Sei sulla pagina 1di 9

Understanding Agrarian Impasse in Bihar

Author(s): Avinash Kishore


Source: Economic and Political Weekly , Jul. 31 - Aug. 6, 2004, Vol. 39, No. 31 (Jul. 31 -
Aug. 6, 2004), pp. 3484-3491
Published by: Economic and Political Weekly

Stable URL: http://www.jstor.com/stable/4415344

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

Economic and Political Weekly is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to Economic and Political Weekly

This content downloaded from


52.172.200.163 on Sat, 20 Jun 2020 17:50:54 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Understanding Agrarian Impasse in Bihar
The key hypothesis of policy-makers during the 1980s was that raising tubewell density would
trigger agrarian upsurge in Bihar as it did in Punjab, Haryana and western UP. The state
did record high growth rates of cereal yields during the 1980s, higher than the national
figures. However, this promising development could not be sustained in the 1990s, and cereal
yields have stagnated since then. Based on fieldwork in eight villages of Bihar, the paper
argues that, more than agrarian structure, the lack of adequate infrastructure and
economic incentives has contributed to the agrarian stagnation in Bihar. The growth potential
unleashed by the expansion of shallow tubewell irrigation has been constrained
by (a) complete neglect of public sector investments in physical and institutional infrastructure
and (b) unfavourable output to factor price ratios.

AVINASH KISHORE

Gopalganj, Darbhanga and Madhubani in north Bihar. While


Introduction Darbhanga and Madhubani are agriculturally least developed,
Nalanda and Bhabhua are agriculturally the most developed
fter a century-long stagnation, agriculture in eastern India districts. Muzaffarpur, Saran and Gopalganj fall in between these
experienced a turn around in 1980s with rapid ground-two extremes. This paper is an attempt to distill the lessons learned
water development. Especially, West Bengal and eastern during the fieldwork in these eight villages and put them in
Uttar Pradesh performed very well with growth rates in productionperspective of the larger reality of agricultural development in
becoming as high as 4-6 per cent during 1981-82 to 1991-92. Bihar.
Agricultural production and productivity levels in the 'middle
state' Bihar also witnessed a growth higher than the long-term Ill
growth trend of the state [Pandey and Pal 2000]. Yet, agriculture Literature Review
in the state grew at a slower pace, over a smaller base, for a shorter
time after which the momentum was lost in spite of an impressive Till 1970s, the literature from agrarian studies were dominated
expansion of tubewell irrigation. by discussion on issues related to agrarian structure and pro-
This paper tries to explore the reasons for this relapse. The duction relations, groundwater development through expansion
first section of the paper presents a review of literature availableof tubewell irrigation and development of water markets became
from the existing body of research on reasons for the persistentthe thrust area after the pioneering RBI report on agricultural
agrarian stagnation in eastern India. The second section explores productivity in eastern India [RBI 1984].
Agriculture in Bihar has remained stagnant in spite of rich soil,
the latest trends in tubewell irrigation and discusses the structure
of water markets and their productivity and equity implications abundance of easily accessible water and a rich peasant tradition.
based on data from a primary survey. The third section of the This stagnation has been ascribed to several factors including
paper discusses various macroeconomic factors which limit the state's colonial legacy [Bharadwaj 1993; Banerjee 2002;
farmers' ability to leverage the newly created pump capital toMearns 1999; Banerjee and Iyer 2002], ecological conditions
increase crop productivity and raise incomes. This understanding [Ballabh and Pandey 1997; Ballabh and Sharma 1990], demo-
is based on the knowledge of larger reality of agricultural scenario graphic pressure [Verma 1993] and most importantly, the land
in Bihar and observations from field survey. The last and thetenure system and the agrarian structure it supports [Bhaduri
concluding section discusses various alternatives for raising 1973; Prasad 1974]. These factors are believed to have impeded
crops yield and farm incomes based on studies of well-performing the transition of Bihar's agriculture from a semi-feudal to capi-
farms in the region. talist production system - an essential condition for agricultural
growth [Patnaik 1987].
II Inequitable land distribution and perverse land tenure relations
Methodology Used in Study are considered to be the backbone of semi-feudal agrarian struc-
ture in Bihar and therefore comprehensive land reforms is sug-
The study involved an extensive review of literature available gested as the policy measure. Abolition of 'zamindari', redistri-
on issues of agrarian structure and production relations, agricul- bution of surplus land, tenancy reforms and land consolidation
tural growth, groundwater development and water markets in are four components of comprehensive land reforms [Ballabh
eastern India and primary data collection using focused group and Walker 1992]. Among all Indian states, land reforms have
discussions and interview schedules. been the worst failure in Bihar, even when it took the first
The primary data were collected from field studies carried out initiative in this direction by abolishing the zamindari system
in eight villages from six districts of Bihar in 2003. Two of our in 1953. While West Bengal could accomplish tenancy reforms
villages are from Nalanda and Bhabhua districts of south Bihar through operation Barga and UP had considerable success in land
while the rest six are from districts, viz, Muzaffarpur, Saran, consolidation [Pant 2004] both projects were abysmal failure in

