Sei sulla pagina 1di 28

Revisiting the Image of Limited Good: On Sustainability, Thermodynamics, and the Illusion

of Creating Wealth
Author(s): Paul Trawick and Alf Hornborg
Source: Current Anthropology, Vol. 56, No. 1 (February 2015), pp. 1-27
Published by: The University of Chicago Press on behalf of Wenner-Gren Foundation for
Anthropological Research
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/679593 .
Accessed: 14/02/2015 19:16

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

The University of Chicago Press and Wenner-Gren Foundation for Anthropological Research are collaborating
with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Current Anthropology.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Current Anthropology Volume 56, Number 1, February 2015 1

Revisiting the Image of Limited Good


On Sustainability, Thermodynamics, and the Illusion of Creating Wealth

by Paul Trawick and Alf Hornborg

Two worldviews are now contending for cultural dominance: the open-system model long promoted by economists,
here called the “image of unlimited good,” and a more traditional closed-system view, Foster’s “image of limited
good,” still widely found among peasant societies today. The former rests on the assumption that people “create”
wealth, an illusion that conflates the properties of wealth’s real and virtual forms while ignoring the economy’s
extreme reliance on fossil fuels and other nonrenewable resources. The laws of thermodynamics dictate that as
“growth” occurs in such a system, it fundamentally destroys; thus the net sum cannot be positive, and the system
is not expanding but steadily running down. The latter rests on the assumption that most of the “goods” valued
by people in life are scarce, being derived from finite raw materials through the expenditure of human labor and
extrasomatic energy. Such goods are therefore “subtractable,” their limited supply forming a commons that must
somehow be shared. Based on an ethnological argument centering on the successful management of scarce water
for irrigation, a shift toward the closed-system worldview is shown to be necessary if people are to act collectively
to limit their expanding consumption, a change already widely underway, particularly in the global South.

Several decades ago anthropologists learned of a belief, ap- Malthus, like Ricardo and Marx, was right about some
parently held by people in peasant societies throughout the things and wrong about others. He famously worried that
world, that any affluence enjoyed by one person inevitably there ultimately had to be limits on the amount of land suit-
comes at the expense of someone else. In the heyday of mod- able for cultivation and for supporting human populations
ernization theory, this zero-sum or closed-system view of the regardless of the state of development of production tech-
world was labeled “the image of limited good” (Foster 1965) nology. Ricardo was then astute in observing that nineteenth-
and regarded by its critics as a cultural misconception stand- century Britain was proving itself able to transcend those
ing in the way of development. Today, the planetary predic- limits by substituting labor and capital for land while out-
ament unleashed by highly unstable growth, increasing eco- sourcing its land requirements to other continents. And Marx
nomic polarization, peak oil, and climate change appears to was prescient in pointing out that capitalists accumulate
be vindicating the intuitions of historical and contemporary wealth through exploiting other people’s labor by minimizing
peasant populations, now transposed from the village to the wages while maximizing profits from sales, a process that he
global scale. Although the acknowledging of biophysical con- noted was being extended imperialistically to other countries.
straints on the economy still tends to be rejected by main- But Ricardo and Marx had their own shared blind spot, par-
stream economists, who refer to it as the “Malthusian fallacy,” ticularly regarding the ephemeral nature of environmental
current concerns about sustainability are opening up oppor- constraints and the inherent virtues of technological progress.
tunities for a renewed discourse on the limits to growth, not Although it is not possible to predict exactly when or where
least on what the technological transcending of those limits the limits to economic growth will be reached in a particular
tends to entail in terms of the displacing or “outsourcing” of part of the world, because development strategies tend to
both labor inputs and environmental loads. These concerns displace such limits in time and/or space, it is no longer
are very much aligned with those of the alternative globali- reasonable to conclude that such limits do not exist. And
zation and Occupy Wall Street movements as they were with neither Ricardo nor Marx really foresaw them.
intellectual predecessors such as dependency theorists. The open-system worldview that they appear to have
shared, here called “the image of unlimited good”—which is
adhered to today by most economists (Hornborg 1992, 2001,
Paul Trawick is Associate Professor and Chair of the Department
of Anthropology at Idaho State University (921 South 8th Avenue,
2011, 2013a, 2014a, 2014b)—emerged out of the historical
Stop 8005, Pocatello, Idaho 83209-8005, U.S.A. [trawpaul@isu.edu]). experience of a highly privileged segment of the population
Alf Hornborg is Professor in the Human Ecology Division of Lund of nineteenth-century Europe. It reflects both a misunder-
University (221 00 Lund, Sweden). This paper was submitted 1 XII standing and a mystification of the related phenomena of
11, accepted 3 III 14, and electronically published 29 I 15. economic growth and technological development, a fact that

䉷 2015 by The Wenner-Gren Foundation for Anthropological Research. All rights reserved. 0011-3204/2015/5601-0001$10.00. DOI: 10.1086/679593

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
2 Current Anthropology Volume 56, Number 1, February 2015

has become increasingly obvious from its incapacity to deal study funded by the United Nations (Davies et al. 2008) re-
with twenty-first-century issues of sustainability. Although cently concluded that the richest 1% of the world’s people
their perceptions focused on different scales and levels of now own approximately 40% of the existing assets, and the
social organization—local, national, and global—and had richest 10% own an astonishing 85%, while the bottom 50%
very different ontologies, the peasants of Tzintzuntzan (Foster own less than 1% of the total available wealth. An unprece-
1965), peasants in Colombia echoing the preindustrial phy- dented amount is now concentrated in so few hands that the
siocrats (Gudeman and Rivera 1990), Thomas Malthus per capita distribution cannot be represented graphically on
(1820), Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen (1971a), and William a single printed page in a way that the average person can
Catton (1980) all adhered to a contrasting worldview and understand (Korten 2001:110–112). This is the kind of society
were not wrong: there are limits to the extent and the spread that three decades of neoliberalism has produced under the
of material affluence. This is because its cost—the other side famous Anglo-Saxon model (Gray 1998), that is, the freeing
of the coin of growth—is a corresponding environmental de- up of markets, particularly those involved in finance, which
cline that ultimately has to be shared by everyone. It is pre- were formerly thought to be capable of regulating themselves.
cisely when such limits appear to be transcended by novel People’s reaction to this kind of news is instructive and
technologies and sources of energy that we have reason to reveals a great deal about their view of the world. When the
suspect some new form of environmental load displacement, findings of the United Nations study were first announced in
some new externalization of costs, whose victims have now the Guardian newspaper in England in 2006, Madsen Pirie,
become the majority of people on the planet. an economist then directing the Adam Smith Institute in
The use of imported natural resources in devising tech- London—a free-market think tank—commented on the fig-
nologies that replace local labor is a phenomenon that ev-
ures, disagreeing with a statement by Oxfam that the current
erywhere hinges on the relative price of labor. Thus, it deserves
distribution of wealth is unfair and ought somehow to be
to be examined with new eyes by social scientists concerned
corrected:
with widening inequalities in the global distribution of wealth.
These are profoundly anthropological issues, as they illustrate The implicit assumption behind this [assertion] is that there
that the material modes of operation of economic systems is a supply of wealth in the world and some people have
are driven by cultural worldviews (Gudeman 1986), all-en- too much of that supply. In fact wealth is a dynamic; it is
compassing perspectives that are rarely examined but are now constantly created. We should not be asking who in the past
in great need of close scrutiny. has created wealth and how we can get it off them. . . .
Instead the question should be how more and more people
could create wealth. (Guardian, December 6, 2006)
Real Wealth versus Virtual Wealth: A Source
of Conceptual Confusion One frequently hears these references to wealth creation
nowadays in the media, generally made by financiers, pundits,
Economists have long championed “growth” in the gross do- and politicians, in statements that invariably suggest we can
mestic product as the key to widespread and cumulative en- all somehow join in the process. They go unchallenged be-
hancements in human well-being, and they have strongly pro- cause they express an almost sacred proposition lying at the
moted it as an alternative to the redistribution of already heart of the worldview sustaining the relatively unregulated
accumulated wealth. Yet as Sen (1999), Stiglitz (2002), Wade form of capitalism that now prevails in most countries. Such
(2003), Callinicos (2003), Pollin (2005), and others have remarks are in fact a kind of category mistake, as we will see
shown, such expansion—for example, the increasing per cap- below, and are ironic at a time when an unprecedented
ita consumption of goods and services—is only taking place amount of this “created” wealth—that is, virtual wealth in
in certain parts of the world and, even within that limited the form of finance capital—has suddenly vanished, inducing
set of developed and newly developing countries, its benefits a global economic crisis and precipitating the most massive
are largely confined to the privileged classes, the nouveau bailout of private-sector entities by government and “the pub-
riche, and the traditional elites. Everywhere that it is now lic”—that is, of banks and bankers and wealthy investors in
underway, such growth is in fact a destructive boon and a general—that the world has ever seen.
luxury being enjoyed by a minority at the expense of the Note that if real wealth, the kind that cannot abruptly
majority (Nash 1994, 2007), a fact that is illustrated dramat- disappear, is not constantly created, then the argument against
ically by the declining real income—very evident now for redistributing it by imposing upper limits on its accumulation
several decades—of the middle and lower classes in all of the and consumption quickly falls apart. Certainly the argument
“developed” countries. would be greatly weakened if the creative process supposedly
The profoundly uneven benefits of this “growth” are re- lying at the heart of global capitalism were shown to be an
flected in the most skewed distribution of income and re- illusion. This would clearly be welcomed by members of the
sources the world has seen, certainly since the dawn of the Occupy Wall Street movement, who in 2011 took to the streets
industrial age, a pattern that is steadily getting worse. A unique all over the world to express outrage about the highly skewed

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Trawick and Hornborg Revisiting the Image of Limited Good 3

distribution but who seemed to be searching for a coherent wealth and very little labor and raw materials as well, a fact
alternative vision to guide them. that highlights the contrast being made here and that un-
In order to debunk the proposition that people create derlines the entirely symbolic and socially constructed nature
wealth and to see more clearly how the global system works of the resulting value. If “real wealth” ultimately consists of
from an ecological or materialist point of view, the properties inputs of physical matter-energy, virtual wealth is imaginary
of two basic kinds of wealth must be distinguished and the or fictive in the sense that it does not require such inputs.
common mistake of confusing them by using the concepts Essentially consisting of a kind of promissory note on fu-
interchangeably—as in the above example—must be cor- ture flows of income, paper money and other virtual assets
rected. Such clarifications form part of a radical critique that do not degrade with time, as does everything else in the
has emerged during recent decades through the work of eco- physical world, including the sun on which all life on Earth
logical economists, one whose implications for worldview depends. On the contrary, they have the unique property of
have yet to be recognized widely, even in affluent parts of the growing exponentially and increasing in value at compound
world. Several observers have noted a widespread tendency rates of interest, thereby contradicting the laws of thermo-
to confuse the two basic forms of wealth, evident today among dynamics, nature’s most fundamental laws (Soddy 1921,
experts and nonexperts alike, the first of whom was Nobel 1926). By reproducing themselves in this ultimately illusory
laureate Frederick Soddy (1921, 1926). way, such virtual assets act as powerful catalysts that increase
“Real wealth”—sometimes referred to as “productive cap- the production and consumption of real wealth, further ac-
ital,” but a category still in need of precise definition—can celerating the ongoing and linked processes of wealth con-
be said to consist of material goods such as fossil fuels after centration and thermodynamic decline, as we will see below.
they have been extracted and refined; other raw materials that Thus their “creation” is ultimately—and quite inevitably—a
have been transformed from their natural state; land that has destructive process, that is, destructive of order, as a number
been altered to make it habitable or productive; food of all of ecological economists have pointed out, and as a growing
kinds; manufactured goods such as tools, machinery, and number of people in the world now seem to understand.
technology; and consumer items in general. As Marx was the
first to point out, these tangible forms of wealth, which typ- Virtual Wealth, Financialization, and Crisis
ically become traded commodities, are produced through the
expenditure of human energy, that is, labor, which imbues In order to illustrate the defining characteristic of finance
raw materials with utility or use value as well as with exchange capital and to show how the “creation of wealth” works, let
and surplus value. But the adding of that value also requires us say that someone—either a real individual or a “juridical”
the expenditure of huge amounts of extrasomatic or non- one, that is, a corporation—takes out a loan of $1,000 from
human energy, a vital input on which he placed far less em- a bank. The first thing to note is that no cash actually changes
phasis.1 As both Soddy and Georgescu-Roegen (1971a, 1971b, hands when credit is given in these transactions; today they
1975) later observed, such inputs are finite and, in a situation merely consist of an exchange of promissory notes, or prom-
of growing population, increasingly scarce, a point that echoed ises to pay with future income or assets, issued by both parties.
the early argument of Malthus. The interest-bearing note of debt will remain with the bank
“Virtual wealth,” on the other hand—sometimes referred of origin, to be paid off by the borrower at compound interest,
to as “finance capital” or, more usefully, “credit money” with the cash coming from their future wages or, in the case
(Graeber 2011)—consists of intangible and abstract forms of of a business firm, from future profits. Note that this debt,
wealth such as stocks, bonds, securities, and derivatives: paper a flow of future income, has been “created” by the bank only
or even merely digital assets that originate in the issuing of in the sense that the flow would not go where it ultimately
credit and debt and the simultaneous creating of money by ends up without the issued credit. The material and energetic
banks. Although people do create such wealth—nowadays inputs required for the financed activity have not been created
mainly bankers at the behest of governments—its value is because without the lending agreement, these tangible assets
merely symbolic, potential, or virtual, that is, largely imagi- would merely be spent up and used up by someone else in
nary and effectively projected into the future.2 Note that very some other way. Nothing real has been created except a new
little expenditure of energy is required to produce such virtual creditor/debtor relationship and a corresponding change in
the flow of the future income of the debtor. To speak here
1. No less than other economists since the days of the physiocrats, of the “creation of wealth” is therefore to engage in a fun-
Marx at times appears to have confused physics and economics (cf. damental mystification that obscures the heart of what is really
Hornborg 2014b). It is always potentially misleading, and thus inadvis- going on and draws attention away from the ensuing deg-
able, to apply anthropocentric concepts such as “wealth” or “use value” radation and dissipation of all the necessary energy and ma-
to physical quantities such as energy. The notion of “real wealth” should
terial resources.
thus be provided with quotation marks.
2. The abstract nature of pecuniary wealth was evident even before Meanwhile, the borrowed money, if spent as a unit on some
the advent of paper money, but the material constraints of gold and silver investment or on consumption, will end up as a set of elec-
at least implied a physical limitation on the creation of money. tronic digits in an account file in another bank. Under current

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
4 Current Anthropology Volume 56, Number 1, February 2015

political conditions, the bank can then lend most of that viduals. What this means is that if everyone involved were to
fictitious money again at compound interest—as before, with- suddenly pay off their debts while doing no more lending
out any currency actually changing hands—issuing more there would soon be no money in circulation, a fact of which
credit and thereby creating more virtual wealth in a sort of relatively few people seem to be aware.
repeating loop (Korten 2001:182–185; Soddy 1921:24–56, Nowadays, in the era after the abandonment of the gold
1926:303–305). This process is widely misunderstood today; standard in 1971, paper money, like the digital money in bank
people commonly assume that it is the savings of individuals, accounts—modern forms of what Graeber (2011:73–75) calls
or their monthly earnings entrusted to banks in personal credit money, which itself has a very long history—embodies
checking accounts, that is lent and passed on temporarily to and represents nothing more than debt; that is its primary
other people. In fact only a very small amount comes from function. Traded massively worldwide every day as a com-
that source; the rest is simply created by the banks out of modity, the value of currency—whether in cash or electronic
nothing—and profited on through the charging of compound form—ultimately rests on the trust and confidence of people
interest—when bankers decide to take on a certain amount that existing debts will eventually be repaid, even though that
of risk and to issue credit (Coggan 2011; Daly and Farley would be disastrous if it really happened. In many countries,
2003; Douthwaite 1996; Graeber 2011; Lancaster 2010). there are no capital reserve requirements and no reserve bank-
The idea that banks actually “lend” money to people in ing system, particularly the offshore tax havens and centers
these situations, temporarily giving up something that belongs of global finance. There the amount of self-reproducing
to them, which justifies the notion that banks and bankers wealth created by private banks through the “lending” of
should be paid interest for the “opportunity cost” of the lent money is potentially limitless.
capital, is largely an illusion, one that has long been promoted All of this is to say nothing about the practice—also largely
by a transnational capitalist class of extremely wealthy people unregulated today—of banks selling the consumer debt cre-
(Sklair 2000) who profit from the confusion at the expense ated through their lending, of repackaging it and selling it to
of everyone else. What the banks are seemingly giving up is each other and to wealthy investors as a commodity, while
merely the future product of their debtors’ own labor, which insuring themselves against any possible future loss due to
they are effectively extracting beforehand. default on the initial loans. In the case of the housing market,
As many authors have noted, such “borrowed” but actually the resale of this debt and the buying of the insurance—in
created money is then lent by the banks again and again, to the form of derivatives such as “collateralized debt obliga-
consumers and to businesses, at compound interest, and also tions” and “credit default swaps”—became so massive by 2008
lent by banks to each other. In the United States, fractional that it brought the entire system of global finance to the brink
reserve requirements supposedly restrict the amount to 90%, of collapse. Note that this reselling is just as dubious, from
or $900 of the initial $1,000 loan. This ultimately means—as a moral point of view, as the right to create money by issuing
Herman Daly, David Korten, David Graeber, and others have credit and interest-bearing debt in the first place. We hear a
pointed out—that, through the continual relending of this great deal today about the responsibility of debtors to repay
shrinking 90%, every $1,000 deposited within the banking loans and to avoid bankruptcy for the benefit of society but
system soon multiplies into $10,000 of newly created digital nothing about the duty of creditors to hold on to the resulting
money, all bearing interest and accumulating in the accounts debt and to fully absorb the risk they have undertaken.
of banks (Korten 2001:182–185). This process of “wealth cre- This is the legacy ultimately created by the political deci-
ation” actually drives the printing of money and determines sion, made early in the sixteenth century in Europe, to legalize
the money supply in most developed countries, a fact that usury. That pivotal decision to recognize the opportunity cost
again is not widely understood. Modern paper currency—the of lending coinage—real-wealth money made from naturally
essence of Soddy’s virtual wealth—is physically created by scarce gold and silver—was endorsed by Luther and later by
banks out of nothing through the issuing of credit and the Calvin during the Protestant Reformation, which eventually
creation of debt, such as that incurred by governments in forced the Pope and other leaders of the Catholic Church to
order to finance wars, whether “cold” or “hot” (Graeber follow along (Graeber 2011:321–323; Hyde 1983:122–140).
2011). Initially the interest rate was limited by the early European
In the United States it is the Federal Reserve Bank, which states to no more than 5% per year, and usury continued to
is merely a consortium of privately owned banks headed by be closely regulated thereafter through caps on the rate right
a government-appointed chairman, that does this. The up until the financial system was deregulated almost com-
world’s other central banks, such as the Bank of England and pletely at the end of the twentieth century. In any case, that
the European Central Bank, operate in basically the same way. decision ultimately led to the invention of a wide array of
In each case an initial government debt, underwritten by pur- purely virtual forms of wealth—paper money and its many
chased treasury bonds, is monetized by the reserve “bank” derivatives—all based on lending and on usury, a practice
and the respective national mint through the printing of cash that was previously considered to be exploitative and inher-
money and then circulated widely by lending it to other pri- ently sinful by Christians and Muslims alike.
vate banks, which in turn lend it to businesses and to indi- Today, this process of magical multiplication of other peo-

