Sei sulla pagina 1di 209

Jorge Eduardo Fernandez-Pol

Charles Harvie

Understanding
the Creative
Economy and
the Future
of Employment
Understanding the Creative Economy and the Future
of Employment
Jorge Eduardo Fernandez-Pol • Charles Harvie

Understanding the Creative


Economy and the Future of
Employment
Jorge Eduardo Fernandez-Pol Charles Harvie
Economics Discipline, Economics Discipline,
Faculty of Business Faculty of Business
University of Wollongong University of Wollongong
Wollongong, NSW, Australia Wollongong, NSW, Australia

ISBN 978-981-15-1651-1 ISBN 978-981-15-1652-8 (eBook)


https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-1652-8

© Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. 2020


This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved by the Publisher, whether the whole or part
of the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations,
recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other physical way, and transmission or
information storage and retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or dissimilar
methodology now known or hereafter developed.
The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc. in this
publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are exempt
from the relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use.
The publisher, the authors, and the editors are safe to assume that the advice and information in this book
are believed to be true and accurate at the date of publication. Neither the publisher nor the authors or the
editors give a warranty, expressed or implied, with respect to the material contained herein or for any
errors or omissions that may have been made. The publisher remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional
claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

This Springer imprint is published by the registered company Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.
The registered company address is: 152 Beach Road, #21-01/04 Gateway East, Singapore 189721,
Singapore
Preface

We would like to open this preface by stating the obvious. The most striking feature
of the modern economy is the rapidity of innovations in virtually every sector.
Innovations can happen almost everywhere – from places as diverse as backyard
sheds to university halls to corporate laboratories. But whatever the place, innova-
tion is about people – the people who create the new idea, the people who develop
and deliver that idea, the people who benefit from that innovation and the people
negatively affected due to, for example, job losses associated with labour-saving
innovations. Many innovations occur because people want to make money with their
creative efforts. As a result, innovation becomes an economic activity to be taken
seriously.
We believe that there is a need to adequately prepare the layperson for under-
standing what is going on in the modern economy with a view to the relentless
progression towards automation of human tasks involving mental functions. We
hope that this book will enable readers to get a better picture of the world in which
they live and the direction in which it is moving.
The purpose of Understanding the Creative Economy and the Future of Employ-
ment is to help a broad audience to acquire a working knowledge of the contempo-
rary economy and form an opinion about the implications of an innovation-driven
economy. Indeed, the present book aims at being accessible to readers with only
superficial knowledge (if any) in economics and is thus largely self-contained.
Throughout the book, we keep the exposition at a level appropriate to a wide
audience. The key concepts are relatively easy to grasp because they are illustrated
with practical examples taken from the real world.
As the title suggests, it is a book designed to provide readers with insights and
intuition about the workings of a modern economy with sharp focus on new ideas
and the convergence to an automated economy. In writing the book, we have
followed to the letter the principle introduced by Albert Einstein: “Everything should
be made as simple as possible, but not simpler”.
A salient feature of this book is its adherence to a discursive, non-mathematical
style. We rely on the power of the written ordinary language, not on mathematical

v
vi Preface

diagrams or formulas. We keep the mathematical technicalities to a minimum. The


first six chapters contain only sporadic use of arithmetic. The only chapter with some
elementary mathematical diagrams and formulas is Chapter 7, but we are confident
that it is possible to follow the thread of the argument without any special mathe-
matical competence.
The present book has been written under the assumption that what readers
initially want is clarity combined with conciseness. The core of each chapter is
relatively brief. Brevity has been achieved by supplementing the themes in each
chapter with appendices. We are confident that these two features (brief core and
appendices) will help avoid reader’s fatigue.
In this book, we use non-mathematical diagrams to succinctly summarize con-
cepts and conceptual frameworks in a visual fashion. Somewhat roughly, a
non-mathematical diagram is a snapshot that encompasses the main points or
relationships between concepts associated with a specific topic. These schemes do
not prove anything, but we believe they are useful to encode information in the
reader’s biological memory.
Finally, it should be emphasized that many topics covered in the book cannot be
found in elementary economics textbooks. The reason is that innovation as an
economic activity is a neglected area of both high school and undergraduate teach-
ing. This suggests that our book could be useful to supplement the orthodox teaching
of basic economics.

Wollongong, NSW, Australia Jorge Eduardo Fernandez-Pol


September 2019 Charles Harvie
Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful for the support of the Centre for Contemporary Australasian
Business and Economics Studies (CCABES), allowing us to distribute this prelim-
inary version of the book for comments of the members of the Centre.
We are indebted to two anonymous reviewers for detailed and helpful comments.
We have incorporated some of the strategic points made by the reviewers. We firmly
believe that their comments have greatly improved the book.

August 2019 Eduardo Pol


Charles Harvie

vii
Introduction

In broad terms, the thread of the argument of this book can be easily outlined.

Chapter 1 A Bird’s-Eye View of the Economy and Economics

This introductory chapter will not turn anyone into an economist, but it will provide
everyone with an overview about the economy and economics. The “economy” and
“economics” are terms that should not be used interchangeably. The term economy
refers to innumerable activities of production and consumption that constitutes the
economic reality. Economics is the discipline that studies the economy. Economists
use guiding insights to understand how the economy works and evolves. In partic-
ular, they formulate predictions or prognostications of the future based on evidence
from the past.

Chapter 2 What a Creative Economy Is and How It Works

A creative economy is one in which the increase in the standard of living at a country
level is based on the capacity for innovation. Understanding the Creative Economy
requires two steps. The first step consists of conceiving innovation as an economic
activity. This activity involves three dimensions: creativity, intellectual property and
innovation environment. The second step entails the statement of the principles that
govern the behaviour of a creative economy.

ix
x Introduction

Chapter 3 Creativity and Intellectual Property

The first dimension in the innovation process is creativity. Innovators perform


creative thinking to produce new ideas. Different types of thinking are explained
and exemplified. The act of innovation typically gives rise to intangible property.
This is why we have a second dimension called intellectual property (ownership of
an idea by the person who came up with it). It is important for innovators to have the
right to prevent others from using their new ideas without authorization. Different
tools for protecting intellectual property are explained and illustrated.

Chapter 4 Innovation Environment

Even if creativity has a powerful grip of the nation’s collective imagination and the
country in question has an excellent protection of intellectual property, the production
of new ideas with economic value may be low. Innovators require an appropriate
innovation environment. The third dimension – innovation environment – has two
constitutive parts: an innovation infrastructure (macro factor affecting the production
of profitable new ideas throughout the nation) and a system of interconnected
components (micro factor conducive to competitive advantage within a cluster).

Chapter 5 Microeconomic Aspects of Innovation

Innovation as any economic activity uses inputs (e.g. creative thinking) to create
outputs (e.g. products new to the world). There are three risks associated with this
economic activity: technical, commercial and economic. The allocation of inputs
may not create any output (risk 1: the new product is not technically feasible). It may
be the case that the new product is technically feasible but it does not merit
commercial introduction (risk 2: the cost of production is prohibitive). It may also
be the case that the new product is commercialized but the market rejects it (risk 3:
the innovation is not profitable).
In practice, there are two types of innovative companies. Some companies create
new products by modifying existing products (type 1 companies), e.g. creation of a
new binary digital electronic computer based on transistors and capacitors where the
novelty is just a curved screen; other companies focus their creative energies on the
generation of products that represent an important shift from anything that has come
before (type 2 companies), e.g. creation of a quantum computer (completely differ-
ent from binary digital electronic computers). The innovator’s dilemma focuses
attention on the following real possibility: type 1 companies become complacent
through implementing small changes to existing products but suddenly lose market
dominance under unexpected attacks launched by type 2 companies.
Introduction xi

Type 1 and type 2 companies are merging into a third type of innovative company
following the fast innovation approach which emphasizes differentiation to attract
premium prices, speed to market to avoid commoditization and pursuit of disruptive
innocations to protect themselves against other disruptors.

Chapter 6 Looking to the Near Future

Some of the new products or processes – even new forms of organization – intro-
duced in the economy focus on two attributes that are not mutually exclusive: cost
reductions and efficiency gains. A new wave of automation propelled by artificial
intelligence (AI) and robotics is increasingly focussing on these attributes. The
immediate impact of these innovations may be human replacement.
For example, a worker can have the skills and capabilities to perform a produc-
tive job, but if a robot is cheap to buy and can do the same job at a lower cost, a
profit-seeking firm will buy a robot. Productivity and output could increase
dramatically, but these robots would bring severe dislodgements to the labour
market. Quite obviously, every economically rational employer would prefer
robots because they provide at least equal capability at a lower cost. Even those
managers who initially resist replacing humans with robots eventually would have
little choice but to reduce the number of workers to make the transition once their
competitors do so. Consequently, profit-seeking employers would replace most
human workers.
AI may allow tasks once thought to be out of reach from automation (think of
driving cars and making medical recommendations) to succumb. The current debate
between the technology enthusiasts and technology sceptics about the future of
employment is not about whether jobs will be lost but whether the economy will
create enough new jobs to compensate for those jobs taken by robots forever.
Technology enthusiasts use historical evidence to show that there is nothing to
worry about. In opposition to this view is the contention emerging from the sceptics
that this time is different.

Chapter 7 Looking to the Distant Future

After being concerned in Chapter 6 with the near future, in this (final) chapter, we
shift our attention to the distant future. Since no data is available from the future,
economic logic is essential to envisage the creative economy of the remote future. If
there are increasing returns to automation –meaning a relentless progression towards
even more automation – the creative economy will converge on a situation where
robots substitute for workers entirely and no one will have an income from any type
of labour. The solution to this paradox may be to abandon capitalism.
xii Introduction

This speculative narrative is in line with Schumpeter’s prophecy – capitalism is


doomed – but the reasons for the collapse are different. Schumpeter claimed that the
breakdown of capitalism would be caused by a toxic sociology inherent to the
capitalist system. However, the central line of reasoning in Chapter 7 is that
capitalism turns out to be the victim of its own success because the creative economy
will lead to pervasive unemployment.

Appendices

Each chapter has one or two appendices designed to provide additional knowledge
about key issues. The purpose of the appendices is to avoid reader fatigue in the
sense that the reader first goes through a particular chapter and, then, decides
whether to absorb more details.

Appendices to Chapter 1

Appendix A: Innovation as a Problem Area of Economics


In this appendix, we argue that innovation is an integral part of economics.
Appendix B: The Invisible Hand and Innovation
Adam Smith introduced the famous metaphor or notion of the “invisible hand”
suggesting that self-interested individuals are guided by unseen forces to promote
prosperity in an economy where private property and economic freedom coexist. It is
not difficult to realize that profit-seeking innovators are self-interested creatures, and,
consequently, they foster economic prosperity.

Appendices to Chapter 2

Appendix C: Ideas and Human Capital as Economic Products


Ideas and human capital possess different attributes. To see this, we review the
standard classification of products learned in introductory economic courses. In the
economic jargon, ideas with economic value are nonrival and at least partially
excludable. Human capital is rival and excludable. In this appendix, we clarify and
exemplify these technicalities.
Appendix D: Creative Economy and Endogenous Growth Theory
In this appendix, we point out that the idealized economy formalized in endog-
enous growth theory fits nicely with the notion of a creative economy.
Introduction xiii

Appendices to Chapter 3

Appendix E: Further Aspects on Creative Thinking


This appendix has two parts. In the first part, we list, in a more or less self-
contained way, various aspects revolving around different types of creative thinking.
The second part mentions that the new ideas emerging from creative thinking require
long periods of gestation.
Appendix F: Further Aspects on Intellectual Property
In this appendix, you will find the answer to the following questions. Why are
patented ideas only partially excludable? How this relates with the broader notion of
knowledge spillovers? Why these spillovers are a particular case of externalities?
What short of legal protection is available for software? And how do magicians
protect their magic tricks?

Appendix to Chapter 4

Appendix G: Miscellaneous Points on the Innovation Environment


This brief appendix consists of two parts. Part a succinctly summarizes the
National Innovation and Science Agenda to illustrate the notion of innovation
policy. Part b condenses the sometimes awkward venture-capitalist-innovator
relationship.

Appendix to Chapter 5

Appendix H: Business Innovation and Social Innovation


The purpose of this appendix is to show that business innovation and social
innovation can be defined independently of each other in such a way that allows us to
see the relationship between concepts. In the real world, one can exist without the
other, but the majority of social innovations are also business innovations.

Appendix to Chapter 6

Appendix I: Expert Opinions in Australia and the USA on the Impact of Automation
Many economists reject the notion that the current wave of automation will have
undesirable effects on employment. This point emerges from surveys carried out in
Australia and the USA.
xiv Introduction

Appendices to Chapter 7

Appendix J: Technological Progress in the Twenty-First Century


A working knowledge of the triad of terms “digital, exponential and combinato-
rial” is necessary to understand the dizzying speed of current technological progress.
Appendix J demarcates the components of the triad.
Appendix K: Robots, Artificial Intelligence and “the Singularity”
This highly speculative appendix is a drastic departure from the practical argu-
ments developed in our book. Ever-accelerating technological progress in robots and
artificial intelligence suggests the possibility of building a true thinking machine.
“The singularity” refers to the creation of superhuman intelligence that will end the
human era. How plausible is the singularity? It is anyone’s guess whether the ultra-
intelligent machine can be created. However, it is wise to never say never.

Afterthought

The book ends with a striking point: even though the invisible hand always holds
sway in a creative economy, we cannot rule out the possibility of convergence to a
dystopian economy.
Contents

1 A Bird’s-eye View of the Economy and Economics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1


1.1 What Is an Economy? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2
1.1.1 Economic Agents, Prices and Profits . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
1.1.2 Performance, Strong Economy, Weak Economy . . . . . . . 3
1.1.3 Scarcity and Choice . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
1.1.4 The Economy as a Complex Variable System . . . . . . . . 4
1.1.5 Time Travelling . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
1.1.6 Technological Progress and the Profit Motive . . . . . . . . . 6
1.2 What Is Economics? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
1.2.1 Macroeconomics and Microeconomics . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
1.2.2 Thinking in General . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
1.2.3 Thinking Like an Economist . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
1.2.4 Economic Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8
1.2.5 Selecting Tools . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
1.2.6 Two Different Kinds of Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
1.2.7 Progress in Economics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
1.3 Guiding Insights . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
1.3.1 Insight ①: Economies Are Complex and Evolving
Systems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
1.3.2 Insight ②: Models Are Necessary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
1.3.3 Insight ③: Material Incentives Matter . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
1.3.4 Insight ④: Prices and Profits Decide the Allocation
of Resources . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
1.3.5 Insight ⑤: Innovation Is a Prime Mover
of the Modern Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
1.4 Economic Predictions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
1.5 Chapter Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17

xv
xvi Contents

Appendices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
Appendix A: Innovation as a Problem Area of Economics . . . . . . 18
Appendix B: The Invisible Hand and Innovation . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
Selected References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25
2 What a Creative Economy Is and How It Works . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
2.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
2.2 Defining Characteristics of a Creative Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
2.2.1 Creative Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29
2.2.2 Creative Society . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29
2.3 A Narrative Model of Economic Evolution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30
2.3.1 Stylized Economies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30
2.3.2 Porter Development Path . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31
2.4 Innovation as an Economic Activity: Background Model . . . . . . . 32
2.4.1 Dimension 1: Creativity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
2.4.2 Dimension 2: Intellectual Property . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
2.4.3 Dimension 3: Innovation Environment . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
2.5 The Essentials of a Creative Economy: Ideas and Human
Capital . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
2.5.1 Ideas and Human Capital . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34
2.5.2 Ideas with Economic Value . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36
2.5.3 Profitable New Ideas . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36
2.6 The Mechanics of a Creative Economy: Basic Model . . . . . . . . . 36
2.6.1 Perpetual Innovation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37
2.6.2 Basic Model of a Creative Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37
2.6.3 Concluding Comment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39
2.7 Chapter Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39
Appendices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40
Appendix C: Ideas and Human Capital as Economic
Products . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40
Appendix D: The Creative Economy and Endogenous
Growth Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45
2.8 Concluding Remark . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48
Selected References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48
3 Creativity and Intellectual Propery . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49
3.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50
3.2 Creative Thinking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51
3.2.1 Logical Thinking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51
3.2.2 Lateral Thinking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53
3.2.3 Imaginary Thinking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54
3.2.4 Critical Thinking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54
3.2.5 Concluding Remarks on Creative Thinking . . . . . . . . . . 55
Contents xvii

3.3 Intellectual Property . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56


3.3.1 Patents . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56
3.3.2 Copyrights . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61
3.3.3 Trade Secrets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62
3.3.4 Trade Secrets Thefts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63
3.3.5 Trademarks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63
3.4 Chapter Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64
Appendices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66
Appendix E: Further Aspects on Creative Thinking . . . . . . . . . . . 66
Appendix F: Further Aspects on Intellectual Property . . . . . . . . . 70
Selected References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73
4 Innovation Environment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75
4.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76
4.2 Innovation Infrastructure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77
4.3 Clusters . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77
4.3.1 Anatomy of a Cluster . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78
4.3.2 Linkages Between Integral Parts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 80
4.4 Competitive Advantage: Domestic and International . . . . . . . . . . 81
4.4.1 T-entrepreneurs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81
4.5 Venture Capital . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81
4.5.1 Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82
4.5.2 Innovation Life Cycle . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82
4.5.3 Filing the Financial Void . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83
4.5.4 Pattern of Behaviour of Venture Capitalists . . . . . . . . . . 84
4.5.5 Profile of the Ideal Innovator . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84
4.5.6 Venture Capital Market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 85
4.5.7 Angel Investors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 85
4.6 Chapter Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86
Appendix G: Miscellaneous Points on the Innovation
Environment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89
Incentives Regime . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89
Venture Capitalist-Innovator Relationship . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 91
Selected References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92
5 Microeconomic Aspects of Innovation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 93
5.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 94
5.2 Innovation Process and Related Terminology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95
5.2.1 Inputs and Outputs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95
5.2.2 Research and Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96
5.2.3 Profit-Seeking R&D . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96
5.2.4 Factors Influencing R&D Undertakings . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97
xviii Contents

5.2.5 Classifying Innovation Outputs: Technological


and Organizational Innovations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97
5.2.6 First Risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98
5.2.7 Second Risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 99
5.2.8 Third Risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 99
5.2.9 Innovation Costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100
5.2.10 Successful Innovation and Commoditization . . . . . . . . . 100
5.3 The Innovator’s Dilemma . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100
5.3.1 Sustaining and Disruptive Innovations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 101
5.3.2 Examples of Disruptive Innovations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 101
5.3.3 Innovation and Market Power . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 103
5.3.4 Statement and Solution of the Innovator’s Dilemma . . . . 103
5.3.5 Incumbents Disrupting Themselves . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 104
5.4 Fast Innovation Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 105
5.4.1 Fast Innovation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 105
5.4.2 Creative Economy: Boon or Bone? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 106
5.5 Chapter Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 106
Appendix H: Business Innovation and Social Innovation . . . . . . . . . . . . 108
Bifocal Innovations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109
Pure Social Innovations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109
Putting Them Altogether . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111
Concluding Comment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111
Selected References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 112
6 Looking to the Near Future . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113
6.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114
6.2 Historical Perspective . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 116
6.2.1 Luddites . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 116
6.2.2 The Machinery Question: Ricardo . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 116
6.2.3 Marx: Wrong Prediction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117
6.2.4 Marshall: Two Penetrating Insights . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117
6.2.5 Marshall Decomposition Formula . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118
6.2.6 Keynes-Schumpeter . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118
6.2.7 The Return of the Machinery Question . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119
6.3 Key Terminology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119
6.3.1 Human Replacement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119
6.3.2 Enabling Products . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 120
6.3.3 Enabling Firms- Recipient Firms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 120
6.3.4 Robots, a Terminological Decision . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121
6.3.5 Robots and Task Content of Production . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121
6.3.6 Robot-Based Enabling Products . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 122
6.3.7 Examples . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 122
Contents xix

6.3.8 Section Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 125


6.3.9 Marshall Decomposition Formula, Revisited . . . . . . . . . 126
6.4 Robots: Friends or Foes? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 126
6.4.1 Technology Enthusiasts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 127
6.4.2 Technology Sceptics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 128
6.4.3 Resolving the Controversy: Preliminary Remarks . . . . . . 129
6.4.4 Resolving the Controversy: Not Possible,
Time Will Tell . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131
6.4.5 Two Predictions About the Next Economy . . . . . . . . . . 131
6.4.6 Robotize or Perish . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131
6.5 The Future of Employment: Anticipation Exercises . . . . . . . . . . . 132
6.5.1 Occupation-Based Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 133
6.5.2 Task-Based Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 134
6.5.3 Predicting New Occupations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 134
6.6 Rational Response to the March of the Robots . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 135
6.6.1 T-shaped Knowledge Workers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 135
6.6.2 Classifying Tasks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 136
6.6.3 Mapping Skills to Tasks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 137
6.6.4 Skill-biased Technological Progress . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 137
6.6.5 Two Types of Automation Technologies . . . . . . . . . . . . 138
6.6.6 Investment in Human Capital . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 138
6.6.7 Components of the Protective Belt . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 139
6.6.8 Australia’s Chief Scientist . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 139
6.7 Chapter Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 139
6.8 Concluding Comment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 140
Appendix I: Expert Opinions on the Impact of Automation . . . . . . . . . . 140
Australian Poll . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141
Comparison of Responses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141
Overview of the Australian Poll by Borland and Potts . . . . . . . . . 142
Delloite Report: The Panglossian Economy is Attainable . . . . . . . 142
Selected References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 144
7 Looking to the Distant Future . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 145
7.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 146
7.2 Technological Unemployment Revisited . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 147
7.2.1 Hypothetical Example . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 148
7.3 Demarcating the Notion of a Robot Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 153
7.3.1 No Generally Agreed Definition . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154
7.3.2 Whatls.com Definition . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154
7.3.3 Proffered Definition of Robot Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154
7.3.4 Hypothetical Example (Cont.) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 155
7.4 Is the Robot Economy Near? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 156
7.5 The Robot Economy Paradox . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 158
7.5.1 Increasing Returns . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 158
xx Contents

7.5.2 The Paradox, Stated . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 158


7.5.3 Norbert Wiener: A Forerunner of the Paradox . . . . . . . . 159
7.5.4 Resolving the Paradox . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 159
7.6 Schumpeter’s Famous Prophecy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 162
7.7 Arthur’s Prophecy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 164
7.8 Chapter Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 165
Appendices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 166
Appendix J: Technological Progress in
the Twenty-First Century . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 166
Appendix K: Robots, Artificial Intelligence, and Technological
Singularity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 173
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 176

Afterthoughts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 179

Index of Names . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 181

Subject Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 185


About the Authors

Eduardo Pol (Jorge Eduardo Fernandez-Pol) is a Doc-


tor in Economic Sciences (PhD equivalent) from the
University of Buenos Aires, Argentina, and has past
publication success. He is Senior Lecturer in Economics
in the School of Accounting, Economics and Finance at
the University of Wollongong (UOW) and Member of
the National Academy of Economic Sciences (Argen-
tina). His current research interests are innovation as an
economic activity, technological unemployment and
automation, economic development issues and human
development and social innovation. He is the Creator of
the subject ECON 231: The Creative Economy (intro-
duced in 2008) – which is open to all the UOW
students – and the Designer of ECON 802: The Eco-
nomics of Global Business Challenges, a subject offered
by the UOW Sydney Business School.

Charles Harvie is an Associate Professor in the School


of Accounting, Economics and Finance in the Faculty of
Business, University of Wollongong, Australia. He
holds a PhD in Economics from the University of War-
wick, UK. He is currently the Co-director of his
Faculty’s Centre for Contemporary Australasian Busi-
ness and Economics Studies and the forthcoming Head
of the School of Accounting, Economics and Finance
for the period 2020–2022. His research interests relate to
the economies of East and Southeast Asia, SMEs and
economic development and the macromodelling of
resource production. He has published his research

xxi
xxii About the Authors

outcomes widely in the form of books, book chapters


and scholarly academic journals such as Energy Eco-
nomics (UK), Regional Studies (UK), Journal of Asian
Economics (USA), Economic Modelling (UK), Applied
Economics (UK) and The Manchester School (UK). He
has also been involved in providing reports on factors
impacting the efficiency performance of regional SMEs,
including the role of innovation, for organizations such
as the Asian Productivity Organization (Japan), Asian
Development Bank (Philippines), Asian Development
Bank Institute (Japan), Economic Research Institute for
ASEAN and East Asia (ERIA) (Indonesia), Interna-
tional Trade Centre (Geneva, Switzerland) and the
OECD (Paris).
Chapter 1
A Bird’s-eye View of the Economy
and Economics

Contents
1.1 What Is an Economy? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2
1.1.1 Economic Agents, Prices and Profits . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
1.1.2 Performance, Strong Economy, Weak Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
1.1.3 Scarcity and Choice . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
1.1.4 The Economy as a Complex Variable System . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
1.1.5 Time Travelling . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
1.1.5.1 First Industrial Revolution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
1.1.5.2 Second Industrial Revolution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
1.1.5.3 Third Industrial Revolution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
1.1.5.4 Fourth Industrial Revolution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
1.1.6 Technological Progress and the Profit Motive . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
1.2 What Is Economics? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
1.2.1 Macroeconomics and Microeconomics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
1.2.2 Thinking in General . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
1.2.3 Thinking Like an Economist . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
1.2.4 Economic Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8
1.2.5 Selecting Tools . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
1.2.6 Two Different Kinds of Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
1.2.6.1 Two Types of Imaginary Humans . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
1.2.7 Progress in Economics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
1.3 Guiding Insights . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
1.3.1 Insight ①: Economies Are Complex and Evolving Systems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
1.3.2 Insight ②: Models Are Necessary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
1.3.3 Insight ③: Material Incentives Matter . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
1.3.4 Insight ④: Prices and Profits Decide the Allocation of Resources . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
1.3.5 Insight ⑤: Innovation Is a Prime Mover of the Modern Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
1.4 Economic Predictions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
1.5 Chapter Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17
Appendices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
Appendix A: Innovation as a Problem Area of Economics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
Pitfalls with the Standard Definition of Economics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
A Working Definition of Economics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
Innovation as a Problem Area: Logical Justification . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
Innovation and Mainstream Economics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19
List of Problem Areas: Incomplete and Open . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20

© Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. 2020 1


J. E. Fernandez-Pol, C. Harvie, Understanding the Creative Economy and the Future
of Employment, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-1652-8_1
2 1 A Bird’s-eye View of the Economy and Economics

Appendix B: The Invisible Hand and Innovation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21


Physiocrats . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
Adam Smith . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
Wealth of Nations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22
Invisible Hand Passage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22
Invisible Hand: Context and Individuals Alluded . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22
Reasonable Income Distribution: Not Guaranteed . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
Darwinism and the Invisible Hand . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23
Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
Curious Interpretation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
Selected References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25

Concise Preview
• The words ‘economy’ and ‘economics’ tend to be used interchangeably but they
do not mean the same thing. This chapter draws the line of separation between the
economy and economics
• The way of thinking employed by economists – known as “thinking like an
economist” – involves models in a fundamental way.
• Two kinds of economic models – mathematical models and narrative models –
are succinctly described.
• Progress in economics is cumulative in the sense that previous economic knowl-
edge accumulates and feeds into the development of new economic models.
• This chapter contains an overview of the insights that economists use to under-
stand the behaviour of the economy.
• Chapter 1 concludes with a few comments about the limitations of economic
predictions.
• Appendix A proffers a working definition of the economics discipline that
focuses on problem areas. We show that innovation as an economic activity
should be one of the problem areas.
• Appendix B shows that the Invisible Hand of Adam Smith also reaches innova-
tion as an economic activity.

1.1 What Is an Economy?

We start by defining an economy in the loosest possible way. Naturally, this implies
that there will be many details hidden in the definition. In general, the term economy
refers to a collection of interrelated economic activities within a geographic area.
Sometimes the term economy has sharp focus on a nation state and we talk about a
national economy (for example, the Australian economy) and at other times we are
interested in regional economies (for example, the economy of South East Asia). In
this book, when we use the word economy we are talking about a national economy
that lies within the borders of a nation state.
1.1 What Is an Economy? 3

1.1.1 Economic Agents, Prices and Profits

An economy includes economic agents such as, for example, consumers, managers,
innovators, venture capitalists and the government as well as laws, regulations,
taxes, subsidies, and many factors that affect the allocation of resources. Prices
and profits are the signals that determine where the resources will flow. Earnings
(positive profits) emerging from a particular activity attract resources into that
activity, and losses (negative profits) induce resources to move elsewhere.

1.1.2 Performance, Strong Economy, Weak Economy

The main goal of nation states in regard to the economies for which their govern-
ment’s claim responsibility is to provide a high and rising standard of living for its
residents. The ability to do so hinges on the performance of the economy. Aggregate
economic performance depends on the degree of national competitiveness. Indica-
tors of economic performance include, but are not limited to, the level and growth of
Gross Domestic Product (GDP), foreign debt, household debt, inflation, and
unemployment.
Speaking loosely, good economic performance involves an appropriate combi-
nation of several factors, including: keeping costs to a minimum; low prices;
increasing real wages; high innovation rates; and fairness in the distribution of
income, wealth, and opportunities. Poor economic performance occurs when one
or more of these factors are not present.
Good economic performance implies a strong economy. There are many draw-
backs associated with a weak economy. If the economy is performing poorly, the
country cannot provide high employment levels; cannot sustain a growing invest-
ment in health, education, and roads; cannot afford to defend the nation; and cannot
deliver security to the residents so that they can live their lives in peace.

1.1.3 Scarcity and Choice

It should be clear that resources (e.g. arable land, fish in the ocean, human capital,
and entrepreneurial talent) are scarce in the sense that they are not available in
unlimited quantities for free. Economies exist because scarcity is a pervasive and
important phenomenon.
Given that resources are scarce and wants of people and institutions are virtually
insatiable, an economy has less to offer than people wish to have. Hence choices
have to be made as to how to use those resources and how they might be distributed.
It goes without saying that these choices are often difficult to make when faced with
competing uses.
4 1 A Bird’s-eye View of the Economy and Economics

1.1.4 The Economy as a Complex Variable System

One of the fundamental ideas to keep in mind is that the economy is a system with
interconnected parts: a disturbance or change to one part may cause reverberations in
in many others. For example, the banking crisis of 2007–2008 caused a recession in
the USA. Thus, a shiver in one part of the economy brought about a chill in many
others.
Economists agreed that the distinguishing features of any economy are complex-
ity and variability. Complexity is due to the fact that an economy typically involves
millions of interconnections between economic agents operating in a variety of
economic sectors. Variability arises, in a substantial part, because of human creativ-
ity. Incessant innovation changes the economic landscape.
The economy, like a large airplane carrier, does not change direction quickly. For
example, at the beginning of the twentieth century the Australian economy was
based on bulk-processing of resources such as coal and grain. In the twenty-first
century, the Australian economy revolves around both bulk-processing of resources
and deliberate creation of profitable new ideas.

1.1.5 Time Travelling

To visualize the attribute of variability, we can consider a science-fiction exercise.

1.1.5.1 First Industrial Revolution

Imagine that you are a time-traveller and you decide to visit England and the United
States during the First Industrial Revolution which occurred in the period 1760 –
1830. You will see the transformation of economic activity due to three innovations:
the steam engine, cotton gin and the power loom.1

1.1.5.2 Second Industrial Revolution

Then you jump into the Second Industrial Revolution that took place in Europe and
the United States roughly between 1860 and 1911 to see the introduction of

1
As a reminder, James Watt invented the steam engine in 1765 but it was not until Matthew Boulton
contributed some ‘missing elements’ that a commercially viable steam engine was installed in 1776
(11 years of research and development). Eli Whitney invented the cotton gin in 1793. The cotton gin
was a device that increased the processing of raw cotton by over 50 times. The power loom was
invented in the United States in 1814 by Francis Cabot Lowell. The power loom allowed large
amounts of cloth to be made in a shorter time than a human could do it. For the first time mass
production of finished textile products became possible.
1.1 What Is an Economy? 5

important innovations such as, for example, electricity (in particular, electric light
and electric motors), internal combustion engine (e.g. automobile and air transport),
telegraph, telephone, phonograph, motion pictures, radio, and television. These
mega-innovations implied a dramatic change in the economy. Furthermore, you
would see that everyday standard of living improved dramatically due to the
introduction of running water, indoor plumbing, and urban sanitation infrastructure.
Note 1 General Purpose technologies
Economists call innovations that have important impacts on many sectors of the
economy General-Purpose Technologies (GPTs). Steam power, electricity, and the
internal combustion engine are typical examples of GPTs. The cotton gin was
important within the textile sector at the start of the nineteenth century, but insig-
nificant outside this sector. Consequently, the cotton gin cannot be considered as
a GPT.

1.1.5.3 Third Industrial Revolution

Then, you will see the Third Industrial Revolution associated with the Information
Technology Revolution. The introduction of mega-innovations such as, for example,
the PC by IBM in 1981, Windows by Microsoft in 1985, the Internet in 1995,2 the
iPhone by Apple in 2007, and the iPad by Apple in 2010, giving rise to the
‘digitized’ economy characterized by the existence of computer networks which
leads to network economies which in turn lead to temporary monopolies.

1.1.5.4 Fourth Industrial Revolution

We are living through the early period of a Fourth Industrial Revolution (4IR).3
Computer technology combines with Artificial Intelligence and robotics to create a
general-purpose technology capable of delivering productivity-enhancing innova-
tions across many economic sectors. The resulting products, processes, and new
forms of organization are substituting for and augmenting human brainpower in
much the same way that the steam engine and associated developments in mechan-
ical engineering, chemistry and metallurgy substituted for and augmented human
muscle power.

2
The computer scientist Sir Tim Berners-Lee submitted his proposal for the web in 1989. He is
considered as the inventor of the Internet.
3
The person who coined the term ‘Fourth Industrial Revolution’ was Professor Klaus Schwab, the
founder and executive chairman of the World Economic Forum, using it as the title of a 2016 book.
6 1 A Bird’s-eye View of the Economy and Economics

1.1.6 Technological Progress and the Profit Motive

The foregoing suggests – correctly – that the complex entity we call “economy” is an
evolving object propelled by technological progress (or technological change).
Technological progress is the result of innovations and imitations.
But technological progress does not happen without a reason. The profit motive
has strong influence on technological progress. This point was forcibly made by
Nobel Prize winner Paul M. Romer (1990) in his model of endogenous technological
progress. Somewhat roughly, the argument presented by Romer revolves around
three premises: first, technological progress lies at the heart of economic evolution;
second, market incentives (profit motive) play an essential role in the production of
new ideas (innovations); and third, ideas can be used over and over again by many
people simultaneously. As to the second premise, Romer observes:
The second premise is that technological change [technological progress] arises in large part
because of intentional actions taken by people who respond to market incentives. Thus the
model is one of endogenous rather than exogenous technological change. This does not
mean that everyone who contributes to technological change is motivated by market
incentives. An academic scientist who is supported by government grants may be totally
insulated from them. The premise is that market incentives nonetheless play an essential role
in the process whereby new knowledge is translated into goods with practical value. Our
initial understanding of electromagnetism arose from research conducted in academic
institutions, but magnetic tape and home videocassette recorders resulted from attempts by
private firms to earn a profit. (Romer 1990a, b, p. S72)

1.2 What Is Economics?

An economy is an enormously complex and variable system, ripe with a myriad of


interdependencies and feedback loops. Change one parameter (say the tax rate on
profits) and a variety of effects are likely to cascade through the system, some of
which may counteract the expected effects of the initial change. The economy is the
reality that we want to understand. It should be clear that understanding this complex
and variable system is not an easy task.
Economies are created by human beings, but we find it difficult to understand our
own creation due to their complexity and variability. In part this is due because
economies are rarely, if ever, designed on a systematic basis as some sort of original,
grand plan for human societies. They grow on a relatively unplanned basis for long
periods of time.
Economics is not a clearly defined discipline. Its frontiers are constantly chang-
ing, and their definition is constantly a subject of controversy. It is not necessary to
get bogged down in definitional issues as far as this book is concerned. The loosest
1.2 What Is Economics? 7

possible characterization of economics, namely: economics is the scientific disci-


pline that imparts an understanding of the economy, is good enough.4

1.2.1 Macroeconomics and Microeconomics

Macroeconomics is the study of the behaviour of the economy as a whole by


focusing on broad aggregates such as national income and total employment.
Underlying the behaviour of the economic aggregates are the decisions of individ-
uals. Microeconomics is the study of the actions of individual economic agents
(e.g. consumers, firms, innovators, and venture capitalists) and the way that those
actions interact with each other.
This well-established dichotomy “macro-micro” is useful for pedagogical pur-
poses but the line of separation between macro and micro tends to be fuzzy because
fluctuations in the broad aggregates are influenced by the actions that
individuals take.

1.2.2 Thinking in General

Economics helps develop our ability to think ‘in general’ rather in terms of ‘partic-
ular cases.’ For example, the study of innovation allows us to understand the
economic implications of this activity in general rather than only to understand
specific historical cases such as, for example, the impacts of the introduction of
Gillette’s sensor razor in the razor industry in 1990. This is not to indicate that
empirical cases are unimportant. Historical examples enable economists to develop
general models about innovation as an economic activity.
Economics is regarded as a set of tools useful for understanding the world we live
in and for analysing real economic problems. It is also regarded as a way of thinking
known as “thinking like an economist.”

1.2.3 Thinking Like an Economist

Every discipline has its own language and its way of thinking. How do economists
go about analysing economic issues? Economists use a particular way of thinking
which is reflected in the expression “thinking like an economist.” Thinking like an

4
This broad description is the starting point of a working definition of economics that we succinctly
discuss in Appendix A.
8 1 A Bird’s-eye View of the Economy and Economics

economist means to use the economic language with precision and follow the model
building approach.
The vocabulary of economics is vast. Economic profit, demand, supply, market
equilibrium, marginal analysis, externalities, and money multiplier are terms that
constitute an integral part of the economics terminology. The economics vocabulary
is difficult to follow because economists use familiar words in highly specialized
ways. Examples abound: opportunity cost, sunk cost, accounting profit, economic
profit are a few. Furthermore, economists use, for entirely different things, the same
word. For example, the term ‘institutions’ may refer to a central bank, other banks,
and hedge funds, or laws and regulations that affect the material incentives to invest
in physical capital, human capital, and innovation.

1.2.4 Economic Models

But a working knowledge of the language of economics is not enough. "Thinking


like an economist" requires the use of economic models. Economic models are
mental constructs designed to capture the essence of specific economic issues by
concentrating on what seems to be the core features of an economy and the
relationship between economic phenomena.
More precisely, an economic model is a simplified conceptual framework in
which economists isolate some relevant variables and consider the remaining vari-
ables unchanged to answer one or more economic questions without cluttering the
issue with unnecessary detail. Models contain imaginary humans or economic agents
(consumers, producers, innovators and so on) that make decisions to influence the
selected variables.
Economic models involve assumptions in a fundamental way. Assumptions are
formulated to make the world easier to understand. For example, a first simplification
commonly used is to assume an economy populated by profit-seeking imaginary
people. In doing so, we leave out of the model many other elements,
e.g. benevolence, or the fact that people are most definitively not single-minded
profit-seeking machines. It is not that the ignored elements are totally meaningless;
rather, the omitted elements are seen to be less important for gaining an understand-
ing of what an economy is and how it works.
Keep in mind once and for all: it is impossible to have a model without
assumptions. An assumption shared by all economic models is the ceteris paribus
assumption which means that "all other things remain unaltered“. This is under-
standable. To analyse a complex economic reality, economists confine attention to
the relationship between a few variables and assume that all other variables do not
change.
1.2 What Is Economics? 9

1.2.5 Selecting Tools

Joan Robinson (1903–1983) was a British economist well known for her contribu-
tions to the economics discipline. She suggested that economics should be viewed as
a “box of tools.” This metaphor is useful still today. Economics helps us to
understand the economy (real world) using economic models. These models are
the tools of analysis, and, thus, you can view economics as a toolbox useful for
organizing thinking about the economy.
The toolbox offers a large collection of models and the task of analysts consists of
recognizing this multitude and to select models that are fit for a context of applica-
tion. John Maynard Keynes (1883–1946) put it best in a letter to Roy Harrod on
4 July 1938: “Economics is a science of thinking in terms of models joined to the art
of choosing models that are relevant for the contemporary world.” As Keynes
explained, “unlike the typical natural science, the material to which [economics] is
applied is, in too many respects, not homogenous through time.” The expression ‘not
homogenous through time’ alludes to the fact that the economy is variable
through time.

1.2.6 Two Different Kinds of Models

An economic model is merely a conceptual framework, and there is no inherent


reason why it must be mathematical. If the model is mathematical, it will usually
contain equations formalizing the assumptions. Through the application of the
relevant mathematical operations to these equations, the economist derives conclu-
sions which logically follow from the assumptions.
Purely descriptive models were the first stage in the historical development of
economics. However, as quantitative relationships were formulated in increasing
numbers, purely verbal analysis became more difficult to formulate consistently.
Mathematical relationships underlay most of these early models, though they were
seldom made explicit. Nowadays, economic models tend to be cast in mathematical
terms.
Without striving for rigor, we can say that there are two kinds of economic
models useful to gain an understanding of the economy: Mathematical models,
which facilitate the deduction of testable conclusions from initial assumptions
based on deductive logic. Narrative models derive conclusions from initial assump-
tions but the conclusions do not necessarily display logical compulsion.
In this book we prefer narrative models and verbal analysis. You will find some
simple diagrams useful to organize the discussion, but they are not indispensable to
follow the argument. Anyhow, we do not assume any previous knowledge of
mathematics or plane geometry. When a diagram is presented, its interpretation
will be explained.
10 1 A Bird’s-eye View of the Economy and Economics

Note 2 Narrative models and narrative economics


The use of the term ‘narrative’ requires clarification. When we talk about ‘narra-
tive’ economic models we refer to a line of reasoning that (a) starts with initial
assumptions; and (b) allows us to arrive at certain conclusions, but the line of
reasoning is not subject to a mathematical straightjacket. For example, a narrative
model of economic development may describe the phases navigated by a hypothet-
ical country over time under the assumption that there are gradual improvements in
competitiveness and arrive at the conclusion: the country will converge to an
innovation-driven economy. But this conclusion is not obtained according to math-
ematical derivation.
However, the word ‘narrative’ is also frequently used with a different meaning.
Mass psychology tends to be tuned to simple stories that many people want to bring
up in conversation or on social media or on news and these stories may influence
economic decisions. Narratives maintain a core contagious element in the form of
successful spreading. In brief, ‘narrative’ may refer to a telling story that attaches
meaning and significance to the story in question.
Professor Robert J. Shiller delivered an American Economic Association presi-
dential address – entitled “Narrative Economics” and published in 2017 – where he
argued that the methods of economics should be expanded to include economic
narratives, predicting that “As research methods advance, and as more social media
data accumulate, textual analysis will be a stronger field in economics in coming
years.” Shiller (2017a, b) also argued that it is important for economists to appreciate
the popular economic narratives that go ‘viral’ (narratives that come and go
according to epidemiological patterns). More recently, Shiller (2019) explores
narratives about technology-induced job degradations.
In Chap. 7 of the present book we will describe the “Robot Economy narrative”
(somewhat roughly, fears about the effects of Artificial Intelligence and robotics on
our jobs) and point out that this narrative emerged in 2011 with the paper by Arthur
“The Second Economy” and went ‘viral’ in 2013 with the publication of the report
by Frey and Osborne “The Future of Employment: How Susceptible Are Jobs to
Computerization?”.

1.2.6.1 Two Types of Imaginary Humans

There is a long tradition in economics viewing the imaginary human as an optimiz-


ing creature seeking satisfaction (e.g. a profit-maximizing agent), sometimes known
as homo economicus or economic human.5 This fictitious human – who deals with
existing products, processes and organizational schemes – is an optimizing machine
that has no creative demands on his consciousness. He does not undertake wasteful
experimentation to introduce new products or processes. In brief, the creature in

5
The use of the words ‘homo’ and ‘human’ are intended to mean ‘gender-neutral person.’ More-
over, in this book the pronoun ‘he’ is tacitly used interchangeable with ‘she’ and vice versa.
1.2 What Is Economics? 11

question is a stylized ideal useful in the study of an imaginary economy without


innovation.
However, there is nothing to prevent us from introducing another type of imag-
inary human, resembling a real profit-seeking innovator. Homo creativus or creative
human is both a profit-oriented creature (like her cousin homo economicus) but she is
also a novelty-seeking person. She is a decision maker unable to optimize because
uncertainty pervades the innovation process. However, she is able to create in a
proactive sense. Her job is to create new ideas with economic value and put them
into effect. For her today’s practice is never good enough for tomorrow.
We can think of the empirical counterparts of homo economicus and homo
creativus as being the manager and the entrepreneur, respectively. This distinction
is not intended to denigrate the importance of managerial activity, merely to stress
that innovation springs primarily from the efforts of the entrepreneur.