3484 Economic and Political Weekly July 31, 2004


This content downloaded from
52.172.200.163 on Sat, 20 Jun 2020 17:50:54 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Figure 1: Shallow Tubewell Density in Bihar while land has become less important. This is reflected in the
< 12.00 29.19 9.83 declining share of land in the gross value of produce. But, eastern
.c 10.00 7.2.
? 8.00 _ ._ _ 6.61' _____-- -_ India suffers from severe capital scarcity and existence of
monopolistic markets which exacerbate the existing inequality
2.00 and reinforce the outmoded structure. Machine-reforms, wherein
o~ 0.00
the government would help the resource poor farmers and land-
1986-1987- 1988-1989- 1990-1991-1992- 1993
less labourers to get ownership of agricultural implements so that
87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94

the inequity in landholdings could be compensated by equity in


Source: Minor Irrigation Census of India (1993).
access to groundwater and technology, can bulldoze the ossified
agrarian Pumpsets
Figure 2: Density of Bores and structure and unfold a new era of rapid agricultural
(per 100 ha if NCA)
growth with relative equity and reduced poverty. They suggest
1 00 _ - Bore Densitya government
[ Pump Density
supported and subsidised capital formation in 1
80
private sector with special targeting on poor and landless to bring
60 -
40 about the change.
0 --- This was in line with the key recommendation of the widely
quoted RBI report on eastern India [RBI 1984] which also
cI
m ()
CutseC
pm
E o,lg
l
0 r
: :c
stressed mainly on a machine based approach of exploiting
(003 fo o , region's abundant groundwater resources using shallow tubewell
technology to intensify irrigation and increase agricultural pro-
ductivity, thereby reducing poverty. Rapid tubewell capital
Source: Ballabh et al (2002) for Machhahi and Fari
formation through government subsidised projects like free-
(2003) for other seven village.
boring scheme became the corner stone of public policy in Bihar
Bihar. For all practical as well as in other eastern states. This marked athe
purposes, clear shift in
stat
on this project of land reforms.
the policy After
focus from land-based strategies to water the a
and machine
consolidation was passed in
capital-based strategy 1956
for agrarian change in Biha
in the region. Unlike
the total cultivated in
land
the past, thewas reported
tubewell capital formation was encouragedto h
mainly
till 1976 and in fact land
in the private domainconsolidation
and special targeted schemes like the
formally been abolished in
million wells scheme the
were devised state
for small [W
and marginal farmers
Changing the of scheduled of
structure castes and scheduled tribes.
landownership p
because zamindari Evolution system the
of rental markets inwas highly
pumpsets (often called wate
the dominant groups were
market in irrigationvery strongly
literature) helped overcome the probleme o
machinery itself. Thelumpinesspolitical
of investment and scale difficultie
bias of the tubewell techno-
Rath [cited in Bardhan and
logies, earlier thought to Rudra
be the main problems1979] in adoptionh
overpopulated statetheselike
technologiesBihar,
in Bihar and rest of it is
eastern futil
India having stam
size plots and highby
problem of rural poverty land fragmentation
re-distribut [Dhawanl982]. Wate
short supply as this marketswill have
facilitated access to
to groundwater be
of even ach
the small an
extremely low land marginal
ceilings farmers. Rapid which cannot
groundwater development took place i
economic considerations
Bihar powered by both or policyrational
push and private initiative. calDensit
Hayami (1981) argued of borewells
that and pumping
in sets had registered an exponenti
conditions o
population pressure growth
on over land, land
last two decades. Betweenreform
the two minor irrigatio i
censuses in 1986-87 andthe
and futile without reversing 1992-93, trend
the pump density ofincreased
in
land relative to labour.
fourfold inHe posited
Bihar (Figure that
1). Primary surveys carried out the
in nin
as long as increase in
villagessupply
in six districts of Bihar of labour
in 2002 and 2003 suggestou th
labour demand and the hence
pump density has te best
increased even morecurerapidly in theto last 1
and inequality was years
toafter augment
the latest minor irrigation land by
census (Figure i
2).2 Th
systems and developing land
surveys suggest that the density saviand
of borewells is much higher nd than
logies. He consideredthe pumpthe technocratic
density. In fact in these nine survey villages there ap w
practical approach for
one borewell agrarian transfor
for every 2.5 ha of cultivated area. Such high
since land redistribution
borewell densityis extremely
is a response to high and increasing landdif frag
and administratively mentation [Hayami
in the state and this has 1981].
been made possible by lo
cost of boring [Ballabh and Choudhary 2002) and portability
IV of diesel pumpsets.
From Land to Groundwater: The Paradigm Shift
Water Market as an Embedded Exchange: Examining
This has been the viewpoint of development economists, namely,
Polanyist Argument
Tushaar Shah and Richard Palmer-Jones also who argued that
in rainfed low productivity agricultural system control over land Even though the density of groundwater extraction measure
and labour were the key and as a result inequitable land distri- (WEMs) has rapidly increased, the actual role and potential o
bution has been at the core of the current outmoded agrarian this pump-led market based reform strategy to bring equitabl
structure. However, in the modern land-saving, inputinntensive growth in the precapitalist agrarian economy of Bihar has been
agriculture, access to capital holds the key to agricultural growth, questioned by many researchers (for instance Wood (1995),

Economic and Political Weekly July 31, 2004 3485

This content downloaded from


52.172.200.163 on Sat, 20 Jun 2020 17:50:54 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Figure 3: Land Ownership vs Water Selling marginal and small f
c 500
cent of all pumpsets
c) - 400 -
300 * * * total land-owned by
The IWMI survey sho
marginal category of
3 o-- owned pumpsets. From
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 farmers had nine
pum
Land (0.5
Ownership - 1 ha landholding

250 1-. o.. . . .----?-- .-------.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .


