Sei sulla pagina 1di 6

Renewabh,Eneryy Vol. 3, No. 8, pp. 891--896, 1993 096~|481/93 $6.00+.

00
Printed in Great Britain. ,]" 1993 Pergamon Press Ltd

ECONOMICS OF OCEAN THERMAL ENERGY


CONVERSION (OTEC)

D. E. CAVROT
Institute of Marine Studies, University of Plymouth, Plymouth, PL8 4AA, U.K.

(Received 26 November 1992 ~accepted 27 January 1993)

Abstract--Ocean thermal energy conversion (OTEC) has for many years been recognised as a possible
energy of the future. Recently, the emphasis has changed towards combination plants offering not only
power, but also freshwater, mariculture and other deep ocean water applications (DOWA).
The models used in this modified cost-benefit analysis indicate under what economic circumstances
OTEC, which is presently only competitive in a few remote islands, may become more widelycompetitive
in the near future. Among the model variables are the plants' capital cost, operation and maintenance
costs, the price of oil and desalinated water as well as a hypothetical carbon tax.

1. INTRODUCTION U.S. Gulf Coast and Caribbean regions, and Africa


Asia are expected to develop later.
Ocean thermal energy conversion (OTEC) consists of
extracting energy from the relatively high temperature 2.2. Type o f OTEC plants
difference found in some tropical seas between the Market surveys show that there is a need for both
warm surface water and cold 'deep' water, and con- floating and land-based variants, indicating that
verting it into electricity. The emphasis used to be on about half of the present locations for pure OTEC
the production of power alone. Recently, desalinated plants are suitable only for the floating version [1].
water, a by-product of the open-cycle (OC) and hy- However, initially, the preference for smaller size
brid-cycle (HC) OTEC, has changed this trend. plants, and the demand for fresh water should favour
Today, because the sites where OTEC may first be the land-based versions in the OC- or HC-con-
used are often short of potable water, as well as power, figuration. The first commercial OTEC plants will
the 'water' option is receiving growing attention. The have electrical outputs ranging from 1 to 10 MWe [2].
perspective of using the cool and nutrient rich deep In the long term, the Pacific and Asian islands offer a
water for deep ocean water applications (DOWA) market for 1-100 MW~, OTEC plants.
such as mariculture, drip irrigation and air con-
2.3. Time scale
ditioning further enhances the chances of OTEC
It is estimated that continued R&D could open
becoming economically viable. The technology is con-
markets to OTEC in the Asia Pacific region in the
tinuously improving due to specific research and tech-
mid-1990s, and that globally, at least 350 MWe could
nology transfer from other fields such as the offshore
be provided by OTEC by the year 2005, and 2100
oil and gas industry.
MW~ by 2010. Later, the production of methanol and
In this paper, the economic viability of OTEC is
hydrogen as transportation fuels may prove to be
assessed and compared with that of conventional oil-
economically feasible and could raise this potential by
powered stations.
a factor of five to the 10 GW~ range [3].

2. OTEC MARKET
3. E C O N O M I C VARIABLES
2.1. Location
The market for OTEC will be greatest where elec- 3.1. Cost components
tricity produced from fossil fuels is most expensive Capital cost. Since OTEC technology requires no
such as island communities which have to rely upon fuel for plant operation, its major cost component
imported oil. For that reason, and because of their is the very substantial capital investment. At over
need for desalinated water, the Pacific islands are $10,000/kW, the capital cost of OTEC plants is almost
expected to be the initial market for OC-OTEC. The one order of magnitude higher than that of oil-fired