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Trawick and Hornborg Revisiting the Image of Limited Good 5

ple’s future income—that is, of the benefits of making loans and accumulating more and more finance capital for its share-
but not the material and other associated costs of doing it— holders and its top executives (the fiduciary duty of the cor-
ultimately generates a huge amount of virtual wealth, all bear- porations and their chief executive officers). Whether they
ing interest, thereby generating the enormous profits and ex- work in the service or the manufacturing sector, such people
orbitant salaries that have come to characterize the banking are engaged throughout every working day in “making
sector in the era of financial deregulation. Those profits are money” and “creating wealth” for someone else, while at an
generally reinvested today, speculatively, within the financial individual level this is mainly done in order to (1) satisfy the
sector and used in the purchase or sale of other forms of immediate subsistence, education, and health-care needs of
finance capital in an effort to increase their yield continuously. family members, thus reproducing the household as a unit
Many of those extremely lucrative “instruments” were only of production, and (2) pay off their taxes and their accu-
recently created thanks to deregulation; and many—such as mulating debt. Meanwhile, the hope of an accompanying
the commodity indexes widely traded by hedge funds, a wid- wage increase, adjusted for inflation—of growth in their “real”
ening array of derivatives, and the opportunity to engage in income in “real” dollars—to support all the previous con-
high-frequency trading more generally—are exclusively avail- sumption, fades and has been doing so for several decades
able to members of the transnational or global elite. now for most people, even in “developed” countries like the
The entire financial system has become highly unstable as United States.
a result because of the uncontrolled spreading of risk together The experience of living under the new debt servitude—
with the accompanying concentration of profit, which now so increasingly like the lived colonial reality of poor and ex-
threaten the future of most people on the planet (Krugman ploited people everywhere but especially those in Latin Amer-
2008, 2012; Radelet and Sachs 1999; Stiglitz 2010). The system ica (see Escobar 2010a; Mignolo 2010; Walsh 2010)—is one
has always been unstable, for that is a part of its inner logic of working harder and harder, faster and faster, just to try to
of creating and accumulating wealth, but deregulation has stay in the same place relative to everyone else, as many critics
made it more volatile now than ever before (Harvey 2010). have observed. The same logic applies to the ongoing inten-
The current situation, wherein the famous “moral hazard” sification of resource extraction (Pérez Rincón 2006). This,
has been allowed to become structural or endemic to the paradoxically, is how open-system thinking is generated in
banking system—so that it massively shifts future income most “modern” people and how the hegemony of the unlim-
from debtors to creditors, from the increasingly poor to the ited-good worldview is ultimately maintained. Such people
increasingly rich—led the editor of the world’s most prom- simply have to believe that all of this effort, all of this fruitless
inent financial newspaper, Martin Wolf (2008) of the Financial daily struggle in fighting a losing battle, is somehow mutually
Times in London, to say recently, “No other industry has a beneficial to everyone in the long run in a fluctuating and
comparable talent for privatizing gains and socializing losses.” cyclical kind of “positive-sum” game (cf. Wright 2000).
The lifelong servicing of personal debt through continual Unless they are subalterns or indigenous people—who of-
interest payments to agents in the financial, insurance, and ten tend to know that the “game” has a different logic and
real estate sectors of the economy has, in the view of some that the struggle will in fact never cease—such people cling
analysts, become the “new road to serfdom” (Hannan 2010; to a basic faith that it will all somehow come right in the
Hudson 2006; Toussant 2004), which people today tend to end, with the market’s invisible hand doing its promised
embark on without even thinking about it. A permanent re- magic by redistributing all of that “created” wealth, trickling
lationship of dependency on finance capitalists for credit now it down so that their children, too, can eventually benefit.
seems to be widely accepted as somehow natural or certainly Today, after the recent financial collapse, they do this even as
necessary for modern life. This personal relationship may help it becomes increasingly obvious that the collective future of
to explain people’s complacency about the recent bank bail- those children has effectively been mortgaged. Such faith can
outs, which, along with the wars in Afghanistan and Iraq only be maintained, in a seemingly rational and logical man-
(Stiglitz and Blimes 2008), have created enormous national ner, within an expanding universe wherein wealth—that is,
deficits that have effectively mortgaged the future of hundreds real as well as virtual wealth—is continually being created.
of millions of people, especially the young. Note that this This, we assert, is the sacred proposition lying at the heart of
situation is analogous to the paralyzing debt servitude that the open-system worldview of global capitalism. But no such
people in “Third World” countries experienced during the universe exists.
1970s through the 1990s, a legacy of economic dependency The awareness of bankers, on the other hand, is not difficult
that has not gone away. Instead, such servitude has become to fathom, as they now spend most of their work time gam-
the defining feature of modern economic life under globali- bling with the money—that is, with the commoditized debt—
zation. of other people while off-loading all of the associated risk.
Most people in the world now spend the majority of their There can no longer be any illusion among them of creating
working lives, that is, of their labor time, working for someone any wealth within an expanding physical world. Given the
else—generally a big corporation or a subcontractor of such magnitude of the economic crisis that such thinking has in-
a corporation—that is itself concerned with increasing profits duced around the globe, and the real possibility that such

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
6 Current Anthropology Volume 56, Number 1, February 2015

periodic crises will now be allowed to continue (Harvey 2010; can be a star, be rich and famous, and have all the luxury
Volker 2010), as well as the protracted daily struggle of most goods and the associated “bling.” Such bits of conventional
people merely to survive and to stay employed in the game, wisdom, reflected today in the expanding plethora of reality
an obvious question arises: will a moment ever come when TV shows, in turn express a “positive-sum” or open-system
the majority of people finally see what is going on and decide model of the global economy, the view—strongly promoted
they have had enough and their worldview suddenly changes? for decades now by free-market economists—that the world
David Graeber (2011:365), our most eloquent authority on consists of an unlimited and expanding “pie” of wealth. This
the whole phenomenon of debt,3 notes that Henry Ford once essentially inflationary model is strongly appealing because it
said that “if ordinary Americans found out how the banking depicts a world where everyone can prosper without limit,
system really worked, there would be a revolution tomorrow.” with no need for anyone to sacrifice for the benefit of others—
Such a comment, given its original source, confirms the extent for example, the next generation—by forgoing any oppor-
of the public’s mystification about the nature and the origins tunities to consume. Such financial folklore again rests on the
of wealth. sacred postulate that wealth is created by people, so that it is
The steady, credit-driven growth of consumption during not “subtractable” or characterized by the quality that econ-
the last 30 years created a rising tide of optimism in global omists call “rivalness,” of which more will be said below.
society that has now abruptly been reversed. That sudden If such false propositions are seen as true, then people’s
change, brought on by the ongoing crisis, has effectively called decisions about spending money and about consuming more
into question certain secular myths that are all derived from generally appear not to have any third-party effects, any op-
the sacred presupposition underlying the dominant capitalist portunity costs or resulting losses in quality of life that are
worldview. These too are central fictions supporting free-mar- borne by someone else. That belief, too, is simply false, as
ket ideology and sustaining the culture of overconsumption Herman Daly and Richard Farley, two of the founders of
that prevails so widely today, especially in the global North. ecological economics, have noted in discussing the concept
They include the popular and populist metaphor that “a rising of virtual wealth and other insights presented in the early
tide lifts all boats.” work of Frederick Soddy.
The current global distribution of household wealth, which This undisciplined, imaginary magnitude was used as a sym-
has grown steadily more skewed for several decades, shows bol and counter for real wealth, which has an irreducible
that the metaphor is a false and misleading one. A global “free physical dimension, and cannot be created or annihilated.
market” is, after all, just a massive system of voting in which Money is a problem precisely because it leads us to think
people vote with their money, and the more money one has, that wealth behaves like its symbol, money; that because it
the more votes he or she gets (Chang 2007). Starting with is possible for a few people to live on interest, it is possible
the neoliberal revolutions of Reagan and Thatcher, the po- for all to do so; that because money can be used to buy
litical process of most states has effectively been distorted and land, and land can yield a permanent revenue, therefore
subverted in this fundamental way, co-opting the very heart money can yield a permanent revenue. (Daly and Farley
of democracy and other forms of modern governance. 2003:255)
The end result has been the accumulation of vast amounts The fact is that money, which symbolizes only debt, cannot
of finance capital by an increasingly wealthy transnational and will not do this kind of magic for everyone. The notion
class of people—the famous 1%, who are the world’s main that it can is, like all illusions, based on a fundamental mis-
creditors—at the expense of the majority, the other 99%, who perception of reality along with a deliberate, widespread, and
are the world’s debtors. The conflict of interest between bor- very clever bit of ideological sleight of hand.
rowers and lenders that underlies such “growth,” although
seemingly new—and certainly becoming more intense every
day—is in fact a fundamental one with a long history that Production as Destruction: The Finite
lies at the very core of the “free market” and indeed of modern Materiality of Real Wealth
democracy (Coggan 2011; Graeber 2011). Real wealth, unlike its virtual counterpart, is something that
The facts of postmodern life have yet to dislodge another human beings do not and cannot create in godlike fashion
pervasive idea, strongly promoted today by the corporate me- the way they create ideas and symbolic phenomena such as
dia, that we can all somehow become rich and famous in a value. Yet the whole episteme of modern or Western culture—
world potentially consisting of winners and no real or per- the philosophical and metaphysical tradition lying at its core
manent losers. We all can have our 15 minutes of fame and and dating all the way back to Descartes—ascribes that il-
can cash in heavily on that moment when it arrives; we too lusory power to humankind, that is, to man (Foucault 1970;
Grosfoguel 2010:68). As a category, real wealth consists of the
3. It is noteworthy, however, that Graeber’s (2001, 2007, 2011) vo-
luminous and insightful critiques of conventional economic theory are
transformed products of low-entropy forms of matter-energy
completely silent on material aspects such as energy, technology, and that are themselves scarce by definition and subject to nature’s
ecology. laws. Such wealth—sometimes referred to as “productive cap-

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Trawick and Hornborg Revisiting the Image of Limited Good 7

ital” but basically just manufactured “stuff”—being a highly national Energy Agency (2009, 2010, 2013), we have nearly
ordered form of matter-energy, can only be transferred from reached—almost exactly as predicted—the critical consump-
one person to another, converted into a different and less- tion threshold known as “peak oil.” The recent surge of oil
ordered form, and ultimately consumed and degraded, lead- coming from fracking in the United States and from the rising
ing in every case to a gradual increase of heat, waste, and exploitation of tar sands in Canada are not exceptions to this
disorder (Georgescu-Roegen 1971a, 1971b, 1975). Its pro- phenomenon, as many people seem to think, but rather clear
duction takes place within a largely closed planetary system— illustrations of it. At a global level, more than 80% of the
that is, one that can exchange energy and information with total energy consumed daily by people in one form or another
its cosmic environment but not significant inputs of matter now comes from nonrenewable fossil fuels, a figure that varies
(Martinez-Alier 1987; Rifkin 1989). Within such a system the significantly among countries but has generally shown a dra-
“creation” of wealth is an illusion because real-wealth pro- matic increase, especially in developing nations, during the
duction is a physically destructive process. last few decades.
Far from increasing the total amount of order and well- In a world characterized by continued population expan-
being existing on the planet, as neoliberal theorists would sion and the increasing per capita consumption of finite non-
have us believe, economic growth—the increasing per capita renewable resources, the more we squander the limited re-
consumption of goods and services—steadily reduces it, caus- sources that are available, by converting them into physical
ing increasing disorder within the system as a whole. To the wealth, the faster the accompanying environmental decline
extent that the world economy is fundamentally dependent and the bigger and more disruptive of our lives the problems
on limited stocks of mineral resources such as fossil fuels, of poverty, pollution, and climate change will become. In
phosphates, and metal ores, the model of a limited world effect, the less time we will have as a species to make other
inevitably in decline merely expresses the Second Law of Ther- and better institutional arrangements (see Rifkin 1989:64–65).
modynamics, the famous entropy law, as we will see below. All of the seemingly creative activities we engage in require
It is not derived, like the other worldview, from a narrative raw materials and extrasomatic energy, and all of them con-
generated by affluent men jostling for wealth, power, and sume and degrade that matter-energy, most of which is a
prestige in the playing of some language game; rather, it ex- direct substitute for displaced human labor. As Georgescu-
presses a single, universal, and potentially revolutionary truth. Roegen noted, like Soddy (1926) before him, “In entropy
In the long run there is no way that the majority of the terms, the cost of any biological or economic enterprise is
world’s people can benefit from such growth, which is in fact always greater than the product. . . . Any such activity nec-
destructive of order, that is, of usable raw materials and avail- essarily results in a deficit” (1971b:80, emphasis added).
able energy. Admittedly, conceiving the ideas and technolog- This, rather than the fictions of wealth creation, the rising
ical insights that underlie production is very creative indeed— economic tide, and the self-regulating market, is what science,
sometimes even miraculously so—but the process of indus- both natural science and social science, now tells us. In the
trial transformation itself is exactly the opposite, as Geor- physical world, and in the “real economy,” the creation of
gescu-Roegen, the founder of ecological economics, pointed wealth is an illusion, because to produce it, to accumulate it,
out long ago. Why, then, do we call it “growth” and continue and to consume it is fundamentally to degrade and to destroy.
to speak—as Bill Clinton so enthusiastically does—of “grow- The current global system of economic and cultural produc-
ing the economy?” Perhaps it would be best if, when talking tion is thus violent by its very nature, a violence in which all
about wealth in general, we dispensed with the metaphor of affluent people are to some degree complicit. Agribusiness,
creating it. strangely enough, provides the best illustration of all of these
All of the above points would be true of the global economy points. In the United States and other “developed” countries,
no matter how we chose to construct it. But note the full spectacular yields per hectare are achieved by virtually pump-
extent of our reliance today on a limited and very dirty supply ing extracted petroleum products back into the ground and
of fossil fuels. In the United Kingdom, roughly 88% of the into the air—tractor fuel, petrochemical fertilizers, and in-
total energy consumed by people each day comes from these secticides—while rapidly eroding the topsoil and mining the
(International Energy Agency 2004, 2009), while the much groundwater stored in underlying aquifers. This is what most
bigger economy of the United States is just as dependent, with farmers now do on a daily basis, whether they work for an
hydrocarbons now accounting for approximately 86% of its agribusiness corporation or are struggling to hold on to a
energy consumption. The United States uses up a huge per- family farm. The self-contradiction that this generally in-
centage—approximately 30%—of the planet’s dwindling oil volves, the utter negation of the traditional values that have
stock. This is to say nothing of petroleum’s importance as a always underlain stewardship of the land, has been empha-
raw material in making plastics and other synthetic com- sized by many people (e.g., Berry 1977, 1981), as has the
pounds, materials that form a major component of the built extent of the resulting cognitive dissonance and stress that
environment in affluent parts of the world and that are now many farmers now suffer from. From a scientific point of
the predominant form of waste or trash contaminating both view, such creation through destruction is the defining feature
terrestrial and marine ecosystems. According to the Inter- of economic growth as we now define it.

