Sei sulla pagina 1di 10

Energy Policy 49 (2012) 552–561

Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect

Energy Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/enpol

Consumer responses to time varying prices for electricity


Paul Thorsnes a, John Williams b, Rob Lawson b,n
a
Department of Economics, University of Otago, PO Box 56, Dunedin, New Zealand
b
Department of Marketing, University of Otago, PO Box 56, Dunedin, New Zealand

H I G H L I G H T S

c Seasonal effects in winter.


c High conservation effect from information.
c Higher peak prices no effect on peak use.
c Low off-peak prices encourage less conservation off-peak.

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: We report new experimental evidence of the household response to weekday differentials in peak and
Received 23 November 2011 off-peak electricity prices. The data come from Auckland, New Zealand, where peak residential
Accepted 29 June 2012 electricity consumption occurs in winter for heating. Peak/off-peak price differentials ranged over four
Available online 31 July 2012
randomly selected groups from 1.0 to 3.5. On average, there was no response except in winter.
Keywords: In winter, participant households reduced electricity consumption by at least 10%, took advantage of
Electricity pricing lower off-peak prices but did not respond to the peak price differentials. Response varied with house
Time of use and household size, time spent away from home, and whether water was heated with electricity.
Price elasticity & 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction closely to production costs. At one extreme, the retailer could


vary prices half-hourly in response to variation in wholesale
As in most parts of the world, residential electricity prices in prices and to stress on the distribution system. This ‘dynamic’
New Zealand do not really reflect the variation over time in or ‘real time’ pricing challenges households to monitor prices and
marginal production cost. There are three types of schemes that adjust consumption accordingly. One option is a display mounted
have a time based component. Some suppliers offer seasonal in a prominent place in the home. Another option, given time and
pricing options because production costs are higher in winter due investment, is enabling technology, such as a computer that
to the widespread use of electricity for heating. Also, to take monitors prices and controls appliances. At the other extreme, if
advantage of lower-cost production at night, households have had patterns in electricity demand are fairly regular, the retailer could
the option of installing a second electricity meter usually wired to vary prices daily across a relatively small set of time periods,
a special heater that stores heat at night, and releases it slowly which is commonly referred to as time-of-use (TOU) pricing. The
over the day. In return for a slightly lower price many households simplest gives two prices for peak and off-peak periods.
also allow ‘ripple control’ which allows the electricity supplier This strategy is being actively discussed at both an industry
to switch their water heater off remotely (and without their and a political level in many countries as a means of ‘managing
knowledge) during high-cost peak periods. However, even when demand’. For example, Section 1252 of the 2005 United States
considered together all these schemes amount to small variations Energy Policy Act affirms that ‘‘y time-based pricing and other
on a ‘flat’ retail pricing structure. forms of demand response, whereby consumers are provided
The roll-out of new meters that record electricity consumption with electricity price signals and the ability to benefit by respond-
at half hour intervals provides opportunities to tune prices more ing to them, shall be encouraged’’. This makes of interest the
extent to which households will respond to daily variation
in price. Studies conducted over the last forty years in various
n
Corresponding author. Tel.: þ64 3 479 1100.
places and under various conditions indicate that peak demand
E-mail addresses: paul.thorsnes@otago.ac.nz (P. Thorsnes), is, on average, price inelastic. Nevertheless, even seemingly
john.williams@otago.ac.nz (J. Williams), rob.lawson@otago.ac.nz (R. Lawson). small responses can have significant effects on marginal peak

0301-4215/$ - see front matter & 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2012.06.062
P. Thorsnes et al. / Energy Policy 49 (2012) 552–561 553