891
892 D.E. CAVROT

plants. Thus, on the basis of capital cost alone, OTEC plants is around "70% [5]. For OTEC plants, with
shows up badly against oil- and coal-fired power gen- routine preventive maintenance, an availability factor
eration [1]. of 90% is possible, but initially values near 80% seems
Operation and maintenance costs. Operation and more likely [4, 6].
maintenance (O&M) costs for well developed oil-fired Operating l~'e. The 30-year design life of OTEC
plants are low (typically 3% of capital cost per plants is similar to that of fossil fuel power stations,
annum), whereas for low-efficiency OTEC plants they and 5 years longer than that of nuclear plants.
will be relatively high. For floating OTEC plants, Temperature difference, AT. To be able to produce
including inspection and crew costs, they will be about the design power at all times, the design AT must be
5%, but may be considerably less for land-based the minimum available at the plant location ["7]. The
plants [1,4]. reference design AT is normally 20C, which is esti-
Fuel cost. Although OTEC fuel (i.e. sun and water) mated to provide an overall operating efficiency of
is free, the price of fossil (and nuclear) fuel still 2.5% . The gross output of an OTEC plant depends
inherently determines the competitiveness of OTEC on (AT) 2, and a 2 C increase in AT can increase the
against conventional power generation. One can pre- efficiency by over 20%. There is also a strong depen-
dict that as reserves of fossil fuels dwindle, com- dence of capital cost on design AT. In fact it has been
petition for existing stocks increases, and the cost of shown [4] that
exploitation of remaining stocks rises accordingly. As
Cost ~c AT k
a result, the price ofoil is expected to increase 'fin real
terms" (i.e, above inflation rate) at a rate of about where 2 < k < 2.5.
3% per annum [5]. Insurance. Potential accidents include accidental
3.2. Economie fiwtors release of hazardous chemicals, possible interference
Size and eeononO' of scale. Depending on the plant with shipping and with defence submarines by the
configuration, unit generating costs will increase sig- mooring line, the cable and the cold water pipe. An
nificantly below a critical size. For example, a annual value of 2% of the capital cost is typical [1].
reduction in size below 5-8 MW for a land-based Other considerations. Some of the other key factors
plant, and 2 5 4 0 MW for floating plants, will result include taxes, interest during construction, rate of
in substantial increases in unit capital and generating inflation and financial incentives.
costs. 3.3. Operatin.q conditions
Economy of replication. In predicting the pro- Early OTEC experiments drew on the deep ocean
duction cost of OTEC hardware, one needs to keep water as a key element of the energy system. Now,
in mind various cost-reduction measures applied to applications for the cold water will play a key role in
industrial processes. For example, industry dis- improving the economic appeal of the total OTEC
tinguishes between the cost of early units of a pro- system, and in purely economic terms, there is sub-
duction line and the asymptotic cost after a given stantial logic in choosing a 'combination' plant of
number of units have been produced and learning has OTEC, desalination and aquaculture providing
been achieved [4]. power, water and a product to sell [1].
Knock-on effbet. In addition to possible direct cost Fresh water. In regions where both electric power
reduction, technological refinements may also have and fresh water are valuable, it may be economically
indirect effects on the overall design cost. A typical advantageous to produce both because the desali-
example is the use of aluminium as a cheaper and nated water will offset the high cost of electricity pro-
more efficient heat exchanger material. The resulting duced from the system. However, there is a trade-off
size reduction of the heat exchanger will significantly situation between the generation of power and the
reduce the mass and size of floating plants, and in production of fresh water, one being produced at the
turn. the required strength of the mooring lines. expense of the other [8].
Capacity fiwtor. The capacity factor may be sep- Aquaculture. To the aquaculture user, OTEC plants
arated into two components : ( 1) acaihlbility, which is provide a significant supply of electric power to run
the percentage of time the plant is ready to deliver his sea-water pumps and other operations. In such
output (e.g. consider possible plant closure duc to circumstances the costs of the OTEC plant can
hurricanes or severe weather); and (2) an enciron- become quite competitive [9] and in fact, in Hawaii
mentalfiwtor, which is the percentage of full output many successful commercial ventures have already
based on the seasonal variation of the thermal resulted from the mariculture development [2].
resource. The capacity factor for oil- and coal-fired Deep ocean water applications. Although the con-
Ocean thermal energy conversion 893