Thus, a large number
Figure 4: Hours of Pump-Renting vs L
small farmers, who ar
from their own fields
c 200
viable. They pump f
1 50 Woods (1995) and Dub
out pumpsets to imp
access to groundwate
R2 0.009 Interestingly, the ana
I 0 * 2--0;- - large farmers were sel
0 5 10 15 farmers. The correlat
20 25
Landholding inwater
Acres selling per yea
significant only at 90
Figure 5: Hours of probably
Pump-Renting vs Land
indicates inc
200 the well off sections o
the early days of gro
150-
taboo [Clay 1974 as c
Wood argues that qu
E 100
enders in groundwate
0 50 0 2 combinations irrigate
competitive kin secon
random group of non-
0 2 4 6 8 10 12
who are generally th
Landholding in Acres
deprived castes, like ta
more precarious acce
Chakravarty (2001)timeliness
and Wilson (2002).
and price T
village studies to show how machine d
realise the full poten
increased the inequity and strengthened
sub-optimal the
producti
capacity) of already dominant landlord
Wood's analysis was
rental markets forequipments s are
in Purnea: far
one from
of th
neutral as assumed Weinmade
neoclassical econ
an attempt t
that exchanges in rural water markets hav
of the state and if the
and they are essentially linked to the soc
Wood did his study. W
in social relationships.
yearThe
of imperfect, soc
water buyers
water markets have functioned to reinforc
correlation between
dependence, constraining the opportunity
insignificant. The sca
with non-favoured client status to and
large farmers increa
ve
sity. As a productivity outcome,
irrigation perland
acre is
ofeit
t
into the hands of adequately capitalised
farmers. The correlatf
with the new technology is under-realis
farmers (> 10 acres of
logical opportunities are socially const
correlation coefficien
productive purposes.
(0.525); positive and s
This, however, does not seem to be tru
level (Figure 5). This su
survey, we found access to groundwate
Table 1: Distribution
than the land distribution in Bihar.
Different Land Acco
Clas
irrigation census ( 1992), 76.67 per cent o
Farmer Size Marginal Small Medium Large
tubewells (STWs) in the <2.5acres state are
2.5-5acres 5-10acres owned
>10acres Total
farmers. This is much more than their sha
Pump-owners (PO) 34 39 31 30 134
land in the state. This was
Land (acres) 55.19corroborated
157.94 239.03 613.02 1065.18 in
of 263 Land/PO 1.62
carried farmers
out4.05 7.71by 20.43 7.95
IWMI i
Non-owners
districts of both north and south 64 29 22 Bihar14 129 (T
Land (acres) 66.96 118.66 158.57 187.8 531.99
the table, marginal farmers
Land/PO 1.05 4.09 7.21 in 13.41
the 4.12sam
Pumps/100 acre 27.83
of the total land cultivated by 14.10 7.80 3.75
the 8.39
sample
25 per cent of all pump-owners
Source: Primary Survey, 2003. in the

3486 Economic and Political Weekly July 31, 2004


This content downloaded from
52.172.200.163 on Sat, 20 Jun 2020 17:50:54 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Figure 6: Installation of Pumpsets over Last Two Decades over last decade. It would be interesting t
80 .. -76
76 more than half of all pumpsets the sampl
137) were purchased after 1995, the year w
60 carried their study in Muzaffarpur (Figur
42

40 Groundwater Irrigation Intensity in Ric


19
20- The irrigation pattern of pump-owners was
0 of renters for paddy and wheat. The purpo
was to see if the differential pumping patter
Till 1985 1985-95 After 1995 impacts on the productivity outcomes. In
portant crop for Bihar, there was no significa
Figure 7: Annual Pumpage pump-owners
Range (Rice and + Wheat)
renters ha of hours
in terms
32.87
per acre and crop yield (Table 3). Also, the
35.00 - percent hours of irrigation/acre of paddy and the yie
'5 30.00- 21.30 to be weak and insignificant at the state
D ' 25.00 percent 15.74
standable as rainfall in the survey year was
ce 25.00 -percent
E 20.00 14.35 percent
7.87 A recent collaborative study by Rajendra Ag
LL 15.00 2.78 per cent 4.63 (RAU) and International Rice Research Ins
0. 5.00 percent 0.46
5.00 pe'cent per cent villages of north Bihar also showed similar r
0.00 I I ,
coefficient being weak and insignificant in
0-25 25-50 50-75 75-100 100- 125- 150- 230
tion plotted for paddy [Singh, Paris and
125 150 175
Hours of Pumping/Year/ha
In the case of wheat, a weak but positi
correlation was found between pump-ow
an inverted 'U' shaped pattern vis-a-vis landholding size.
irrigation/acre Small
provided to the crop. Hours o
and medium farmers (cultivating 2.5 to also had of
10 acres weak but
land) positive and significant
practice
the most input intensive agriculture while theBut
them. sub-marginal and between pump-ow
the correlation
large farmers have diversified away from agriculture
insignificant. giving
A closer look at the data sugg
relatively lower attention to farming on their own
incidence of land.
pump-ownership was higher a
Wood's analysis of pumpset as an abettor south Bihar, wheat
of inequality yields were lower the
is not
This dichotomy
acceptable for two reasons: first, it was found was noticed during IWM
that diesel pumps
were the most widely distributed mechanical input
Farmers across various
in villages of south Bihar invest grea
landholding classes and castes in all the villages
and effort and second,crop
in kharif no while rabi crops
significant and systematic difference was noticed in the pump
Table Also,
rentals paid by different categories of farmers. 2: Increase
none of in the
Cost of Agricultural I
129 water purchasers in the sample complained Muzaffarpur
about any dif- between 1995 and 200
ficulty in accessing pumpsets on rent.Item
This 1995
is the(1)
reason
2003why
(2) Ratio (2/1)
except the severely waterlogged areas, almost all land cultivated
Diesel (Rs/liter) 7.85 24 3.05
by the sample farmers was irrigated. Irrigation (Rs/hr) 22-25/10-12 50-60 2.5
Over the years as pump densities have increased,
Tractor water markets
(Rs/ha) 400 825-1100 2.06
Team (Rs/day)
have become broader, deeper and more efficient and monopoly40 60 1.5
Thressor 16th share 10th share 1.6
rents have gone down significantly as is evident
Sowing from
Rs 20the
+ declining
Meal Rs 40 + Meal 2
water to diesel price ratio in the area. For example, when
Spade-work RsShah
20.00 Rs 40 2
and Ballabh studied the six villages in Weeding
1995, Rs 8-10/half
diesel daywas
price Rs 15/half day 1.5
Storage (Rs/qtl) 65 140 2.15
around Rs 7.50 - 9.05 while water price ranged from Rs 20 to
30 (Table 4 in Shah and Ballabh 1997:A-186).
Source:Seven years later,
Fieldwork Report of IRMA
Coordinated
when one of the six villages (Nariyar) was revisited, by Shah and Ball
it was found
authors' primary survey for dat
that while diesel price had increased more than threefold to
around Rs 25 per litre, water price in the village had increased
Table
only twofold from Rs 22-25 to Rs 50 per hour. 3: Crop-Economics
The water to diesel of
and High Yield of Wh
price ratio had declined from 2.80 - 3.18 to less than 2 now.
The timeline data on water to diesel price
Wheat ratio in Table
Modal Yield 4 of
(N = 23) High Yield (N = 5)
Shah and Ballabh (1997) study reveals that in
Yield 1990s, one
(Q/ha) rupee 20 34
increase in price of diesel used to cause several
Gross times higher
return 11,000 18,700
Seeds
increase in pump-rent in the market. IWMI's 1,339.2
field studies in Bihar1,573.75
Fertilisers 2,616.25 2,780
suggest that the trend has now reversed. Several water buyers
Tractor 1,965 2,600
admitted to us that pump rentals had not increased as frequently
Irrigation 1,756.25 2,250
as diesel prices after the recent enforcement of open cost
Labour market1,375
price 2,337.5
Total cost 9,051.7 11,541.25
regime on diesel. This indicates a significant increase in the buyer
Cost/quintal 452.58 339.44
power in the market which might have occurred due to increased
competition in the market induced by increase
Source: inPrimary
pump density
Survey, 2003.

