05 2.11 6.53
Riau 2.28 6.46 2.63 5.36 2.08 4.96 2.00 5.74
Jambi 2.81 8.07 2.37 5.36 2.00 6.89 1.51 4.71
South Sumatera 3.08 6.46 2.64 6.05 2.70 9.26 1.98 6.46
Bengkulu 2.98 6.48 2.99 8.88 2.52 7.82 2.04 6.61
Lampung 4.18 11.49 2.54 6.15 1.97 5.54 1.61 3.67
Bangka Belitung 1.31 2.84
Jakarta 6.17 13.60 7.34 18.57 4.86 10.87 2.91 5.52
West Java 3.99 9.48 3.41 9.42 2.43 6.66 1.80 5.25
Central Java 3.53 7.28 3.33 7.47 2.53 6.07 2.32 6.59
DI Yogyakarta 8.15 16.24 7.32 15.48 8.50 23.52 4.99 14.10
East Java 3.16 7.48 2.94 7.06 2.41 5.78 2.01 5.08
Banten 1.74 3.76
Bali 3.35 9.22 2.98 6.31 2.17 4.91 1.90 5.87
West Nusa Tenggara 2.58 5.76 1.67 4.17 1.68 4.80 1.12 3.17
East Nusa Tenggara 2.79 7.37 2.25 7.41 1.43 4.18 1.48 4.99
East Timor 1.53 3.73 1.40 3.29
West Kalimantan 2.20 4.92 1.97 4.70 1.86 4.91 1.31 4.19
Central Kalimantan 2.21 5.66 1.78 4.71 1.23 3.43 1.24 3.78
South Kalimantan 3.01 6.82 2.07 9.15 1.51 5.18 1.09 3.23
East Kalimantan 2.87 5.77 2.96 6.12 2.22 4.99 2.38 6.78
North Sulawesi 2.32 5.83 2.19 7.97 1.38 4.44 1.83 5.71
Central Sulawesi 2.43 7.78 2.35 5.21 1.61 5.96 1.16 4.72
South Sulawesi 3.38 8.70 2.56 6.20 1.79 6.34 1.72 4.76
Southeast Sulawesi 2.53 7.20 1.94 6.26 1.57 4.98 1.52 7.23
Gorontolo 0.99 2.30
Maluku 2.57 5.09 2.51 4.62 2.32 5.83
Irian Jaya 1.83 5.06 1.64 3.82 1.24 3.47 2.27 6.40
North Maluku 3.70 12.33
INDONESIA 3.25 7.71 2.85 7.06 2.38 6.67 2.02 5.86
Source: SUSENAS, several years
Note: Missing values due to civil unrest or governmental changes

19
Table 19. National Education Development Expenditure, 2001

Total Development
Province Expenditure Rp ('000,000) % of total
North Maluku 16,500 0.23%
Maluku 37,500 0.51%
East Kalimantan 47,000 0.64%
Bali 49,200 0.67%
Bengkulu 51,600 0.71%
Jambi 52,700 0.72%
West Nusa Tenggara 54,700 0.75%
Irian Jaya 59,900 0.82%
West Kalimantan 60,300 0.82%
East Nusa Tenggara 63,200 0.86%
Southeast Sulawesi 64,000 0.88%
Riau 76,600 1.05%
Lampung 80,100 1.10%
Central Sulawesi 89,300 1.22%
West Sumatera 95,200 1.30%
North Sulawesi 104,000 1.42%
South Sumatera 108,000 1.48%
DI Yogyakarta 127,000 1.74%
Aceh 136,000 1.86%
South Sulawesi 142,000 1.94%
Central Kalimantan 146,000 2.00%
North Sumatera 153,000 2.09%
Central Java 188,000 2.57%
North Kalimantan 192,000 2.63%
East Java 253,000 3.46%
West Java 442,000 6.05%
Jakarta 4,420,000 60.47%
INDONESIA 7,310,000 100%
Source: 2001 APBN