1.2.7 Progress in Economics

Economics has progressed far enough to provide insights about the best way to
organize an economy or to answer other important questions such as, for example,
what kind of economy is able to overcome scarcity and diminishing returns and
deliver sustainable increases in the living standards of its residents?
Progress in economics is cumulative and based on the great economic thinkers of
past and present times, as well as the less dramatic findings of lesser scholars and
practitioners. Previous economic knowledge accumulates and feeds into the gener-
ation of modified and new models. Generally, knowledge is made obsolete by the
emergence of newer, superior models.
An economist today sees further than her predecessors because she stands on the
shoulders of earlier giants. Or, to put it differently, in the process of creating new
models theorists build on insights embodied in previous models. They achieve
success by standing upon the shoulders of giants (Newton aphorism).6 A very
small sample of intellectual giants of economics and some of their insights can be
seen in Table 1.1.
These great economic thinkers were fascinated by the economic world around
them. They are sometimes referred to as “worldly philosophers” because their
philosophical ideas revolve around the most earthly of human activities, namely

6
Sir Isaac Newton (1642–1727) was a scientific genius. It is well known that he was the formulator
of the law of gravity. It is less well known that he was an alchemist. Alchemy was an addiction in
which he dabbled to the end of his life, slowly poisoning himself by the repeated and unwise
handling of mercury. It is even less well known that Newton was an unsuccessful stock market
investor (gambler?). He lost a lot of money in the famous South Sea Bubble of 1720.
12 1 A Bird’s-eye View of the Economy and Economics

Table 1.1 A small sample of great economists


Great economic
thinker Life span Insight
Francois Quesnay 1694–1774 Economic sectors are interrelated
Adam Smith 1723–1790 Economic freedom enables the economy to get the best it can
from its scarce resources
Jeremy Bentham 1748–1832 Economic behaviour is governed by the desire to experience
pleasure and avoid pain
David Ricardo 1772–1823 The crucial element for gains from international trade is com-
parative advantage
Alfred Marshall 1842–1924 Prices are determined by a vast set of complex interacting
forces
John Maynard 1883–1946 Economic freedom does not guarantee full employment
Keynes
Joseph Alois 1883–1950 Innovation is the prime mover of economic dynamism
Schumpeter

the pursuit of wealth. It is no exaggeration to say that the extraordinary power of


their visions helped shape and sway mass psychology in many countries.7
It would be hardly necessary to mention that an economic issue such as, for
example, economic development, is never exclusively economic; other important
aspects (psychological, political, cultural, etc.) always exist. Economics helps in
answering many important questions in conjunction with other disciplines. For
instance, does economic growth cause happiness? To answer this question one
needs not only information about economic growth itself but also a variety of
subjective well-being indicators (e.g. family life satisfaction, work stress, and
tiredness after returning from work) that are outside the scope of economics.
To reiterate, economics has progressed far enough to be able to provide valuable
tools to shed light on the answer to important problems. However, it would be
unwise to form exaggerate expectations about the power of economics. One should
not believe that economics is the key that will unlock the answer to all of the great
social problems of the day. There are confronting questions that economics is unable
to answer. These include, but are not limited to, how much poverty is acceptable and
fair? And which economic goals and individual values make for a good quality of
life?
Note 3 Why are we in a sweet spot?
Scientists often face important questions which they are unable (but not unwill-
ing) to answer. The distance between the Earth and the sun is 93 million miles. This
distance is perfect for life. Why are we in a sweet spot? The German astronomer and
mathematician Johann Kepler (1571–1630) asked that very question and he spent

7
The term “worldly philosophers” was coined by Robert L. Heilbroner in his book The Worldly
Philosophers: The Great Economic Thinkers, first published in 1955 (Heilbroner 1969).
1.3 Guiding Insights 13

years trying to find a physical reason, some law of nature that requires the earth to be
93 million miles from the sun. But Kepler never found it because it does not exist.
There is not any physical law requiring the Earth to be 93 million miles from the sun.
It is simply one possibility of the many you would expect to find in a universe we
know is full of solar systems.
To sum up, the aim of economics is to understand how the economy works and
evolves. To this end, economists use precise language and models. Models are
conceptual frameworks for organizing thinking about a problem. They simplify
the economic reality by making assumptions and leaving out many details of the
real world in order to concentrate on the essentials. No model is perfectly correct.
Note 4 Models and theories
The reader may have noticed that we have tried to avoid use of the word ‘theory’.
But we need to say something about the difference (if any) between a theory and a
model. Sometimes economists use the words ‘model’ and ‘theory’ interchangeably.
At other times, a theory is understood as a collection of models about a specific
phenomenon. In Appendix C (Chap. 2) you will find the expressions ‘old growth
theory’ and ‘endogenous growth theory’ and each of these theories include a number
of models. Unfortunately, there is no unanimity among economists about the line of
separation between models and theories.

1.3 Guiding Insights

Before going into the main theme of this book – the Creative Economy – it is helpful
to have an overview of the insights that economists use to understand how an
economy works and evolves. Each insight captures fundamental truths that serve
as foundation stones of contemporary economic reasoning.

1.3.1 Insight ①: Economies Are Complex and Evolving


Systems

An economy is a complex system because it involves the decisions of millions of


people interacting through a variety of communication channels. An economy is an
evolving system chiefly because of the changes induced by human innovation.
14 1 A Bird’s-eye View of the Economy and Economics

1.3.2 Insight ②: Models Are Necessary

Models are mental constructs with two useful characteristics: they are representa-
tions of components of the ‘real thing’ being analysed that are simpler than the thing
itself and capture the most important characteristics of the problem under
investigation.

1.3.3 Insight ③: Material Incentives Matter

Human beings typically respond to material incentives (e.g. profits for firms and
income for households). These incentives are the signals that guide the allocation of
resources (such as financial capital and human capital) to produce already existing
products and to create new products and new and better ways to producing them.

1.3.4 Insight ④: Prices and Profits Decide the Allocation


of Resources

Market prices and profits are the key factors governing the allocation of resources.
Sometimes market prices do not exist because the product does not exist; in those
cases, potential profits associated with new products or new production techniques
govern the allocation of resources.

1.3.5 Insight ⑤: Innovation Is a Prime Mover of the Modern


Economy

Innovation as an economic activity is important in the modern economy. In partic-


ular, no complete understanding of the modern economy is possible unless compe-
tition through innovation is brought into the picture.
Note 5 Schumpeter
The Insight ⑤ is inextricably linked to the name of one of the most important
20th century economists. Joseph Alois Schumpeter (1883–1950) lived beyond his
time. Early in the past century, Schumpeter started the task of articulating a vision of
the economy which turns out to be remarkably important today. He was the first
economist to identify the importance of profit-seeking innovation (Schumpeter
1934, 2010).
1.3 Guiding Insights 15

The Theory of Economic Development was published in German in 1911 and


translated into English in 1934. In this book, Schumpeter developed a narrative
model of innovation as an economic activity. Furthermore, in 1942 he introduced a
crucial insight in Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, namely: the notion of
creative destruction, and also pointed out that in some markets competition through
innovation is more important than price competition.
Price competition is based on price management. Non-price competition is any
kind of competition that does not depend on price management. The most important
tools of non-price competition are business innovation, advertising, and brand
recognition. Economic competition revolving around the introduction of new prod-
ucts or new processes or new forms of business organization is called competition
through innovation.
In the contemporary economy economic competition is not just about maximiz-
ing profits based upon existing products (think of standard products already avail-
able in the market) but, instead, is a dynamic process that includes innovation in a
fundamental way. Any firm introducing a new (tangible or intangible) product in the
market will enjoy market power because it will be offering a differentiated product.
The market power will last until competitors supersede or imitate your innovation.
The preceding fundamental insights are at the heart of our book (see
Diagram 1.1).

Diagram 1.1 Guiding insights


16 1 A Bird’s-eye View of the Economy and Economics

1.4 Economic Predictions

Economists want not only understand the behaviour of the economy but also predict
the direction in which the economy as a whole (of part of it) is moving. In general,
economic predictions relate to the future and, consequently, economists face two
obstacles: first, nobody knows with certainty what the future holds; and second, there
is no data streaming in from the future. The evidence on which economists base their
predictions comes from the past. It may be the recent past, but it is the past
nonetheless.
It is important to realize that an economic prediction is a statement of the form:
This is what will happen if something does not come up to prevent it.

These statements are weak propositions because of two reasons: the ceteris
paribus clause and the impossibility of knowing all future outcomes. On the one
hand, underlying the statement is the ceteris paribus clause (“other things being
equal”). The problem here is that we can give examples of the elements assumed to
be constant, but we are usually unable to give a list of all the things those “other
things” may be.
On the other hand, there may be disturbances emerging from outcomes that do not
exist today. It is impossible to specify, or even imagine, all future outcomes that can
occur and nullify the prediction. A simple thought experiment can clarify this crucial
feature. Suppose time travelling to the past is possible; locate oneself at the begin-
ning of the twentieth century, and then try to imagine the launching of the Internet in
1995. The point is that, in the case of fundamental technological shifts, past
experiences and events are no guide to future developments and outcomes.
Where all this leave us? Economic predictions are always doubtful and in many
instances turn out to be wrong. The following quote – attributed to the Canadian-
born economist John Kenneth Galbraith (1908–2006) – illustrates the widespread
lack of credibility concerning economic predictions: “The only function of economic
forecasting is to make astrology look respectable.” One position adopted by defeat-
ists is that anything can happen and, therefore, we can never know what to expect.
We believe that this is the position of the obscurantist.
We suggest the truth lies in the following advice coming from the great English
economist Sir John Richard Hicks (1904–1989):
But even if our propositions are weak, it does not follow that they are useless. Far from it. It
is better to have some knowledge of what to expect than no knowledge at all. Prognostica-
tions of the future have to be made, as a basis for current action, and it is very desirable that
they should be as good as possible. But we should see them for what they are. It is not
desirable that more should be claimed for them than they deserve. (Hicks 1984, p. 217)

We mention, in passing, that the 1972 Nobel Prize in economics was awarded
jointly to John R. Hicks and Kenneth J. Arrow “for their pioneering contributions to
general economic equilibrium theory and welfare theory."
Our advice to the readers is as follows. When economists try to convince you
about the plausibility of their predictions by means of technicalities (such as, for
1.5 Chapter Summary 17

example, esoteric language and abstruse econometric models) ask them: “Would you
mind terribly if I asked you to state in plain English what are the basic assumptions
of your policy recommendations, including what factors are assumed to be constant
and what are the most important outcomes for the foreseeable future envisaged in
your model?”

1.5 Chapter Summary

• The term economy refers to the system of economic activities carried out in the
real world by real humans.
• The economy is a complex and variable system propelled by technological
progress and the profit motive.
• Economics is the discipline that explains the behaviour of the economic system as
well as the behaviour of its parts.
• Modern economists do not subscribe to a uniform definition of their subject but
there is universal agreement about the way of thinking in economics.
• Thinking like an economist means to use the economic language with precision
and follow the model building approach.
• Models are simplifications of the real world. These imaginary worlds postulate
the existence of imaginary humans (economic agents) and involve assumptions
formulated to make the economic reality easier to understand.
• The usefulness of a model depends on whether it succeeds in explaining the set of
phenomena that it is intended to explain.
• Mathematical models use equations to formalize the assumptions and derive
conclusions with logical rigor.
• Narrative models derive conclusions from the assumptions but the derivation
does not guarantee logical compulsion as in the case of mathematical models.
• Economic models deal with two types of imaginary humans: Economic man
(optimizing machine that does not innovate and never will) and creative man
(someone who introduces novelty to make money).
• Progress in economics is cumulative and based on the great economic thinkers of
the past and present.
• The insights economists use to understand the economic system and its parts are
the following five:
①: Economies are complex and evolving systems;
②: Models are necessary;
③: Material incentives matter;
④: Prices and profits decide the allocation of resources; and
⑤: Innovation is a prime mover of the modern economy
• Even though economic predictions are plagued with difficulties, it is better to
have some knowledge about what to expect than no knowledge at all.
18 1 A Bird’s-eye View of the Economy and Economics

Appendices

Appendix A: Innovation as a Problem Area of Economics

Jacob Viner (1892–1970) is reported to have said that “Economics is what econo-
mists do.” This is a slightly disturbing statement. However, the predominant inter-
pretation of Viner’s quip is that the subject of economics is too broad to be usefully
pinned down in a concise definition. In this appendix we proffer a definition of
economics based on an “incomplete and open” list of problem areas that includes
innovation as an economic activity and provide reasons for the inclusion.

Pitfalls with the Standard Definition of Economics

A commonly used definition characterizes economics as the study of how people


deal with scarcity. We believe that from a pedagogical viewpoint it is not entirely a
good idea to define economics in this Omni-comprehensive and abstract way.
There are four reasons for our claim. One, the definition is too brief to be of much
value, especially if it is not followed by a fuller discussion of what is implied by the
definition. At best, it has a ‘signpost’ value, indicating the direction in which a fuller
discussion and definition should proceed. Two, scarcity is not a problem confined to
economics. Humans have to deal with issues such as status, reputation, meaning of
life, and so on. The means to achieve any of these ends are notoriously scarce and do
not necessarily fall into the domain of economics. Three, it appears to cast a rather
negative light over economics, suggesting that it is all about problems associated
with poverty and lack of income whereas a great deal of economic thought is about
exciting, challenging topics characterized by hopefulness such as, for example,
achieving higher standards of living through business innovation. Finally, a sharp
focus on scarcity fails to indicate that economics deals with an evolving system.8

A Working Definition of Economics

One thing is clear. There is no perfect definition of economics. A working definition


of economics useful for the purposes of the present book has two parts. Economics is
the discipline that studies how the economy works and evolves (part 1) and involves
problem areas (part 2) such as, for example, resource allocation, income distribution,
economic growth, unemployment, inflation, economic institutions, human develop-
ment, and innovation as an economic activity (see Diagram 1.2).

8
For more definitional issues, see Backhouse et al. (2009).
Appendices 19

Diagram 1.2 Working definition of economics

Innovation as a Problem Area: Logical Justification

Nowadays, no one needs to be convinced that innovation plays a vital role as a


catalyst for economic progress. CEOs know that the most successful firms are those
that find new ways of doing things such as creating new products or developing new
markets. Economists and particularly policy makers are well aware that business
innovation is the prime mover of economic prosperity.
The incorporation of innovation as a distinct economic activity on the list of
problem areas of economics can be logically justified. Economics is the study of how
an economy works and evolves. Economic evolution is brought about by innovation
in a fundamental way. Consequently, nothing could be plainer that the proposition
that innovation is a problem area of economics.

Innovation and Mainstream Economics

The history of economic thought shows that not all problem areas are automatically
included in mainstream economics. A case in point is the last problem area on the list
in Diagram 1.2. Interest in innovation as an economic activity is stronger today than
it was when Joseph Alois Schumpeter wrote many years ago. There was little or
nothing in the writing of economists about the economics of innovation before
Schumpeter.
Until the appearance of his Theory of Economic Development in 1911, economics
was under the influence of what philosophers have called the “principle of pleni-
tude.” This bizarre principle postulates that every conceivable entity already exists,
and therefore, it follows at once that innovation is out of the question.9

9
A discussion of the principle of plenitude can be found in the book by David Warsh (1984).
20 1 A Bird’s-eye View of the Economy and Economics

Schumpeter was the twentieth century’s defining scholar of the economics of


innovation but he was underrated by most of the mainstream economists. Other
major pioneers of innovation were Allyn A. Young, Simon Kuznets, Nathan Rosen-
berg, Richard R. Nelson, and Sydney Winter, to name some of the most prominent
scholars in the economics of innovation. None of them were considered mainstream
economists.
In the 1950s, the work of Nobel laureate Robert Solow established that economic
growth is caused primarily by the contribution of technological progress
(or technological change). It became increasingly clear that the engine of techno-
logical progress is innovation and imitation. However, innovation as an economic
activity could hardly be considered as one of the problem areas for mainstream
economics during the forty-year period 1950–1990.
It was not until the early 1990s that innovation entered mainstream economics as
a tidal wave, largely due to the formal contributions of what is often called New
Growth Theory. This theoretical field includes the endogenous growth theory as
developed by 2018 Nobel Prize winner Paul M. Romer (1990a, b), and Aghion and
Howitt (1992). More on this in Chap. 2.

List of Problem Areas: Incomplete and Open

Quite obviously, the list of problem areas in Diagram 1.2 is incomplete. Environ-
mental protection, for example, should be included in the list of problem areas. The
environment has never been a bigger issue than it is today. We value clear air, clean
water, wildlife, and unspoiled natural scenery. Protecting the environment has a cost,
and therefore, we can use the tools of economics to understand what the associated
costs and benefits might be.
It should be emphasized that the list of problem areas facing economics is open in
the sense that the number of problem areas is not fixed. Two examples will help
clarify the openness of the problem areas. Space pollution may well be a new
problem area. To see this, remember that the outer space (located between 700km
and 1,000km up) was seen to be too vast to fill up. This intuition is being proved to
be wrong. Today thousands of satellites are orbiting the Earth. Unfortunately, there
are collisions between satellites creating dangerous junk that litters the outer space
(even a small fragment of such junk can destroy a satellite or a shuttle). This is
known as ‘space pollution’ and has an economic dimension.
Another illustration – particularly relevant for this book – is the economics of
robots. We are accustomed to the dizzying speed of innovation in Artificial Intelli-
gence (AI) and robotics. Nowhere in recorded history do we find such a rapid rate of
improvement. The economic possibilities and limitations of these devices have
become so fashionable that they are discussed in newspaper articles almost daily.
Moreover, we already have at our disposal ground breaking books such as
Brynjolfsson and McAfee (2014) The Second Machine Age and Ford (2015) The
Rise of the Robots, and a myriad of scientific papers on this emerging problem area.
Appendices 21

Assuming that there will be a relentless progression toward full automation, some
of the important questions that the economics of robots should answer are: Will
robots replace humans like the internal combustion engine replaced horses? What is
the future of employment? Will governments have to introduce a “universal basic
income” to assist technologically unemployed workers? Should robots pay tax? Can
capitalism survive? These questions will be addressed in Chaps. 6 and 7 of the
present book.

Appendix B: The Invisible Hand and Innovation

Physiocrats

The first systematic attempt to found an economic discipline was made in France
around the middle of the eighteenth century by the Physiocrats. The Physiocrats
consisted of a small group of French statesmen and philosophers under the leader-
ship of Francois Quesnay, the physician of Louis XV (King of France 1715–1774).
Agriculture occupied a central position in physiocracy. The favourite phrase of
physiocracy was “Laissez-faire, laissez-passer” which means “there should be
both free access to the market and free mobility of resources between countries,”
but this principle was only to be applied in regard to the agricultural sector.10

Adam Smith

Adam Smith (1723–1790) resided several years in France and interacted with the
Physiocrats. In that epoch, new technologies were being created and applied to the
manufacture of products such as cotton, wool, and iron, in what came to be called the
First Industrial Revolution. Adam Smith was keenly interested in technological
innovations because he wanted to understand the sources of the wealth of nations.
However, Smith undertook the task of founding the economic discipline focusing
on existing products, and, thereby, he left the issue of introducing new products into
the market untouched. Quite obviously, the fact that business innovation was left out
of the picture does not imply that technological innovation was irrelevant to him. It
was left to Schumpeter’s acute powers of observation and abstraction to go inside the
black box of technological progress and pull out business innovation as the most
important factor underlying economic change.

10
According to John Maynard Keynes, the first writer to use the maxim laissez-faire and emphasize
the undesirability of government intervention was the Marquis d’Argenson: “the Marquis was the
first man to wax passionate on the economic advantages of governments leaving trade alone. To
govern better, he said, one must govern less.” (Keynes 1928, p. 278).
22 1 A Bird’s-eye View of the Economy and Economics

Wealth of Nations

In 1776, at the age of 53, Adam Smith published An Inquiry into the Nature and
Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Due to this book (usually referred to as Wealth of
Nations) economists regard Adam Smith as the founder of modern economics. One
of Smith’s enduring contributions to the economic discipline was the insight of the
“invisible hand” of the market-guided economy. This immortal metaphor alludes to
the power of the market as a guiding Invisible Hand conducive to economic
prosperity and is mentioned in nearly all contemporary economics textbooks.

Invisible Hand Passage

It is generally agreed that Adam Smith invoked the Invisible Hand – an expression
that occurs only once in the Wealth of Nations – to send a message to posterity that
prices and profits are the unseen forces guiding economic behaviour conducive to
prosperity. Adam Smith’s justly famous Invisible Hand passage is this:
Every individual necessarily labours to render the annual revenue of the society as great as
he can. He generally, indeed, neither intends to promote the public interest, nor knows how
much he is promoting it. By preferring the support of domestic to that of foreign industry, he
intends only his own security; and by directing the industry in such a manner as its produce
may be of the greatest value; he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other
cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of it. Nor is it always the
worse for the society that it was not part of it. By pursuing his own interest he frequently
promotes that of the society more effectively than when he really intends to promote
it. (Smith 1976, p. 423) [Italics added]

Invisible Hand: Context and Individuals Alluded

What is the context in which the Invisible Hand works its magic? It is a market-
guided economy, that is, an economy revolving around economic freedom and
private property of resources. Such an economy is able to generate prices able to
coordinate the interactions between individuals and engenders a continuous flow of
innovations that add to economic prosperity. The individuals decipher the signals
sent by either the prices of existing products or potential profits associated with
products not yet introduced in the market.
Smith is saying that individuals are motivated by self-interest and the Invisible
Hand of the marketplace guides these profit-seeking creatures into promoting eco-
nomic prosperity. It should be clear that the ‘individual’ involved is any person
acting economically.11 As a result, the Invisible Hand passage does not exclude
profit-seeking innovators in any imaginable way.

11
People act economically when an opportunity for gain is presented to them and they take it.
Appendices 23

Smith did not formally prove anything in relation to the Invisible Hand of the
market mechanism. Strictly speaking the Invisible Hand of Adam Smith is a
conjecture about the virtues of the market-guided economy.12

Reasonable Income Distribution: Not Guaranteed

Whenever a market economy allocates its scarce resources a market outcome


emerges (think of final products such as computers and cars) and two distinct
phenomena happen. First, when the products are sold there will be a certain amount
of money called income that will be generated. Second, the resulting money value is
apportioned among the economic agents (workers, producers, innovators, etc.13) and
generates a distribution of income. The distribution of income is determined by a
variety of factors, including wealth, effort, talent, health, and luck. It is a fact of life
that people are not equally endowed with these factors.
Does the Invisible Hand of the market-oriented economy ensure that the most
deserving people obtain their just income? In a word, no. The Invisible Hand says
nothing about the reasonableness of the distribution of income thrown up by the
market-oriented economy. Certain groups (e.g. successful innovators) may receive
lots of income and other groups (e.g. the “working poor”) very little.
The Invisible Hand works its magic under conditions of strong economic com-
petition. It brings economic prosperity but remains silent about the distribution of
prosperity. Unfortunately, the Invisible Hand cannot guarantee a good job, an
adequate income or a safe environment.

Darwinism and the Invisible Hand

The Invisible Hand of economic competition resembles Darwin’s theory of evolu-


tion through natural selection of those best adapted to survive in the struggle for
existence. In “The End of Laissez-Faire,” first published in 1926, John Maynard
Keynes described a parallelism between the Invisible Hand of Adam Smith and
Darwinism as follows:
This [Invisible Hand] implies that there must be no mercy or protection for those who
embark their capital or their labour in the wrong direction. It is method of bringing the most
successful profit-makers to the top by a ruthless struggle for survival, which selects the most
efficient by the bankruptcy of the less efficient. Just as Darwin invoked sexual love, acting
through sexual selection, as an adjutant to natural selection by competition, to direct

12
The Invisible Hand Theorem and the Invisible Hand Doctrine are related to the Invisible Hand
conjecture but they will not be considered here. In Pol (2013) it is shown that failure to distinguish
the Invisible Hand Theorem from the Invisible Hand Doctrine distorts thinking about Adam Smith’s
message, creating the misconception that the Invisible Hand passage excludes innovators.
13
People receive income from wages, from the profits of the firms they own (or own shares in), from
successful innovations introduced in the economy, and from the capital that they invest.
24 1 A Bird’s-eye View of the Economy and Economics

evolution along the lines which should be desirable as well as effective, so the individualist
invoke the love of money, acting through the pursue of profit, as an adjutant to natural
selection, to bring about the production on the greatest possible scale of what is most
strongly desired as measured by exchange value. (Keynes 1928, p. 284)

Nowadays, the expression “economic Darwinism” refers to the survival of the


fittest in the rough and tumble market-oriented economy.

Summary

More than two centuries ago, Adam Smith imagined that a market-guided economy
populated by self-interested individuals is apt to promote economic prosperity. In
pursuing his own gain in a particular economic activity, the individual is led by an
Invisible Hand to promote an end that he does not intend, and which is conducive to
economic prosperity. It should be emphasized that this interpretation does not
assume perfect competition (as a reminder, perfect competition is incompatible
with business innovation).
Adam Smith’s Invisible Hand alludes to the role of prices and profits in a market-
guided economy. If market prices do not exist because the products do not exist,
potential profits engender a legion of innovators that substantially contribute to
economic prosperity by creating new products, new processes and new forms of
organization. Innovation is an economic activity where the Invisible Hand shines
through. Finally, a compelling caveat: the Invisible Hand produces economic pros-
perity but is indifferent to the distribution of prosperity. It is a serious mistake to
claim that the Invisible Hand will always lead to an equitable distribution of
prosperity. In Chap.7 we will encounter an extreme and supreme example of unfair
distribution of income (emerging from the “robot economy paradox”) consistent
with the Invisible Hand.

Curious Interpretation

We have looked at Invisible Hand through twenty-first century lenses but in the
times of Adam Smith ‘the invisible hand’ was a standard expression implying God.
Highly respected economists had suggested that the Invisible Hand conjecture had a
religious element, and Adam Smith was referring to the invisible hand of God. For
example, William J. Baumol (1922–2017) gave two reasons for this interpretation.
First, ‘the invisible hand’ was a standard eighteenth century circumlocution connot-
ing God. Second, Adam Smith was a theist who strongly believed in the guiding role
of God. (Baumol 1986, pp. 241–246).
Selected References 25

Selected References

Aghion P, Howitt P (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica


60:322–352
Arthur WB (2011) The second economy. McKinsey Quarterly, October
Backhouse RE, Steven G, Medema (2009) On the definition of economics. J Econ Perspect 23
(1, Winter):221–233
Baumol WJ (1986) Microtheory: applications and origins. Harvester Wheatsheaf, Birmingham
Brynjolfsson E, McAfee A (2014) The second machine age: work, progress, and prosperity in a
time of brilliant technologies. W.W. Norton & company, New York
Ford M (2015) The rise of the robots. Technology and the threat of mass unemployment. Oneworld
Publications, London
Frey C, Osborne M (2013) The future of employment: how susceptible are jobs to computerization?
Oxford University Press, Oxford
Heilbroner RL (1969) The worldly philosophers: the great economic thinkers. Allen Lane, London
Hicks JR (1984) Is economics a science? Interdiscip Sci Rev 9:213–219
Keynes JM (1928) The end of Laissez-faire. In: The collected writings of John Maynard Keynes,
Essays in biography, vol X. Macmillan St Martin’s Press for the Royal Economic Society, 1972
Keynes JM (1938) Letter to Roy Harrod. Collect Writings John Maynard Key 14:296–297
Pol E (2013) Reconciling the invisible hand and innovation. Econ Innov New Technol 22:431–446
Romer PM (1990a) Are non-convexities important for understanding growth? Am Econ Rev
80:97–103
Romer PM (1990b) Endogenous technological change. J Polit Econ 98:S71–S102
Schumpeter JA (1934) The theory of economic development. Cambridge University Press, Cam-
bridge, MA. First published in Germany, 1911
Schumpeter J (2010) Capitalism, socialism and democracy (with a new introduction by Joseph
E. Stiglitz). Routledge Classics, London/New York. First published in 1942
Shiller RJ (2017a) Robotization without taxation? Project Syndicate, 2 April
Shiller RJ (2017b) Narrative economics. Am Econ Rev 107:967–1004
Shiller, Robert J. (2019): “Narratives about technology-induced job degradations then and now,”
National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 25536. http://www.nber.org/papers/
w25536
Smith A (1976) An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. Clarendon Press,
Oxford. First published in 1776
Warsh D (1984) The idea of economic complexity. Viking Press, New York
Chapter 2
What a Creative Economy Is and How It
Works

Contents
2.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
2.2 Defining Characteristics of a Creative Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
2.2.1 Creative Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29
2.2.2 Creative Society . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29
2.3 A Narrative Model of Economic Evolution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30
2.3.1 Stylized Economies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30
2.3.2 Porter Development Path . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31
2.4 Innovation as an Economic Activity: Background Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32
2.4.1 Dimension 1: Creativity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
2.4.2 Dimension 2: Intellectual Property . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
2.4.3 Dimension 3: Innovation Environment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
2.5 The Essentials of a Creative Economy: Ideas and Human Capital . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33
2.5.1 Ideas and Human Capital . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34
2.5.2 Ideas with Economic Value . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36
2.5.3 Profitable New Ideas . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36
2.6 The Mechanics of a Creative Economy: Basic Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36
2.6.1 Perpetual Innovation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37
2.6.2 Basic Model of a Creative Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37
2.6.3 Concluding Comment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39
2.7 Chapter Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39
Appendices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40
Appendix C: Ideas and Human Capital as Economic Products . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40
Classification of Products # 1: Rivalness . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40
Classification of Products # 2: Excludability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42
Two-Way Classification of Products . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43
Appendix D: The Creative Economy and Endogenous Growth Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45
Concluding Remark . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48
Selected References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48

Concise Preview
• It appears that the term ‘creative economy’ was first introduced by Coy (2000) to
mark the association between creativity and economic prosperity.
• Economies evolve over time. A factor-driven economy progresses to an
efficiency-driven economy, and then, reaches the status of innovation-driven
economy.

© Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. 2020 27


J. E. Fernandez-Pol, C. Harvie, Understanding the Creative Economy and the Future
of Employment, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-1652-8_2
28 2 What a Creative Economy Is and How It Works

• Innovation as an economic activity is a complex phenomenon requiring a con-


ceptual model to identify the elements (dimensions) making up this activity.
• The critical inputs in the production of innovations are ideas and human capital.
• The functioning of a creative economy revolves around incessant production of
new ideas and “creative destruction” and can be encapsulated in a simple
conceptual model.
• There are two Appendices adding material to what is explained in the text.
Appendix C provides the framework to understand the difference between ideas
and human capital as economic products. Appendix D locates the Creative
Economy in the context of endogenous growth theory.

2.1 Introduction

This chapter defines the notion of a ‘creative economy’ and describes the way an
economy evolves over time to attain the innovation-driven status. The notion that
creativity is an important factor in achieving economic success was broached by
Joseph Alois Schumpeter a century ago in his book The Theory of Economic
Development, although Schumpeter never used the term ‘creative economy’ in his
writings.
‘Innovation’ is a term associated with Schumpeter. Schumpeter’s book The
Theory of Economic Development emphasized the importance of the innovator, the
person who introduces “new combinations.” Schumpeter throughout his various
works defines the essence of innovation to be the “carrying out of new combina-
tions.” He writes further:
As a rule, the new combinations must draw the necessary means of production from some
old combinations (. . .) development consists primarily in employing existing resources in a
different way, in doing new things with them (. . .) (Schumpeter 1934, p. 68)

As will become apparent, innovation as an economic activity is the essential


ingredient of a creative economy. To study this distinct economic activity we need a
conceptual model. The proffered model of innovation as an economic activity is
called ‘background model ’. But this model remains silent about the way a creative
economy functions. A different conceptual framework is required to understand the
behaviour of a creative economy. We call this mental construct ‘basic model’ of a
creative economy.

2.2 Defining Characteristics of a Creative Economy

It appears that the introduction of the term ‘creative economy’ to mark the associ-
ation of creativity and economic prosperity was first introduced by Business Week in
August 2000:
2.2 Defining Characteristics of a Creative Economy 29

Now the Industrial Economy has given way to the Creative economy, and corporations are at
another crossroads. Attributes that made them ideal in for the 20th century could crippled
them in the 21st. so they will have to change, dramatically. The Darwinian struggle of the
daily business will be won by the people –and organizations– that adapt most successfully to
the new world that is unfolding. (Coy 2000)

When creativity is applied to producing ideas with economic value there is the
potential to improve living standards. For example, when Joanne Rowling on a train
to London dreamed up the story of a boy wizard (Harry Potter), she engendered
enormous amounts of wealth and public happiness.
More and more people are coming to understand that innovation is a means by
which most residents of an economy can improve their living standards. ‘Innovation’
can mean different things for different people. However, it is generally agreed that an
innovation is a new idea and the generation of a new idea tends to be associated with
a creative act. Thus, to be innovative means to be creative.1

2.2.1 Creative Economy

Definitions do not change economic reality but may change the lenses with which we
look at the economy. We believe that the essence of a creative economy can be
captured by the following definition: a creative economy is a profit-oriented, market-
guided economy in which the improvement of the standard of living of its residents
is substantially based on the production of profitable new ideas. This is the kind of
economy envisaged by Joseph Alois Schumpeter and rigorously formalized by Paul
M. Romer, a winner of the Nobel Prize in economics.2
Many real economies resemble a creative economy. A small sample of
innovation-driven economies includes Australia, France, Germany, Singapore,
United States, and United Kingdom. The opposite extreme of a creative economy
is the stick-in-the mud economy, one populated by individuals lacking initiative,
opposed to new ideas, progress and novelty. The isolated communities of feudal
Europe illustrate this polar case.

2.2.2 Creative Society

A creative society is one in which innovation has a powerful grip of the community’s
imagination and new ideas abound. Is an economy embedded in a creative society
necessarily a Creative Economy? Strictly speaking the answer is ‘not necessarily’

1
There is one slightly ambiguous feature of the characterization of an innovation as a new idea. In
practice, the word ‘new’ requires qualifications (“new to the world”, “new to the market” and so
on).
2
For more details about Romer’s contributions, see the section Innovation and Economic Growth in
Appendix D.
30 2 What a Creative Economy Is and How It Works

because an ‘esoteric case’ may happen. A society where new ideas abound but the
innovations have little or no economic relevance falls into the category of ‘creative
society.’ However, the corresponding economy cannot be considered as a creative
economy because one of the defining characteristics of this special type of economy
is the production of profitable new ideas.
A case in point is the Athenian society (500 BC or thereabouts). Many new –and
fundamental– ideas were created: democracy, procedures to establish (or confute)
arguments, and philosophical insights. The Athenian society was a creative society.
However, those ideas did not have economic value in a fundamental way, and
therefore, the economy associated with the Athenian society was not a creative
economy.3
As will become apparent, Michael E. Porter also envisaged the notion of a
creative economy. Porter’s (1990) pioneering four-year study of the patterns of
competitive success in ten leading trading nations (Denmark, Germany, Italy,
Korea, Japan, Singapore, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United
States) is the origin of his narrative model presented in Chap. 10 of The Competitive
Advantages of Nations. According to Porter, economic development (or economic
evolution) is a sequential process where the economy travels across different stages
over time to increase the standard of living of its residents.

2.3 A Narrative Model of Economic Evolution

Economic evolution can be thought of as a sequential process. The economy follows


a pattern of change over time consisting of different stages accompanied by a
specification of both the order in which the economy progresses through the stages
and the conditions required for the transition from one stage to another.

2.3.1 Stylized Economies

To fix ideas, suppose that a hypothetical economy goes through three stages of


evolution. Whenever the economy is located in a particular a stage of evolution, the
economy is characterized by a set of distinguishing features i.e. an economy will
display different defining characteristics depending on the particular stage of
evolution.
The representative economy of the first stage is called “factor-driven economy.”
The factor-driven economy focuses on resource extraction, assembly, and labour-
intensive manufacturing. Firms produce primary commodities or relatively simple

3
Socrates (469-399 BC) invented the Socratic Method, an important innovation in the field of
critical thinking but not a profitable new idea.
2.3 A Narrative Model of Economic Evolution 31

products of long-standardized technology designed abroad. Unskilled labour is


pervasive. Low labour cost and unprocessed natural resources are the dominant
sources of competitive advantage and exports. Primary economies are those that
compete on both price and low cost of resources. This kind of economy is highly
sensitive to commodity price fluctuations and exchange rate volatility.
After a period of transition, the factor-driven economy transforms into an “effi-
ciency-driven economy.” The economy is now in stage 2. In the efficiency-driven
economy, the emphasis is on efficiency in producing standard products. In this type
of economy, manufacturing plays a major role. Capital-intensive firms are more
dominant. Efficiency in producing standard products becomes the key source of
competitive advantage, but technological progress is largely exogenous for the
economy in question (new technology and designs come from abroad although
some domestic firms begin to develop the capacity to improve on them). Price
competition is the predominant form of economic competition.
Finally, after another transitional phase the efficiency-driven economy morphs
into an “innovation-driven economy”. In stage 3, innovation becomes a pervasive
and important economic activity. Price competition is still highly relevant for the
economy as a whole, but competition through innovation is intense in sectors where
technological progress is imperative, such as telecommunications and computers. In
this kind of economy, the ability to produce new products at the global technological
frontier becomes the dominant source of competitive advantage. An innovation-
driven economy is likened to –or perhaps indistinguishable from– a creative
economy.
These three stylised types of economies do not purport to capture everything
about real economies. No country will fit a stage exactly. Furthermore, it should be
clear that there are two transitional phases (from stage 1 to stage 2, and from stage
2 to stage 3) that have to be taken into account in order to articulate the notion of
economic evolution as a sequential process. Given the appropriate circumstances,
the hypothetical national economy gradually moves from one stage to another.

2.3.2 Porter Development Path

The Global Competitiveness Reports published by the World Economic Forum have
established intervals of GDP per capita (in $US) to identify stylized economies in the
real world. For example, any economy with GDP per capita greater than $17,000 is
considered an innovation-driven economy operating in phase E of Diagram 2.1.
In brief, this imaginary and stylized economy evolves along a path in five phases:
phase A (or stage 1), phase B (transitional phase), phase C (or stage 2), phase D
(transitional phase), and phase E (or stage 3). We call this path the Porter Develop-
ment Path.
What is the use of all this? The Global Competitiveness Reports are used to
associate national economies with stylized economies. For example, according to the
Global Competitiveness Report 2016–2017, GDP per capita for Argentina and
32 2 What a Creative Economy Is and How It Works

Diagram 2.1 Different types of economies

Australia were US$13,589 and US$50,962, respectively. Therefore, Argentina is an


economy in transition operating in phase D and Australia is an innovation-driven
economy operating in phase E (see Diagram 2.1). It should be emphasized that there
is no guarantee that moving along this path will occur for all economies. In practice,
relatively few countries are successful. Some may get stuck in a particular phase.

2.4 Innovation as an Economic Activity: Background


Model

One of the striking features of our society is the incessant urge for the creation,
adoption and diffusion of innovations. There are many sorts of innovations: busi-
ness, social, artistic, for example. A creative economy has sharp focus on business
innovations. These innovations are new ideas (think of new products or new
processes or new marketing methods or new forms of organization) introduced in
the economy with the intention of making money. Consequently, the production of
business innovations is an economic activity.
Innovation as an economic activity is a complex phenomenon. To understand
complex phenomena it is often necessary to construct simple models to organize our
thinking. The simplest model of innovation as an economic activity affirms that there
are three discernible ‘dimensions’ that lie in the background of this activity, namely:
creativity, intellectual property, and innovation environment.
2.5 The Essentials of a Creative Economy: Ideas and Human Capital 33

2.4.1 Dimension 1: Creativity

To see the inner meaning of this dimension, we just have to note that there would be
no new ideas without people using their personal creative energies. Innovators
pursue the three Fs: Fame, Fortune, and Freedom. They are the stuff of which
dreams are made. It is no exaggeration to say that the vast majority of new ideas
emerge because people and organizations want monetary gains from their creative
efforts.

2.4.2 Dimension 2: Intellectual Property

The act of innovation typically creates intellectual property, and governments help
innovators to protect this kind of property. Innovators protect their new ideas using
patents, copyrights, trade secrets, and trademarks.

2.4.3 Dimension 3: Innovation Environment

Innovators do not operate in a vacuum. They need a fertile ecology to produce new
ideas. Innovation is unlikely in a society that is extremely traditional because the
creation of new ideas requires diversity and tolerance.
The three dimensions of innovation can be assembled in one picture that provides
a visual model. For lack of a better term we will refer to it as the Background Model
(see Diagram 2.2). It is not difficult to see that any relevant topic concerning business
innovation is included at least in one of the three dimensions.4

2.5 The Essentials of a Creative Economy: Ideas


and Human Capital

Research pioneered by Paul M. Romer has unravelled the codes of a creative


economy. Stripped to its bare essentials a creative economy revolves around two
elements: ideas and human capital. The mastery of the meaning of these terms is
absolutely essential for anyone willing to understand how the creative economy
works.

4
Although the dimensions were described separately, this is done only for expository purposes. In
the real world the three dimensions are intertwined.
34 2 What a Creative Economy Is and How It Works

Diagram 2.2 The three dimensions of innovation as an economic activity

2.5.1 Ideas and Human Capital

Ideas and human capital are familiar notions. These concepts are often conflated but
are logically distinct. The concept of ‘idea’ means any conception such as, for
example, any opinion, knowledge, view or belief, existing in the mind; ‘human
capital’ consists of the intangible resources (e.g. personal knowledge) possessed by
individuals and groups within a given population.
Almost thirty years ago Nobel Prize winner Paul M. Romer emphasized that ideas
and human capital are inherently different products. Romer refines this familiar
characterization of ‘idea’ and ‘human capital’ by locating these concepts on two
distinguishable planes. On one plane, ideas are knowledge or information that can be
stored in places outside the human brain such as books, videos, compact disks, and
2.5 The Essentials of a Creative Economy: Ideas and Human Capital 35

memory sticks (USBs). On the second plane, human capital is the stock of educa-
tion, training, and experience stored in the human brain.
To understand the conceptual difference between ideas and human capital, it
helps to have concrete examples in mind. Sir Isaac Newton (1642–1727) formulated
the law of gravity (idea). His human capital does not exist any longer, but the law of
gravity has lived on after he died. The great English economist Alfred Marshall
(1842–1924) introduced the idea of elasticity of one variable with respect to another.
His human capital does not exist any longer but the concept of elasticity lives after he
is gone. Additional examples pointing out the difference between ideas and human
capital abound.
Ideas and human capital are tightly linked in real life. For example, ideas are used
in the educational process (think of textbooks) to produce human capital and human
capital produces ideas (e.g. a new statistical tool).
Note 1 Socrates and the written word
The separation between ideas and human capital is a deep insight. Historically
speaking, the separation became clear with the invention of writing to represent the
spoken word. Apparently, the Greek philosopher Socrates was the first thinker to
point out an implication of the bifurcation of ideas/human capital. According to
Plato’s Phaedrus, Socrates lamented the development of writing.
Specifically, he feared that as people came to rely on the written word (as a
substitute for the knowledge they used to carry inside their brains), they would slow
down the exercising of their memory, become forgetful and less creative. He could
not foresee that the many ways of writing and reading would serve to expand our
memory and spur fresh ideas. This should not be surprising [Remember that the
arrival of Gutenberg’s printing press happened in the fifteenth century (1453)]
Note 2 Tacit knowledge
Human capital includes the skills absorbed in early childhood programs, the skills
accumulated in primary school, secondary school, tertiary education, and on-the-job
training. But there are also other skills stored in the human brain referred to as tacit
knowledge. The key insight underlying this type of knowledge is that a person can
know how to do things, without being able to describe how to do it. This is a special
type of knowledge used by those who possess it, but it is not easily communicated to
others.
Tacit knowledge is difficult or impossible to put in a codified form (perhaps
‘indefinable knowledge’ might be a better expression). The skills of a master
craftswoman are not learned from a textbook, but during years of experience and
apprenticeship. Tacit knowledge tends to be transferred by teachers to students by
doing things together (think of a dance class) and by working through examples
(doing mathematics depends to some extent on intuitive understanding that some-
times cannot be put down).
36 2 What a Creative Economy Is and How It Works

2.5.2 Ideas with Economic Value

There are many kinds of ideas but in this book we are interested in ideas with
economic value, that is, ideas capable of making money. It should be clear that ideas
with economic value and business innovations mean the same thing. It should also
be clear that any new idea with economic value might be rejected by the market, and
therefore, would be an unsuccessful business innovation.
Necessity is an important source of new ideas. A new parent would pay just about
anything to get a baby to sleep after weeks of sleepless nights. Hana-Lia Krawchuk
could not get her son, Elijah, to sleep through the night. Hana-Lia came up with a
new idea with economic value: at the kitchen table, with needle and thread, she
stitched a swaddling suit with sleeves raised above the head. Her swaddling suit
worked remarkably well. Elijah was able to sleep through the night. Hana-Lia
patented her innovation (the swaddling suit) and created a new firm, Love to
Dream. The company grew at 35% a year in the period 2014–2016, with exports
to 45 countries.

2.5.3 Profitable New Ideas

Reverting to the notion of a creative economy, we can observe that an integral part of
the definition is “profitable new ideas”. Profitable ideas are economic ideas that in
fact earn money. It follows at once that profitable new ideas and successful business
innovations are indistinguishable. The introduction of the Personal Computer (PC)
by IBM in 1981; Windows by Microsoft in 1985; iPhone by Apple in 2007; iPad by
Apple in 2010, and Snapchat by Murphy and Spiegel in 2011 are outstanding
examples of successful innovations in the IT sector.

2.6 The Mechanics of a Creative Economy: Basic Model

One question immediately suggests itself. How does a creative economy work? The
mechanics of a creative economy involves two principles that allow us to see what is
truly important in this special kind of economy. Both principles emerge from direct
observation of the real economic world and recognize the deep insights contributed
by Joseph Alois Schumpeter.
2.6 The Mechanics of a Creative Economy: Basic Model 37

2.6.1 Perpetual Innovation

Before going into the principles that govern the way a creative economy works, we
must pause for a moment and ask: is innovation in the real world likely to stop? It is
very unlikely that innovation stops. To see this, consider the line of reasoning
inaugurated by Paul M. Romer. An innovation is a new idea, and a new idea is
always the recombination of old ideas (this tenet is called ‘recombinant innovation’).
For instance, the innovation ‘body-pump’ introduced in the fitness industry in 1995
is a physical exercise consisting of a combination of weights (old idea) and music
(old idea).
The number of new ideas is fantastically large because combinatorial possibilities
explode very quickly. For example, if the number of existing ideas is equal to twenty
(20), the number of new ideas (denoted by NI) that can be generated by
reconfiguring 20 ideas turns out to be: NI ¼ 1018.4 (10 to the power of 18.4). This
number results from selecting and arranging, in order, 20 objects from 20 objects.
The size of this number is beyond imagination.5 In brief, reordering existing ideas is
an immense source of new ideas.

2.6.2 Basic Model of a Creative Economy

A conceptual model highlighting the essential mechanisms underlying a Creative


Economy consists of three building blocks (ideas, human capital and non-human
capital) and two principles that we do not propose to question. Because this model is
just a starting point we will call it the Basic Model.
Principle 1 (Recombinant Innovation): There is incessant reconfiguration of ideas
into new valuable ideas that themselves have the possibility of later becoming
reconfigured into yet new ideas.
Principle 2 (Creative Destruction): Profit-seeking innovators try to achieve market
dominance by creating better products than their competitors. Over time the new
products displace old ones, earn profits for some period of time, and are replaced
in turn.
These principles are consistent with the empirical evidence and we do not
propose to challenge them. Both principles are associated with the Harvard econo-
mist Joseph Alois Schumpeter. The notion of recombinant innovation goes back at
least to (Schumpeter 1934, p. 68). In his 1942 book Capitalism, Socialism, and

5
See Romer (1993a, b) “Ideas and Things.” Mathematically speaking 1018.4 ¼ 20! The symbol “!”
means “factorial” and factorial, in turn, means the product of an integer and all the integers below it;
for example, factorial four (denoted by 4!) is, by definition, 4  3  2  1 (equal to 24).
38 2 What a Creative Economy Is and How It Works

Diagram 2.3 The components of the basic model

Democracy, he described capitalism as a process of “creative destruction” in the


sense that new innovations replace old technologies (think of new products
destroying old products). See Schumpeter (2010), especially Chap. 7.
It should be clear that Principles 1 and 2 mean that in a creative economy the
interaction between ideas and human capital is never ending. This reciprocal influ-
ence resembles a perpetual motion machine.6 It should also be clear that any model
of a creative economy based on Principles 1 and 2 presupposes the existence of
creative people (homo creativus) in a fundamental way. Homo economicus cannot
be the central economic agent in this type of economy simple because he does not
innovate and never will.
Diagram 2.3 assembles the components of the Basic Model (building blocks and
principles) in a single picture. Recombinant innovation and creative destruction
constitute useful conceptual tools to gain an understanding of the workings of a
creative economy, but innovations do not fall like manna from heaven. Instead, they
are created by human beings, in the process of trying to create new products, to find
new and better ways of doing things, and to profit from opening up new markets.
Note 3 Competition through innovation and creative destruction
Competition through innovation is an integral part of the Basic Model of the
creative economy. What may not be so clear is the conceptual relationship between

6
A perpetual motion machine is a theoretical device that would continue to operate forever.
2.7 Chapter Summary 39

competition through innovation and creative destruction. Can one exist without the
other?
Creative destruction presupposes competition through innovation. However,
competition through innovation does not necessarily imply creative destruction.
Consider, for example, the market for antidepressants. In 1988, Elli Lilly introduced
one of the most lucrative mental health drugs in history, Prozac. In 1992, Pfizer Inc.
introduced a rival antidepressant, Zoloft, and sometime later, SmithKline introduced
a third antidepressant drug, Paxil. This is a clear case of innovation-based compe-
tition. The three drugs are still on the market, and therefore, this is not an example of
creative destruction.
In a nutshell, creative destruction cannot exist without competition through
innovation but innovation-based competition can exist without creative destruction.
In the real world, most innovation comes from improving existing products rather
than destructive innovation.

