Sei sulla pagina 1di 16

Food Policy xxx (xxxx) xxxx

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Food Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/foodpol

Seasonal rural labor markets and their relevance to policy analyses in


developing countries
Arndt Feuerbachera,b,⁎, Scott McDonaldb, Chencho Dukpac, Harald Gretheb
a
Agricultural and Food Policy Research Group, University of Hohenheim, Schwerzstr. 46, 70599 Stuttgart, Germany
b
Department of Agricultural Economics, Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin, Berlin, Germany
c
Research and Development Center Yusipang, Ministry of Agriculture and Forests, Thimphu, Bhutan

ARTICLE INFO ABSTRACT

Keywords: Seasonality is a salient feature of rural livelihoods and particularly within agriculture the demand for labor
Rural livelihoods varies with the seasons and weather. In low-income countries, agriculture employs almost two-thirds of the labor
Seasonal labor force and incomes from labor are a major determinant of welfare. Therefore, an appropriate model re-
Rural labor markets presentation of rural labor markets is critical when analyzing agricultural and food policies. Economy-wide
Economy-wide modeling
models are commonly used for ex-ante policy analysis, but have so far ignored the influence of seasonality,
Policy analysis
Bhutan
implicitly assuming separability of seasonal labor demand and supply. This study relaxes that assumption using a
computable general equilibrium (CGE) model calibrated to the Bhutanese economy as an illustrative case. Using
JEL classification: model setups with and without seasonal labor markets, a cereal export ban of India is simulated leading to higher
C680 import prices for Bhutan. Results demonstrate that neglecting the influence of seasons on rural labor markets
J220 systematically biases model results. Assuming homogeneity of labor units, i.e., allowing substitution across
J430 seasons, understates the impacts of policy changes on rural wage rates, distorts households' labor-leisure trade-
O130 off decisions and overstates agricultural supply response. Given the widespread use of economy-wide models, the
results are important for understanding the implications of domestic and global policy changes for agriculture
and welfare in developing economies.

1. Introduction Globally, seasonality particularly affects the extreme poor, more


than 80% of whom reside in rural areas (Castañeda et al., 2018). Em-
Agricultural production is a biological process governed by the pirical studies have recorded evidence of seasonal labor shortages and
weather and seasons: the demand for inputs follows the seasons and underemployment in economies as divergent as China (Zhang et al.,
sequencing of agricultural operations, e.g., soil preparation, planting, 2011), Malawi (Wodon and Beegle, 2012), India (Reddy et al., 2014)
weeding and harvesting. Seasonal fluctuations in labor demand are a and the U.S. (Taylor et al., 2012). Seasonal underemployment rather
feature of agriculture in all economies, but are particularly pronounced than open unemployment is the prevalent observation in rural areas,
in low-income agrarian economies, due to labor-intensive methods of since farmers find some level of employment in non-farm activities
production and limited options for investment in labor-saving tech- during slack periods (Bezu et al., 2012; Binswanger and Rosenzweig,
nologies (Taylor and Charlton, 2019). With “agriculture being a sea- 1981). Seasonal underemployment disproportionately affects women
sonal operation, it is somewhat misleading to speak in terms of a (Jarvis and Vera-Toscano, 2004), is a driver of seasonal migration
homogeneous unit of labor. A unit of labor at the time of harvesting is (Bryan et al., 2014) and a target of public employment schemes
not replaceable by a unit of labor at a slack period” (Sen, 1966, p. 440). (Devereux, 2016). Seasonality is also the reason why agricultural
This insight is important for an understanding of rural labor markets; workers in Sub-Saharan Africa tend to supply much less hours per year
seasonal labor bottlenecks are constraints on agricultural output “re- than workers in industry and services explaining a substantial share of
gardless of the degree of [apparent] underemployment” (Ruthenberg, the labor productivity gap (McCullough, 2017).
1971, p. 78). Also, farmers’ awareness about the risk of seasonal labor Seasonality of labor markets has been taken into account by
shortages is reflected within their resource allocation and production econometric studies (e.g., Jarvis and Vera-Toscano, 2004; Jessoe et al.,
planning (Fafchamps, 1993). 2018) and micro-level models such as farm-level, multi-agent and


Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: a.feuerbacher@uni-hohenheim.de (A. Feuerbacher), cdukpa@moaf.gov.bt (C. Dukpa), grethe@hu-berlin.de, grethehx@hu-berlin.de (H. Grethe).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2020.101875
Received 25 June 2019; Received in revised form 27 February 2020; Accepted 29 February 2020
0306-9192/ © 2020 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Please cite this article as: Arndt Feuerbacher, et al., Food Policy, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2020.101875
A. Feuerbacher, et al. Food Policy xxx (xxxx) xxxx

multi-period models incorporating stochastic sequential decision followed, by details of the scenario implemented and the model settings
making (e.g., Antle, 1983; Berger and Troost, 2014). In the case of in section 4. The results are analyzed in section 5, followed by reports
micro-level models, the absence of seasonality of labor demand distorts on sensitivity analyses in section 6. The paper ends with a discussion of
model outcomes, since it allows the use of more resources than those the conclusions and their implications.
available (Hazell and Norton, 1986, pp. 42–46). Micro-level models
neither capture consumption and forward and backward linkages
2. Background
within economies nor do they depict the operations of labor markets.
But, economy-wide models such as computable general equilibrium
2.1. Seasonality of labor markets
(CGE) models, which are extensively used for policy analysis
(Devarajan and Robinson, 2005), have neglected the seasonality of
Demand for seasonal labor can be derived from a production func-
labor demand. They commonly assume strong separability between
tion x a = f (l, k, n, i , , ) , where x a is a vector of outputs of activity a;
production and consumption decisions, which implies perfect inter-
l, k , and n (labor, capital and land) are vectors of primary inputs, i is a
temporal substitution in decisions by households about labor supply
vector of intermediate inputs, σ is a vector of substitution elasticities
across a year. Such annual model setups sidestep the reality of the
and a vector of efficiency factors. The labor inputs can be defined
seasonal fluctuations of labor demand in agriculture addressed else-
using skill types, e.g., by education or occupation categories, and sea-
where.
sonal types, e.g., by months. Nested constant elasticity of substitution
Only two studies that incorporate seasonal demands for labor in an
(CES) functions allow flexibility in substitution possibilities such that,
economy-wide framework are known. Finnoff and Tschirhart (2008)
for instance, the substitution possibilities between labor of different
model the interrelations between the Alaskan fishery and tourism sector
skill types can be greater than the substitution possibilities between
as non-consumptive services of the marine ecosystem in a bioeconomic
labor of different seasonal types within each skill type.1 The associated
general equilibrium model. Within a three-sector recursive-dynamic
first order conditions identify the factor returns and allow wage rates
CGE model, seasonal wage differentials are identified as workers expect
for each type of labor to vary across seasons reflecting the seasonal
higher payment within the fishing season compensating them for the
patterns of labor demand.
likelihood of facing unemployment in the off-season. Filipski et al.
The elasticities of substitution of seasonal labor depend on the
(2017) analyze the impacts of Saffron price volatility on rural liveli-
economic activity. Cropping activities, e.g., paddy rice, may follow
hoods in a Moroccan village characterized by a strong gender based
rigid sequences defined by nature, as noted by Sen (1966), which im-
division of labor. The rural labor market is segmented by gender and
plies no, or limited, substitution possibilities. Non-farm activities may
two seasons, the Saffron harvest (<1 month) and the growing season
provide complementary employment options for rural labor with a
(rest of the year). This allows analyzing how changes in seasonal labor
counter seasonal pattern relative to cropping activities (Reardon et al.,
demand impact male and female wages and the substitution between
1998). For manufacturing activities, the degree of substitution of labor
seasonal labor and leisure within and outside the Saffron harvest
across seasons will be greater.
season. Both studies rely on case study specific model specifications at
Labor supply adjusts to the (rigid) seasonal labor demand, de-
either the village or sub-national level. They only distinguish between
pending on the ease with which households can trade-off time for lei-
two seasons and give no (Finnoff and Tschirhart, 2008) or limited
sure with participation in the labor force in one period, and vice versa
(Filipski et al., 2017) consideration of the wider effects of labor sea-
in other periods. Economic theory argues that individuals maximize
sonality on rural economies and the agricultural sector. Filipski et al.
utility by trading off consumption and leisure - uh = u (x c, h , leic, h) , where
(2017) highlight bottlenecks of female labor supply during the Saffron
uh is a vector of household utilities, x c, h is a vector of consumption of
harvest season, but they do not include intraseasonal substitution of
commodities, c, by household, h; and leic,h is a vector of household
leisure. Finally, in both studies consumption and leisure are gross
specific domestic services. Domestic services comprise leisure and ser-
complements.
vices from social reproduction (e.g., house maintenance, child care and
This study contributes to the literature by reporting the first
cooking). These are produced outside the System of National Account’s
economy-wide model that incorporates seasonality of labor and leisure
(SNA) production boundary (ISWGNA, 2009 para 1.41), which only
at a national scale, with intraseasonal substitution of leisure. This sea-
encompasses goods and services that could be sold on markets at un-
sonal model is compared to an annual model (with annualized instead
iquely defined prices (ISWGNA, 2009 para 6.24). Leisure and social
of seasonal labor markets). The model and experiments scrutinize the
reproduction thus need to be modelled using household specific activ-
standard (implicit) assumption of economy-wide models that seasonal
ities (see Section 3.1.3).
labor demand and supply are separable, i.e., labor types are measured
The labor force (persons employed, self-employed and seeking em-
in ‘homogenous units’. With some 63% of the labor force in low-income
ployment) is defined internationally as those “individuals willing to
countries employed in agriculture (World Bank, 2019), and incomes
supply labour to undertake an activity included in the SNA production
from labor being a primary determinant of welfare, the study addresses
boundary” (ISWGNA, 2009. 405 para 19.5). The size of an economy’s
how the neglect of seasonal labor demand may bias the results from
labor force, and its composition, can change seasonally as households
economy-wide models.
trade-off hours supplied inside the production boundary and social re-
Bhutan serves as an illustrative case, for which data on seasonal
production activities. This is particularly relevant for economies char-
labor and leisure quantities were collected and compiled as a social
acterized by large variations in the seasonal demand and limited sub-
accounting matrix (SAM) (Feuerbacher et al., 2017). A range of food-
stitution possibilities for social reproduction.
price shock simulations provide evidence that ignoring seasonal labor
Modelling labor supply is more complex because it is necessary to
demand systematically biases the results with implications for agri-
allow for the observed periods of apparent underemployment and those
cultural supply response, income and household welfare. The analyses
periods when there are high demands for labor, e.g., for harvesting and
and various robustness checks demonstrate that core results apply to
weeding. If labor demand is less time dependent, the availability of
countries with large shares of labor in seasonal activities and underline
labor for production activities is less time critical. The time dependency
the importance of considering seasonal labor in economy-wide ana-
of labor used to produce leisure is, arguably, more flexible than labor
lyses, particularly in developing agrarian economies.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The next section re-
views the definition of the labor force and seasonal labor and gives an 1
Regular nested CES functions “are globally well-behaved and can provide a
overview of the Bhutanese economy. The third section reviews the local approximation to any globally well-behaved cost function” (Perroni and
model and data used and details about model calibration. This is Rutherford, 1995).