Economic and Political Weekly July 31, 2004 3487

This content downloaded from


52.172.200.163 on Sat, 20 Jun 2020 17:50:54 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Figure 8: Pumping/ha of Wheat (Hours) of six villages in Muzaffarpur. Water buyers in IWMI's sample
50.00 44.29
also use lesser hours of groundwater irrigation but use it more
,_i? n ~ percent productively to reap same levels of yields as the pump owners.
E 40.00- 30.00 Thus, it can be inferred that water markets have become more
u" per cent widespread and dense over the years facilitating almost universa
30.00
0
access to groundwater in Bihar. Markets have also become more
c0 20.00 - 1 15.24
-~ 40.00-~ perentper cent efficient as evident from declining monopoly rents over the years
0 5.71 4.76 Even though groundwater irrigation has become widespread and
10.00 percent percent
Q. 0.00-- - market exchanges have become more equitable, the intensity of
0-25 25-50 50-70 70-90 100+ groundwater irrigation has remained quite low. Farmers continu
to economise on their irrigation cost which has risen sharply due
Figure 9: Yield Range (Rice to +
riseWheat) in
in diesel prices. TheTonnes/ha
need for upfront cash payment for
34.42 diesel pump irrigation also forces cash-starved farmers to under-
40.00- per cent irrigate. The economisation of irrigation cost is clearly evident from

e 30.00- 21.86
the annual pumpage data of all categories of farmers in our sample
16.28 percent 17.21 (Figure 7). Three-fourths of sample farmers in Bihar provide less
D 20.00- per cent ~ per cent 6.51
than hundred hours of irrigation per hectare of their land under
per cent 3.26 intensive rice-wheat cropping system. Assuming an average
percent 0.47
discharge of 35 m3/hour, the depth of irrigation works out to
0.000oo.00---II
10.00- 1 0 percent 3. percent
20 35 per cent
be less than 0.35 metres for 71.3 per cent farmers. This is quite
0-5 5 to 6 6 to 7 7 to 8 8 to 9 9 to 10 10+ low for a double cropped land even in a high rainfall area like Bihar
Tonnes/ha If we look at wheat, the main rabi crop in the state, it can be found
that half of the farmers provide less than 50 hours of irrigation
Figure 10: Gross Value of Produce/ha
per hectare of their cropped area (Figure 8). This translates to an
average irrigation depth of just 0.175 metres which is much lower
40.00- 35.19
than the irrigation level recommended for the crop in the state
35.00- ^ ,35.00- R ,? @ @ @ ,-percent
This over-economy of groundwater use affects the yields of
to tefmritevlg
Sore.00 21.76 ofo30.00- Separate21.76 23.15
the crops received in the state and precludes further intensi-
r25.00 ' percent peer cent
20.00- fication of cultivation on land in spite of high population pressure
?15.00- 9.25 7 37 Figure 6 shows that 40 per cent of the farmers in Bihar receive
u 10.00- 0.00 per cent 3.70 less than 6 tonnes of cereal yield (rice + wheat) per hectare o
5.00 hours
in00- - cent jperc cen percent
ofirrigationgivenper ent
0.00
net sown area. Almost three-fourths of farmers (72. 56 per cent
0-10'000 10-20000 20-25000 25-30000 30-35000 35-40000 40-45000 receives less than 7 tonnes of cereal yield per hectare of net sow
area (Figure 9). Combined yield of rice and wheat of one-fifth
of farmers in our sample was less than a typical Punjabi farmer
Figure 11: Comparative Performance of Rice Yields rice yield alone. Accordingly, gross returns from agriculture ar
in Bihar, West Bengal and UP also extremely low. While one-third of farmers in the sampl
earned Rs 25 to Rs 30,000 per hectare of their net sown area
under rice-wheat system, another one-third realised less than
Rs 25,000. Combined per hectare gross value of produce at farm
1500
gate prices was less than Rs 35,000 for 90 per cent of the farmers
1000 in the state (Figure 10). The average figure for the whole sample
is around Rs 28,000/ha/year. Considering the land-man ratio of
12.78 persons/ha in rural Bihar, the gross value of produce/capita/
year amounts to just around Rs 2,000.
q u ,t we" N ,n 02 rp iv' N , p t ,, ,N N, N This is one of the important reasons for high incidence of rural
poverty in Bihar. the only state in India where the absolute number
-4- Bihar-- UP -6- West Bengal
of poor people below poverty line has registered an increas
Source: Agriculture, CMIE, November 2000: 69 between the last two rounds of sample surveys of NSSO
[Ahluwalia 2001].
to the farmers in the villages of north Bihar. Separate analysis
carried out for the four villages of north Bihar showed that yield V
difference between. pump-owners and water buyers was small
Why Tubewell Irrigation Development Is Not
but significant at 95 per cent confidence level while the difference
Enough to Sustain Growth?
in hours of irrigation given per unit area of wheat was significant
even at 99 per cent confidence level. Correlation coefficients Agricultural growth remains low in Bihar in spite of increased
between ownership and yield and ownership and hourspump of density
ir- and access to irrigation. Growth fuelled by ground-
rigation were also found to be positive and significant thoughwater development has been short-lived and much less significant
quite weak (0.176 and 0.281 respectively). Except in case of in the neighbouring West Bengal, Eastern UP and even
than that
wheat in the four villages of north Bihar, the results of our Bangladesh
surveywith which it shares its history and ecology (Figure 11).
are similar to what Shah and Ballabh (1997) found in theirWhatever
studyproduction increase has been realised had been offset