production costs, potentially reducing investment in expensive There was, of course, variation in the response to the pricing
peak generation or additional transmission or distribution across the households in each group. All else constant, peak price
capacity. elasticity increased with floor area, household size and outdoor
In this paper we report the results of a time-of-use pricing temperature, and decreased with time spent away from home and
experiment conducted in Auckland, New Zealand. The study has electric water heating. Not surprisingly, those who spent more
at least three novel aspects. First, this study is not concerned time away from home (usually during peak periods) were more
about summer air conditioning. Electricity demand in New likely to take advantage of lower off-peak prices. This suggests
Zealand peaks in winter for heating, rather than in summer for that the average responses would likely have been different if our
cooling. Auckland, the largest urban area in New Zealand, is in the sample houses and households varied more in their character-
relatively mild north (about the latitude of Virginia Beach, istics, in line with the variation in the country over all.
Virginia and Seville, Spain). Mild summer temperatures and The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The next
breezes mean very little air conditioning in summer. Winters, sections briefly summarize the results from existing studies of time-
however, are cool, though not cold, and most heating is done varying prices. After this we describe the sample and experimental
with electricity. Wood is the most common alternative energy setup and then report the results from three sets of analysis of
source. monthly, daily, and half-hour data, respectively. Finally we discuss
With a comprehensive survey of participating households we implications for electricity retailing and complementary govern-
were also able to collect a more extensive range of personal and ment policy.
household data than has been collected in previous TOU experi-
ments. This has enabled the examination of some new variables
to test their influence on peak and off-peak demand. A final 2. Background literature
difference is that our study, with the cooperation of a major New
Zealand electricity retailer was deliberately aimed at the ‘meat of There is a small but established body of literature on the
the market’ as opposed to attempting to be nationally represen- responsiveness of households to changes in the price of electri-
tative. The roll-out of smart meters by geographic area means city. In this literature there are studies that examine TOU pricing
that a nationally representative sample is not possible anyway (e.g., Faruqui and George 2002) and others that examine critical
but the selected area involved prime customers in relatively new period pricing (CPP) (e.g., Matsukawa, 2001; Herter et al., 2006;
housing occupied by somewhat older and relatively high-income Herter, 2007). With TOU pricing plans customers know when and
households. This last factor is important if TOU policies are to be by how much price varies. With CPP, the customer agrees to a
implemented on a voluntary as opposed to mandatory basis. The pricing plan where the retail price rises, usually substantially,
area under consideration in our study would be regarded as a when the wholesale price reaches a critical point. Aigner (1985)
prime target in which to encourage the early adoption of TOU gives a review of early work on TOU experiments. Conclusions
pricing and the residents regarded as more capable of adjusting from the more recent literature on the price elasticity of elec-
lifestyles to suit compared with more deprived neighborhoods, tricity demand can be summarized as follows:
for example.
The study lasted for one year. Each participant household was  Demand is price inelastic: typically, a 100% price change might
assigned randomly to one of four pricing groups. The peak to off- produce around a 20% change in demand (EPRI, 2008). Faruqui
peak price ratio ranged from 1.0, no price differential, to (approxi- and Sergici (2009b) report responses to peak period prices
mately) 1.25, 1.75, and 3.5 (e.g., roughly 28b/kW h peak/ 8b/kW h under a standard TOU pricing system of 2% to 6%, translating to
off peak). We had access to daily peak and off-peak consumption own price elasticities of 0.02 to 0.1. This seems unsurprising:
data and half-hour readings from both the experimental period and electricity prices are typically low enough that electricity
the previous year. We were thus able to conduct differences-in- payments make up only a small portion of the average house-
differences analyses. hold’s budget, and consumers likely perceive electricity as a
Results indicate no response by participants relative to a necessity during peak times. Price elasticities within TOU
control group that was unaware of the experiment, except in schemes seem to increase over time as people are able to
winter when electricity consumption and monthly payments both adjust their lifestyle to suit the scheme. People become both
increase considerably. During winter, the households in the more experienced at managing their life around regularly
experimental groups conserved an average of about 12% relative time-varying electricity prices and also are able to acquire
to households in the control group. This level of conservation is appliances that enable them to control the timing of electricity
surprising. Faruqui et al. (2009a) report that in-home displays of usage (Filippini, 2011).
energy consumption typically encourage conservation of about  Several TOU studies report overall conservation effects in
7%. Thus 12% conservation in this case is relatively large, espe- electricity usage (EPRI, 2008). This may reflect a ‘‘Hawthorne’’
cially given that the information households received consisted effect induced by knowingly participating in an experiment.
only of a set of energy saving tips at the start of the experiment As noted earlier, it may also result from receiving better
and a chart in their monthly bill showing daily peak and off-peak information about electricity consumption.
consumption over the month.  There appears to be considerable variation in sensitivity to
The response to TOU pricing differed between peak and off- electricity prices across segments of the market. Reiss and
peak periods. During peak periods, there was surprisingly no White’s (2008) six year study of the Californian market
variation, on average, across the experimental groups in the indicates that nearly half (44%) of households show no short-
amount of conservation in winter; e.g., those facing a peak price run response to price fluctuations. Households who heat with
of 28b/kW h conserved at roughly the same rate as those facing electricity tend to be more sensitive and higher-income house-
18b/kW h. On average, households in all of the groups appear to holds less sensitive to price. Bernstein and Griffin (2006)
have been taking the steps they were willing to take to conserve, report differences in price elasticities across the regions of
regardless of price. In contrast, those who faced lower offer-peak the United States which they speculated result from variation
prices conserved less; households who faced 8b/kW h off-peak in climate, available substitutes and demographic character-
prices took advantage of the low price by conserving less, on istics Archibald et al. (1982) reports that price elasticities vary
average, than those who faced 18b/kW h. seasonally.
554 P. Thorsnes et al. / Energy Policy 49 (2012) 552–561