2
A. Feuerbacher, et al. Food Policy xxx (xxxx) xxxx

used for social reproduction. Substituting time use across periods, in Agricultural households in the temperate zones (AEZ3) are closer to
response to changes in wage rates, means taking less leisure during urban centers (particularly Thimphu and Paro in Western Bhutan).
periods of peak labor demand with compensating increases in leisure They have more diversified income sources, particularly the landless
during periods of slacker labor demand.2 Such patterns of labor demand agricultural households. Per capita incomes decline with decreasing
across production cycles are a feature of agricultural production in both altitude and increasing distance from the Western urban areas. While
developed and developing economies and are an explanation for the climate at higher altitudes is a constraint, it allows farmers to
“[apparent] underemployment” in developing countries (Ruthenberg, supply out of season produce to India and Bangladesh (MoEA, 2012).
1971, p. 78).3 The main cash crop exports are vegetables, potatoes and apples from
the temperate regions (AEZ3), and citrus, cardamom and ginger from
the subtropical zones. The cultivation of cereals, particularly rice and
2.2. Country context Bhutan maize, occupies two-thirds of cropland. Cereal yields are low compared
to other South Asian countries, reflecting low adoption levels of agro-
Bhutan, known for its development philosophy of Gross National chemicals (Feuerbacher et al., 2018).
Happiness, has a population of about 735,000 of which 62% reside in Bhutan maintains a free trade agreement with India. With sub-
rural areas (NSB, 2018). The country is landlocked in the mountainous sistence consumption absorbing the largest share of farmers’ cereal
Eastern Himalayas, with its main access routes being south into India. production, Bhutan is reliant on cereal imports from India; 35% of total
Bhutan’s poverty headcount ratio declined from 23% to 8% between cereal demand (Feuerbacher et al., 2017). Increasing the degree of food
2007 and 2017 (NSB and World Bank, 2017). Economic development self-sufficiency, for inter alia, reasons of sovereignty, is a political
largely benefitted the urban population and poverty became a rural priority in Bhutan. Recently, India has imposed export bans on cereals,
phenomenon, particularly in the Southern and Eastern districts of but exempted Bhutan. If India imposed a cereals export ban on Bhutan
Bhutan. Compared to other South Asian countries, Bhutan scores well the import costs would increase sharply due to the higher transporta-
on most nutrition indicators with only 2.8% of the population living tion costs.
under the food poverty line of 2,124 kcal in 2012 (NSB and World Bank,
2012). However, stunted growth, in children younger than five years 3. Data and model
old, and anemia, which affects women and children, remain challenges
(Atwood et al., 2014). 3.1. The model
Bhutan is a peasant economy, despite increasing investments in the
formal economy, with about 50% of the labor force working in agri- The model is a single country comparative-static CGE model de-
culture (NSB and ADB, 2012) – similar to other South Asian countries veloped from the STAGE2 (McDonald and Thierfelder, 2015) and
(World Bank, 2019). Agriculture is dominated by semi-subsistence STAGE_DEV models (Aragie et al., 2017). There are three substantive
smallholders cultivating, on average, 1.2 ha (NSB, 2018). Only 3% of developments.
Bhutan’s land area is used for farming, which is driven by labor and
capital scarcity rather than land scarcity. About 21% of arable land is 3.1.1. Production system
left fallow, with an increasing trend over recent years (MoAF, 2016). The nesting of the production functions is extended to incorporate
Labor shortages are the main farming constraint, reflecting the very low seasonal labor and fertilizer – a land saving intermediate input (see
population density (19 people per km2) (NSB, 2018) and limited scope Fig. 1). The top nests aggregate non-land saving intermediate inputs
for mechanization, e.g., power tillers for land preparation, due to steep and value-added components using CES or Leontief technologies. At the
slopes of rainfed land and narrow rice terraces. second level, Leontief technologies aggregate non-land saving inter-
Bhutan is a “monsoon economy” (Reardon et al., 1998). The onset of mediate inputs and CES technologies aggregate the fertilizer-land and
monsoon rains determines the cropping pattern of rice, with seasonal capital-labor composites. The third level combines land and aggregate
labor bottlenecks observed during the rice transplanting and harvesting fertilizers, where the latter is a combination of chemical and organic
periods. Farm labor demand is relatively low in slack periods, i.e., fertilizers (manure) from the fourth level; both use CES technologies.
outside the main cropping seasons, when farmers pursue non-farming The capital-labor composite is a combination of capital and aggregate
activities such as textile weaving and forestry. There are considerable labor, with aggregate labor being a combination of seasonal and per-
regional differences in monsoon rain patterns and climatic conditions. manent labor (level 4) – seasonal labor inputs are shaded. Permanent
Three major agroecological zones (AEZs) have been identified: the labor is a combination of skilled and unskilled labor, while seasonal
humid subtropical zone (AEZ1, below 1200 m of altitude), the dry labor is an aggregate of farm labor from all 12 months. All the capital
subtropical zone (AEZ2, 1200 – 1800 m) and the temperate zone (AEZ3, and labor components are aggregated with CES technologies. The point
above 1800 m). Agricultural households and cultivated land are almost estimates for the CES elasticities, used at each level of the production
equally distributed across these zones. system, together with the sources used are detailed in the supplemen-
Rural settlements are scattered and difficult to access, despite a tary material (Appendix A).
growing rural road network. Except for pastoralists migrating between
summer and winter camps, there is little evidence and no data on rural- 3.1.2. The demand system
rural seasonal migration. Rural livelihoods are dependent on crop The demand system in STAGE_DEV is extended to a three level CES-
agriculture. Cattle husbandry, which dominates livestock agriculture, is LES-CES nest, where LES is the Linear Expenditure System. In the first
land extensive, but labor intensive; reflecting low productivity and (CES) level households trade-off aggregate leisure/social reproduction
widespread discouragement of slaughtering due to Buddhist beliefs. services and aggregate consumption. At the second (LES) level house-
holds determine the optimum consumption levels of aggregate com-
2
modities, e.g., processed food, services, other goods, subject to
Another form of adjustment in developing, and developed, economies is
minimum (subsistence) levels of consumption. At the third (CES) level
seasonal labor migration; slack periods in some areas coincide with peak per-
households choose optimum mixes of ‘natural’ commodities subject to
iods in other areas.
3
In high-income countries farmworkers, historically, worked shorter weeks relative commodity prices and the constraints of preferences, income,
during slack (winter) seasons and longer weeks in peak seasons and worked available labor resources and subsistence requirements. This setup al-
more overtime during peak seasons. Other examples of adaptation to seasonal lows households to substitute similar goods and services, e.g., rice,
workloads include the use of contractors, e.g., the harvest teams that work their maize and other cereals. The income elasticities of demand for com-
way north harvesting grains in the U.S. modity groups at the LES level were estimated using cross-sectional

3
A. Feuerbacher, et al. Food Policy xxx (xxxx) xxxx

Fig. 1. Production structure incorporating seasonal labor.

household data from the 2012 Bhutan Living Standard Survey crop calendars and cost of production studies (Appendix D). The de-
(Feuerbacher, 2019). The CES parameters to aggregate the commodity mands for ‘skilled’ and ‘unskilled’ labor and all other factor are not
groups are documented in the supplement (Appendix B). seasonal.
Seasonal farm labor dominates the rural labor market, although
3.1.3. Labor-leisure and social reproduction non-farm workers like teachers, shop owners, etc., also reside in rural
Each household has an activity that produces household specific leisure areas. The rural labor market is also segmented by the three AEZs, to
(including social reproduction), which requires inputs of labor services reflect variations in climate and altitude and differences in growing
owned by the associated households. These production functions are de- conditions in Bhutan. Non-farm labor is classified as unskilled and
fined as CES aggregates of labor by permanent and seasonally employed skilled (permanent) labor. Farm labor is demanded by agricultural, food
labor, i.e., there are labor substitution possibilities in the production of processing and off-farm activities. Non-farm labor is demanded by
household leisure. By defining activities that produce commodities outside manufacturing and service activities. Households are classified as
the production boundary as household specific, i.e., they can only be pro- agricultural if at least one household member is reported to work
duced and consumed by the household, there are uniquely defined prices within agriculture. Agricultural households are sub-divided by AEZs
for commodities and services produced inside and outside the boundary and access to land, i.e., farm and landless households. There are five
(Aragie et al., 2017). The approach in this model is a generalization of a land accounts (rainfed, irrigated, orchard, pasture and forestland),
method used by Fontana and Wood (2000). which are sub-divided by AEZs. There are four capital factors: two li-
This specification means that only those labor services owned by vestock capital accounts (cattle and other animals), and two physical
each household not used to produce leisure can be supplied to other capital factors by ownership (agricultural household and incorporated
activities. This requires that labor markets are cleared, in quantity business enterprise owned).
terms, at the household level. It is common in CGE models (e.g., Hertel, Seasonal activities are those that demand seasonal labor. Their
1997; Lofgren et al., 2002; McDonald and Thierfelder, 2015) to clear shares in total output, required person-days and characteristics of sea-
labor markets by implicitly assuming that the proportions of each type sonal labor demand are reported in Table 1. Cropping activities have
of labor supplied by each household are constant. In the model this is ‘rigid’ labor demands, i.e., operations such as transplanting or har-
defined as a FDf , a FSIins, f , where FDf , a is the factor, f, de- vesting of paddy are performed in specific time windows (Appendix E).
ins
manded by activity, a, and FSIins, f is the factor supplied by institution, Other seasonal activities such as livestock husbandry or textile weaving
ins, which includes households (Aragie et al., 2017). Labor market by farm households are performed with flexibility in labor demand.
clearing at the household level ensures that labor services used by ac- Some crops, in Bhutan, are cultivated in different seasons or with dif-
tivities within the production boundary, and outside the production ferent cropping patterns, e.g., double or single cropping of maize; these
boundary for social reproduction and leisure, cannot exceed those activities were disaggregated accordingly. Cropping activities account
available to the household. This formulation endogenizes the distribu- for 52% of seasonal activities’ output, by value, and 43% of total
tion of income, i.e., the distribution of earned income among house- person-days. The high labor intensity of rice production − 250 person-
holds is a variable dependent on the quantities of labor each household days per hectare4 – means that rice cultivation accounts for ~ 38% of
sells to activities. cropping labor. There are 37.9 million person-days provided by about
170,000 farmers, i.e., an average of 225 working days per person; this
excludes labor used for social reproduction and leisure. Overall, em-
3.2. The data
ployment in seasonal activities accounts for 48% of Bhutan’s labor days.
The available data do not allow for a meaningful separation of the
The database is a SAM for Bhutan in 2012 (Feuerbacher et al., 2017)
accounts for social reproduction and leisure; they are therefore treated
with satellite accounts for quantities of factors and elasticities (see
as a single account – ‘leisure’
Appendix C for Bhutan’s economic structure as represented in the
SAM). The seasonal demands for farm labor were estimated for 12
monthly periods from primary data, seasonal calendars, secondary data
from the (national) 2012 agricultural sample survey (MoAF, 2013), 4
Maize has half the labor intensity per hectare.