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
8 Current Anthropology Volume 56, Number 1, February 2015

The efficiency of the U.S. food production system, as mea- they apply this simple idea to everything desirable in life:
sured by its energy input-to-output ratio, is shockingly low access to resources like land, water, and labor; the crops pro-
and utterly unsustainable, as most farmers today must be duced yearly through cultivation of the land; the opportunity
keenly aware, simply because it costs them so much money to earn money and enhance one’s social status; and the en-
and drives them so far into debt to continue to participate joyment of less tangible things such as a sense of honor and
in that energy-intensive system. For every kilocalorie of food prestige or even parental love.
energy consumed by people in America today, 10 kilocalories Peasants, he said, are highly aware of their lack of any power
of energy—mostly petroleum derived—are consumed and to increase the quantities of these that are available, so that
made unavailable for anyone else on the planet to use in the any such “good,” “like land, is seen as inherent in nature,
future (Giampietro and Pimentel 1993, 1994; Pimentel 1993). there to be divided and re-divided, if necessary, but not to
A large part of this consists of fuel for tractors and other be augmented” (Foster 1965:296). Consequently, their sub-
equipment to replace the labor that has been displaced from sistence-oriented village societies feature norms that discour-
the cultivation process, but the greatest amount is expended age any effort to acquire more goods and thus to draw at-
on packaging and on transport after the food leaves the farm. tention to oneself or to do anything else that might threaten
In the short space of 50 years, this basic distortion of ag- the stability of established social relationships, which are based
riculture by agribusiness has “progressed” to such an extent on the sharing of a prevailing scarcity.
that fossil-fuel inputs now constitute approximately 60% of Foster’s argument was criticized for being tautological and
the total energy used in food production, while the solar providing a rationale for contradictory kinds of behavior as
energy harnessed through photosynthesis accounts for only well as for lacking scientific rigor (e.g., Kaplan and Saler 1966).
40%. Meanwhile, the nutritional content of our food has Furthermore, he sided with the “developmentalists” of his
declined dramatically even as the environmental costs of the day by expressing confidence that capitalism and the opening
industrialized production process have steadily gone up. Be- up of rural markets would eventually increase the material
cause agriculture is the sector of the economy tied most di- resources available to peasants so that ultimately they would
rectly to solar energy capture—the process on which the food be able to abandon their traditional worldview and adopt a
chain and the whole web of life depend—there can be no more modern one (Nash 2007). Neither he nor most of his
clearer illustration of the fact that economic “growth” as we critics ever argued that there really is a limited good out there
have conceived it historically is fundamentally both inefficient and that peasants are more in touch with reality than “mod-
and destructive. The belief that this kind of “progress” is erns” are.
somehow creative and benign and can therefore go on for- He did, however, point out that a closed-system worldview
ever—that is, is sustainable—emerged during the heyday of could, theoretically, just as easily sustain strong leadership and
the seriously flawed worldview that we refer to as “the image lead to widespread cooperation as it could promote envy and
of unlimited good” (Hornborg 1992; Nash 2007). jealousy among individuals, the behavioral outcomes on
which he unfortunately placed the greatest emphasis. In any
Vindicating the Image of Limited Good case, his work soon faded from view, but it was not forgotten.
As one of the earliest attempts to consider the behavioral
One of the first anthropologists to employ the concept of implications of a closed-system worldview, his work was des-
worldview was George Foster (1965), who spoke of a general tined to be revived.
“cognitive orientation” that guides people in their behavior Foster’s influence can be seen in the later work of Stephen
and that is shaped by a set of axioms or presuppositions about Gudeman (1986; Gudeman and Rivera 1990) and other con-
the world and how it works. Pointing out that we are not temporary anthropologists, but its implications are most
necessarily conscious of our worldview or able to say much clearly spelled out by June Nash (2007; also see Nash 1994),
about it, because the presuppositions are culturally inherited, who uses the concept as a central theme in discussing her
Foster argued that people in peasant societies tend to share years of experience with Mayan people affiliated with the
a distinctive model of reality, one profoundly shaped by their Zapatista political movement in highland Mexico. She also
material poverty and the closed nature of their local social employs it in reflecting on her previous experience in working
worlds, which as we now know are based on a relatively with displaced peasants and tin miners in Bolivia and an
sustainable and labor-intensive kind of traditional agriculture intervening period of study of Mandalese rice cultivators in
(Mayer 2002; Netting 1993). The central axiom of that model Burma. For her, the idea of limited good is indispensable in
he called the “image of limited good.” accounting for the remarkable resilience of all of these people
According to this hypothesized folk understanding, there and the rural peasant societies of which they are a part.
is only a limited amount of “good” available in the world; The Zapatistas, still the most highly visible political move-
thus any good that one person acquires and enjoys necessarily ment of peasants on the world stage, are of course known
comes at the expense of someone else, denying them of that for extraordinary forms of leadership and cooperation that
same chance to acquire it. Foster insisted that peasants see extend across lines of gender, age, and other social divisions
their impoverished local worlds as closed systems and that as well as for the practice of direct democracy. Nash portrays

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Trawick and Hornborg Revisiting the Image of Limited Good 9

their ongoing struggle for autonomy and self-defence in the This has been well documented in studies of the so-called
militarized zone of Chiapas, like other similar confrontations physical trade balances of less-developed nations (e.g., Pérez
occurring today in Bolivia and other parts of the global South, Rincón 2006).
as a conflict between two distinct ways of seeing the world: The essence of the dependistas’ argument has always been
the “notion of limited good” and the “specter of the unlimited that the game of global capitalism is fixed in terms of a pre-
good.” And there is no doubt about which of the two world- determined division of labor and exploitative terms of trade,
views she considers more accurate as a depiction of physical and that the net sum of all of this production and interna-
and social reality. tional trade is basically zero. Wallerstein (1974, 1979, 1984,
The growing awareness of the finite nature of the good has 1995) took up the challenge of providing a more complex
transformed the expectations of unlimited possibilities into model in his famous “world-systems” analysis wherein the
a specter of paradise lost for growing multitudes of impov- same dynamics take place within a three-tiered hierarchy of
erished people. . . . Those whose response is to declare war core, semiperipheral, and peripheral countries. Widely influ-
on all who compete for control of diminishing oil, water, ential today, especially among academics and cultural theorists
minerals and other resources are beginning to encounter in Latin America, this formulation places the BRIC nations
resistance from social movements that seek to reinforce in- (Brazil, Russia, India, and China) and other semiperipheral
ternational covenants on the environment and the rights of countries in the advantageous intermediate position that they
the poor. I hope to rescue Foster’s insights on the peasant now occupy within the global economy.
worldview and what that may offer for those concerned with According to this body of theory, the vast majority of the
a sustainable future for world populations. (Nash 2007:36) profits generated by the investment of foreign capital in the
developing or peripheral countries—initially for the extrac-
Nash’s account firmly grounds the peasant worldview in tion of primary products and, nowadays, also increasingly for
the practical activity of people—both indigenous people and the assembly of low-cost consumer items in sweatshops—
those who, like the Zapatistas, also call themselves campesinos, have always been repatriated by foreign capitalists to the met-
or peasants—who derive their livelihood from cultivating, ropolitan or core countries where they live or put into offshore
investing their limited labor every day in the exploitation of bank accounts in order to avoid taxes. The rest has been
scarce resources such as tiny plots of land and inadequate exported by the allies of foreign capital—complicit national
flows of irrigation water. Her overall argument (see also Nash elites—into foreign bank accounts and then either used to
1994), like Foster’s before her, implies that when a person’s finance consumption or reinvested, usually in speculative en-
subsistence and physical survival—that is, their food or “daily terprises and in hedge funds. The end result in either case
bread”—come directly from such a limited resource base and has been the “development of underdevelopment” (Escobar
their own constant household labor, they cannot help but to 1995; Frank 1966): the gradual enrichment of people in the
see the world clearly as it is, a world in which everyone’s global North at the expense of most of those in the South,
livelihood is similarly derived, that is, from limited and ex- where the profits resulting from international trade would
haustible resources, whether they work in a tiny rainforest otherwise have been invested or spent.
plot or in an office on Wall Street. The dependistas’ original argument was somewhat under-
There is, of course, an academic version of this general way stated, being overly focused on relations of international trade
of viewing the world, a school of thought in political economy while largely ignoring the worsening inequalities of wealth
known as dependency theory. It originated in Latin America that are evident today within all countries, both the metro-
and, despite rumors to the contrary, it too is alive today and politan or core ones and those of the semiperiphery and
still very much a part of popular culture in the global South, periphery. As numerous works have subsequently shown (Ar-
although perhaps in need of some rejuvenation. righi 1994; Hardt and Negri 2000; Sen 1999; Stiglitz 2002;
The classic anticolonial formulations of Cardoso, Frank, Wade 2003)—especially the aforementioned United Nations
Amin, Petras, and others published in the 1960s and 1970s study of the world distribution of household wealth (Davies
pointed to the disadvantageous position shared by most peo- et al. 2008)—most recent growth has in fact occurred at the
ple in the “underdeveloped” countries lying at the periphery expense of the majority of people in both the developed and
of the world system, with its historically derived division of the developing countries. Across the globe it can now be seen
labor. Their arguments focused on the “unequal terms of as the internally stratifying and class-based phenomenon that
exchange” that result from this structural marginality, rooted it always was, which many critical theorists regard as a process
in colonialism, which have persisted largely unchanged of increasing internal domination and, at a cultural level,
through time. These circumstances constrain people in the widening “coloniality” (Mignolo and Escobar 2010).
developing countries by keeping real wealth, in the form of This perspective casts a sceptical and pessimistic light on
primary products (minerals, fossil fuels, other raw materials, the seemingly spectacular growth that is suddenly evident
and agricultural produce) along with the profits resulting from today in Latin America and even in Africa. The growth now
their exportation, flowing out of the periphery and accu- occurring there is almost entirely based—as the dependistas
mulating in the hands of people in the developed countries. originally argued and as some of them ultimately predicted

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
10 Current Anthropology Volume 56, Number 1, February 2015

(O’Hara 2004; Perez 2003; Petras and Veltmayer 2001)—on a lump of coal in ways that are more or less efficient, but
the exporting of primary products and now even on the “grab- in general equilibrium models the economy can’t create new
bing” of the best agricultural land, as in Africa, mainly to wealth any more than a lump of coal can reproduce. This
support the ongoing expansion of industry and consumption emphasis on a fixed pie of wealth caused the English econ-
in China and other parts of Asia. omist Lionel Robbins in 1935 to famously call economics
Most of the recent critiques of globalization lend support the “science of scarcity.” (Beinhocker 2005:67)
to this view in terms of their gloomy prediction of no sig-
One would never suspect any of this today, mainly because
nificant social and economic mobility and no substantial long-
the “neoclassical synthesis” emerged in the 1950s, whereby
term economic gain for the vast majority of the world’s people
the traditional theory was abruptly fused with endogenous
(see, e.g., Grosfoguel 2010). It has even been suggested that
growth theory, as Beinhocker goes on to explain. Unfortu-
some governments in the Southern Hemisphere should con-
nately, that awkward synthesis—basically an academic coup
sider “decoupling” their economies as much as possible and
d’état—completely changed the theory of markets as a way
moving toward a more self-reliant strategy for development,
particularly in the domain of food production (Barkin 1998; of representing the physical and social worlds. The “fixed pie”
Bello et. al. 2000; Taylor 1991). Many Latin Americans will of wealth was replaced with an “expanding-pie” view—one
be struck by the fact that this is precisely the kind of “eco- based on an entirely new and faulty assumption of limitless
nomic nationalist” path pursued by governments throughout and inexhaustible natural resources—which was apparently
Latin America during the 1960s and 1970s by popular leaders more consistent with the political agenda of most economists,
such as Allende, Roldos, Torrijos, and Velasco until they were or at least those of the dominant Chicago School, the famous
deposed and assassinated, allegedly with U.S. government shapers of the Washington Consensus.
support (Perkins 2004). According to the version of events handed down in the
Dependency theory and world-systems analysis continues lore of the discipline, the basic elements of the original theory
to be highly influential today in Latin America and other parts were established independently by several prominent thinkers
of the global South, but its star has faded somewhat in recent of the nineteenth century: Ricardo, Walras, Jevons, Pareto,
years, just at the time when the seemingly spectacular growth and others. Yet as Mirowski (1984) has shown, those ideas
in the hemisphere began to arise. By and large, this body of were generally borrowed or copied directly from physics:
work overlooks the crucial role of energy, and despite the “economic theory was appropriated wholesale from mid-
strong focus on primary products and scarce raw materials, nineteenth-century physics; utility was redefined so as to be
it does not actually portray the global economy as a closed identical with energy” (8). And if value was to be equated in
system. Perhaps its effect has diminished for these very rea- the social world with a kind of energy, then that value, ac-
sons. The irony is that a revival of sorts could easily have cording to the newly discovered first law, had somehow to
come about long ago, inspired by an unlikely source: eco- be conserved in economic transactions. Both Mirowski and
nomic theory. Beinhocker criticize early economists for this unacknowledged
borrowing and for inappropriate use of what for them is only
a loosely fitting metaphor: value as a kind of social energy.
Economic Theory and Energy: Revisiting the
Yet they also chide the early theorists for having basically
“Science of Scarcity”
ignored the second law of thermodynamics, the so-called en-
Although it is not widely known outside the academic dis- tropy law.
cipline, the canonical versions of market theory of the nine- Mirowski (1991:88–98) casts doubt on the relevance of both
teenth century were based on a general equilibrium model laws to economics and is quick to point out that value or
that depicted the economy as a closed system governed by “utility” is ultimately a subjective and social phenomenon that
the laws of Newtonian mechanics as well as the newly dis- cannot simply be reduced to embodied energy, as Georgescu-
covered First Law of Thermodynamics. The global economy Roegen (1971a, 1971b, 1975) emphatically showed. But he
was said to be a closed system in which total economic value seems to overreact in suggesting that economists today should
or utility was conserved even as value was converted from abandon energetics altogether. What would the implications
one form into another through production and exchange. have been for classical market theory as originally formulated
Beinhocker notes some of the implications in a recent over- of the second law, which was not widely understood even by
view of the history of the discipline. physicists until the latter part of the nineteenth century?
Traditional economics typically portrays value as a fixed The second law of thermodynamics states that in an isolated
quantity that is converted from one form to another. . . . system, energy, although conserved in absolute quantity, in-
New wealth isn’t actually created; rather, the world begins evitably undergoes a qualitative change that proceeds in only
with a finite set of resources that are allocated among pro- one direction. The available or free energy steadily degrades,
ducers, who in turn create a finite set of commodities that turning into bound energy and thereby becoming unavailable
are allocated among consumers. One can allocate that wealth and incapable of doing any further work (Georgescu-Roegen
in ways that are more or less efficient, just as one can burn 1971b:76–83). The second law is often dismissed as irrelevant