3488 Economic and Political Weekly July 31, 2004

This content downloaded from


52.172.200.163 on Sat, 20 Jun 2020 17:50:54 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Figure 12: Net State Domestic Product of Agriculture of Bihar of Agricultural Cost and Prices (CACP), let
at 1993-94 Constant Prices
support price offered by government of
Post-1991 increase in oil prices, reduction
1800000
and fertiliser and slackening food prices
uo 1600000
international markets have together crea
0. 1400000 terms of trade have progressively move
c 1200000 and the profitability of food productio
spite of a modest increase in crop pr
? 1000000
According to Harriss (1993), it was favo
o 800000
ratio (in conjunction with availability of
< 600000
variety of rice (IR 36)) that facilitated agr
C 400000 West Bengal. Now, depressed foodgrain pr
C)

200000 of cultivation are producing a reverse effect


margins and motivation to intensify inputs
ing in relapse of stagnation in state in lat
o o Itc ( ', 0 0 N a '-T o ro N 0c) o o' o N 0)
(D O
o0 (Do0
(00)(ON NN
C0 0) No0
O O - - :- 0)
) o0 Doo)X0 0( o
0) 0~ 0)Oa) axcMn
) cn O ) 0
period of growth in the 1980s. Similar
reported
Source: Directorate of Economics and Statisticp, in Bangladesh
Government of Bihar also when rise in d
the Gulf war resulted in a fall in boro pro
by population growth and as a result, years per capita food availability
[Palmer-Jones 1999]. Decline in r
and labour productivity have remained at ratio
price the same level associated
has been as in with slow
the 1960s (Figure 12). growth in Bangladesh [Shahabuddin 1999
What explains the persistence of agrarian stagnation
and Kalita 2004].inIn
Bihar
an analysis of slowd
in spite of rapid pump capital formation? Why
growth in have farmers
Bangladesh, in
Palmer-Jones (1999)
Bihar failed to leverage access to groundwater to increase
of rice prices pro-
in relation to agricultural in
ductivity, intensity and income fromagricultural
agriculture? wages have been an import
agricultural growth.
Declining Output-Input Price Ratio
Decapitalisation of the Rural Areas
This issue was raised repeatedly in focus group discussions
with farmers during the fieldwork and in all the
Reduced eight
rate villages
of public capital formation
covered in the study the response was of
unanimous: sharp (such
infrastructure increase
as rural roads, pow
in diesel prices is the principal factor affecting
medium agricultural
irrigation systems, sugar mills, etc
growth. Today diesel has replaced muscle as the main
the situation. motive
Empirical results for a per
power in agriculture and its price has India
increased more than threethat gross dom
level study suggest
times in last eight years (from 1995 to 2003)
culture resulting
(GDPA) in a influenced by:
is strongly
corresponding increase in costs of irrigation, land preparation
in agriculture; and (b) terms of trade [Gu
and threshing (Table 3). Since diesel Traditionally,
is available only on capital
public cash formation in a
payment, there has been a substantial been increase in form
mainly in the cash
of major and medium
outlay of agriculture with increased whereas in the 1970s and 1980s
dieselisation andthe focus shifted towards
rising
diesel prices, resulting in a resourceexpanding
squeeze well in these
irrigation credit-
by providing increasing amount of
starved villages. electricity to agricultural sector [Dhawan 1996].
As subsidies were reduced, there has been a substantial increase
In the last two decades, public capital investment in agriculture
in price of chemical fertilisers, For example, the retail
in Bihar has concentrated price
mainly of
in increasing the density of
urea remained stable at Rs 2.50/kg. throughout
shallow tubewells the 1980sthrough
and pumpsets whilecredit and subsidy
in last 10 years the price has increased more
schemes like than two
Free Boring times
Scheme, to Shallow Tubewell
Million
about Rs 5.30/kg. There has been a much steeper
Project, On-farm rise
Water in prices
Management Project, IRDP loans, etc.
of DAP and potash. Agricultural wages have also doubled up irrigation systems
However, performance in major and medium
and between 1995 and 2003 and they haveand ruralbecome progressively
electrification which would have given long-term cost
more monetised. There has been a sharper increase
advantage to farmers in inthepeak-season
state has been miserable. The actual
wage rates than the non-peak season irrigated
wagearea rates.
by majorIncreased out-
and medium schemes has gone down from
migration in peak seasons is cited as the reason
2.15 million for in
hectares this increase
1990 to 1.58 million hectares in 1997
even during a time when land owners' returns
[Sharma from
1998]. Nearly agriculture
21,000 villages are yet to be electrified
have taken a beating. in the state, while by Bihar State Electricity Board's own ad-
Depressed foodgrain prices and absence of effective
mission, 18,000 of the electrifiedprice
47,000 villages have become
support were also considered to be de-electrified
equally responsible for
due to various reasons.3 The per capita annual
agricultural stagnation. It was pointed outconsumption
power that while cost
is as low as 22of
kWh all
in north Bihar and
inputs have increased manifold, food 87prices have
kWh in south gone
Bihar down
[Sharma in when private cost
1998]. Thus,
real terms. The average farm-gate price of paddy
of irrigation and
was falling in wheat has
other states of India on account
hovered around Rs 350/quintal and Rs 525/quintal
of free and subsidisedrespectively
power supply in 1980s and 1990s,
in the last three seasons. The harvest price
farmers ofincurred
in Bihar paddy is lower
increasingly high cost for irrigation.
than even its C2 cost of cultivation asPoor
estimated by
infrastructure Commission
means inefficiencies and higher costs of