cepts of temperature control in refrigeration or air- ducing at least 1 MW~ of electricity plus 3500 m 3 of
conditioning systems and irrigation for crop growth desalinated water per day, and 10 MW~ have been
have been proven, their application on a large scale proposed for the land-based and floating versions,
still has to be demonstrated. respectively.
Other options. The remaining options make use of Cost. Because of the high capital cost of OTEC,
OTEC electrical power in situ to realize energy inten- even a demonstration plant would still be pro-
sive products such as hydrogen, ammonia, fertilizers, hibitively expensive and therefore difficult to fund.
produce metals from their ores (e.g. aluminium) and Dilemma for OTEC. A confusing situation emerges
even, given an international legal regime, manganese from the following findings :
nodule mining operations. However, the economic
viability of these processes is not yet established. ( 1) the economics of power generation (i.e. econ-
omy of scale) suggests that a very large leap
3.4. Risks evaluation forward is needed ;
The OTEC technology is now at a point where the (2) engineering prudence suggests that an
unknowns are limited and their scale can be predicted incremental approach (i.e. demonstration
with reasonable accuracy, but traditional financial plant) is the soundest way to proceed :
institutions seldom support new technology, and the (3) the problems of financing the incremental
fact that no commercial plants are currently in oper- approach are complicated by the fact that,
ation will continue to preclude financial support [9]. as small electric power plants, they are
Quantification of the potential risks and problems for uneconomic :
a specific OTEC project would normally be the object (4) the problems of financing a large leap foward
of a risk analysis. are bound to be considerable in view of the
Contin.qeneies. Deployment and possible damage risks of meeting unforeseen problems,
from adverse weather conditions are relatively high-
risk elements. Unknowns also arise from the assemb- One possible way out of this dilemma is a com-
ling of all the components at a commercial scale as mercial "combination" system based primarily on
well as the further development of items such as large aquaculture supporting the costs of installing sea-
diameter cold water pipes, turbines for OC-OTEC water pipes and pumps, and flexible enough to provide
and tension leg platform moorings. the basis l\~r the incremental development of the
Phmt reliahilio'. As mentioned earlier, there are OTEC concept itself [11]. Again. one must ask if the
good economic reasons to opt tk~r 'combination' added complexity of such a system and resulting
plants providing power, fresh water, mariculture and reductions in efficiency and reliability warrant this
other DOWA activities. However, the extent to which approach.
the added complexity affects the reliability of oper-
3.6. t')mding and collahoration
ation will require careful consideration.
Demonstration phase. The first demonstration
Mar/,elthtclualions. A combination plant needs to
plantls) will require non-commercial funding. The
be flexible enough to cater for the varying demands
potential economic, social and political benefits to
I\)r each product. Unstable oil price can also adversely
developing (and developed) nations offered by OTEC
affect the rates of return expected by OTEC investors.
should influence Ihvourably international institutions
These doubts suggest the need for a prudent and
regarding loans or grants [7]. Among the possible
progressive approach towards the commercialization
international institutions are: the World Bank, the
of OTEC: this is the funding, construction and full
European Community (currently reasscssing OTEC's
operation of "simple' demonstration plants.
potential), the EUREKA initiative, the International
3.5. Demon.vtrati(m plant Energy Agency, the International Finance C o r p o f
Thc construction of a demonstration plant will pro- ation, the Inter-American Development Bank, and
vide meaningful inl\)rmation on long-term per- the Asian Development Bank, etc.
formance and reliability, and experience on oper- Ultimately. the joint cooperation between diverse
ations and maintenance. Such a facility could also government agencies, private investors and inter-
serve to put to rest any remaining doubts harboured national bodies will lead not only to improved funding
by tinancial agencies regarding the technical viability prospects but also settlements on regulating and
of OTEC [I 0]. licensing issues.
Si-_e. The scaling factors between demonstration ('ommercial pha,~e. Although developing nations,
and production plants should not exceed a wdue of where much of the early OTEC market exists, arc in
approximately 10 [101. Demonstration plants pro- short supply of capital, their substitution to OTEC-
894 D. E. CAVROT