 Some studies report estimates of the elasticity of substitution Table 1


between higher-price peak and lower-price off-peak periods. Household composition.
Caves et al. (1984, 1989) report average within day substitu-
Number of people Number of households Percent of sample
tion elasticities of 0.12, but with considerable variation across
households. A later study by Midwest Electricity Systems 1 42 12.7
reports a somewhat larger range in substitution elasticities, 2 116 34.9
0.39 to zero, partially explained by ownership of major 3 60 18.1
4 69 20.8
appliances (Baladi and Herriges, 1998) while a more recent 5 or more 45 13.5
study in California reports large differences between house- Total 332 100.0
holds with and without air-conditioning, a response first
identified by Lillard and Aigner (1984).
233 of the 322 households have lived the majority of their lives in
the city and a further 21 households have moved to the study area
from other parts of New Zealand. Residents in the other 68
3. Experimental design households have moved to the area from a wide variety of
countries with the main origins being China (19), India (10) and
We partnered with Mercury Energy, one of the major New the U.K. (9).
Zealand electricity retailers, to undertake an experiment in TOU Comparing these figures to the New Zealand census data, the
pricing. Mercury was in the process of replacing conventional sample is older, wealthier and with fewer Māori and Pacific Islanders
residential electricity meters with meters that send readings than the national average.
wirelessly every half hour.1 Approximately 4000 meters had been
installed at the time of the study, all in a suburban area to the
south of the Auckland CBD. 4. Experimental setup
Invitations to participate in the study were sent to 1400 of these
4000 households. Recruiting ceased when 400 households had Each of the participant households received two types of
agreed to participate. This was the maximum sample size that the information. Prior to the start of the TOU pricing period, each
company was willing to support over the course of the project. household received a one-page list of tips for conserving energy.
The process began with a face-to-face survey of the member of In addition, the monthly power bill included a simple bar chart
each household who was responsible for managing the electricity where the height of the bar showed total daily power consump-
account. The survey was conducted by professional staff tion and colors indicated the proportion of the total consumed
employed by a market-research company. Data were collected during peak and off-peak periods.
on the characteristics of: The price paid per kilo-watt hour prior to the experiment
varied across participant households. Mercury customers choose
 the house from an array of pricing plans. Some plans are tailored for low
 energy-using appliances electricity users. Some plans trade off a higher fixed daily charge
 household energy behaviors for a lower unit charge. A household can decrease their unit
 household composition and demographics. charge by agreeing to allow the power to their water heater to be
 householder attitudes toward energy and the environment2 switched off remotely, and without their knowledge, during
periods of peak demand. Prices varied from essentially 17b to
21b, with the average and the mode being just over 19b/kW h.
Roughly three-quarters of the households paid either 19.9b or
3.1. Sample characteristics
17.4b/kW h.
Each of the 400 participant households was assigned randomly
Table 1 provides information about household size. Most of the
by Mercury staff to one of four groups:
single-person households were older females while the largest
single type of grouping is married (or partner couples) without
1. Information-only group: these households were interviewed
children. On average, participants in the sample are older (median
and received the initial information sheet and monthly con-
age is in the 50–54 bracket) while the mode lay in the 60–64
sumption chart, but they did not face time-varying prices, so
bracket. They are more affluent than the average New Zealand
the peak/off-peak price ratio equals 1.
household with the median before-tax household income for the
2. Low price differential group: a peak/off-peak price differential
sample falling between $90,000 and $100,000 per annum before tax.
of 4b. That is, peak and off-peak prices equal the household’s
Consistent with the relatively high income, only 62 (18.7%) of
current price plus or minus 2b, respectively.
the households include someone who does not work at least part
3. Medium price differential group: a peak/off-peak price differ-
time. About a third of households (35.5%) have at least two people
ential of 10b.
in full-time paid employment. Across all of the people in all of the
4. Large price differential group: a peak/off-peak price differen-
households, the average time spent away from home on a normal
tial of 20b.
weekday is six hours.
There are few Māori (22) or Pacific Island (12) respondents in
the sample. New Zealanders of European descent constitute by far The experiment started on 1st August 2008 (winter time in the
the largest proportion of the sample (72.1%). Respondents from southern hemisphere) and finished at the end of July 2009. The
peak period was defined as 7 am to 7 pm Monday to Friday. All
other times and public holidays were off peak.
1
The signals from sent from each meter are received using antennas places Of the 400 initial participants, 332 remained in the study through
strategically around the neighbourhoods. If a signal is blocked, the meters store the duration of the trial. Mercury supplied daily peak and off-peak
information temporarily or relay the signal through meters on neighbouring
houses.
electricity consumption and half-hour consumption for each house-
2
The environmental values scale used was the New Environmental Paradigm hold over both the year of the experiment and the previous year.
Scale (NEP) developed by Dunlap et al. (2000). Mercury also supplied similar consumption information for 55
P. Thorsnes et al. / Energy Policy 49 (2012) 552–561 555