Economic and Political Weekly July 31, 2004 3489


This content downloaded from
52.172.200.163 on Sat, 20 Jun 2020 17:50:54 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
production, marketing, storage and processing making agricul- production and increasing profit margins. IWMI research in north
ture uncompetitive in the state. China shows that it is through relentless intensification and
raising crop yields that Chinese farmers have retained the
viability of their farming in the face of declining global foodgrain
Absence of 'the New Agrarianism4 in Bihar
prices and rising input costs and local taxes [Shah, Giordano
Some researchers argue that phenomena like rapid decline in and Wang 2004].
rural infrastructure, absence of procurement support and poor This strategy, however, will catch on only if production and
performance of rural credit schemes may well be the problems price risks are low and farmers have access to suitable crop
of demand rather than supply [Wilson 1999 and Shah, personal varieties which respond adequately to input intensification. Paddy
communication]. Kalpana Wilson argues that de-electrification crop faces risk from flood in large parts of north Bihar. Lack
and state apathy by themselves cannot explain the stunted growth of suitable varieties for poorly drained low lands called 'chaunrs'
of capitalism in Bihar. Faced with similar problems, farmers in which form a significant proportion of the total cultivable land
other parts of country have responded very differently. Remu- in the region is also a big stumbling block. This is the reason
nerative prices, reliable power supply, free electricity and writing why south Bihar where problems of flood and drainage are not
off of farm loans have been the rallying points of peasant very serious (except in Mokama Tal) level of input use in paddy
movements in the capitalistically developed rural areas of the and its yields are much higher when compared to flood-prone
country like western UP, Punjab, Haryana, Gujarat, Maharashtra north Bihar.
and Karataka where peasants of varying economic status came In case of wheat, the main rabi crop in Bihar, almost all our
together to extract concessions from the state [Gail Omvedt respondents complained that the crop was not very responsive
quoted in Harriss 1992]. This marked a clear shift from the to input intensification and seed up-gradation. Agronomists
historical pattern of peasant movements which had almost always agree to this point. The problem lies in the late sowing of wheat
targeted at intra-rural class relationships [Hariss 1992]. But there in Bihar which forces early maturity, resulting in lower yields.
has been complete absence of any such movements in Bihar Field experiments carried out by the ICAR scientists in Direc-
which shows a lack of demand for such services even if the need torate of Water Management Research, Patna have shown that
is not lacking. Wilson (1999) argues that this is mainly because one month delay in wheat sowing from its recommended time
the peasant capitalist development which started in parts of Bihar of November 19-25, results in about 53 per cent reduction in
under favourable conditions of 1970s and 1980s could not be yield [Singh et al 2002]. Such delay is common in Bihar and
supported by the underlying agrarian structure and the nature inoffact in many areas the sowing goes on till as late as second
the state. week of January. The delay is caused by late sowing (and hence
late harvest) of paddy crop. At present farmers wait for monsoon
VI rains to sow paddy and transplantation is carried out generally
Towards Breaking Agrarian Impasse in the third week of July. ICAR studies show that advancing
sowing of rice by a month will help to realise higher yields of
Input Intensification for Improving Efficiency and both rice and wheat. However, this requires irrigation for the crop
Income: A Possible Option for Farmers in pre-monsoon period. Therefore, increasing groundwater use
is still the key to agrarian development in Bihar [Singh et al 2001].
With all these structural and macroeconomic constraints facing Prohibitively high cost of irrigation is the biggest hurdle in large-
agriculture in Bihar, what are the options available for an in- scale adoption of this proven strategy of yield enhancement in
dividual farmer to expand his production and profit margins? rice-paddy systems of Bihar.
To understand this, an analysis of best practices in agriculture
was carried out in one of our study villages, in which the VII
agricultural practices and crop-economics of a small group of Policy Choices for State
farmers who achieved the highest productivity levels were studied
and compared with that of the modal group of farmers. The Rural electrification is one state initiative which can provide
comparison revealed two important points. First, the yield ob- major boost to agriculture in Bihar. It can bring down the cost
tained by most of the farmers was just enough to cover their input of irrigation and improve the working capital situation of farmers.
costs and there was hardly any surplus left even for consumption, It can also trigger growth in storage and processing infrastructure
let alone capital formation. This resulted in continued poverty which will permit value addition and the much needed crop
and stagnation of agrarian economy. Also, with just 28 per cent diversification in the state.5 Cheaper access to irrigation with
increase in cost of cultivation, the productivity increased by 85 electricity will also encourage farmers to bring larger areas under
per cent and the net returns increased by more than 250 per cent. summer crops where higher yields can be obtained under more
This means that most of the farmers in Bihar are practising controlled conditions.
what Tushaar Shah calls 'cost-covering agriculture' and from this Behaviour of producer prices has been another important
point if the crop yields are raised even by 20-25 per cent, the impediment to agricultural growth in Bihar. The high level
net incomes of farm households would increase by 60-70 per Committee Report on Food Policy notes that the producer prices
cent making a significant dent in rural poverty in the state. Second, were higher in this region than Punjab-Haryana in the early 1980s
farmers who made more intensive use of inputs and incurred but became lower in the early 1990s as surpluses appeared (http:/
higher costs towards cultivation were more efficient and /fcamin.nic.in/hlc_contents.htm). The combined pressure from
competitive producers with much lower per quintal cost of subsidised sales by Food Corporation of India (FCI) under its
cultivation. This shows that input intensification to increase Open Market Sales Scheme (OMSS) and local seasonal gluts
yields is one possible way of reducing per quintal cost of results in producers getting prices well below the actual economic