derived electricity will help relieve them of much of adds to the rationality of decision-making. For exam-
their outflow of foreign exchange [12]. Hence, in so ple, the economic cost of resource degradation is con-
far as funds continue to be available to them for ventionally measured in terms of foregone GNP [! 5].
the importation of oil, their provision of capital for Even so, economists differ as to how far quantification
investment in OTEC would be an attractive alter- can reasonably be pushed.
native [t 3].
4.2. Model concept
Appraisal method. An economic model has been
4. ECONOMIC APPRAISAL designed to compare the generating cost of electricity
in S/kWh for both OTEC and oil-fired plants. This
4.1. Framework for modified cost-benefit analysis
cost is derived from the discounted cash flow over the
Background. The first items to be accounted for in
life of the plant (i.e. NPV) rated against the total
a cost-benefit analysis (CBA) are those expressed in
output of the plant. In the case of OC- and HC-OTEC
monetary terms. Standard evaluation techniques
plants, the desalinated water produced is counted as
include Payback Period, Net Present Value (NPV),
a source of revenue. Table 1 lists the model variables
Internal Rate of Return (1RR) and Accounting Rate
for both OTEC and oil-powered stations.
of Return. However, in a comprehensive CBA, too
Externalities. The model allows only one environ-
many factors cannot be valued directly in monetary
mental factor to be "internalized" by applying a
terms at all, or only very speculatively, for the results
"carbon tax" expressed in "S/barrel of oil". As noted
to provide much reliable evidence for a decision. On
earlier, it is important to realize that the OTEC alter-
the other hand, specific economic measurements that
native should not be considered on the monetary
are designed to help investment decisions or appli-
grounds alone. OTEC also has many benefits difficult
cations of policies can be helpful so long as their
or impossible to quantify realistically but which need
intrinsic limitations are understood. Such an exercise
to be incorporated in the decision-making process.
may be described as a 'modified' CBA [14].
Some of these externalities may even far outweigh
Externalities. Much of modern CBA can be seen as
economic factors. Locally or on a larger scale, these
an attempt to deal with the problem of externalities.
benefits include: energy self-sufficiency; minimal
Because of the mostly harmful effects which the uses
environmental impact; improved sanitation and
of modern technology have upon 'free goods' such as
nutrition for inhabitants from desalinated water and
water and air, and upon welfare and social properties
mariculture products; regional development, e.g.
such as the quality of the environment, some econ-
employment; strategic diversity of energy sources;
omists have naturally concerned themselves with the
alternative investment to other energy sources, and
social costs of these processes. Those economists have
insurance against unpredictable increases in primary
a practical problem over where they should place the
energy costs, since the cost of generation is inde-
limits of their investigations and should concede that
pendent of energy prices.
there are cases of welfare loss or gain which simply
cannot be expressed in monetary terms. 4.3. Baseline conditions
Quantification. The use of a common scale of The economic factors not previously quantified are
quantification such as hypothesized money values or given below.
ranking techniques by numerical rating or weighting Operating conditions. Only electricity and water

Table 1. Model variables for both OTEC and oil-powered stations

OTEC plant Oil-powered plant

Thermodynamic cycle (OC/CC) Nominal size (MWe)


Nominal size (MWe) Capacity factor (%)
Capacity factor (%) Capital cost ($/kW)
Capital cost ($/kWe) O&M cost (% CC/year)
O&M cost (% CC/year) Price of oil (S/barrel)
Price of water ($/m~) real term increase (%/year)
Discount rate (%/year) Carbon tax (S/barrel)
Interest rate (%/year) Discount rate (%/year)
Grant (%/CC) Interest rate (%/year)
Annuity period (year) Grant (% CC)
Annuity period (year)
Ocean thermal energy conversion 895