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Trawick and Hornborg Revisiting the Image of Limited Good 11

to processes in the biosphere, as the earth is not an isolated cally different. Value would not be said to be conserved or
but a closed system, receiving a continuous input of energy even augmented as economic “growth” unfolds within an
from the sun. It is commonly argued that direct use of solar expanding global economy founded on the depletion of finite
energy will enable us to recycle dissipated materials to an mineral stocks. Instead, it would be seen as undergoing an
extent that would make thermodynamic constraints irrelevant accelerating and inevitable decline, as does the total sum of
(e.g., Kåberger and Månsson 2001). Nevertheless, the contin- matter-energy available, at least under current conditions.
ued strong reliance of the world economy on finite stocks of This insight would have strengthened the scientific credibility
fossil fuels and other mineral deposits indeed implies that the of political economy and given dependency theory and related
entropy law is of crucial significance for economics. Not only forms of critical theory greater clarity and force than they
does it mean that we will run out of those finite stocks but have today.
also that the disorder generated in their conversion into com- The opportunity to generate wealth, and thus the oppor-
modities, for example, carbon dioxide—unlike the heat gen- tunity to prosper economically, would be seen to be just as
erated by biological processes—will remain with us in the limited as the quantities of land and other natural resources—
biosphere. Georgescu-Roegen (1993) argued that photovoltaic both renewable and nonrenewable—from which all human
power, because of its massive material requirements, cannot activity (including labor) is ultimately derived. Prosperity
replace fossil fuels as an important source of energy for mod- would be regarded as a kind of scarce commodity, achievable
ern civilization (cf. Ayres 1998; Hornborg 2014a). He is cur- by limited numbers of people during limited periods of time.
rently being vindicated by studies indicating that solar energy Its cost, in terms of the entropy and general disorder pro-
has a comparatively low-energy return on (energy) investment duced, would be capable of being passed on to some other
as well as having significant negative environmental conse- people in some other place (i.e., externalized) or even in some
quences (Andersen 2013; Prieto and Hall 2013; cf. Hornborg other time, as indeed it commonly is, in the form of exported
2014a). The trap of our need for material or stored forms of pollution and waste, widespread environmental degradation,
energy appears to be one that we cannot escape. endemic poverty, and a warming and increasingly unstable
Entropy, as a mathematical measure of the disorder or global climate.
randomness prevailing in the encompassing system, signifies The economy would thus be portrayed not as a self-reg-
gradual degradation increasing inexorably with time. The ulating mechanism, an abstract “free market,” but as the com-
early economists, when they appropriated the energy concept, plex political, social, cultural, and material phenomenon that
were only dimly aware of the significance of this increasing it actually is, one based on a fundamental and inescapable
disorder, which of course gives a direction to time and to scarcity. Some countries would be seen to have occupied a
history and imparts an irreversibility to all human affairs. privileged position in both geographical space and in histor-
Thus they equated value with energy in general rather than ical time, having been effectively able to spend up the future
with available or free energy, as they probably would have had that other countries might otherwise have experienced. Today
they been aware of the newly discovered second law. Geor- it would be even more obvious that it is a new global class
gescu-Roegen’s (1971a) insights were to demonstrate that, or society of people—the “high-net-worth” and “ultra-high-
rather than being strictly parallel phenomena or being posi- net-worth” individuals now found in very small but growing
tively correlated, value and energy are in one sense inversely numbers in all of the world’s countries—who are effectively
correlated in economic processes (Hornborg 1992, 2001). As colonizing and displacing the rest of us, gobbling up our
the value or utility of a given set of resources is increased collective future in this way. Certainly our cultural image of
through the transformations that we think of as production, wealth would have changed as a result, along with our illusions
the remaining energy available in those same resources de- about creating it, and perhaps even our ideas about how that
creases. Again, this illustrates that the production of wealth wealth—more correctly seen as a gift of nature and thus a
is inherently destructive of order. form of common property—should rightly be distributed.
The implications of considering thermodynamic laws in Although he lacked this overall clarity of vision, the words of
economics could have been profound because we cannot “cre- Alfred Marshall, one of the foremost economists of the early
ate” or increase the total amount of free energy and low- twentieth century, nevertheless ring true today.
entropy matter that is available for use on the planet. The Man cannot create material things. . . . When he is said to
first and second laws, taken together, are simply incompatible produce material things, he really only produces utilities; or
with endogenous growth theory; their proper appreciation in other words, his efforts and sacrifices result in changing
would arguably have prevented the neoclassical synthesis and the form or arrangement of matter to adapt it better for
precluded the emergence of the expanding-pie worldview, the satisfaction of wants. (Marshall 1947:63, cited in Mi-
which is promoted most strongly today by neoclassical econ- rowski 1991:290)
omists, the high priests of capitalism.
Had the early economists correctly equated the “creation”
of value with the degradation of available matter-energy, the
worldview promoted by the discipline today would be radi-

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
12 Current Anthropology Volume 56, Number 1, February 2015

The Current Distribution of the Closed- see below. This subsistence labor, which has always been ig-
System Worldview nored by economists in their analyses of the dynamics of
capitalism, as Nash has emphasized in her work with the
At this point it might be asked, who subscribes to the closed- Zapatistas (Nash 1994), is primarily devoted to reproducing
system worldview today and who does not? Although the issue the peasant household as an economic and social unit, that
has never been adequately explored, an “entropic” worldview is, to maintenance, sustenance, and sustainability, and only
(see Rifkin 1989) was clearly traditional at one time to many secondarily to accumulating any capital (Mayer 2002; Netting
of the world’s indigenous peoples, as Nash (2007) insists. It 1993).
is still widespread, for instance, among rural populations in The limited labor so continually and heavily invested is of
Latin America (Gudeman and Rivera 1990). It is probably course gendered labor, with women playing a central role in
still widespread today among groups inhabiting limited that daily household struggle, and often today it is done by
patches of the Amazon rainforest (see, e.g., Reichel-Dolmatoff women alone, without the support of a man. Wherever this
1974, 1978), and it may formerly have prevailed among subsistence orientation persists—or where a strong appreci-
hunter-gatherers living in circumscribed territories within ation of its economic significance exists, as among the mem-
more temperate zones such as aboriginal California (Bean and bers of the decolonial movement—the limited-good world-
Blackburn 1976). At the other end of the spectrum of socio- view is likely to prevail. Wherever people are being exploited
cultural complexity, we believe that the closed-system model by forcing them to work harder and harder just in order to
probably predominates today among most of the world’s sci- survive and for less and less material gain, that extractive and
entists, who intuitively understand that all forms of economic essentially colonial reality provides fertile ground for the
activity on the planet—like all biological processes—are gov- emergence of a “limited-good” perspective.
erned by the laws of thermodynamics, as Georgescu-Roegen Both of the worldviews under discussion are in fact sub-
pointed out several decades ago. scribed to, to some extent, by most people today, whether
The closed-system worldview is highly consistent with the knowingly or not. We carry both of them around in our heads,
political agendas of countless subaltern groups allied with the and we are often confused about how and when to use them
worldwide alternative globalization movement who partici- appropriately. The relationship between them is, we would
pate in the biannual World Social Forum (Correa-Leite 2005; argue, somewhat paradoxical and homologous to the one that
De Sousa 2006; Sen and Waterman 2012). Via Campesina, Parry and Bloch (1989) analyze so compellingly in their ex-
the extraordinary global peasant and neopeasant organization, ploration of the two conflicting and competing discourses—
would be an obvious example. Another example is the mem- seemingly found in most societies throughout much of human
bers of the emerging decolonial movement, an expanding history—that people engage in when talking about money.
group of academics—most of them social scientists and crit- One discourse is a positive one generated by a short-term
ical culture theorists from Latin America, many of whom are view, focusing on the liberating power of money for the “in-
women—who are exploring collectively the close historical dividual” and his creative pursuit of his own self-interest. The
and ideological links between modernity and coloniality and other is a more negative longer-term view, focussing on the
who are seeking “un paradigma otro,” another way of thinking destructive and ultimately demonic nature of that selfish pur-
about and talking about the postmodern world (Mignolo and suit if allowed to continue unchecked to the point that it
Escobar 2010:33). Their collective project seeks nothing less undermines a more fundamental concern for the common
than a fundamental “decolonization” of thought itself (Es- good, thus threatening the very foundation of society. The
cobar 2010a; Mignolo 2010; Walsh 2010): to free most people strong moral message conveyed by the myths and rituals of
throughout Latin America and the world from domination a great many peasant societies throughout the world, Parry
by an alien and modernist Western tradition. We suggest that and Bloch (1989) argue, is that the latter discourse must
a step in this direction might be to adopt, or to endorse, a always take precedence over and somehow limit the former,
closed-system worldview. Indeed, this model is fundamental as a kind of final judgement about money and the morality
to and profoundly compatible with the “relational” worldview of exchange.
that members of this growing movement, especially Arturo One of the worldviews that we have at our disposal today,
Escobar (2010b), are now advocating as a kind of culmination the image of limited good, must now displace and take pre-
of the whole poststructuralist effort in the humanities and cedence over the other, because we now know that it is sup-
the social sciences. ported resoundingly by science as well as by other, more local
The closed-system worldview continues to be widely sus- regimes of truth and knowledge existing today throughout
tained today by the materiality and the limited and cyclical the world. It is supported by the other knowledges of many
nature of the peasant labor process (Trouillot 1988), which peoples, many Others, whose voices have for so long been
still holds many poor subsistence farmers tightly within its ignored and silenced, particularly in the global South. Mean-
grasp. This is especially true when the resources being utilized while, the contrasting and dominant worldview, the image of
belong not to individuals but to the peasant community and unlimited good, has been shown to be literally bankrupt and
are worked to some extent in a communal manner, as we will utterly refuted. Neoliberalism and free-market theory have

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Trawick and Hornborg Revisiting the Image of Limited Good 13

effectively been dethroned in the wake of the global financial local user groups (Bromley 1992; McKay and Acheson 1987;
crisis (see, e.g., Keen 2011), making possible, at least theo- National Research Council 1986; Ostrom 1990, 2000; Ostrom
retically, a dramatic convergence that actually reflects, for the et. al. 1999, 2002). A great surge of studies has focussed on
first time in history, the lived experience of the majority of the communal management of pasturelands, forests, inshore
people on the planet. fisheries, and water for irrigation, many of them inspired by
What would be the implications of such a thing happening? a desire to refute Hardin’s (1968) classic argument on “the
Would people become more cooperative in sharing the limited tragedy of the commons.” These analyses reveal the complex
amount of “good” that is available, or would they merely dynamics behind many local situations, documenting and ex-
compete and fight over it with even greater intensity, perhaps plaining many different outcomes, positive and negative, in
being overcome by envy and even resorting to the sort of people’s efforts to cooperate in sharing scarce resources. But
witchcraft that seems to be universal in peasant societies? on the whole they show that human beings, when they face
Rather than a more equitable and cooperative world, the out- a mutual scarcity, are quite capable of working together and
come could be the darker dynamic portrayed in Taussig’s resolving the “commons dilemma,” the supposedly inevitable
(1980, 1991) various accounts of “the devil and commodity conflict between the interests of the individual, assumed by
fetishism” in South America, or in the Comaroffs’ (1999) Hardin to be entirely selfish, and the cooperative needs of the
disturbing tales of a new form of human sacrifice geared group.
toward the trade in people’s body parts that is occurring today The solution, and the key to avoiding a tragic outcome, is
widely in Africa. The implications of such work are clear: as for individuals to exert a form of mutual self-restraint, as
poor and marginalized but still “traditional” people struggle Hardin noted, each limiting her consumption so that the
to survive in a world characterized increasingly by market- resource can be utilized in a sustainable way that is beneficial
driven greed and scarcity, they sometimes resort to sorcery for everyone in the long run. A great number of ethnographic
and even to violence in their pursuit of wealth and power. studies have shown that local resource users are capable, by
That some people do so is hardly surprising, given the es- working together, of devising their own institutions or rules
sentially magical and latently violent nature of the dominant that accomplish this. They do not necessarily need to be co-
capitalist worldview (see Austen 1993). erced into doing it by an authoritarian state—one of Hardin’s
Beinhocker (2005:430), in a recent book on the origins of proposed solutions—nor would they benefit from having the
wealth, points to the crucial importance of worldview in de- resource privatized so that it can be allocated in a more selfish
termining the kind of economic behavior that people engage and competitive way by markets—his other proposed solu-
in. He emphasizes the need for a cultural conviction that there tion. At a relatively small scale and on a local level, people
are payoffs for reciprocity and self-restraint but claims that can do this on their own without a supporting institutional
“societies that believe in a fixed pie of wealth have a difficult context provided by outsiders, and they have been doing it
time engendering cooperation.” No evidence is given to sup- for a very long time.
port the latter assertion. Again, the statement reflects the prej- The ethnographies in each case show how a fixed pie of
udice that is nearly universal today among economists: surely natural wealth is shared within one or more user groups, a
people will only cooperate with each other if they are part of scarce resource that is “subtractable” in the sense that one
a system that is somehow expanding in terms of total available person’s use of it comes at the expense of everyone else by
wealth. But a “zero-sum” or “fixed-pie” worldview can just reducing the overall amount that is available. Natural re-
as easily support strong leadership and widespread cooper- sources cannot be expanded, or they can be increased only
ation as it can encourage envy and mutual mistrust among with great difficulty; they can merely be recycled at very low
individuals; that is the point that Nash makes so convincingly cost by natural ecosystems and thus renewed. Their avail-
in her reflections on the Zapatistas. Beinhocker’s error, like ability is ultimately driven by gravity and by the cyclical dy-
so many other economists before him, is to assume that in namics of the earth’s hydrosphere, and here of course we are
a fixed-pie context where “the good” is seen to be limited, speaking of water, the quintessential subtractable common-
there are no rewards for cooperation. Nothing could be fur- pool resource, particularly water used for irrigation. This
ther from the truth, as the ethnographic record clearly shows. unique resource, we suggest, can usefully be viewed here as
being a kind of proxy for, or as being representative of, real
The Prospects for Cooperation in a Closed- material wealth.
System World: Lessons from Water Some distinctive characteristics of water as a common-pool
Management in Irrigation resource must also be noted. First of all, the boundaries of a
sustainable irrigation system are necessarily fixed, like the
One of the major developments of the last 30 years in an- boundaries of the planet, that is, the land area irrigated and
thropology and other social sciences has been the emergence the total number of people using the resource. But the amount
of a vast literature on the management of “common-prop- of water flowing through the systems every year is not. That
erty” or “common-pool” resources, forms of natural wealth flow or throughput varies widely between years but diminishes
that belong, not to individuals, but to communities and to notably every year during the dry season, thereby imposing

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
14 Current Anthropology Volume 56, Number 1, February 2015

a cyclical scarcity, somewhat like that of the fluctuating global specific rules—in each case institutions that are local, tradi-
market. People can do nothing to increase the total amount tional, and in that sense collectively chosen—require that the
that becomes available for use in a given year, as all irrigators water scarcity be shared by all users on a single schedule of
understand and can clearly see in their daily work. They can rotation in such a way that it affects all land and all landowners
only use the water more or less efficiently by wasting or not in the same way and to a similar extent.
wasting the resource, and by obeying or not obeying the rules That achievement is highly significant because the com-
for using and consuming it. And in sustainable irrigation munities are stratified in every case, including both large land-
systems, that choice of behavior directly determines the length holders and smaller ones, so that like all human societies, they
of the irrigation cycle. contain significant internal differences in wealth. While ir-
Again and again in Peru, Mexico, the southwestern United rigation is taking place, at a rhythm or pace that is the same
States, Spain, India, Nepal, Bali, and the Philippines, relatively for everyone, a basic proportionality is maintained among
autonomous communities of irrigators—peasants and small household water rights, a uniform land-to-water ratio that
subsistence farmers in nearly every case—have been shown limits the total volume of water consumed by the farmers
to share this vital form of natural wealth in a sustainable way during each distribution round. These upper limits are im-
by imposing upper limits on their consumption of a scarce posed by the farmers simply by following traditional rules
resource on which the lives and livelihoods of all households and techniques in carrying out routine work, thereby exerting
depend.4 This kind of self-restrained collective action, now numerous forms of self-restraint throughout their daily effort.
known to characterize a great many local hydraulic societies A remarkable symmetry is ultimately created, a basic equity
throughout the world, is an achievement that policy makers, that pervades the existing set of rights and the set of corre-
until recently, thought to be impossible. The benefits and costs sponding duties and governs the relationship between rights
of operating the systems and using the water are fully inter- and duties. The rules in each case require that the contri-
nalized by the community in each case, through a basic kind butions of households to yearly maintenance of the canal
of circularity or self-closure, that is, the exclusion of outsiders system, in the form of labor, food, money, and other inputs,
from using the resource (Trawick, Ortega, and Palau 2014). be proportional to the amount of irrigated land that each
The benefits are realized and internalized through an intensive family has and thus to the amount of water that people use.
labor process in which all households are continually engaged: Because of this pervasive symmetry created through constant
that of distributing the water daily, of using it—mainly for work—work shaped by communal institutions expressing a
household subsistence—and of maintaining the canal system need and a desire for cooperation, fairness, and mutual self-
each year through communal and usually highly festive group restraint—and endorsed in most cases by unifying ritual, this
work. Most of this labor, it should be noted, falls into the type of system has been called “the moral economy of water”
special category of work being discussed here, that is, that (Trawick 2001b, 2010).
intended primarily for subsistence and for the production of The studied examples range in complexity from small-scale
use value as opposed to exchange value.5 systems operated by a single peasant community to multi-
Comparative analysis of data on sustainable irrigation sys- community systems covering many thousands of hectares and
tems in a wide array of countries shows that these communal requiring the daily coordinated action of tens of thousands
systems, which are bottom-up forms of social and political of small commercial farmers. They exist today in remote cor-
organization, together constitute the most striking example ners of the Andes—the highlands of Ecuador, Peru, and Bo-
of convergent social evolution ever identified in the ethno- livia—in small peasant communities throughout much of the
graphic record (Trawick, Ortega, and Palau 2014). They are Middle East and Asia, and in the bustling tourist zone of
based on the central principle of equity or fairness, which Valencia on the Mediterranean coast of Spain, one of the
seems to be defined and achieved by all of these local farmers world’s most cosmopolitan cities. The institutions governing
throughout the world in basically the same way (Trawick them in these cases are hundreds of years old, and they appear
2001a, 2001b, 2002a, 2002b, 2003, 2005, 2008, 2010). The to have emerged repeatedly, and often independently, on dif-
ferent continents, forming the heart of distinct Andean and
4. A large number of studies document positive outcomes in com- Islamic hydraulic traditions (Glick 1970; Maass and Anderson
munity-managed irrigation; they are summarized in Trawick, Ortega, and 1978; Ostrom 1990, 1992; Trawick 2001b; Trawick, Ortega,
Palau (2014). For a debate about how equity is defined in these systems
and Palau 2014).
and how much they all have in common in that respect, see Trawick
(2005) and Boelens and Davila (1998) as well as Beccar, Boelens, and From a practical point of view, fairness in these contexts
Hoogendam (2002) and Boelens and Hoogendam (2002). has always meant the same thing that it does today: no one
5. It is important to note, however, that in Valencia, Spain, one of the person or household is allowed to accumulate or use so much
largest and most complex successful systems that has been studied (Glick water that they jeopardize the rights and the livelihood of
1970; Maass and Anderson 1978; Ostrom 1990; Trawick 2008; Trawick,
everyone else. In a context of scarcity, no one may irrigate
Ortega, and Palau 2014), the irrigators are all small commercial farmers
who do cultivate for household subsistence but mainly produce for the more often, or use more water, than the prevailing conditions
markets and supermarkets that today help to provision a city of over a allow in situations where mutual well-being and the mini-
million people. mization of social conflict are widely shared goals. Similarly,