3490 Economic and Political Weekly July 31, 2004


This content downloaded from
52.172.200.163 on Sat, 20 Jun 2020 17:50:54 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
cost of production in Bihar. Poor infrastructure and under- Gulati, Ashok and Seema Bathila (2001): 'Capital Formation in Indian
Agriculture: Revisiting the Debate', Economic and Political Weekly,
developed primary agricultural marketing network further worsen
36(20), pp 1697-1708.
the problem of farmers by increasing the cost of marketing and Hagen, James R (2000): The Raw and the Simmered: Environmental Contexts
price fluctuations. Unless this is addressed by extending procure- of Food and Agrarian Relations in the Gangetic Plain, Power, Agrarian
ment operations more effectively in the state, there will be Structure and Peasant Mobilisation in Modern India: A Symposium, May
insufficient incentive for the sustained yield increase. 131 23-25, University of Virginia.
Harriss, John (1992): 'Does the 'Depressor' Still Work? Agrarian Structure
and Development in India: A Review of Evidence and Argument',
Address for correspondence Journal of Peasant Studies, 19 (2), pp 189-227.
a.kishore@cgiar.org -(1993): 'What Is Happening in Rural West Bengal? Agrarian Reform, Growth
and Distribution', Economic and Political Weekly, 28(24), pp 1237-47.
Notes Hayami,Yujiro (1981): 'Agrarian Problems of India from an Eastern and
South Eastern Asia Perspective', Institute of Economic Growth, New
Delhi.
1 Very few people would know that transplanted, wet rice was firstHussain, T A and R R Kalita (2004): 'Shallow Tubewell Irrigation in Assam:
developed and used in the world in the amply watered fields below the
Bountiful Production but Forlorn Farmers', unpublished paper.
Rajgir Hills in Patna district during the sixth century BC [Hagen 2000].
Mearns, Robin (1999): Access to Land in Rural India: Policy Issues and
2 Data for two of these nine villages (Machhahi and Fariyani) have been
Options, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2123.
obtained from Ballabh et al(2003).
Palmer-Jones, Richard (1999): 'Slowdown in Agricultural Growth in
3 http://www.bihar.nic.in/Depts/Energy/rural_electrification.htm
Bangladesh: Neither a Good Description nor a Description Good to Give'
4 The word New Agrarianism was used first by L I Rudolph and S H
in Ben Rogaly, Barbara Harriss-White (eds), Sonar Bangla: Agricultural
Rudolph in their famous book: In the Pursuit of Lakshmi: The Political
Growth and Agrarian Change in West Bengal and Bangladesh, Sage
Economy of the Indian State' first published in 1987 by Chicago Publications, New Delhi.
University Press.
Pandey, Sushil and S Pal (2000): 'The Nature and Causes of Changes in
5 Among all states in India, Bihar has the highest share of its gross cultivated
Variability of Rice Production in Eastern India: A District Level Analysis'
area under cereals (- 90 per cent) and it has increased in last 10 years.
in S Pandey, B C Barah, R A Villano and S Pal (eds), Risk Analysis
and Management in Rainfed Rice Systems, NCAP/IRRI Workshop on
References Risk Analysis and Management in Rainfed Rice Systems, September
21-23, 1998, New Delhi.
Ahluwalia, Montek S (2000): 'Economic Performance of States in Post- Prasad, Pradhan H (1974): 'Reactionary Role of Usurer's Capital in Rural
Reforms Period', Economic and Political Weekly, 35 (19), pp 1637-48.India', Economic and Political Weekly, 9 (32-34), pp 1305-08.
Ballabh, Vishwa and B M Sharma (1992): HYVAdoption, Productivity Gaps Reserve Bank of India (1984): Agricultural Productivity in Eastern India,
and Production Adjustment Mechanisms in Flood-prone Areas of Uttar Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai, India.
Pradesh: A Synthesis, Research Report 5, IRMA, Anand Shah, Tushaar and Vishwa Ballabh (1997): 'Water Markets in North Bihar:
Ballabh, Vishwa and Kameshwar Choudhary (2002): 'Groundwater Six Village Studies in Muzaffarpur District', Economic and Political
Development and Agriculture Production: A Comparative Study of Weekly, 32 (52), pp A-183-A-190.
Eastern Uttar Pradesh, Bihar and West Bengal', Draft Discussion Paper Shah, Tushaar, Mark Giordano and Jinxia Wang (2004): 'Water Institutions
Presented in 2nd IWMI-Tata Annual Partners' Meet, January 27-29.in a Dynamic Economy: What Is China Doing Differently from India?'