production are considered in this analysis. Other oper- to be deducted. The remaining capital cost, effectively
ations such as mariculture or air-conditioning would a loan, is then reimbursed as annuities (equal yearly
require a more elaborate model and a substantial payments) over an annuity period of 30 years.
amount of data not readily available.
Capital cost. Unfortunately, a great deal of dis-
crepancies exist between estimates of OTEC's capital
5. RESULTS AND CONCLUSION
cost produced by American and English sources. The
highest estimates (i.e. those derived by R&D carried 5.1. Baseline scenario
out in the U.S.A.) were chosen and are listed in Table Model predictions indicate that OTEC electricity is
2. The capital cost of oil-fired plants is typically in the not directly competitive with oil-generated electricity,
order of $2100/kW [16]. Even in the 40 MW CC-plantship and 40 MW single-
Fresh water price. In the OTEC model, the value of stage land-based OC-configurations, the generating
water is used as a revenue offsetting the cost of OTEC costs are $0.078/kWh and $0.104/kWh, respectively.
electricity, and can be changed to cater for different This does not compare favourably with the
market conditions. In the Pacific islands, the market $0.059/kWh value obtained for oil-fired plants (in any
value of this water ranges from $0.40/m 3 to $1.60/m 3 size).
[3].
In the model used for the oil-fired plant, the cost of 5.2. Competitive scenario
desalinated water produced by reverse osmosis or Using the OTEC oil-fired plant models sim-
multi-stage flash is given on the basis of the following ultaneously, it is possible to identify a critical oil cost
expression used by Vega and Trenka [16]: above which OTEC becomes competitive with oil-
fired plants. For comparison, at the time of writing,
Cost ...... = 0.049 CB ($/m3),
the cost of North Sea oil was $20/barrel. The best
where CB = cost of oil per 42 US-gallon barrel ($). scenarios are for the 40 MW CC-OTEC plantship and
Price of oil. In the baseline conditions, a value of the 10 MW land-based OC-OTEC plant.
$18/barrel is chosen (1989 value). It is assumed that OTEC shows its best potential in the 40 MW CC-
the oil price does not affect the generating cost of OTEC plantship configuration, with a generating cost
OTEC-derived electricity. With a thermal efficiency of of $0.078/kWh which is comparable with electricity
36%, the heat rate equals 9500 Btu/kWh, and with a generated from oil at $35/barrel. Such a scenario
heating value for oil of approximately 144,000 Btu/ could occur in the near future but is precluded at this
gallon, it can be shown [2] that : stage by the very high capital cost and risks involved
before the demonstration stage. In the land-based
Coste~c = 1.571 10 3. CB (S/kWh).
configuration, the 10 MW OC-OTEC equipped with a
Discount/'actor. Assuming it to be a public sector second stage requires a fuel cost of at least $45.3/barrel
project, a relatively low 5% value is chosen for the (against $57/barrel for a 40 MW CC-OTEC plant).
baseline conditions [5, 17]. At present, such conditions already exist in certain
Interest rate. An interest rate of 11%, similar to less-developed Pacific Island Nations with small
that used by Lennard and Johnson [9], was selected. populations such as Western Samoa ($47/barrel) and
Financial incentives and loans. Each model allows a the Kingdom of Tonga ($50/barrel) [16]. However,
grant (expressed as a percentage of total capital cost) even a 10 MW plant is probably too big for the needs
of the local economy. In the worst situation, a I MW
single stage OC plant would require an oil cost in the
Table 2. Capital cost estimates in $/kW-net for OTEC plants
[16] order of $88/barrel to be competitive. This illustrates
the problem of financing small size and economically
Capital cost non-viable demonstration plants.
Type of OTEC plants (1989 dollars)
5.3. lnfluence of other parameters
t MW OC-OTEC (land-based) 18,000
1 MW OC-OTEC with 2nd stage 23,000 Carbon tax. The study has indicated that to make
10 MW OC-OTEC (land-based) 11,000 OTEC competitive today, a very substantial carbon
10 MW OC-OTEC with 2nd stage 15,000 tax would need to be applied, i.e. greater than the
40 MW CC-OTEC (land-based) 6000 $13/barrel tax sometimes quoted before the Earth
40 MW Hybrid-OTEC 9200 Summit (June 1992).
40 MW CC-OTEC (plantship) 4500 Water revenue. In places where the cost of de-
salinated water is high, the use of a second stage
896 D. E. CAVROT