Table 2
Determinants of average daily electricity consumption.

Variable Average daily consumption Proportion off-peak

Before During Before During

p b p b p b p b

Month 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 – 0.000 –


Floor area 0.013 0.001 0.002 0.001
Electric water heating 0.002 0.404 0.000 0.611 0.002 0.033
Number of people 0.031 0.066 0.012 0.086
Income (in bands) 0.002 0.678 0.000 0.798
Special health needs 0.025 0.437 0.015 0.535
Hours away from home 0.012  0.028 0.004  0.036 0.000 0.006 0.000 0.006
Environment values 0.011  0.112 0.036  0.103
Pricing plan 0.000 – 0.000 –

‘control’ households from the same suburb who were unaware of the fixed-effects model (sometimes known as least-squares with
the experiment, were not interviewed, and did not receive any dummy variables) cannot estimate the effects of time-invariant
additional information about their consumption. explanatory variables (Baltagi, 2005, p. 13).
Unfortunately, not all of this data was usable. Some of the half- We included a large number of explanatory variables in our
hour and daily data from August through November 2007 had model, each of which had either been found in previous research
been ‘backfilled’ due to technical problems and were unreliable. to be influential on either total use or time of use, or could
Our year-on-year comparisons are consequently restricted to the reasonably be supposed to be so. These variables included
eight months December through July. characteristics of the household (number of people, income
etc.), the dwelling (age, construction, insulation methods) and
the individual who responded to the household survey (age, sex,
5. Year-on-year analysis of monthly averages of daily personal values regarding environmental issues etc.).
consumption Table 2 lists the variables from the household survey that best
explain the variation in the monthly average of daily electricity
Our overall analysis strategy was to account for as much consumption. There are 20 monthly observations for each of the
variation as possible in both (a) overall electricity consumption; 332 participant households. Households in the control group are
and (b) the proportion of consumption at peak times before we not included because they did not complete the household
assessed the impact of TOU pricing. This approach helps to survey. There are two dependent variables: the square root of
alleviate problems due to the allocation into experimental groups daily consumption averaged over the month and the square root
being confounded with pre-existing group differences in electri- of the proportion of daily consumption consumed during the off-
city consumption. The more common approach to analysis of peak period4. A complicating factor emerged in that mean and
experimental data, ANOVA, cannot detect this possibility. We median electricity consumption differ significantly across experi-
start by analyzing observations on the daily household consump- mental groups prior to the experiment. However, the distribu-
tion of the participants in the experiment averaged over each tions in consumption over-lap, and we expect much of the overall
month. Median daily consumption was used instead of total variation to be explained by variation in house and household
consumption to account for missing data. Because we have panel characteristics and season. Because of these pre-existing differ-
data (multiple observations from the same experimental units) ences in consumption between the groups noted above, the
we estimated a linear mixed effects (LME) model with dummy models were estimated separately for data from before and
variables to capture the effects of each household in order to during the experimental period.
accommodate unobserved individual heterogeneity.3 The first seven independent variables listed in Table 2 are fairly
Using notation following Baltagi (2005), the model is: obvious, but a few require explanation. The monthly dummies are,
not surprisingly, highly significant due to the seasonality of elec-
yit ¼ ai þ bi xit þui þ Eit i ¼ 1,. . .,n; t ¼ 1,. . .,T; E½u ¼ 0; E½E ¼ 0 tricity consumption. As expected, average daily consumption
where y is value of the dependent variable in household i at time increases with the size of the house and whether water is heated
t, ai is the mean level of y for household i when all explanatory using electricity. Household characteristics also matter: consump-
variables are zero, x is a vector of explanatory variables and bi tion increases with household size and income and when someone
their associated coefficients for household i. Finally, ui is known as in the house has special health needs that require electrical
the individual error, while Eit is known as the idiosyncratic error. appliance to treat. Not surprisingly, average consumption decreases
The idiosyncratic errors are assumed to be uncorrelated with both when householders spend more weekday time away from home.
the individual errors and the explanatory variables. The LME Of interest is that the estimated coefficients on several of these
approach is required because of the presence of dummy variables variables change during the experimental period. In particular,
that represent each household. If the individual errors are larger estimated coefficients suggest that those with higher
correlated with the bs, the OLS estimator is inconsistent. Hence incomes, more people in the house, and those heating water with
electricity responded relatively little to participation in the
experiment.
3
Specifications of the model include: random coefficients (intercepts and
slopes within household), time specified as a cubic polynomial, correlation of
residuals modeled by AR (1) and heteroscedasticity of residuals modeled by a
4
power function. AR(1) provided the best fit of all alternatives for modeling the The square root is used as a variance-stabilising transform and was selected
residuals, as judged by likelihood ratio tests. Inspection of ACF and PACF plots by the Box-Cox procedure. After transformation, inspection of residual plots
supported using AR(1) as opposed to higher order serial correlation. confirmed that assumptions of OLS modelling were satisfied.
556 P. Thorsnes et al. / Energy Policy 49 (2012) 552–561