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Trawick and Hornborg Revisiting the Image of Limited Good 15

people’s duties to give back to the community are propor- line—with Oxfam, the World Economic Forum, the Inter-
tional to the benefits that they derive from living there and national Monetary Fund, and even the Economist now joining
using its resources. in6—and is now being conveyed through increasingly bold
Such collective agreements are achievable and sustainable and massive forms of direct political action. This, according
because the canal systems are highly transparent in that com- to a great many activists, critical theorists, and “ordinary”
munity members are routinely able to monitor each other’s working people, is what a sustainable world would look like.
behavior in the act of irrigating. People can tell through direct All of these various struggles are now underway, and what
observation whether or not the rules are generally being is at stake is indeed our mutual survival, as people in the
obeyed. The rules are simple and known to everyone, re- global South have been insisting for some time. The forces
quiring the unbroken movement of water—canal by canal arrayed against such collective action—economic, political,
and field by field—through well-defined and contiguous sec- and military—are formidable and capable of extreme vio-
tors of irrigated land. Consequently, the stealing of water— lence, a fact of which southerners need no reminder. Current
the most socially disruptive form of cheating or free riding— revelations about the surveillance capacity of countries such
is easily detected, reliably punished, and extremely rare. Order as the United States and the United Kingdom show that we
and self-restraint generally prevail. all must be mindful of the grave threat to democracy that
our digital links with each other have ultimately created.
Scaling Upward from the Local to the Global Nevertheless, popular demand for all of these changes is
increasingly expressed by northerners, too, and is now a truly
Unfortunately, worldview has not been examined in any of global phenomenon. The greatest challenge in any effort to
these irrigation studies, so it is not possible to claim that the “scale up” existing cooperative institutions of this type lies in
limited-good model predominates among farmers in any of convincing people that they are all part of a closed system in
the systems, as likely as that may seem. These local societies which such mutual self-restraint is necessary because of a
merely demonstrate what people tend to do with such a fun- prevailing scarcity, as Elinor Ostrom (1990, 2000) showed in
damental and necessary “good”—water—once they realize her ground-breaking work on the management of common-
that it is indeed limited and is circulating within a system property resources. That theme, consequently, has been the
that is effectively closed. But what would it take to create the primary focus of our discussion here: the true nature of the
same kind of outcome in the production, distribution, and global system, taken as a whole, and how it is represented in
consumption of material wealth and of scarce resources more our worldview. We have no wish to understate the magnitude
generally, at a global level? of a further step toward a more equitable global commons,
A pervasive equity and transparency are certainly difficult and we cannot propose a plan for political action that would
to envision creating on such a scale, through mutually im- even begin to accomplish it here.
posed limits on the per capita consumption of common-pool In order to scale up effectively, states throughout the world
resources such as petroleum, other fossil fuels, and the elec- would have to debunk the open-system perspective and pro-
tricity that is derived from them. That, of course, is the main
mote in its place the alternative closed-system view, with the
challenge we are faced with today at a global level in order
state in each case actually having to reverse completely its
to stabilize the earth’s climate. The same can be said of the
previous historical position in that regard. To expect states to
many other institutional changes that so many people and
do so voluntarily would be naive in the extreme, but gov-
organizations are calling for so loudly today, taking to the
ernments today are under a great deal of pressure “from be-
streets all over the world in order to demand them: a limit
low,” not least from the risk of a repeating financial crisis.
on the size and structure of banks; the regulation and taxing
The pressure is to see and think no longer “like a state”—
of international flows of finance capital; and upper limits on
as James Scott (1998) so compellingly portrays it—but to
bonuses and executive pay, not just in the financial sector but
think and to act more like “the people,” according to a realistic
more generally throughout the corporate world. The latter, if
model of reality and in the name of the common good (see
extended to the entire public and private sectors all over the
Scott 2012). To do this would require solving, on an un-
planet, would amount to a global maximum wage, a limit
precedented scale, Ostrom’s (1990:42–45) “assurance prob-
that is advocated today by growing numbers of people.
lem,” the second crucial step in any effort by people to co-
Such steps would merely set a series of upper limits or
ceilings on economic growth, imposed in the name of the operate by limiting their own consumption by (1) coming
common good, in order to create new channels of redistri- up with a set of rules and principles that constitute an agree-
bution to counter the wealth concentrating and monopolistic ment for doing so, one endorsed at various sociopolitical
tendencies of an unregulated global market. The same can be levels by mutual consent, and, more importantly (2) assuring
said of a system of fair and progressive taxes, both individual
6. See http://www.oxfam.org/sites/www.oxfam.org/files/cost-of-
and corporate, that allows no tax havens and is fully trans- inequality-oxfam-mb180113.pdf; http://www.weforum.org/issues/global-
parent. The call for both of these radical reforms has become risks; http://blog-imfdirect.imf.org/2011/04/08/inequality-and-growth/;
almost deafening throughout the world, both online and off- http://www.economist.com/node/21564413.

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
16 Current Anthropology Volume 56, Number 1, February 2015

people that such an agreement would be enforceable and the members of future generations—they may become more
would work. willing to take action to restrain that growth by mutually
In the digital age, information technology makes it possible limiting their own consumption. The political challenges in-
to do all this and to create the needed transparency on a scale volved in moving humankind toward sustainability in this
never achieved before; that is the great advantage we now way are of course daunting, and any effort to scale up existing
have. Such technology unfortunately also makes it possible cooperative institutions to the highest levels of organization
for governments to watch us in unprecedented and all-per- will be fraught with great difficulty. But we have argued here
vasive ways, but the upside is that it has also become possible, that they are fundamentally cultural challenges too, posing if
theoretically, for us to watch each other and the government nothing else an enormous task of mutual education, com-
just as thoroughly, holding each other accountable and reliably munication, and deliberation. What is ultimately most needed
enforcing any agreed-on set of rules at any level of social and for such constraints on accumulation to finally be imposed
political organization (Hart 2001). is the adoption of a view of the world, and of a global economy
Local economies can obviously be made much more eq- now fully coextensive with it, that acknowledges the kinds of
uitable and transparent at the ground level; that much is material constraints and the zero-sum logic that mainstream
clearly doable. Witness the growing “transition town” move- economists have for many years now systematically denied.
ment in the United Kingdom, the United States, and the It requires people to finally see that, for human beings, there
European Union; the alternative currency systems that have is no such thing as “the creation of wealth.”
sprung up now in so many communities throughout the This kind of worldview accurately depicts physical and so-
world (Greco 2009; Lee 1996); and of course the sustainable cial reality. That may explain why it first emerged in many
farmer-managed irrigation systems that exist all over the peasant societies throughout the world, and why it appears
planet. These kinds of local experiments and alternative com- to be prevalent today among exploited and displaced peoples,
munities would have to be nested hierarchically within similar especially the former peasants and indigenous people of the
institutions at higher levels, creating and sustaining polycen- global South. We believe that the limited-good perspective lies
tric governance in the regulation of economies at local, re- at the heart of “the light at the edge of the world,” the vast
gional, national, and global scales (Dolšak and Ostrom 2003; and rich body of indigenous knowledge about which Wade
Ostrom 1990, 2000, 2000; Ostrom et. al. 1999, 2002; Marshall Davis (2009) writes so movingly, and that this light is now
2005). And, as Roy Rappaport’s (e.g., 1979, 1999) work spreading from the earth’s margins to its political and cultural
showed with such great foresight, it would probably all have center or core.
to be made meaningful through ritual that promotes the new The “image of limited good” also emerged and flourished
worldview and replaces the gaudy and grotesque spectacles briefly within academia, having been promoted initially by
that are emblematic of unregulated global capitalism in the nineteenth-century theory in economics and then adopted by
postmodern era. Stephen Lansing’s (1991, 1993, 2006) ex- dependency and world-system theorists and other radical crit-
traordinary work on the famous subaks and water temples of ics whose work is still highly influential in Latin America and
Bali gives us an encouraging glimpse of how such a highly other parts of the Southern Hemisphere today. It is consistent
complex and ritualized system of production can work on an with the views expressed by a wide array of participants in
impressive scale. the World Social Forum and more widely within the subaltern
This will not be easy, of course, for the global economy is and marginalized groups that form the core of the growing
not just a big irrigation system. Yet there is no reason, the- alternative globalization and “decolonial” movements. It
oretically, why the world cannot be made to work more like seems equally consistent with the demands that were implied
one. The political will to do this on a massive scale is growing by the extraordinary Occupy Wall Street movement. Finally,
rapidly today, and necessity will only add to the mounting that worldview is firmly vindicated by contemporary knowl-
pressure as time goes on. But the current groundswell of edge in the natural and social sciences, especially the relatively
support, of popular resistance and revolt against business as new field of ecological economics, based on a renewed un-
usual, will only become truly global if people widely come to derstanding of how the laws of thermodynamics express
see the world in a more accurate and realistic way. themselves as fundamental constraints in human affairs.
The magical worldview long promoted by neoclassical
Conclusion: Acknowledging a World of economists and finance capitalists must now be replaced with
Limited Good a more realistic one built on the axiom that the “good” in
human affairs is always limited. The former worldview could
The argument presented throughout this essay is that if people only prevail within the narrow historical space between the
come to realize that economic “growth” is a physically de- initial outsourcing of land and labor (i.e., energy) require-
structive process rather than a creative one, based on the ments represented by the industrial revolution—including
consumption of limited stocks of natural resources that are our dependence on subterranean fossil fuels (Hornborg 2006;
being rapidly drawn down and made more scarce every day Pomeranz 2000; Sieferle 1982)—and the contemporary ac-
at a planetary level—both for contemporary Others and for knowledging of global limits to growth. Today the closed-

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Trawick and Hornborg Revisiting the Image of Limited Good 17

system worldview, which focuses the mind on everything we ited-good/fixed-pie model drives behavior and relationships,
have in common as the inhabitants of a biosphere that is people cooperate to manage resources, building political order
steadily deteriorating, seems destined finally to prevail. and institutions to help manage the system. What the authors
It would be naive to claim that this vision of reality has argue for, drawing from the “fixed-pie” model, is nothing less
the capacity to unite people all over the world, producing a than a profound reversal of the contemporary global eco-
great “aha!” moment that suddenly changes everything based nomic system: “if people come to realize that economic
on a new awareness of our shared relationship to forms of ‘growth’ is a physically destructive process rather than a cre-
property that ultimately belong to us all. Yet we are all now ative one . . . they may become more willing to take action
deeply immersed in crises from which none of us can escape, to restrain that growth by mutually limiting their own con-
not even those who are fortunate enough to be wealthy. Con- sumption.” Like other recent debates on these issues, Trawick
ventional politics appears utterly unable to save us, but new and Hornborg’s idea is exciting. Solid analysis of social science
forms of political struggle are now breaking out everywhere. (and physics!) theory (historical and contemporary) under-
The time would seem to be ripe for a change, a global con- pins their argument, and it certainly intersects with much
vergence on a scale never seen before. We may soon find out post-2008 economic downturn activism (the Occupy Move-
just how important worldview really is. ment, “99%,” antiglobalization, etc.).
There is, indeed, a growing clamor for a rebalancing of the
world political-ecological and economic order. Shifting our
Acknowledgments collective worldviews to recognize and understand the phan-
tom of “invisible hand” economics, the finite materiality of
We wish to express our gratitude to the John D. and Catherine our daily lives, and the real (and dire) social and ecological
T. MacArthur Foundation for supporting the irrigation re- costs of excessive wealth and consumption, must be integral
search discussed in the latter part of this paper and to ac- in this rebalancing. However, like ideas of carrying capacity—
knowledge support from the European Commission’s Seventh which must be examined and employed with caution and
Framework Programme for the projects “Environmental Jus- clear intention (Cliggett 2001), “the image of the limited
tice Organizations, Liabilities, and Trade” and “Financialis- good” worldview may be more a metaphor to motivate change
ation, Economy, Society, and Sustainable Development.” Sev- than a grounded reality with scalable lessons.
eral people deserve thanks for their critical comments on While I appreciate the depth of theoretical framing in this
earlier versions of this article: Jim Harris, Ben Orlove, June article—from classical economics to the first and second laws
Nash, Stephen Gudeman, and David Graeber. This article is of thermodynamics to contemporary political-economy cri-
dedicated to the memory of Elinor Ostrom, an inspiring men- tiques of finance capital—as an ethnographer seeking ground-
tor and generous benefactor who is sorely missed. ing in real people’s lives, I miss clear examples of diverse
communities living successfully within the bounds of the
fixed-pie model. The authors offer examples of irrigation sys-
tems in Latin America that have stood the test of time for
Comments managing scarce water in specific communities. Steven Lan-
sing’s work on water temples in Bali also exemplifies the idea.
Lisa Cliggett However, working with agropastoralists in postcolonial
Department of Anthropology, University of Kentucky, 211 Lafferty Zambia’s increasingly dry and climatically volatile Southern
Hall, Lexington, Kentucky 40506-0024, U.S.A. (lisa.cliggett@uky
Province, where annual hunger seasons have increased in se-
.edu). 23 VI 14
verity and duration, I have trouble reconciling the authors’
Trawick and Hornborg call for a fundamental shift in how optimistic take on “the limited-good” worldview. They do
(the global) “we” think about our economies and resources acknowledge that Foster focused his attention on envy and
with resulting transformations in behavior toward more sus- jealousy—calling this emphasis “unfortunate”—and suggest
tainable living. The authors examine what they identify as two that there could have been equal attention to cases of the
opposing worldviews driving contemporary exchange systems opposite.
and resource use. The first they call “the image of the unlim- It is indeed “unfortunate” to see envy and jealousy in ac-
ited good,” with players in global capitalism the biggest pro- tion—in Zambia these sentiments have been linked to the
ponents. In this “open-system” experience of the world, pesticide poisoning (and murder) of an ambitious man pe-
wealth and value are (mysteriously) created, and proponents rusing education as a path to a better life and to the burning
claim all can benefit and have a share of “the good.” The of another man’s chicken coop just as his efforts to start a
second worldview, “the image of the limited good,” which small-scale business began to show a return on his hard work,
the authors adopt from George Foster’s (1965) American An- to say nothing of numerous cases of witchcraft accusations.
thropologist article, frames resources, wealth, and “good I suspect that my examples are not unique among anthro-
things” as coming at a cost—particularly ecological. pologists working in impoverished places.
According to the authors, in communities where the lim- This is not to say that there are not instances where co-

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
18 Current Anthropology Volume 56, Number 1, February 2015

operation and solidarity may come about through the same what can simply be called speculation where the volume of
viewpoint or that the misfortune I mention relates solely to credit/debt is expanded without anything occurring in the
the limited-good worldview. However, without Trawick and real economy. So there are two dichotomies involved here.
Hornborg offering more examples other than the very unique The first harks back to the thermodynamic paradox of life as
cases of irrigation as proof that a “fixed-pie” system can pro- detailed by Schrödinger in which the latter is dependent on
mote cooperation, it is difficult to envision the scaling up its ability to consume its surroundings, turning the rest of
they call for. the world into a source of its negentropy. And this of course
The real question is, under what conditions do we see “a implies increasing entropy in the larger environment, whether
fixed-pie” worldview intersecting with cooperation and strong local or global (thus the link to imperialism). The more con-
leadership? What are the factors that promote positive social temporary work of Prigogine on the nature of living and even
and management relations when resources are scarce and peo- nonliving crystalline structures as rendered possible by the
ple know it? What makes the balance tip one way or another? appropriation of energy to maintain states that are far from
How do people and communities without previous experience thermodynamic equilibrium clearly delineates both the dy-
of cooperative institutions learn new ways of doing things? namics and fragility of evolutionary processes. But if all of
And how do communities with heterogeneous worldviews life is negentropic and therefore exploitative/imperialistic ac-
negotiate those differences? I suspect many of the answers tivity, then one should not be surprised if the human species
relate to the diversity of resource types and uses, ownership followed suit.
systems, and community socioeconomic dynamics, as Netting As much as one might be appalled by it, the archaeological
(1981) taught us long ago. record does not reveal stable zero-sum societies but, from the
As it is, this article is a provocative think piece with an very start, dynamic and expansive societies. Competitive ac-
underlying optimism that change for the better is possible. It cumulation seems such a commonplace that it is difficult to
is a call to act (or at least think) differently. But I, for one, deny its pervasiveness in world history. This might be ques-
would benefit from more evidence of the way such worldviews tioned, and it goes back to my debate with ecologists in the
play out in a broader range of ecosystems and communities. 70s. From a time in which hunter-gatherers of the contem-
porary world were assumed to represent the lost world of
ecological equilibrium, a great number of studies have shown
that such steady-state populations are most often the products
of collapsed larger systems and/or marginalization within such
Jonathan Friedman systems. This does not mean that they are not good to “think”
Department of Anthropology, University of California, San Diego, with, but as a model of world history they might represent a
9500 Gilman Drive, La Jolla, California 2093-0532, U.S.A. false dichotomization. Of course there are examples of co-
(jafriedman@ucsd.edu) and École des hautes études en sciences
sociales, 96 boulevard Raspail, Paris 75006, France. 21 VII 14 operative sharing and division of labor, but the latter need to
be historically contextualized.
This is a welcome article and much more than a mere reaction The second dichotomy is one that finds its best exempli-
to the crisis that has shocked so many since 2008, one that fication in Marx’s dynamic understanding of the relation be-
has been moralized and anguished about by economists and tween fictitious and real accumulation. Here again, while
other social scientists including anthropologists. It is difficult agreeing with the authors suggestions, I would propose a
to take on the total richness of the arguments proposed in a slightly different interpretation. Thus fictitious accumulation
short comment, so I restrict myself to a few themes. occurs periodically when real accumulation falters and is, as
The article builds on a well-known dichotomization of the is often the case, exported to other geographical areas. This
world, as of world history, into “closed” and “open” systems has been going on, but certainly not for the first time, since
characterized as stability/steady-state reproduction versus un- the 1980s, and the bubble economy that exploded in 2007–
limited growth. This is the model that has deep roots in the 8 is a result of that process, but one that is linked to declining
history of anthropology. From Sahlins’s critique of the Ne- real profits and the export of capital where the wealth “left
olithic revolution as a universal disaster to the Whole Earth behind,” so to say, is invested where it can most easily make
Catalog, this is a powerful way of talking about the runaway money, in the financial markets.
nature of the contemporary world. It has been taken up in a Finally, the authors suggest that the difference between
plethora of different discourses, from Marx’s simple versus closed and open systems is determined by closed and open
expanded reproduction, to Bateson and Rapport’s steady-state worldviews. I have difficulty in accepting such cultural de-
negative feedback versus civilizational-expansionism positive terminism. Competition and the accumulation of anything
feedback. There is then a second dichotomization, charac- from prestige to capital is not a cosmological imposition.
teristic of commercial economies, opposing the real (pro- Rather, the cosmology and even its ontologies emerge in a
ductive) and the virtual (financial) economy, the latter which complex interaction of social strategies and conditions of re-
has become increasingly savage in recent years with the emer- production. This was the weakness of Rappaport’s model of
gence of a large array of derivative instruments that enable the Maring of Papua New Guinea because they exemplify the