2.6.3 Concluding Comment

The Basic Model highlights the creation of profitable new ideas and creative
destruction. It is understood that non-human capital also plays an important role in
the real world of innovation. The fact that capital goods (e.g. equipment and
infrastructure) as well as natural resources (e.g. land and fish in the ocean) are left
out of the picture does not imply that they are irrelevant, merely that they are not the
central focus of the Basic Model. The importance of resource endowments will be
considered in Chap. 4.

2.7 Chapter Summary

• Most but not all economies evolve along the Porter Development Path to attain
the status of creative economies. This empirical fact is an integral part of the
Porter model of economic development. More details about this model can be
found in Pol (2020).
• The notion of a creative economy was initially envisaged by Joseph Alois
Schumpeter in The Theory of Economic Development (first published in German
in 1911), empirically isolated by Michael M. Porter in The Competitive Advan-
tage of Nations (first published in 1990), and theoretically analysed by Paul
M. Romer in his pathbreaking paper “Endogenous Technological Change”
published in 1990. Neither of them used the expression ‘creative economy’ in
their writings.
• An innovation is a new idea and the generation of a new idea tends to be
associated with a creative act.
• A creative economy is defined in this book as a profit-oriented, market-guided
economy in which the improvement of the standard of living of its residents is
substantially based on the production of profitable new ideas.
40 2 What a Creative Economy Is and How It Works

• A stick-in-the mud economy is one in which misoneism is pervasive.7


• New ideas introduced in the economy with the intention of making money are
called business innovations.
• The simplest model of innovation as an economic activity (Background Model)
identifies three dimensions: creativity, intellectual property, and innovation
environment.
• Ideas and human capital are often conflated but are logically distinct.
• Ideas are knowledge or information stored outside the human brain.
• Human capital is the stock of education, training and experience stored in the
human brain.
• Ideas with economic value and business innovations mean the same thing.
• Profitable new ideas are successful business innovations.
• The simplest model of a Creative Economy (Basic Model) is made up of three
building blocks –ideas, human capital, and non-human capital– and two funda-
mental principles: incessant production of innovations (Principle 1) and destruc-
tion of old products by new products (Principle 2).

Appendices

Appendix C: Ideas and Human Capital as Economic Products

We have now finished our broad sweep of the creative economy. The time has come
to get out the microscope and to bring into sharp focus the different attributes of
ideas and human capital as economic products. In thinking about the various
products in the economy, it is useful to classify them according to different
characteristics.
There are two different classifications of products. One classification is based on
whether or not the use of a product by one person precludes its use by another. The
second classification revolves around property rights.8

Classification of Products # 1: Rivalness

• Rival products
A product is rival if its use by one person precludes its use by another person.
A hard copy of a book is a rival product because when I read it at home you are
precluded from reading it at the same time. Likewise, human capital is a rival product

7
According to the Merriam-Webster dictionary, “misoneism” means “a hatred, fear, or intolerance
of innovation and change.”
8
Appendix C draws heavily on Romer (1992).
Appendices 41

Diagram 2.4 Classification


# 1: Rival/non-rival
products

under the assumption that we do not put what we know in writing or any other means
of communication.
• Non-rival products
A product is said to be non-rival if its use by one person does not reduce the
ability of another person to use the same product.
Ideas are non-rival products because knowledge store outside the human brain
can be used by many people simultaneously without reducing the ability of any
person to use the same knowledge (see Diagram 2.4).
Examples of non-rival products abound: an e-book (when I read it at home you
are not precluded from reading it simultaneously), a recipe for making a cake (its use
by one person does not preclude another person from using the same recipe
simultaneously), access to the Internet (the use of the Internet by a particular person
does not prevent another user from getting on to the same network), a radio
broadcast (it can be received by any number of listeners without any reduction in
the ability of other listeners to tune in), and digital information are a few.
Hypothetical Example
It should be noticed that the difference between rival and non-rival products is
subtle. To see this, consider a hypothetical example. Suppose that a firm carries
out research and development and creates a new software product consisting of a
software code. Assume, in addition, that the software product is embedded in a USB.
This means that the software product can be “bifurcated” into an idea (software
code) and a physical object (USB). This is illustrated in Diagram 2.5.

Note The 3-4-5 triangle rule and the carpenter


The difference between ideas and human capital can be illustrated with a concrete
example. A right triangle is a triangle in which one angle is a right angle (that is, a
90-degree angle). The longest side opposite the right angle is called the hypotenuse.
The Pythagorean Theorem says that “the square of the hypotenuse of a right triangle
is equal to the sum of the squares of the lengths of the other two sides.” In symbols,
Pythagoras’ theorem states that a2 þ b2 ¼ c2 , where a and b are the lengths of the
other sides, and c is the length of the hypotenuse. For example, a ¼ 3, b ¼
4 implies 32 þ 42 ¼ 52 .
The Pythagorean Theorem is an idea that can be found, for example, on the
Internet. Carpenters use this idea to build square corners by constructing a triangle
42 2 What a Creative Economy Is and How It Works

Diagram 2.5 Conceptual bifurcation of a software product using classification # 1

with sides in the proportions, 3, 4, and 5.9 Human capital here consists of connec-
tions between neurons in the carpenter’s head, a rival product. Note that every
carpenter in the world can use the 3-4-5 triangle rule at the same time without
reducing the ability of the other carpenters to use the same rule.

Classification of Products # 2: Excludability

As a reminder, you have property rights on an item when you own or have exclusive
rights to use that item.
• Excludable product: property rights can be enforced.
For example, the mobile phone that I own is excludable. Legally, you cannot use
my mobile phone without my consent. Also, human capital is an excludable product:
there is no way for anyone to use my human capital without my consent –at least
unless they use force. Ideas protected by trade secrets are also excludable products.
• Partially excludable product: property rights exist but are difficult to enforce.
Property rights on elephants and rhinos are not easy to enforce. Patented ideas are
partially excludable products because competitors “invent around” using the infor-
mation contained in the patents.
• Non-excludable product: property rights cannot be established or enforced.

9
A 3-4-5 triangle is a right triangle where 3 and 4 are the lengths of the shorter sides, and 5 is the
length of the hypotenuse. If a triangle has sides measuring 3, 4, and 5 feet (or any other unit) it must
be a right triangle with a 90 angle between the short sides. If you can "find" this triangle in your
corner, you know the corner is square.
Appendices 43

Diagram 2.6 Different degrees of excludability

Diagram 2.7 Conceptual bifurcation of a software product using classification # 2

Fish in the ocean beyond maritime boundaries is a non-excludable product. Ideas


in Wikipedia are non-excludable products.
Diagram 2.6 takes advantage of classification # 2 to discern different kinds of
ideas.
Hypothetical Example (Cont.)
We revert to our hypothetical example to make the following point: property rights
can be established on the software code (e.g. a patent or copyright) but copy
protection can be infringed (software piracy is a pervasive phenomenon). The
USB is totally excludable. As a result, the software code is at least partially
excludable (it might be completely excludable using a trade secret) and the USB is
excludable. This (second) bifurcation of the software product is illustrated in Dia-
gram 2.7.

Two-Way Classification of Products

Using the preceding classifications we can generate different categories of products.


This can be easily seen: superimposing classifications # 1 and # 2 yields a two-way
classification of products (see Diagram 2.8).
44 2 What a Creative Economy Is and How It Works

Diagram 2.8 The two-way classification of products with examples

Category I (Private Goods)


Private goods are both rival and excludable. Most products in the economy are
private goods, like computers, coffee makers, washing machines, deodorants and so
on. Human capital is a private good. Unless my human capital is converted into a
non-rival product (for example, by putting what I know in writing) my human capital
is both rival and excludable.
Category II (Quasi-Private Goods)
Rival products which are partially excludable (e.g. elephants, rhinos) may be called
quasi-private goods.
Category III (Common Resources)
Products that are rival and non-excludable are called common resources. A typical
example is fish in the ocean beyond national boundaries. The product ‘fish in the
ocean’ is rival because when one person catches fish, there are fewer fish for you to
catch and we mentioned before that it is non-excludable. In some African countries,
elephants are a common resource. They are a rival product without any owners.
Category IV (No Name)
In this category we find ideas that are fully excludable.
Category V (No Name)
This category includes ideas protected by patents or copyrights.
Category VI (Public Goods)
Public goods are both non-rival and non-excludable. A public good is available to
everyone everywhere (normally within national boundaries) and people are not
charged for the use of the public good. ’Free-to-air-TV signals’ and ‘national
defence’ are standard examples of public goods.
Linchpin Category
Categories IV and V can be agglomerated to create a conceptual category for
sharpening thinking about a creative economy. In fact, the agglomeration yields a
linchpin category for understanding ideas as economic products. Ideas with eco-
nomic value are always non-rival and at least partially excludable
Appendices 45

It should be clear that ideas and human capital have different attributes as
economic products. Ideas are always non-rival and at least partially excludable.
Human capital is a private good. A glance at Diagram 2.8 shows that equating ideas
with human capital is misleading.

Appendix D: The Creative Economy and Endogenous Growth


Theory

Opening Remark
There are many mathematical models that develop the deep insights provided by
Principle 1 (Recombinant Innovation) and Principle 2 (Creative Destruction). These
models fall within the so-called “endogenous growth theory.” The outstanding
pioneers are Paul M. Romer (1990a, b) and Aghion and Howitt (1992) for principles
1 and 2, respectively. But there are many others.10
Because we assume that the readers of this book may not be familiar with the
progress in economic growth theory, we must pause for a moment to briefly explain
recent developments in the economics of growth. We start by introducing a very
useful formula that expresses the economy’s growth rate as a combination of simpler
components.
Solow Decomposition Formula
The simple, yet fundamental question in economic growth theory is: what deter-
mines the rate of economic growth? The short answer is factor inputs (labour and
capital) and technological progress (elements that affect productivity such as inno-
vation and imitation). The standard formula used to separate the components of
economic growth is as follows. If g represents the economy’s growth rate, then

g¼lþkþρ

where l denotes the contribution of labour, k the contribution of capital and ρ is


technological progress. This formula –known as the Solow decomposition formula–
separates out the contributions of the three immediate elements driving observed
economic growth.
Note carefully that the Solow decomposition formula does not make any
behavioural assumptions on its components (singly or jointly). For example, looking
at the Solow formula alone we cannot say whether ρ is given (exogenous) or is
explained by market incentives (endogenous).

10
Readers interested in the foundations of modern growth theory, from the neoclassical paradigm to
the current frontier in growth theory, can find valuable material in the ground-breaking book
Introduction to Modern Economic Growth by Acemoglu (2009).
46 2 What a Creative Economy Is and How It Works

Old Growth Theory


Old growth theory, as developed by Nobel Prize winner Robert M. Solow in his
1956 paper “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth”, Quarterly Journal
of Economics, dominated economists’ thinking about long-run economic growth for
more than 30 years. The old growth theory assumes that technological progress is
exogenous, that is, technological progress is a black box, and technology is a public
good, i.e. technology is available to everyone for free.
Solow (1957) empirically showed that the lion’s share of economic growth was
accounted for by technological progress emerging from the contributions by inno-
vations and imitations. Increases in factor inputs (labour and capital) could empir-
ically explain only a small proportion of observed growth in industrial countries. The
interpretation of this result is that economic growth cannot be understood solely in
terms of the accumulation of labour and capital.
The fact that technological progress is the most important component of eco-
nomic growth stands to this day. But in the old growth theory technological progress
is a black box. Consequently, the old growth theory left the most important part of
economic growth (ρ in the Solow decomposition formula) unexplained.
Endogenous Growth Theory
Endogenous growth theory goes inside the black box and provides an explanation of
technological progress in terms of innovations taking place largely in response to the
profit motive. Furthermore endogenous growth theory drops the assumption that
technology is a public good and assumes that technology has proprietary aspects.
Endogenous growth theory started with the seminal 1990 paper “Endogenous
Technological Change” by 2018 Nobel Prize winner Paul M. Romer. This paper
ended the dominance of the Solowian approach.
Aghion and Howitt (1992) operationalized Schumpeter’s notion of creative
destruction. Their approach was initiated in 1987 at MIT, where Philippe Aghion
was a first-year assistant professor and Peter Howitt a visiting professor on sabbatical
from the University of Western Ontario. More precisely, Aghion and Howitt (1992)
constructed a mathematical model of the competitive process by which innovators
are constantly looking for new ideas that will render their rivals’ ideas obsolete. By
focusing on innovation as a distinct economic activity, this approach opens the door
for further understanding of how firms, institutions, and government policy
interact.11
Innovation and Economic Growth
The Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences awarded the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in
Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2018 to William D. Nordhaus (“for
integrating climate change into long-run macroeconomic analysis”) and Paul
M. Romer (“for integrating technological innovations into long-run macroeconomic

11
The extension of the old growth theory to the endogenous growth theory exemplifies the fact that
knowledge in economics is cumulative. This point was made in Chap. 1 as a characteristic of the
economics discipline. See Table 1.1.
Appendices 47

analysis”). According to the Royal Academy of Sciences, “Romer’s solution, which


was published in 1990, laid the foundation of what is now called endogenous growth
theory. The theory is both conceptual and practical, as it explains how ideas are
different to other goods and require specific conditions to thrive in a market. Romer’s
theory has generated vast amounts of new research into the regulations and policies
that encourage new ideas and long-term prosperity.” Models of endogenous growth
theory are developed using advanced mathematics. In particular Romer’s model
involves fairly difficult mathematics. However, the essence of Romer’s model can be
described in non-mathematical terms.
Romer's Model: Integration of Five Premises
One of the most important achievements of Romer’s work is the integration of five
premises in a general equilibrium model.

Premise ➀: Recombinant innovation (Schumpeter 1934, p. 68)


The act of innovation consists of reconfiguring old ideas to produce new ideas.
Premise ➁: Profit motive and new ideas (Schmookler 1966, p. 208)
Innovation is essentially an economic phenomenon, or at least explicable in
economic terms.
Premise ➂: Proprietary aspects of new ideas Nelson (1982))
The act of innovation is typically imperfectly appropriable.
Premise ➃: Increasing returns and new ideas Romer (1990a)
The existence of intangible inputs renders increasing returns inevitable.
Premise ➄: Ideas and human capital Romer 1990b
Ideas and human capital are inherently different economic products.
What does all this mean? Somewhat roughly, the message conveyed by Romer’s
model is that economic growth can be understood in terms of the creation of new
ideas. Romer explains the intuition behind his model as follows:
Economic growth occurs whenever people take resources and rearrange them in ways that
are more valuable. A useful metaphor for production in an economy comes from the kitchen.
To create valuable final products, we mix inexpensive ingredients together according to a
recipe. The cooking one can do is limited by the supply of ingredients, and most cooking in
the economy produces undesirable side effects. If economic growth could be achieved only
by doing more and more of the same kind of cooking, we would eventually run out of raw
materials and suffer from unacceptable levels of pollution and nuisance. Human history
teaches us, however, that economic growth springs from better recipes, not just more
cooking. New recipes generally produce fewer unpleasant side effects and generate more
economic value per unit of raw material. Romer (1993a, b)
48 2 What a Creative Economy Is and How It Works

Concluding Remark

It should be stressed that Romer’s model proffers that the source of sustained growth
is technological progress based on profit-seeking innovations. In his model, ideas
and human capital are mutually reinforcing in the sense that ideas are the critical
input in the production of more valuable human and non-human capital and human
capital is also the most important input in the production of new ideas. In particular,
skills acquisition through education and learning by doing are necessary for the
evolution of a creative economy.
Another conceptual framework for thinking about sustained growth is the so-
called “Lucas approach.” Lucas (1988) emphasized human capital accumulation as
an alternative source of sustained growth (alternative to technological progress).
Profitable new ideas do not play any role within Lucas’s model of economic growth
and this render the Lucas approach incapable of capturing the essence of a creative
economy.

Selected References

Acemoglu D (2009) Introduction to modern economic growth. Princeton University press,


Princeton
Aghion P, Howitt P (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica
60:322–352
Coy P (2000) The creative economy. Business week, 28 August
Lucas RE (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. J Monet Econ 22(1):3–42
Nelson RR (1982) The role of knowledge in R&D efficiency. Quarter J Econ 96(August):453–470
Pol E (2020) Porter model of economic development at the back of an envelope. Forthcoming
Australian Economics Papers
Porter ME (1990) The competitive advantage of nations. Macmillan Press. Re-issued in 1998 with
an introduction by the author
Romer PM (1990a) Are Non-convexities Important for understanding growth? Am Econ Rev
May:97–103
Romer PM (1990b) Endogenous technological change. J Polit Econ October:S71–S102
Romer PM (1992) Two strategies for economic development: using ideas and producing ideas. In:
Proceedings of the World Bank annual conference on development economics 1992. World
Bank, Washington, pp 63–91
Romer PM (1993a) Ideas and things. Economist, 11 September
Romer PM (1993b) Economic growth. In: Concise encyclopedia of economics: library of econom-
ics and liberty. http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/Economic Growth.html
Schmookler J (1966) Invention and economic growth. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA
Schumpeter JA (1934) The theory of economic development, vol 1911. Cambridge University
Press. First published in Germany, Cambridge, MA
Schumpeter JA (2010) Capitalism, socialism, and democracy, with an introduction by Joseph
E. Stiglitz. Routledge Classics. First published in 1942, Londond/New York
Solow RM (1957) Technical change and the aggregate production function. Rev Econ Stat
39:312–320
The Prize in Economic Sciences (2018) Press release. NobelPrize.org https://www.nobelprize.org/
prizes/economic-sciences/2018/press-release/
Chapter 3
Creativity and Intellectual Propery

Contents
3.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50
3.2 Creative Thinking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51
3.2.1 Logical Thinking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51
3.2.2 Lateral Thinking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53
3.2.3 Imaginary Thinking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54
3.2.4 Critical Thinking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54
3.2.5 Concluding Remarks on Creative Thinking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55
3.3 Intellectual Property . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56
3.3.1 Patents . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56
3.3.1.1 First Patent System: Venice 1474 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56
3.3.1.2 Discoveries and Inventions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57
3.3.1.3 Patentability Guidelines . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57
3.3.1.4 Eligibility Conditions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58
3.3.1.5 Bogus Patents . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58
3.3.1.6 Licensing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59
3.3.1.7 Expiring Patents . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59
3.3.1.8 Enforcing Patent Rights . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60
3.3.1.9 Portfolio of Patents and Patent Trolls . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60
3.3.2 Copyrights . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61
3.3.2.1 Term of a Copyright . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61
3.3.2.2 Smiley Face: A Sad Lesson . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61
3.3.2.3 Warning . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61
3.3.2.4 Copyright Infringements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62
3.3.2.5 Copyrights and Moral Rights . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62
3.3.3 Trade Secrets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62
3.3.4 Trade Secrets Thefts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63
3.3.5 Trademarks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63
3.3.5.1 Trademarks and Packaging . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64
3.4 Chapter Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64
Appendices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66
Appendix E: Further Aspects on Creative Thinking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66
Logical Inference and Mathematics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66
Lateral Thinking and Schizophrenic Thinking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67
Critical Thinking and Previous Knowledge . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67
Sudden and Rapid Breakthroughs? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68
Edison’s Rule . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69
The Photocopier . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69

© Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. 2020 49


J. E. Fernandez-Pol, C. Harvie, Understanding the Creative Economy and the Future
of Employment, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-1652-8_3
50 3 Creativity and Intellectual Propery

Harry Potter . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69
Atlassian . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70
Appendix F: Further Aspects on Intellectual Property . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70
Patents and Partial Excludability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70
Knowledge Spillovers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71
Externalities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71
Software Protection . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71
Protecting Magic Tricks: “Shadows” . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72
Selected References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73

Concise Preview
• Our task in this chapter is to explore Dimension 1 (Creativity) and Dimension
2 (Intellectual Property) of the Background Model sketched in Chap. 1.
• Innovators perform different types of creative thinking. Logical thinking, lateral
thinking, imaginary thinking, and critical thinking are described and illustrated in
this chapter.
• Intellectual property is materialized with legal tools: patents, copyrights, trade
secrets, and trademarks. This chapter draws the line of separation between them.
• Appendix E and F explain additional details for Dimension 1 and 2, respectively.

3.1 Introduction

It is not unusual to find analysts arguing with terms such as innovation and creativity.
We are not going to undertake the task of drawing the line of separation between
innovation and creativity because the two notions are intertwined. The reason is
obvious. An innovation is a new idea, and a new idea involves a creative act.
What do we know about the creative act? Not much. Creativity is a black box or
magic machine – you have to ask your brain to think of something and hope that out
of nowhere you get a “little bolt.” However, what we do know is that creativity (be it
in arts, mathematics, business or anything else) occurs by combining existing ideas
into new, different ideas.
There are basically two attitudes toward the creative act. One possibility is to
claim that the “little bolt” is an absolutely random event, and therefore, lady luck
calls the shots. This view involves an element of defeatism, i.e. acceptance of defeat
without struggle. Another possibility is found at the opposite extreme. Many ana-
lysts believe that anyone can be an innovator.
We do not know what is inside the black box sparking off the “little bolt,” but it
seems reasonable to conjecture that innovators connect ideas to create new ideas.
Innovators excel at connecting seemingly unconnected things. The creative associ-
ations often come from creative thinking.
Suppose that the “little bolt” happens and you create a new idea. Typically, you
would like to protect your new idea. Intellectual property enables people to earn
recognition or financial benefit from what they create. Protecting ideas with eco-
nomic value is not new.
3.2 Creative Thinking 51

The recorded history shows that technologies were protected by extreme means in
Venice. At the beginning of the fifteenth century there were two competing math-
ematical technologies: abacists (who used the abacus and Roman numerals) and
algorists (who used algebraic formulas and Arabic numerals). Each group of tech-
nicians guarded their technologies carefully, making their students sign blood oaths
never to reveal their secrets. Venetian glass was also protected by extreme means.
People born on the Venetian island of Murano could never leave because the might
reveal the technology used to produce glass.

3.2 Creative Thinking

What is inside the minds of successful innovators? How do they go about their
business? The short answer to these questions is: innovators perform “creative
thinking.” They look at problems or situations from a fresh perspective. Creative
thinking involves different procedures or types of thinking such as, for example,
logical thinking, lateral thinking, imaginary thinking, and critical thinking. These
procedures tend to be dispersed in different sources of learning, and therefore, it may
be convenient to describe the distinguishing features attached to each of them.

3.2.1 Logical Thinking

Logical thinking is reasoning that is coherent. For example, consider an innovation


policy based on the assumption that innovators are profit-seeking creatures and
proposing that their private ideas should be freely available in order to encourage
innovation as an economic activity. The policy is incoherent. The reasoning is
illogical. Innovators need to have a material incentive to create new ideas with
economic value; they must be able to reap for themselves some fruits of their
activities. If their new ideas can be used by other people without paying for them,
innovation is extremely unlikely to happen.
If we want to be more precise, we have to mention that there are two types of
logical thinking: logical inference and reliable inference. Logical inference is an
inference in which granted the truth of the premises (or assumptions) the conclusions
must be true.1 Logical inference is based on the so called “If-then” scheme. Some-
what roughly, this means inferences of the form: “If this works like this, and like
that, the result must be such and such.” In logical inference, the conclusions
necessarily follow from the assumptions. Mathematics is a very powerful tool for
making logical inferences.

1
Sometimes logical inference is referred to as “vertical thinking.”
52 3 Creativity and Intellectual Propery

Example 1
The use of logical inference is quite common in economics. In most –if not all–
introductory microeconomics texts you will find the assertion: “If a firm maximizes
profits, then it can be shown that marginal revenue (MR) must be equal to marginal
cost (MC).” The assumption is profit maximization and the conclusion is “MR ¼
MC.”
In reliable inference the conclusions do not necessarily follow from the premises
with logical compulsion but there are reasons to believe that the conclusions are
correct.
Example 2
The type of reasoning performed by fictional detectives to untangle seemingly
intractable puzzles falls into the category of reliable inference. For example, in “A
Scandal in Bohemia” Sherlock Holmes and Dr Watson are faced with a mystery. An
unknown gentleman wants to consult Sherlock Holmes about a strictly confidential
matter (the anonymous request came by the last post). The note is without signature
or address, and says that the man will wear a mask when meeting Holmes. They are
trying to draw conclusions about the country of origin of the unknown gentleman by
examining a sheet of thick pink-tinted note-paper that came by the post. Dr Watson
says:
The man who wrote it was presumably well-to-do. Such paper could not be bought under
half a crown a packet. It is peculiarly strong and stiff.
“Peculiar – that is the very word,” said Holmes. “It is not an English paper at all. Hold it up to
the light.”
I [Dr. Watson] did so, and I saw a large E with a very small g, a P, and a large G with a small
t woven into the texture of the paper.
“What do you make of that?” asked Holmes.
“The name of the Maker, no doubt; or his monogram, rather.”
“Not at all. The G with the small t stands for ‘Gesellschaft,’ which is the German for
‘Company.’ It is a customary contraction like our‘Co.’ P, of course, stands for ‘Papier.’
Now for Eg. Let us glance at our “Continental Gazetter.” He took down a heavy brown
volume from his shelves.
“Eglow, Eglonitz – here we are, Egria. It is a German-speaking country – in Bohemia, not far
from Carlsbad. ‘Remarkable as being the scene of the death of Wallenstein, and for its
numerous glass factories and paper mills.’ Ha, ha, my boy, what do you make of that?”
His eyes sparkled, and he sent up a great blue triumphant cloud from his cigarette.
“The paper was made in Bohemia,” I said.
“Precisely. And the man who wrote the note is a German. Do you note the peculiar
construction of the sentence –‘This account of you we have from all quarters received.’
A Frenchman or Russian could not have written that. It is the German who is so
uncourteous to his verbs. It only remains, therefore, to discover what is wanted by this
German who writes upon Bohemian paper, and prefers wearing a mask to showing his
face. (. . .) (Doyle 2014, pp. 9–10)

Sherlock Holmes performs reliable inference, not logical inference. Strictly


speaking, the pink-tinted note-paper could have been made in another German
speaking region and the man who wrote the note could have been French.
3.2 Creative Thinking 53

3.2.2 Lateral Thinking

The term “lateral thinking” was introduced by de Bono (1967). The traditional
Western thinking system revolves around judgements such as yes/no, right/wrong,
and true/false. This sort of system tends to be incomplete or inadequate at dealing
with change. De Bono claimed that dealing with change requires “what can be” more
than “what is.” Expressions such as “usually” and “sometimes” are acceptable in
place of the “always” and “never” of the traditional thinking system.
The system of thinking should allow you to freely associate different aspects or
elements without being constrained by logical rigour. This does not mean that
ultimately anything goes; it means that to generate new ideas one often has to
disregard the rigidity associated with logical inference. For those fond of novelty,
loose thinking about vaguely formed intuitions may have potential to create big new
ideas.
Lateral thinking is a tool which seeks the solution to a problem located in a
particular area by making associations with other seemingly unrelated areas, rather
than pursuing one logical train of thought focusing on the original area. de Bono
distinguished vertical thinking (logical inference) from lateral thinking, and
suggested that lateral thinking may be a more effective way of engendering new
ideas.
It should be emphasized that lateral thinking is not a substitute for vertical
thinking but a complement. Typically lateral thinking generates new ideas and
vertical thinking develops them. The difference between lateral thinking and vertical
thinking can be easily grasped: with vertical thinking logic is in control of the mind,
whereas with lateral thinking logic is at the service of the mind.
Getting new ideas from a given set of premises following the rules of logical
inference tends to become increasingly difficult. It is like digging for oil in the same
hole deeper and deeper. Lateral thinking is trying again elsewhere. In de Bono’s own
words:
It is not possible to dig a hole in a different place by digging the same hole deeper. Logic
[logical inference] is the tool that is used to dig holes deeper and bigger, to make them
altogether better holes. But if the hole is in the wrong place, then no amount of improvement
is going to put it in the right place. No matter how obvious this may seem to every digger, it
is still easier to go on digging in the same hole than to start all over again in a new place.
Vertical thinking is digging the same hole deeper; lateral thinking is trying again elsewhere.
(de Bono 1968, p. 26)

The beauty of lateral thinking is that it is open to everyone because it does not
depend on sheer intelligence. Unfortunately, lateral thinking is still a primitive art.
Example 3
The use of analogies to create new ideas is an example of lateral thinking. To
design a new product B we can make an analogy between product A (which is
well-understood) and product B. This may suggest certain ways to approach the
design of B and certain hypotheses to test, without implying that because they are
54 3 Creativity and Intellectual Propery

valid for A they are necessarily valid for B. In other words, to design product B we
see “what makes product A work.”

3.2.3 Imaginary Thinking

This type of creative thinking is based on mental images of entities that do not exist
in reality. For example, the kind of reasoning used by J. K. Rowling when writing
about Harry Potter falls into the category of imaginary thinking. Another example is
science fiction, that is, a fiction which draws imaginatively on scientific knowledge
and speculation in its theme.
Example 4
Examples of imaginary thinking in economics do not abound but can be easily
construed. Reverting to our imaginary humans introduced in Chap. 1 (economic
human and creative human), suppose that you asked economic man “What do you
do for a living? He would answer: “I optimize. I accept reality as it is. Give me the
relevant information and I will compute the most profitable outcome that can be
achieved. I am both efficient and conformist.” If we asked the same question to
creative man, he would answer: “I range widely and am determined, often in the face
of opposition and scorn. I notice, I remember, I see, and above all, I rearrange
existing ideas into new ideas with economic value. I am both creative and rebel.”
In a sense, economic man is a conservative, focused on the status quo and
maximizing benefits from the existing situation. Creative man, in contrast, is more
radical, excited by change and its prospects, rejecting the existing situation, with an
eye to the future and the profits that can be gained from new products or new
processes or new forms of organization.

3.2.4 Critical Thinking

Critical thinking also has a role in relation to the search for new ideas. It is generally
agreed that Socrates was a pioneer of critical thinking. His method of questioning is
often referred to as ‘Socratic method’ and is the best known critical thinking teaching
strategy. Confused meanings, inadequate evidence, or self-contradictory beliefs
often lurked beneath smooth but largely empty rhetoric. In his mode of questioning,
Socrates highlighted the need in thinking for clarity and logical consistency.2
Socrates’ practice was followed by Plato (who recorded Socrates’ thought),
Aristotle, and the Greek sceptics, all of whom emphasized that things are often

2
The word ‘critical’ derives etymologically from two Greek roots: ‘kriticos’ (meaning discerning
judgment) and ‘kriterion’ (meaning standards). Consequently, ‘critical thinking’ entails the devel-
opment of ‘discerning judgment based on standards.’
3.2 Creative Thinking 55

very different from what they appear to be and that only the trained mind is prepared
to see through the way things look to us on the surface (delusive appearances) to the
way they really are beneath the surface (the deeper realities of life).
Critical thinking involves careful analysis and judgment of a given approach to
deal with an issue in order to determine both merits and faults of the approach. This
is the loosest possible definition of critical thinking. Critical thinking has potential to
engender new ideas especially when trying to improve inadequate or deficient
aspects of the approach.
Example 5
As an illustration, consider a solution of the pollution problem based on a carbon tax.
The whole purpose of a carbon tax is to force economic agents (both producers and
consumers) to take into account their negative impact on the natural environment.
The expected outcomes from a carbon tax are that the tax will (a) encourage the big
polluters to pollute less; and (b) drive the technological innovations that will be
energy-efficient and cost-reducing. To gain an understanding of the effects of the
introduction of a carbon tax economists use the familiar supply and demand model.
The merit of this model lies in the clear conclusions emerging from its application. It
can be easily shown that a carbon tax will increase the equilibrium price of electricity
and reduce the equilibrium quantity of pollution in comparison to a no-tax initial
situation.
Let us apply critical thinking. Beyond any doubt, the supply and demand model is
useful. However, this model confirms expected outcome (a) but remains silent about
expected outcome (b). The supply and demand model is not fully adequate and has
to be supplemented because it is unable to deal with induced technological innova-
tions. In 1932, Nobel Prize winner Sir John R. Hicks introduced the model of
induced innovation, which states that changes in relative input prices should lead
to innovations that reduce the need for the relatively expensive input. For example, if
the relative price of coal in terms of clean energy goes up due to a carbon tax,
innovations that reduce the need for coal should happen.

3.2.5 Concluding Remarks on Creative Thinking

Three brief remarks are in order.


• First, creative thinking is already in a new phase that combines the preceding
ways of thinking taking advantage of computers, data mining, and Artificial
Intelligence (AI). For example, creative thinking is currently facilitated by tech-
nologies allowing new ways of finding and combining information through data
searching. Creative thinking can also be facilitated by intelligent algorithms.3

3
Intelligent algorithms use masses of data to form associations made possible by clever statistical
methods.
56 3 Creativity and Intellectual Propery

• Second, innovators may perform creative thinking either in isolation or in col-


laborative groups. One of the reasons for the increasing importance of collabo-
rative networks is the intrinsic limitations of our cognitive architecture.
Encyclopaedic knowledge of any discipline such as, for example, mathematics,
economics or biology, is a thing of the past.
• Finally, the readers interested in expanding their knowledge on creative thinking
in the context of business innovation will benefit by consulting Think, Play,
Do. Technology, Innovation, and Organization by Dodgson et al. (2005).

3.3 Intellectual Property

Ideas are knowledge, and knowledge is an economic resource. Clearly, if knowledge


once created is freely appropriable by others we have a typical free-rider problem
that severely limits the incentive to create new ideas. Since the rewards for innova-
tive activity are reduced by imitation, governments intervene to give innovators
specific protection. The term intellectual property relates to intangible property
associated with new ideas. Generally speaking, this kind of property is materialized
by means of patents, copyrights, trade secrets, and trademarks.

3.3.1 Patents

Patents give innovators the exclusive right to their respective new ideas (products,
processes, substances or designs) for a limited time only. Governments grant
innovators property rights on their innovations in exchange for making a public
disclosure of their new ideas. Note carefully that a patent does not give a patent
holder an automatic right to commercializing her innovation. For example, it is legal
to patent the formula for a new drug in the USA but it is not legal to sell the drug
without Food and Drug Administration (FDA) approval.

3.3.1.1 First Patent System: Venice 1474

One might be inclined to think that patents are relatively new instruments for
protecting innovations. However, this is not true. In 1474 a patent system was
formally introduced in the Republic of Venice. It is interesting to mention that the
rationale for the patent system contains much of the insight present in the current
patent laws. As pointed out by the author of The Economics of the Patent System,
In 1474 (. . .) a formal patent code was promulgated. Its preamble states:
3.3 Intellectual Property 57

“We have among us men of great genius, apt to invent and discover ingenious devices . . .
Now, if provisions were made for the work and devices discovered by such persons, so that
others who may see them could not build them and take the inventor’s honour away, more
men would then apply their genius, would discover, and would build devices of great utility
to our commonwealth.”

The code specified that the subject of invention had to be proven workable and useful, if only
by means of a model. (. . .) Also, no imitation was permitted for 10 years without express
permission from the inventor. (Kaufer 1989, pp. 5–6)

The pioneering approach of Venice to protecting the production of new ideas was
followed gradually in Europe. For example, in 1624 England passed the famous
patent law entitled Statute of Monopolies.4
The United States has always been a leading country in the context of intellectual
property. The Constitution of the United States was signed on 17 September 1787 by
the delegates to the Constitutional Convention in Philadelphia. According to the US
Constitution (1787) Article 1, Section 8, Clause 8: “The Congress shall have the
power . . . to promote the progress of science and the useful arts by securing to
authors and inventors the exclusive rights to their respective writings and discover-
ies.” The first USA Patent Act, written by Thomas Jefferson, was passed by congress
in 1790. Congress has revised this Act several times.

3.3.1.2 Discoveries and Inventions

A glance at the preamble of the formal patent code promulgated in Venice in 1474
suggests that both inventions and discoveries can be patented. Today we know that
there is a clear difference between “invention” and “discovery.” Moreover, we know
that discoveries are not patentable.
By definition, an invention creates or makes or constructs something new. The
notion of invention is inextricably linked to a new idea. For example, Thomas Alva
Edison invented the light bulb (new idea) and patented his invention in 1879. A
discovery reveals or uncovers something that already exists or has existed. For
example, Galileo discovered (but obviously did not invent) the moons around
Jupiter. It should be clear that the kind of novelty associated with inventions is
markedly different from that of discoveries.

3.3.1.3 Patentability Guidelines

Not every new idea is patentable. There is a dichotomy which is useful for organiz-
ing thinking about patentability guidelines. The defining characteristic of a product
of nature (or natural item) is that the existence of the item is independent of human
beings. For example, eagles, wombats, Jupiter’s moon Io, rain, and gravity exist

4
The system of granting patents in the Australian colonies was based upon this law.
58 3 Creativity and Intellectual Propery

independently of human beings. Products of human ingenuity (or artificial items) are
created by human beings, and therefore, their existence depends on humans.
Patent laws specify the permissible categories of patentable subject matter.
Products of nature are not patentable. Products of human ingenuity can be patented.
Theoretical ideas (e.g. quantum theory, Big Bang theory, and laws of nature) are
products of human ingenuity but they are not patentable.

3.3.1.4 Eligibility Conditions

A new idea5 is a product of human ingenuity and is patent-eligible if it satisfies the


following three conditions.
Non-obviousness: The ‘concept’ is not obvious to a person trained in the
relevant field and has not been disclosed or created
previously.
Usefulness: The ‘concept’ has some practical use in the sense that it
must have more than hypothetical use.
Enabling description: The ‘concept’ is described in enough detail to allow others
skilled in the field to make the innovation.
To obtain a patent the applicant must show that the innovation meets these three
conditions. They are necessary but not sufficient conditions. The patent authority
(e.g. United States Patent and Trade Mark Office (USPTO) or IP Australia) decides
whether to grant the patent or not.

3.3.1.5 Bogus Patents

It is the job of the bodies that grant patents to weed out non-genuine innovations. A
patent is said to be bogus if it does not entail any genuine innovation. If patents are
too easy to obtain they may stifle innovation more than promote it.
Example 6
Suppose that a drug company has a patent on the formula for the “elixir of life” and
the dose is contained in a capsule. Before the patent expires the same company
applies for a new patent on the “elixir of life” claiming that the new innovation
involves change in the dose from a capsule to a tablet while keeping the formula for
the “elixir of life” intact. If the application is successful we are in the presence of a
bogus patent.

Note 1 Patent exclusion based on ethics

5
In patent law ‘new idea’ is referred to as ‘concept.’
3.3 Intellectual Property 59

Some countries use ethics to justify the patent exclusion. Australia, Canada, and
the USA do not accept ethical grounds for exclusion. For example, the USPTO
granted monopoly rights to a computer matching technology that could help people
custom-design babies through IVF. The technology allows couples to predict the
likely characteristics of their children such as, for example, eye colour. The tech-
nology could also allow prospective parents to screen sperm or egg donors for
particular genetic dispositions. This could lead to people specifying height, eye
colour, muscle development and personal traits in selecting their children.6

3.3.1.6 Licensing

Patent holders sometimes sell some or all of their patent rights to others. They
licence patent rights in return for a percentage of profits or loyalties. An exclusive
license is a license that excludes granting of the licensing to anyone else by the patent
holder. Non-exclusive licenses are less profitable to the licensee because the license
cannot prevent others from using or selling an innovation.

3.3.1.7 Expiring Patents

Patents do not last forever. Patents rights are typically enforceable for a period of
twenty 20 years counted from the filing date of the patent application. This is the case
in Australia and the United States. During the life of the patent the patent holder is a
monopolist and if the patent is successful the innovator is likely to make abnormal
profits. But when the patent runs out, the abnormal profits encourage new firms to
enter the market. Typically, when the patent expires the market switches from being
monopolistic to being more competitive.
Example 7
Consider the market for pharmaceutical drugs. Suppose that a company files a patent
for a new drug and obtain the patent after one year. The company cannot sell the drug
until it has FDA approval. Suppose in addition that the company passes the FDA
barrier in one’s year time. At this point, we have a government-created monopoly
allowed to sell the drug for 18 years. When the patent runs out other companies are
entitled to produce and sell the same drug which receives the name “generic drug”,
and it is chemically identical to the proprietary drug whose patent has expired. The
market switches from monopoly to oligopoly because new firms will be selling the
same drug. One would expect a decrease in the price of the original drug and a
reduction in abnormal profits.7

6
See Ross (2013).
7
The original innovator does not lose all its market power because some consumers will remain
loyal to the former monopolist’s brand-name drug. Consumers may also be concerned that the
generic drugs are not identical with the drug they have been using for a long time.
60 3 Creativity and Intellectual Propery

3.3.1.8 Enforcing Patent Rights

The use of an idea protected by a patent without authorization from the patent holder
is called patent infringement. Examples of patent infringements abound. Enforcing
patent rights is plagued with uncertainties as the following examples illustrate.
Example 8
Eli Whitney invented the cotton gin, a very efficient and very simple machine to
separate the seeds out of cotton. Whitney applied for a patent and received one in
1794. He found a financial partner to put up the money to start a business to produce
the corresponding machines (Whitney’s partner resembles what nowadays is called
‘angel investor’). Cotton planters found it easy to copy Whitney’s machine. Whitney
sued in court for patent infringements. The states of Georgia, South Carolina, North
Carolina, and Tennessee agreed to pay a lump sum to Whiney to purchase the rights
to the cotton gin. The amount paid was just enough to recoup the expenses of
Whitney and his partner.
Example 9
George Baldwin Selden invented a version of the automobile. Selden was granted a
patent for a “horseless self-propelled carriage” in the United States. Selden tried to
force all car manufacturers (including Henry Ford) to pay royalties to him. He argued
that his patent covered all self-propelled, gasoline-powered vehicles and sued the car
manufacturers for patent infringement. Henry Ford and four other car makers
resolved to contest the patent infringement suit filed by Selden. Henry Ford argued
that the concept of “horseless self-propelled carriage” was too vague to be patentable
and won the legal fight in January 1911.

3.3.1.9 Portfolio of Patents and Patent Trolls

Some companies extend and pyramid the market power derived from their patents by
accumulating a massive portfolio of patents. When du Pont scientists invented nylon,
(. . .) they did not rest content with patenting the basic super polymer composition and
process of producing it. They systematically investigated the whole range of molecular
variations with property similar to nylon, blanketing their findings with hundreds of patent
applications to prevent other firms from developing an effective substitute. Similar tactics
have been pursued by du Pont and many other corporations in such fields as cellophane,
plastics, synthetic leather, synthetic rubber, photo supplies, radio, television, shoe machin-
ery, data processing equipment, electric lamps, telephone equipment, copying processes, and
can closing machinery, to name just a few. When one company comes to dominate a field by
accumulating a massive patent portfolio, it not only prevents rivals from operating except on
its acquiescence, but also becomes the logical buyer for related new concepts patented by
independent inventors, and so at some point the process of patent accumulation may take on
a “snowball effect.” (Scherer 1970, 391)

Patent portfolios may contain sleeping patents. These are patents that, once
obtained, are “put to sleep” and not used. Companies that amass huge patent portfolios
and sue innovative firms for alleged infringements are known as patent trolls.
3.3 Intellectual Property 61

3.3.2 Copyrights

Copyright protects original works of authorship (e.g. books, musical composition,


photographs, and dramatic work). Copyrights are economic rights. For example, an
innovator with a copyright on a song can make money from her original song by
selling her own work or licensing other people to copy and market the work.

3.3.2.1 Term of a Copyright

A natural question to ask is how long does a copyright last? As a rule, copyright
protection lasts for the life of the author plus an additional 70 years. The scope of
copyright in Australia is defined in the Australian Copyright Act 1968 (as amended).
Until 2004, copyright in Australia was based on the “plus 50” law which restricts
works until 50 years after the author’s death. In 2004 this was changed to a “plus 70”
law in line with the USA and European Union, but this change was not made
retroactive.

3.3.2.2 Smiley Face: A Sad Lesson

In 1963 two companies were about to be merged. The atmosphere in one of them
was tense because employees believed that they could lose their jobs and morale was
very low. The management commissioned a marketing man named Harvey R. Hall
to produce something ingenious to boost morale and make the whole merger process
more tolerable for everyone.
Ball had a brilliant new idea. He created a big yellow dot with a pair of black
ovals for eyes and a semicircle for a mouth: It was an instant success. ‘Smiley face’
buttons, T-shirts and stickers were soon selling in their millions around the world.
You might think that Ball became an instant millionaire. Not at all. He made a tragic
blunder. He did not protect his new idea by a copyright and only received his original
fee of $45.00 from the company.

3.3.2.3 Warning

A copyright holder is entitled to prevent other people from making unauthorized


copies or unauthorized use of the original works. It should be emphasized that
copyrights protect original works but not the insights and principles described by
those works.
Example 10
Suppose that an innovator publishes a paper describing a new car alarm and
copyrights the paper but she does not patent the car alarm. This means that it is
illegal to make a copy of the paper without her authorization, but someone can
62 3 Creativity and Intellectual Propery

reproduce the design of the car alarm without fear for legal penalties. Clearly, in this
case copyrights do not provide the innovator with a great deal of protection
concerning her new ideas.