4
A. Feuerbacher, et al. Food Policy xxx (xxxx) xxxx

Table 1
Seasonal activities represented in the 2012 Social Accounting Matrix for Bhutan.
Activity %-Share in total seasonal Person-days (in Share in total person-days employed in Seasonal labor substitution
output value thousand) production elasticity σ

Milled, rice 12.7 6,065 16.0 0


Double cropping of maize 1.8 1,102 2.9 0
Single cropping of maize 5.2 2,971 7.8 0
Other cereals and oilseeds 2.5 1,100 2.9 0
Vegetables - first season 4.5 786 2.1 0
Vegetables - second season 4.5 1,107 2.9 0
Potato - first season 5.9 1,411 3.7 0
Potato - second season 0.2 96 0.3 0
Spices 4.3 453 1.2 0
Fruits 10.1 1,032 2.7 0

Total cropping activities 51.6 16,123 42.5

Cattle husbandry 9.6 8,249 21.8 0.1


Other animals 5.3 2,049 5.4 0.1
Dairy production 12.5 3,914 10.3 0.2

Total livestock activities 27.4 14,212 37.5

Other cereal milling 1.0 146 0.4 1.5


Cereal processing 2.6 345 0.9 1.5
Araa production 4.0 786 2.1 1.5

Total food proc. activities 7.6 1,277 3.4

Community forestry 8.6 4,164 11.0 1.5


Textile weaving 4.8 2,123 5.6 1.5

Total non-farm activities 13.4 6,287 16.6

Total seasonal activities 100.0 37,899 100.0

Total seasonal leisure 14,655 0.2

Please note: Each seasonal activity is further disaggregated by agroecological zones.


a
Ara is a traditional home-brewed alcoholic beverage made from cereals

3.3. Labor market calibration AEZ1 - Humid subtropical zone


1600
3.3.1. Labor-leisure trade-off 1200
Each household can consume leisure produced by its own labor. A 800
simple formula to calibrate a plausible income elasticity of labor supply, 400

H , Y , is H , Y = H T 1, where H denotes annual days worked and T is 0


households’ annual disposable time-endowment (Boeters and Savard, 2013,
in 1000 person-days

AEZ2 - Dry subtropical zone


p. 1654). T consists of H and households’ annual quantity of leisure, F, 1600
1200
(T = H + F). H is calibrated to 225 days per years in order to match the
800
total imputed days worked with the number of agricultural workers in
400
Bhutan. The need is to determine T. The upper bound for T, 365 days, is
0
unrealistic, since this would result in empirically implausible income elas-
ticities of labor supply. The lower bound for T ranges between 262 (in AEZ3 - Temperate zone
1600
AEZ3) and 298 days (in AEZ1), if it is assumed there is zero leisure at peak
1200
labor demand. Assuming a minimum quantity of leisure (including re-
800
production) every month, T is set to 312 days per year (or six days per
400
week) for all AEZs, leaving 87 days (312–225) for leisure and social re-
0
production. The distribution of seasonal labor demands is reported in Fig. 2. Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec
For (farm and landless) agricultural households the implicit income Months
elasticity of labor supply is −0.28 ( H , Y = 225 312 1). For non-agri-
Seasonal activities Cropping Livestock Non-Farm Leisure
cultural households, the leisure endowments are estimated for an elasticity
of −0.15. Two factors restrict the choice of H , Y towards the upper bound. Fig. 2. Distribution of seasonal labor demand across agroecological zones in
First, the minimum annual quantity of leisure determined by seasonal labor 1000 person-days per month.
peaks (assuming constant seasonal time endowments). Second, the as-
sumption that leisure is a normal good, since a positive H , Y would require low-income countries report higher levels of H , Y (Barrett et al., 2008;
H > T . The above calibrated H , Y fall within the range of estimates reported Jacoby, 1993; Skoufias, 1994) implying lower quantities of leisure, which
by Bargain and Peichl (2016).5 The studies using shadow-wage data from would amplify the effects of seasonal labor market constraints. This is
shown by the sensitivity analyses reported in Section 6 below.
5
The CES substitution elasticity for the labor-leisure trade-off, lei, X ,
Excluding the case of leisure being an inferior good, the estimates range
can be calibrated by the formula lei, X = 1 H , w H , Y , where H , w is the
between 0.00 and −0.40.

5
A. Feuerbacher, et al. Food Policy xxx (xxxx) xxxx

Table 2
Changes in Bhutan’s import prices of cereals following an Indian export ban on cereals.
Commodity Base ExpBan (Export Ban)

Share in total cereal Import intensity Import unit price Quantity imported Share imported from Increase of cereal import prices (CIP)a
demand (2012) (2012) India (in foreign currency)
(%) (%) (USD/ton) Tons (%) (%)

Milled rice 67 43 325 72,297 100 36


Maize 22 3 225 2,257 100 52
Wheat and other cereals 11 41 277 5,967 60 25
Cereals, total 35 298 80,521 96 37

Source: Author’s calculation based on 2012 Bhutan SAM and World Bank, 2017.
a
Computed by dividing the increase in import cost of 117 US-$ ton-1 by the import unit price times the share imported from India.

wage elasticity of labor supply (Boeters and Savard, 2013). The wage world market to Bhutan is estimated to be 117 USD/ton (World Bank,
elasticity of labor supply is set to 0.15 following Goldberg (2016), who 2019). This is the applied mark-up on world cereal prices (Table 2),
estimated the wage elasticity in rural Malawi.6 The resultant elasticities which increases the carriage insurance and freight paid price (in USD)
of labor-leisure substitution, lei, X , are 1.54 for agricultural and 2.00 for of imported cereals by 35%. Additional scenarios with changes in im-
non-agricultural households. Sensitivity analysis demonstrates the ro- port prices of cereals ranging between −50% and +50% were run to
bustness of model results across a range of elasticities. assess the results’ robustness to the magnitudes of price changes.
Labor demand patterns differ markedly across activities, particularly for
cropping activities with rigid labor demand (Fig. 2). Potential seasonal labor 4.1. Model setups and closure
bottlenecks are driven by the paddy transplanting and harvesting seasons,
which vary by AEZ, e.g., in AEZ1 transplanting is in June-July and har- The impacts of changes in cereal import prices on Bhutan’s economy
vesting in November-December. Livestock activities, comprising more than are simulated with two different behavioral specifications; a model with
a third of total seasonal labor (Table 1), and leisure have more flexible labor seasonal labor data (henceforth, the seasonal model) and a model with
demand. Non-farm activities have highly flexible labor demand and follow a annual labor data (henceforth, the annual model). The seasonal model
counter-cyclical pattern, i.e., their labor demand is lowest during peak depicts seasonality as described in the model structure, with twelve
periods and highest during lean seasons. monthly farm labor accounts per AEZ (as in nest L5.1 in Fig. 1). In
contrast, the annual model has one farm labor account per AEZ: this
3.3.2. Production of leisure excludes seasonality and replicates the standard assumption of homo-
There are no known estimates of substitution elasticities for different genous labor. Imports are modelled as imperfect substitutes for do-
labor types (skilled, unskilled or seasonal) in the production of leisure. An mestically produced goods and services (using CES functions)
elasticity of 0.50 is assumed, i.e., inelastic substitution. Total seasonal leisure (Armington, 1969) as are exports (using constant elasticity of trans-
is a CES aggregate that allows households to substitute seasonal leisure formation functions) (de Melo and Robinson, 1989). The elasticities
across time subject to an (implicit) intertemporal elasticity of substitution used are reported in the supplement (Appendix A). The consumer price
(IES). The intra-seasonal substitution of leisure is analogous to the inter- index (CPI) serves as the model’s numéraire. The small country as-
temporal substitution of labor supply due to short-term (or transitory) wage sumption is used, i.e., fixed world market prices, and the external
changes in the life-cycle labor supply theory (Lucas and Rapping, 1969). balance (foreign savings) is cleared by a flexible exchange rate. The
Most estimates for the IES range between 0.00 and 0.50 (Card, 1994; models are investment-driven; the investment quantities are fixed and
Heckman and MaCurdy, 1982; Lee, 2001), but other estimates range be- the investment-savings account is cleared by flexible household saving
tween 0.01 (Connolly, 2008) and 1.2 (Fehr and Goette, 2007). Few esti- rates. Government savings are fixed in real terms and income tax rates
mates for developing countries use shadow wage estimations. Fafchamps vary (additively) to clear the government account. Alternative macro-
(1993) reports an infinite elasticity, while Skoufias (1996) estimates IES for economic closures are evaluated in the sensitivity analysis.
female workers ranging between 0.057 and 0.079. There are no estimates
for Bhutan. Recognizing that leisure here includes social reproduction, an 4.2. Factor market clearing
elasticity of 0.20 is used (see Table 1). The results are robust when varying
the IES between 0.1 and 1.2. If the IES is infinite, there is, by definition, no A medium-term horizon is imposed for clearing the factor accounts. The
seasonality. supplies of each type of capital are fixed and perfectly mobile across ac-
tivities.7 All labor accounts, skilled, unskilled and seasonal labor, are per-
4. Model scenarios fectly mobile across activities: they are segmented by characteristics (skill-
level, AEZ and time-period) which cannot be altered, i.e., no labor mobility
The core scenario is rooted in a possible policy change: an export across characteristics. Land is perfectly mobile within its land-type across
ban on cereals by India requiring Bhutan to purchase cereals from cropping activities, i.e., the export ban is assumed to persist over the
countries other than India. This scenario is referred to as ExpBan. medium-to long-term allowing farmers to adjust their land allocation. A
During periods of world food price spikes, India has repeatedly applied land supply curve (Eickhout et al., 2009) is implemented to account for the
export taxes or even bans to stabilize domestic food prices (e.g., Villoria 21% of arable land left fallow in Bhutan. Land supplies depend on the land
and Mghenyi, 2016). So far Bhutan was exempted from these measures rental rate and approaches an asymptote of maximum land supply as the
(GoI, 2014). Bhutan has no border crossings with China, its Northern factor price for land goes towards infinity. An inelastic supply of land, with a
neighbor, hence cereal imports from the rest of the world must arrive by price elasticity, nAL = 0.8, is used following the estimate of Eickhout et al.
land through India or by air. The average import cost per ton from the (2009) for the South Asian region. Model results are robust to variation of
this parameter.
6
Barrett et al. (2008) report a wage elasticity of 0.12 which is based on
7
shadow wage estimations. The simulation results hardly differ, if this elasticity Capital is only mobile between activities that employ the respective capital
is used instead. category in the base SAM.