The two remaining independent variables are a bit unusual. Table 3


The first indicates that, all else constant, households who profess Summary of results of modelling total and proportional usage.
relatively strong environmental values on average consume less
Dependent Period Comparison GoF GoF Group
electricity. It seems that in this case values translate to behavior (B) (W) effect?
in a significant way. Of interest is that the magnitude of the
coefficient falls during the experiment; those with environmental Average daily consumption Before Control 0.59 0.91 0.781
values consume less, but not quite as much less relative to the Info 0.67 0.90 0.315
During Control 0.52 0.82 0.853
others in the experiment. The conservation effects we report later Info 0.60 0.82 0.396
suggest that it is the others that are changing their behavior to be Proportion of consumption Before Control 0.06 0.78 0.062
more like those that express strong environmental values. off-peak Info 0.24 0.79 0.127
Finally, the pricing plan chosen by the household (i.e., the During Control 0.05 0.64 0.045
Info 0.21 0.64 0.187
tradeoff between the fixed daily charge and the charge per kW h
consumed) correlates strongly with consumption. This seems
unsurprising because we would expect that households choose
their plan based in part on their consumption patterns. That this 6. Seasonal variation in peak and off-peak consumption
comes out in the statistics, however, indicates that households are
indeed sensitive to the differences in the pricing plans. The apparent lack of response to TOU pricing reported in the
The right-hand side of the table indicates that surprisingly few of previous section is surprising, but the aggregation may hide a
the variables collected in the survey explain the cross-sectional seasonal response. In addition, the results reported above may be
variation in the proportion of the daily consumption consumed off- influenced by unobserved house or household characteristics. We
peak. Not surprisingly, those who spend less time at home tend to can treat the problem of unobserved variables by comparing daily
consume a higher proportion their energy off-peak. Of potential consumption for each household from the year before the
interest is that off-peak water heating is significant only during the experiment with consumption during the experiment. That is,
experiment. Some households may have been able to restrict water we conduct a differences-in-differences analysis: we estimate the
heating to take advantage of lower off-peak prices. average differences across each experimental and control group in
Table 3 provides goodness of fit measures for the models the year-to-year differences in each household’s electricity con-
above in addition to other models of interest, and tests for sumption during peak and off-peak periods. Specifically we
differences across in groups. Two goodness-of-fit (GoF) measures estimate the following equation using OLS:
are distinguished for each model. The first, GoF (B), measures the
proportion of cross-sectional variation explained by the model, X
4 X
4
lnðQ i Þ ¼ a þ bg dGg þ j dTOU þ rg dTOU  dGg þ g temp þ e
i.e., the differences across households averaged over time. The g¼1 g¼1
average daily consumption models fit fairly well for a cross- ð1Þ
sectional analysis and are as good as other similar estimates, for
example the study of domestic Californian consumption reported where Qi is the quantity of electricity consumed each day during
by NETL (2009). Note that the fit for the control sample is the peak or off-peak period by household i. (Taking the natural log
relatively low as we lack explanatory variables taken from the of consumption generates estimates of the coefficients that are
household survey. Not surprisingly, the fit of the models explain- interpretable as percentage changes.) a is a constant term that is