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Trawick and Hornborg Revisiting the Image of Limited Good 19

competitive accumulation that is dominant in the area. Con- (in which a commons may be found), commerce (the ex-
versely it would be difficult to argue that Chinese or Indian change of goods and services for money), finance (commercial
cosmologies, which are all about universal equilibrium, could banks, insurance companies, and the like that trade money),
generate such expansive and destructive socioeconomic pro- and metafinance (derivatives, structured investment vehicles,
cesses that characterize the dynamic histories of these im- and other instruments that center on making and taking risk
perialist social formations. for money). The spheres overlap and are linked through rents
So if we do find steady-state cosmologies and even relatively that flow upward. Rents, broadly, are returns received over
stable social orders in the world, it is not evident to me that and above productive efforts. The house and community re-
such models can be used to imagine a different global order. ceive “rents” (if the term is used here) from the earth and
On the contrary, I would suggest that it is the imagining of other natural elements. In myriad ways, money and labor
such an order from within our own expansionist system that rents—through tribute, tithes, monopolies, patents, bank
seeks its own opposite in the past or in the margins of our charges, high interest rates, and obfuscation (as in the Paul-
own world. The authors have done a splendid job in imag- son/Goldman Sachs example in which Paulson bet against a
ining that order, but we do not necessarily need the “other” vehicle he helped design for Goldman Sachs to sell)—flow
as a source of inspiration because it is we who created the upward through the spheres. As one illustration, in 2013 the
latter as category. top hedge fund managers received 25 billion dollars. If this
sum had been redistributed to the house and community
realms, it could have been used to improve children’s lunches
and health and help pay mortgages. Or, with reference to
entropy, placing a cap on these top-end gains and on the
Stephen Gudeman
Anthropology Department, University of Minnesota, 301 19th Av-
competitive expansion of markets into the natural world
enue South, Minneapolis, Minnesota 55403, U.S.A. (gudeman@ would lead to less pressure to secure rents and less pressure
umn.edu). 30 V 14 on the material environment. As Thomas Piketty (2014) has
recently argued, the rate of growth of capital over long periods
Trawick and Hornborg present a strong case for paying at-
of time and across many countries exceeds the rate of growth
tention to the second law of thermodynamics or entropy.
of the economy. This fascinating finding means that someone
Standard economics, as Georgescu-Roegen (1971a) made
is losing (as the increase of inequality suggests) and something
clear, does not incorporate this continual movement toward
is being despoiled (as the loss of butterflies and arctic ice
“chaos” or degradation of usable energy in our physical world.
suggests).
This reality undermines the idea that material wealth is an
Here I am in tangential agreement with Trawick and Horn-
“unlimited good” and that the gross national product can be
borg. As a community we must strengthen regulations on and
endlessly expanded. The solution, they argue, is to think of
limits to market expansion, impose progressive taxes in dif-
the earth’s resources as a commons whose use must be reg-
ferent forms, and use like measures. Markets have many ben-
ulated. Anthropologists have accumulated cases in which the
efits, but they promote invidious competition that leads to
image of “limited good” is the primary worldview and in
their continual expansion and overflow into the community,
which a commons is shared according to one or another social
house, and environmental spheres. Markets are a social in-
principle. Adoption of this alternative worldview can lead us
vention, however, and the social commons surrounding,
toward sustainability. I agree with many of the authors’ ar-
guments, although the problem of scaling up from the local structuring, and enabling them is a higher or more general
view and ways of doing to the national and international one than a physical commons consisting of a pasture or water
stages remains. rights. Actions such as Occupy Wall Street or the use of com-
I have other puzzlements. The authors draw a division munity no-interest currencies are helpful in bringing the crises
between physical or real capital and virtual or financial capital. of inequality, uncontrolled markets, and despoliation of the
But if one starts with the idea of entropy, then the idea of environment to the consciousness of people. But we also need
creating any wealth, whether real or virtual, is surely a cultural to reawaken our moral sensibilities and commitments—about
mystification. Any economic “good” is achieved at some phys- which Durkheim had much to say—and reinvigorate the idea
ical expenditure, that is, entropy. One might even argue that of economy as serving social and not only individual ends,
virtual wealth—in the extreme, trading one money sum for as economists and most people seem to think. Perhaps the
another over time—is less entropic than growing crops (with- environmental crisis will help us to do so. As I sometimes
out additives) for sustenance. Something more is needed to express it, we need to see economy as a tension between self-
make their model work. interested calculation and social relationships by which, for
I prefer to think of economies, especially capitalist ones, which, and through which it flows (Gudeman 2008, 2012).
in terms of spheres (an assertion with which I am certain Social relationships and commitments to others are not lim-
Hornborg agrees). I see modern economies as made up of ited goods. The economy must be brought into better balance
five spheres: the house (using the term broadly), community between its two sides.

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
20 Current Anthropology Volume 56, Number 1, February 2015

despite the seductive rhetoric of wealth creation, these laws


Karim-Aly Saleh Kassam are inviolable. The open-system paradigm at the heart of
Department of Natural Resources and American Indian Program, global capitalism does not exist in the physical universe. Ad-
College of Agriculture and Life Sciences, Cornell University, 122
Fernow Hall, Ithaca, New York 14853-3001, U.S.A. (karim-aly herence to its tenets has measurable and widespread conse-
.kassam@cornell.edu). 15 IX 14 quences. Humanity in the twenty-first century is a sociocul-
tural, ecological, and geophysical force. The Nobel laureate
The central argument made by Trawick and Hornborg is that Paul Crutzen (2002) has coined this epoch the Anthropocene
contemporary economic dogma of “wealth creation” contra- because of the massive environmental change induced on the
venes the laws of thermodynamics. What they call the “image planet. The current simultaneously occurring economic, en-
of unlimited good” (emphasis added) is just that, a mirage ergy, and environmental crises are unparalleled in human
that violates the fundamental laws of thermodynamics. “Real history and put all life on this planet in peril.
wealth,” they maintain, requires physical inputs of matter and The finite system we call the earth is a “commons” gov-
energy. The authors contrast the notion of “real wealth” with erned by the laws of thermodynamics. However, is the tragedy
that of “virtual wealth.” Virtual wealth is debt generation akin of the commons (Hardin 1968), while pervasive, necessarily
to legalized usury resulting in a contemporary form of serf- inevitable? Here Trawick and Hornborg draw on their own
dom. In this sense, virtual wealth is economically unproduc- and the work of others to show how human communities
tive, as it shifts the burden of debt onto future generations. are able to engage in wise use of scarce resources. Drawing
What Trawick and Hornborg are asserting is not new. Adam on literature from indigenous communities and peasant so-
Smith, especially, was cognizant of the “idle” or “unproduc- cieties, they illustrate the tragedy is not an inevitability. Hu-
tive” elements in eighteenth century society. “There is one man communities are capable of sustainably using limited
sort of labour which adds to the value of the subject upon common pool resources. This ecological consciousness, while
which it is bestowed; there is another which has no such effect. not easy to measure empirically in contemporary indigenous
The former is ‘productive’ and the latter is ‘unproductive’” communities, is present. However, the no-analogue (Crutzen
(Smith 1976:351). He elaborates: “The rent of land and the and Steffen 2003) character of the Anthropocene is at a speed,
profits of stock are everywhere, therefore, the principal sources scale, frequency, and intensity that defies the specific examples
from which unproductive hands derive their subsistence” scholars are able to furnish. The predicament ushered in by
(Smith 1976:354). “But there is no country in which the whole the Anthropocene requires a mindfulness that is not easily
annual produce is employed in maintaining the industrious. articulated and practiced.
The idle everywhere consume a great part of it” (Smith 1976: What is needed is a methodology of hope that outlines a
61), he explains. Adam Smith is specifically referring to the strategic way forward without engaging in facile platitudes of
virtual wealth creators of his generation such as the aristoc- sustainable development. For indigenous communities and
racy, courtiers, land and property owners, and bankers (Saul peasant societies, neither environmental degradation nor
1995). structural poverty is an option in the twenty-first century.
If what Trawick and Hornborg have to say is not new and This is a challenge the community of scholars who contribute
was recognized over 200 years ago by one of the founding to this journal and other applied journals in the biophysical
fathers of the market economy, why does it still need to be and social sciences as well as the humanities have failed to
repeated? Herein is the malady of the political economy in effectively meet. Regrettably, Trawick and Hornborg will con-
which humanity is currently ensnared. It is not unlike Alz- tinue to have to repeat what is already known but ignored
heimer’s disease befalling populations of entire societies— by the myopia of global capitalism. It seems there is no cure
namely, cultures that cannot recall the essential relationships to self-imposed dementia.
that sustain life and livelihoods. Society seems to be struck
by a collective dementia where both long- and short-term
memory is affected. The simile to Alzheimer’s is not com-
pletely accurate because human beings besot by this painful
Susan Paulson and Chuck Paulson
disease and their families did not have a choice, whereas Center for Latin American Studies, University of Florida, P.O. Box
pursuit of the illusory notion of wealth creation is religiously 115530, Gainesville, Florida 32611-5530, U.S.A. (spaulson@latam
propagated by our sociocultural institutions with an obsession .ufl.edu)/Division of Math and Science, Minneapolis Community
characteristic of addicts. and Technical College, 1501 Hennepin Avenue, Minneapolis, Min-
The language of wealth creation through financial or stock nesota 55403, U.S.A. 23 VI 14
management is conflated with the actual act of making. How-
ever, the euphemism of growing stock portfolios is not equiv-
Does Limited Material Mean Limited Good?
alent to making wealth. Creation involves destruction. The
cliché one needs to break eggs to make an omelet is apropos. By asking how worldviews interact with thermodynamic pro-
The laws of thermodynamics are applicable to all biophysical cesses, Trawick and Hornborg push us to think systemically
processes, including economic development. Furthermore, about the relations between meaning and material that con-

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Trawick and Hornborg Revisiting the Image of Limited Good 21

stitute all human life. They focus on one sociocultural insti- be described as “limited material good” to distinguish from
tution—economy—arguing that recent developments in sym- the sociocultural meanings that make economic goods good
bolic dimensions of economy have catalyzed dangerous (e.g., satisfaction, usefulness, beauty, prestige, pleasure, self-
expansion in the biophysical processes of economic produc- esteem). In a context where the only path to those subjective
tion. In solidarity with the desire to disrupt worldviews that gains is through increased material consumption, the quantity
propel limitless material production, we seek to strengthen of socially meaningful good is indeed limited.
alternative visions for progress. Our challenge is to learn from sociocultural systems that
Human meaning interacts with the transformation of mat- generate meaningful good in greater proportion to material
ter and energy in remarkably varied ways. For participants in throughput. As the authors recognize, the ethnographic rec-
today’s complex economies, symbolic phenomena of finance ord shows that cooperation reaps rewards in “limited-good”
capital associated with what the authors call “virtual wealth” contexts. Obviously participants in commons management
obscure relations with the physical world, boosting the illusion are rewarded with sustainable access to physical goods such
of infinitely expandable wealth. In contrast, people who par- as irrigation water and healthy watersheds. Yet ethnographers
ticipate directly in physical processes that create “real wealth” observe that these are intertwined with other kinds of good:
can see more easily how their work transforming raw materials community solidarity, identity, ritual exhilaration, and—im-
(low-entropy forms of matter and energy) will reach envi- portantly—a sense of equity and fairness (Wagner 2013). Cer-
ronmental limits. tainly elements of what Trawick (2001b) calls “the moral econ-
Trawick and Hornborg make a comparison, and demand omy of water” feel good in themselves; they also help generate
a choice, between two generalized worldviews. We hope their other kinds of good. As Wilkinson and Pickett (2011) argue
article motivates empirical study of manifestations of each for contemporary societies, greater equity is key to a range
and dynamics between them. The authors rightly locate the of social goods including longer lives, higher literacy and
“image of unlimited good” in a specific historical moment. numeracy, less incarceration, and better mental health.
Emerging from the experience of privileged Europeans, it de- Trawick and Hornborg conclude that “if people come to
veloped parallel with their ability to draw productive resources realize that economic ‘growth’ is a physically destructive pro-
(including land, labor, and energy) from distant sources, fa- cess . . . they may become more willing to take action to
cilitated by colonialism, the industrial revolution, and glob- restrain that growth by mutually limiting their own con-
alization. A concept of expandable wealth became instru- sumption.” Together with degrowth thinkers (D’Alisa, De-
mental in framing Europeans—and later global elites—as maria, and Kallis 2014), we propose moving beyond individ-
creators rather than plunderers. Over two centuries, views ual restraint to push for collaborative creativity. This move is
have changed in important ways. As Trawick and Hornborg facilitated by an anthropological conceptualization of “pro-
point out, classical economics was founded on a general equi- duction” in which humans produce not only food, shelter,
librium model depicting the economy as a closed system; it and clothing but also biophysical landscapes, financial sys-
was eventually called “the science of scarcity.” Smith, Malthus, tems, traditions of resource governance, and, most amazingly,
Jevons, and Marx analyzed interactions among diverse forms people socialized with skills, values, and worldviews. Critical
of financial and physical capital (including land, labor, coal) analysis of worldviews, calculation of thermodynamic pro-
in changing technological and politico-legal contexts. It is no cesses, and ethnography of commons management are all
surprise that so many anthropologists have engaged with this useful resources in the collaborative construction of socio-
classic body of thought. Nor is it surprising that so many cultural systems that distribute and employ the same amount
anthropologists have censured the neoclassical turn that nar- of material good in ways that bring about more social good.
rowed the scope of economics to market activity and, in the
second half of the twentieth century, worked to institution-
alize and disseminate the “image of unlimited good” via ac-
counting systems such as gross domestic product and the
United Nations System of National Accounts that exclude Laura Rival
natural and human capital from the measure of each country’s School of Anthropology, University of Oxford, 51 Banbury Road,
Oxford OX2 6PE, United Kingdom (laura.rival@anthro.ox.ac.uk).
wealth. 20 VII 14
The term “closed system” helps to interpret evidence that
human activity is pushing environmental limits, including Trawick and Hornborg are to be commended for addressing
measures of ocean acidification, nitrogen and phosphorous the ecological crisis and sustainability as core issues on which
inputs in the biosphere, and changes in climate and strato- anthropological thinking can be brought to bear. They chal-
spheric ozone (Royal Society 2012). It also draws necessary lenge the profoundly flawed ontology on which orthodox
attention to the distribution of environmental costs and ben- economics is based. In their view, mythical understandings
efits across space and time. However, the term “limited good” of wealth creation used to justify unending increases in ma-
needs more precision. The real constraint lies in the bio- terial and energy throughput on a finite planet must give way
physical throughput of economic production, which might to cultural worldviews that accurately depict physical and so-