6
A. Feuerbacher, et al. Food Policy xxx (xxxx) xxxx

Table 3 is hindered by seasonal labor constraints.


Changes in summary results, welfare and agriculture sector indicators. Agricultural households’ consumption increases, since they benefit
GDP components (volumes valued Base share Change from base year (%) from higher food prices and increased land cultivation. The positive
at base prices) of GDP (%) impacts accruing mostly within rural areas (where also non-agricultural
Annual Seasonal households reside) are offset by non-agricultural households (due to
model model their lower purchasing power) and overall reduction of labor supply.
GDP 100.0 −0.04 −0.09 These factors explain the overall decline in household consumption and
Absorption (C + I + G) 131.5 −0.27 −0.31 the modest reduction in real GDP. The trade deficit in volumes valued
Consumption (C) 45.2 −0.76 −0.88 at base prices declines, since agriculture attracts more land over time
Consumption, agricultural 15.2 0.49 0.16 allowing for a substantial substitution of cereal imports. This is why
households
Bhutan’s domestic currency rate appreciates in nominal terms.
Consumption, non-agricultural 30.0 −1.39 −1.40
households In the seasonal model, the supply response to changes in cereal
Investment (I) 67.0 0.00 0.00 prices is less than in the annual model. This is because seasonal labor
Government (G) 16.2 0.00 0.00 bottlenecks result in surging wage rates during periods of peak labor
Exports (E) 34.7 −0.63 −0.57
demand, resulting in larger increases in cereal prices than in the annual
Imports (M) 66.2 −0.78 −0.77
Other macro indicators model. The annual model allows for perfect intertemporal substitution
Nominal exchange rate (Domestic −1.55 −1.58 of labor and leisure, thereby providing more usable labor for crop
currency/foreign currency) production. Consequently, real GDP, absorption and welfare decline
Real exchange rate (Domestic 0.10 0.10 less than in the seasonal model. The increase in labor supply in the
currency/ foreign currency)
annual model also results in a smaller decline of average household
Producer price index (PPI) −1.12 −1.16
Labor supply −0.10 −0.23 income. However, when accounting for leisure, average changes in
Avg. household income (excl. −0.82 −0.93 welfare, at least at the aggregate level, are similar in both models.
leisure)
Avg. household welfarea −0.53 −0.56
5.2. Commodity prices and output
Agriculture sector indicators
Crop producer prices 2.40 3.11
Crop production 2.75 1.53 The rice and other cereals commodity accounts are affected most by
Farm labor wages 2.15 3.79 the Indian export ban, due to their high import intensities, i.e., imports
Farm labor supply 0.55 −0.14 as shares of domestic demand: about 50% of the increase in rice and
Arable land rent 5.44 3.37
other cereal import prices is transmitted to consumers. Maize has a very
Arable land supply 3.14 2.48
low import intensity (3.1%) and hence a low-price transmission.
a
Welfare changes are measured by the Slutsky equivalent variation incl. Overall, the increase in cereal import prices are dampened by the slight
leisure expressed as a share of households’ base expenditure. nominal appreciation of the domestic currency.
The extent of the agricultural supply responsiveness is, inter alia,
5. Results subject to the scarcity of production inputs. Incorporating seasonal
labor introduces further production constraints. This is reflected in the
The simulation results of the export ban scenario are analyzed with lower supply response of the seasonal model with cereal output in-
an emphasis on differences between the seasonal and annual labor creasing by only 7.5% compared to 10.5% in the annual model
market specification. First, summary results at the macro level are (Table 4). In the case of rice, the supply response of the annual model is
presented, followed by a presentation of changes in commodity prices 40% higher than in the seasonal model. Maize production changes only
and output. Changes on the factor market are presented in greater de- very slightly, because it is hardly traded. Maize output declines in the
tail, since this is where the model differences are most pronounced. seasonal model (0.6%), where maize is competing with the paddy
Subsequently, the implications of differences in factor market results on sector for (scarce) labor during the peak seasons. Other cereals are an
household consumption and welfare are described. Finally, the sys- aggregate of various cereals predominantly cultivated in the off-season,
tematic extent of the bias in model results is analyzed by simulating e.g., wheat, barley, millet, which results in a lower activity-specific
changes in cereal import prices ranging between ±50%. wage in the seasonal model (see also Fig. 5). Hence, output of other
cereals increases slightly more in the seasonal model (5.1%) than in the
annual model (4.9%). In both models, farmers shift from the production
5.1. Summary results
of other crops (vegetables, potatoes, spices and fruits) to cereals. Ve-
getables and potatoes are labor intensive and grown on rainfed land,
The hypothetical Indian export ban has a negative terms of trade
just as maize and other cereals. Their cost of production increases, since
shock, leading to a reduction in absorption and a reallocation of re-
labor and rainfed land prices increase strongly, yet output declines due
sources towards cereal producing activities (Table 3). The increase in
to an appreciating nominal exchange rate and lower domestic demand.
import prices boosts cereal production in Bhutan over the medium- to
Spices and fruits are less labor intensive and grown on permanent
long-term, increasing demand for arable land, agricultural capital and
cropland, which does not compete with cereal cultivation.
farm labor. The export ban only affects cereal import prices (due to the
higher transportation costs to import cereals from countries other than
5.3. Factor markets
India). Hence, cereal export prices are unaffected and there is only a
slight depreciation in the real exchange rate of 0.1%. In the model
The difference between the model setups emphasizes the treatment of
closures, investment and government expenditure volumes are fixed,
the rural labor market; this sub-section identifies the channels and me-
which requires absorption to adjust through household consumption.
chanisms in factor markets that explain differences in the annual and sea-
This results in a decline of real GDP, and reductions of average
sonal model results. Seasonality of labor has negligible effects on factor
household incomes and welfare.8 These effects are stronger in the
prices and supply within the formal (non-rural) economy. Factor prices of
seasonal model, since the readjustment process on the production side
non-farm labor and incorporated capital decline by similar magnitudes
(Table 5). The main causes are a drop in purchasing power leading to re-
8
Measured GDP and absorption exclude leisure. Leisure is included in the duced domestic demand for secondary and tertiary goods and services and
welfare measure. the reduced competitiveness of export-oriented sectors.

7
A. Feuerbacher, et al. Food Policy xxx (xxxx) xxxx

Table 4
Percentage changes in commodity prices.
SAM Sector or group Import %-changes
sectors name intensity (%)
Import price (in Import price in domestic Producer price Consumer price Output
foreign currency
currency)
Annual Seasonal Annual Seasonal Annual Seasonal Annual Seasonal
Model model Model model Model model Model model

1–10 Agriculture 30.2 12.0 10.2 10.2 1.7 2.1 3.1 3.4 1.1 0.2
1–7 Crops 26.8 23.2 20.9 20.9 2.4 3.1 5.5 6.1 2.7 1.5
1–3 Cereals 34.6 34.6 32.5 32.4 6.6 8.4 12.3 13.7 10.5 7.5
1 Rice, milled 42.7 35.9 33.8 33.8 8.8 11.2 15.5 17.2 16.7 12.0
2 Maize 3.1 51.7 49.4 49.3 3.4 4.8 3.5 4.6 0.2 −0.6
3 Other cereals 41.4 24.8 22.9 22.8 3.2 3.4 10.6 10.6 4.9 5.1
4–7 Other crops 18.7 −0.4 −0.4 −0.6 −0.6 −2.3 −2.4
4 Vegetables 25.2 0.9 0.8 0.3 0.2 −2.5 −2.4
a
5 Potatoes 9.5 see note below 1.0 0.8 1.7 1.6 −5.8 −5.7
6 Spices 23.7 −1.2 −1.2 −1.0 −0.9 −2.3 −2.7
7 Fruits 19.5 −1.0 −1.2 −1.0 −1.2 −0.7 −0.5
8–10 Livestock 35.1 0.5 0.3 −0.4 −0.5 −2.1 −2.2
11–12 Forestry 7.8 0.3 −0.9 0.1 −0.9 −0.7 −0.1
13 Mining 59.6 −1.6 −1.6 −1.6 −1.6 0.1 0.2
14–19 Food processing 46.5 0.9 0.9 0.0 0.0 −5.5 −5.8
20–21 Textile weaving 38.4 −0.7 −1.3 −1.1 −1.4 −1.2 0.0
17–22 Other 81.6 −1.5 −1.6 −1.5 −1.6 0.0 0.2
manufacturing
23 Electricity 0.3 −1.6 −1.6 −1.7 −1.7 0.3 0.4
24 Construction 5.9 −1.5 −1.6 −1.5 −1.6 0.0 0.0
26–32 Services 11.8 −1.5 −1.5 −1.5 −1.5 0.0 0.0

a
As a response to the appreciating nominal exchange rate, the import prices of all commodities except cereals, and export prices of all commodities decline by 1.5
and 1.6%, respectively.

The seasonal model generates consistently greater increase in farm production. The land rent and supply of irrigated land can increase
wages, in all AEZs (Table 5). Surprisingly, at first sight, this is accom- substantially more in the annual model, because it is complemented by
panied by a decrease in farm labor supply in the first two zones and much cheaper labor. The actual difference in wage rates for labor used
only a low increase in labor supply in AEZ3. Both, the differences in in rice cultivation between both models is much higher than reported in
seasonal wage changes and the composition of aggregate leisure are the Table 5, as in the seasonal model rice cultivation requires labor in
main reasons (see next section). With less labor for cereal production, periods of wage spikes (see also the results on activity-specific changes
total arable land increases only by 2.5% in the seasonal model, com- in price of labor and Fig. 5). The land expansion, via the asymptotic
pared to 3.1% in the annual model. Overall, land rents increase land supply curve, is dependent on the change in real land prices (de-
strongly, because of increased demand for irrigated land for rice flated by the PPI), explaining the increases in rainfed land supply de-
spite low or slightly negative changes in nominal land prices.