20
Table 20. Gross Regional Domestic Product at Current Market Prices, 1998-2000

1998 2000
GRDP GRDP per GRDP (Billion GRDP per
Province (Billion Rps) capita (Rp) % of total Rps) capita (Rp) % of total
Aceh 24,957 6,348,920 2.81% 28,626 7,282,293 2.45%
North Sumatera 50,706 4,352,575 5.70% 68,212 5,855,281 5.85%
West Sumatera 17,643 4,152,339 1.98% 22,368 5,264,383 1.92%
Riau 17,643 3,558,759 1.98% 55,430 11,180,752 4.75%
Jambi 42,838 17,746,783 4.82% 55,430 22,963,354 4.75%
South Sumatera 6,859 994,105 0.77% 9,061 1,313,250 0.78%
Bengkulu 33,072 21,099,480 3.72% 45,669 29,136,192 3.92%
Lampung 18,482 2,741,551 2.08% 23,253 3,449,264 1.99%
Jakarta 138,564 16,516,472 15.58% 188,036 22,413,407 16.12%
West Java 142,764 3,995,686 16.05% 181,630 5,083,469 15.57%
Central Java 84,610 2,709,346 9.51% 118,405 3,791,515 10.15%
DI Yogyakarta 9,864 3,159,242 1.11% 12,965 4,152,430 1.11%
East Java 135,753 3,902,783 15.26% 177,274 5,096,476 15.20%
Bali 13,526 4,292,385 1.52% 16,510 5,239,337 1.42%
West Nusa Tenggara 7,549 1,882,891 0.85% 11,937 2,977,357 1.02%
East Nusa Tenggara 4,868 1,231,694 0.55% 6,329 1,601,355 0.54%
West Kalimantan 14,635 3,627,735 1.65% 17,863 4,427,894 1.53%
Central Kalimantan 8,610 4,636,511 0.97% 10,871 5,854,066 0.93%
South Kalimantan 12,245 4,101,848 1.38% 17,688 5,925,152 1.52%
East Kalimantan 51,505 20,978,608 5.79% 72,178 29,398,970 6.19%
North Sulawesi 9,449 4,696,093 1.06% 11,762 5,845,640 1.01%
Central Sulawesi 6,630 2,988,593 0.75% 8,240 3,714,330 0.71%
South Sulawesi 21,951 2,723,575 2.47% 26,596 3,299,905 2.28%
Southeast Sulawesi 4,377 2,403,250 0.49% 5,730 3,146,132 0.49%
Maluku 5,226 4,334,990 0.59% 4,531 3,758,485 0.39%
Irian Jaya 19,053 8,578,823 2.14% 20,714 9,326,707 1.78%
INDONESIA 955,753 4,633,626 100% 1,290,684 6,257,419 100%
Source: Indonesian Bureau of Statistics, www.bps.go.id
Note: Discrepancies due to rounding

21
Table 21. Per Capita Provincial Revenues, 2001

Share non-tax
Own source from natural DAU 2001 +
Province revenue resources Share tax contingency
Aceh 23,000 276,000 28,000 538,000
North Sumatera 31,000 6,000 27,000 299,000
West Sumatera 31,000 8,000 20,000 442,000
Riau 66,000 863,000 88,000 479,000
Jambi 33,000 32,000 33,000 451,000
South Sumatera 22,000 97,000 24,000 247,000
Bengkulu 22,000 8,000 19,000 494,000
Lampung 14,000 32,000 13,000 272,000
Bangka Belitung 34,000 25,000 33,000 351,000
Jakarta 202,000 11,000 289,000 92,000
West Java 29,000 8,000 22,000 179,000
Central Java 27,000 2,000 12,000 266,000
DI Yogyakarta 45,000 1,000 20,000 366,000
East Java 31,000 5,000 21,000 265,000
Banten 38,000 1,000 33,000 158,000
Bali 215,000 2,000 33,000 426,000
West Nusa Tenggara 22,000 16,000 16,000 344,000
East Nusa Tenggara 14,000 3,000 14,000 577,000
West Kalimantan 23,000 10,000 21,000 421,000
Central Kalimantan 33,000 102,000 52,000 589,000
South Kalimantan 40,000 72,000 38,000 399,000
East Kalimantan 67,000 1,657,000 136,000 761,000
North Sulawesi 35,000 7,000 19,000 486,000
Central Sulawesi 38,000 11,000 18,000 549,000
South Sulawesi 31,000 9,000 23,000 377,000
Southeast Sulawesi 22,000 7,000 14,000 535,000
Gorontolo 20,000 6,000 14,000 448,000
Maluku 25,000 14,000 24,000 662,000
Irian Jaya 31,000 130,000 107,000 1,315,000
North Maluku 8,000 48,000 24,000 632,000
Source: MOF Budget Department, SIKD, and Staff Estimates
Hofman, Bert, Kai Kaiser, and Soraya Goga. 2003. Decentralizing Indonesia. The World Bank, Jakarta.
Note: Figures rounded to nearest 1,000

22
23

Potrebbero piacerti anche