3.3.2.4 Copyright Infringements

A copyright holder is entitled to prevent other people from making unauthorized


copies of her creation. Penalties for copyright infringement can be substantial. For
example, in 1976 George Harrison (the former Beatle) was ordered to pay US
$587,000 for taking the melody to his song “My Sweet Lord” from the 1963 hit
“He’s So Fine” created by Ronnie Mack.
Technologies that enable illegal uses of material subject to copyright tend to be
detrimental to copyright holders. For example, the Internet enables copy and trans-
mission, illegally, of music and movies. Such Internet piracy is pervasive and
companies with copyrighted products sue and seek compensation from those who
infringe copyright, particularly the facilitators of piracy.
Technology firms that distribute software which lets users share files online with
others are called peer-to-peer (P2P) firms. Sometimes the content exchanged by the
users of the software violates copyrights of music companies or movies companies.
P2P firms are liable for copyright infringements if they induce their customers to
violate copyright.

3.3.2.5 Copyrights and Moral Rights

The rights of attribution of authorship (to be named in connection with one’s work)
and the right of integrity of authorship (the right of an author to object to treatment of
a work that demeans the author’ reputation) are called moral rights. Copyrights are
separate and distinct from moral rights. Moral rights remain with the author even
though she may have transferred copyright in the work concerned to another person,
natural or juridical such as, for example, a publishing company.

3.3.3 Trade Secrets

A trade secret is knowledge that the holder of the secret does not disclose to others.
The archetypal example is the Coca-Cola formula: the formula is not protected by a
patent, but guarded as a trade secret. It is interesting to note that no one has been able
to exactly reproduce the flavour of this product, despite its widespread availability
for many years. Additional examples of ideas protected by trade secrets include
metallurgical formulas, mechanical drawings, computer-chip designs, and software
used to find oil and gas.
3.3 Intellectual Property 63

Secrecy laws allow competitors to decipher each other’s secrets by legitimate


means such as reverse engineering or search on publicly available documents. Trade
secrets work well only when the information can be kept secret. This is certainly the
case of innovations that are extremely difficult to reverse engineer such as food
recipes.
Example 11
If a company creates and sells (but does not patent) a new type of motorbike alarm,
then another company can reverse engineer the motorbike alarm, discover the
design, and manufacture exactly the same alarm, without infringing the law.

3.3.4 Trade Secrets Thefts

If a trade secret is used without authorization from the trade secret holder, it is a theft.
The notion of “trade secret theft” is unusual because the owners of the trade secrets
are not deprived of the use of the ideas involved. Trade secrets thefts are deemed as
an act of economic espionage.
Example 12
In June 2013, the USA filed criminal charges against one of China’s biggest makers
of wind turbines and two senior executives at the company. The issue involved two
companies: Sinovel Wind Group and AMSC, a Massachusetts engineering firm. A
federal grand jury in the Western District of Wisconsin indicted Sinovel for trade
secret theft, criminal copyright infringement, and wire fraud. The indictment alleged
that Sinovel stole source code for software used to control wind turbines from
AMSC. Chinese wind turbine maker Sinovel Wind Group Co was convicted in
January 2018 that it stole trade secrets from AMSC, causing the Massachusetts-
based company to lose more than $800 million. In July 2018, a judge ruled that
Sinovel must pay $59 million for stealing trade secrets from wind technology firm,
American Superconductor Corp.
Cyber-attacks on companies to steal commercial secrets place pressure on gov-
ernments to respond either via law enforcement or diplomatic channels. Australia
condemns the cyber-enabled theft of intellectual property from any country.

3.3.5 Trademarks

Trademarks are legally protected symbols, logos, words or other distinguishing


features to identify products. By registering the trademark, the owner obtains the
exclusive right to that mark. The trademark excludes others from free riding on the
costs associated with maintaining the reputation of the quality of the product.
Owners of a trademark can resort to the courts to prevent others from using their
trademarks.
64 3 Creativity and Intellectual Propery

In Australia trademarks are registered according to the Trade Marks Act 1995.
The Australia Trade Mark Office evaluates whether the brand meets the require-
ments of the Act. The mark can be registered for an initial period of 10 years. In
principle, the trademark can be renewed ad infinitum.
By allowing identification of the unobservable characteristics of the products
trademarks play a central role in helping consumers to recognize “experience
products.” A product whose quality cannot be observed until after the product has
been consumed is termed experience product. For example, wine trademarks play an
important role in informing consumers about the quality of a wine.8

3.3.5.1 Trademarks and Packaging

The Australian Tobacco Plain Packaging Act 2011 prevents tobacco companies
using branding, logos, symbols, and other forms of advertising on cigarettes or
their packaging and enables the government to decide what will appear on the
package. A group of tobacco companies argued in the High Court that the plain
packaging legislation was invalid because it meant the government was acquiring
their intellectual property, but not on “just terms,” as required by the Constitution. In
particular, they argued that removing branding from cigarette packaging is equiva-
lent to stealing tobacco companies’ intellectual property rights. At the heart of the
case was the issue of whether laws preventing the use of trademarks on packaging
imply an acquisition of intellectual property. In August 2012, the High Court struck
down the challenge and the Australian government won.

3.4 Chapter Summary

• Dimension 1 (Creativity) encompasses different types of creative thinking that


can be used to engender new ideas. Diagram 3.1 puts together the four creative
thinking tools previously described. Although occasionally the classification
becomes blurred, it is useful to think about creative thinking as a collection of
distinct tools.
• Would-be innovators search for innovation opportunities. Then they carry out
thought experiments where conscious and subconscious energies mull over a

8
Products whose quality can be assessed before they are bought are called search products.
Examples of such products are basic foods and petrol.
3.4 Chapter Summary 65

Diagram 3.1 Different types of creative thinking

problem using creative thinking. If the creative act is materialized (Eureka!


moment), a new idea with economic value has been created.9 What comes next
is the protection of the new idea.
• The act of innovation typically generates intellectual property. Innovators want to
protect their new ideas with economic value. This is why the Background Model
involves a second dimension.
• Dimension 2 (Intellectual Property) encompasses different options to protect new
ideas with economic value. The protective tools of intellectual property can be
seen in Diagram 3.2. The options are not mutually exclusive. For example, a new
idea can be protected by both a trade secret and a trademark.
Where to now? It goes without saying that this chapter has introduced a significant
number of important concepts. You are now well on your way to becoming a
knowledgeable person regarding innovation as an economic activity. But we still
need to unravel Dimension 3 of the Background Model.

9
Eureka is the reputed exclamation of the Greek genius Archimedes (287—212 BC) when he
discovered the amount of alloy in the crown of the king of Syracuse. Archimedes was not only a
great mathematician and physicist but also a remarkable inventor.
66 3 Creativity and Intellectual Propery

Diagram 3.2 Four options for protecting new ideas

Appendices

Appendix E: Further Aspects on Creative Thinking

This appendix supplements the general points made in Chap. 3 about creative
thinking and points out that the notion of sudden and rapid breakthroughs is
unrealistic.

Logical Inference and Mathematics

Logical inference includes both formal logic and mathematics. Mathematical rea-
soning is essentially logical in character but mathematics necessitates the introduc-
tion of a concept foreign to formal logic: the concept of ‘infinity’ (the infinitely large
and the infinitely continuous). Examples of logical inference in economics abound.
It is quite common to use mathematics to prove ‘if-then’ propositions. We can
think of the ‘if’ part of the proposition as the point of departure of the reasoning and
the ‘then’ part as a destination. Mathematics is a quick means of transportation from
a set of assumptions (point of departure) to a set of conclusions (destination). The
mathematical approach has remarkable advantages, including (a) the use of mathe-
matics forces the analyst to define terms precisely, and (b) the mathematical lan-
guage is more precise and concise than the verbal language.
Appendices 67

The precise statement of the rule ”MR ¼ MC“ mentioned in Example 1 of


Chap. 3 is as follows. If the profit function is differentiable and gives rise to an
inverted U profit curve, profit-maximization implies with logical compulsion that
marginal revenue must be equal to marginal cost, i.e. MR ¼ MC.
Generally speaking, symbols are more convenient to use in the process of logical
inference (that is, in the actual proof that B logically follows from A) than words.
However, if one is not interested in the process of deduction and knows that the
conclusions follow from the assumptions (because someone else has proven that),
then it is sufficient to know that if A is true, then B is true as well.

Lateral Thinking and Schizophrenic Thinking

Lateral thinking tends to diverge from the strict rules of logical inference. However,
it should be emphasized that lateral thinking is not based on random associations of
existing ideas to generate new ideas. Lateral thinking uses reasoning in a
fundamental way.
Schizophrenic thinking consists of uncontrolled random associations. One of the
most characteristic features of schizophrenia is the “butterfly mind” which moves
swiftly from concept to concept. The essential difference between lateral thinking
and schizophrenic thinking is that with lateral thinking the process is strictly
controlled by the mind. (de Bono 1968, p. 18).

Critical Thinking and Previous Knowledge

A point implicit in our description of critical thinking should be made explicit.


Critical thinking without a sound knowledge of the subject matter tends to produce
wishful thinking combined with razzmatazz. Critical thinking cannot be efficiently
accomplished divorced from knowledge. To perform critical thinking is necessary to
possess a deep knowledge of the subject matter. An example suffices to illustrate this
point.
Consider the view of some die-hard environmentalists who disregard the eco-
nomic dimension of the problem. They claim that clean air and clean water are
fundamental human rights that should not be debased by considering them in
economic terms. How can you put a price on clean air and clean water? The
environment is so important that we should protect it as much as possible, regardless
of the cost. We should eliminate all pollution. This approach is untenable because it
completely ignores the existing knowledge about the pollution problem. The eco-
nomic approach to pollution shows that the elimination of all pollution is impossible.
Students cannot learn to be critical thinkers until they have actually learned
something to think about. For example, you cannot learn to be a critical thinker in
accounting if you do not have a basic knowledge of the accounting principles. In a
nutshell, critical thinking cannot be cultivated independent of the acquisition of
knowledge.
68 3 Creativity and Intellectual Propery

Sudden and Rapid Breakthroughs?

The history of innovation shows that the development of new ideas conducive to
General Purpose Technologies (GPTs) such as, for example, steam power, electric
power, internal combustion engine, and atomic energy, requires a long period before
their effects are realized. This point was forcibly made by Simon Kuznets
(1901–1985).
Simon Kuznets was awarded the 1971 Nobel Prize in economics for his contri-
butions to both the systematic statistical measurement of economic phenomena and
economic growth, including the relationship between technological progress and
population growth. Specifically, Kuznets’s view was that high population growth
spurs innovation because it increases the number of potential innovators. In partic-
ular, Kuznets observed that the concentration of innovation occurs in cities and
argued that population and research productivity change in the same direction
because higher population allows knowledge spillovers.
The long periods of development periods following the gestation of big new ideas
is best described by Kuznets:
It took about a century for steam power to evolve from the revolutionary breakthrough in the
1770’s to the final domination of ocean transportation and the competition of a basic railroad
network in the economically developed countries in the third quarter of the nineteenth
century. It has taken almost as long for electric power to move from the power stations of
the 1880s into households in recent decades. It has taken the internal combustion engine in
cars over half a century to evolve from a useful capital good on U.S. farms at the beginning
of World War I to a mass consumption durable good affecting residential housing and life in
general well after World War II. One may speculate on the time it will take before atomic
energy works its way through successive developments to tap its full potentials –not clear
even today, over a quarter of a century since its first major application for war purposes. The
long periods of developments following the gestation are particularly relevant to the
consideration of the [human and institutional] adjustments to be discussed in the next
section. These adjustments partly explain the long development periods and can be under-
stood only if we abandon the romantic notion of sudden and rapid breakthroughs that
produce major results within a few years. (Kuznets 1974, pp. 194–195)

While Kuznets did not deny the importance of pure theory, he devoted his
intellectual efforts to the empirical research for laws or generalizations based on
historical-statistical material. The common thread of his research agenda was the
search for economic laws about long-run economic change based on empirical facts.
Or, to put it differently, Kuznets always had in mind Marshall’s dictum: “It is the
business of economics, as almost every other science, to collect facts, to arrange and
interpret them, and draw inferences from them.”
We mention, in passing, that one of the insights Kuznets drew from his empirical
research was the existence of a regularity concerning the behaviour of a sector
influenced by a major innovation: rapid sectoral growth (often accompanied by a
Appendices 69

decline in the price of its output) and gradual generation of forces leading to a
deceleration in the rate of growth of the sector in question.10

Edison’s Rule

In general, Edison’s immortal inspiration-perspiration rule (namely: “Genius is one


percent of inspiration and ninety nine per cent of perspiration”) applies to the
innovation process. Examples abound: the photocopier, Harry Potter, and Atlassian
are a few.

The Photocopier

The idea of the photocopier is due to Chester Carlson whose work in the patent
division of a company in the 1930s induced him to explore a cheaper and faster way
to make copies of drawings and documents. He was concerned about the difficulty of
copying documents efficiently. For several years he spent a significant proportion of
his spare time thinking of the problem and browsing in potentially relevant scientific
literature. Eventually, Carlson conceived the idea of xerography in 1938. He began
to design a photocopy machine by combining elements of electrostatics with pho-
toconductivity. In October 1938 he construed a machine that was able to photocopy:
“10-22-38 Astoria”. This is the precise date (October 22, 1938) and place (Astoria)
where the achievement was attained. After patenting his ideas between 1940 and
1944, Carlson began to approach companies to finance research on a photocopier for
commercial application. The first commercial photocopier Xerox 914 was intro-
duced in 1959. In brief, it took more than 20 years between the time the new idea was
conceived and the introduction of the Xerox 914.

Harry Potter

Even when the new idea occurs as a flash of inspiration the innovation process tends
to be very time consuming. The idea of Harry Potter came to J. K. Rowling during a
train journey between Manchester and Clapham Junction:
All of a sudden the idea for Harry just appeared in my mind’s eye. I can’t tell you why, or
what triggered it. But I saw the idea of Harry and the wizard school plainly. I suddenly had
this basic idea of a boy who didn’t know who he was, who didn’t know he was a wizard
until he got his invitation to wizard school. I have never been so excited by an idea. (Smith
2002, p. 107)

10
See Pol and Carroll (2004).
70 3 Creativity and Intellectual Propery

However, it took 7 years from the moment that Harry Potter appeared in
Rowling’s mind to the publication of the first book Harry Potter and the Philoso-
pher’s Stone.

Atlassian

Another example illustrating the long period of gestation associated with the creation
of new products is Atlassian. This Australian software company developed products
for software developers, project managers, and content management. It is best
known for its issue tracking application, Jira, and its team collaboration and wiki
product, Confluence. The company’s success in 2016 was the culmination of
13 years of hard work. The 2016 valuation made the founders of Atlassian (Mike
Cannon-Brookes and Scott Farquhar) among the richest Australian people. On paper
each were worth $AU2.56 billion, based on their respective 37% stake in the
technology company.11

Appendix F: Further Aspects on Intellectual Property

Patents and Partial Excludability

The information contained in a patent application can be used by other innovators to


learn the relevant features of the patented innovation and use that knowledge in their
innovation projects.12 To see this, consider a hypothetical example. Suppose that
innovator A has a patented design for a special type of neck pillows (say neck
pillows type A). No one can use the patented design to make neck pillows type A
without the agreement of innovator A. However, innovator B is free to spend time
studying the patent application for the neck pillow type A and learn knowledge that
helps in the design of a slightly different neck pillow (say neck pillow type B). This
means that innovator A cannot appropriate the totality of the benefits emerging from
the innovation neck pillow type A. Some of the benefits are captured by innovator B
for free.
In general, patent protection for an innovation does not guaranteed full exclud-
ability of the benefits derived from the innovation. With their typical verbal flair,
economists say that patented products are “at least partially excludable.”

11
The Initial Public Offering (IPO) of Atlassian in 2016 threw up a market valuation of US$5.74
billion ($AU8 billion). Atlassian’s successful debut on the Nasdaq made it the most successful
Australian listing on a US stock exchange.
12
Studying the enabling description of a patent to find out “what makes the product work” is an
example of reverse engineering.
Appendices 71

Knowledge Spillovers

An economic resource is appropriable when economic agents (e.g. producers or


innovators) can capture its full economic value. Examples of appropriable resources
are land, coal, gas, and oil. Generally speaking, private ideas are only partially
appropriable.
When private ideas are captured by individuals who have paid nothing toward
their cost it is said that knowledge spillovers occur. In addition to reverse engineer-
ing, labour mobility and interpersonal networks are important sources of knowledge
spillovers.

Externalities

Some economic activities have collateral effects on the individuals who are not
directly involved in those economic activities. These collateral effects are termed
externalities. The side effects can be positive or negative. Moreover, externalities are
classified on the basis of the means of transmission.
An externality is said to be pecuniary if the collateral effect emerging from the
economic activity is transmitted through the market. The typical case is where
investment in one sector enlarges the size of the market for output in other sectors.
For example, investment in the fast food sector has beneficial effects in other sectors
such as paper products and furniture, the former needed to package fast food, the
latter for persons to sit on while waiting for or eating fast food.
Technological externalities arise when economic activities bestow benefits
(or impose costs) that are not paid for in the market place. For example, innovation
as an economic activity is an important source of positive technological externalities
(think of knowledge spiilovers emerging from business innovation).

Software Protection

The intellectual property of software is protected by either patents or copyrights or


trade secrets. A software patent outlaws any other software that attains the same
effect irrespective of how the end result is achieved. A software copyright prohibits
plagiarizing the software code, but allows competitors to design a different code
attaining the same end. The supercomputer Watson lives in the “cloud.” As a result,
it is unavailable to those who might wish to reverse-engineer it. The computational
nitty-gritty of Watson’s modus operandi remains IBM’s trade secret.
72 3 Creativity and Intellectual Propery

Protecting Magic Tricks: “Shadows”

Magic tricks are guarded as trade secrets. Typically, magicians do not tell people
how a trick is done. Profitable magic can only be performed by never giving away
how it works. If the secret of the trick is revealed, it is unlikely that the original
owner of the trick can enjoy financial gain. Magicians who reveal tricks are often
brought into line by stinging rebuke of public shaming and shunning from their own
communities.
Magic tricks cannot be copyrighted. But the expression of the idea as a dramatic
work or performance can be. Trying to protect tricks from thieves by enshrining their
copyright inside performances goes back to Houdini, who used pantomimes in an
effort to stave off imitators by registering the works with the US copyright office.
There is one magic trick that remains a mystery and is considered the holy grail of
magic. It is a visual trick –called “Shadows” – created by the American magician
Raymond Joseph Teller: “Shadows essentially consists of a spotlight trained on a
bud vase containing a rose. The light falls in such a manner that the shadow of the
real rose is projected onto a white screen positioned some distance behind it. Teller
then enters the otherwise still scene with a large knife and proceeds to use the knife
to dramatically sever the leaves and petals of the rose’s shadow on the screen slowly,
one-by-one, whereupon the corresponding leaves of the real rose sitting in the vase
fall to the ground, breaking from the stem at exactly the point where Teller cut the
shadow projected on the screen behind it.” Teller registered Shadows with the
U.S. Copyright Office in 1983. Teller’s partner, Penn Jillette, has publicly stated:
“No one knows how Shadows is done, and no one will ever figure it out.”
In 2010, Teller discovered that there was someone (Gerard Dogge of Belgium) on
YouTube performing his trick, under the name of “The Rose and Her Shadow,”
offering to sell its secret to anyone who wanted it for $US3,050. Teller tried to
convince Dogge not to sell his signature trick. Private negotiations failed, and Teller
continued with legal action.
US District judge James Mahan (Nevada federal court) found that “Teller’s
“Shadows” and Dogge’s “The Rose and Her Shadow” are nearly identical twins.”
The defendant challenged the validity of the registration as a pantomime drama, but
the judge waived such an objection off:
“While Dogge is correct that magic tricks are not copyrightable, this does not mean that
Shadows is not subject to copyright protection,” writes Judge James Mahan in his ruling.
“Indeed, federal law directly holds ‘dramatic works’ as well as ‘pantomimes’ are subject to
copyright protection, granting owners exclusive public performance rights. The mere fact
that a dramatic work or pantomime includes a magic trick, or even that a particular illusion is
its central feature does not render it devoid of copyright protection.”

Dogge next tried to argue that in Penn’s pronouncement that “no one will ever
figure it out” the statement was a challenge and an invitation for others to copy. But
the judge read what Penn intended to say and stated: “This statement merely
provokes others to unearth the secret, not perform the work.”
Teller won a ruling from copyright infringement of his “Shadows.”
Selected References 73

Selected References

de Bono E (1967) The use of lateral thinking. Jonathan Cape, London


de Bono E (1968) New think: the use of lateral thinking in the generation of new ideas. Basic
Books, New York
Dodgson M, Gann D, Salter A (2005) Think, play, do. technology, innovation, and organization.
Oxford University Press, Oxford
Doyle AC (2014) “A scandal in bohemia,” the adventures of sherlock holmes. Atlantic Publishing.
First published in, Hertfordshire, p 1892
Hicks JR (1932) The theory of wages. Macmillan, London
Kaufer E (1989) The economics of the patent system. Harwood Academic Publishers, Chur
Kuznets S (1974) Population, capital, and growth. Selected essays. Heinemann Educational,
London
Pol E, Carroll P (2004) Reviving and assessing the kuznets law of innovation. Econ Innov New
Technol 13:127–140
Ross J (2013) Patent for ‘custom-designed’ IVF babies sparks ethical concerns in the US,
Australian, 04 October
Scherer FM (1970) Industrial market structure and economic performance. Rand McNally, Chicago
Smith S (2002) J.K. Rowling: a biography. Arrow, London
Chapter 4
Innovation Environment

Contents
4.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76
4.2 Innovation Infrastructure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77
4.3 Clusters . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77
4.3.1 Anatomy of a Cluster . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78
4.3.1.1 Resource Endowments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78
4.3.1.2 Home Demand . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79
4.3.1.3 Related and Supporting Industries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79
4.3.1.4 Context for Local Competition . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79
4.3.1.5 Government Factor . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 80
4.3.1.6 Chance Events . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 80
4.3.2 Linkages Between Integral Parts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 80
4.4 Competitive Advantage: Domestic and International . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81
4.4.1 T-entrepreneurs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81
4.5 Venture Capital . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81
4.5.1 Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82
4.5.2 Innovation Life Cycle . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82
4.5.3 Filing the Financial Void . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83
4.5.4 Pattern of Behaviour of Venture Capitalists . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84
4.5.5 Profile of the Ideal Innovator . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84
4.5.6 Venture Capital Market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 85
4.5.7 Angel Investors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 85
4.6 Chapter Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86
Appendix G: Miscellaneous Points on the Innovation Environment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89
Incentives Regime . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89
2015 Australian Innovation Agenda: Generalities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89
2015 Australian Innovation Agenda: Criticisms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90
Venture Capitalist-Innovator Relationship . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 91
Principal-Agent Problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 91
Innovators Behaving Badly . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92
Avoiding Principal-Agent Problems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92
Selected References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92

© Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. 2020 75


J. E. Fernandez-Pol, C. Harvie, Understanding the Creative Economy and the Future
of Employment, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-1652-8_4
76 4 Innovation Environment

Concise Preview
• This chapter explores the content of Dimensions 3 (Innovation Environment) of
the Background Model.
• The exploration of Dimension 3 enriches the Basic Model.
• Inside Dimension 3 we find an innovation infrastructure, clusters, and the rela-
tionship between them.
• Successful clusters lead to domestic competitive advantage.
• International competitive advantage requires the presence of additional attributes.
• This chapter describes a particularly important market in the area of innovation as
an economic activity (“hidden” in Dimension 3) namely: the venture capital
market.
• Appendix G contains miscellaneous points on the Innovation Environment.

4.1 Introduction

It should be clear that in a Creative Economy firms must gain and maintain
competitive advantage through innovation. But what is meant by ‘competitive
advantage’? Competitive advantage refers to the characteristics of an economic
entity (e.g. a firm or a nation) that allow it to outperform its rivals. Competitive
advantage is gained and maintained through continual change. When the concept of
competitive advantage is used in relation to a firm, analysts have in mind at least one
characteristic that allows a firm to generate greater sales or margins than its
competitors.
There are two sources of competitive advantages at the firm level. Cost advantage
refers to a firm’s ability to produce a product at a lower cost than its competitors.
Thus, the firm can sell its products at a lower price than its competitors or generate a
larger margin on sales. A differential advantage exists when a firm’s products differ
from its competitors or are perceived as better than a competitor’s products by
costumers. Differential advantage is typically gained by developing innovations.
In the real world, firms that are not able to innovate tend to slip behind.
To understand how the Creative Economy works we introduced the Basic Model
in Chap. 2. It would hardly be necessary to mention that in this model innovation
happens in a vacuum. The reason is not far to seek. The Basic Model completely
ignores the environment in which the two fundamental principles operate. There has
to be an innovation environment (Dimension 3 of the Background Model) conducive
to the creation of profitable new ideas.
The Creative Economy is like a delicate plant whose flourishing depends on the
appropriate surroundings and climate. For example, innovation is unlikely in a
society that is extremely traditional because the creation of new ideas requires
diversity and tolerance. This immediately raises the question: what is inside Dimen-
sion 3 (Innovation Environment)? The short answer is: innovation infrastructure,
clusters that allow firms to develop their competitive advantages, and the strength of
linkages between these two. This framework to characterize Dimension 3 is due to
Furman et al. (2002). Let us make this answer more precise.
4.3 Clusters 77

4.2 Innovation Infrastructure

Innovation infrastructure refers to the national circumstances which broadly affect


the production of profitable new ideas throughout the economy. Evidently, it is an
omnibus term encompassing a disparate collection of elements such as the political
situation, legal framework, general economic framework, technology distribution
power and incentive regime. These elements singly or jointly may encourage or
retard the production of profitable new ideas.
The empirical evidence supports the view that an appropriate innovation infra-
structure exists when the political situation is stable and predictable, the general
economic framework involves credible macro and microeconomic policies, property
rights are secure, Science and Technology institutions (e.g. universities) target
industry needs, and the incentives regime is materialized in government support
for innovation.
The notion of innovation infrastructure can be distilled into a working definition
based on the concept of ‘institutions.’ A terminological digression is necessary here.
‘Institution’ is a term with several meanings. One possible meaning of the notion of
institution refers to an organization for the promotion of a particular object (usually,
one for some public, education, charitable, or similar purpose). This interpretation of
the term ‘institution’ is often used in economics. Thus, a central bank (a public
authority that supervises other banks and financial firms, financial markets and the
payment system, and conducts monetary policy) is an institution. However, there is a
second sense in which the term ‘institutions’ is used in economics, namely: institu-
tions refer to the laws, regulations, and policies that affect material incentives to
invest in physical capital, human capital, and innovation. Examples of institutions
are patent and copyright laws, and Science and Technology (S&T) policy, and
mechanisms for supporting research and higher education.
The term innovation infrastructure can be characterized as the set of institutions
which broadly influences the production of profitable new ideas, where it is under-
stood that ‘institutions’ is used in the second sense highlighted previously.

4.3 Clusters

Geographical agglomeration is an important source of competitive advantage. This


point was forcibly made by Michael E. Porter in his book The Competitive Advan-
tage of Nations, first published in 1990. Michael Porter empirically shows how
clusters enable innovation, reduce transaction costs, ease the formation of new
business, and create collective assets such as associations between universities and
private firms.
Clusters are geographical agglomerations of companies within a particular field
of activity (e.g. Information Technology, health care, and renewable resources).
Clusters are capable of engendering a variety of positive feedbacks and knowledge
78 4 Innovation Environment

spillovers which individual firms enjoy due to the activities of the other firms in the
cluster. In particular, personal encounters for the exchange of technical information
tend to be easy, cheap, and quick within a cluster. Typical examples of clusters are
Silicon Valley and Hollywood.

4.3.1 Anatomy of a Cluster

The anatomy of a cluster is described by a conceptual model known as the Porter


Diamond. The model consists of a system with six (6) interconnected components
(four determinants of competitive advantage and two additional factors). We start by
describing the determinants of competitive advantage.

4.3.1.1 Resource Endowments

Resources can be classified into two broad categories: tangible resources


(e.g. factories) and intangible resources (e.g. knowledge). Intangible resources
such as ideas and human capital are the most significant ones for attaining and
sustaining competitive advantage. The modern economy has shifted from the brute
force of natural resources to the power of ideas and human capital.
Resource endowments refer to the match between resources and industry needs.
Normally, the availability of low cost and high quality resources allows firms to gain
and maintain competitive advantage. In particular high quality human capital (sci-
entific, technical, and managerial personnel) together with ample supply of venture
capital are essential elements for gaining competitive advantage.
Note 1 Resource strengths and innovation
Abundance of resources (e.g. land, water, fishing grounds, and infrastructure)
signals resource strengths. An unfavourable endowment of resources (e.g. harsh
climate, lack of domestic raw materials, high land costs, and inappropriate health
care system) implies resource disadvantages. As a general rule, innovations to
exploit resource strengths are less likely than innovations that overcome factor
disadvantages. The reason is that resource disadvantages tend to originate pressures
to innovate around them. In contrast, abundance of resources may not encourage
novelty-seeking behaviour. The case of Japanese firms clearly illustrates the positive
role of resource disadvantages in stimulating innovation:
The most obvious case of selective disadvantage is where local firms experience the high
absolute cost of a factor compared to foreign rivals. Japanese firms in a variety of industries,
for example, faced extremely high land costs and severe factor space constraints. To
circumvent these difficulties, they created just-in-time and other space-saving production
techniques that also dramatically reduced needed inventory. (Porter 1990, pp. 83–84)
4.3 Clusters 79

4.3.1.2 Home Demand

Demand conditions influence competitive advantage in subtle ways. For instance,


firms are likely to exhibit novelty-seeking behaviour where sophisticated and strin-
gent buyers induce domestic firms to meet high standards in terms of product quality
and service, rapid domestic demand leads to the more rapid adoption of new
technologies, and saturated markets create pressures to replace all products with
newer versions.

4.3.1.3 Related and Supporting Industries

Competitive advantage may grow out of close working relationships between


suppliers and producers. Regular interactions between them are important in the
innovation process. The interplay creates opportunities for information flows and
technical interchange. Suppliers help producers to discover new methods and pro-
ducers influence suppliers technical efforts. For example, Japanese machine tools
companies drew on capable local suppliers of numerical control units, motors, and
other components.

4.3.1.4 Context for Local Competition

The nature and intensity of local competition tend to influence novelty-seeking


behaviour. When competition (actual or potential) is vigorous, firms are forced to
become more efficient and more innovative.
Note 2 Potential competition
We already know that there is price and non-price competition. There are two
other types of economic competition: actual competition between established firms
and potential competition arising from the potential entry of firms outside the
industry. The importance of potential competition lies in the fact that the threat of
entry of new firms keeps established firms on their toes.
Example 1
It is the interconnections between determinants that generate competitive advantage.
The archetypal example is the Dutch flower cluster. A cold and wet climate is a
resource disadvantage. This selective disadvantage led to innovations in the glass
house growing techniques, new strength of flowers, energy conservation, etc. A
strong home demand was present in Holland for fresh flowers year-around. Suppliers
of glass houses contributed to upgrading. Local competition (actual and potential)
took place at the grower, auction, and marketer levels. The Dutch flower cluster
illustrates the central point, namely: the role of any determinant cannot be viewed in
isolation in the sense that the effect of any particular determinant on competitive
advantage also depends on the other determinants.
80 4 Innovation Environment

4.3.1.5 Government Factor

Government has a role to play as an influencer of the determinants of competitive


advantage. For example, investment in education influences resource endowments,
government purchases influences home demand, and competition policy influences
local competition. Government policy can also be influenced by each of the four
determinants. For example, a strong home demand for new drugs may induce the
introduction of new safety standards.
Governments can induce creativity, collaboration and business growth by
investing in collective assets such as concentrations of university research, post-
graduate students and innovative companies in a single campus.
Note 3 Wollongong Innovation Campus (Australia)
The Innovation Campus (iC) is led by the University of Wollongong (UOW) and
powered by a team committed to business innovation. The iC is a place designed for
creativity, collaboration and business growth. Specifically, the iC sits on land given
to the UOW by the New South Wales Government with the purpose of clustering the
best and brightest researchers, innovative companies and postgraduate students
across the country and around the world to produce new ideas with economic
value. The fields of interest of the Wollongong iC include Artificial Intelligence,
biotechnology, nanotechnology, and superconductors.

4.3.1.6 Chance Events

Sudden occurrences beyond the control of firms and (possibly) of governments may
affect competitive advantage. Chance events abound: surges of demand (e.g. a surge
in demand for environmental quality), political decisions by foreign governments
(e.g. establishment of barriers to international trade), random shocks (e.g. droughts,
epidemics, and terrorist attacks), and wars are a few examples.

4.3.2 Linkages Between Integral Parts

Linkages between the innovation infrastructure and the clusters constitute the final
ingredient of our discussion of Dimension 3. For example, research on human skin
colour carried out in universities (innovation infrastructure) is used by biotech
companies (cluster) to treat conditions affecting skin pigment. Cooperative Research
Centres (CRCs) in Australia and the USA were established with the specific inten-
tion of improving the links between the innovation infrastructure and industrial
clusters.
4.5 Venture Capital 81

4.4 Competitive Advantage: Domestic and International

It should be emphasized that each of the components (singly or jointly) may either
contribute to or detract from competitive advantage. A Porter Diamond is said to be
successful if the interplay of its components leads to novelty-seeking behaviour and
domestic competitive advantage.
When we open the economy to international trade, the existence of a successful
Porter Diamond does not guarantee international competitive advantage (e.g. export
success). The existence of domestic competitive advantage is necessary but not
sufficient for international competitive advantage.
Three additional attributes are required to attain international competitive advan-
tage. First, domestic competitive advantage must be valuable in other countries.
Second, domestic competitive advantage must be difficult to supersede, replicate or
nullify. Finally, profitable opportunities abroad are not necessarily obvious, and
therefore, there must exist individuals that respond to the opportunities for operating
beyond national boundaries.

4.4.1 T-entrepreneurs

Moving into international markets requires expenditure of time and money on


acquiring country-specific information, such as, for example, knowledge and con-
tacts. For lack of a better name, we call the entrepreneurs who see the globalization
of the world economy as an opportunity rather than an obstacle, transnational
entrepreneurs or T-entrepreneurs. The term T-entrepreneurs is used here in a
broad sense to include directors of international business operating in multinational
firms, export marketing managers working in medium sized firms, and individual
managers conducting internationally competitive small firms. These economic
agents have a sound understanding of the cultural and socio-economic characteristics
of the foreign countries in which they operate.
T-entrepreneurs use guiding principles such as, for example, world best practices
in their export efforts; outward foreign investment as a vehicle for market access and
development; and distribution networks to gain access to overseas markets.

4.5 Venture Capital

There are people who sell new ideas (innovators) and people who buy new ideas
(investors, often venture capitalists). The supply of new ideas as well as the demand
of new ideas plays a crucial role in the context of a Creative Economy. The market
for new ideas is conceptually located within the category of Resource Endowments.
An important part of this market revolves around venture capital. The present section
draws heavily on Zider (1998).
82 4 Innovation Environment

Venture capital is an equity-linked form of investment that implies higher risks


and returns than investing in the stock market. The venture capital market is a
complex topic with a number of concepts to fit together. The key to understand
this special market is the notion of ‘innovation life cycle.’ Before describing this
cycle, we need to pause for a moment to present important conceptual tools that have
been developed by economists. These tools are applicable in many different contexts
but we will focus attention to the innovation context.

4.5.1 Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard

Innovators have more information than bankers about the characteristics of their new
ideas. This asymmetry of information between the parties (innovators and bankers)
has two important implications. First, banks know that among the innovators some
are better risks than others but they do not know who are less risky due to lack of
information about the risk characteristics of the new ideas. It may happen that
bankers select the innovators who are most likely to produce bad outcomes. This
phenomenon is called adverse selection. Second, once the lending decision has been
made banks do not have the resources necessary to monitor the efforts of innovators.
Bankers are vulnerable to moral hazard in the sense that the innovator may devote
her energies to pursue goals inconsistent with the repayment of the loan such as, for
example, abandon the original new idea and use the loan to do curiosity driven
research with no economic value.

4.5.2 Innovation Life Cycle

All successful innovations have a life cycle that essentially involves four consecutive
phases:
① Idea Phase: An innovator has a new idea (e.g. a new technology) that requires
development.
② Infant Phase: A small firm is established to develop and commercialize the
new idea.
③ Adolescent Phase: The new product reaches the stage of commercialization
and the firm enters a period of growth.
④ Maturity Phase: The firm reaches both size and credibility, so that either is sold
to a bigger firm or goes into an ‘initial public offering’ (IPO).1

1
An IPO is the first time that the stock is offered to the public.
4.5 Venture Capital 83

Innovators face an important financial barrier when they try to move from the
Idea Phase to the Infant Phase. Access to early stage capital is crucial. Money is
needed to provide assets and working capital. But it will not be available because
innovators typically do not have hard assets to guarantee their financial
commitments –bankers will only finance a new business if they are able to secure
the debt against hard assets. In addition, banks are vulnerable to adverse selection
and moral hazard. In a nutshell, there is a financial void at the transitional point from
the Idea Phase to the Infant Phase.
Example 2
A case in point is an innovator who owns a patent on a drug and needs to
implement costly clinical trials to gain approval from the FDA.2 Typically, inno-
vators are not eligible borrowers. Bankers will not normally cater for the innova-
tor’s financial needs.

4.5.3 Filing the Financial Void

The fundamental issue is: how do innovators finance their innovative endeavours?
Venture capitalists (VCs) fill the financial void allowing young innovative firms to
receive the financing that they cannot obtain from the traditional financial system.
More precisely, VCs finance innovators by receiving a percentage of the equity of
the company in return for the requisite funding. Equity finance offers the important
advantage of having no interest charges.
Venture-backed firms tend to enjoy a good reputation because their business
plans have passed careful scrutiny by the VCs. This, in turn, means that venture-
backed firms are likely to attract interest from other investors such as investment
banks.
We do not know who can be considered as the first venture capitalist. What we do
know is that the first true venture capital firm was American Research and Devel-
opment, established in 1946 by Karl Compton (MIT president) and General Georges
F. Doriot (Professor at the Harvard Business School). This company made high-risk
investments in young and small firms that were based on the technology emerging
from the World War II.
Example 3
A real-life example of the innovation life cycle is the app created by former
Australian schoolboy Nick D’Aloisio. The content of the consecutive phases can
be succinctly described as follows.

2
An innovator can have a patent based on her research findings, but these findings are not always
supportable by evidence obtained from clinical trials. The innovator has to show that the clinical
trials yield positive results in order to pass the FDA barrier.
84 4 Innovation Environment

Idea phase: Nick created the Trimit application when he was 15 years old. He was
inspired to develop it after struggling with information overload while doing his
history homework. He saw the need for an app that would pull in summaries of
Internet searches of topics rather than the entire text of articles. Trimit could crunch
text content down into summaries of various lengths and scored good reviews in the
Apple App Store in early 2011.
Infant phase: It also attracted the attention of Hong Kong billionaire Li Kashing,
who seeded Nick with $US300,000 of venture capital. Nick revamped Trimit and
relaunched it as Summly in December 2011 and attracted further funding with
backers including Yoko Ono, Stephen Fry, Ashton Kutcher, and Wendi Murdoch
(former wife of Rupert Murdoch, the chief executive and chairman of News
Corporation).
Adolescent phase: Summly reached the stage of commercialization when it was
available for iPhone users through Apple’s App Store.
Maturity phase: Nick sold the new idea to Yahoo! and became one of the
youngest innovators and self-made millionaires on this planet (the acquisition was
thought to be worth $US30 million).

4.5.4 Pattern of Behaviour of Venture Capitalists

The VCs display a well-known pattern of behaviour. In fact, VCs invest in sectors
with high growth rates (such as, for example, biotechnology, information technol-
ogy, and renewable energy); avoid both the Idea phase and the Maturity phase; buy a
stake in an innovator’s new idea; nurture innovation for a relatively short period of
time; and exit at the end of the Adolescent phase. For their services, venture capital
firms receive a significant cut of any resulting capital gains.
During the Infant and Adolescent phases VCs provide general support for the
innovation project as a whole as well as financial and business support. The Infant
and the Adolescent phases constitute the venture stage.

4.5.5 Profile of the Ideal Innovator

The scarcest input a VC has is time, not capital. The challenge of the VCs is to
identify innovators who can advance new ideas (e.g. a new technology) to the
Maturity Phase where the company can be sold to a bigger corporation or taken to
an IPO. VCs face a difficult task because they have to evaluate risks not only about
the new ideas but also about the personal characteristics of the innovator.
4.5 Venture Capital 85

Ideally, an innovator should display several attributes, including but not limited
to, the innovator has a good reputation and is well qualified in an area of high growth
(e.g. renewable energy sector); the innovator tells a compelling story about her new
idea; the innovator understands why equity has to be allocated to other people and is
not offended by that; and the innovator understands the typical deal structure and is
not offended by that.3

4.5.6 Venture Capital Market

The venture capital market converts new ideas into functioning businesses. There are
three categories of economic agents in this market: Innovators (sellers of new ideas);
venture capitalists (buyers of new ideas); and limited partners of venture funds
(passive investors who hold debt and equity claims on the start-up). The venture
capital market resembles an oligopsony: there are many sellers of new ideas (inno-
vators) and just a few buyers of new ideas (venture capitalists). Unfortunately, we
cannot apply the textbook supply and demand model because a small number of VCs
have an extraordinary degree of market power.4

4.5.7 Angel Investors

Angel investors are wealthy individuals who are involved in the start-ups they back
and who typically are not professional investors such as venture capitalists. The
empirical evidence shows that firms who are backed by angel investors are more
likely to survive, create more jobs, and have a greater chance of exiting the
adolescent phase than otherwise comparable firms without this support. For exam-
ple, USA angel-backed firms hire 40% more employees and angel-backing increases
the probability of successful exit from the start-up stage by 10–17 percent. See
Lerner et al. (2015)
Note 4 Business incubators
Business incubators also help young innovative firms to survive and grow, but
they are not equity partners of the supported business. They provide management,
financial, business and technological assistance to start-up firms.

3
Real-life contracts between VCs and innovators show that VCs get the lion’s share in terms of
property rights, voting rights, and liquidation.
4
As a reminder, for the familiar supply and demand model to be applicable there must be many
sellers and many buyers without market power.
86 4 Innovation Environment

4.6 Chapter Summary

• The constitutive parts of Dimension 3 (Innovation Environment) are the innova-


tion infrastructure, clusters and the relationship between them.
• The components of the innovation infrastructure together with the corresponding
positive attributes required for the production of profitable new ideas throughout
the economy are shown in Diagram 4.1.
• The anatomy of a cluster is a Porter Diamond.
• A Porter Diamond is a system with six interconnected components (Resource
endowments, Home demand, Related and supporting industries, Context for local
competition, Government factor, and Chance events). A snapshot of a Porter
Diamond is shown in Diagram 4.2, where the two-headed arrows indicate recipro-
cal influence. A successful Porter Diamond generates domestic competitive
advantage.
• International competitive advantage requires additional attributes: domestic com-
petitive advantage must be valuable abroad, domestic competitive advantage
cannot be neutralized, and there are T-entrepreneurs (See Diagram 4.3).
• Innovations tend to navigate consecutive phases described by the innovation life
cycle. As pointed out by Diagram 4.4, the most important reason for the existence
of venture capital is the financial void faced by innovators when they want to
move from the Idea Phase to the Infant Phase.

Diagram 4.1 Appropriate national circumstances for the production of profitable new ideas
4.6 Chapter Summary 87

Diagram 4.2 Porter Diamond and domestic competitive advantage

Diagram 4.3 Successful Porter Diamond and international competitive advantage

• Venture capital finances innovation projects in exchange for a portion of the


equity of the company.
• The venture capital market has three distinguishing features: there are many
sellers (innovators), the number of buyers (venture capitalists) is small, and
buyers have strong market power (see Diagram 4.5). It is an unusual type of
market resembling an oligopsony.
88 4 Innovation Environment

Diagram 4.4 Lack of appropriate resources to finance the development of the new idea

Diagram 4.5 Supply and demand of new ideas


Appendix G: Miscellaneous Points on the Innovation Environment 89

Appendix G: Miscellaneous Points on the Innovation


Environment

Incentives Regime

A glance at Diagram 4.1 shows that one of the positive attributes influencing the
production of profitable new ideas is “government support for innovation.” What
follows is a brief discussion of a concrete case of “incentives regime.”

2015 Australian Innovation Agenda: Generalities

The Australian government addressed the “innovate or perish” challenge by releas-


ing an innovation policy statement on 7 December 2015, entitled National Innova-
tion and Science Agenda (NISA). The innovation package NISA (2015) is crystal
clear: “While historically high commodity prices have driven the growth in our
living standards over the last decade, fostering innovation and commercialising ideas
will be the key driver of future jobs and growth.” (NISA 2015, p. 3)
The message conveyed by NISA (2015) is that Australian residents have to
develop an innovative frame of mind. This is not wishful thinking. Theory and
empirical evidence suggest that anyone can be an innovator. When launching NISA
in December 2015 the then Prime Minister Malcom Turnbull expressed:
We want to be a culture, a national culture of innovation, of risk-taking, because
as we do that, we grow the whole ecosystem of innovation right across the economy.
We become more experienced, more innovative, more agile, more prepared to take
on risk and become a culture of ideas because it is the ideas boom that will secure our
prosperity in the future. It is believing in our human capital and remembering that the
best assets we have, the most important assets we have in this country are not to be
found under the ground, but walking around on top of it is the 24 million Australians,
the men and women of Australia, these and their ideas are what secures our future.
And this package [NISA] will incentivise, dynamise, energise that enormous
opportunity.
The innovation scheme NISA can be thought of as a tool of attitude and
permission to take a risk, be an innovator, and think deeply about the industries of
the future that will create jobs and wealth to sustain living standards. The motto
underlying NISA is “Risk-takers, Growth-makers.”
NISA (2015) identifies four specific barriers hampering innovation in Australia:
School students’ math skills are falling; insufficient access to early stage capital;
insufficient collaboration between industry and researchers; and government follow-
ing on innovation, not leading. These challenges are obstacles to be overcome, not
the pursuit of the impossible.
NISA put forward a package of initiatives in correspondence to each of the
specific barriers to innovation. First, according to NISA (2015) “The talents and
90 4 Innovation Environment

skills of our people is the engine behind Australia’s innovative capacity. We need to
create an environment that attracts the world’s best and brightest, while making sure
Australians are equipped with the skills they need to thrive in a rapidly evolving
workforce.” Second, NISA (2015) includes an initiative to opening up new sources
of finance for new innovative start-up firms. This initiative is related to venture
capital and angel investors. Third, there is an initiative to increase collaboration
between industry and researchers to create jobs and economic growth. Finally, the
Australian government will lead by example by embracing innovation in its
activities.