Table 5
5.3.1. Farm labor wages and supply
Changes in factor prices and factor supply.
The changes in seasonal wages reflect the seasonal pattern of labor
Factor accounts Change in factor price (%) Changes in factor supply (%) requirement for cereal cultivation, predominantly rice (Fig. 3a). For
example, the strong increases in seasonal wages in the low altitude zone
Annual Seasonal Annual Seasonal
(AEZ1) during June, July and November, coincide with the periods of
Skilled labor −1.6 −1.6 −0.2 −0.2 land preparation, transplanting and harvesting of rice. Due to the colder
Unskilled labor −1.5 −1.6 −0.3 −0.3 climate, rice field operations occur about a month earlier in AEZ2 vis-à-
Farm labor – nationala 2.1 3.8 0.5 −0.1
vis AEZ1, and another month earlier in AEZ3. Hence, the pattern of
Farm labor - AEZ1 2.4 4.9 0.6 −0.7
Farm labor - AEZ2 2.8 4.7 0.6 −0.1 seasonal increases in farm wages occur in phase shifts across the AEZs.
Farm labor - AEZ3 1.4 2.1 0.4 0.3 Additional labor demand for maize production further exacerbates
Arable land national 5.4 3.4 3.1 2.5 seasonal labor shortages. Both single and double cropping of maize are
Rainfed land - national −0.9 −1.1 0.2 0.0 activities in the model. Of the two systems, double-cropping of maize
Rainfed land - AEZ1 −1.0 −1.8 0.1 −0.5
Rainfed land - AEZ2 −1.2 −0.6 −0.1 0.4
overlaps most with the rice transplanting period. Consequently, output
Rainfed land - AEZ3 −0.5 −0.9 0.5 0.2 of double-cropped maize decreases at greater rates in AEZ1 and AEZ2 in
Irrigated land - national 25.8 17.8 12.0 9.7 the seasonal model while in AEZ2 the output of single cropped maize
Irrigated land - AEZ1 23.1 14.8 13.0 9.7 increases.
Irrigated land - AEZ2 26.5 17.0 10.8 8.8
The results for seasonal wages cannot be compared with empirical
Irrigated land - AEZ3 28.2 22.9 12.3 11.2
Orchard land – national −2.2 −2.2 −0.9 −0.9 seasonal wage data. Farm labor transactions (hiring labor in and out)
Pasture land - national −5.7 −4.9 0.0 0.0 predominantly take place in months of peak labor demand and are not
Forestland - national −1.9 −1.4 −0.7 −0.2 recorded over time. Particularly in the lean season, there is no spot
Livestock - national 6.2 2.8 0.0 0.0 market for farm labor, i.e., the reported seasonal wages are shadow
Unincorporated capital 12.1 7.8 0.0 0.0
Incorporated capital −1.6 −1.6 0.0 0.0
wages. Nevertheless, the results are consistent with field observations
and records of farmers reporting labor shortages in the rice trans-
a
Changes in aggregate farm labor computed based on farm labor used within planting and harvesting season. Seasonal wages decline in months with
productive boundary, excluding leisure. low or no labor demand by cereal activities (Fig. 3a). Non-cereal

8
A. Feuerbacher, et al. Food Policy xxx (xxxx) xxxx

activities reduce their demand for seasonal labor due to reduced con- how the assumption of perfect intertemporal substitution affects the
sumer demand and a decline in competitiveness. Furthermore, due to mechanisms of farm labor mobility and supply in the annual model.
the rigid pattern of labor demand for cropping, non-cereal crop activ- First, it allows for perfect mobility of farm labor across activities, in-
ities also have to reduce labor demand in those months with little or no dependent of the periods in which labor is supplied or demanded (see
competition with cereal activities. also the results on reallocation of labor). Second, the changes in the
Farm wages increase less in the annual model, but the increased aggregate price of leisure for agricultural households is mostly de-
supply of farm labor is greater (Fig. 3b). The difference is explained by termined by the annual change in farm wage. Consequently, the

AEZ1 - Humid subtropical zone


29.9
30

Avg. of
20
seasonal model, 4.9
11.9 12.3
10 Annual model, 2.4
0.8 1.5
0
-2.1 -0.8
-2.9 -3.0 -2.9 -3.5 -2.3

-10

AEZ2 - Dry subtropical zone


% farm labor wage changes

30 27.5

20 Avg. of
seasonal model, 4.7 14.2 14.3

10 Annual model, 2.8


4.5

0
-2.2 -1.0 -1.0 -1.2
-3.4 -3.1 -2.8 -2.4

-10

AEZ3 - Temperate zone


30

20 Avg. of 17.4
seasonal model, 2.1 12.8
10
Annual model, 1.4
3.9
1.6
0
-2.0 -0.7 -1.1 -1.3 -2.1 -1.8
-3.3 -2.2

-10
Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec
Months
Seasonal Annual Avg. of
model model seasonal model
Fig. 3a. Changes in farm labor wages. Source: Own model results.

9
A. Feuerbacher, et al. Food Policy xxx (xxxx) xxxx

AEZ1 - Humid subtropical zone

Annual model, 0.6


1.0
0.5
0.1 0.2 0.1
0.0
-0.5 -0.5 -0.4
-1.0 -1.0
-1.0 -1.1 -1.1
-1.2
-1.5
Avg. of seasonal -1.7
-1.7
model, -0.7

AEZ2 - Dry subtropical zone


% farm labor supply changes

Annual model, 0.6


1.0 0.5 0.6 0.7
0.5
0.2
0.0
-0.2 -0.2 -0.2
-0.5 -0.5 -0.5
-0.5 -0.6 -0.6
-1.0 Avg. of seasonal
-1.5 model, -0.1

AEZ3 - Temperate zone


Annual model, 0.4
Avg. of seasonal
1.0 0.9
1.0 model, 0.3
0.4
0.5 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.2
0.1 0.0 0.1 0.1
0.0
-0.1
-0.5
-1.0
-1.5

Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec
Months
Seasonal Annual Avg. of
model model seasonal model
Fig. 3b. Changes in farm labor supply. Source: Own model results.

increase in the composite wage results in an increase in the aggregate direction (see Appendix F).
price of leisure (Table 6). In this model, despite substantial increases in The effects of the labor-leisure trade-off are less straightforward in
household income, labor supply by agricultural households increases, the seasonal model. The change in the aggregate price of leisure
reflecting the domination of the substitution effect of labor moving out (Table 6) differs from the change in labor income, mainly because the
of leisure over the expansion effect, which works in the opposite share of leisure in time use varies over seasons (see Fig. 2). In periods of

10
A. Feuerbacher, et al. Food Policy xxx (xxxx) xxxx

Note: A negative (positive) expansion effect (E) reported in the last column means that the change in utility is dominant leading to positive (negative) labor supply. A negative (positive) substitution effect denotes that the
labor shortages, seasonal leisure is scarce, because most household time
is absorbed by activities within the production boundary. Conversely,

Seasonal model
in lean months disproportionately more leisure time is available to
Domination of expansion (E) or

households. Allowing for some intertemporal substitution of leisure,


households can substitute leisure in periods with strong increases in
wages by consuming more leisure in periods of declining seasonal
substitution (S) effect

E
E
S
S

S
S
S
S
S
wages (see Fig. 3b). Accordingly, the composite price of seasonal leisure
either drops or increases at substantially lower rates than the average
Annual model

income from labor (Table 6). Hence positive substitution or expansion


effects are observed, which dominate the labor-leisure trade-offs with
consequent declines in labor supply.
-E
-S
-S
-S
-S
-S

S
S
S
% changes in household total labor

Seasonal model

5.3.2. Reallocation of farm labor


The bias in model results is transparent when investigating the
differences in allocations of farm labor across activities. In the annual
−0.71
−0.56
−0.32
−0.07
−0.02
−0.02
−0.19
−0.23
−0.27

model, the perfect mobility across activities allows for unrealistic re-
allocations of labor from counter-cyclical activities, like forestry and
textile production, to cereal production (Fig. 4). Counter-cyclical ac-
Annual model

tivities account for 16.3% of reallocated labor in the annual model,


compared to only 3.9% in the seasonal model. Flows of labor from li-
−0.17
−0.22
−0.24
supply

0.15
0.23
0.13
0.47
0.10
0.07

vestock to cereal activities play a much more important role in the


seasonal model, accounting for 50.3% of labor flows compared to
Seasonal model
% change in composite price of

37.1% in the annual model. Most striking are the differences of labor
supply from leisure. Consistent with Sen’s observation, the annual
model leads to an effective increase of labor endowment. Assuming
−0.71
−0.28
−0.30
0.78
0.27
1.24
0.61
0.71
0.37

perfect intertemporal substitution allows for an increase in labor units


price difference between utility and leisure is dominant leading to positive (negative) labor supply. See Appendix F for more details.

supplied in peak periods by reducing leisure in slack periods. This effect


Annual model

accounts for 18.1% of the reallocated labor in the annual model. In the
seasonal model, with heterogeneity of labor over time, labor supplied
−0.70
−0.30
−0.32
utility

during peak periods increases marginally, but overall there is a higher


0.96
0.52
1.28
0.72
0.70
0.34

demand for leisure accounting for 6.5% of the reallocated labor. These
mechanisms and channels explain the greater reallocation of labor in
Seasonal model
% change in composite price of

the annual model: 3.0% of total available farm labor flows to cereal
activities, compared to 1.9% in the seasonal model.
−0.46
−0.66

−0.51
−1.64
−1.58
−1.63
0.92
0.63
0.48

5.3.3. Activity-specific price of composite farm labor


In the seasonal model, each seasonal activity has a specific pattern
Annual model

of labor demand. Because the changes in seasonal wages can differ, the
price changes of composite farm labor are activity specific. Composite
−0.34
−1.59
−1.54
−1.58
leisure

1.31
0.78
1.90
1.50
0.76

price changes of agricultural labor are highest for activities that depend
on labor supplied during bottleneck periods such as for rice and maize
% change in composite wage

in AEZ1 (Fig. 5). Activities with counter-cyclical labor demand com-


pared to paddy and maize (e.g., forestry or textile weaving) benefit
Seasonal

−0.50
−1.55
−1.58
−1.56

from a falling composite price of seasonal labor. Consequently, in the


model

2.00
1.11
2.53
1.86
0.98
Determinants of households’ labor supply via the labor-leisure trade-off.

seasonal model the aggregate output of forest products (0.1%) and


textiles (0.0%) remains stable but declines in the annual model (0.7%
and 1.2%, respectively) (see Table 4).
Annual

−0.58
−1.52
−1.55
−1.53
model

1.48
0.73
1.98
1.40
0.74

5.4. Household consumption and welfare


% change in household utility

Agricultural households spend the largest share of income (54%) on


food, which includes home production for home consumption. Hence,
Seasonal

−0.18
−1.01
−0.80
−1.28
−1.12
model

food price rises disproportionately affect their cost of living. The impacts
0.43
0.70
0.66
0.58

in terms of food security, approximated by food consumption, are more


adverse in the seasonal model (Table 7), which also reports higher food
prices. Despite the decline in food consumption, agricultural households in
Annual

−0.04
−1.06
−0.81
−1.25
−1.17
model

both models increase household consumption of real goods and services,


0.50
0.19
0.83
0.15

i.e. excluding leisure, due to higher household income. The seasonality of


labor leads to two structural differences reflected in the consumption and
Farm household

Farm household

Farm household

Other income households

welfare measures. First, the relatively higher farm labor wages and lower
Unskilled households

land rents in the seasonal model (Table 5) favor landless households


Skilled households
Landless

Landless

Landless

whose consumption and welfare increase more (or decrease less) in the
annual model. And second, the lower aggregate prices of leisure result in
Households

either positive dominant expansion or substitution effects increasing lei-


Table 6

AEZ1

AEZ2

AEZ3

sure consumption in the seasonal model compared to a consistent drop in


leisure consumption in the annual model (see Appendix G for detailed

11
A. Feuerbacher, et al. Food Policy xxx (xxxx) xxxx

1200

800

1000 person-days
400

-400

All Other Other Food Community Textile


Rice Maize Livestock Leisure
Model setup cereals cereals crops processing forestry weaving
Annual model 1135 1095 -10 50 -186 -425 -130 -113 -73 -207
Seasonal model 711 711 -49 49 -192 -409 -131 -19 -12 53

Fig. 4. Net reallocation of farm labor. Note: Measured in thousand person-days across seasonal activities and leisure aggregated at the national level.