condenser can improve the economics of O C - O T E C fired and Oil-fired Power Stations. Central" Electricity
significantly. It remains to be seen whether maricul- Generating Board (1980).
Iure or other D O W A could further improve O T E C ' s 6. A. Lavi, Ocean thermal energy conversion: a general
introduction. Energy 5, 46%480 (1980).
competitiveness. 7. D. E. Lennard, Prospects and potential for ocean ther-
Comparison with other studies. Other economic mal energy conversion. World Energy Conference
studies on O T E C generally confirm the findings Monograph, 43 pp (1986).
above, i.e. that, at present, O T E C is only competitive 8. Solar Energy Research Institute, Environmental impacts
of ocean thermal energy conversion. Solar Technical
in a few remote island locations but that further cost Information Program (1986).
reductions and/or more favourable economic cir- 9. D. E. Lennard and F. A. Johnson, Improvements in
cumstances could make O T E C more widely com- closed-cycle ocean thermal energy conversion. Under-
petitive in the near future. However, the generating water Technol. 17, 24--28 (1991).
costs predicted with this model are slightly higher than 10. A. R. Trenka, A pre-commercial OTEC plant--a sum-
mary. Pacific International Center for High Technology
those predicted in other studies [9, 16, 18]. It is thought Research, 18 pp. (1990).
that their more optimistic results are due to slightly 11. F. A. Johnson, A 250 kW closed-cycle land-based ocean
different initial assumptions and the use of simpler thermal energy plant. Proceedings, International Con-
models which do not discount the cash flow of the .ference on Ocean Energy Recovery, ICOER (Ocean
Ener,qy Recovery) (Edited by Hans-Jurgen Krock), pp.
plant over its 30-year life. 247-256 (1989).
12. L. E. Dunbar, Market potential for OTEC in developing
countries. Proceedings, 8th Ocean Eneryy Conference,
Washinyton, U.S.A., pp. 947 956 (1981).
13. R. Cohen, Energy from the ocean. Phil. Trans. R. Soc.
REFERENCES Lond. 307, 405437 (1982).
14. P. Self, Econocrats and the Policy Process : The Politics
I. D. E. Lennard, Ocean thermal energy conversion past and Philosophy of Cost-Benefit Analysis, 212 pp.
progress and future prospects, lEE proceedinys 134, Macmillan, London (1975).
381 391 (1987). 15. D. Pearce, Conserving global natural wealth : economics
2. P. K. Takahashi and A. Trenka, Ocean thermal energy and politics. Polytechnic South West, Plymouth, 31 pp.
conversion: its promise and a total resource system. (1991).
Energy 17(7), 657-668 (1992). 16. L. A. Vega and A. R. Trenka, Near term market poten-
3. Solar Energy Research Institute, The potential of renew- tial for OTEC in the Pacific basin. Pacific International
able energy--an interlaboratory white paper. Appendix Center for High Technology Research, Honolulu, HI
D (Ocean Energy Technologies). Prepared for the Office (1990).
of Policy, Planning and Analysis, U.S. Department of 17. J. G. Caar, The economics and possible financing of the
Energy (1990). two Severn barrages. Symposium on Tidal Power, The
4. G. H. Lavi, Issues in OTEC commercialization. Institution of Civil Engineers, pp. 121-153 (1986).
Energy--Int. J. 5, 551 560 (1980). 18. Anonymous, PICHTR Scientists Reported Near Term
5. CEGB Costs qf Producin9 Electricio'from Nuclear, Coal- 0 TEC Market Potential IOA Newsletter 1, No. 2 (1990).

Potrebbero piacerti anche