2015 Australian Innovation Agenda: Criticisms

The federal government’s innovation policy NISA was trumpeted as the route for
developing an “agile and creative” economy as the mining boom receded. NISA was
a $1.1 billion innovation fund which promised to transform the economy. However,
NISA was the target of harsh criticism. For example, Andrew Walsh (CEO of the
$2 billion financial market software company IREE) criticized NISA arguing that the
government was using the language of innovation in a “very empty” way. Malcom
Turnbull’s ideas boom is “shallow” and “inflated with bad clichés,” Walsh is
reported to have said.5 These and other criticisms prompted a response from Alan
Finkel (Australia’s Chief Scientist) clarifying the interpretation of the 2015 innova-
tion agenda. To quote Australia’s Chief Scientist extensively,
I am not pretending that we can achieve success by putting down all our big
dreams in a policy document. You cannot order your country to have ideas. You
cannot order your country to pursue them – any more than you can order a soccer
team to win. You can exhort, you can encourage, you can get creative with salary
caps – but ultimately, you need to build the capabilities to play the game consistently
well. The same is true with innovation policy: it is a business of maximizing the
potential for people to perform, through a combination of smart regulation and
strategic investment. Alan Finkel, Australia’s Chief Scientist, 18 August 2016.
What NISA does is to get the settings right to encourage existing firms to grow
and new firms to start creating new opportunities and jobs. In brief, the philosophy of
NISA can be condensed in the following proverb: “You could lead the horse to water
but you could not make him drink.”
More criticisms were launched in September 2017 when the then Minister of
Industry, Innovation and Science Arthur Sinodinos told the Australian Financial
Review Summit that Malcom Turnbull’s innovation agenda did not resonate with
everyday Australians, but denied the government had abandoned its agenda.

5
See Roddan (2016).
Appendix G: Miscellaneous Points on the Innovation Environment 91

Regional politicians believed that NISA scared off voters due to the perception that
they may lose their job to machines. Freelancer.com founder Matt Barrie6 said
Australia suffered from delusions of grandeur about the strength of domestic inno-
vative activities.
Furthermore, NISA was evaluated by the Australian National Audit Office
(ANAO). In a damning report the Auditor-General’s report questioned the economic
impact, policy bases and preparation of NISA. As we mentioned before, the mea-
sures in NISA addressed four barriers hampering innovation in Australia, but the
auditor said there was not enough evidence provided to support why these hurdles
were a problem: “A number of the proposals that involved significant expenditure
aimed at transforming parts of the innovation system relied on assertions rather than
evidence,” the auditor said in the report. Moreover, “The ANAO observed that much
of the advice was general in nature and did not present a quantitative in-depth
analysis of problems, expected impacts or how outcomes would be measured.”
ANAO (2017).
Unfortunately, it appears that NISA has not achieved much.
Note 5 Policies to promote innovation
Countries willing to attain or maintain the status of being a creative economy may
implement policies to promote innovation. Innovation policy is a vast and complex
topic, currently under active investigation. There are different tools to encourage
innovation as an economic activity such as, for example, R&D tax credits and skilled
immigration. We will not attempt to review the literature here, since this task has
already been conducted by Bloom et al. (2019).

Venture Capitalist-Innovator Relationship

Further insight into the subtleties underlying the navigation of the innovation life
cycle is provided by the relationship between venture capitalists (VCs) and
innovators.

Principal-Agent Problem

In economics, situations in which one person (the agent) performs tasks for another
(the principal) are called ‘principal-agent relations.’ To be more precise, the principal
(e.g. a manager) is someone who wants something to be done and the agent (e.g. a
worker) is the person that has to do it for the principal. Both principal and agent wish

6
Barrie was one of the country’s successful innovators alongside the founders of Atlassian, SEEK,
and Wise Tech Global.
92 4 Innovation Environment

to maximize their own well-being. The ‘principal-agent problem’ arises when the
agent wants to do things other than what the principal wants.

Innovators Behaving Badly

The innovator (agent) may not behave in the manner desired by the venture capitalist
(principal). Two typical examples can be mentioned here. First, the innovator may
have a difficult personality or show lack of focus. Second, innovators may pursue
their own goals even at the cost of retarding the progress of the innovation project.
This is the case when an inventor uses the R&D lab to carry out abstract research in
medicine instead of accelerating clinical trials to pass the FDA.
Why is that innovators may develop an ‘independent life’? VCs cannot monitor
everything that innovators do because innovators have more information that VCs in
relation to the development of the new idea. This information asymmetry combined
with conflicting goals may lead to a ‘principal-agent problem.’

Avoiding Principal-Agent Problems

The principal is concerned with ways to keep the agent in line with the progress of
the innovation project. VCs try to avoid principal-agent problems by designing
contracts that give the innovators incentives to perform effectively. A good example
of such an incentive mechanism is conditional funding, that is, release of funds
contingent on performance milestones being achieved by the agent.

Selected References

ANAO (2017) Design and monitoring of the national innovation and science agenda. Australian
National Audit Office, Auditor-general report no. 10 of 2017–2018, 27 September
Bloom N, Reenen VJ, Williams H (2019) A toolkit of policies to promote innovation. J Econ
Perspect 33:163–184
Furman JL, Porter ME, Stern S (2002) The determinants of national innovative capacity. Res Policy
31:899–933
Lerner J, Schoar A, Sokolinski S, Wilson K (2015) The globalization of angel investments:
evidence across countries. NBER work paper no. 21808
NISA (2015) National innovation and science agenda. Commonwealth of Australia
Porter ME (1990) The competitive advantage of nations. Macmillan Press. Re-issued in 1998 with
an introduction by the author
Roddan M (2016) Turnbull’s ‘empty’ ideas boom. Australian, Tuesday 24 May
Zider B (1998) How venture capital works. Harv Business Rev 76:131–142
Chapter 5
Microeconomic Aspects of Innovation

Contents
5.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 94
5.2 Innovation Process and Related Terminology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95
5.2.1 Inputs and Outputs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95
5.2.2 Research and Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96
5.2.3 Profit-Seeking R&D . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96
5.2.4 Factors Influencing R&D Undertakings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97
5.2.5 Classifying Innovation Outputs: Technological
and Organizational Innovations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97
5.2.6 First Risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98
5.2.7 Second Risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 99
5.2.8 Third Risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 99
5.2.9 Innovation Costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100
5.2.10 Successful Innovation and Commoditization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100
5.3 The Innovator’s Dilemma . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100
5.3.1 Sustaining and Disruptive Innovations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 101
5.3.2 Examples of Disruptive Innovations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 101
5.3.3 Innovation and Market Power . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 103
5.3.4 Statement and Solution of the Innovator’s Dilemma . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 103
5.3.5 Incumbents Disrupting Themselves . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 104
5.4 Fast Innovation Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 105
5.4.1 Fast Innovation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 105
5.4.2 Creative Economy: Boon or Bone? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 106
5.5 Chapter Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 106
Appendix H: Business Innovation and Social Innovation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 108
Bifocal Innovations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109
Pure Social Innovations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109
Anticipatory Shipping . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 110
Facebook . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 110
Clean Up the World . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 110
Putting Them Altogether . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111
Concluding Comment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111
Selected References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 112

© Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. 2020 93


J. E. Fernandez-Pol, C. Harvie, Understanding the Creative Economy and the Future
of Employment, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-1652-8_5
94 5 Microeconomic Aspects of Innovation

Concise Preview
• This chapter enlarges our understanding of innovation through the introduction of
new microeconomic concepts.
• Our understanding of innovation at the micro level is also enlarged by analysis of
two paradoxical situations, which turn out to be well founded.
• Economic success based only on efficiency of existing products may lead to
failure (first paradoxical situation).
• Good companies known for their ability to be efficient and innovative fail or lose
market dominance (second paradoxical situation).
• The message conveyed by this chapter is simple, yet fundamental: what matters in
a Creative Economy is not just being rapidly innovative but becoming increas-
ingly attentive to disruptive innovations.
• Appendix H discusses the relationship between business innovation and social
innovation, an issue that tends to be misunderstood.

5.1 Introduction

There are many microeconomic concepts in the field of innovation as an economic


activity that we have to describe and assemble. These include the innovation process,
inescapable risks associated with an innovation project, successful innovation,
commoditization, and disruptive innovation. Furthermore, we need to address seem-
ingly paradoxical situations facing the majority of –if not all– modern firms.
Efficient firms operating in a Creative Economy immediately realize that success
based only on efficiency may lead to failure. Or, to put it differently, each firm faces
a paradox that we call the Efficient Firm’s Dilemma: the more an efficient firm strives
to remain as it is today the more likely it is that it will fall away.1
To overcome this paradox, firms need to contemplate two domains of activity:
one related to efficiency (maintaining quality of existing products and keeping costs
down) and another associated with innovation (sharp focus on the creation of new
products or new processes or new forms of organization). Thus, the firm has to
optimize at two levels, efficiency and innovation.
Many analysts and CEOs are perfectly aware of the Efficient Firm’s Dilemma. In
the article “Innovation Key to Keeping Manufacturing Onshore“, Sarah Martin
(2013) explores the view that “The future can still be bright if the nation [Australia]
learns to focus on value-adding, not metal banging.” To this end, she uses a brief
case study associated with the company Redarc Electronics located in Adelaide’s
south. In this newspaper article we can find the opinion of Redarc Chief executive
Anthony Kittel:
“To buck the trend in the downturn of manufacturing, we are investing a minimum of
15 per cent of our revenue back into research and development each and every year.

1
The term ‘dilemma’ is used in this chapter to mean a ‘difficult situation or problem.’
5.2 Innovation Process and Related Terminology 95

Innovation drives our company’s bottom line. Not everything is successful, but that is part
of ground breaking research and having new ideas – some will fail, but you will get some
really super-successful ones. If you are just competing on cost, you will definitely lose; if
that is the approach you take, then your manufacturing plant in Australia is destined to
move offshore or close.”

To stay atop of their industries firms have to be innovative. However, innovative


practices conducive to short-run success may lead to decay in the medium term. This
subtle issue is known as the “innovator’s dilemma” and will be addressed in this
chapter.
In the last 20 years or so the pace of innovation has increased dramatically. We
are accustomed to the dizzying speed of innovation in mobile phones, where new
products appear monthly. But other sectors are witnessing rapid innovation. The
increase in the pace of innovation reflects the “fast innovation approach” that has
been adopted by many companies.

5.2 Innovation Process and Related Terminology

5.2.1 Inputs and Outputs

Any element that enables innovative activities is considered an innovation input. For
example, technology, human capital, and R&D labs, are innovation inputs. Speaking
loosely, innovation outputs are the results of innovative activities. For example, a
company could acquire technology in the form of patents (input) to design a new
product new to the world (output). The innovation process consists of using
innovation inputs to create innovation outputs. As in all production processes,
“zero input” means “zero output.”
What is the difference between producing “alfresco dining chairs” (a product that
already exists) and creating a new type of dining chair? If you have a company
producing alfresco dining chairs, the output is certain in the sense that you know how
to produce this type of chairs. The creation of a new type of dining chair cannot be
guaranteed because we do not know whether the new chair is technically feasible.
In general, the creation of new products or processes is beset by risks. You spend
money on innovation inputs but you do not know whether you will get an innovation
output. If the attempt at innovation fails, there are innovation inputs but there is no
innovation output.
Note 1 Think, Play, Do
Note that describing the innovation process as an activity that transforms inno-
vation inputs into innovation outputs is simplistic because this description tells us
nothing about the flow of connected and interactive activities that turns inputs into
outputs. Or, to put it differently, the description helps our intuition but creates a
96 5 Microeconomic Aspects of Innovation

black box.2 The Think, Play, Do approach goes inside the black box and enhances
our understanding of the innovation process in the real world. See Dodgson et al.
(2005)
An innovation project is said to be partially successful if the use of innovation
inputs leads to the creation of an innovation output. Quite obviously, in this case we
have innovation inputs and one innovation output (e.g. a product new to the world).
However, it may well happen that the use of innovation inputs does not lead to
innovation outputs because the creation of the new product is out of the question. In
this case the innovation project is said to be technically unsuccessful.

5.2.2 Research and Development

Research and Development (R&D) is an input in the innovation process. In general,


R&D comprises investigative work undertaken on a systematic basis in order to
increase the stock of knowledge with a view to using this stock to devise new
applications. Some of these applications may be commercially driven (such as, for
example, the design of a new i-phone) and others may be curiosity driven only (such
as, for example, planet hunting).
Examples of R&D abound: the validation of string theory; research on laser drills
for dentistry; construction of prototypes for technical testing and pilot plants;
development of new or substantially modified computer software; and research
work in social sciences and humanities are a few.

5.2.3 Profit-Seeking R&D

Typically, R&D performed by business firms is carried out with the purpose of
developing new or improved products or processes of commercial value. This kind
of R&D is referred to as profit-seeking R&D. Firms require R&D not for its own sake
but as a means to innovate. Note carefully that R&D is an input to be optimized,
not maximized. There is no merit in spending large amounts on R&D activities when
the innovation can be attained with a relatively small R&D expenditure.
R&D is a very important input in many innovation projects. However, R&D is
not a necessary input to create a new product or process. For example, a company
may acquire technology in the form of patents, licenses, and trademarks, and design
a new product without performing R&D.

2
Black box in the sense that we are aware of the existence of a complex system whose internal
workings are hidden, but we remain silent about that.
5.2 Innovation Process and Related Terminology 97

It should be emphasized that R&D does not necessarily lead to an innovation


output. In any unsuccessful R&D project there are innovation inputs but no innova-
tion outputs.

5.2.4 Factors Influencing R&D Undertakings

Investments are flows of expenditure that normally provide benefits in the future
beyond the repayment of the outlay of funds. R&D undertakings are an investment.
R&D performers hope to recoup today’s costs and earn profits with successful
innovations.
What may not be so obvious is that there are several factors influencing R&D
undertakings. Firms are highly likely to invest in R&D if they provide an affirmative
answer to eight key questions:
① Is novelty necessary for generating and maintaining competitive advantage?
② Can the firm make a novel product (or process) at a reasonable cost in a
reasonable time?
③ Will consumers want the firm’s innovation enough to pay a reasonable price
for it?
④ Can the firm make the novel product (or process) cheaper and better than other
firms?
⑤ Does the firm reward success more than punish failure?
⑥ Is the firm able to appropriate sufficient returns from the innovation to make the
R&D investment worthwhile?
⑦ Is the Innovation Environment favourable to R&D performers?
⑧ Are there proper sources of finance for R&D projects?

5.2.5 Classifying Innovation Outputs: Technological


and Organizational Innovations

Innovation outputs (in brief, innovations) are divided into two major categories,
namely: Technological innovations and Organizational innovations. The category
‘technological innovation’ contains two sub-categories: product innovation and
process innovation. Product Innovations are new or improved products; similarly,
process innovations are new or improved processes.3
Examples of technological innovations abound: a new razor with floating blades;
new corkscrew; new satellite technology; and Microsoft’s products (Word, Excel,

3
Note that there is one slightly ambiguous feature of this characterization in that it does not define
‘new’ very precisely. If necessary, we can make the distinction “new to the world” innovations
(such as, Amazon’s “anticipatory shipping”) or “new to the Australian market” innovations (such as
a razor with floating blades first introduced in the USA and now introduced in Australia).
98 5 Microeconomic Aspects of Innovation

e-mail, etc.) are a few. New business models, new competitive strategies (such as the
opening up of a new market abroad), changes in management techniques (such as the
introduction of new space-saving procedures designed to reduced needed invento-
ries); and the introduction of cost-reducing innovations (such as Robotic Process
Automation) are examples of organizational innovations.
Note 2 Product/process innovations
As in many classificatory schemes, the distinctions are not clear cut. Although we
distinguish product innovation from process innovation, in many cases the creation
of a new or improved product is inextricably linked to a new manufacturing process.
In other words, product innovation is often really process innovation. To see this
with a real-life example, consider the ‘Gillette sensor’ (the razor with floating
blades):
Introduced in 1990, Gillette’s sensor razor became one of the most successful
new products in the history of the razor industry. Unlike existing razor designs with
fixed mounted blades, the Sensor incorporated floating blades, which could better
follow the contours of a man’s face and thus provide a closer shave.
Compared with razor designs at the time, the sensor was a highly complex product,
incorporating 23 parts (compared with the five pieces for most disposable razors). Its
complexity created stiff manufacturing challenges. For example, because the blades needed
to float on springs independently of one another, they had to be much more rigid (to hold
their shape) than those existing systems and, therefore, had to be mounted on a thick steel
bar. Since gluing them to the bar would have been too unreliable, imprecise, and expensive
for high-volume manufacturing, Gillette engineers, working with a vendor, developed a laser
spot-welder capable of performing 93 highly intricate welds per second –faster than any
existing razor. Gillette also needed to develop intricate moulds so that it could make the head
of the razor (which holds the blades) within tolerance of  .0002 inches. (Pisano and
Wheelwright 1999, pp. 86–87)

We mention, in passing, that the manufacturing processes developed to make


Gillette’s razor and its blade were a major barrier to entry.

5.2.6 First Risk

There are several inescapable risks involved in any innovation project. The first type
of risk (Risk 1 or technical risk) is the possibility that the project will not reach
technical completion. This may be due to lack of internal talent. When an innovation
problem cannot be resolved internally, firms have two options: ‘floating labs’
(setting up R&D labs in nations endowed with the appropriate type of human capital)
or ‘crowd innovation’ (innovation is sourced out to the public using the Internet).4

4
Somebody outside the firm may have a critical piece of knowledge to solve the innovation
problem.
5.2 Innovation Process and Related Terminology 99

5.2.7 Second Risk

Assume that the creation of a new product is technically feasible (Risk 1 is not
materialized). Risk 2 or commercial risk is the possibility that the innovation output
will not merit commercial introduction. For example, the new product can be
produced but the cost of producing the new product is too high in relation to existing
products.
Example 1
As an illustration, consider the innovation project of the energy company
Geodynamics that received $90 million in taxpayer money from the Australian
government (Renewable Energy Demonstration Program). The geothermal power
project involved drilling several kilometres down to hot rocks, which would then
superheat water and drive generators of electricity. This project reached technical
completion (Risk 1 was not materialized), but Geodynamics had to abandon the
project because of the huge cost of the technology in bringing power to distant cities
(Risk 2 was materialized). In brief, the project was not commercially viable.

5.2.8 Third Risk

Now, assume that an innovation project turns out to be commercially viable.5 It may
well happen that once the new product is introduced in the market consumers (for
whatever reason) do not want to buy the new product. The Stanley Steamer (a car run
on steam) and Premiers smokers (a smokeless and tasteless cigarette) are examples
of innovations rejected by the market. This suggests – correctly – that there exists a
third kind of risk, Risk 3 (economic risk). Even if Risks 1 and 2 were not materi-
alized there would still remain the economic risk, that is, the risk that the new
product would not be profitable.
To summarize, innovation as an economic activity involves three inescapable
risks, namely
Risk 1 (technical risk): the possibility that the innovation project will not reach
technical completion;
Risk 2 (commercial risk): the possibility that the new product will not merit
commercial introduction; and
Risk 3 (economic risk): the possibility that the innovation will not be profitable.

5
This means that neither Risk 1 nor Risk 2 has been materialized.
100 5 Microeconomic Aspects of Innovation

5.2.9 Innovation Costs

The cost of creating a new idea (or innovation cost) is a one-time cost simply
because any idea needs to be created once. Innovation costs are non-production fixed
costs. The innovation costs incurred in order to produce the first unit of the new
product tend to be high in comparison with the cost of subsequent units. For
example, the first disk of Windows to go out the door cost Microsoft US$50 million,
the second and subsequent disks cost US$3!

5.2.10 Successful Innovation and Commoditization

A successful innovation is one that turns out to be profitable (Risk 3 is not


materialized). Typically, a successful innovation commands a premium price
(it may sometimes enjoy a killing margin), but as time goes by ‘commoditization’
tends to show its ugly face. Commoditization is a term in innovation theory that
refers to the process by which an innovation loses market power (think of falling
prices) due to imitation by competitors.
Example 2
The IBM personal computer (PC) –introduced on 12 August 1981– was a successful
innovation. In fact, the PC allowed IBM to gain 95% of the industry’s profits.
However, the onset of commoditization was quick. The PC used an operating system
made by Microsoft and a microprocessor by Intel. Neither of them was exclusive to
IBM. Within a year competitors (Apple, Compact, Dell, etc.) worked out how to
make cheaper versions of the PC. IBM lost market power due to commoditization.
The reasons underlying the commoditization of the PC are shown in Diagram 5.1.

5.3 The Innovator’s Dilemma

It is easy to explain why poorly run firms fail. However, to explain why the best-run
firms lose their position of leadership is not an easy task. The list of leading
companies that displayed unusual abilities to innovate but lost their position of
leadership is long. In 1997 Harvard Professor Clayton Christensen put forward the
hypothesis that the companies in question followed principles of management that
were only temporarily correct and formulated the “innovator’s dilemma.” This
dilemma cannot be understood without the notions of ‘sustaining innovation’ and
‘disruptive innovation.’
5.3 The Innovator’s Dilemma 101

Diagram 5.1 Reasons for


the commoditization of
the PC

5.3.1 Sustaining and Disruptive Innovations

Clayton Christensen classifies innovations into two types: innovations that improve
the performance of existing products (sustaining innovations) and innovations that
represent an important shift from everything that has come before (disruptive
innovations).
Sustaining Innovations consist of minor changes to existing products such as, for
example, altering lipstick shades (existing product: lipstick); Aloe Vera tissues
(existing product: facial tissues); a razor with five floating blades (existing product:
razor with floating blades); fridge drawers more conveniently sized and arranged
(existing product: fridge drawers); and fractionally quieter air conditioners (existing
product: air conditioner).

5.3.2 Examples of Disruptive Innovations

Disruptive innovations tend to take companies by surprise, and often inflict unex-
pected damage on the incumbents. There are many examples of disruptive innova-
tions. The case of Digital Equipment Corporation, commonly known as DEC or
Digital, is a classic example of an incumbent producer paralysed by a disruptive
102 5 Microeconomic Aspects of Innovation

innovation: the desktop computers disrupted the mini-computer.6 Furthermore,


transistors disrupted vacuum tubes; mini-mills disrupted integrated mills; the ball-
point pen disrupted the fountain pen; digital cameras disrupted non-digital cameras;
and the e-book innovation has disrupted the brick-and-mortar bookstores.
Note 3 Mini-mill, ballpoint pen
The ‘mini-mill’ is a classic example of disruptive innovation. Integrated pro-
ducers of steel transform iron ore into a broad range of steel products, including steel
sheets and re-bars. The introduction of the mini-mill based on an electric arc furnace
made it possible to produce low quality re-bars from scrap metal at a lower cost than
integrated producers could achieve (20% less or thereabout).
A ballpoint pen is a pen in which the point of the nib is a fine ball-bearing,
depositing an extremely thin film of ink, which is stored in a cartridge. Hungarian
brothers László and György Bíró are credited with inventing the pen we still use
today. A fountain pen is a pen with a reservoir for supplying ink to the point of the
nib. The cost of producing a ballpoint pen today is around 20 cents. Fountain pens
are expensive because of high material costs and high production costs (the cheapest
fountain pen could be around $100.00 and one of the Forzieri fountain pens is close
to $71,000.00).
Five additional examples of disruptive innovations, which by no means exhaust
the list of possibilities, are: cloud computing (the trend to compute and store data on
the Internet, rather than on a local computer), iPhone, Facebook, Twitter, and
Airbnb. More examples of disruptive innovations can be found in Christensen
et al. (2015).
Note 4 The cloud
The ‘cloud’ is a delocalized nebula of processing power and storage floating in
the Internet. Nowadays, software is a big chunk of code sitting on a hard disk
embedded in your computer. With the cloud, software becomes a service through
the Internet. This may spell the death of hard disk software. Byrne et al. (2018) found
that the prices of cloud services have plummeted, market size has burgeoned, and
investment in related technology has soared.
Note 5 Creative destruction and disruptive Innovations
At first glance, the relationship between creative destruction and disruptive
innovations appears to be obvious: whenever a disruptive innovation is introduced
in the market, creative destruction follows. It is true that disruptive innovations may
generate creative destruction. For example, the CD destroyed the video-cassettes.

6
The term ‘mini-computer’ can be a bit confusing and requires clarification. DEC (Digital Equip-
ment Corporation) was founded in 1957 by Kenneth Olsen. In 1960, Digital offered the first ‘small’
computer to the world, the PDP-1 (Program Data Processor). It cost $120,000 at a time when the
only available computers were million dollar (room-sized) mainframes from companies such as
IBM and Univac. Unlike the mainframe computers of the day, the PDP-1 was of the size of a
standard refrigerator. In 1965, DEC introduced the PDP-8. This machine was small enough to fit on
a cart, and is generally considered as the first ‘mini-computer.’
5.3 The Innovator’s Dilemma 103

Table 5.1 The impact of different types of innovations


Type of innovation introduced by the Market power
outsider (incumbent) Response (incumbent)
Sustaining (Improvements to existing Threatened Fighting rather than
items) fleeing
Disruptive (Redefines the playing field) Eroded Fleeing rather than
fighting

However, disruptive innovations do not necessarily destroy old products or pro-


cesses. For example, mini-mills and integrated mills, ballpoint pens and fountain
pens, and i-phones and home phones coexist.

5.3.3 Innovation and Market Power

Disruptive innovations are very attractive to industry outsiders. Disruptors often fly


below the radar of incumbent businesses. Incumbents are often caught flat-footed
and they are unable to react to a disruptive innovation – they flee rather than fight.
The dichotomy sustaining/disruptive innovation has important implications in rela-
tion to the market power of incumbent firms.
Innovation theory has established the impact of different types of innovations on
market power and specified the typical reaction of the incumbent firm. If a compet-
itor introduces a sustaining innovation, the incumbent’s market power tends to be
threatened. The incumbent fights rather than flees. However, when the competitor
launches a disruptive attack the incumbent’s market power is eroded and, typically,
the incumbent will flee rather than fight. These relationships can be shown in tabular
form (see Table 5.1).
We mention, in passing, that Bill Gates was haunted by the notion of disruptive
innovation. The Economist reported that Gates asked for Professor Christensen’s
help to avoid disruption.7

5.3.4 Statement and Solution of the Innovator’s Dilemma

The Innovator’s dilemma revolves around the conflicting demands of sustaining


innovations and disruptive innovations. To explain the dilemma, Professor
Christensen wrote a landmark book entitled The Innovator’s Dilemma. At the
beginning of this book we find an intriguing paragraph:
This book is about the failure of companies to stay atop their industries when they confront
certain types of markets and technological change. It’s not about the failure of simply any

7
See The Economist (2008), p. 15.
104 5 Microeconomic Aspects of Innovation

company, but of good companies – the kinds that many managers have admired and tried to
emulate, the companies known for their abilities to innovate and execute. Companies
stumble by many reasons, of course, arrogance, tired executive blood, poor planning,
short-term investment horizons, inadequate skills and resources, and just plain bad luck.
But this book is not about companies with such weaknesses: It is about well-managed
companies that have their competitive antennae up, listen astutely to their customers, invest
aggressively in new technologies, and yet still lose market dominance. (Christensen 1997,
p. vii) [Italics in original]

The Innovator’s Dilemma refers to innovative companies that fail. They fail
because they focus only on sustaining innovations. More precisely the Innovator’s
Dilemma can be stated as follows: the more an innovative firm confines attention to
sustaining innovations, the more likely it is that it will fall away in the medium term
due to the introduction of disruptive innovations by competitors.
At the core of the innovator’s dilemma is the insight that companies intent on
listening to their best customers frequently miss opportunities to create new growth
businesses. It is true that there is value in listening to demanding customers, but it is
true, also, that established firms’ tendency to responding to the needs of their best
customers makes it difficult to anticipate the future impact of disruptive innovations
on their core businesses. In brief, companies focusing only on their best customers
end up producing products that are too good for mainstream consumers. This
overshooting creates opportunities for disruptors.
Firms with resource allocation processes designed to support sustaining innova-
tions tend to get blindsided by disruptive innovations. Attempts to resolve the
Innovator’s Dilemma can be found in Christensen (1997) as well as in Christensen
and Raynor Michael (2013). The optimal response for getting to the crux of the
dilemma consists of creating disruptive innovations rather than being destroyed by
them, becoming disruptors rather than disruptees.

5.3.5 Incumbents Disrupting Themselves

It is difficult to disrupt yourself from within –that is, using the existing organization
to disrupt your own business. Incumbent managers tend to dislike disruptive inno-
vations because profits are not predictable and current customers may have no
interest in the innovation. However, it appears that the optimal solution to the
Innovator’s Dilemma is attracting increasing attention. Many companies are trying
to create disruptions rather than being destroyed by them. In fact, there are a growing
number of long-established market leaders that are turning disruption from a threat
into an opportunity.
In the 1980s and 1990s, only about 25% of disruptive innovations we tracked in our data
base came from such incumbents, with the rest coming from start-ups. But during the 2000s,
35% of disruptions were launched by incumbents. Scott and Christensen (2011)

What are the biggest threats for the big Australian banks? According to Andrew
Thorburn, CEO of National Australia Bank (NAB),
5.4 Fast Innovation Approach 105

Competition is coming from traditional banks and fintech players, but more significantly
from global tech giants that have entered financial services. We need to be ready for new
types of technology and better service or customers will go elsewhere. One of the ways we
are facing competition is to disrupt ourselves from within, through our innovation hub NAB
labs. The Deal, Issue 101, March 2018, p. 15

UBank is a digital-only bank with full license banking from NAB. In 2017 this
digital bank introduced “Robochat” for home loan applications.

5.4 Fast Innovation Approach

Inert growth is bound to be stopped by the almost inevitable commoditization curse.


The growth of a modern firm is conceived as organic growth, i.e. growth displaying
the sort of interconnectedness characteristic of the relations of the parts of a living
organism to the whole. This sort of growth excludes growth attributable to takeovers,
acquisitions or mergers. In practice, organic growth is attained by continual
innovation.

5.4.1 Fast Innovation

It should be clear that what matters in a Creative Economy is not just being rapidly
innovative but becoming increasingly attentive to disruptive innovations. These
insights are incorporated in the so-called “fast innovation approach.” Fast innova-
tion is the process of creating innovations with enough differentiation and speed
such that the firm maintains above-average returns for decades.
In essence, the fast innovation approach consists of a burning platform (expla-
nation to staff members why the firm must be good at innovation) and three engines
of organic growth: differentiation, fast-time-to-market, and probing for disruption.
Differentiation is needed to fetch a premium price or increase the firm’s market
share. Fast-time-to-market means quickly creating innovations to counter the com-
moditization curse. Finally, probing for disruption refers to the use of disruptive
opportunities to make competitors’ products obsolete.
The fast innovation approach is closely related to the theory of disruption
developed by Professor Christensen. This approach has been developed in the
book Fast Innovation by George et al. (2005) with a Foreword written by Clayton
M. Christensen. In the Foreword Christensen expresses:
My understanding of innovation has been enlarged through my interactions with Mike
[Michael George]. I am grateful that in the writing of this book Mike has relied upon my
research and that I have similarly been able to build upon his understanding. I thank him for
providing all of us with the set of practical implementation tools presented in this book.
(George et al. 2005, p. ix)
106 5 Microeconomic Aspects of Innovation

Note 6 Think, Play, Do


Dodgson et al. (2005) give a new perspective on how innovation processes are
organized around a family of innovation technologies with potential to speed up and
intensify innovation.
In Sect. 2.6.2 (Chap. 2), we have made an analogy between a Creative Economy
and a perpetual motion machine. It appears that the machine not only would continue
to operate forever but with an ever increasing pace of innovation. The fast innovation
approach supports the view that the interaction between ideas and human capital
(Principle 1 in the Basic Model) and creative destruction (Principle 2 in the Basic
Model) is happening faster and faster.

5.4.2 Creative Economy: Boon or Bone?

Karl Marx (1818–1883) predicted that capitalism would destroy itself as labour-
saving technological progress reduces the demand for labour, creating massive
unemployment, and this would lead eventually to revolution. It is well-known that
Marx’s prediction proved to be wrong. In the past, labour-saving innovations
stimulated more human employment in total than it destroyed. However, what was
true in the past does not necessarily imply that it will be true in the future.
Elementary economic logic suggests that a Creative Economy may harbour a
tendency toward human unemployment. By definition, a Creative Economy is a
profit-oriented economy and the firms operating in this sort of economy are pre-
dominantly profit-seeking firms. Consequently, they will strive for cost-minimiza-
tion and acquire cost-reducing innovations as soon as they are available. Cost-
reducing innovations tend to be labour-saving, not labour-augmenting.
Some analysts believe that the vision of a lazy, automated tomorrow has given
way to a much darker prospect. For them, the impact of automation on jobs
represents humanity’s biggest existential threat. The next chapter provides an over-
view of the debate between “technology enthusiasts” (automation is not a problem)
and “technology sceptics” (this time is different).

5.5 Chapter Summary

• Both the Efficient Firm’s Dilemma and its solution are evident in the context of a
Creative Economy (see Diagram 5.2)
• Clayton Christensen’s famed concept of “The Innovator’s Dilemma” is less
obvious but once understood, the optimal solution is not far to seek (see Diagram
5.3)
• The fast innovation approach throws light on the increase in the pace of innova-
tion currently observed in advanced economies (see Diagram 5.4)
5.5 Chapter Summary 107

Diagram 5.2 The Efficient Firm’s Dilemma: statement and solution

Diagram 5.3 The Innovator’s Dilemma: statement and solution


108 5 Microeconomic Aspects of Innovation

Diagram 5.4 The fast


innovation approach:
pictorial description

Appendix H: Business Innovation and Social Innovation

What is the relationship between business innovation and social innovation? To


answer this question we need to define the terms ‘business innovation’ and ‘social
innovation.’ It is generally agreed that business innovations are new ideas created
with the intention of making money. No agreed definition of social innovation exists.
Quite obviously, we cannot proceed any further unless we select a definition of
social innovation. Our definitional choice is the frequently quoted definition formu-
lated by Pol and Ville (2009):
(. . .) By and large, the existing definitions revolve around new ideas conducive to human
welfare enhancement. We use this defining characteristic to suggest the following definition:
an innovation is termed a social innovation if the implied new idea has the potential to
improve either the quality or the quantity of life. Examples of innovations that fit nicely with
this definition abound: innovations conducive to better education, better environmental
quality and longer life expectancy are a few. (Pol and Ville 2009, p. 881) [Italics in original]

There are three qualifications of this definition. First, ‘quality of life’ is under-
stood in a macro sense and involves at least following ten components, not neces-
sarily in order of importance: material well-being; education opportunities; health
domain; job security; family life; political freedom; political stability and security;
gender inequality; community life; and natural environment. Second, ‘improvement’
in the quality or the quantity of life means increase in the number of valuable options
Appendix H: Business Innovation and Social Innovation 109

that people can choose from. Finally, it is implicit in the above quoted definition that
we are interested in desirable social innovations, i.e. social innovations that in fact
improve the quality of life or extends life expectancy.
To organize our thinking, consider two sets of innovations. The first set, denoted
by BI, is the set of all business innovations. The second set is the set of all social
innovations, denoted by SI. As will become apparent, the pedagogical advantage of
the language of sets is that it allows us to draw diagrams able to help our intuition.

Bifocal Innovations

Are there innovations that are both business innovations and social innovations? The
history of innovation shows that the majority of business innovations tend to have
beneficial effects not only for the innovators but also for the community as a whole.
This suggests that there are many business innovations that are social innovations as
well. An innovation which is both a business innovation and a social innovation is
located in the overlapping of the sets BI and SI, and is termed bifocal innovation.8
For instance, solar panels –innovations designed to absorb the sun's rays as a source
of energy for generating electricity or heating– is a bifocal innovation.

Pure Social Innovations

Note, however, that stating that there are a lot of innovations which are simulta-
neously business innovations and social innovations is not the same as saying that
the sets BI and SI are identical. Business innovations need not be social innovations
and social innovations are not necessarily driven by the profit motive. The innova-
tion “razor with floating blades” introduced by Gillette in 1990 is a business
innovation but it does not appear to have had a perceptible influence on the quality
of life. “Micro-lending” is a social innovation consisting of the extension of very
small loans to extremely impoverished people (including unemployed) who are not
considered bankable. The creator of micro-lending was Muhammad Yunus –a
Bangladeshi banker and economist – who was not a profit-seeking innovator.
The foregoing naturally leads to a refinement of the terminology. A pure business
innovation is a business innovation that does not belong to SI (the” razor with
floating blades” is a pure business innovation), and similarly, a pure social innova-
tion is a social innovation that does not belong to BI (“micro-lending” as envisaged
by Yunus is a pure social innovation).

8
In the language of sets, a bifocal innovation belongs to the intersection (or overlapping) of the sets
BI and SI, denoted by BI \ SI.
110 5 Microeconomic Aspects of Innovation

Before going into a diagrammatic summary, it is convenient to do a classificatory


exercise based on the innovations “Anticipatory shipping,” “Facebook,” and “Clean
Up the World.” To this end, we briefly described the innovation, and then allocate it
to one of the previous categories.

Anticipatory Shipping

In 2013, Amazon created a new idea (“anticipatory shipping”) to eliminate the major
disadvantage that Internet sellers have compared with physical stores: the delay
between buying an item and receiving it. Specifically, “anticipatory shipping” is an
algorithm (a software program) to predict what people will buy –before customers
have clicked the purchase button! Using this information, Amazon will send these
predicted items to a nearby “hub” or local warehouse. This new idea is an innova-
tion. Amazon obtained a patent for this innovation. The impact of this innovation on
the quality/quantity of life is negligible. Anticipatory shipping is a pure business
innovation.

Facebook

Facebook is an American company based in Menlo Park, California. Its website was
launched on February 4, 2004, by Mark Zuckerberg, along with fellow Harvard
College students and roommates Eduardo Saverin, Andrew McCollum, Dustin
Moskovitz and Chris Hughes. Facebook is a profit-seeking organization where the
bulk of revenue comes from digital advertisements. It is also a popular free social
networking website that allows registered users to create profiles, upload photos, and
videos, send messages and keep in touch with family, friends, and colleagues.
Facebook is a bifocal innovation.

Clean Up the World

Clean Up the World is associated with the United Nations Environmental


Programme (UNEP). Clean Up the World is a community-based environmental
innovation (created in 1993) that mobilizes millions of volunteers from more than
120 countries annually to clean up, fix up, and protect our planet from environmental
degradation. There is no profit motive attached to Clean Up the World, and,
therefore, it is a pure social innovation.
Appendix H: Business Innovation and Social Innovation 111

Diagram 5.5 The relationship between business innovation and social innovation

Putting Them Altogether

Classificatory exercises tend to be tedious mental gymnastics. However, we can help


our biological memory by drawing diagrams. To visualize the relationship between
business innovation and social innovation we can use two circles, one to represent
the set of all business innovations BI and another to represent the set of all social
innovations SI. A point in one of the circles of Diagram 5.5 identifies either a
business innovation or a social innovation or both. The overlapping of the circles
constitutes the collection of all bifocal innovations. Diagram 5.5 also shows the
location within the circles of the six innovations mentioned in this appendix.

Concluding Comment

Many readers –if not all– would recognize that Diagram 5.5 is a Venn diagram. This
kind of diagram begins with a box called universal set (not shown in Diagram 5.5).
The universal set contains all possible types of innovations. The dashed circles BI
and SI will be inside the box. If curiosity driven research leads to a new result such
as, for example, “the optimal number of legs for an insect is 9,” this innovation will
112 5 Microeconomic Aspects of Innovation

be a point within the universal set. But this innovation is neither a business
innovation nor a social innovation, and therefore, it cannot be allocated to either
circle in Diagram 5.5.

Selected References

Byrne D, Corrado C, Sichel DE (2018) The rise of cloud computing: minding your P’s, Q’s and K’s.
National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER Working Paper No. 25188, October
Christensen CM (1997) The innovator’s Dilemma. Harvard Business School Press, Boston
Christensen CM, Raynor Michael E (2013) The innovator’s solution: creating and sustaining
successful growth. Harvard Business Review Press, Boston. First published in 2003
Christensen CM, Raynor ME, McDonald R (2015) What Is disruptive innovation? Harv Bus Rev
93:44–53
Dodgson M, Gann D, Salter A (2005) Think, play, do. Technology, innovation, and organization.
Oxford University Press, Oxford
George ML, Works J, Watson-Hemphill K (2005) Fast innovation. McGraw-Hill, New York
Martin S (2013) Innovation key to keeping manufacturing onshore. The Weekend Australian,
November 16–17
Pisano GP, Wheelwright SC (1999) “The new logic of high-Tech R&D,” originally published in
Harvard Business Review, May-June 1993. Reprinted in Harvard business review on managing
high-tech industries. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, vol 1999, pp 55–116
Pol E, Ville S (2009) Social innovation: buzz word or enduring term? J Socio-Econ 38:878–885
Scott DA, Christensen CM (2011) The empire strikes back. Technology review, Thursday,
December 1
The Economist (2008) The meaning of Bill Gates. The Economist 28 June
Chapter 6
Looking to the Near Future

Contents
6.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114
6.2 Historical Perspective . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 116
6.2.1 Luddites . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 116
6.2.2 The Machinery Question: Ricardo . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 116
6.2.3 Marx: Wrong Prediction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117
6.2.4 Marshall: Two Penetrating Insights . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117
6.2.5 Marshall Decomposition Formula . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118
6.2.6 Keynes-Schumpeter . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118
6.2.7 The Return of the Machinery Question . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119
6.3 Key Terminology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119
6.3.1 Human Replacement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119
6.3.2 Enabling Products . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 120
6.3.3 Enabling Firms- Recipient Firms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 120
6.3.4 Robots, a Terminological Decision . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121
6.3.5 Robots and Task Content of Production . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121
6.3.6 Robot-Based Enabling Products . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 122
6.3.7 Examples . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 122
6.3.8 Section Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 125
6.3.9 Marshall Decomposition Formula, Revisited . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 126
6.4 Robots: Friends or Foes? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 126
6.4.1 Technology Enthusiasts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 127
6.4.2 Technology Sceptics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 128
6.4.3 Resolving the Controversy: Preliminary Remarks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 129
6.4.4 Resolving the Controversy: Not Possible, Time Will Tell . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131
6.4.5 Two Predictions About the Next Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131
6.4.6 Robotize or Perish . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131
6.5 The Future of Employment: Anticipation Exercises . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132
6.5.1 Occupation-Based Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 133
6.5.2 Task-Based Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 134
6.5.3 Predicting New Occupations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 134
6.6 Rational Response to the March of the Robots . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 135
6.6.1 T-shaped Knowledge Workers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 135
6.6.2 Classifying Tasks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 136
6.6.3 Mapping Skills to Tasks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 137
6.6.4 Skill-biased Technological Progress . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 137
6.6.5 Two Types of Automation Technologies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 138
6.6.6 Investment in Human Capital . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 138

© Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. 2020 113


J. E. Fernandez-Pol, C. Harvie, Understanding the Creative Economy and the Future
of Employment, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-1652-8_6
114 6 Looking to the Near Future

6.6.7 Components of the Protective Belt . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 139


6.6.8 Australia’s Chief Scientist . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 139
6.7 Chapter Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 139
6.8 Concluding Comment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 140
Appendix I: Expert Opinions on the Impact of Automation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 140
Australian Poll . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141
Comparison of Responses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141
Overview of the Australian Poll by Borland and Potts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 142
Delloite Report: The Panglossian Economy is Attainable . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 142
Selected References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 144

Concise Preview
• The key question in this chapter is: what would a creative economy look like in
the near future?
• It is generally agreed that the “next economy” will revolve around smart
machines aka robots.
• It is unclear whether the current wave of automation will lead to unemployment in
the near future.
• Concerns about human competition with machines are not new. They go back
200 years ago.
• Technology enthusiasts believe that there is nothing to worry about with new
technology, but technology sceptics are deeply concerned with the relentless
progression toward automation.
• Which jobs will be affected by automation? To assess the future of human work
researchers carry out anticipation exercises.
• This chapter ends with the design of a rational response to the unstoppable march
of the robots.
• The majority of economists are not concerned with the current wave of automa-
tion. This can be verified with the information provided in Appendix I.

6.1 Introduction

In this chapter we ask: given the relentless progression toward automation, what
would a creative economy look like in the not-too-distant future? This is an awkward
question because the answer requires predictions under conditions of deep
uncertainty.
Economists are concerned with the future as well as with the past. But it is from
the past that they have to begin. The past provides them with the facts which they use
to construct models. Any quantitative, data-driven analysis necessarily depends
entirely on information gathered in the past, and, in some cases, that data may
have been collected many years ago.
It should be clear that to address questions concerning the future we can only use
empirical data from the past simply because future data do not exist. To tentatively
answer questions referring to the future it is often necessary to imagine the future by
6.1 Introduction 115

Diagram 6.1 Propelling


factors of a creative
economy

developing models. It should also be clear that the fact that an economist can
visualize a future in his model is not evidence that it is likely to happen.
The fruitfulness of any model hinges on the degree to which factors relevant to
the particular investigation at hand are brought into sharp focus. The point of
departure of our reasoning is that a creative economy is propelled by two essential
factors inextricably tied together, namely: technological progress and the profit
motive. The importance of these two factors emerges from the study of the history
of earlier periods.1 Diagram 6.1 is a primitive picture designed to point out that the
fundamental impulses that keep the creative economy engine in motion come from
technology and profit. The creative economy not only never is but never can be
stationary.
Being schematic, Diagram 6.1 ignores an ocean of facts, but it points out the most
important factors (technology and profit) causing economic change in a free-market
economy. Almost everyone agrees that the “next economy” will revolve around
smart machines aka robots where workers will struggle to fend off obsolescence.
Thus, robots might engender unemployment due to widespread human replacement.
Is this fear misplaced?
Roughly speaking, the answer depends on whether you are a member of the
“technology enthusiast” group or the “technology sceptic” group. These groups have
specific approaches. While the group of enthusiasts follow the historical approach
and point out that the fear of robots is not justified, the group of sceptics develop an
argument based on economic logic to show that this time is different.

1
A glance at Appendix D shows that these factors are emphasized by the endogenous growth
theory.
116 6 Looking to the Near Future

Before delving into this debate, it is helpful to have a historical perspective. As


will become apparent, history shows that concerns about the downside of new
technology (namely: human replacement) are not new. It is also helpful to introduce
some new terminology and examples about human replacement.