15
Seasonal model Annual model
11.9 Avg. of seasonal model
10 9.7
% changes

6.0 5.6 Avg. of seasonal model, 4.9


4.5
5 3.9 3.5 3.5 Annual model, 2.4
1.8
0.3
0
-0.4 -0.4 -0.0
-1.8

-5
Rice Double Single Other Veg. early Veg. late Potato Spices Fruits Cattle Other Dairy Community Textile
cropping cropping cereals season season husbandry animals production forestry weaving
maize maize
Rural economic activities in AEZ1

Fig. 5. Changes in the activity specific price of composite seasonal labor within AEZ1.

Table 7 5.5. Evidence for a systematic bias


Changes in welfare and household consumption.
Welfare incl. leisure Share total pop. (%) Change from base year (%)
In addition to the export ban scenario, changes in cereal import
prices ranging between ±50% are simulated. Summary results of the
Annual Seasonal export ban and a variant with the exact opposite effect, i.e., a decrease
model model in cereal import prices by 35%, are presented in the supplement
Average household 100.0 −0.53 −0.56
(Appendix H). The scenarios with positive or negative changes in im-
Non-agricultural 52.9 −0.99 −0.99 port prices demonstrate a systematic bias if seasonality of labor is ig-
households nored.
Agricultural households 47.2 0.40 0.30 The percentage changes in farm wages, the driving force behind all
Farm households 43.8 0.46 0.34
the results, are consistently greater, i.e., more negative and more po-
Landless households 3.4 −0.48 −0.23
Consumption of Share of household sitive, in the seasonal than in the annual model (Fig. 6a). Despite the
agricultural consumption (%) greater changes in farm wage rates, the farm labor response is not
households straightforward; the interaction of income and substitution effects in
Household consumption 100.0 0.34 0.01 the labor-leisure trade-off, and changes in the output mixes by farmers,
Food 54.5 −1.60 −2.11
Non-food items 45.5 2.66 2.55
produces a decline in farm labor supply in the seasonal model as cereal
Leisure 20.7 −0.11 1.10 prices increase (Fig. 6b). On the other hand, in the annual model labor
supply increases with higher cereal prices. In the event of decreasing
cereal import prices, the seasonal model interestingly reports an in-
crease in labor supply. This is because labor demand only declines in
results on household consumption). Both factors lead to a generally lower
the cereal cropping period, which is when wages decline most. Yet,
household consumption level in the seasonal model. This divergence in
outside the cropping period seasonal wages increase leading to a
household consumption is similar, in terms of welfare, measured as Slutsky
smaller drop in the price of leisure than in the annual model. Conse-
equivalent variation (EV) including leisure. Welfare results differ ac-
quently, the expansion effect dominates resulting in increasing labor
cording to households’ income composition. For the average farm (land
supply.
owning) household welfare increases by 0.5% in the annual model, but
Since farm wages are less elastic to changes in cereal prices in the
only by 0.3% in the seasonal model (Table 7). This is due to the larger
annual model, land supply is more elastic (Appendix I) allowing for a
price response and smaller increases in the land rents in the seasonal
systematically higher agricultural supply response (Fig. 6c). In case of
model. In contrast, in the annual model landless households experience a
the seasonal model, land supply increases less strongly and due to lower
higher loss in welfare, because of the lower increase in agricultural wages.
farm labor supply and higher agricultural wages, aggregate agricultural

12
A. Feuerbacher, et al. Food Policy xxx (xxxx) xxxx

Fig. 6. Aggregate changes in farm wages, farm labor supply, agricultural supply and agricultural household welfare depending on changes in cereal import prices.
Note: Welfare changes are measured by the Slutsky equivalent variation incl. leisure expressed as a share of households’ base expenditure.

supply hardly increases. In comparison with the annual model, culti- households owning land.
vation becomes less labor intensive (measured in person-days per
hectare) and increases in cereal production are accompanied by 6. Robustness of model results
stronger declines in non-cereal output. The last panel (Fig. 6d) shows
that the systematic bias in the changes of factor prices and supply also Sensitivity analyses were conducted to test the robustness of model
results in different changes in income and welfare for landless and farm

Table 8
Description of sensitivity analyses.
Sensitivity analysis Description

Sigmasea The seasonal labor substitution elasticity, a,t , is varied by ± 50%. The elasticity of formerly rigid activities remains zero when decreasing the elasticity and
is set equal to 0.1 when increasing the elasticity.
Intertemp The IES set at 0.2 is varied to encompass the empirically plausible range from 0.1 to 1.2.
MinMaxLei The income elasticity of labor supply, H , Y of agricultural households is varied between the minimum and maximum possible quantities of leisure. This
results in lower bound income elasticities of labor supply of 0.25 (AEZ1), 0.18 (AEZ2) and 0.14 (AEZ3) and an upper bound elasticity of 1.38 for all AEZs
(such that the time endowment equals 365 days).
LandEla The land supply elasticity, n , is varied by ± 50%
SeasMigr The model is changed to allow for rural-rural seasonal migration among AEZs. The database is modified, assuming that each seasonal activity receives about
10% of its farm labor demand from the other two regions. Two simulations are run assuming seasonal labor to be substitutable across AEZs with a CES
elasticity of 0.8 and 2, respectively.

13
A. Feuerbacher, et al. Food Policy xxx (xxxx) xxxx

Crop Crop Cereal Cereal Arable land Land Farm labor Farm labor Reallocated
output prices output prices supply prices wages supply farm labor
4.0
+50%

3.5
Min Reference (Difference in results
+50%
0.1 between annual-seasonal)
Deviation from reference by
3.0 sensitivity analysis variant
Percentage point difference

0.8

+50%
2.5 Max -50%

2 +50% Min
-50% 0.1 +50%

2.0 1.2 +50% -50% 0.8


+50%
Min

Max 0.1 +50%


0.8
0.1 Min 2
1.5 +50% -50% -50% -50% 0.8
Min +50%
0.1 +50% 2
-50% 1.2
Max Max 0.1 Min +50%
0.8 -50% 1.2 2
1.0 Max -50% 1.2
0.8
2 +50% +50% Min Max -50%
-50% 0.1 Min +50% 2
+50% Min +50% +50%
1.2 0.1 0.1 -50%
0.8 0.8 0.8 1.2
Max
0.5 -50% 1.2
-50%
2
-50%
-50% 1.2 Max -50% 2 -50% 1.2 Max 2

0.0
Reference
Sigmasea
IES
MinMaxLei
LandEla
SeasMigr

Reference
Sigmasea
IES
MinMaxLei
LandEla
SeasMigr

Reference
Sigmasea
IES
MinMaxLei
LandEla
SeasMigr

Reference
Sigmasea
IES
MinMaxLei
LandEla
SeasMigr

Reference
Sigmasea
IES
MinMaxLei
LandEla
SeasMigr

Reference
Sigmasea
IES
MinMaxLei
LandEla
SeasMigr

Reference
Sigmasea
IES
MinMaxLei
LandEla
SeasMigr

Reference
Sigmasea
IES
MinMaxLei
LandEla
SeasMigr

Reference
Sigmasea
IES
MinMaxLei
LandEla
SeasMigr
Fig. 7. Sensitivity analysis of variations in model parametrization. Red bars report the absolute percentage point difference in main indicators between the seasonal
and annual model in the reference setting. Yellow bars show the positive and negative deviation from the reference model in percentage points for changes in model
parameters described in Table 8. Labels at the lower and upper end of the yellow bars refer to the respective change in the model parametrization.