ing cross-sectional variation in the proportion of consumption the average daily peak or off-peak consumption of the households
off-peak is smaller. in the control group. dGg is a dummy variable that equals 1 if the
The second goodness-of-fit measure, GoF (W), measures the household is in one of the experimental groups. For example, if
proportion of time series variation explained by the model, i.e., g¼1, then the household is in the information-only group. The
the variation within each household from month to month. In this coefficients bg measure the difference in the average daily con-
case the goodness of fit measures are relatively high because most sumption of the households in each experimental group from that
of the time series variation is seasonal and is easily captured by of the control group. dTOU is a ‘dummy’ variable that equals 1 if
the time variable. the day is in 2009, i.e., during the TOU pricing period. The
The right-hand column labeled ‘‘Group Effect’’ lists the estimated coefficient j measures the average percentage differ-
p-values for the differential effect of being in one of the groups ence in control-group consumption in 2009, under TOU pricing,
exposed to TOU pricing (i.e., in one of the low, medium, or high relative to that in the same period in 2008. We expect j to be
price differential groups). The row labeled ‘Control’ compares all positive in winter because the winter of 2009 was colder than the
the experimental groups against the control group and the row winter of 2008. dTOU  dGg interacts dTOU with a dummy that
labeled ‘info’ compares the groups with a pricing treatment equals 1 if the household is in each of the four sample groups.
against the information only group. The effects should not be Thus r1, r2, r3, and r4 measure the average percent changes from
significant before the experimental period, and this is achieved 2008 in consumption by the households in each experimental
with the possible exception of the comparison to the control group relative to that of the households in the control group.
group for the proportion of off-on peak usage (p¼.062). Surpris- These are the estimates of interest. temp is the maximum for peak
ingly, we would expect to see more significant differences or minimum for off-peak daily temperature, so the estimate of g
between groups during the experiment, and that is not the measures the overall average percentage effect on consumption of
generally the case, though the significant of the difference a one degree change in temperature. e is the ‘error term’. It
between the control group and the experimental groups becomes represents all of the variation in household consumption not
slightly more significant during the experimental period. It should explained by the variation in temperature, the group, or the year.
be borne in mind that the models explaining the variation in To detect seasonal effects we run a series of regressions on six
control group consumption contain fewer explanatory variables weeks of weekday observations of each household’s consumption.
(mainly just month and pricing plan). The first regression uses data from late summer when vacation
The interpretation is that there is no significant annual impact season has ended. Each subsequent regression starts one day
of TOU pricing on either average electricity consumed or on the later, with the last of the 170 regressions centered on a day in
average proportion of daily consumption consumed off-peak. mid-winter (early July). We then plot each of the four coefficients
P. Thorsnes et al. / Energy Policy 49 (2012) 552–561 557

15.00%

10.00%

5.00%

0.00%

21-Jan
28-Jan
4-Feb
11-Feb
18-Feb
25-Feb

6-May
13-May
20-May
27-May
3-Jun
10-Jun
17-Jun
24-Jun
1-Jul
8-Jul
4-Mar
11-Mar
18-Mar
25-Mar
1-Apr
8-Apr
15-Apr
22-Apr
29-Apr
-5.00%

-10.00%

-15.00%

-20.00%

-25.00%

-30.00%
Info-only Low Medium High
-35.00%

Fig. 1. Moving six-week average % difference from control in weekday peak consumption.