Ballabh, Vishwa and Sushil Pandey (1999): 'Transitions in Rice Production Paper presented in 3rd IWMI-Tata Annual Partners' Meet, Anand,
Systems in Eastern India: Evidence from Two Villages in Uttar Pradesh',February 17-19.
Economic and Political Weekly, 34(13), pp Alll-A116. Sharma, I D (1998): Report on Concurrent Evaluation of Integrated Rural
Ballabh,VishwaandT S Walker(1992): 'LandFragmentationandConsolidationDevelopment Programme: 5th Round: July 1995-June 1996, A N Sinha
in Dry Semi-arid Tropics of India', Arth Vijnana, 34(4), pp 363-87.Institute of Social Studies.
Banerjee, Abhijeet V (2002): 'Who Is Getting the Public Goods in India: Singh, R K P, Thelma R Paris and Joyce S Luis (2002): Impact of Labour
Some Evidence and Some Speculation', unpublished. Out-Migration on Rice-Based Household Economy and Gender Roles
Banerjee, Abhijit and Lakshmi Iyer (2002): 'History, Institutions and Economicin Bihar, India, Draft Report of a Collaborative Project of Rajendra
Performance: The Legacy of Colonial Land Tenure Systems in India',Agricultural University, Bihar and International Rice Research Institute,
http://info.worldbank.org/etools/docs/voddocs/183/367/ Philippines.
land_tenure_india.pdf Singh, Sita Ram, U S Gautam, Ujjwal Kumar, A Rahman and S K Sinha
Bardhan, Pranab and Ashok Rudra (1979): 'Labour Employment and Wages (2001): Groundwater Development to Enhance Surface and Rain Water
in Agriculture: Results of a Survey in West Bengal', Economic and Utilisation and Agricultural Productivity in Southern Bihar, ICAR-
Political Weekly, 15 (45 and 46), pp 943-49. IWMI Ground Water Policy Initiative, Policy Dialogue on Groundwater
Bhaduri, Amit (1973): 'A Study in Agricultural Backwardness under Semi- Management, CSSRI.
Feudalism', Economic Journal, 83, pp 120-37. Shahabuddin, Quazi (1999): 'Agricultural Growth Performance in Bangladesh:
Bharadwaj, Krishna (1993): 'Regional Differentiation in India' in Binoy A Note on the Recent Slowdown' in Ben Rogaly, Barbara Harriss-White
N Verma (ed), Agrarian Relation Institutional Change and Colonial(eds), Sonar Bangla: Agricultural Growth and Agrarian Change in West
Legacy, Volume (III), Ashish Publishing House, New Delhi. Bengal and Bangladesh, Sage Publications, New Delhi.
Chakravarty, Anand (2001): 'Caste and Agrarian Class: A View from Bihar',
Stiglitz, Joseph E (1989): 'Rational Peasants, Efficient Institutions and a
Economic and Political Weekly, April 28, pp 1449-62. Theory of Rural Organisation: Methodological Remarks for Development
Clay, EJ (1974): 'Innovation, Inequality and Rural Planning: The Economics Economics' in Pranab Bardhan (eds), Economic Theory of Agrarian
Institutions, Clarendon Publishers, Oxford.
of Tubewell Irrigation in Kosi Region, Bihar, India', PhDThesis, University
of Sussex cited Mukherji, Aditi (2004), Groundwater MarketsSwain, in Mamata (1999): 'Agricultural Tenancy and Interlinked Transactions-
Ganga-Meghana-Brahmputra (GMB) Basin: A Review of Literature. I: Neoclassical and Marxist Approaches', Economic and Political Weekly,
Paper presented in 3rd IWMI-Tata Annual Partners' Meet, Anand,34 (37), pp 2657-66.
February 17-19. Wilson, Kalpana (1999): 'Patterns of Accumulation and Struggles of Rural
Dhawan, B D (1982): Development of Tubewell Irrigation in India, Agricole
Labour: Some Aspects of Agrarian Change in Central Bihar', Journal
Publishing Academy, New Delhi. of Peasant Studies, 26 (2-3), pp 316-54.
- (1987): 'Impact of Irrigation on Farm Economy in High Rainfall Areas:
- (2002): 'Small Cultivators in Bihar and New Technology: Choice or
Kal Project', Economic and Political Weekly, 23(53). Compulsion?' Economic and Political Weekly, March 30, pp 1229-38.
Wood, Geoff (1995): 'Private Provision after Public Neglect: Bending
- (1996): 'Relationship in Public and Private Investments in Indian Agriculture
with Special reference to Public Canals', Indian Journal of Agricultural Irrigation Markets in North Bihar', Development and Change, 30 (4);
Economics, 51(1-2). pp 775-94.

Economic and Political Weekly July 31, 2004 3491

This content downloaded from


52.172.200.163 on Sat, 20 Jun 2020 17:50:54 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

Potrebbero piacerti anche