results to changes in model parametrization and setup (Table 8).9 The differences. Accounting for rural-rural seasonal migration substantially
base elasticities used were estimated, derived from the literature (Ap- reduces seasonal wage differentials in the seasonal model and leads to
pendix A), or, where no estimates were available, imposed. The elas- smaller model differences. But the patterns of seasonal labor demand
ticities varied are those that have most influence on the difference in across AEZs are not complementary and peak labor months partially
results between the annual and seasonal model: details of the sensitivity overlap, which limits the potential of labor exchanges (Appendix E).
analyses are reported in Table 8. In addition, a variant of the model
setup is included allowing for seasonal rural-rural migration across 7. Discussion
AEZs with different degrees of spatial labor mobility. Seasonal migra-
tion was not included in the core analysis, due to its minor role for Seasonality affects rural livelihoods in multiple ways, e.g. through
Bhutan and a lack of data. seasonal food shortages and hunger (Vaitla et al., 2009), seasonal in-
The sensitivity analyses demonstrate that changes in main model cidences of diseases and births (Chambers et al., 1981; Devereux et al.,
parameters do not change the signs on the key results although they do 2012) and seasonal labor shortages and underemployment. The season-
influence the magnitudes; hence the main findings from the core analysis ality of labor demand is particularly relevant as labor units cannot be
remain valid (Fig. 7). Variations in the intertemporal substitution of leisure substituted across time. While seasonality of labor is a recognized phe-
(sigmsea) produced the largest changes in the results (measured in per- nomenon within agricultural economics, most economy-wide models
centage points). Given that seasonal leisure includes reproduction activ- have, implicitly, assumed perfect intertemporal labor substitution. This
ities, which have limited substitution possibilities in low income countries, study relaxes this assumption and the results demonstrate the importance
an IES of the upper end (1.2) is high. The differences in model results of accounting for seasonality of labor in low-income economies.
remain substantial and would only become very small when applying a Ignoring seasonality produces a systematic upward bias in model
very large IES (differences in model results disappeared with an IES of >8). results, particularly agricultural supply and welfare changes, due to
The second largest changes come from variations in the seasonal overstating the labor supply response through the assumption of perfect
labor substitution elasticity. When the assumption of non-substitut- intertemporal substitution. This conclusion is logically consistent in a
ability of seasonal labor, i.e. Leontief technology, is relaxed (substitu- constrained optimization problem: the presumption of perfect inter-
tion elasticity of 0.1) cropping activities can substitute labor originally temporal substitution relaxes a constraint. This study identifies two
required in peak periods with labor from other periods in which wages main sources for the biases. First, ignoring the seasonality of labor
increase at lower rates or even decline. In practice, some substitution is (annual model) overestimates the labor mobility between economic
possible among field operations, e.g., reductions in the labor demand activities with different seasonal labor demand patterns. This produces
for transplanting paddy (“sloppier transplanting”) may be compensated unrealistic labor reallocations, e.g., labor used to produce rice, a
by increased diligence when weeding; although such substitutions may summer activity, is drawn from forestry, a winter activity. And second,
result in reduced productivity. This is over and above the flexibility neglecting the seasonality of leisure distorts households’ labor-leisure
offered by reducing leisure time within a month. trade-off decisions, where leisure time is available in slack periods, i.e.,
The remaining variations all result in relatively small changes. The counter-cyclical to the cropping periods. Consequently, models with an
model differences are amplified/reduced with lower/higher calibrated annual labor market specification will report a stronger labor supply
quantities of leisure; greater (assumed) quantities of leisure dampen the response than models with seasonal labor markets.
seasonal constraints. A lower elasticity of land supply mainly reduces These systematic upward biases in agricultural supply responses and
the agriculture supply response in both models. A short-term analysis, structural changes are inter alia relevant when assessing the economy-wide
with no land expansion and reallocation, results in very low model effects of food security (e.g., Golub et al., 2013) or agricultural trade lib-
eralization scenarios (e.g., Anderson et al., 2006) and can be important to
the distribution of income and welfare results. For example, the seasonal
9
In addition, the macroeconomic closure settings were varied by either fixing labor specification results in higher farm wages and substantially lower
the exchange rate or using a savings driven closure. Differences in model results land rents in case of a cereal import price increase in Bhutan, and will thus
were very low and are therefore not reported. produce greater benefits for landless households compared to farm

14
A. Feuerbacher, et al. Food Policy xxx (xxxx) xxxx

households. 7.2. Conclusion


New technologies, especially if labor saving, and seasonal migration
will mitigate these phenomena. Many developing countries report This paper reports on the first economy-wide model that incorporates
seasonal migration. Sensitivity analysis demonstrates that seasonal seasonal labor markets on a national scale. The simulations provide evi-
migration reduces wage differentials, but unless it produces perfect dence that ignoring seasonal labor demand systematically biases the results
intertemporal substitution, the seasonality constraint will persist. The with marked implications for agricultural supply response, income and
limited reductions in wage differentials from seasonal migration are household welfare. The findings are empirical and model validations of
consistent with empirical observations, in countries such as India, Amartya Sen’s insight that “it is somewhat misleading to speak in terms of a
where despite seasonal migration seasonal labor shortages and under- homogeneous unit of labor” in the context of agriculture (Sen, 1966,
employment are common (Reddy et al., 2014). Incorporating season- p. 440). Importantly, the nature of the bias demonstrated in this study has
ality in economy-wide models allows future studies to explicitly model implications for the interpretation of the results for the agricultural sector
seasonal migration and beyond that to account for realistic rates of derived from economy-wide models and for policy design based on such
seasonal underemployment, which otherwise would be included within model analyses. For instance, studies of global agricultural trade liberal-
annual underemployment (McCullough, 2017). ization will overestimate agricultural supply responses in developing
While not at the core of this study, the empirical analysis of the countries because of implicit labor endowment effects. Similarly, single
impact of an Indian cereal export ban on the Bhutanese economy shows country studies of the implications of increases/decreases in global food
that even large changes in import prices of cereals will have limited prices will over/under estimate the labor supply responses. These implica-
welfare implications for Bhutanese households. Increases in cereal im- tions point to a need to improve the modelling of labor markets, especially
port prices of 35% will, on average, reduce household welfare by 0.5% rural labor markets, even when this requires confronting data challenges.
and reduce average food consumption by some 2.7%, although the
distributional impacts are more pronounced. Results are broadly con- CRediT authorship contribution statement
sistent with the literature on food-price impacts (e.g. Arndt et al.,
2008). The muted results reflect the model’s medium-term horizon Arndt Feuerbacher: Conceptualization, Data curation,
closure allowing for land reallocation within Bhutan’s agriculture Investigation, Visualization, Writing - original draft. Scott McDonald:
sector. The economy-wide changes would differ substantially in a short- Conceptualization, Writing - review & editing. Chencho Dukpa: Data
term horizon with no possibility of land reallocation. curation, Validation, Supervision. Harald Grethe: Conceptualization,
Writing - review & editing, Supervision.

7.1. Potential extensions and avenues for further research Declaration of Competing Interest

The analyses can be further developed. Data limitations preclude the None.
differentiation of labor types by gender and age profile and the differ-
entiation of ‘leisure’ activities between ‘pure’ leisure and social reproduc- Acknowledgements
tion. The implications of relaxing these limitations will depend upon the
extent to which roles are rigidly segmented by gender, school holidays This study was funded by a field research grant of the fiat panis
coincide with peak labor demands and the opportunity costs of trading-off foundation (Ulm, Germany) and by a PhD scholarship of the University
leisure and social reproduction for agricultural labor services change. of Hohenheim. Institutional support by the Humboldt-Universität zu
Further research is also needed to improve the understanding of seasonal Berlin and Bhutan’s Ministry of Agriculture and Forests is gratefully
activities in and outside of the production boundary, particularly con- acknowledged. The authors thank three anonymous referees for their
cerning the role of gender and social reproduction (Fontana and Wood, valuable and constructive comments that helped to improve the article.
2000). Such developments may increase or decrease the degree of inter- Furthermore, the authors would like to thank Kinley Tshering, Tulsi
temporal substitution, but they cannot fully relax the constraint imposed Gurung, Phub Dorji, Mahesh Ghimiray, Thomas Daum, Jonas
by imperfect intertemporal labor substitution. Luckmann, Anton Orlov, and Khalid Siddig as well as participants of the
Similarly, the model could be formulated as a dynamic model to 30th International Conference of Agricultural Economists in Vancouver
evaluate, inter alia, the implications of demographic change (see Aragie for their helpful comments on previous versions of this study.
et al., 2017) and the introduction of labor-saving technology changes.
Particularly in case of the latter, a model with seasonal labor markets Appendix A. Supplementary material
would allow for an improved assessment of technologies, which miti-
gate seasonal labor bottlenecks, e.g., the mechanization of paddy Supplementary data to this article can be found online at https://
transplanting. Further model developments in this direction should doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2020.101875.
account for the nuances of seasonality which have not been addressed
in this article, such as the limited substitutability of machinery with References
specific seasonal usability, e.g., a plough cannot be transformed into a
harvester in the short run and vice versa. Machinery also has a limited Anderson, K., Martin, W., van der Mensbrugghe, D., 2006. Doha merchandise trade re-
seasonal capacity, i.e., it can only be used for a certain amount of time, form: what is at stake for developing countries? World Bank Econ. Rev. 20 (2),
while farmers often demand labor-saving machinery at the same time.10 169–195. https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/lhj009.
Antle, J.M., 1983. Sequential decision making in production models. Am. J. Agric. Econ.
In other contexts it would be important to account for seasonality of 65 (2), 282–290. https://doi.org/10.2307/1240874.
irrigation water flows or that increasing heat stress due to climate Aragie, E., Dudu, H., Ferrari, E., Mainar Causapé, A., McDonald, S., Thierfelder, K., 2017.
change reduces labor productivity seasonally, but not necessarily all STAGE_DEV: a variant of the STAGE model to analyse developing countries.
Publications Office of the European Union, Brussels.
year round. These aspects may be addressed using an multi-period Armington, P.S., 1969. A theory of demand for products distinguished by place of pro-
model with sequential decision making as already explored in the duction. IMF Staff Papers 16 (1), 159–178.
micro-level model literature (Antle, 1983; Fafchamps, 1993; Taylor and Arndt, C., Benfica, R., Maximiano, N., Nucifora, A.M.D., Thurlow, J.T., 2008. Higher fuel
and food prices: impacts and responses for Mozambique. Agric. Econ. 39 (August),
Charlton, 2019).
497–511. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1574-0862.2008.00355.x.
Atwood, S., Nagpal, S., Mbuya, N., Laviolette, L., 2014. Nutrition in Bhutan: Situational
Analysis and Policy Recommendations, Washington DC, USA. <http://documents.
10 worldbank.org/curated/en/397081468227331146/Nutrition-in-Bhutan-situational-
We are grateful to an anonymous referee for highlighting this.

15
A. Feuerbacher, et al. Food Policy xxx (xxxx) xxxx

analysis-and-policy-recommendations>. Agriculture. Macmillan, New York.