on the dTOU  dGg interaction variable for every regression. Thus, There are several house characteristics that might influence
each of the plots shown consists of a series of 170 six-week the percentage winter-time response in consumption to a change
moving-average estimates of the percent difference in each in price. In this relatively short-run setting, we expect the
experimental group’s year-to-year consumption relative to that percentage response to higher prices to be smaller in the presence
of the control group.5 of house characteristics that encourage higher overall consump-
Figs. 1 and 2 show the results of most interest. Fig. 1 shows tion. For example, we would expect a lower percentage response
how the weekday peak-period consumption of each of the to higher prices in larger houses and in houses with electric water
experimental groups differs from that of the control group from heating. Another key characteristic of New Zealand houses is that
summer to winter. The left side of the graph, which covers very few were built with any thermal insulation before insulation
February into May, indicates little systematic response to the requirements were introduced in 1978. Ceiling insulation has
TOU pricing experiment in late summer and autumn.6 The been retro-fitted in most of these houses, but they remain
standard errors vary slightly around 3%, so differences between relatively poorly insulated. Electricity consumption in these
group averages are largely insignificant.7 houses tends to be higher in winter, so we expect a smaller
The abrupt drop in all of the curves in May corresponds to the percentage response to higher winter prices. Another unusual
onset of winter in the southern hemisphere and shows a sig- characteristic of New Zealand houses is that central heating is
nificant conservation response to participation in the experiment. very rare, 2.5% in our sample. Indeed, most households heat with
Higher electric bills apparently encouraged significant conserva- relatively small resistance heaters. More recently, more efficient
tion in winter. There is surprisingly no statistical difference across heat pumps have been become popular, with about 11% of our
groups in the extent of conservation. Indeed, the group facing the sample heating with a heat pump. We would expect the greater
highest peak prices appears to have conserved the least, though efficiency of these heat pumps to discourage a strong response to
the difference from the information-only group is not statistically higher peak prices.
significant. There also are several common household characteristics that
Fig. 2 similarly shows relative changes in year-on-year weekday seem likely to affect response to higher peak prices. We expect
off-peak consumption relative to control. On average, each of the higher income households to respond less to higher prices
experimental groups again conserves relative to control. Standard because most of the household services that require electricity
errors again vary around 3%, so off-peak conservation in summer and to produce are probably income normal. A larger number of
autumn is border-line significant. Again, conservation grows in people in the household implies a lower per-capita income, and
percentage terms in winter; larger winter-time bills apparently should perhaps have the opposite effect. Households who spend
encourage more effort at conservation, averaging about 15% relative more time away from home on weekdays seem also likely to
to Control. In contrast to peak-period consumption, and more in line respond less to higher peak prices, in part because they may have
with expectations, the groups that experience lower off-peak prices more opportunity to adjust their work schedule to avoid peak
respond by conserving less than those in the Information-only group. times at home, and in part because they consume relatively little
The year-on-year responses of individual households in during peak (note that household size and hours away from home
each group not surprisingly vary from the averages shown in are positively correlated with income).
the figures above. We would expect this variation to depend We expect that many of these house and household character-
systematically on house and household characteristics, at least in istics are likely to lead to the opposite effects off-peak, i.e., to a larger
winter. response to lower prices. For example, higher income households
seem less likely to conserve in response to high peak prices and
more likely to take advantage of low off-peak prices. And we expect
5
The estimated coefficients and standard errors for the first six weeks a lower percentage response to price the lower the outdoor
regression and the last weeks regression are reported in the appendix.
6
The previous summer months also showed no difference to control and have
temperature (in part because overall consumption is higher).
not been plotted for the sake of clarity in the figure. We estimate the following equation to obtain the average
7
Showing 95% confidence intervals clutters the diagrams excessively. effects of one unit changes in house and household characteristics
558 P. Thorsnes et al. / Energy Policy 49 (2012) 552–561

5.00%

0.00%

13-May
20-May
27-May
11-Feb
18-Feb
25-Feb
21-Jan
28-Jan

11-Mar
18-Mar
25-Mar

10-Jun
17-Jun
24-Jun
15-Apr
22-Apr
29-Apr
6-May
4-Feb

4-Mar

3-Jun
1-Apr
8-Apr

1-Jul
8-Jul
-5.00%

-10.00%

-15.00%

-20.00%

-25.00%

Info-only Low Medium High


-30.00%

Fig. 2. Moving six-week average difference from control in weekday off-peak consumption.