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
22 Current Anthropology Volume 56, Number 1, February 2015

cial reality. Anthropology has a role to play in showing that 2001) and by reconsidering property rights in this new light.
the world is ecologically constrained and in identifying the We should not forget, however, that the institutional facts
true nature of real wealth. with which the discipline of economics concerns itself are
The authors are right to invite anthropologists to use their rooted in the symbolic power of language (Searle 2005). Un-
rich heritage to ask how new worldviews conducive to prin- like physics and chemistry, economic theory is dependent on
ciples of social organization consonant with sustainable re- human beliefs. Foucault, of course, would claim that deontic
source use in the longue durée may be fostered. I also welcome powers permeate the natural sciences every bit as much as
their proposition that one fruitful way for the discipline to they do constitute the social sciences. Modeling human be-
participate in the current interdisciplinary dialogue is to focus havior has thus profound implications for cultural evolution
on models and their underlying values and principles. Better and the ways in which social actors consider themselves ca-
political-economy theories embedded in system complexity pable or not of changing the course of their actions (Muradian
are needed. and Rival 2012). This is also true of our descriptions of world-
However, the dual opposition of images of limited versus views. No one has discussed the role of words in liberating
unlimited good, or of open- versus closed-system model, is the moral imagination better than James Fernandez (e.g.,
far too simplistic, as the controversy caused by Foster’s (1965) 1998). In his search for a new formulation of environmental
article plainly illustrates (e.g., Foster 1972). Rediscovering choices, Princen (2005) notes that “saying enough, indeed
world systems theory and cybernetics without revisiting the practicing enough, is not just a means of surviving, it is a
anthropological literature on culture and cognition will not means of thriving” (5). Perhaps the authors will consider
illuminate the myths humans live by, nor will it convince replacing “limited” with “thriving,” a word more amenable
sceptics that modeling peasant behavior has any relevance for to worldviews based on abundance rather than on deficit.
modeling human social behavior in the twenty-first century.
Moreover, anthropologists must address the fact that as they
describe and model the world, social scientists too enact
worldviews and base themselves on values, some of which are
of a normative nature; scientific objectivity depends on mak- Reply
ing these values explicit.
As Princen (2005) shows, hegemonic representations of We are grateful to the commentators for their thoughtful
how humans perceive the environment and should live their considerations of our argument. Although the specific im-
lives cannot be confronted without attending to norms and plications they draw from it differ, all seem to share our
values. Not unlike the authors, Princen distinguishes ecolog- fundamental conviction that the conventional economic
ical and nonecological rationality as two fundamentally op- worldview is deeply flawed and needs to be aligned with basic
posed worldviews guiding behavior and the organization of facts of natural science as well as insights expressed in some
society—especially its economy. Given that “maximisation nonmodern cosmologies elucidated by anthropologists. What
makes sense for machines but not for organisms and eco- difference this alignment might make on people’s consump-
systems” (Princen 2005:9), humans are perfectly capable of tion and their attitude toward wealth is disputed, as is the
confronting limits and of choosing sufficiency over efficiency. relative novelty of our proposal.
For Princen, such preference is guided not only by knowledge In response to Cliggett, we consider the closed-system
of the world’s biophysical properties but also by ethical con- model and the corollary image of limited good to be much
siderations. It is through moral reasoning that sufficiency more than a metaphor. It corresponds to a physical reality, a
comes to make perfect good sense in contemporary industrial set of incontrovertible facts. Those facts about the constraints
societies, as it has done throughout human history. His anal- on economic life have been widely acknowledged, especially
ysis comes remarkably close to Gudeman’s, for whom the in the field of ecological economics, but remain little discussed
core values of the “mutual realm” (means-to-ends forms of in a discipline like anthropology, which has tended to em-
reasoning such as thrift, sufficiency, or economizing) are phasize relativism and constructivist critique at the expense
bound to limit the expansion of competitive trade and cal- of objectivity and science. But the first and second laws of
culative reasoning (Gudeman 2008:45). Any long-term field- thermodynamics are not merely historical and social construc-
worker will know that the dialectics of trade and mutuality tions. They govern global society, circumscribing its future
that keep all economies in tension are far from symmetrical. development; and they are part of the foundation on which
Their dynamic tension often results in the former engulfing an ecological ethics and a politics of sustainability can be
the latter. If economy is a hierarchy of value spheres, as Gu- based.
deman proposes, why does sufficiency exist as a subordinate Cliggett’s point that acknowledgment of such constraints
principle, and how can it be restored to an ordinate one? is not tantamount to cooperation and social harmony is, how-
In addressing this question, we may start, as Trawick and ever, right on the mark. In fact, it can be argued, as we note
Hornborg do, by looking at economy as an open subsystem in the article, that tightening material constraints may be more
of a larger, finite, and nongrowing ecosystem (e.g., Hall et al. conducive to conflict than to cooperation. Thus it is com-

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Trawick and Hornborg Revisiting the Image of Limited Good 23

pletely justifiable to ask us to clarify our vision of how rec- metries in trade, accumulation, and inequalities. The weighing
ognizing such limits could lead to better arrangements of of cost against demand is conditioned by factors (such as
socioecological relations. Cliggett would also like to see more supply and purchasing power) that are distinct from the ma-
examples of diverse communities living sustainably within the terial content of exchange. The former is mainstream “eco-
fixed-pie model. The community-managed irrigation systems nomics” (Heilbroner 1995[1953]:210). The latter are concerns
we point to number in the hundreds, however; they are quite of classical political economy raised today by “heterodox”
diverse in scale and social complexity and are found today in schools such as Marxism and ecological economics. What the
nearly all parts of the globe. world desperately needs is a return to political economy. The
As for the factors and conditions that sustain them, the intricate mathematics of market equilibrium that is the stuff
most critical one was identified by Ostrom (2000). The scar- of neoclassical economics will not deliver us from the
city of the common-pool resource must be significant, with alarming prospects of the Anthropocene.
far less than enough to go around during a substantial part Friedman perfectly captures the connections we wish to
of the year, yet not so severe and enduring as to jeopardize illuminate between thermodynamics and imperialism. We
people’s livelihoods. The situation must be one of shared agree that this connection goes much farther back in human
hardship or challenge, not of a life-threatening shortage, history than the industrial revolution, and we admit that the
which would lead instead to tragedy, the outcome that Cliggett “others” to whom we look for more realistic cosmologies are
dreads and has observed so often in Africa. This is a sobering often the marginalized products of our own expansion. It is
realization, for it indicates that as the human population con- also valid to propose that cosmologies are generated by eco-
tinues to grow and capitalist extraction of resources inten- nomic processes rather than vice versa. This could in fact be
sifies, the conventional economic worldview will provide little exemplified by the economic rethinking that we assert is being
guidance on how to avert such tragedies. prompted by current financial and ecological crises. The sev-
Gudeman raises the crucial issue of spheres of exchange. eral failures of neoclassical economic theory are a consequence
Although we have only briefly mentioned alternative currency of its incapacity to account for the material limits being en-
systems, visions of better socioecological relations might well countered by the society it has encouraged. Rather than “cul-
focus on traditional monetary systems as well as on traditional
tural determinism,” we are suggesting that a change in world-
technologies for resource distribution such as water manage-
view is now widely underway that is the result of real
ment. The fundamental problem with the world economy
socioecological processes.
may not be the market principle itself as much as the im-
We cannot agree with Gudeman’s suggestion that virtual
plications of general-purpose money and the globalized scale
wealth may be less entropic than growing crops. As ecological
of the market. General-purpose money makes all values com-
economists ever since Sergei Podolinsky (2008 [1883]) have
mensurable regardless of whether they pertain to the repro-
argued, human augmentation of biomass on Earth is a way
duction of human organisms, of communities, of ecosystems,
of accumulating negative entropy ultimately deriving from the
or of the world system itself. It was the exploitation of glob-
sun, whereas the kinds of processes stimulated by the pursuit
alized price differences (i.e., arbitrage) that provided the con-
of capitalist profits generally imply destruction of finite nat-
ditions for the turn to fossil fuels in eighteenth-century Brit-
ural resources and increasing entropy. The alleged demater-
ain, which inaugurated anthropogenic climate change and the
ialization of the economy now underway in core areas of the
so-called Anthropocene. A way of curbing the destructive
world system is an illusion produced by environmental load
consequences of economic globalization might be to redis-
cover the virtues of distinguishing local values (such as those displacement to the periphery, especially China and India but
concerned with food, shelter, energy, community, place) from increasingly also Africa and Latin America. This zero-sum
the values pertaining to global trade and communication logic of the world economy is well acknowledged in Gude-
(Hornborg 2007, 2013b). Such a distinction would need to man’s conclusion that “someone is losing . . . and something
be acknowledged by our monetary system as well as in our is being despoiled.”
worldview. It may suffice, however, to have only two major Virtual wealth originates in the creation of debt, and it is
spheres of exchange rather than Gudeman’s five. used mainly as a catalyst to increase investment and/or con-
The very idea of money is to economists like water is to sumption. Such debt involves the creation of nothing material,
fish. The standard textbooks that have shaped the minds of basically just allowing people to spend tomorrow’s income
generations of economists devote not a word to reflecting on today by diverting their own future flows of that income. The
this strangest of human inventions without which economics most unfortunate aspect of this sleight of hand of “wealth
as a discipline would not exist (cf. Heilbroner 1995 [1953]). creation,” however, is that it causes people to overlook all the
The logic of market exchange explored by Alfred Mar- energy and materials that will have to be consumed in order
shall—whether identified in rates negotiated by Andean peas- to generate those future income flows. These are real material
ants at a rural vegetable market or in those used by Wall Street effects or costs of lending, but bankers do not have to pay
stock brokers—is an issue quite distinct from questions of for any of them, and such costs are widely and very delib-
the biophysical substance of commodity flows, material asym- erately ignored. This is what the vaunted “creation of wealth”

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
24 Current Anthropology Volume 56, Number 1, February 2015

does; it speeds up the ongoing process of thermodynamic the logic of economic accumulation calls for more than moral
decline and is destructive of order. appeals to a rearrangement of priorities. In order for suffi-
The distinction between “productive” and “unproductive” ciency to become a pervasive principle of human social life,
elements of the economy that Saleh Kassam traces back to the beliefs underlying economic theory need to be revised.
Adam Smith is not equivalent to our distinction between real For humans to thrive in the long run, the open-system model
and virtual wealth. The adding of exchange value by labor, underlying the image of unlimited good will have to be aban-
which so preoccupied Smith, Ricardo, and Marx, is not pro- doned.
ductive either from the perspective of thermodynamics (Geor- A decade ago the culture theorist Fredric Jameson observed
gescu-Roegen 1971b) or from that of peasants in Colombia that most people find it easier to imagine the end of the world
(Gudeman and Rivera 1990). This means that much of what than to imagine the end of capitalism. But globalized capi-
is conventionally considered “real wealth” is actually an index talism is increasingly a zero-sum game of winners and losers.
of entropy. Even Marx recognized that all human labor was If it is not substantially reorganized, most people on the planet
ultimately tributary to farming (Burkett 2003:150). If some- will ultimately be losers. We believe that anthropology ought
one has indeed said all of this before, as Kassam suggests, it to engage much more actively in imagining in this way,
certainly needed to be said again. Considering how well aware through a critical exploration of worldview, what Cliggett calls
traditional peasant populations once were of the limited na- “change for the better.”
ture of the good, “collective dementia” is an apposite diag- —Paul Trawick and Alf Hornborg
nosis.
A “strategic way forward” in the Anthropocene, which Kas-
sam calls for, requires radical insights about the entropy-ac-
celerating logic of general-purpose money. As we have shown, References Cited
mainstream economists are utterly unconcerned with ther-
Andersen, Otto. 2013. Unintended consequences of renewable energy. London:
modynamics. The uniquely human sign system we know as Springer.
“money,” which economists take for granted, needs to be Arrighi, Giovanni. 1994. The long 20th century: money, power and the origins
redesigned so as to distinguish between local values related of our times. London: Verso.
Austen, Ralph A. 1993. The moral economy of witchcraft: an essay in com-
to physical metabolism and survival on the one hand and parative history. In Modernity and its malcontents: ritual and power in post-
values related to global trade and communication on the colonial Africa. John L. Comaroff and Jean Comaroff, eds. Pp. 89–110.
other. The idea of complementary or community currencies Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Ayres, Robert U. 1998. The second law, the fourth law, recycling, and limits to
is thus far more significant than just bringing crises to people’s growth. INSEAD Working Paper 98/38. Fontainebleau, France: INSEAD.
consciousness, as suggested by Gudeman. Barkin, David. 1998. Wealth, poverty, and sustainable development. Mexico City:
The Paulsons propose that the challenge is to generate more Editorial Jus.
Bean, John L., and Thomas C. Blackburn. 1976. Native Californians: a theo-
meaningful good in proportion to material throughput, but retical retrospective. Menlo Park, CA: Balleena.
this is difficult to distinguish from the conventional aspira- Beccar, Lily, Rutgerd Boelens, and Paul Hoogendam. 2002. Water rights and
tions of sustainability discourse. The proposal demands that collective action in community irrigation. In Water rights and empowerment.
Rutgerd Boelens and Paul Hoogendam, eds. Pp. 1–19. Assen, The Neth-
we assess the outputs of production as being more or less erlands: Van Gorcum.
meaningful, which seems anthropologically unfeasible. Con- Beinhocker, Eric D. 2005. The origin of wealth: evolution, complexity, and the
sumption is inherently meaningful for consumers. Rather radical remaking of economics. London: Random House.
Bello, Walden, Kamal Malhotra, Nicola Bullard, and Marco Mezzera. 2000.
than pass judgment on specific kinds of consumption, we Notes on the ascendancy and regulation of speculative capital. In Global
need to realize that the economic processes stimulated by finance: new thinking on regulating speculative capital markets. W. Bello, N.
consumption—and thus by human meaning-making—are Bullard, and K. Malhotra, eds. Pp. 1–26. Dhaka, Bangladesh: New University
Press.
destructive of the biosphere and disproportionately cater to Berry, Wendell. 1977. The unsettling of America: culture and agriculture. San
the purchasing power of a global elite. To disconnect human Francisco: Avon.
meaning making from environmental degradation and capital ———. 1981. The gift of good land: further essays on culture and agriculture.
San Francisco: North Point.
accumulation requires redesigning the monetary system that Boelens, Rutgerd, and Gloria Davila. 1998. Reflections. In Searching for equity:
now connects them. That would entail a truly massive cultural conceptions of justice and equity in peasant irrigation. Rutgerd Boelens and
and political shift consonant with the shift in worldview we Gloria Davila, eds. Pp. 445–459. Assen, The Netherlands: Van Gorcum.
Boelens, Rutgard, and David Hoogendam, eds. 2002. Water rights and em-
are advocating.
powerment. Assen, The Netherlands: Van Gorcum.
Rival disagrees that the premises underlying peasant be- Bromley, David, ed. 1992. Making the commons work: theory, practice and
havior may be relevant for human social behavior in the policy. San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies.
twenty-first century. She suggests that moral reasoning rather Burkett, Paul. 2003. The value problem in ecological economics: lessons from
the physiocrats and Marx. Organization and Environment 16:137–167.
than recognition of physical limits may suffice for sufficiency Callinicos, Alex. 2003. An anti-capitalist manifesto. Cambridge: Cambridge
to “make perfect good sense” in the contemporary world. We University Press.
believe that the failure of sustainability discourse over the past Catton, William R., Jr. 1980. Overshoot: the ecological basis of revolutionary
change. Urbana: University of Illinois Press.
half century shows that moral reasoning is not enough. The Chang, Ha-Joon. 2007. Bad Samaritans. London: Random House.
fact that notions of sufficiency continue to be subordinate to Cliggett, Lisa. 2001. Carrying capacity’s new guise: folk models in anthropology