6.2 Historical Perspective


6.2.1 Luddites

Concern about the downside to new technology goes back at least to Ned Ludd’s
destruction of two stocking frames in 1779 near Leicester, England. Ludd (a weaver
from Anstey) is supposed to have broken two stoking machines in a fit of rage. He
became a mythical leader figure. Wherever any machinery was smashed the claim
“Ned Ludd must have done it” became a catchphrase, and so the association with the
myth and legend grew. More than three decades later –in 1812– about 150 armed
workers (self-named Luddites) marched on a textile mill in Huddersfield, England, to
smash equipment. The British army promptly killed or executed 19 of their mem-
bers. Later in 1812, the British Parliament passed a law authorizing death for
vandalizing machines.

6.2.2 The Machinery Question: Ricardo

David Ricardo (1772–1823) was the first economist to focus on the issue of human
competition with machines. The buzzword at the time was the “machinery question,”
posed by Ricardo.2 In a speech in Parliament in 1819 Ricardo maintained that the
introduction of machinery did not reduce the demand for labour. But soon after this
pronouncement Ricardo changed his mind. In the third (and last edition) of The
Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, published in 1821, Ricardo added a
new chapter entitled “On Machinery” in which he analysed the effect on the
economy of the introduction of machinery. At the beginning of Chapter XXXI, On
Machinery, he wrote:
In the present chapter I shall enter into some inquiry respecting the influence of machinery
on the interest of the different classes of society, a subject of great importance, and one
which appears never to have been investigated in a manner to lead to any certain of
satisfactory results. (. . .) (Ricardo 1911, p. 263)

The conclusion reached by Ricardo was pretty striking:

2
The “machinery question” refers to the controversy over the dangers posed by machines, e.g. the
substitution of machinery for human labour may render humans redundant.
6.2 Historical Perspective 117

(. . .) I am convinced that the opinion entertained by the labouring class, that employment of
machinery is frequently detrimental to their interests, is not founded on prejudice and error,
but is conformable to the correct principles of political economy. (Ricardo 1911, p. 264)

6.2.3 Marx: Wrong Prediction

Karl Marx (1818–1883) predicted that capitalism would destroy itself. The mecha-
nization of the economy would lead to mass unemployment and deteriorate the
standard of living of workers, ultimately driving them to a subsistence wage (Marx
1906, pp. 708–709). It is well-known that Marx’s prediction proved to be wrong. In
the past, mechanization stimulated more employment in total than it destroyed.
Living standards have grown dramatically. However, we should reiterate here that
what was true in the past does not necessarily imply that it will be true in the future.

6.2.4 Marshall: Two Penetrating Insights

Alfred Marshall (1842–1924) contributed two penetrating insights relevant to the


machinery question in his 1890 Principles of Economics. He was the first economist
to connect the advent of labour-saving machines with repetitive tasks (first insight):
We are thus led to a general rule, the action of which is more prominent in some branches of
manufacture than others, but which apply to all. It is, that any manufacturing operation that
can be reduced to uniformity, so that exactly the same thing has to be done over and over
again in the same way, is sure to be taken over sooner or later by machinery. There may be
delays and difficulties; but if the work to be done by it is on a sufficient scale, money and
inventive power will be spent without stint on the task till it is achieved. (Marshall 1966,
p. 212)

Furthermore, Marshall pointed out that machinery replaces tasks for human
workers, but also creates new tasks for them (second insight):
The machinery constantly supplants and renders unnecessary that purely manual skill, the
attainment of which was, even up to Adam Smith’s time, the chief advantage of division of
labour. But this influence is more than countervailed by its tendency to increase the scale of
manufactures and to make them more complex; and therefore to increase the opportunities
for division of labour of all kinds, and especially in the matter of business management.
(Marshall 1966, pp. 212–213)

Somewhat roughly, this means that with the introduction of labour-saving


“mechanical-muscle” machines some jobs will go and others will come.
118 6 Looking to the Near Future

6.2.5 Marshall Decomposition Formula

More precisely, Alfred Marshall identified a decomposition of the effect of new


mechanical-muscle machinery on jobs. Paraphrasing Marshall, the total effect on the
number of jobs of new machines supplanting purely manual tasks can be
decomposed into a displacement effect, which measures the reduction in the number
of jobs, and a compensating effect representing the new jobs emerging from
increases in productivity and possibly new tasks created by the new machines.
It stands to reason to refer to Marshall’s second insight as the Marshall Decom-
position Formula. To fix ideas, we write the corresponding formula as follows:

Total Effect of
Mechanical‐muscle ¼ Displacement effect þ Compensating Effect
Machines ð Þ ðþ Þ

where the sign of each partial effect is printed below it. A glance at the Marshall
Decomposition formula reveals that if the displacement effect is not being
counterbalanced by the compensating effect there will be a reduction in the number
of jobs. It should be clear that we cannot make predictions without using empirical
evidence because the total effect is qualitatively ambiguous (the partial effects have
opposite signs, and, consequently, the total effect can be negative, zero or positive).
A digression is pertinent here. Daron Acemoglu and Pascual Restrepo have made
seminal contributions in the economics of automation. For example, Acemoglu and
Restrepo (2019) present a framework for thinking through the implications of
technology for labour demand and productivity. In particular, they show that the
net impact of automation on labour demand can be divided up into a displacement
effect (capital takes over tasks previously performed by labour) and a productivity
effect (the contribution of automation to the demand for labour in non-automated
tasks). The total effect of automation on labour demand depends on how the
displacement and productivity effects weigh against each other. This “Acemoglu-
Restrepo Decomposition Formula” is reminiscent of the Marshall Decomposition
Formula.

6.2.6 Keynes-Schumpeter

In the first quarter of the twentieth century rapid technological progress was in the
minds of two colossuses of economic thought living beyond their time: John May-
nard Keynes (1883–1946) and Joseph Alois Schumpeter (1883–1950). Keynes
provided deep insight into the meaning of technological unemployment.
In the early 1930s, with the United States in deep depression, it seemed to many
that Karl Marx was right and capitalism was indeed doomed. John Maynard Keynes
writing in the midst of the Great Depression pointed out a new disease called
6.3 Key Terminology 119

‘technological unemployment.’ This is what Keynes wrote about technological


unemployment:
We are being affected with a new disease of which some readers may not have yet heard the
name, but of which they will hear a great deal in the years to come –namely, technological
unemployment. This means unemployment due to our discovery of means of economising
the use of labour outrunning the pace at which we can find new uses for labour. (Keynes
1930, p. 325) [Italics in original]

He went on to say that ‘this is only a temporary phase of maladjustment,’ predicting


a future of leisure and plenty one 100 years hence (Keynes 1930, p. 325). His prophesy
gained reinforcement with Schumpeter’s 1942 encomium to ‘creative destruction’
(Schumpeter 2010).

6.2.7 The Return of the Machinery Question

By the end of the 1940s the machinery question had faded away because the overall
effect of mechanisation turned out to be massive job creation. The nineteenth century
Luddites lost the battle to prevent weaving machinery stealing their jobs and we have
accepted the unquestioned march of technological progress since. However, artificial
intelligence, automation, and robotics are now prompting the same concerns as
mechanisation did two centuries ago. After 200 years, the machinery question
is back.

6.3 Key Terminology

We believe it is a good idea to start by demarcating several key terms. We single out
three terms: human replacement, enabling products, and robot-based enabling
products.

6.3.1 Human Replacement

For economists, ‘human replacement’ means ‘the production by ourselves of ever


better substitutes for ourselves.’ The link between human replacement and smart
machines has a powerful grip on the collective imagination of humans.
120 6 Looking to the Near Future

6.3.2 Enabling Products

Within the set of all firms operating in a creative economy there is a subset of
companies focusing on the creation of enabling products, which are, by definition,
either cost-reducing technologies or efficiency-enhancing technologies or both.
Many enabling products have entailed a substitution of capital for labour in
particular economic sectors but pervasive human replacement has not been the
general rule. To illustrate this point, we mention the tractor, the personal computer
(PC), and the so-called smart connected products.
The tractor has been an enabling product in agriculture that replaced humans,
horses, mules, and oxen, but did not completely replace human labour. The
indispensability of human mental functions fulfilled by human labour such as,
for example, constant attention of alert drivers, guiding hand, and sharp eyes, could
not be replaced. The personal computer (PC) has been an enabling product leading
to efficiency gains in many sectors, but mental functions are still required to
operate a PC.
Augmented reality (AR) is a set of technologies that allow us to take the digital
information available on the cloud and overlaid it on a human’s view of the real
physical world in real time. It is expected that AR will change how we work.
According to Michael Porter, AR is a profound next step in transforming competi-
tion in business.
In particular, AR has allowed the advent of what Michael Porter calls smart
connected products. These products are not easy to conceptualize, but some intuitive
understanding can be gleaned from the following brief description.3 We all know
that there are physical products and digital products. The intuition behind smart
connected products is that they bridge the gap between the two. A smart connected
product links a physical product (e.g. a car) and a digital product (e.g. information on
the cloud) and establishes a two-way communication between the physical product
and the digital product in real time. The link may be established by overlaying a
dashboard on the physical product. Smart connected products are at least efficiency-
enhancing technologies, and therefore enabling products.

6.3.3 Enabling Firms- Recipient Firms

The firms creating enabling products (enabling firms, for short) sell their innova-
tions to firms operating in a variety of sectors (agricultural sector, manufacturing
sector, financial sector, etc.). Any firm buying enabling products is termed a recip-
ient firm. The demand for enabling products is a derived demand in the sense that the
recipient firms demand those products not for its own sake but because of their

3
The HBR Video by Porter and Heppelman (2018) offers a visual description of smart connected
products.
6.3 Key Terminology 121

production attributes such as, for example, cost reductions. Because managers are
obsessed with cost-minimization and efficiency-gains over time, the demand for
enabling products is always present.4

6.3.4 Robots, a Terminological Decision

Automation encapsulates the development and adoption of new technologies that


enable capital to be substituted for labour in a range of tasks. Artificial Intelligence
(AI) and robotics exemplify automation. However, the line of separation between AI
and robotics is not easy to draw. For example, the economic use of robotics centres
on substituting machines for tasks previously performed by humans, involving
interactions with the physical world (e.g. moving around parcels). To achieve the
automation of these tasks, robotics makes use of AI and other digital technologies.
At this point, it is necessary to make a terminological decision. Any device based
on Artificial Intelligence (AI), robotics or other digital technologies will be included
in the category ‘robots’. This definition is general enough to capture industrial
robots –defined as fully autonomous reprogrammable, multipurpose machines–
and other machines requiring a human operator but able to reduce the quantity of
human jobs.5

6.3.5 Robots and Task Content of Production

With a model in which robots compete with human labour in the production of
different tasks, Acemoglu and Restrepo (2017a) estimated the equilibrium impact of
industrial robots and found that on average the arrival of one new industrial robot in
a local labour market coincides with an employment drop of 5.6 workers. They
conclude their paper by expressing that “the negative effects we estimate are both
interesting and perhaps somewhat surprising, especially because they indicate a very
limited set of offsetting employment increases in other industries and occupations.”
(Acemoglu and Restrepo 2017a, p. 37).
The conventional approach in economics bypasses tasks and directly posits a
production function Q ¼ F(K, L), where Q denotes output level, and K (capital) and
L (labour) represent the factors of production. Acemoglu and Restrepo (2019)
pointed out that the conventional approach lacks descriptive realism and can force
economists into misleading conclusions. These authors developed a formal model
where tasks are the fundamental unit of production and each task can be performed

4
The rule “supply creates its own demand” (economists call this rule Say’s law) works exceedingly
well for enabling products.
5
In this book, we will use the terms ‘robots’ and ‘automation technologies’ interchangeably.
122 6 Looking to the Near Future

by capital (including both machines and software) and human labour. The allocation
of tasks to capital and labour determines the task content of production.

6.3.6 Robot-Based Enabling Products

Labour-saving technological progress has gradually moved from mechanical-muscle


machines to “mechanical-mind” machines. In particular, enabling products has been
gradually mutating toward robots. Robot-based enabling products are enabling
products capable of performing one or more tasks previously carried out by the
human mind, e.g. speech recognition and visual perception.

6.3.7 Examples

In order to identify robot-based enabling products, we have to verify that the product
in question encapsulates two features: first, the product reduces costs or enhances
efficiency (it is an enabling product); and second, the software replaces mental
functions.
Example 1 Hamburger-making robot
The most advanced robot cook is the hamburger maker developed by Momentum
Machines. The robot takes in raw meat, buns, condiments, sauces and seasonings,
and converts these into finished, bagged burgers (up to 120 burgers per hour).
Moreover, this smart machine allows consumers to customize their burgers, speci-
fying not only how they would like them cooked, but also the mix of meat in the
patty. The robot cook can be viewed as more hygienic since fewer workers come into
contact with the ingredients. Each machine costs under $US1 million. The
hamburger-making robot is expressly designed to displace two to three full-time
kitchen workers, thus saving fast-food companies $90,000 per franchise per year.6
To sum up, the hamburger-making robot is an enabling product that reduces
labour cost and increases efficiency (automated preparation is more hygienic), and
the software replaces the mental actions of human employees. Therefore, the robot
cook is a robot-based enabling product.

6
Momentum Machines co-founder Alexandros Vardakostas is devastatingly unambiguous: “Our
device isn’t meant to make employees more efficient,” he said. “It’s meant to completely obviate
them” as quoted in Wade Roush “Hamburgers, Coffee, Guitars, and Cars: A Report from Lemnos
Labs,” Xeconomy.com, 12 June 2012. Vardakostas and Steven Frehn, a mechanical engineer, will
open a burger shop in San Francisco where a robot prepares, cooks, and assembles burgers for the
relatively affordable price of $US6.00 (AU$8.10).
6.3 Key Terminology 123

Example 2 Robotic Process Automation (RPA)


Robotic Process Automation (RPA) is a technical term that refers to a
non-humanoid robot. The robot consists of a software that is quick to install and
configure, works on top of existing software, and replicates the mental actions a
human worker would make. It is particularly applicable in the areas of accounting
and finance.
The tasks performed by this robot include the following four: ① Pulls PDF
attachments from an e-mail inbox; ② Transposes the data in each PDF to a row in
a master Excel document, which is saved on the machine; ③ Logs into a web system
and the data from each record in the Excel document is entered into the system to
generate an invoice; and ④ Confirms process completion via e-mail.
It is both cost-reducing (4 min of work for the robot is equivalent to about 1 h of
work for a person) and efficiency-enhancing (the robot reduces the error rate to
almost nil and strengthens risk and control management). Many firms are unwilling
to talk publicly about RPA because of the impact of the software on staff – white
collar job losses are expected when a firm introduces the robot. To sum up, RPA is
an enabling product (reduces cost and increases efficiency) and is capable of
replacing mental actions. Therefore, RPA is a robot-based enabling product.
Example 3 WorkFusion
In RPA any repetitive task can be recorded and performed using a robot, that is, it
only works with simple lower level tasks. The execution of projects in large
corporations tends to be highly labour-intensive requiring non-repetitive tasks.
WorkFusion is a New York-based software robot company officially incorporated
in 2011. The product offered by WorkFusion consists of an intelligent software
platform that manages the execution of projects through a combination of automa-
tion and crowd sourcing. The software not only automates the management of
projects but also learns from experience.
The WorkFusion software initially classifies tasks into three groups: tasks that
can be directly automated; tasks that must be performed by in-house professionals;
and tasks that can be crowd sourced. Then, automatically post job listing on the
Internet and manage the recruitment and selection of qualified freelance workers.
Once the workers are hired, the software allocates tasks and evaluates performance.
WorkFusion uses quick-thinking AI systems to create bots that trim down work-
loads. Adam Devine, vice president of marketing for WorkFusion, said: “I think if
there is going to be an Oracle of intelligent automation, we are that company.” as
quoted in “WorkFusion using $35M in New Cash to Expand in Business Automa-
tion,” Xeconomy.com, 1 February 2017.
Quite obviously, the WorkFusion software ticks the two boxes to be classified as
a robot-based enabling product. The software reduces the need for in-house
employees, and, thereby, reduces costs. It also replaces mental actions because it
automatically matches tasks with the capability of individuals; moreover, if a par-
ticular worker is unable to complete a given assignment, the AI system will auto-
matically escalate that task to someone with the required skills.
124 6 Looking to the Near Future

It is clear that WorkFusion creates new opportunities for freelance workers. What
is not so obvious is whether the number of new freelance jobs created by the
software is greater than the number of in-house jobs destroyed by the robot-based
enabling products. We mention, in passing, that WorkFusion‘s learning algorithms
register the activities of the freelancers and generate the training data that will
gradually lead to their replacement with further automation. WorkFusion has
found that, as the system’s machine learning algorithms incrementally automate
the process further, costs typically drop by about 50% after a 2 year of operation
(Ford 2015, p. 98).
Example 4 Social robots
As machines become smarter than us, they are taking over jobs historically done
by humans. For example, social robots are designed to interact with people in a
manner that is consistent with human psychology. Their ability to engage people
along social and emotional dimensions is remarkable. Social robots not only hold a
basic conversation but also connect with you emotionally using eye contact. They
are making their mark in the health sector. These robot-based enabling products are
taking over nursing and physicians tasks. Apparently, people want to talk to robots
and even accept criticism from robots because they are not humans.
Example 5 World’s largest robot
Rio Tinto operates about 200 locomotives on more than 1700km of track in
Australia’s Pilbara region which is the origin of half the world’s iron ore exports.
These locomotives move iron ore from 16 inland mines to 4 port terminals in
Western Australia. In December 2018, Rio Tinto successfully deployed AutoHaul,
establishing the world’s largest robot and first automated heavy-haul, long distance
rail network. It is a driverless train system. The trains are operated hundreds of miles
away in an office block in Perth. Mr Ivan Vella, Rio Tinto’s head of iron ore
expressed that AutoHaul drives better than the best driver.
Before the introduction of AutoHaul, Rio Tinto had to shuttle drivers around the
sparsely populated Australian outback to switch train drivers three times for each
journey (a return journey is of the order of 500 miles). Needless to say, Rio Tinto’s
driverless system is a cost-reducing innovation. Its impact on train driver jobs is
obvious. It is also efficiency-enhancing. The different ways that human drivers run
locomotives leads to inconsistent wear-and-tear and fuel use. Human error accounts
for more than one-third of accidents.7

7
In November 2018, BHP was forced to derail a 268-wagon runaway train in the Pilbara region. The
train rolled away after its driver disembarked to inspect a wagon and failed to secure the brake.
6.3 Key Terminology 125

6.3.8 Section Summary

To fix ideas, we assemble in a single picture the main notions introduced in this


section (see Diagram 6.2). As new generations of robot-based enabling products are
developed, many non-routine jobs protected from automation will be pulled into the
routine category. Society has lawyers, accountants, architects, teachers and other
professionals to solve problems that are too complicated for us to handle ourselves.
Yet these jobs are increasingly under threat from Artificial Intelligence (AI) capable
of replacing the jobs of human experts.
Reverting to Diagram 6.1, it is not difficult to realize that underlying the propel-
ling factors of a creative economy are enabling products. Incessant creation and
adoption of new enabling products makes the creative economy evolve over time. In
the real world cost reductions and efficiency improvements come in 1001 different
forms. A proper subset of the set of enabling products is the collection of robot-based
enabling products.8

Diagram 6.2 Enabling products and robot-based enabling products

8
For readers unfamiliar with the language of sets, this means that a robot-based enabling product is
always an enabling product, but there are enabling products that are not robot-based enabling
products because they do not replace mental functions.
126 6 Looking to the Near Future

6.3.9 Marshall Decomposition Formula, Revisited

Robot-based enabling products may have negative or positive effects on employ-


ment. The negative effect (displacement effect) comes from the direct displacement
of workers by robots (capital takes over mental tasks previously performed by
workers). The positive effects are the counterbalancing forces, which push against
the displacement effect.
The counterbalancing forces may increase the demand for labour. For example,
productivity improvements in one sector due to new robots may expand employment
in other sectors and absorb the labour freed up from the tasks that are now performed
by robots, or when assembly lines in manufacturing plants substitute robotic arms for
workers these plants will require humans to service and maintain the robots. These
counterbalancing forces are encapsulated under the term compensating effect.
Invoking the Marshall Decomposition Formula, it is natural to write

Total Effect of
Robot‐based ¼ Displacement effect þ Compensating Effect
Enabling Products ðÞ ðþÞ

Which says that robot-based enabling products have two competing effects on the
demand for labour: one reduces the demand for labour (displacement effect) and the
other increases it (compensating effect). For example, software and computers
replace labour in some white-collar tasks (e.g. corporate librarians and administra-
tive assistants) and create new tasks (e.g. engine optimizers and webpage designers).
The important message conveyed by the Marshall Decomposition formula when
applied to robot-based enabling products is as follows. If the absolute value of the
displacement effect is greater than the compensating effect, there will be a reduction
in labour demand.

6.4 Robots: Friends or Foes?

Competition between humans and robots is a booming area of research –and


controversy. It should be emphasized that analysts do not disagree about jobs
vanishing in the future, they argue over whether these will be replaced by new
human jobs. Somewhat roughly, the controversy revolves around the dynamic
behaviour of the difference between the number of jobs taken by robots and the
number of jobs taken by humans.
6.4 Robots: Friends or Foes? 127

6.4.1 Technology Enthusiasts

Broadly speaking, the argument of the technology enthusiasts is as follows. Labour


has benefited from labour-saving technologies in a particular sector because these
technologies were accompanied by other technological advances conducive to the
creation of new labour-intensive tasks (in which humans have a competitive advan-
tage) in the same sector or in other sectors. A case in point is agricultural mechani-
zation. Circa the middle of the nineteenth century mechanization reduced
employment in the agricultural sector, but overall labour demand rose due to a
range of new tasks that were introduced in both manufacturing and services. In
brief, agricultural jobs were destroyed but many new manufacturing and services
jobs emerged.
Technology enthusiasts have a valid point. History shows that fast technological
progress did not provoke persistent unemployment because it created more jobs than
it destroyed. On this basis, some analysts believe that the dizzying speed of innova-
tion in AI, automation, and robotics we are witnessing will lead us to an economy in
which technological unemployment is not something to worry about. Workers will
shift into new economic sectors as has always been the case. Economies will adapt
and robots will create more jobs than they destroy. New technologies such as, for
example, the growing ubiquity of self-checkout at supermarkets and drug stores may
temporarily displace workers but a growing economy may quickly create jobs for
these workers.
In essence, the argument of the technology enthusiasts revolves around historical
extrapolations. They use history as proof that the advance of technology is always a
long-term economic blessing. History shows that James Watt, Thomas Boulton,
Thomas Alva Edison, Alexander Graham Bell, Henry Ford, Bill Gates, and many
others created new industries that more than replaced the work that was eliminated
by labour-saving innovations. The current transformation of the economy will create
an equally large opportunity.
According to Borland and Coelli (2017), automation anxiety cannot be justified
on the basis of the available historical evidence. These authors suggest that techno-
phobia emerges from ignorance of history and a human bias to feel that we live in
special times:
An absence of knowledge of history, the greater intensity of feelings about events which we
experience first-hand, and perhaps a desire to attribute significance to the times in which we
live, all contribute to this bias. The bias make us predisposed to believe that phenomena such
as technological change are having a more substantial and different effect today than at
earlier times. (Borland and Coelli 2017, p. 14)

It is not difficult to see that the enthusiast group claims: “What was true in the past
will be true in the future.” According to the enthusiasts, the creative economy of the
128 6 Looking to the Near Future

Diagram 6.3 Technology enthusiasts: convergence to a Panglossian economy

future will be a Panglossian economy where smart machines permanently assist


human workers without creating substantial involuntary unemployment.9 This line
of reasoning is schematically depicted in Diagram 6.3.

6.4.2 Technology Sceptics

Technology sceptics call into question predictions based on historical extrapolations.


The gloomiest of all sceptics is Martin Ford, a software entrepreneur and the
bestselling author of Rise of the Robots, a book that predicts a “jobless future.”
Ford (2015) points out that most jobs can be broken down into a series of routine
tasks, more and more of which can be done by robots. Under conditions of never
ending technological progress fuelled by profit-seeking innovation, it seems rash to
predict the future by projecting past experience. The Achilles heel of historical
extrapolations is not far to seek: “What was true in the past may not necessarily be

9
According to the Merriam-Webster dictionary, ‘Panglossian’ means ‘marked by the view that all is
for the best in this best of possible worlds: excessively optimistic.’ The origin of the adjective
‘Panglossian’ goes back to Voltaire's satirical novel Candide, published in 1759. Dr Pangloss –one
of the protagonists of this novel– was an optimist par excellence who claimed that “all is for the best
in this best of all possible worlds.” He kept his optimism intact even after witnessing and
experiencing great cruelty and suffering.
6.4 Robots: Friends or Foes? 129

true in the future.” For example, up until the first successful airplane was invented by
Wilbur and Orville Wright on December 17, 1903 it was an incontrovertible fact that
human beings strapped in heavier than air objects do not fly.10
The argument of the technology sceptics has sharp focus on innovations that
economise the use of labour but are not accompanied with a sufficient number of
new uses for labour. More precisely, the economic logic used by the sceptics to claim
that a creative economy harbours a tendency toward technological unemployment is
as follows. A creative economy is populated by profit-seeking firms. Profits are
inextricably linked to two goals: cost-minimization and efficiency enhancing.
Robot-based enabling products focus on these goals. There is always high interest
in these products (the supply of robot-based enabling products creates its own
demand). Consequently, technological progress is driven by a relentless progression
toward the production of better robot-based enabling products which, in turn, pro-
vokes pervasive human replacement.11
This simple economic logic suggests that creative economies may transform
themselves into economies in which technological unemployment is pervasive,
Robot Economies, for short. The thread of the argument presented by the sceptics
is summarized in Diagram 6.4.12

6.4.3 Resolving the Controversy: Preliminary Remarks

Consider an economy where all the negative and positive effects of automation on
employment have taken place at the end of year t. This means that at the end of year t
there will be a number representing the jobs taken by robots and a number revealing
the number of jobs taken by humans. A piece of notation is necessary here. From
now on,
R(t) denotes the number of jobs taken by robots at the end of year t;
H(t) denotes the number of jobs taken by humans at the end of year t; and
R(t) + H(t) is the total number of jobs in the economy at the end of year t.
As will become apparent, what matters in the controversy between technology
enthusiasts and technology sceptics is the temporal behaviour of the discrepancy
RðtÞ  HðtÞ.

10
The preceding criticism does not of itself prove that the technology enthusiast’s arguments are
logically inconsistent. A logical argument based on the behaviour of a creative economy is required
to reinforce the historical approach (e.g. showing that labour-augmenting innovations will dominate
labour-saving innovations).
11
The tacit assumption is that the displacement effect is not counterbalanced by other economic
forces (lumped together under the label “compensating effect”).
12
More on technological unemployment and the ‘robot economy’ in Chap. 7.
130 6 Looking to the Near Future

Diagram 6.4 Technology sceptics: convergence to a Robot Economy

Example 6 Super simplified example


To get a sense of the meaning of the discrepancy R(t) – H(t), it helps to construct a
super simplified example. Suppose that the chief executive of a bank implements a
restructure announcing that at the end of 2020 the bank will slash 6000 employees
from its workforce and hire 2000 digital people with outstanding capabilities in the
use of smart machines useful to automate financial activities. To simplify things,
suppose in addition that the bank is the economy. At the end of 2020 the number of
jobs taken by the smart machines will be

Rð2020Þ ¼ 6000 jobs

and the number of jobs taken by the technology people will be

Hð2020Þ ¼ 2000 jobs

As a result, the restructure of the bank will lead to a net reduction of 4000 human
jobs. In symbols,

Rð2020Þ  Hð2020Þ ¼ 4000 jobs


6.4 Robots: Friends or Foes? 131

6.4.4 Resolving the Controversy: Not Possible, Time Will Tell

In broad terms, the controversy between enthusiasts versus sceptics can be easily
outlined. The viewpoint of the technology enthusiast group is

RðtÞ < HðtÞ ðyear after yearÞ ð6:1Þ

In contrast, the claim of the technology sceptic group is that the discrepancy

RðtÞ  HðtÞ ð6:2Þ

will grow increasingly rapidly year after year, and technological unemployment will
happen in the future. Who is right: the enthusiasts (mostly orthodox economists and
historians) who claim that in the end technology always creates more jobs than it
destroys or the sceptics (mostly perceptive economists and futurists) who say this
time is different and robots will take an intolerable number of human jobs?
Regrettably, the controversy is inconclusive because the implications of a General
Purpose Technology (GPT) such as automation cannot be known ex-ante. If we were
technologically omniscient, that is, if all the implications of a new technology were
instantly known, we could resolve the debate right off. Short of such powers, we
have to admit that predictability of the type that would yield acceptably firm
expectations of direction and magnitude is not possible.

6.4.5 Two Predictions About the Next Economy

Readers might be asking themselves: if the controversy cannot be resolved in


advance, what is the value of the debate? We believe it has value because it confronts
us with a choice between two predictions about the next economy. First prediction,
robots will become an increasingly important enabling technology and the next
economy will be populated by smart machines that permanently assist humans
without creating intolerable unemployment. The fear that jobs are under threat is
overdone. Work is changing, not disappearing. Or, second prediction, the creative
economy will gradually transform itself into a Robot Economy. Technological
progress driven by cost-minimization and job destruction will be accelerating. In
this case, it would be desirable to prepare the appropriate responses well before the
impact of such change.

6.4.6 Robotize or Perish

Our choice is the second prediction. Our line of argument is economic common
sense. What is the catalyst behind the dizzying speed of innovation concerning
132 6 Looking to the Near Future

robot-based enabling products? A partial answer is cost-minimization. If an enabling


firm introduced a robot, which is cheap to buy, and able do a job that a human worker
could perform, every economically rational employer would prefer robots because
they provide at least equal capability at a lower cost. Even those managers who
initially resist replacing humans with robots eventually would have little choice but
to reduce the number of workers to make the transition once their competitors do
so. Consequently, profit-seeking employers would replace most human workers with
robot-based enabling products. Productivity and output could increase dramatically,
but these robots would bring severe dislodgements to the labour market. Unfortu-
nately, if the only argument against the iron law “Robotize or Perish” is that “People
need jobs” then it is not a good argument from the economic point of view.
Corporate social responsibility is difficult to reconcile with shareholder returns.
Recent technological progress has been biased toward the creation of robot-based
enabling products. The consequence of this trend has been declining labour share in
national income. Regrettably, we are not convinced that the economy of the future
will be a Panglossian economy.

6.5 The Future of Employment: Anticipation Exercises

The robots are coming for our jobs. How many robots and which jobs? No one
knows. There have been several reports looking at the future of employment. To
assess the future of human work, researchers carry out anticipation exercises. The
common presumption underlying these efforts is that predicting occupational and
skills demand is feasible. There are two approaches: the Occupation-based approach
and the Task-based approach. Two limitations of these approaches should be
emphasized at the outset. First, they only estimate which jobs are potentially
automatable – not how many will actually be automated. Second, they do not assess
the potential for job creation in occupations and tasks complemented by automation.
Note 1 First Terminological Digression
Before going into these exercises, it is convenient to specify the meaning of some
terms particularly relevant in the context of anticipation exercises. The generally
accepted definition of ‘job’ is well known: a job is an individual piece of work
involving different tasks done in one’s occupation. For example, a dentist job
involves heterogeneous tasks within the occupation dentistry; a bookkeeper job
involves heterogeneous tasks within the occupation clerical work; and so on. The
tasks associated with a particular job require appropriate skills to perform the job
satisfactorily.
6.5 The Future of Employment: Anticipation Exercises 133

6.5.1 Occupation-Based Approach

The revival of the “machinery question” happened on 17 September 2013 with the
study “The Future of Employment: How Susceptible Are Jobs to Computerization?”
The authors of the study, Carl Frey and Michael Osborne, employed an occupation-
based approach which assumes that whole occupations rather than single job-tasks
can be robotized. For example, the occupation ‘hamburger-making cook’ consists of
many tasks such as taking in raw meat, buns, condiments, sauces and seasonings,
and converting these ingredients into finished, bagged burgers. The hamburger-
making robot introduced by Momentum Machines may destroy this occupation
and the corresponding tasks.
Frey and Osborne (2013) used a sample of occupations (hand-labelled by
machine-learning experts as strictly automatable or not automatable) to quantify
the probability of automation. The computation of the probability of automation
takes into account three bottlenecks to automation: perception and manipulation,
social intelligence, and ideation.
Note 2 Second Terminological Digression
In the present context, perception tasks refer to identifying people, objects and
their properties. Robots are still unable to match the depth and breadth of human
perception. Social intelligence is the ability to get along with others and to get them
to cooperate with us. Contract negotiation is a good example. “Emotional intelli-
gence” is inextricably linked to social intelligence. Emotions tend to drive our
behaviour and impact people –positively or negatively.13
Ideation or creative intelligence is the process of creating new ideas by making
unfamiliar combinations of familiar notions. The challenge here is to articulate
combinations that “make sense.” Ideation is often described as “thinking outside
the box,” and this characterization signals a competitive advantage of human labour
over digital labour. It seems unlikely that occupations requiring a high degree of
creative intelligence will be automated in the next decades.
Frey and Osborne (2013) estimated the probability of automation for 702 occu-
pations. Any occupation with a probability of automation of above 70% was
classified as at ‘high risk of automation.’ They predicted that in the US 47% of
employment was at high risk over the next one to two decades.14
So, which occupations are most vulnerable? As indicated in Table 6.1, many
workers in sales and services (telemarketers, accountants and auditors, retail

13
Emotional intelligence is a term created by two researchers – Peter Salavoy and John Mayer – and
popularized by Dan Goleman in his 1996 homonymous book. It is generally agreed that this kind of
intelligence is the ability to recognize, understand and manage our emotions as well as recognize,
understand and influence the emotions of others. Learning how to manage emotions is especially
important for us, humans, and extraordinarily difficult for them, robots.
14
The Frey and Osborne (2013) study was published in Technological Forecasting and Social
Change in 2017. See Frey and Osborne (2017).
134 6 Looking to the Near Future

Table 6.1 Probability of automation of different occupations, 2013


Occupation Probability of automation (1.00 ¼ Certain)
Telemarketers 0.99
Accountant and auditors 0.94
Retail salespeople 0.92
Technical writers 0.89
Real-estate sale agents 0.86
Word processors and typists 0.81
Clergy 0.008
Athletic trainers 0.007
Dentists 0.004
Recreational therapists 0.003
Source Frey and Osborne (2013)

salespeople, technical writers, real-estate sale agents, and word processors and
typists) face high risk of automation. Clergy, athletic trainers, dentists, and recrea-
tional therapists are safe.

6.5.2 Task-Based Approach

The preceding findings have not gone unchallenged. The realism of the Frey-
Osborne occupation-based approach was questioned by Arntz et al. (2016). They
proffered a different approach which recognizes that an occupation usually consists
of performing a collection of tasks, and argue that automation does not necessarily
destroy all tasks within an occupation. “Rather than assuming that it is occupations
that are displaced by machines, we argue that it is certain tasks that can be
displaced.” (Arntz et al. 2016, p. 8).
The application of the task-based approach resulted in a much lower probability
of automation compared to the occupation-based approach. Indeed, using the task-
based approach Arntz et al. (2016) showed that Frey and Osborne (2013) and other
studies grossly overestimated the risk of automation:
We find that applying a task-based approach results in a much lower risk of automation
compared to the occupation-based approach. For instance, while Frey and Osborne find
that 47% of US jobs are automatable, our corresponding figure is only 9%. (Arntz et al.
2016, p. 8)

6.5.3 Predicting New Occupations

A recent study about the future of employment shows both what we can expect and
where we should be uncertain Bakhshi et al. (2017). The report The Future of Skills
6.6 Rational Response to the March of the Robots 135

finds that 18.7% of the US labour force and 21.2 of that in Britain are in occupations
vulnerable to technology disruption. Unlike other studies, they predict what kinds of
new occupations may come into existence.
Nowadays, technology is not having a big disruptive impact on human jobs.
Collaboration between humans and robots is not unusual. For example, the company
Zume cooks made-to-order pizza using humans and robots. Having said this, we
have to position ourselves because the march of the robots is unstoppable.

6.6 Rational Response to the March of the Robots

To start with the obvious, as technology changes the skills needed for each occupa-
tion will have to adjust. Workers will have to acquire new skills. What do we know
about learning new skills? The learning curve describes the mastery of a skill over
time. As a human learns a new skill, the newly acquired ability builds on itself, and
so the learning curve starts out looking like the exponential growth. But skills tend to
be bounded, so as the new expertise is mastered, the law of diminishing returns sets
in and growth in mastery levels off.15 The learning curve appears to be universal.
Slugs, for example, follow the learning curve when learning how to ascend a new
tree in search of leaves. But there is a remarkable difference between humans and
slugs: humans are capable of innovation. Thinking of the next economy, we ask:
what is the practical use of the learning curve? The learning curve is too general to be
useful. It does not provide guidance for the acquisition of relevant skills.
We believe that a smooth and successful adjustment to the next economy requires
a rational response involving two distinct stages. First, we have to reinvent ourselves
as ”T-shaped knowledge workers”; and second, we have to manufacture our per-
sonal “protective belt” against robots.

6.6.1 T-shaped Knowledge Workers

To become a T-shaped knowledge worker one has to follow a two-step procedure:


first, acquire deep expertise in at least one discipline; and second, apply that
expertise within a team and be ready to develop new skills as opportunities arise.
The order of the steps is crucial: you have to walk before you can run. These steps are
highlighted in Diagram 6.5.

15
A learning curve looks like an S leaning to the right because exponential growth is followed by a
levelling off.
136 6 Looking to the Near Future

Diagram 6.5 The two steps to become a T-shaped knowledge worker

6.6.2 Classifying Tasks

The standard classification of tasks distinguishes between workplace activities using


a matrix.
• Cognitive/Manual Tasks: The dividing line between cognitive and manual tasks
is not straightforward. Almost all manual tasks are based on acquired knowledge,
and therefore cognitive, but certain tasks are predominantly manual.
• Routine/Non-routine Tasks: Routine tasks are, by definition, tasks that can be
accomplished by following a set of explicit rules. By contrast, in the case of
non-routine tasks the procedures for accomplishing these tasks are not sufficiently
well understood to be codified. Non-routine tasks are insusceptible of automation.

Note 3 Shifting definitional boundary


The allocation of examples to the “routine/non-routine” dichotomy is not in the
nature of a “once and for all” allocation. What sort of task is “driving a car”, routine
or non-routine? The case of driverless cars illustrates the shifting definitional
boundary around what it means for work to be ‘routine.’ In the chapter “Why People
Still Matter” Levy and Murnane (2004) expressed that driving in traffic is a
non-routine task in a fundamental way (due to the difficulties of replicating human
perception). Cars that can drive themselves using artificial intelligence software able
to mimic the decisions made by a human driver already exist.

                        

The classification of tasks is shown in Table 6.2 together with some illustrative
examples. This table allows us to identify six (6) categories of tasks. As in all
6.6 Rational Response to the March of the Robots 137

Table 6.2 Six categories of tasks with examples

classificatory schemes, the distinctions are not clear-cut. It is not perfect, but it is
useful to fix ideas.16 Table 6.2 has proven a workhorse for economists. Nevertheless,
we have to be cautious with the illustrations taken for the real world. Publicans
(Category 4) is a case in point. A bar in Strasbourg became the first in France to
employ a robot (its name is Walter) to serve cocktails.17

6.6.3 Mapping Skills to Tasks

Mapping skills to the tasks performed by human labour is the natural next step.
Low-skill labour refers to blue collar and some white collar workers. Generally
speaking, the “right” skills for the future tend to be associated with categories ②, ④,
and ⑥. For example, social skills associated with category ⑥ provide the tools for
efficient coordination which underpins a productive workplace – these tools are
subtleties that robot-based enabling products have yet to master. The empirical
evidence supports the view that significant job growth since 1980 has been in
occupations that are relatively social-skill intensive (category ⑥).

6.6.4 Skill-biased Technological Progress

Skill-biased technological progress is a shift in the production technology that


favours skilled over unskilled labour by increasing its relative productivity and,

16
The line of separation between cognitive and non-manual tasks is difficult to draw. We use this
distinction simply because it helps to organize thinking.
17
See “Robot Bartender is as Rude as the Real Thing,” The Times, 10 April, 2019. The bar owner
said Walter would cost more than employing a human but was a good investment because of the
publicity.
138 6 Looking to the Near Future

therefore, its relative demand. Recent technological change has been skill-biased
because it has increased the demand for highly educated workers (performing tasks
in category ②) while reducing demand for less educated workers whose tasks
usually fall into categories ① and ③. Generally speaking, categories ④ and ⑥
tend to be technological change-resistant. However, Artificial Intelligence (AI) may
increasingly automate non-routine cognitive tasks performed by high-skilled
workers.

6.6.5 Two Types of Automation Technologies

AI can be thought of as a new form of automation that may allow tasks that were
previously thought out of reach from automation to succumb. In particular, AI
applications are poised to increasingly encroach on the skills associated with cate-
gory ②. For this reason, Acemoglu and Restrepo (2017b) separate two types of
automation.
First, high-skill automation allows robots to compete against high-skill labour in
complex tasks. The new generation in AI technology, in conjunction with big data
and machine learning, already has the potential to perform many tasks in which
human judgement was previously thought to be indispensable. Second, low-skill
automation expands the range of tasks that robots can perform at the low end of the
complexity distribution of tasks.
Occupations facing at least partial automation from advances in AI include
accounting, valuation of property, financial planning, management consulting, mort-
gage origination, paralegals, and various medical specialties including general
practice, radiology or even surgery.

6.6.6 Investment in Human Capital

Investment in human capital with particular regard to written communication,


analytic reasoning, problem solving, and critical thinking will be increasingly
important as routine tasks become automated and the need for “non-digitally
capturable intelligence” increases. The ability to formulate interesting new questions
seems to be uniquely human.
We predict that people who are good at idea creation will continue to have a comparative
advantage over digital labour for some time to come, and will find themselves in demand. In
other words, we believe that employers now and for some time to come will, when looking
for talent, follow the advice attributed to the Enlightenment sage Voltaire: “Judge a man for
his questions, not his answers.” (Brynjolfsson and McAfee, 2014, p. 192)
6.7 Chapter Summary 139

6.6.7 Components of the Protective Belt

The components of the protective belt are attributes that robots cannot easily
replicate, supersede or nullify. It should be clear that these attributes are the ones
in categories, ②, ④ and ⑥. In a nutshell, the future for T-knowledge workers with
skills to perform non-routine tasks is bright.

6.6.8 Australia’s Chief Scientist

The foregoing does not mean that the next generation of workers should be gener-
alists. As indicated by the vertical bar in Diagram 6.5, there must be deep expertise in
at least one discipline. A discipline is like a ladder of cumulative knowledge. One
has to put in the effort to climb it little by little, gradually. Australia’s Chief Scientist
Dr Alan Finkel has expressed concern about the notion that students should special-
ize in nothing at all. We, as a nation, will go badly astray “if we take away from the
next generation of workers the disciplinary ladders that we climbed ourselves.”
(Finkel 2018).
Encouraging creativity is of fundamental importance. However, it is unlikely that
new ideas with economic value can be created without subject knowledge. Further-
more, trying to be creative without relevant previous knowledge carries the risk of
reinventing the wheel.

6.7 Chapter Summary

• Assuming relentless progression toward automation, one question immediately


suggests itself. Does the creative economy harbour a tendency toward techno-
logical unemployment?
• Concerns about the downside of new technology go back to 200 years ago.
• The rising standard of living of the masses emerging from the interaction between
technological progress and the profit motive – which Schumpeter emphasized – is
an incontrovertible historical fact.
• Robot-based enabling products reduce costs or increase efficiency by replacing
mental functions such as human informational grunt work.
• Robot-based enabling products have negative and positive effects on employ-
ment. These products replace some kinds of human labour (they displace workers
from the tasks they were previously performing) but may generate greater
demand for labour in non-automated tasks and in other sectors. In general, the
full impact of automation is difficult to predict.
• Technology enthusiasts use history as a proof that the positive effects will be
greater than the negative effects. For them, current automation, like previous
140 6 Looking to the Near Future

waves of technological progress, will increase labour demand, and, thereby,


employment and wages.
• Technology sceptics use economic logic to claim that the creative economy will
generate technological unemployment and converge to a Robot Economy in the
near future. They see the creative economy as the harbinger of wide spread
joblessness.
• The controversy between enthusiasts versus sceptics is inconclusive. It is impos-
sible to predict the evolution of a General Purpose Technology (GPT) such as
automation. GPTs generate a long chain of interweaving links of technological
and social change in a sequence of uncertain speed and mixture of successes and
failures.
• To foresee the future of employment, researchers carry out anticipation exercises.
According to the occupation-based approach, 47% of US jobs are automatable.
However, the corresponding figure emerging from the task-based approach is
only 9%.
• Faced with this uncertainty, how can we defend ourselves from the unforgiving
advance of robot-based enabling products? We believe it is a good defence to
become a T-knowledge worker (not a generalist) and develop a protective belt
with emphasis on skills associated with non-routine tasks.

6.8 Concluding Comment

Before going on to consider expert opinions on the impact of automation a remark is


in order. All the themes considered in this –and the next– chapter are currently under
active investigation by economists. For example, the Journal of Economic Perspec-
tives (Vol 33, Issue 2, Spring 2019) contains a symposium on Automation and
Employment synthetizing recent developments on the research frontier. This sug-
gests that innovation as an economic activity topic and its implications for the future
of employment will have to be taught at the major centres of economics learning, if
we want our students to be prepared for ongoing developments in the creative
economy.

Appendix I: Expert Opinions on the Impact of Automation

In general, economists are convinced that technological progress has always been
labour-augmenting on the whole in the past and is likely to remain so in the future.
Consequently, automation will not prevent technological progress from being
labour-augmenting. This time is not different.
Appendix I: Expert Opinions on the Impact of Automation 141

Australian Poll

Surveys carried out in Australia and the US tend to confirm the predominant view
among economists, namely: the possibility that millions of people may be at risk of
technological unemployment should be dismissed. In October 2017, the following
questions were put to the Economic Society of Australia’s National Economic Panel:
Question 1: “Holding labour market institutions and job training fixed, rising use of
robots and artificial intelligence is likely to increase substantially the number of
workers in Australia who are unemployed for long periods.”
Question 2: “Rising use of robots and artificial intelligence in Australia is likely to
create benefits large enough that they could be used to compensate those workers
who are substantially negatively affected for their lost wages.”

Comparison of Responses

The same two questions were put to eminent US economists in September 2017
(in Questions 1 and 2, ‘US’ rather than ‘Australia’). The majority of respondents to
the Australian poll answered Question 1 in the negative and the vast majority of
respondents to Question 2 answered the question affirmatively.
The comparison of the responses by Australian economists and those made by US
economists who were asked essentially the same questions can be seen in Table 6.3.
A glance at this table shows that the responses to the first proposition differed
significantly. It seems that there are more technology enthusiasts in Australia than
in the US. On the second proposition, economists from Australia and the US are in
substantial agreement.