Bargain, O., Peichl, A., 2016. Own-wage labor supply elasticities: variation across time Heckman, J.J., MaCurdy, T., 1982. Corrigendum on a life cycle model of female labour
and estimation methods. IZA J. Labor. Econ. 5 (1), 635. https://doi.org/10.1186/ supply. Rev. Econ. Stud. 49 (4), 659–660.
s40172-016-0050-z. Hertel, T.W., 1997. Global Trade Analysis: Modeling and Applications. Cambridge
Barrett, C.B., Sherlund, S.M., Adesina, A.A., 2008. Shadow wages, allocative inefficiency, University Press.
and labor supply in smallholder agriculture. Agric. Econ. 38 (1), 21–34. https://doi. ISWGNA, 2009. System of National Accounts 2008. UN, OECD, World Bank, IMF and EC,
org/10.1111/j.1574-0862.2007.00278.x. New York NY.
Berger, T., Troost, C., 2014. Agent-based modelling of climate adaptation and mitigation Jacoby, H.G., 1993. Shadow wages and peasant family labour supply: an econometric
options in agriculture. J. Agric. Econ. 65 (2), 323–348. https://doi.org/10.1111/ application to the Peruvian Sierra. Rev. Econ. Stud. 60 (4), 903–921. https://doi.org/
1477-9552.12045. 10.2307/2298105.
Bezu, S., Barrett, C.B., Holden, S.T., 2012. Does the Nonfarm Economy Offer Pathways for Jarvis, L., Vera-Toscano, E., 2004. Seasonal adjustment in a market for female agricultural
Upward Mobility? Evidence from a Panel Data Study in Ethiopia. World Develop. 40 workers. Am. J. Agr. Econ. 86 (1), 254–266. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.0092-5853.
(8), 1634–1646. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2012.04.019. 2004.00576.x.
Binswanger, H.P., Rosenzweig, M.R., 1981. Contractual arrangements, employment, and Jessoe, K., Manning, D.T., Taylor, J.E., 2018. Climate change and labour allocation in
wages in rural labor markets: a critical review. Studies in Employment and Rural rural Mexico: evidence from annual fluctuations in weather. Econ. J. 128 (608),
Development 67, Washington D.C., USA. <http://documents.worldbank.org/ 230–261. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecoj.12448.
curated/en/412971467997610342/Contractual-arrangements-employment-and- Lee, C.-I., 2001. Finite sample bias in IV estimation of intertemporal labor supply models:
wages-in-rural-labor-markets-a-critical-review>. is the intertemporal substitution elasticity really small? Rev. Econ. Stat. 83 (4),
Boeters, S., Savard, L., 2013. The labor market in computable general equilibrium models. 638–646. https://doi.org/10.1162/003465301753237722.
Handbook Comput. General Equilib. Model. 1, 1645–1718. https://doi.org/10.1016/ Lofgren, H., Harris, R.L., Robinson, S., 2002. A Standard Computable General Equilibrium
B978-0-444-59568-3.00026-2. (CGE) Model in GAMS. Intl Food Policy Res. Inst, Washington D.C., USA.
Bryan, G., Chowdhury, S., Mobarak, A.M., 2014. Underinvestment in a profitable tech- Lucas Jr., R.E., Rapping, L.A., 1969. Real wages, employment, and inflation. J. Polit.
nology: the case of seasonal migration in Bangladesh. Econometrica 82 (5), Econ. 77 (5), 721–754.
1671–1748. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA10489. McCullough, E.B., 2017. Labor productivity and employment gaps in Sub-Saharan Africa.
Card, D., 1994. Intertemporal Labor Supply: An Assessment. Advances in Econometrics, Food Policy 67, 133–152. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2016.09.013.
Sixth World Congress. Cambridge University Press. McDonald, Scott, Thierfelder, Karen, 2015. A Static Applied General Equilibrium Model -
Castañeda, A., Doan, D., Newhouse, D., Nguyen, M.C., Uematsu, H., Azevedo, J.P., 2018. Technical Documentation STAGE Version 2. self-published. http://www.cgemod.
A new profile of the global poor. World Develop. 101, 250–267. https://doi.org/10. org.uk/STAGE%20CGE%20Model%20v2.pdf.
1016/j.worlddev.2017.08.002. MoAF, 2013. Agricultural Sample Survey 2012 - Dataset. Department of Agriculture,
Chambers, R., Longhurst, R., Pacey, A., 1981. Seasonal Dimensions to Rural Poverty. Thimphu, Bhutan.
Frances Pinter. MoAF, 2016. Microdata on the Agricultural Sample Survey rounds conducted in 2012,
Connolly, M., 2008. Here comes the rain again: weather and the intertemporal sub- 2013, 2014 and 2015 first and second year half. Ministry of Agriculture and Forests,
stitution of leisure: weather and the intertemporal substitution of leisure. J. Labor Thimphu, Bhutan.
Econ. 26 (1), 73–100. https://doi.org/10.1086/522067. MoEA, 2012. Diagnostic Trade Integration Study. Ministry of Economic Affairs, Thimphu,
de Melo, J., Robinson, S., 1989. Product differentiation and the treatment of foreign trade Bhutan.
in computable general equilibrium models of small economies. J. Int. Econ. 27 (1–2), NSB, 2018. 2017 Population and Housing Census of Bhutan: National Report. National
47–67. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-1996(89)90077-9. Statistics Bureau (NSB) of Bhutan, Thimphu, Bhutan. <http://www.nsb.gov.bt/
Devarajan, S., Robinson, S., 2005. The Influence of Computable General Equilibrium publication/download.php?id=1352> (accessed 19 August 2018).
Models on Policy. Frontiers in Applied General Equilibrium Modeling: In Honor of NSB, ADB, 2012. Bhutan Living Standard Survey 2012 - dataset. National Statistics
Herbert Scarf, 402–428. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511614330.016. Bureau; Asian Development Bank, Thimphu, Bhutan.
Devereux, S., 2016. Social protection for enhanced food security in sub-Saharan Africa. NSB, World Bank, 2012. Bhutan Poverty Analysis 2012. National Statistics Bureau; World
Food Policy 60, 52–62. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2015.03.009. Bank, Thimphu, Bhutan http://www.nsb.gov.bt/publication/files/
Devereux, S., Sabates-Wheeler, R., Longhurst, R., 2012. Seasonality Revisited: New pub6pg3078cg.pdf.
Perspective on Seasonal Poverty. Seasonality, Rural Livelihoods and Development. NSB, World Bank, 2017. Bhutan Poverty Analysis 2017. National Statistics Bureau; World
New York, USA: Earthscan. Bank, Thimphu, Bhutan http://www.nsb.gov.bt/publication/files/
Eickhout, B., van Meijl, H., Tabeau, A., Stehfest, E., 2009. The impact of environmental pub6pg3078cg.pdf.
and climate constraints on global food supply. Econ. Anal. Land Use Global Clim. Perroni, C., Rutherford, T.F., 1995. Regular flexibility of nested CES functions. Eur. Econ.
Change Policy 14, 206. Rev. 39 (2), 335–343. https://doi.org/10.1016/0014-2921(94)00018-U.
Fafchamps, M., 1993. Sequential labor decisions under uncertainty: an estimable Reardon, T., Stamoulis, K., Cruz, M.E., Berdegué, J., Banks, B., 1998. Rural non-farm
household model of West-African Farmers. Econometrica 61 (5), 1173. https://doi. income in developing countries: Special Chapter. The state of food and agriculture
org/10.2307/2951497. 283-356. FAO, Rome, Italy. <http://www.fao.org/docrep/w9500e/w9500e00.
Fehr, E., Goette, L., 2007. Do workers work more if wages are high? Evidence from a htm>.
randomized field experiment. Am. Econ. Rev. 97 (1), 298–317. https://doi.org/10. Reddy, D.N., Reddy, A.A., Bantilan, M.C.S., 2014. The Impact of Mahatma Gandhi
1257/aer.97.1.298. National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (MGNREGA) on Rural Labor Markets and
Feuerbacher, A., 2019. Economy-wide Modelling of Seasonal Labour and Natural Agriculture. India Rev. 13 (3), 251–273. https://doi.org/10.1080/14736489.2014.
Resource Policies. Dissertation. Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin, Berlin, Germany. 937271.
https://doi.org/10.18452/19825. Ruthenberg, H., 1971. Farming systems in the tropics. Oxford University Press,
Feuerbacher, A., Dukpa, C., Grethe, H., 2017. A 2012 Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) for Oxford, UK.
Bhutan with a detailed representation of the agricultural sector: Technical Sen, A.K., 1966. Peasants and Dualism with or without Surplus Labor. J. Polit. Econ.
Documentation. Working Paper 94. Department of Agricultural Economics, Faculty of 425–450.
Life Sciences, Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin, Berlin. <https://www.agrar.hu- Skoufias, E., 1994. Using shadow wages to estimate labor supply of agricultural house-
berlin.de/de/institut/departments/daoe/publ/wp/wp94.pdf>. holds. Am. J. Agr. Econ. 76 (2), 215–227. https://doi.org/10.2307/1243623.
Feuerbacher, A., Luckmann, J., Boysen, O., Zikeli, S., Grethe, H., 2018. Is Bhutan destined Skoufias, E., 1996. Intertemporal substitution in labor supply: Micro evidence from rural
for 100% organic? Assessing the economy-wide effects of a large-scale conversion India. J. Develop. Econ. 51 (2), 217–237. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-3878(96)
policy. PloS One 13 (6), e0199025. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0199025. 00413-0.
Filipski, M., Aboudrare, A., Lybbert, T.J., Taylor, J.E., 2017. Spice price spikes: simulating Taylor, J.E., Charlton, D., 2019. The farm labor problem: A global perspective. Academic
impacts of saffron price volatility in a gendered local economy-wide model. World Press, London, United Kingdom, 1 Online-Ressource.
Develop. 91, 84–99. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2016.10.018. Taylor, J.E., Charlton, D., Yúnez-Naude, A., 2012. The end of farm labor abundance. Appl.
Finnoff, D., Tschirhart, J., 2008. Linking dynamic economic and ecological general Econ. Perspect. Pol. 34 (4), 587–598. https://doi.org/10.1093/aepp/pps036.
equilibrium models. Resour. Energy Econ. 30 (2), 91–114. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. Vaitla, B., Devereux, S., Swan, S.H., 2009. Seasonal hunger: a neglected problem with
reseneeco.2007.08.005. proven solutions: a neglected problem with proven solutions. PLoS Med. 6 (6),
Fontana, M., Wood, A., 2000. Modeling the effects of trade on women, at work and at e1000101. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pmed.1000101.
home. World Development 28 (7), 1173–1190. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0305-750X Villoria, N.B., Mghenyi, E.W., 2016. The impacts of india's food security policies on South
(00)00033-4. Asian Wheat and Rice Markets. World Bank Econ. Rev. 31 (3), 730–746. https://doi.
GoI, 2014. Exemption to Bhutan from the application of export bans by India on export of org/10.1093/wber/lhw002.
Milk Powder, Wheat, Edible Oils, Pulses and Non-Basmati Rice. Government of India, Wodon, Q., Beegle, K., 2012. Labor shortages despite underemployment? Seasonality in
Delhi, India. <http://dgft.gov.in/exim/2000/NOT/NOT13/not8114.htm>. time use in Malawi. Chapter 5. In: Blackden, M.C., Wodon, Q. (Eds.), Gender, Time
Goldberg, J., 2016. Kwacha Gonna Do? Experimental Evidence about Labor Supply in Use, and Poverty in Sub-Saharan Africa. World Bank, Washington, DC, pp. 97–116.
Rural Malawi. Am. Econ. J.: Appl. Econ. 8 (1), 129–149. https://doi.org/10.1257/ World Bank, 2019. World Development Indicators. Dataset, Washington DC, USA http://
app.20130369. data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators (accessed 7 October
Golub, A.A., Henderson, B.B., Hertel, T.W., Gerber, P.J., Rose, S.K., Sohngen, B., 2013. Global 2019).
climate policy impacts on livestock, land use, livelihoods, and food security. Proc. Natl. Zhang, X., Yang, J., Wang, S., 2011. China has reached the Lewis turning point. China.
Acad. Sci. USA 110 (52), 20894–20899. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1108772109. Econ. Rev. 22 (4), 542–554. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chieco.2011.07.002.
Hazell, P.B.R., Norton, R.D., 1986. Mathematical Programming for Economic Analysis in

16

Potrebbero piacerti anche