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Trawick and Hornborg Revisiting the Image of Limited Good 25

and the longitudinal study of environmental change. Africa Today 48(1):3– Gray, John. 1998. False dawn: the delusions of global capitalism. London: Granta
20. [LC] Books.
Coggan, Philip. 2011. Paper promises: money, debt, and the new world order. Greco, Thomas H. 2009. The end of money and the future of civilization.
New York: Penguin. London: Chelsea Green.
Comaroff, Jean, and John L. Comaroff. 1999. Occult economies and the vi- Grosfoguel, Ramón. 2010. The epistemic decolonial turn: beyond political-
olence of abstraction: notes from the South African postcolony. American economy paradigms. In Globalization and the decolonial option. Walter D.
Ethnologist 26(2):279–303. Mignolo and Arturo Escobar, eds. Pp. 65–77. New York: Routledge.
Correa-Leite, Jose. 2005. World Social Forum: strategies of resistance. Chicago: Gudeman, Stephen. 1986. Economics as culture: models and metaphors of live-
Haymarket. lihood. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.
Crutzen, P. J. 2002. Geology of mankind. Nature 415:23. [KSK] ———. 2008. Economy’s tension: the dialectics of community and market. New
Crutzen, P. J., and W. Steffen. 2003. How long have we been in the Anthro- York: Berghahn. [SG, LR]
pocene era? Climate Change 61:253. [KSK] ———. 2012. Vital energy: the current of relations. Social Analysis 66(1):57–
D’Alisa, Giacomo, Federico Demaria, and Giorgios Kallis, eds. 2014. Degrowth: 73. [SG]
a vocabulary for a new era. London: Routledge. [SP/CP] Gudeman, Stephen, and Alberto Rivera. 1990. Conversations in Colombia: the
Daly, Herman, and Joshua Farley. 2003. Ecological economics: principles and domestic economy in life and text. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
applications. New York: Island Press. Hall, Charles, Dietmar Lindenberger, Reiner Kümmel, Timm Kroeger, and
Davies, James B., Susanna Sandstrom, Anthony Shorrocks, and Edward N. Wolfgang Eichhorn. 2001. The need to reintegrate the natural sciences with
Wolff. 2008. The world distribution of household wealth. World Institute for economics. Bioscience 51(8):663–673. [LR]
Development Economics Research Discussion Paper 2008/03. Helsinki: Hannan, Daniel. 2010. The new road to serfdom: a letter of warning to America.
World Institute for Development Economics Research. New York: Harper.
Davis, Wade. 2009. The light at the edge of the world: a journey through the Hardin, Garret. 1968. The tragedy of the commons. Science 162:1243–1248.
realm of vanishing cultures. Vancouver, British Columbia: Douglas & Hardt, Michael, and Antonio Negri. 2000. Empire. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
McIntyre. University Press.
De Sousa Bonaventura, Santo. 2006. The rise of the global left: the World Social Hart, Keith. 2001. Money in an unequal world. New York: Texere.
Forum and beyond. London: Zed. Harvey, David. 2010. The enigma of capital and the crises of capitalism. New
Dolšak, Nives, and Elinor Ostrom, eds. 2003. The commons in the new mil- York: Profile.
lennium: challenges and adaptation. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Heilbroner, Robert. 1995 (1953). The worldly philosophers: the lives, times and
Douthwaite, Richard. 1996. The ecology of money. Devon, UK: Green Books. ideas of the great economic thinkers. 7th edition. London: Penguin.
Escobar, Arturo. 1995. Encountering development: the making and unmaking Hornborg, Alf. 1992. Machine fetishism, value, and the image of unlimited
of the Third World. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. good: towards a thermodynamics of imperialism. Man, n.s., 27:1–18.
———. 2010a. Postconstructivist political ecologies. In International handbook ———. 2001. The power of the machine: global inequalities of economy, tech-
of environmental sociology. 2nd edition. Michael Redclift and Graham Wood- nology, and environment. Walnut Creek, CA: AltaMira.
gate, eds. Pp. 91–105. Cheltenham, UK: Elgar. ———. 2006. Footprints in the cotton fields: the industrial revolution as
———. 2010b. Worlds and knowledges otherwise: the Latin American mo- time-space appropriation and environmental load displacement. Ecological
dernity/coloniality research program. In Globalization and the decolonial Economics 59(1):74–81.
option. Walter D. Mignolo and Arturo Escobar, eds. Pp. 33–64. New York: ———. 2007. Learning from the Tiv: why a sustainable economy would have
Routledge. to be multicentric. Culture and Agriculture 29(2):63–69.
Fernandez, J. 1998. Trees of knowledge of self and other in culture: our models ———. 2011. Global ecology and unequal exchange: fetishism in a zero-sum
for the moral imagination. In The social life of trees. L. Rival, ed. Pp. 81– world. London: Routledge.
110. London: Berg. [LR] ———. 2013a. The fossil interlude: Euro-American power and the return of
Foster, G. M. 1972. A second look at limited good. Anthropological Quarterly the physiocrats. In Cultures of energy: power, practices, technologies. Sarah
45(2):57–64. [LR] Strauss, Stephanie Rupp, and Thomas Love, eds. Pp. 41–59. Walnut Creek,
Foster, George. 1965. Peasant society and the image of limited good. American CA: Left Coast Press.
Anthropologist 67(2):293–315. ———. 2013b. Revelations of resilience: from the ideological disarmament
Foucault, Michel. 1970. The order of things: an archaeology of the human of disaster to the revolutionary implications of (p)anarchy. Resilience: In-
sciences. London: Tavistock. ternational Policies, Practices and Discourses 1(2):116–129.
Frank, Andre Gunder. 1966. The development of underdevelopment. Monthly ———. 2014a. Ecological economics, Marxism, and technological progress:
Review 18:17–31. some explorations of the conceptual foundations of theories of ecologically
Georgescu-Roegen, Nicholas. 1971a. The entropy law and the economic prob- unequal exchange. Ecological Economics 105:11–18.
lem. In Valuing the earth: economy, ecology and ethics. Herman E. Daly and ———. 2014b. Why solar panels don’t grow on trees: technological utopi-
Kenneth E. Townsend, eds. Pp. 75–88. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. anism and the uneasy relation between Marxism and ecological economics.
———. 1971b. The entropy law and the economic process. Cambridge, MA: In Green utopianism. Johan Hedrén and Karin Bradley, eds. Pp. 76–97.
Harvard University Press. London: Routledge.
———. 1975. Selections from “Energy and Economic Myths.” Southern Eco- Hudson, Michael. 2006. The new road to serfdom: an illustrated guide to the
nomic Journal 41(3):347–381; repr. in Herman E. Daly and K. E. Townsend, coming real estate collapse. Harper’s Magazine, May.
eds. 1993. Valuing the earth: economy, ecology and ethics. Pp. 89–112. Cam- Hyde, Lewis. 1983. The gift: imagination and the erotic life of poetry. New York:
bridge, MA: MIT Press. Vintage.
———. 1993. Thermodynamics and we, the humans. In Entropy and bioe- International Energy Agency. 2004. Key world energy statistics. Paris: Inter-
conomics: proceedings of the First International Conference of the European national Energy Agency.
Association for Bioeconomic Studies. Joseph C. Dragan, Eberhard K. Seifert, ———. 2009. World energy outlook. Paris: International Energy Agency.
and Mihai C. Demetrescu, eds. Pp. 184–201. Milan: Nagard. ———. 2010. World energy outlook. Paris: International Energy Agency.
Giampietro, Mario, and David Pimentel. 1993. The tightening conflict: pop- ———. 2013. International energy outlook. Paris: International Energy Agency.
ulation, energy use, and the ecology of agriculture. NPG Forum, October. Kåberger, Tomas, and Bengt Månsson. 2001. Entropy and economic processes:
———. 1994. Energy utilization in agriculture. In Encyclopedia of agricultural physics perspectives. Ecological Economics 36:165–179.
science, vol. 2. C. J. Arntzen and E. M. Ritter, eds. Pp. 63–76. San Diego, Kaplan, David, and Benson Saler. 1966. Foster’s “Image of Limited Good”:
CA: Academic Press. an example of anthropological explanation. American Anthropologist 68(1):
Glick, Thomas F. 1970. Irrigation and society in medieval Valencia. Cambridge, 202–206.
MA: Harvard University Press. Keen, Steve. 2011. Debunking economics: the naked emperor dethroned? London:
Graeber, David. 2001. Toward an anthropological theory of value: the false coin Zed.
of our own dreams. Houndmills, UK: Palgrave. Korten, David. 2001. When corporations rule the world. Bloomfield, CT: Kum-
———. 2007. Possibilities: essays on hierarchy, rebellion, and desire. Oakland, arian.
CA: AK Press. Krugman, Paul. 2008. The return of depression economics and the crisis of 2008.
———. 2011. Debt: the first five thousand years. New York: Melville House. New York: Penguin.

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
26 Current Anthropology Volume 56, Number 1, February 2015

———. 2012. End this depression now. New York: Norton. Perkins, John. 2004. Confessions of an economic hit man. San Francisco: Berrett-
Lancaster, John. 2010. Whoops! why everyone owes everyone and no one can Koehler.
pay. London: Penguin. Petras, James, and Henry Veltmayer. 2001. Globalization unmasked: imperi-
Lansing, J. Stephen. 1991. Priests and programmers: technologies of power in alism in the 21st century. London: Zed.
the engineered landscape of Bali. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Piketty, Thomas. 2014. Capital in the twenty-first century. Cambridge, MA:
———. 1993. Emergent properties of Balinese water temples. American An- Harvard University Press. [SG]
thropologist 95(1):97–114. Pimentel, David. 1993. Economics and energetics of organic and conventional
———. 2006. Perfect order: recognizing complexity in Bali. Princeton, NJ: farming. Journal of Agricultural and Environmental Ethics 6:53–60.
Princeton University Press. Podolinsky, Sergei. 2008 (1883). Human labor and unity of force. Historical
Lee, Richard. 1996. Moral money? LETS and the social construction of local Materialism 16(1):163–183.
geographies in southeast England. Environment and Planning A 28(8):1377– Pollin, Robert. 2005. Contours of dissent: U.S. economic fractures and the land-
1394. scape of global austerity. London: Verso.
Maass, Arthur, and Raymond L. Anderson. 1978. And the desert shall rejoice: Pomeranz, Kenneth. 2000. The great divergence: China, Europe, and the making
conflict, growth and justice in arid environments. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. of the modern world economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Malthus, Thomas R. 1820. Principles of political economy. London: Murray. Prieto, Pedro A., and Charles A. S. Hall. 2013. Spain’s photovoltaic revolution:
Marshall, Alfred. 1947. Principles of economics. 8th edition. London: Blackwell. the energy return on investment. New York: Springer.
Marshall, Graham R. 2005. Economics for collaborative environmental man- Princen, T. 2005. The logic of sufficiency. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. [LR]
agement: renegotiating the commons. London: Earthscan. Radelet, Stephen, and Jeffrey Sachs. 1999. What have we learned, so far, from
Martinez-Alier, Joan. 1987. Ecological economics: energy, environment and so- the Asian financial crisis? CAER II Discussion Paper 37. Cambridge, MA:
ciety. Oxford: Blackwell. Harvard Institute for International Development.
Mayer, Enrique. 2002. The articulated peasant: household economies in the Rappaport, Roy. 1979. Ecology, meaning, and religion. Berkeley, CA: North
Andes. Boulder, CO: Westview. Atlantic Books.
McCay, Bonnie, and James Acheson, eds. 1987. The question of the commons: ———. 1999. Ritual and religion in the making of humanity. Cambridge:
the culture and ecology of communal resources. Tucson: University of Arizona Cambridge University Press.
Press. Reichel-Dolmatoff, Gerardo. 1974. Amazonian cosmos: the sexual and religious
Mignolo, Walter D. 2010. Introduction: coloniality of power and de-colonial imagery of the Tukano Indians. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
thinking. In Globalization and the decolonial option. Walter D. Mignolo and ———. 1978. Beyond the Milky Way: hallucinatory images of the Tukano In-
Arturo Escobar, eds. Pp. 1–21. New York: Routledge. dians. Los Angeles: University of California Press.
Mignolo, Walter D., and Arturo Escobar, eds. 2010. Globalization and the Rifkin, Jeremy. 1989. Entropy: into the greenhouse world. Rev. edition. New
decolonial option. New York: Routledge. York: Bantam.
Royal Society. 2012. People and the planet report. London: Royal Society Science
Mirowski, Philip. 1984. Physics and the marginalist revolution. Cambridge
Policy Centre. [SP/CP]
Journal of Economics 8:361–379.
Saul, John Ralston. 1995. The unconscious civilization. Concord, Ontario:
———. 1991. More heat than light: economics as social physics, physics as
House of Anansi. [KSK]
nature’s economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Scott, James. 1998. Seeing like a state. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Muradian, R., and L. Rival. 2012. Between markets and hierarchies: the chal-
———. 2012. Two cheers for anarchism: six essays on autonomy, dignity and
lenge of governing ecosystem services. Ecosystem Services 1(1):93–100. [LR]
meaningful work and play. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Nash, June. 1994. Global integration and subsistence insecurity. American
Searle, J. 2005. What is an institution? Journal of Institutional Economics 1(1):
Anthropologist 96(2):1–31.
1–22. [LR]
———, ed. 2007. The notion of the limited good and the specter of the Sen, Amartya. 1999. Development as freedom. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
unlimited good. In Practicing ethnography in a globalizing world: an an- Sen, Jai, and Peter Waterman. 2012. World Social Forum: critical explorations.
thropological odyssey. Pp. 35–54. Walnut Creek, CA: AltaMira. New Delhi: OpenWord.
National Research Council. 1986. Proceedings of the Conference on Common Sieferle, Rolf Peter. 1982. The subterranean forest: energy systems and the in-
Property Management. National Research Council. Washington, DC: Na- dustrial revolution. Isle of Harris, UK: White Horse.
tional Academy Press. Sklair, Leslie. 2000. The transnational capitalist class and the discourse of
Netting, Robert. 1981. Balancing on an Alp: ecological change and continuity globalization. Cambridge Review of International Affairs 14(1):67–85.
in a Swiss mountain community. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Smith, Adam. 1976. An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of
[LC] nations. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. [KSK]
———. 1993. Smallholders, householders: farm families and the ecology of in- Soddy, Frederick. 1921. The role of money. London: Routledge.
tensive agriculture. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press. ———. 1926. Wealth, virtual wealth and debt. London: Allen & Unwin.
O’Hara, Phillip A. 2004. A new transnational social structure of accumulation Stiglitz, Joseph. 2002. Globalization and its discontents. New York: Norton.
for long-wave upswing in the world economy? Review of Radical Political ———. 2010. Freefall: America, free markets, and the sinking of the world
Economics 36(3):328–335. economy. New York: Norton.
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for Stiglitz, Joseph, and Linda Blimes. 2008. The three trillion dollar war: the true
collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. cost of the Iraq war. New York: Norton.
———. 1992. Crafting institutions for self-governing irrigation systems. San Taussig, Michael. 1980. The devil and commodity fetishism in South America.
Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies Press. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.
———. 2000. Reformulating the commons. Swiss Political Science Review 6(1): ———. 1991. Shamanism, colonialism, and the wild man: a study in terror
29–52. and healing. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Ostrom, Elinor, Joanna Burger, Christopher B. Field, Richard B. Norgaard, Taylor, Lance. 1991. Economic openness: problems to the century’s end. In
and David Policansky. 1999. Revisiting the commons: local lessons, global Economic liberalization: no panacea (the experiences of Latin America and
challenges. Science 284(5412):1–10. Asia). T. Banuri, ed. Pp. 91–147. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Ostrom, Elinor, Thomas Dietz, Nives Dolšak, Paul C. Stern, Susan Stonich, Toussant, Eric. 2004. Your money or your life: the tyranny of global finance.
and Elke U. Weber, eds. 2002. The drama of the commons. Washington, London: Pluto.
DC: National Academy Press. Trawick, Paul. 2001a. The moral economy of water: equity and antiquity in
Parry, J., and M. Bloch. 1989. Introduction: money and the morality of ex- the Andean commons. American Anthropologist 103(2):361–379.
change. In Money and the morality of exchange. J. Parry and M. Bloch, eds. ———. 2001b. Successfully governing the commons: principles of social or-
Pp. 1–32. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ganization in an Andean irrigation system. Human Ecology 29(1):1–25.
Perez, Carlotta. 2003. Technological revolutions and financial capital: the dy- ———. 2002a. Against the privatization of water: an indigenous model for
namics of bubbles and golden ages. Glasgow: Elgar. improving existing laws and successfully governing the commons. World
Pérez Rincón, Mario. 2006. Colombian international trade from a physical Development 31(6):977–996.
perspective: towards an ecological “Prebisch thesis.” Ecological Economics ———. 2002b. Comedy and tragedy in the Andean commons. Journal of
59:519–529. Political Ecology 9:35–68.

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Trawick and Hornborg Revisiting the Image of Limited Good 27

———. 2003. The struggle for water in Peru: comedy and tragedy in the Andean Wade, Robert C. 2003. Is globalization really reducing poverty and inequality?
commons. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press. World Development 32(4):567–589.
———. 2005. Going with the flow: the state of contemporary studies of water Wagner, John Richard, ed. 2013. The social life of water. New York: Berghahn.
management in Latin America. Latin American Research Review 40(3):443– [SP/CP]
456. Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1974. The modern world system. New York: Academic
———. 2008. Scarcity, equity, and transparency: general principles for suc- Press.
cessfully governing the water commons. In Mountains: sources of water, ———. 1979. The capitalist world-economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University
sources of knowledge. Ellen Wiegandt, ed. Pp. 43–62. Dordrecht, The Neth- Press.
erlands: Springer. ———. 1984. The politics of the world economy. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni-
versity Press.
———. 2010. Encounters with the moral economy of water: general principles
———. 1995. After liberalism. New York: New Press.
for successfully managing the commons. In Water ethics: foundational read-
Walsh, Catherine. 2010. Shifting the geopolitics of critical knowledge: deco-
ings for students and professionals. Peter Brown and Jeremy J. Schmidt, eds.
lonial thought and cultural studies: “others” in the Andes. In Globalization
Pp. 155–166. Washington, DC: Island Press. and the decolonial option. Walter D. Mignolo and Arturo Escobar, eds. Pp.
Trawick, Paul, Mar Ortega, and Guillermo Palau. 2014. Encounters with the 78–93. New York: Routledge.
moral economy of water: convergent evolution in Valencia. Wiley Interdis- Wilkinson, Richard, and Kate Pickett. 2011. The spirit level: why greater equality
ciplinary Reviews: Water 1(1):87–110. makes societies stronger. New York: Bloomsbury. [SP/CP]
Trouillot, Michel Rolf. 1988. Peasants and capital: Dominica and the world Wolf, Martin. 2008. Fixing global finance: how to curb financial crises in the
economy. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University. 21st century. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Volker, Paul. 2010. The time we have is growing short. New York Review of Wright, Robert. 2000. Nonzero: the logic of human destiny. New York: Random
Books 57(11):12–14. House.

This content downloaded from 128.59.222.12 on Sat, 14 Feb 2015 19:16:33 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Potrebbero piacerti anche