Table 6.3 Experts in Australia and US: a comparison of opinions


Questions about rising use of robots Australian US
and artificial intelligence economists economists Comparison
“Holding labour market institutions 58% 21% Significant disagreement
and job training fixed, rising use of (Disagree) (Disagree) between economists from
robots and artificial intelligence is Australia and the US
likely to increase substantially the
number of workers in Australia
(US) who are unemployed for long
periods.”
“Rising use of robots and artificial 73% 88% Substantial agreement
intelligence in Australia (US) is likely (Agree) (Agree) between economists from
to create benefits large enough that Australia and the US
they could be used to compensate
those workers who are substantially
negatively affected for their lost
wages.”
142 6 Looking to the Near Future

Overview of the Australian Poll by Borland and Potts

Professor Jeff Borland and Professor Jason Potts overviewed the results of the
Australian poll. According to Professor Borland,
The proposition that rising use of robots and AI is likely to lead to a substantial number of
workers being unemployed for longer periods was disagreed with by a majority of respon-
dents (58%). Mostly this was based on the belief that while new technologies destroy jobs,
they will also create an approximately equal number of new jobs. The history of new
technologies having this balanced effect on job destruction and job creation was also
emphasized. (Borland and Potts 2017)

Furthermore,
The proposition that new technologies would bring sufficient gains to allow workers who are
negatively affected to be compensated brought forth an even larger majority –in this case
agreeing (73%). In fact, a reading of the comments suggests that the support for the
proposition was almost unanimous. Most of those who disagreed with the proposition
seem to have done so because they did not believe that compensation would actually be
provided, rather than because it would not be feasible to provide compensation. But this was
a viewpoint that was also shared by many of those who supported the proposition. (Borland
and Potts 2017)

To sum up, a majority of eminent Australian economists believe that the impact of
technological progress on the Australian labour market and income distribution
should be relatively limited. There is nothing to worry about.
Beyond any doubt, the October 2017 Survey conducted by the Economic Society
of Australia produced interesting results. However, as pointed out by Professor
Potts, the survey is not free of difficulties:
There was a fair amount of ambiguity and wiggle room in the questions. First, labour market
institutions and job training were assumed to be held fixed, which is a useful analytical
simplification, but eschews a primary mechanism by which adaptation actually takes place.
Also, ‘for long periods’ is open to interpretation along the lines of the economist’s priors.
‘Substantially’ negatively affected is a subjective judgement call. The upshot is that this poll
was inevitably somewhat of a Rorschach test about political economy priors. (Borland and
Potts 2017)

As a reminder, “priors” are convictions that are held to be true by an individual or


a group regarding events; “upshot” means the conclusion or the result, the final issue;
and a “Rorschach test” is a projective psychological test that uses a subject's
interpretation of 10 standard black or coloured inkblot designs to assess personality
traits and emotional tendencies.

Delloite Report: The Panglossian Economy is Attainable

The Path to Prosperity: Why the Future of Work is Human is report # 7 in the
Building the Lucky Country series. The Delloite Report (2019) evaluates three
propositions concerning the future of work, namely:
Appendix I: Expert Opinions on the Impact of Automation 143

Proposition 1: Robots will take the jobs.


Proposition 2: People will have lots of jobs over their careers.
Proposition 3: People will work anywhere but the office.
Based on available evidence today, the authors of the report reject the preceding
proposition as myths. According to the media release on 12 June 2019,
The report dispels these three myths that tend to dominate discussions around the future of
work.
Myth 1: Robots will take the jobs. Technology-driven change is accelerating around the
world, yet unemployment is close to record lows, including in Australia (where it is
around the lowest since 2011). New technologies will have the capacity to automate
many tasks, but also create as many jobs as they kill, and employment is growing in roles
that are hardest to automate.
Myth 2: People will have lots of jobs over their careers. Despite horror headlines, work is
becoming more secure, not less, and Australians are staying in their jobs longer than
ever. And nor is the gig economy taking over. Casual jobs are a smaller share of all jobs
than 20 years ago, and that share hasn’t moved in over a decade. The rate of self-
employment has also been falling for almost 50 years and is at a record low.
Myth 3: People will work anywhere but the office. The office isn’t going away any time
soon, and city CBDs will remain a focal point for workers. More people are working
flexibly, but on a given day only one in every 25 workers work remotely, even though
almost one in five Australian employers offers the ability for staff to work from home.
Being physically close to other creative people is becoming more important, not less, and
working together helps us collaborate and socialise, and provides infrastructure and
support.

Deloitte Access Economics’ forecasting of Australia’s supply and demand of


skills is based on a variety of data sources, modelling techniques and assumptions to
produce a detailed view of the future states of Australia’s skills.
As in any forecasting exercise, the predictions tend to depend on the assumptions.
The Delloite Report (2019) offers a cryptic explanation of the assumptions and
methodology in Appendix A: Skills supply and demand forecasting. For example,
We assume that while there may be a mismatch in the individual skills being supplied and
demanded in an occupation, the total amount of skills within an occupation is equal in
history.
The total skill demanded within an occupation and the distribution of each skill supplied
within an occupation allows us to a) scale up the total skill level within an occupation and
b) do so by the proportional distribution of the skills missing. (Delloite Report 2019,
p. 44)

One of the predictions emerging from the Delloite Report (2019) is that more than
80% of the jobs created between now and 2030 will be for knowledge workers, and
two-thirds of the jobs will be strongly reliant on soft skills. Regrettably, this result
cannot be considered as a confutation of Proposition 1 simply because the report
remains silent about the number of human jobs that will be created between now and
2030. To disprove Proposition 1, it is necessary to show that the number of jobs
taken by humans will be greater than the number of jobs taken by robots.
Having said this, we believe that the advice coming from Sir John Richard Hicks
is valid. To repeat what we quoted in Chap. 1, Sect. 1.4,
144 6 Looking to the Near Future

But even if our propositions are weak, it does not follow that they are useless. Far from it. It
is better to have some knowledge of what to expect than no knowledge at all. Prognostica-
tions of the future have to be made, as a basis for current action, and it is very desirable that
they should be as good as possible. But we should see them for what they are. It is not
desirable that more should be claimed for them than they deserve. (Hicks 1984, p. 217)

Selected References

Acemoglu D, Restrepo P (2017a) Robots and jobs: evidence from US labour markets. National
Bureau of Economic research, working paper 23285. http://w.w.w.nber.org/papers/w23285. pp
1–40
Acemoglu D, Restrepo P (2017b) Low-skill and high-skill automation. National Bureau of Eco-
nomic Research, working paper 24119 http://w.w.w.nber.org/papers/w23285 1-31. Forthcom-
ing Journal of Human Capital
Acemoglu D, Restrepo P (2019) Automation and new tasks: how technology displaces and
reinstates labour. J Econ Perspect 33:3–30
Arntz M, Gregory T, Zierahn U (2016) The risk of automation for jobs in OECD countries. OECD
Social employment and migration working paper no.23285
Bakhshi H, Downing JM, Osborne MA, Philippe S (2017) The future of skills. Employment in
2030. Pearson and Nesta, London
Borland J, Coelli M (2017) Are robots taking our jobs? University of Melbourne working paper, pp
1–26.
Borland J, Potts J (2017) Robotics, AI and the future of work. Economic Society of Australia,
November
Brynjolfsson E, McAfee A (2014) The second machine age: work, progress, and prosperity in a
time of brilliant technologies. W.W. Norton & company, New York
Delloite Report (2019) The path to prosperity: why the future of work is human. Building the Lucky
Country Series # 7
Finkel A (2018) Ladder of success starts with the disciplines. The Australian, November 28
Ford M (2015) The rise of the robots. Technology and the threat of mass unemployment. Oneworld
Publications, London
Frey C, Osborne M (2013) The future of employment: how susceptible are jobs to computerization?
Oxford University Press, Oxford
Frey C, Osborne M (2017) The future of employment: how susceptible are jobs to computerization.
Technol Forecast Soc Chang 114:254–280
Hicks JR (1984) Is economics a science. Interdiscip Sci Rev 9:213–219
Keynes JM (1930) “Economic possibilities for our grandchildren” in the Collected Writings of John
Maynard Keynes, volume IX. In: Essays in persuasion, vol 1972. Macmillan Press, London, pp
321–332
Levy F, Murnane R (2004) The new division of labour: how computers are creating the next job
market. Princeton University Press, Princeton
Marshall A (1966) Principles of economics. Macmillan, London. First published in 1890
Marx K (1906) Capital: a critique of political economy. Modern Library, New York. First published
in 1867
Porter M, Heppelman J (2018) Whiteboard session: why every organization needs an AR strategy.
Harvard Business Review Video
Ricardo D (1911) The principles of political economy and taxation. Everyman’s Library, London.
First published in 1817
Schumpeter JA (2010) Capitalism, socialism, and democracy, with an introduction by Joseph
E. Stiglitz. Routledge Classics, London/New York. First published in 1942
Chapter 7
Looking to the Distant Future

Contents
7.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 146
7.2 Technological Unemployment Revisited . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 147
7.2.1 Hypothetical Example . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 148
7.2.1.1 Tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 148
7.2.1.2 Diagrams Derived from Tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 149
7.2.1.3 Computing Changes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 150
7.2.1.4 Detecting Technological Unemployment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 152
7.2.1.5 Superimposing Diagrams . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 152
7.3 Demarcating the Notion of a Robot Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 153
7.3.1 No Generally Agreed Definition . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154
7.3.2 Whatls.com Definition . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154
7.3.3 Proffered Definition of Robot Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154
7.3.4 Hypothetical Example (Cont.) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 155
7.4 Is the Robot Economy Near? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 156
7.5 The Robot Economy Paradox . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 158
7.5.1 Increasing Returns . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 158
7.5.2 The Paradox, Stated . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 158
7.5.3 Norbert Wiener: A Forerunner of the Paradox . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 159
7.5.4 Resolving the Paradox . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 159
7.5.4.1 Tentative Solution # 1: Introduce a Universal Basic Income . . . . . . . . . . 160
7.5.4.2 Tentative Solution # 2: Tax Robots . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 160
7.5.4.3 Tentative Solution # 3: Replace Mindset . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 161
7.6 Schumpeter’s Famous Prophecy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 162
7.7 Arthur’s Prophecy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 164
7.8 Chapter Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 165
Appendices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 166
Appendix J: Technological Progress in the Twenty-First Century . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 166
Technological Progress: Digital . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 167
Technological Progress: Exponential . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 168
Technological Progress: Combinatorial . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 170
Digression: Exponential Growth and Chess . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 171
Wrapping Up: Exponential Versus Combinatorial Growth . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 173
Appendix K: Robots, Artificial Intelligence, and Technological Singularity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 173
Robots: Origin of the Term and Rules of Behaviour . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 173
Artificial Intelligence: Definition and a Small Sample of Successes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 174
Technological Singularity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 175
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 176

© Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. 2020 145


J. E. Fernandez-Pol, C. Harvie, Understanding the Creative Economy and the Future
of Employment, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-1652-8_7
146 7 Looking to the Distant Future

Concise Preview
• The key question in this (final) chapter is: what would a creative economy look
like in the distant future?
• There is a robot economy narrative conveying the message that the future belongs
to the robots.
• Due to ubiquitous automation, the economy of the distant future could lead to
pervasive unemployment and insufficient aggregate demand.
• The creative economy may be the victim of its own economic success leading to
the breakdown of capitalism.
• Schumpeter’s famous prophesy was that capitalism will destroy itself, but the
reasons he gave were sociological, not economical.
• Technological progress is advancing at a dizzying speed. The engine of current
technological progress is propelled by three mutually reinforcing characteristics:
digitization, exponential growth of computer power, and the combinatorial nature
of innovation. These characteristics are briefly explained in Appendix J.
• Appendix K succinctly describes the so-called “technological singularity” and
points out its immediate economic implications.

7.1 Introduction

Even a casual glance at newspaper articles reveals the existence of a ubiquitous


narrative that stimulates anxiety about the convergence toward an automated econ-
omy in which human unemployment is pervasive. The reader may also detect this
anxiety by paging through influential books such as The Second Machine Age by
Brynjolfsson and McAfee (2014) or The Rise of the Robots by Ford (2015). For lack
of a better name we will refer to it as the robot economy narrative. This narrative is
not absurdly illogical. On the contrary, it is based on varying degrees of truth.1
Somewhat arbitrarily, we can say that the robot economy narrative has its origins
in the rigorous description of the ‘second economy’ (or virtual economy) provided
by Arthur (2011). The mid-1990s marks the beginning of a bifurcation of the real
economy so that a physical economy coexists and interacts with a virtual economy of
algorithms and machines. In the virtual economy business processes “are taking
place in an unseen domain that is strictly digital.”
Arthur (2011) distinguishes “producing prosperity” from “distributing prosper-
ity.” The virtual economy will produce prosperity but it may not produce enough
human jobs:
(. . .) The second economy will certainly be the engine of growth and the provider of
prosperity for the rest of this century and beyond, but it may not provide jobs, so there
may be prosperity without full access for many. This suggests to me that the main challenge
of the economy is shifting from producing prosperity to distributing prosperity. The second
economy will produce wealth no matter what we do; distributing the wealth has become the
main problem. For centuries, wealth has traditionally been apportioned in the West through
jobs, and jobs have always been forthcoming. When farm jobs disappeared, we still had
manufacturing jobs, and when these disappeared we migrated to service jobs. With this

1
We mention in Chap. 1 that a narrative is a telling story that attaches meaning and significance to it.
7.2 Technological Unemployment Revisited 147

digital transformation, the last repository of jobs is shrinking –fewer of us in the future may
have white-collar business process jobs– and we face a problem. (Arthur 2011, p. 7) [Italics
in original]

The robot economy narrative went ‘viral’ with the release of the study “The Future
of Employment: How Susceptible Are Jobs to Computerization?” by Frey and
Osborne (2013). This study provoked widespread anxiety about the future of work.
In this (final) chapter we ask: assuming increasing returns to automation, what
would a creative economy look like in the distant future? We can only speculate
about a possible answer to this formidable question. Our speculative argument will
be based on elementary economic logic. To articulate the line of reasoning, we need
to revisit Keynes’s definition of technological unemployment and demarcate the
concept of a ‘robot economy.’
As will become apparent, the possibility that in the long-run a creative economy
may be the victim of its own economic success cannot easily be overlooked. This
possibility of a break down in capitalism is reminiscent of Schumpeter’s famous
prophecy, namely: capitalism will destroy itself, which can be found in his 1942
book Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. It is well known that the reasons he
gave to justify the collapse of capitalism are sociological, not economical.

7.2 Technological Unemployment Revisited

“Technological unemployment” is conceptually a rather subtle notion and is not


trivial to calculate. When you can express in numbers what you are talking about you
gain further understanding about it. This is why we are going to illustrate the concept
of technological unemployment by using a few numerical tables and figures. The key
variables are the number of jobs taken by robots R(t) and the number of jobs taken by
humans H(t).2
Note 1 Notational digression
We cannot proceed any further without introducing a piece of technical notation.
We need a symbol to represent the difference between the number of jobs taken by
robots at the end of the year t+1, denoted by R(t+1), and the number of jobs taken by
robots at the end of year t, R(t). The symbol conventionally used to denote the
change in the value of a variable is the Greek letter Δ. The change experienced in the
variable R evaluated at year t+1 with respect to year t is

ΔRðtÞ ¼ Rðt þ 1Þ  RðtÞ ð7:1Þ

2
The variables R(t) and H(t) were introduced in Chap. 6 (see Resolving the Controversy: Prelim-
inary Remarks).
148 7 Looking to the Distant Future

Similarly, the expression

ΔHðtÞ ¼ Hðt þ 1Þ  HðtÞ ð7:2Þ

is used to measure the change in the number of jobs taken by humans. In what
follows we will assume that the variables R(t) and H(t) are increasing over time, so
that the symbol Δ means “increase.”

                    

We revert to the concept of technological unemployment as defined by Keynes


1930, p. 325).3 The intuition behind Keynes’s definition can be grasped by compar-
ing the increase in the number of jobs taken by robots, denoted by ΔR(t) and the
increase in the number of jobs taken by humans, denoted by ΔH(t).
We can paraphrase the Keynesian definition of technological unemployment as
follows. Technological unemployment is said to exist, if and only if, the increase in
the number of jobs taken by robots is greater than the increase in the number of jobs
taken by humans. In symbols, technological unemployment means

ΔRðtÞ > ΔHðtÞ ð7:3Þ

7.2.1 Hypothetical Example

To see the intuitive meaning of this definition, we develop a numerical example


using tables and diagrams derived from the tables.

7.2.1.1 Tables

The numerical values of the variables R(t) and H(t) are shown in two separate tables
(Tables 7.1 and 7.2). These tables are self-explanatory.

Table 7.1 The behaviour of t R(t)


the variable R(t) (year) (Jobs taken by robots, millions)
1 11
2 20
3 30
4 55
5 90
6 130
7 185

3
The original Keynesian definition of the term “technological unemployment” was reproduced in
Chap. 6, Sect. 6.2.
7.2 Technological Unemployment Revisited 149

Table 7.2 The behaviour of t H(t)


the variable H(t) (Year ) (Jobs taken by humans, millions)
1 40
2 60
3 75
4 85
5 90
6 95
7 98

Diagram 7.1 Graphical representation of Table 7.1

7.2.1.2 Diagrams Derived from Tables

To visualize the behaviour of the variables R(t) and H(t) we graph the curves
originated by Tables 7.1 and 7.2 on separate figures (see Diagrams 7.1 and 7.2).
150 7 Looking to the Distant Future

Diagram 7.2 Graphical representation of Table 7.2

7.2.1.3 Computing Changes

Our next task is to compute the change in R(t), denoted by ΔR(t), and the change in
H(t), denoted by ΔH(t) using the information provided by Tables 7.1 and 7.2,
respectively.
Computing Changes in R(t)
Look at Table 7.3. The first and second columns of Table 7.3 are identical with
those from Table 7.1. The third column represents the increase in the number of jobs
taken by robots when the economy moves from year t to year t+1. For example, the
increase in R(t) when we move from year 1 to year 2, denoted by ΔR(1), is calculated
as follows:

ΔRð1Þ ¼ Rð2Þ  Rð1Þ ¼ 20  11 ¼ 9 ð7:4Þ

Similarly, the increase in R(t) when we move from year 2 to year 3 is

ΔRð2Þ ¼ Rð3Þ  Rð2Þ ¼ 30  20 ¼ 10, ð7:5Þ

and so on.
7.2 Technological Unemployment Revisited 151

Table 7.3 Change in the number of jobs taken by robots


t R(t) ΔR(t) ¼ R(t + 1) – R(t)
(year) (Jobs taken by robots, millions) (millions of jobs)
1 11 –
2 20 9
3 30 10
4 55 25
5 90 35
6 130 40
7 185 55

Table 7.4 Change in the number of jobs taken by humans


t H(t) ΔH(t) ¼ H(t + 1) – H(t)
(Year) (Jobs taken by humans, millions) (millions of jobs)
1 40 –
2 60 20
3 75 15
4 85 10
5 90 5
6 95 5
7 98 3

Computing Changes in H(t)


We now use the information in Table 7.2 to compute ΔH(t). Look at Table 7.4. The
first row of this table identifies year, number of jobs taken by humans, and the formula to
compute the increase in the number of jobs ΔH(t). The third column of Table 7.4 shows
the increase in the number of jobs taken by humans. For example, the number located on
the third row and the third column in Table 7.4 (¼ 20) is calculated as follows:

ΔHð2Þ ¼ Hð2Þ  Hð1Þ ¼ 60  40 ¼ 20 ð7:6Þ

Similarly, the number located on the fourth row and the third column in Table 7.4
(¼ 15) is obtained as follows:

ΔHð3Þ ¼ Hð3Þ  Hð2Þ ¼ 75  60 ¼ 15, ð7:7Þ

and so on.
152 7 Looking to the Distant Future

Table 7.5 Identification of technological unemployment


t ΔR(t) ΔH(t) Technological
(year) (millions of jobs) (millions of jobs) Unemployment
1 – – –
2 9 20 No
t = 3 10 15 Onset
4 25 10 Yes
5 35 5 Yes
6 40 5 Yes
7 55 3 Yes

7.2.1.4 Detecting Technological Unemployment

To identify the onset of technological unemployment we construct Table 7.5. This


table is derived from Tables 7.3 and 7.4. Technological unemployment exists if and
only if ΔR(t) > ΔH(t). Inspection of Table 7.5 shows that the onset of technological
unemployment happens at year t ¼ 3.
In our hypothetical example, the economy experiences technological unemploy-
ment for t  4 because

ΔRðtÞ > ΔHðtÞ for t  4 ð7:8Þ

7.2.1.5 Superimposing Diagrams

Look at Diagram 7.3. This diagram results from superimposing Diagrams 7.1 and
7.2. Diagram 7.3 provides a visual description of the concept of technological
unemployment. Suppose that the economy moves from year 3 to year 4: The
segment BC represents the value of ΔR; the increase in the number of jobs taken
by robots is 25 million jobs (ΔR ¼ 25) the segment EF represents the increase in the
number of jobs taken by humans (ΔH ¼ 10). A glance at Diagram 7.3 shows that the
increase in the number of jobs taken by robots is greater than the increase in the
number of jobs taken by humans, that is,

ΔR ¼ 25 > 10 ¼ ΔH, ð7:9Þ

and technological unemployment occurs in year 4.


7.3 Demarcating the Notion of a Robot Economy 153

Diagram 7.3 Visualizing the definition of technological unemployment

7.3 Demarcating the Notion of a Robot Economy

What is a ‘robot economy’? A century ago, Henry Moore (a pioneer in quantitative


economics) was concerned about the need for greater care in the use of terms in the
scientific discourse and spoke out against the linguistic muddle prevailing around the
word ‘competition.’ It is interesting to note that he started his article as follows:
Economic terms seem to pass in their historical development through a series of stages
which, without pretension of rigidness, may be described as follows: first, no definition is
given, but it is assumed that everyone has a sufficiently clear idea of the subject to make a
formal definition unnecessary; second, a definition is attempted and a number of exceptional
forms are noted; third, with the further increase of data, the relative importance of the various
forms changes, confusion in the discussion is introduced, logomachy takes the place of
constructive investigation; fourth, a complete classification of the forms embraced under the
original term is made, and problems are investigated with reference to this classes. (. . .)
(Moore 1906, p. 211)

Generally speaking, the term ‘robot economy’ appears to be in a transitional


phase from the first stage to the second stage.
154 7 Looking to the Distant Future

7.3.1 No Generally Agreed Definition

Although the notion of robot economy is latent in Brynjolfsson and McAfee (2014)
and Ford (2015), a definition of this term cannot be found in their ground-breaking
books. It is not known who coined the term “robot economy” and there is no
generally agreed definition of this term. Some analysts write about the robot econ-
omy but they do not explicitly define this special kind of economy –probably
because they assume that everyone has a clear idea of the concept. A case in point
is Von Drehle (2013) otherwise stimulating article “Winner and Losers in the New
Robot Economy.”

7.3.2 Whatls.com Definition

Whatls.com offers an exceedingly simple definition of a robot economy which does


not presuppose the existence of technological unemployment:
The robot economy is a scenario in which most of the labour required to sustain human life is
automated. Although the term robot economy brings to mind an environment full of
humanoid robots (androids) bustling about performing tasks, in this context the word
robot refers to both physical systems and AI-enhanced software systems, and it is the latter
that are expected to replace the bulk of human work. Website visited on 20 December 2018.
[Italics in original]

Is the Whatls.com definition stating that in a robot economy R(t) > H(t)? Prob-
ably, but we cannot say because this definition is overly general and insufficiently
precise. Generality is not an end in itself. A definition may be so general as to be
useless to bring relevant factors into sharp focus.
We believe that an explicit definition of the term robot economy may be useful to
gain further understanding of the robot economy narrative. This is why we propose a
new definition of robot economy. But it goes without saying that we are not
declaring what the robot economy “is.”
Increasing technological unemployment signals that human labour becomes more
and more superfluous over time, and, thereby, the creative economy would be
morphing into a bizarre kind of economy where human labour ceases to be the
most important factor of production.

7.3.3 Proffered Definition of Robot Economy

An economy is said to be a robot economy if it satisfies the following two conditions:


Condition 1: There exists technological unemployment; and
Condition 2: There exists a year T beyond which the number of jobs taken by
robots is greater than the number of jobs taken by humans.
7.3 Demarcating the Notion of a Robot Economy 155

In symbols, a robot economy satisfies two conditions:

ΔRðtÞ > ΔHðtÞ ð7:10Þ

and

RðtÞ > HðtÞ for t > T ð7:11Þ

The onset of the Robot Economy occurs at year T where there is technological
unemployment and the number of jobs taken by robots is greater than the number of
jobs taken by humans, that is,

RðT Þ ¼ HðT Þ ð7:12Þ

7.3.4 Hypothetical Example (Cont.)

To illustrate the definition of a robot economy, we take advantage of the hypothetical


example previously developed in this chapter. To identify the onset of the robot
economy in our hypothetical economy we use the information provided by
Table 7.6.
Inspection of Table 7.6 shows that when t ¼ 5 there is technological unemploy-
ment and the number of jobs taken by robots and humans are equal to each other
(90 million of jobs). Consequently, the onset of the robot economy occurs when
T ¼ 5.
The geometrical meaning of Conditions 1 and 2 in the proffered definition of
robot economy can be seen in Diagram 7.4: Condition 1 is satisfied for t > t
(technological unemployment exists); and Condition 2 is valid for t > T (the number
of jobs taken by robots exceeds the number of jobs taken by humans). In the past,
labour-saving technologies stimulated more employment in total than they
destroyed, that is, the economy has been operating somewhere in the time interval
0 < t < T . The message conveyed by Diagram 7.4 is simple, yet fundamental:

Table 7.6 Numerical identification of a robot economy


t R(t) H(t) Technological Robot
(year) (millions of jobs) (millions of jobs) Unemployment Economy
1 11 40 – –
2 20 60 No No
3 30 75 Onset No
4 55 85 Yes No
T = 5 90 90 Yes Onset
6 130 95 Yes Yes
7 185 98 Yes Yes
156 7 Looking to the Distant Future

Diagram 7.4 A robot economy at a glance

what was true in the past may not be true in the future. It is not inconceivable that the
discrepancy R(t) – H(t) may grow increasingly rapidly in the future.

7.4 Is the Robot Economy Near?

As we mentioned in the introduction to the present chapter, Arthur (2011) argued


that the introduction of the Internet in 1995 marks a bifurcation of the real economy
into two interconnected economies: the physical economy (think of human workers
and other tangible resources such as, for example, land and factories) and the virtual
economy (technologies useful for the physical economy, e.g. digital labour). Arthur
(2017) refines his vision with a deep insight. While the physical economy houses
internal intelligence stored in the human workers, the virtual economy contains huge
7.4 Is the Robot Economy Near? 157

libraries of intelligent functions, i.e. digital algorithms performing intelligent tasks


previously carried out by humans. This sort of ‘external intelligence’ is increasingly
important in the world of business and is gradually rendering human activities
obsolete.4
Brian W. Arthur describes the interactions between the physical economy and the
virtual economy as follows:
The interesting thing here isn’t the form intelligence takes. It’s that intelligence is no longer
housed internally in the brains of human workers but has moved outward into the virtual
economy, into the conversation among intelligent algorithms. It has become external. The
physical economy demands or queries; the virtual economy checks and converses and
computes externally and then reports back to the physical economy –which then responds
appropriately. The virtual economy is not just an Internet of Things, it is a source of
intelligent action –intelligence external to human workers. (Arthur 2017, p. 6)

In simple practical terms, what Arthur is saying is that technology digitalizes


tasks performed by humans (think of bank tellers, office receptionists, bookkeepers,
and data collectors) and bit by bit renders those human tasks obsolete. Humans
observe and record the way other humans complete their assigned tasks, and then
create technology able to do the same tasks. It is as if technology were a gigantic
human capital-suctioning machine transforming internal intelligence (human capi-
tal) into external intelligence (libraries of intelligent functions).
Arthur (2017) reiterates that we have entered a new era where the problem is
distribution of wealth, not production, and states, “we have reached a point in which
technological unemployment is becoming a reality.”
Is the robot economy near? We do not have an answer to this question. We
honestly do not know. It appears that we still have a long way to go. However,
nothing can prevent us from developing a speculative narrative assuming that a robot
economy will be itself an evolving entity.
If new waves of robot-based enabling products arrive faster and faster, and they
are quickly deployed, the economy may not have sufficient time to adapt by creating
human jobs in new sectors or in sectors not disrupted by automation. It is likely that
companies would be unwilling to pay wages that workers will accept. Thus, volun-
tary unemployment may happen. Extremely low wages that do not allow workers to
maintain a decent standard of living would cause massive voluntary unemployment:
This is bad news for the economy, since unemployed people don’t create much demand for
goods and overall growth slows down. Weak demand can lead to further deterioration in
wages and unemployment as well as less investment in human capital and in equipment, and
a vicious circle can take hold. (Brynjolfsson and McAfee 2014, p. 232).

4
Wassily Leontief (1906–1999) –Nobel Prize in Economics awarded in 1973– also emphasized that
automation diminishes the role of human labour, skilled or unskilled: “one might say that the
process by which progressive introduction of new computerized, automated, and robotized equip-
ment can be expected to reduce the role of labour is similar to the process by which the introduction
of tractors and other machinery first reduced and then completely eliminated horses and other draft
animals in agriculture. The competitive price mechanism played a decisive role in this process.”
(Leontief 2019, p. 189).
158 7 Looking to the Distant Future

7.5 The Robot Economy Paradox

7.5.1 Increasing Returns

Worldly wisdom teaches that success breeds success. This adage is a particular case
of the important concept of increasing returns. The notion of increasing returns is
defined as the tendency for that which is ahead to get further ahead (Arthur 1996,
p. 100). For example, analysts say that there are increasing returns in the production
of innovations when a firm produces more innovations the more likely it is to
continue to innovate. This may occur if there is positive feedback between the
accumulation of knowledge and the production of innovations by a firm.
Another example where “strength begets strength” is Artificial Intelligence (AI).
The chairman and chief executive of Sinovation Ventures and president of its
Artificial Intelligence Institute Kai-Fu Lee pointed out:
AI is an industry in which strength begets strength: the more data you have, the better your
product; the better your product, the more data you can collect; the more data you can
collect, the more talent you can attract; the more talent you can attract, the better your
product. It’s a virtuous circle, and the United States and China have already amassed the
talent, market share and data to set it in motion. (Lee 2017)

Increasing returns happen in processes that can feed on themselves. “Technolo-


gies typically improve as more people adopt them and firms gain experience that
guides further development. This link is a positive feedback loop: the more people
adopt a technology, the more improves and the more attractive it is for further
adoption.” (Arthur 1994, p. 10)

7.5.2 The Paradox, Stated

The existence of increasing returns to automation implies a relentless progression


toward ever more automation and suggests that the robot economy itself could
converge to an extreme and supreme case of an economy with mass obsolescence
of the human workforce.
The economy of the distant future appears to pose a paradox that we call the robot
economy paradox. This paradox can be stated as follows: increasing returns to
automation would allow us to attain unprecedented levels of cost reductions and
efficiencies, but would leave us earning too little to purchase the products our robots
can make. In other words, a robot economy would converge to a situation of
ubiquitous automation and insufficient aggregate demand.5

5
This paradox is latent in the ground breaking book by (Brynjolfsson and McAfee 2014, esp.
pp. 231-232) and it is virtually explicit in Ford (2015, Ch. 8).
7.5 The Robot Economy Paradox 159

7.5.3 Norbert Wiener: A Forerunner of the Paradox

The robot economy paradox paints a dystopian future much like the one Norbert
Wiener had imagined in 1949.6 At the request of the New York Times, he wrote an
essay entitled “The Machine Age” which was never published due to a miscommu-
nication. This essay languished for six decades in the M.I.T. archives and was
discovered in December 2012 by an independent scholar, Anders Fernstedt.
Excerpts from the essay “The Machine Age” can be found in the May 2013 article
published by the New York Times science reporter John Markoff. In the article “In
1949, He Imagined an Age of Robots” Markoff explains the reasons for the
miscommunication and makes the following point: “Almost 64 years after Wiener
wrote it, his essay is still remarkably topical, raising questions about the impact of
smart machines on society and of automation on human labour.” Markoff (2013)
Norbert Wiener argued that “if we can do anything in a clear and intelligible way,
we can do it by machine” and added that “These new machines have a great capacity
for upsetting the present basis of an industry, and of reducing the economic value of
the routine factory employee to a point at which he is not worth hiring at any price.”
Wiener warned that this bizarre situation could ultimately lead to “an industrial
revolution of unmitigated cruelty.”7
Note 2 Apocryphal anecdote
There is an apocryphal anecdote that superficially invokes the robot economy
paradox. Henry Ford II (a forceful executive) and Walter Reuther (USA leader of the
United Auto Workers union) took a tour around a newly built and highly-automated
factory inhabited by sophisticated robots. Suddenly, Henry Ford sarcastically asks:
“Hey Walter, how will you get robots to pay union dues? Then Walter replies with
another question: “Hey Henry, how will you get robots to buy cars?”

7.5.4 Resolving the Paradox

Imagine that our self-induced redundancy has created a strange new world in which
machines run themselves and would leave us earning too little to purchase the
products our robots can make. How do we deal with this situation? The straight
truth is that the robot economy paradox remains unresolved. Human work is the
main mechanism through which spending power is allocated in the profit-oriented,
market-guided economy. In a jobless economy this mechanism ceases to exist.
Governments will need to find ways to redistribute income from the people who
own the robots to displaced workers to ensure inclusive growth, that is, to ensure that

6
Norbert Wiener (1894–1964) was a child prodigy who entered university when he was 11 and
completed his PhD when he was just 17.
7
The quotations are from the excerpts published in Markoff (2013).
160 7 Looking to the Distant Future

the benefits of automation-driven growth are shared widely. There are at least three
tentative solutions to the robot economy paradox.

7.5.4.1 Tentative Solution # 1: Introduce a Universal Basic Income

The first idea that comes to our minds is the introduction of a Universal Basic
Income (UBI). The UBI assures that everyone has a decent standard of living. If
people want to improve on it, they certainly can. But even if they do not they will still
receive money and experience a minimum standard of living.
The idea of a basic income is not convincing. To see why, we just have to look at
the following statement due to the Enlightenment sage Voltaire: “Work saves a man
from the three great evils: boredom, vice, and need.” (Voltaire 1991, p. 86). A
guaranteed basic income takes care of need, but not the other two evils. People want
to escape the evils of boredom and vice as well.
Work is beneficial. Joblessness harms feelings of well-being and other measures
of mental health. People want a job, not a welfare cheque. The ultimate reason for the
rejection of an UBI may well be based on the insight of Harvard Professor Michael
Sandel: “Work is about more than making a living: it is also a source of meaning.”
Note 3 Brynjolfsson and McAfee
A UBI is not the first choice for Brynjolfsson and McAfee because “It seems that
all around the world, people want to escape the evils of boredom, vice, and need and
instead find mastery, autonomy, and purpose by working.” (Brynjolfsson and
McAfee 2014, p. 234)
Note 4 Martin Ford
Martin Ford believes that some form of guaranteed income is probably the best
solution to the robot economy paradox. See Chap. 10 of the Rise of the Robots.

7.5.4.2 Tentative Solution # 2: Tax Robots

Investing in robots engenders a negative technological externality (the collateral


effect is human replacement). Investing in robots is like investing in a coal-fired
generator: the investment boosts output but imposes a social cost.
The idea of a tax on robots was raised in a draft report to the European
Commission, prepared by Mady Delvaux from the Committee on Legal Affairs.
The public reaction to Delvaux’s proposal has been quite negative, with the notable
exceptions of Bill Gates and Robert Shiller, who endorsed it.
In an interview with Quartz (an online magazine) Bill Gates suggested that to
forestall a social crisis, governments should consider a tax on robots. Specifically,
companies would be forced to pay when they replace a worker with a robot. If
automation slows as a result of the tax, so much better. The money raised by the tax
7.5 The Robot Economy Paradox 161

on robots could be used to finance an expansion of health care and education which
provide lots of hard-to-automate jobs in caring for the old and sick or in teaching.
Professor Robert J. Shiller, 2013 Nobel laureate in economics, has expressed:
Critics of a robot tax have emphasized that the ambiguity of the term “robot” makes defining
the tax base difficult. The critics also stress the new robotics’ enormous, undeniable benefits
to productivity growth. But let’s not rule out so quickly at least modest robot taxes during the
transition to a different world of work. Such a tax should be part of a broader plan to manage
the consequences of the robot revolution. (Shiller 2017)

Robert Shiller believes that it is better to tax robots rather than just high-income
people, and concludes:
A moderate tax on robots, even a temporary tax that merely slows the adoption of disruptive
technology, seems a natural component of a policy to address rising inequality. Revenue
could be targeted toward wage insurance to help people replaced by new technology make
the transition to a different career. This would accord with our natural sense of justice, and
thus be likely to endure. (Shiller 2017)

7.5.4.3 Tentative Solution # 3: Replace Mindset

A third solution to the robot economy paradox would be to request entrepreneurs,


engineers, and economists to design complements, not substitutes, for labour, and
replace a labour-saving mindset with a labour-augmenting mindset. This “design
philosophy” was introduced by Erik Brynjolfsson in 2013 and revisited by
Acemoglu and Restrepo: “The current tendency is to develop AI in the direction
of further automation, but this might mean missing out on the promise of the “right”
kind of AI with better economic and social outcomes.” Acemoglu and
Restrepo (2019).
The gist of the argument is that AI applications can create new tasks for labour.
Education is a good example:
At the moment, individualized teaching, targeted and adapted to each student or for small
subset of students, is impossible, and not just because the resources in terms of teacher time
and skill are lacking. It is mostly because nobody has the information (and cannot easily
acquire and process the information) to determine a student’s optimal learning style in a
specific subject or topic. AI can change this. AI software can be designed to collect and
process in real time data about the specific reactions, difficulties and successes students have
in different subject areas, especially when taught in different styles, and then make recom-
mendations for improved individualized teaching. The potential improvements in terms of
educational productivity could be quite large (we just don’t know). Societal benefits could
exceed these direct benefits as AI-powered teaching methods may do better in terms of
providing students with skills that will be more valued in future labour markets (rather than
the more back-ward looking curricula and teaching emphasis currently prevailing in
schools). Developing and deploying such technologies would also increase the demand for
human labour in teaching –we would need more teachers with diverse skills to do individ-
ualized teaching, even with help from AI software and other technologies. (Acemoglu and
Restrepo 2019, p. 6).
162 7 Looking to the Distant Future

Labour-augmenting innovations must be substantially less expensive than labour-


saving innovations to offset the labour costs associated with the former or provide
significant efficiency-enhancing results to generate additional revenue to offset
labour costs.
Needless to say, human workers run into many potential issues reinforcing the
bias toward automation. The more human workers you have, the more managers and
human resources staff you need. Moreover, human workers get sick, take vacations,
require offices, need parking spaces, quit unexpectedly, etc.

7.6 Schumpeter’s Famous Prophecy

It is unclear how the robot economy paradox can be resolved. Neither technological
progress nor the profit motive can be redirected to the production of labour-
augmenting innovations unless we abandon the very notion of a creative economy –
which is, by definition, a profit-oriented and market-guided economy. Where does
the robot economy paradox leave us? Surprisingly, the paradox takes us back to
Schumpeter’s famous prophesy.
Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy is a book published in 1942 where
Schumpeter wrote about the future of capitalism. He entitled Part II of this book
with a confronting question: Can Capitalism Survive? In the first paragraph of the
Prologue to Part II, we find a completely unexpected answer:
Can capitalism survive? No. I do not think it can. But this opinion of mine, like that of every
other economist who has pronounced upon the subject, is in itself completely uninteresting.
What counts in any attempt of social prognosis is not Yes or No that sums up the facts and
arguments that lead up to it but those facts and arguments themselves. They contain all that is
scientific in the final result. Everything else is not science but prophecy. Analysis, whether
economic or other, never yields more than a statement about the tendencies present in an
observable pattern. And these never tell us what will happen to the pattern but only what
would happen if they continued to act as they have been acting in the time interval covered
by our observation and if no other factors intruded. “Inevitability” or “necessity” can never
mean more than this. (Schumpeter 2010, p. 53) [Italics in original]

His conclusion was that capitalism would be replaced by socialism. It should be


emphasized, however, that according to Schumpeter capitalism was doomed but not
for the reasons that Karl Marx set forth (Marx 1906).
Schumpeter viewed Marxism as a religion. In the chapter Marx the Prophet, he
wrote: “The religious quality of Marxism also explains a characteristic attitude of the
orthodox Marxist toward opponents. To him, as to any believer in a Faith, the
opponent is not merely in error but in sin. Dissent is disapproved not only intellec-
tually but also morally. There cannot be any excuse for it once the Message has been
revealed.” (Schumpeter 2010, p. 5, fn. 1).
Schumpeter emphasized that Marx was right in relation to the conclusion that
capitalism would break down eventually but he was wrong in his explanation of the
7.6 Schumpeter’s Famous Prophecy 163

manner in which the capitalist society would break down.8 It should be noticed that
unemployment does not play any role in the Schumpeterian argument that capitalism
is doomed:
I hold that the real tragedy is not unemployment per se, but unemployment plus the
impossibility of providing adequately for the unemployed without impairing conditions of
further economic development: for obviously the suffering and degradation –the destruction
of human values– which we associate with unemployment, though not the waste of
productive resources, would be largely eliminated and unemployment would lose practically
all its terror if the private life of the unemployed were not seriously affected by their
unemployment. (Schumpeter 2010, p. 61) [Italics in original]

According to Schumpeter, capitalism may be an economic success, but it is not a


sociological success. He argued that capitalism would wither away because of
disenchantment among the elites.9
Schumpeter develops what he calls a “theory of the atmosphere of hostility to
capitalism.” This includes a mutually beneficial interaction between the bourgeoisie
and the intellectuals. The intellectual group is defined as “people who wield the
power of the spoken and the written word, and one of the touches that distinguish
them from other people who do the same is the absence of responsibility for practical
affairs.” (Schumpeter 2010, p. 131).
Intellectuals display a critical attitude toward the capitalist system. Speakers and
writers stress the inadequacies of capitalist achievement, they express aversion to
capitalists and sympathy with anti-capitalist interests.
The bourgeois defends the intellectuals as a group because they feel that they are
defending themselves:
From this follows both the unwillingness and the inability of the capitalist order to control its
intellectual sector effectively. The unwillingness in question is unwillingness to use methods
consistently that are uncongenial to the mentality shaped by the capitalist process; the
inability is the inability to do so within the frame of institutions shaped by the capitalist
process and without submitting to non-bourgeois rule. Thus, on the one hand, freedom of
public discussion involving freedom to nibble at the foundations of capitalist society is
inevitable in the long run. On the other hand, the intellectual group cannot help nibbling,
because it lives on criticism and its whole position depends on criticism that stings; and
criticism of persons and current events will, in a situation in which nothing is sacrosanct,
fatally issue in criticism of classes and institutions. (Schumpeter 2010, p. 135)

The active hostility of the intellectual group amounts to moral disapproval of the
capitalist order. The bourgeois class loses faith in itself. This negative psychology
combines with a movement into pervasive bureaucratization. In the end, it is this

8
For Marx the reason for the collapse of capitalism is the conflict of interest between the bourgeoisie
and the proletariat.
9
For Schumpeter the driving force of humankind is not classes (e.g. the proletariat, as Marxists
argue) but elites –minorities of individuals with unusual gifts. It is not classes, but elites, that govern
the evolution of society.
164 7 Looking to the Distant Future

capitalist mentality that brings down the system. In Schumpeter’s own words, “there
is inherent in the capitalist system a tendency toward self-destruction which, in its
earlier stages, may well assert itself in the form of a tendency toward retardation of
progress.” (Schumpeter 2010, p. 144). In the process of self-destruction, capitalism
creates the conditions for socialism.
In brief, capitalism creates a critical frame of mind which turns against capitalism
itself and attacks the usefulness of the private property of the means of production.
Faced with the increasing hostility of the social atmosphere, the bourgeois class loses
faith in itself, capitalists and entrepreneurs cease to function. It is a loss of belief that
will kill capitalism. Is this economics? Quite obviously, Schumpeter’s prophesy is
not based on economics. It is essentially a sociological analysis.
The answer to the question can capitalism survive is disquieting. Capitalism will
give way to socialism for Schumpeter’s reasons, not for Marx’s. But Schumpeter did
not stop there. Part III of Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy is also entitled with
a question: Can Socialism Work? Now the answer comes with a second shock: “Of
course it can.” (Schumpeter 2010, p. 149).

7.7 Arthur’s Prophecy

Arthur (2017) has discussed the view that the creative economy in the distant future
will be incompatible with capitalism. His conceptual framework is compelling.
There are two kinds of intelligence: internal intelligence (intelligence stored in the
human workers) and external intelligence (algorithms performing intelligent func-
tions previously performed by humans). As indicated by Diagram 7.5, a bifurcation

Diagram 7.5 Bifurcation


of the real economy
7.8 Chapter Summary 165

of the real economy happened in 1995 with the introduction of the Internet. The
physical economy houses internal intelligence (or human capital); the virtual econ-
omy houses external intelligence (or huge libraries of intelligent functions). There is
a continuous transfer of human jobs from the physical economy to the virtual
economy.
How do people have access to what is produced in a creative economy? Generally
speaking, the answer is jobs. The relentless progression toward automation will eat
up human jobs and these jobs will not be replaced by new jobs.
The economy of the distant future will be potentially able to produce enough for
everyone, but where access to what is produced will be severely limited due to a
continuous reduction in the number of jobs taken by humans. The end result is the
Robot Economy Paradox.
Resolving the paradox requires a mild form of socialism: “When things settle I’d
expect new political parties that offer some version of a Scandinavian solution:
capitalist-guided production and government-guided attention to who gets what.
Europe will find this path easier because a loose socialism is part of its tradition. The
United States will find it more difficult; it has never prized distribution over
efficiency.” (Arthur 2017, p. 11)

7.8 Chapter Summary

In broad terms, the dynamic process leading to the Robot Economy Paradox can be
easily outlined.
• Technological progress and the profit motive combine to increase the rate of
creation of new robot-based enabling products.
• This, in turn, engenders a tendency where the pace of discovery of means of
economising the use of human labour outruns the pace at which the economy
finds new uses for labour (technological unemployment).
• If the tendency persists, the number of jobs taken by robots will exceed the
number of jobs taken by humans and the creative economy becomes a Robot
Economy.
These points can be assembled in one picture (see Diagram 7.6)
• If increasing returns to automation prevail everywhere, a robot economy is bound
to confront a paradox. In fact, if robots substitute for workers entirely, then no one
has an income from any type of labour (see Diagram 7.7).
• If the Robot Economy reaches the paradox point, capitalism would not survive.
• Schumpeter reached the same conclusion arguing that it is the sociology of
capitalism that would destroy the system and not because of the economic success
of capitalism.
166 7 Looking to the Distant Future

Diagram 7.6 Convergence to a robot economy

Diagram 7.7 Robot economy: victim of its own success

Appendices
Appendix J: Technological Progress in the Twenty-First
Century

Technological progress is a major factor affecting the number of human jobs and the
level of wages. In its current form, technological progress displays three mutually
Appendices 167

reinforcing attributes. It is digital, exponential, and combinatorial. The purpose of


this appendix is to get a sense of these attributes.

Technological Progress: Digital

“Information and media” is a catch-all expression encompassing documents, music,


photos, videos, data from instruments and sensors, maps, social networks, and so
on. Digitization consists of translating information and media into ones and zeroes.10
In other words, the phenomenon of digitization consists of encoding information and
media as streams of bits. This means that digitization makes huge amounts of data
readily available.
The digital language allows machine-to-machine (M2M) communication without
any human involvement. For example, ATMs ask their banks how much money we
have in our accounts before letting us withdraw the cash. Digitization facilitates
research because it makes huge amounts of data readily available and this, in turn,
accelerates the discovery of how things work.

Digitized Economy

Digitization gives rise to the digitized economy characterized by the existence of


computer networks. In general, a network is a collection of linkages between nodes.
We all know that there are railroad networks, airline networks, networks of ATM
machines, telephone networks, computer networks, networks of e-mail users, and
the Internet. These networks tend to generate ‘network economies.’
When the benefits of connecting to a network are an increasing function of the
number of other people connected to it, economists say that there are network
economies. Alternatively, the bigger a network gets, the more attractive it becomes.
The intuition behind the concept of network economies is this: when I join the
network you also benefit because the network becomes bigger.11
As an illustration, consider the case of eBay, a company that uses the Internet for a
trading system in which buyers and sellers can establish a genuine market price. The
bigger eBay gets, the more attractive it becomes for buyers and sellers because it can
put them in touch with more and more buyers and sellers. The benefits of connecting
to eBay increase with the number of people who sign in. eBay displays network
economies.

10
As a reminder, electronic computers use the simplest possible digital arrangements to encode
information; everything is broken down into a string of ones and zeroes (‘binary digits’ or ‘bits’).
11
The term ‘network economies’ is sometimes referred to as ‘network externalities’ or ‘demand-
side economies of scale.’
168 7 Looking to the Distant Future

Numerical Example

A simple numerical example is useful to understand the benefits implied by the


increase in the number of users of a network. Let n denote the number of users of a
network. If there is only one user (n ¼ 1) the network is useless. Two users (n ¼ 2)
make possible 2 one-way connections. Three users (n ¼ 3) allow 6 one-way
connections. Four users (n ¼ 4) make possible 12 one-way connections. And so on.

Metcalfe’s Law

How can we calculate the benefit of the network for all users? The total benefit of the
network, denoted by B, can be easily established using the so called Metcalfe’s law.
Under the assumption that the individual benefit of the network is proportional to the
number of users this law asserts:

B ¼ n2  n ð7:13Þ

The behaviour of the variable B is illustrated in Table 7.7. The important thing to
note is that the total benefit of the network rises not proportionally with the number
of users (nodes) but more than proportionately.12

Technological Progress: Exponential

Technological progress is said to be exponential because computer power increases


exponentially over time.

Moore’s Law

The behaviour of computer power is described by the famous “Moore’s law.”


Gordon Moore –a cofounder of Intel– made a famous prediction in a 1965 article

Table 7.7 The benefit of the Number of users Total benefit of the network
network for all users (n) (B)
1 0
2 2
3 6
4 12
5 20
... ...
100 9.900

12
Alternatively, we can put this in the language of elasticity. What Metcalfe’s Law says is that the
elasticity of B with respect to n is greater than one. This can be verified using the elasticity formula.
Appendices 169

entitled “Cramming More Components onto Integrated Circuits” published in the


Electronics magazine. Moore observed the amount of integrated circuit computer
power had doubled each year and predicted that the tendency would continue,
perhaps with some changing to timing.
The period of time required for computer power to double remains a matter of
dispute. Today it is common to use 18 months as the doubling period for general
computing power. We can express this empirical regularity in mathematical terms. If
computer power is denoted by y(t) at the end of period t, Moore’s Law is described
by the formula

y ð t Þ = 2t , t = 0, 1, 2, 3, ð7:14Þ

Table 7.8 shows how the mechanism of “constant doubling” works. For example,
when we are at period t ¼ 4, computer power is 16 and at the end of the following
period will be 32 ð¼ 16  2Þ; if we are at t ¼ 5, computer power in the following
period is 64 ð32  2Þ; and so on. This table gives a hint about the speed of evolution
of the variable y, but it does not do justice to the phenomenal increase of y over time
(because the table stops at t ¼ 8). At the end of this appendix, we resort to the
standard workhorse to illustrate the notion of constant doubling, namely: the story of
the origin of the game of chess.
Note 5 Exponential growth
Formula 7.14 is a particular case of what mathematicians call “exponential
function.” In the language of mathematics, the general expression of the exponential
function is

y ð t Þ ¼ at ð7:15Þ

where a is the fixed based of the function and the variable t is a real number. If the
behaviour of the variable y is described by the function 7.15, it is said that y(t)
displays exponential growth. In the case of Moore’s Law, a ¼ 2.

Table 7.8 Computer power according to Moore’s Law (each period consists of 18 months)
Doubling period Constant doubling
t y(t) ¼ 2t Computer power at the end of period t
0
0 yð0Þ ¼ 2 ¼ 1 1
1 yð1Þ ¼ 21 ¼ 1  2 2
2
2 yð2Þ ¼ 2 ¼ 2  2 4
3
3 yð3Þ ¼ 2 ¼ 4  2 8
4
4 yð4Þ ¼ 2 ¼ 8  2 16
5 yð5Þ ¼ 25 ¼ 16  2 32
6
6 yð6Þ ¼ 2 ¼ 32  2 64
7
7 yð7Þ ¼ 2 ¼ 64  2 128
8 yð8Þ ¼ 28 ¼ 128  2 256
170 7 Looking to the Distant Future

Technological Progress: Combinatorial

Technological progress is said to be combinatorial because the possibilities for


innovation are combinatorial. There are reasons to believe that the production of
innovations consists of recombining elements (ideas) that already exist to create new
ideas. For example, the innovation ‘body combat’ results from combining the idea of
‘music’ with ideas such as idea of ‘martial arts’ and ‘shadow boxing.’ This is exactly
Principle 1 (Recombinant Innovation) of the Basic Model of a creative economy
introduced before.13
Combinatorial possibilities explode very quickly and there is soon virtually an
infinite number of possible recombinations of existing ideas into new ideas: “We
consistently fail to grasp how many ideas remain to be discovered . . . Possibilities do
not merely add up; they multiply.” (Romer 2008).
Note 6 Factorial of a number
How do we calculate the number of ways of ordering n elements? Mathemati-
cians carry out the required calculation simply by multiplying numbers following a
precise rule. For a natural number n, they define a new number

n! ¼ n  ðn  1Þ  ðn  2Þ  ðn  3Þ  ðn  4Þ  . . .  3  2  1

The new number n! (read: n factorial) is the product of the first n integers.
For example,

2! ¼ 2  ð2  1Þ ¼ 2, and 3! ¼ 3  ð3  1Þ ¼ 3  2 ¼ 6

What is the number of ways of ordering four elements? Answer: compute 4 ! , that
is,

4! ¼ n  ðn  1Þ  ðn  2Þ  ðn  3Þ ¼ 4  3  2  1 ¼ 24

Similarly,

5! ¼ n  ðn  1Þ  ðn  2Þ  ðn  3Þ  ðn  4Þ ¼ 5  4  3  2  1 ¼ 120
6! ¼ n  ðn  1Þ  ðn  2Þ  ðn  3Þ  ðn  4Þðn  5Þ ¼ 6  5  4  3  2  1 ¼ 720

The value of n!gives exactly the number of ways of ordering n elements.

13
See Chap. 2, Sect. 2.6.
Appendices 171

Table 7.9 Combinatorial Period Value of z at the end of period t


growth t z(t)
1 Z(1) ¼ 2  1 ! ¼ 2
2 z(2) ¼ 2  2 ! ¼ 2  2 ¼ 4
3 z(3) ¼ 2  3 ! ¼ 2  6 ¼ 12
4 z(4) ¼ 2  4 ! ¼ 2  24 ¼ 48
5 z(5) ¼ 2  5 ! ¼ 2  120 ¼ 240
6 z(6) ¼ 2  6 ! ¼ 2  720 ¼ 1.440
7 z(7) ¼ 2  7 ! ¼ 2  5, 040 ¼ 10.080
8 z(8) ¼ 2  8 ! ¼ 2  40, 320 ¼ 80.640

Note 7 Combinatorial growth


The variable z is said to exhibit combinatorial growth if

zðtÞ = a  t! ðt = 1, 2, 3, . . .Þ ð7:16Þ

where a is a constant and t is an integer number. As indicated by Table 7.9,


combinatorial growth explodes very quickly.

Digression: Exponential Growth and Chess

We revert to the concept of exponential growth. The story of the Emperor and the
Inventor of chess neatly illustrates the power of exponential growth. It is generally
agreed that the game of chess originated in India during the sixth century GE, the
time of the Gupta Empire. The Inventor presented the game to the Emperor who was
impressed by the difficult, beautiful game. The Emperor invited the inventor to name
his reward. A dialogue between them happened along the following lines.
Inventor: All I desire is some rice to feed my family.
Emperor: Name the quantity of rice you want.
Inventor: Place a single grain of rice on the first square of the chessboard, two on the second,
four on the third, eight for the fourth, and so on, so that each square receives twice as
many grains as the previous.
Emperor: Make it so!

Suppose that the variable y represents the number of grains of rice. It is easy to see
that if the Emperor wants to satisfy the Inventor‘s request he has to afford the
following sequence:
One grain of rice on the first square (y ¼ 1)
Two grains of rice on the second square (y ¼ 2)
Four grains of rice on the third square (y ¼ 4)
Eight grains of rice on the fourth square (y ¼ 8)
Sixteen grains of rice on the fifth square (y ¼ 16)
Thirty two grains of rice for the sixth square (y ¼ 32)
172 7 Looking to the Distant Future

The sequence has 64 terms because a chessboard has 64 squares and can be
described by the formula

y = 2n 2 1 ðn = 1, 2, 3, . . . , 64Þ ð7:17Þ

To organize our thinking, we consider the first and second half of the chessboard
separately.

First-Half of the chessboard

After 32 squares (end of the first-half of the chessboard), the Emperor has given
the Inventor about four (4) billion grains of rice. This is about the produce of one
large field.

Second-Half of the Chessboard

In the second-half of the chessboard things start going increasingly out of hand. The
doubling of grains of rice for each square ultimately equals something like 18 quin-
tillion grains of rice:

2641 ¼ 263 ffi 18 quintillion grains ð7:18Þ

Sixty-three (63) instances of doubling yields a huge number (even when starting
with a single grain of rice). If the request of the Inventor were fully honoured, he
would receive more than 18 quintillion grains of rice. This number is so big that it is
inconceivable in the sense that leaves our intuition and experience behind.
How does the story of the Emperor and the Inventor end? There are two versions.
One has the Emperor going bankrupt. The other version has the Inventor losing
his head.
Note 9 Naming the large numbers
We are all familiar with ‘millions’ and ‘billions’. The corresponding mathemat-
ical expressions are

106 ¼ 1:000:000 million


109 ¼ 1:000:000:000 billion

Our intuition fails to capture the magnitude of larger numbers but the mathemat-
ical expression is fairly easy. Going on, we still find a familiar number

1012 ¼ 1:000:000:000:000 trillion


Appendices 173

Note that the exponent of the number 10 indicates the number of zeros following
the number 1. More names of numbers that are intuitively inconceivable are

1015 ¼ 1:000:000:000:000:000 quadrillion


1018 ¼ 1:000:000:000:000:000:000 quintillion
1021 ¼ 1:000:000:000:000:000:000:000 sextillion
10 24
¼ 1:000:000:000:000:000:000:000:000 septillion
1064 ¼ 1 followed by 64 zeroes vigintillion

One thing is clear: our brains are not well equipped to conceive big numbers.

Wrapping Up: Exponential Versus Combinatorial Growth

What is the use of all this? The story of the Emperor and the Inventor provides
insight into the future of technological progress. Where are we now? This is exactly
the question asked and answered by Ray Kurzweil (1999):
So where do we stand now? There has been about thirty two doublings of speed and capacity
since the first operating computers in the 1940s. Where we stand right now is that we have
finished the first half of the chessboard. And, indeed, people are starting to take notice. Now,
as we head into the next century, we are heading into the second half of the chessboard. And
this is where things start to get interesting. (Kurzweil 1999, p. 37)

It is true that exponential growth for a variable y (e.g. constant doubling) gives
rise to phenomenal increases. But it is true, also, that combinatorial growth for a
variable z is by far faster than exponential growth. For example, the number
corresponding to the 15th square of the chessboard is 16.384 but 15! is the astro-
nomical number 2.6525  1032. To reiterate, combinatorial growth explodes very
quickly.

Appendix K: Robots, Artificial Intelligence, and Technological


Singularity

Robots: Origin of the Term and Rules of Behaviour

Karel Čapek (1890–1938) coined the term ‘robot’ in 1920. The word ‘robot’ comes
from the Czech word ‘robota’ which means ‘forced labour.’ Čapek wrote long before
science fiction became established as a separate genre. He is one of the founders of a
branch of science fiction which focuses on possible future human evolution on Earth,
rather than technically advanced stories of space travel.
174 7 Looking to the Distant Future

Čapek wrote the dystopian science fiction masterpiece novel Robots First Czech
In. The play begins with the general manager of Rossum’s Universal Robots
discussing the potential of his assembled beings to raise living standards. The
manager predicts that his robot labourers will lower the prices of products to zero,
ending toil and poverty for all time. Nevertheless, what he was unable to predict is
that the robots decided to overthrow their masters and destroy all humans.
Isaac Asimonov (1920–1992) coined the word robotics in 1941 and had enor-
mous influence on real-world robot making. The creation of robots has been
attracting increasing attention among scientists and science fiction writers. In
1942, Asimonov drew up three rules that should govern robot behaviour:
Rule 1. Never harm a human through action or inaction;
Rule 2. Obey human orders (subject to Rule 1); and
Rule 3. A robot must protect its existence (subject to Rules 1 and 2)
I, Robot is a book containing nine science fiction stories written by Isaac
Asimonov. The stories originally appear in American magazines between 1940
and 1950. The book contains a short story in which Asimonov’s famous three
rules appear. The stories are woven together by a framing narrative. The (fictional)
Dr Susan Calvin is a chief robopsycologist at US Robots and Mechanical Men Inc..,
the major manufacturer of robots. She is interested in what is happening in their
positronic brain.

Artificial Intelligence: Definition and a Small Sample of Successes

Intelligent human behaviour comprises several types of mental activities (simple


computation, data processing, pattern recognition, problem solving, judgement,
creativity, etc.). According to the Miriam-Webster dictionary, Artificial Intelligence
(AI) is “the capability of a machine to imitate intelligent human behaviour.” This
definition immediately evokes important economic issues. For example, what hap-
pens to human employment if AI allows an ever-increasing number of tasks previ-
ously performed by human labour to become automated?
Electricity, internal combustion engines, and semiconductors facilitated automa-
tion in the last century. AI is a new facilitator of automation that may allow tasks
once thought to be out of reach from automation (think of driving cars and making
medical recommendations) to succumb.
In 1997 Gary Kasparov [the best chess player on the planet] was beaten by the
IBM supercomputer Deep Blue. This computer was able to calculate up to 330 mil-
lion moves per second. Kasparov could consider about 100 moves per go. Deep Blue
did not have Kasparov’s creativity, his intuition, strategic insight, and so on. Deep
Blue just had the brute force of computer power.
Watson is a supercomputer that represents IBM’s attempt to crack the market for
AI. In 2011, Watson won a specially staged version of an American TV quiz show
called ‘jeopardy! Innovators are currently developing commercial applications for
Watson.
Appendices 175

In March 2016, AlphaGo defeated the world’s best player of Go.14 It did so by
‘learning’ the game, crunching through 30 million positions from recorded matches,
reacting and anticipating. It evolved as a player and taught itself. AlphaGo was
designed by the organization DeepMind.
‘Cognitive computing’ refers to a software able to modify itself, and then learn as
it goes along. This principle is behind Watson and AlphGo. That single success of
AlphaGo marks a milestone on the road to the ultra-intelligent machine. AI is
moving toward “superintelligence,” which denotes “intellect that is smarter than
the best humans’ brains in practically every field, including scientific creativity,
general wisdom and social skills.” (Bostrom 2006)
Artificial Intelligence (AI) brings with it the anxiety that machines will eventually
threaten humankind, a dread underpinned by the attribution to machines of our
evolutionary instinct to survive at the expense of lesser species.

Technological Singularity

It is quite common nowadays to hear about “Singularity.” Assume that a black hole
has a boundary. What happens when you cross the boundary of a black hole? Within
the black hole’s boundary the normal laws of physics break down. This is the
meaning of the term “singularity” in astrophysics. By analogy, a “technological
singularity” breaks down the rules of society due to the creation of a fully conscious
machine. The advent of superhuman intelligence provokes a drastic discontinuity in
the history of humankind.
Mathematicians and computer scientists have looked into the future and predicted
that technology is moving toward “technological singularity” associated with infinite
intelligence in finite time. Visionary mathematician Norbert Wiener adumbrated the
singularity in 1949:
(. . .) if we move in the direction of making machines which learn and whose behaviour is
modified by experience, we must face the fact that every degree of independence we give the
machine is a degree of possible defiance of our wishes. The genii in the bottle will not
willingly go back in the bottle, nor have we any reason to expect them to be well disposed to
us. In short, it is only a humanity which is capable of awe, which will also be capable of
controlling the new potentials which we are opening for ourselves. We can be humble
and live a good life with the aid of the machines, or we can be arrogant and die. (Norbert
Wiener 1949)15

Good (1965) and Vinge (1993) suggested the possibility of a self-improving AI


leading to an “intelligence explosion.” An ultra-intelligent machine is the last

14
The ancient Chinese board game Go was created long before the invention of writing to represent
the spoken word. According to legend, a Chinese emperor invented this game to teach his subjects
balance and patience, qualities that appear to be unique to human intelligence. This game requires
intuition, strategizing, character reading, along with vast number of moves and permutations.
15
The quotation is from the excerpts published in Markoff (2013).
176 7 Looking to the Distant Future

innovation humans would make. How come? More than 50 years ago, the mathe-
matician Irving Good explained:
Let an ultraintelligent machine be defined as a machine that can far surpass all the intellectual
activities of any man however clever. Since the design of machines is one of these
intellectual activities, an ultraintelligent machine could design even better machines; there
would be then unquestionably an “intelligence explosion,” and the intelligence of man
would be left far behind. Thus the first ultraintelligent machine is the last invention that
man need ever make, provided that the machine is docile enough to tell us how to keep it
under control. It is curious that this point is made so seldom outside of science fiction. It is
sometimes worthwhile to take science fiction seriously. (Good 1965, p. 33) [Italics in
original]

Vinge (1993) believes that technological singularity will cause a discontinuity in


human evolution and the human era will be ended. Opinions about whether anything
like the technological singularity will ever occur are divided. Ray Kurzweil in his
book The Singularity is Near predicts that technological singularity will happen
circa 2045.
One immediate consequence of reaching the singularity point (i.e. smart
machines have achieved superintelligence) is that humans become economically
superfluous because they make no difference to economic performance. The Second
Machine Age contains a brief discussion of technological singularity (Brynjolfsson
and McAfee 2014, pp. 254–257). Ford (2015) devotes a whole chapter (entitled
Super-Intelligence and the Singularity) to this highly speculative topic. 2018 Nobel
Prize winner William D. Nordhaus draws the conclusion that technological singu-
larity is not near: “Fortunately, the euthanasia of the labouring classes is far off and
will flash sufficient warning signals so that, if it does occur, humans will have time to
contemplate the social structures of such an era.” (Nordhaus 2015, p. 38).
Reverting to the robot economy paradox, it should be clear that this paradox does
not presuppose that technology has reached the singularity point. However, if
technological singularity occurs the robot economy paradox is likely to happen.

References

Acemoglu D, Restrepo P (2019) The wrong kind of AI? Artificial intelligence and the future of
labour demand. National Bureau of Economic Research, working paper 25682. http://w.w.w.
nber.org/papers/w25682. pp 1–13
Arthur WB (1994) Increasing returns and path dependence in the economy. University of Michigan,
Ann Harbor
Arthur WB (1996) Increasing returns and the new world of business. Harvard Business Review,
July–August, pp 100–109
Arthur WB (2011) The second economy. McKinsey Quarterly, October
Arthur WB (2017) Where is technology taking the economy? McKinsey Quarterly, October
Bostrom N (2006) How long before superintelligence. Linguist Philos Investig 5:11–30
Brynjolfsson E, McAfee A (2014) The second machine age: work, progress, and prosperity in a
time of brilliant technologies. W.W. Norton & company, New York
References 177

Ford M (2015) The rise of the robots. Technology and the threat of mass unemployment. Oneworld
Publications, London
Frey C, Osborne M (2013) The future of employment: how susceptible are jobs to computerization?
Oxford University Press
Good IJ (1965) Speculations concerning the first ultraintelligent machine. Adv Comput 99:31–83
Keynes JM (1930) “Economic possibilities for our grandchildren” in the collected writings of john
maynard keynes, Volume IX. In: Essays in persuasion, vol 1972. Macmillan Press, London, pp
321–332
Kurzweil R (1999) The age of spiritual machines. When computers exceed human intelligence.
Penguin, London
Lee K-F (2017) The real threat of artificial intelligence. The New York Times, 25 June
Leontief WW (2019) Essays in economics. Routledge, New York
Markoff J (2013) In 1949, he imagined an age of robots. The New York Times, May 21
Marx K (1906) Capital: a critique of political economy. Modern Library, New York. First published
in 1867
Moore H (1906) Paradoxes of competition. Q J Econ 20:211–230
Nordhaus W (2015) Are we approaching an economic singularity? Information technology and the
future of economic growth. National Bureau of Economic Research, working paper 21547.
http://w.w.w.nber.org/papers/w21547, September
Romer P (2008) Economic growth. Library of Economics and Liberty. http://www.econlib.org/
library/Enc/EconomicGrowth.html
Schumpeter JA (2010) Capitalism, socialism, and democracy, with an introduction by Joseph
E. Stiglitz. Routledge Classics, London/New York. First published in vol. 1942
Shiller RJ (2017) Robotization without taxation? Project Syndicate, 02 April
Vinge V (1993) The coming technological singularity: how to survive in the Post-Human Era.
NASA VISION-21 Symposium, March 30–31
Voltaire F-MA (1991) Candide. Dover Publications, Mineola. First published in vol. 1759
Von Drehle D (2013) Winner and Losers in the new robot economy. Time, 09 September
Afterthoughts

In bringing this book to a close, we would like to point out two separate issues. First,
it is appropriate to elucidate the logical connection between the Invisible Hand and
the Creative Economy to avoid misinterpretation. Most economists believe in the
magic incantation of the Invisible Hand of Adam Smith. The reason is well known.
Free markets normally move resources into occupations from which they derive the
greatest advantage and free-market incentives induce people to devote their energies
to producing innovations that add to economic prosperity. Because the Creative
Economy is a market-guided economy, it follows at once that the Invisible Hand
holds sway in a Creative Economy.
The economic logic developed in Chap. 7 appears to challenge Adam Smith’s
idea that humans are always guided, as if by an Invisible Hand, to promote economic
prosperity when pursuing their self-interest. Under the assumption of increasing
returns to automation, unfettered economic freedom combined with private property
of the means of production would make the Creative Economy converge to a
dystopian economy where robot-based enabling products owned by a tiny elite do
all the work, while the vast majority of the population face a meaningless existence
and a hopeless future.
At first glance, it appears a contradiction in terms to say that the Invisible Hand
could lead to a dystopian economy. However, we have to reiterate here what we
mentioned before in Appendix B: the Invisible Hand brings economic prosperity but
is uninterested in the distribution of prosperity. Consequently, there is no
contradiction.
It is difficult to avoid the conclusion that some sort of government policy
intervention will be required to avoid the convergence to a dystopian economy.
Future generations of economists and social scientists will have to rise to the
challenge of designing such policies.
As to the second issue, in a forthcoming article in the Journal of Economic
Literature – entitled “What Students Learn in Economics 101: Time for a Change”
– Samuel Bowles and Wendy Carlin argue that it is time for updating and
modernizing the content of introductory economics courses to include many of the

© Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. 2020 179


J. E. Fernandez-Pol, C. Harvie, Understanding the Creative Economy and the Future
of Employment, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-1652-8
180 Afterthoughts

achievements of the discipline in the past thirty years. In their view, the current
textbooks in use are anachronistic and are not in tune with students’ current
concerns. They advocate the use of the New CORE textbook, The Economy,
available on the Internet for free.
We praise their essay, but praise does not imply perfection. Unfortunately, we
cannot conceal the fact that innovation as an economic activity is not touched upon.
Although Bowles and Carlin believe that their CORE textbook represents a “new
paradigm” imparting an understanding of “what every economics student should
know,” we reiterate that innovation is a prime mover of the modern economy, and
therefore, no complete understanding of the economy is possible without a thorough
grounding of a world based on profit-seeking innovation.
We firmly believe that it would be enormously beneficial for business and
economics students to have at their disposal a text for understanding the relevance
of innovation from an economic perspective. We hope that our book – used as a
supplement to that of orthodox economics texts – may help in changing the percep-
tion that economics, as currently taught, is irrelevant in a rapidly changing world
economy.
Index of Names

A C
Acemoglu, D., 161 Cannon-Brookes, M., 70
Aghion, P., 45, 46 Čapek, K., 173, 174
Airbnb, 102 Carlson, C., 69
AlphaGo, 175 Christensen, C., 100, 101, 103, 105, 106
Amazon’s anticipatory shipping, 97, 110 Clean Up the World, 110
Apple, 5 Coleman, D., 133
Apple’s App store, 84 Compton, K., 83
Archimedes, 65 Coy, P., 29
d’Argenson, 21
Aristotle, 54
Arrow, K.J., 16 D
Arthur, W.B., 157 D’Aloisio, N., 83
Asimonov, I., 174 Delloite, R., 143, 144
Atlassian, 70 Delvaux, M., 160
Digital Equipment Corporation (DEC),
101, 102
B Dodgson, M., 56, 96, 106
Backhouse, R.E., 18 Dogge, G., 72
Bakhshi, H., 134 Doriot, G.F., 83
Barrie, M., 91 Doyle, A.C., 52
Baumol, W.J., 24 Von Drehle, D, 154
Bell, A.G., 127
Bentham, J., 12
Berners-Lee, T., 5 E
BHP, 124 eBay, 167
Bíró, G., 102 Edison, T.A., 57, 127
Bíró, L., 102 Elijah, 36
de Bono, E., 53, 67
Borland, J., 142
Bostrom, N., 175 F
Boulton, M., 4 Facebook, 102, 110
Brynjolfsson, E., 138, 157, 158, 160, 161 Farquhar, S., 70
Byrne, D., 102 Fernstedt, A., 159

© Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. 2020 181


J. E. Fernandez-Pol, C. Harvie, Understanding the Creative Economy and the Future
of Employment, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-1652-8
182 Index of Names

Finkel, A., 90, 139 Levy, F., 136


Ford, Henry, 60, 127 Louis XV, 21
Ford, Henry.II, 159 Ludd, N., 116
Ford, M., 124, 128, 158, 160
Forziery fountain pens, 102
Frey, C., 10, 133, 134 M
Fray, S., 84 Mack, R., 62
Mahan, J., 72
Markoff, J., 159, 175
G Marshall, A., 12, 35, 68, 117, 118, 126
Galbraith, J.K., 16 Martin, S., 94
Galileo, 57 Marx, K., 106, 117, 118, 162, 163
Gates, B., 103, 127, 160 Mayer, J., 133
George, M.L., 105 McAfee, A., 138, 157, 158, 160
Gillette’s razor, 7 McCollum, A., 110
Microsoft, 5
Momentum Machines, 122, 133
H Moore, G., 168
Hall, H.R., 61 Moore, H., 153
Harrison, G., 62 Moskovitz, D., 110
Harrod, R., 9 Murdoch, R., 84
Heilbroner, R.L., 12 Murdoch, W., 84
Heppelman, J., 120
Hicks, J.R., 16, 55, 143, 144
Holmes, S., 52 N
Houdini, 72 Nelson, R.R., 20
Howitt, P., 45, 46 Newton, I., 11, 35
Hughes, C., 110 Nordhaus, W.D., 46, 176

I O
IBM personal computer (PC), 100 Olsen, K., 102
Ono, Y., 84
Osborne, M., 10, 133, 134
J
Jefferson, T., 57
P
Penn, J., 72
K Pisano, G.P., 98
Kasparov, G., 174 Plato, 35, 54
Kaufer, E., 57 Pol, E., 23, 69, 108
Kepler, J., 12 Porter, M.E., 30, 39, 77, 120
Keynes, J.M., 9, 12, 21, 23, 24, 118, 119 Potter, H., 54, 69, 70
Kittel, A., 94 Potts, J., 142
Krawchuk, H.-L., 36
Kutcher, A., 84
Kuznets, S., 20, 68 Q
Kurzweil, R., 173 Quesnay, F., 12, 21

L R
Lee, K.-F., 158 Raynor, M.E., 104
Leontief, W., 157 Redarc Electronics, 94
Index of Names 183

Restrepo, P., 161 U


Reuther, W., 159 US Robots and Mechanical Men Inc., 174
Ricardo, D., 12, 116, 117
Rio, T., 124
Robinson, J., 9 V
Robotic Process Automation (RPA), 123 Vardakostas, A., 122
Roddan, M., 90 Vella, I., 124
Romer, P.M., 6, 33, 34, 37, 39, 46 Ville, S., 108
Rosenberg, N., 20 Viner, J., 18
Rossum’s Universal Robots, 174 Vinge, V., 175
Rowling, J.K., 54, 69, 70 Voltaire, 128, 138, 160

S W
Salavoy, P., 133 Walsh, A., 90
Sandel, M., 160 Walter (robot bartender), 137
Saverin, E., 110 Warsh, D., 19
Schmookler, J., 47 Watson, Dr, 52
Schumpeter, J.A., 12, 19, 20, 28, 29, 36, 37, 39, Watt, J., 4, 127
118, 119, 162, 164 Whitney, E., 4, 60
Scott, D.A., 104 Wiener, N., 159, 175
Selden, G.B., 60 Winter, S., 20
Shadows, 72 WorkFusion, 123, 124
Shiller, R.J., 10, 160, 161 Wright, O., 129
Sinodinos, A., 90 Wright, W., 129
Sinovel Wind Group, 63
Smith, A., 21–24
Smith, S., 69 Y
Socrates, 35, 54 Yahoo!, 84
Solow, R.M., 20, 46 Young, A.A., 20
Summly, 84 Yunus, M., 109

T Z
Teller, R.J., 72 Zuckerberg, M., 110
Trimit, 84
Turnbull, M., 89, 90
Twitter, 102
Subject Index

A B
Adverse selection, 82 Background model, 28, 32, 33
Agricultural mechanization, 127 Basic model, 28, 37, 38
Angel investors and combinatorial possibilities, 170
characterized, 85 components of, 38
Anticipation exercises, 132–135 and innovation environment, 76
Arthur’s prophecy, 165 Bifocal innovations, 110
and Arthur’s prophecy, 164 Bogus patent, defined, 58
Artificial intelligence (AI) Business incubators, 85
and anxiety, 175 Business innovation(s)
and automation, 174 defined, 109
defined, 176 and social innovation, xiii, 109
as a new form of automation, 138 and technological progress, 21
and non-routine congnitive tasks, 138
right kind of, 161
and the singularity, xi C
sofware, 136, 161 Ceteris paribus assumption, 8
threat from, 125 Chance events, 80
Atlassian, 70 Chess, 171–173
Augmented reality (AR), 120 and the power of exponential growth, 171
Australian National Audit Office (ANOA), story of the Emperor and the Inventor, 171
91 Chessboard
Automation first-half of, 172, 173
anxiety, 127 second-half of, 172, 173
and artificial intelligence, 174 Choices, 3
bias toward, 162 Clusters
bottlenecks to, 133 anatomy of, 78
high risk of, 133 defined, 78
high-skill, 138 Collective assets, 80
impact on human labour, 161 Combinatorial, 170
increasing returns to, 147 and exponential growth, 173
low-skill, 138 growth, 171
probability of, 133, 134 Commoditization, 94, 105
relentless progression toward, 114 characterized, 100
technologies, 121 and the IBM personal computer (PC), 100

© Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd. 2020 185


J. E. Fernandez-Pol, C. Harvie, Understanding the Creative Economy and the Future
of Employment, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-1652-8
186 Subject Index

Compensating effect, 118, 126, 129 Design philosophy, 161


Competition Digital labour, 138, 156
actual, 79 and ideation, 133
local, 79 Digitization
potential, 79 characterized, 167
Competitive advantage Digitized economy, 5, 167
and clusters, 77 Disciplinary ladders, 139
and cost advantage, 76 Discovery, defined, 57
defined, 76 Displacement effect, 118, 126, 129
and differential advantage, 76 Disruptive innovation(s), 94, 101, 104
domestic, 81 and creative destruction, 102
four determinants of, 78 defined, 101
international, 81
Constant doubling, 169, 173
Copyright(s) E
characterized, 61 Economic growth
and internet piracy, 62 and technological progress, 20
and moral rights, 62 Economic human, 10, 54
and smiley face, 61 Economic models
infringement and Shadows, 72 and assumptions, 8
infringements, 62 characterized, 8
term of, 61 purely descriptive, 9
Cost minimization, 106, 129, 131 and theories, 13
Counterbalancing forces, 126 as tools of analysis, 9
Creative act, 29, 50 Economic narratives, 10
Creative destruction, 37, 45, 119 Economic performance
and disruptive innovation, 102 good, 3
Creative economy poor, 3
and business innovation, 32 Economic predictions, 143
characterized, ix and the ceteris paribus clause, 16
defined, 29 and data, 16, 114
and enabling products, 126 lack of credibility, 16
and endogenous growth theory, xii Economic prosperity
human unemployment, 106 distribution, 24, 179
and technological unemployment, 131 and invisible hand, 24, 179
Creative human, 11, 54 production, 24
Creative intelligence, see Ideation Economics, ix
Creative society aim of, 13
and creative economy, 30 characterized, 6
defined, 29 progress in, 11
Creative thinking, x, xiii, 51–56 of robots, 20, 21
and collaborative networks, 56 as a toolbox, 9
and intelligent algorithms, 55 working definition of, 18
Creativity, ix, x, 32 Economy, ix
Critical thinking, 54, 55, 138 automated, 146
defined, 55 as a complex, variable system, 4
and knowledge of the subject matter, 67 defined, 2
dystopian, 179
Panglossian, 128
D performance of, 3
Demand for labour, 116 strong, 3
competing effects on, 126 weak, 3
reduction in, 126 Edison’s rule, 69
Subject Index 187

Efficient Firm’s Dilemma, 94 H


Elites, 163 Homo creativus, see Creative human
Emotional intelligence Home demand, 79
characterized, 133 Homo economicus, see Economic human
Employment Human capital, xii, 33–36, 44
future of, 10 defined, 35
Enabling description condition, 58, 70 suctioning machine, 157
Enabling firm(s), 120, 132 and tacit knowledge, 35
Enabling products, 120, 125 Human replacement, xi, 129
defined, 120 defined, 119
Endogenous growth theory, 13, 45 widespread, 115
assumptions, 45 Human work, 159
factors emphasized by, 115
and new growth theory, 20
Environmental protection, 20 I
Eureka! moment, 65 Ideas, 33–36, 41, 44
Exponential growth, 169 defined, 34
and chess, 171 as economic products, xii
and combinatorial growth, 173 with economic value, xii, 36, 54
Externality(ies) Ideation, defined, 133
defined, 71 Imaginary thinking
and knowledge spillovers, xiii characterized, 54
negative technological, 160 in economics, 54
pecuniary, 71 and science fiction, 54
technological, 71 Incentives regime, 89
Inclusive growth, 159
Increasing returns
F and AI, 158
Factorial, 37 to automation, xi, 158
and combinatorial growth, 173 defined, 158
Fast innovation approach, xi, 95 Induced innovation, 55
and Basic Model, 106 Industrial robots
characterized, 105 defined, 121
Fast innovation, defined, 105 equilibrium impact of, 121
Financial void, 83 Inescapable risks, 94
filling the, 83 Information and media
First industrial revolution, 4, 21 characterized, 167
First patent system, 56, 57 digitization, 167
First USA Patent Act, 57 Initial Public Offering (IPO), 70, 84
Food and Drug Administration (FDA), 83 defined, 82
Fourth industrial revolution (4IR), 5 Innovation
Future of work according to Schumpeter, 28
myths, 143 and creativity, 50
widespread anxiety about, 147 defined, 28
input, 95, 96
and the invisible hand, 23
G and living standards, 29
General purpose technologies (GPTs), and market power, 103
5, 68, 131 output, 95, 96
Government, 80 as a problem area of economics, xii, 18
support for innovation, 89 recombinant, 170
Growth and resource disadvantages, 78
combinatorial, 171 and resource strengths, 78
exponential, 135, 171, 173 risks associated with, x
Guiding insights, 13, 15 successful, 100
188 Subject Index

Innovation as an economic activity, 7 and income distribution, 23


and creative economy, 28 and innovation, xii
dimensions of, ix, 32 and profit-seeking innovators, 22
and microeconomic concepts, 94 passage, 22
and technological externalities, 71 theorem, 23
Innovation Campus (iC), 80
Innovation costs, characterized, 100
Innovation-driven economy(ies), 10, 31, 32 J
and creative economy, 31 Job(s), 165
Innovation environment, x, xiii, 32 defined, 132
Innovation infrastructure
appropriate, 77
characterized, 77 K
Innovation life cycle Knowledge spillovers, xiii, 68
characterized, 82 and clusters, 77
Innovation process(es), 94 defined, 71
characterized, 95
new perspective, 106
Innovation project L
partially successful, 96 Labour-augmenting
technically unsuccessful, 96 innovations, 129, 162
Innovative companies on the whole, 140
two types, x Labouring classes
Innovator(s), 28, 81 euthanasia of, 176
behaving badly, 92 Labour-intensive tasks, 127
not eligible borrowers, 83 Labour-saving innovations, 106, 127, 129, 162
and population growth, 68 and cost-reducing innovations, 106
profile of the ideal, 84 Labour-saving machines
Innovator’s Dilemma and repetitive tasks, 117
optimal response to, 104 Labour-saving “mechanical muscle” machines,
stated, 104 122
Institution(s), 8 Labour-saving technologies, 127, 155
several meanings, 77 Large numbers, 172
Intangible resources, 78 Lateral thinking
Intellectual property, 33, 50 and analogies, 53
characterized, 56 defined, 53
cyber-enabled theft of, 63 and schizophrenic thinking, 67
further aspects, xiii Learning curve
Intelligence practical use of, 135
external, 157, 164 Linkages
internal, 156, 157, 164 and Cooperative Research Centers (CRCs),
Internet piracy, 62 80
Invention, defined, 57 Logical inference
Invisible hand characterized, 51
as a conjecture, 23 and mathematics, 51, 66, 67
context of, 22, 23 and vertical thinking, 53
and creative economy, 179 Logical thinking
dectrine, 23 defined, 51
and economic Darwinism, 24 two types of, 51
of God, 24 Luddites, 116
Subject Index 189

M P
Machinery question, 119 Panglossian economy, 128, 132, 142–144
meaning, 116 Patent(s)
return of, 119 characterized, 56
revival of, 133 exclusion, 58
Macroeconomics, defined, 7 expiring, 59
Magic tricks, xiii and generic drugs, 59
and trade secrets, 72 infringements, 60
Market-guided economy licensing, 59
characterized, 22 portfolio of, 60
and creative economy, 29, 179 sleeping, 60
invisible hand of, 22, 23 trolls, 60
Marshall decomposition formula, 118, 126 Patentability guidelines, 57
Marshall’s dictum, 68 Perception tasks, 133
Marxism, 162 Perpetual innovation, 37, 106
Marx’s prediction, 106, 117 Perpetual motion machine, 38
Mathematical model(s), 9, 45, 46 Photocopier, 69
Mathematical technologies, 51 Physical economy, 146, 156, 157, 165
Mathematics, 56, 66 Physiocrats, 21
Mental Porter
activities, 174 development path, 31
functions, 122, 125 diamond, 78
tasks, 136 Prediction, ix
Metcalfe’s law, 168 about the next economy, 131
Microeconomics, defined, 7 Principal agent
Moore’s law, 168 problem, 92
exponential growth, 169 relations, 91
Moral hazard, 82 Principle of plenitude, 19
Private ideas, 71
Process innovation, 97
N Product(s)
Narrative model(s), 9, 30 excludable, 42
example of, 10 experience, 64
Narratives, 10 of human ingenuity, 58
National Innovation and Science Agenda of nature, 58
(NISA), 89 non-excludable, 42
and ANOA, 91 non-rival, 41
criticisms, 90 partially excludable, 42
Network(s) rival, 40
defined, 167 search, 64
economies, 167 Product innovation, 97
New Profit motive, 6, 46
to the Australian economy, 97 and technological progress, 115
to the world, 97 Profitable new ideas, 4
New growth theory, 20 and creative economy, 29, 36
Non-human capital, 37 and innovation infrastructure, 77
Non-obviousness condition, 58 and successful business innovations, 36
Profit-seeking R&D, defined, 96
Protective belt against robots, 135
O components of, 139
Occupation-based approach, 132 Pure
Old growth theory, 13, 46 business innovation, 112
Oligopsony, 85 social innovation, 112
Organic growth, 105 Pythagorean theorem, 41
190 Subject Index

R S
Recipient firms, 120 Say’s law, 121
Recombinant innovation, 37, 45, 170 Scandinavian solution, 165
Related and supporting industries, 79 Scarcity, 3
Reliable inference, 52 and the definition of economics, 18
Research and Development (R&D) Schumpeter’s prophesy, xii, 147, 164
commercially driven, 96 Second economy, 10
curiosity driven, 96 Second industrial revolution, 4
defined, 96 Singularity
project, 97 in astrophysics, 175
undertakings, 97 technological, 175
Resource disadvantages, 78 Smart connected products, 120
Resource endowments, 39 Smart machines, 115, 119
characterized, 78 Social innovation
and venture capital, 78 and business innovation, xiii, 109
Resource strengths, 78 defined, 109
Reverse engineering, 70 Social intelligence
Risk 1 (technical risk), 98 defined, 133
Risk 2 (commercial risk), 99 Socialism, 164
Risk 3 (economic risk), 99 Social robots, 124
Robot(s) Social skills, 137
and automation technologies, 121 a mild form of, 165
coiner of the term, 173 Socratic method, 54
defined, 121 Software
rules of behaviour, 173 code, 41, 43
tax, 160 copyright, 71
Robot Economy(ies), 129, 131, 153, 155 patent, 71
narrative, 10, 146, 154 piracy, 43
new definition of, 154, 155 Solow decomposition formula, 45
onset of, 155 Space pollution, 20
Whatls.com definition, 154 Stick-in-the mud economy, 29
Robot Economy Paradox, 164 and misoneism, 40
apocryphal anecdote, 159 Stylized economies, 30
and Schumpeter’s famous prophecy, 162 efficiency-driven economies, 31
stated, 158 factor-driven economy, 30
and technological singularity, 175 innovation-driven economy, 31
tentative solution # 1, 160 Successful innovation, 94
tentative solution # 2, 160 Supercomputers
tentative solution # 3, 161 AlphaGo, 175
Robot-based enabling products, 129, 132, Deep Blue, 174
137, 179 Watson, 174
catalyst behind, 131 Supply and demand model, 55
defined, 125 and venture capital market, 85
effects on employment, 126 Sustaining innovation(s)
and enabling products, 125 and the innovator’s dilemma, 103
and human replacement, 129 defined, 101
new waves of, 157
Robotic Process Automation (RPA), 98, 123
Robotize/perish, 132 T
Romer’s model Tacit knowledge
message, 47 characterized, 35
Rorschach test, 142 Task(s)
Rule “MR ¼ MC”, 52, 67 cognitive/manual, 136
Subject Index 191

content of production, 122 Third industrial revolution, 5


and conventional approach in economics, Trade secret(s)
121 defined, 62
mapping skills to, 137 thefts, 63
repetitive, 117 Trademarks
routine/non-routine, 136 characterized, 64
six categories of, 137 and packaging, 64
Task-based approach, 132, 134 T-shaped knowledge worker(s), 135, 136
Technological externality(ies), 71 Two-way classification of products, 43
and human replacement, 160
negative, 160
Technological innovations, 97 U
Technological progress (or technological Ultra-intelligent machine, 175
change), 129 Unemployment
and economic growth, 20, 45 and Schumpeter, 163
and human jobs, 166 Universal Basic Income (UBI), 160
mutually reinforcing attributes, 166 Usefulness condition, 58
and the profit motive, 6, 115
and profit-seeking innovation, 128
skill-biased, 137 V
in the Twenty-First century, xiv Venn diagram, 111
Technological singularity, 175 Venetian glass, 51
and the Robot economy paradox, 175 Venture-backed firms, 83
Technological unemployment, 119, 127, Venture capital
129, 131 defined, 82
becoming a reality, 157 Venture-capitalist-innovator relationship,
as defined by Keynes, 119 xiii, 91
keynes’s definition, 147, 148 Venture capitalists (VCs), 83
onset of, 152 Venture capital market, 82
pervasive, 129 defined, 85
risk of, 141 pattern of behaviour, 84
in symbols, 148 Vertical thinking, see Logical inference
visual description of, 152 Virtual economy, 146, 156, 157, 165
Technology Voluntary unemployment, 157
as a human capital suctioning machine, 157
Technology enthusiasts, xi, 106, 114, 127–129,
139, 141 W
and historical extrapolations, 128 Watson, 71
Technology sceptics, xi, 106, 114, 128, 129 Worldly philosophers, 11
argument of, 129
T-entrepreneurs (Transnational entrepreneurs),
81 X
Thinking in general, 7 Xerography, 69
Thinking like an economist, 7

Potrebbero piacerti anche