on peak and off-peak price elasticities:


Table 4
lnQ i ¼ a þ blnPi þ j lnPi  X i þ g dHi þ e ð2Þ Effects on elasticities of each one unit change in house and house characteristics.

in this case, Qi is weekday peak (or off-peak) consumption by Price elasticity Substitution
household i who faces price, Pi. Xi is a vector of house and elasticity
household characteristics. The term dHi is a dummy variable for
Peak Off peak
each household, which produced ‘fixed-effects’ estimates. The
estimates of j on the price/household characteristic interaction Ln Price (peak, off-peak, or ratio)  0.371  0.0902  0.453
terms are reported in Table 4. (0.074) (0.077) (0.048)
The average effects of the same house and household char- Ln Price  floor area (10 m2) 0.0801 0.0127 0.0114
(0.014) (0.0034) (0.0019)
acteristics on the substitution elasticity are estimated using the
Ln Price  built pre-1980 0.586  0.381  0.00954
following (similar) equation: (0.093) (0.066) (0.038)
Ln Price  heat pump 0.0289  0.156  0.0832
Qp Pp Pp
ln ¼ a þ bln þ jln  X þ g dHi þ e ð3Þ (0.0288) (0.047) (0.026)
Q op Pop P op Ln Price  electric hot water 0.261 0.0386 0.146
(0.047) (0.036) (0.020)
Again, the estimates of j are reported in the table. The average Ln Price  household income 0.0311  0.0183 0.0115
price and substitution elasticities reported in the context of ($10,000s) (0.0064) (0.0046) (0.0026)
Figs. 1 and 2 were estimated using similar equations, but with Ln price  hours away from home  0.0345 0.0222  0.00553
the interaction terms omitted. (0.0057) (0.0041) (0.0023)
Ln price  household size  0.0297  0.0462  0.0448
The data consist of observations on consumption of the house- (0.016) (0.013) (0.0073)
holds in the experimental groups on non-holiday week days in Ln price  temperature  0.00327  0.00709 0.0117
June and July (winter) in both 2008 and 2009. The control group (0.00042) (0.00038) (0.0024)
households are excluded because they did not complete the N 17,775 18,201 17,063
household survey, and we therefore lack observations on house
and household characteristics. Note that the estimates are similar
if we restrict the sample to observations in June and July of 2009,
during the TOU experiment. The substitution elasticities in the right-hand column of
Standard errors appear in parentheses, bold indicates signifi- Table 4 are broadly consistent with the price elasticities.
cance at the 5% level. Numbers of observations vary due to
occasional errors in recording of data.
The left-hand column of numbers shows estimates of the 7. Response to the peak/off-peak boundary
influence on peak price elasticity of house and household char-
acteristics. All of the coefficients have signs and magnitudes In this section we take advantage of the half-hour readings to
consistent with expectations, though those on heat pump and look more closely at changes in the pattern of consumption across
household size are insignificant. The middle column shows the 7 pm peak/off-peak time boundary. Half-hour residential
similar estimates for off-peak. As expected, many of the signs consumption peaks at about 6:30 pm. TOU pricing should, in
are opposite those for peak; the households least responsive to theory, encourage a drop in consumption prior to and a rise in
higher prices tend to be the most responsive to lower prices. This consumption after 7 pm.
seems consistent in that these households are relatively keen to To investigate, we look at electricity consumption at half-hour
enjoy the household services produced with electricity. intervals from 4:00 pm to 10:30 pm on twenty consecutive
As expected, the household response to price falls as tempera- weekdays in July 2008 (prior to TOU pricing) and the correspond-
ture rises and overall expenditure on electricity decreases. ing weekdays in July 2009 (during TOU pricing). Our estimating
P. Thorsnes et al. / Energy Policy 49 (2012) 552–561 559

8%  TOU pricing appears to have no statistically significant effect


on average daily electricity consumption or, surprisingly, on
6%
on-peak consumption when averaged over the entire year.
4%  Significant peak-period conservation in winter across all experi-
mental groups relative to the control group. Winter peak con-
2%
servation averages in the range of 10–15%. This is consistent with
0% existing reports of seasonality in response rates.
 No significant variation in peak conservation with price across
4:00

4:30

5:00

5:30

6:00

6:30

7:00

7:30

8:00

8:30

9:00

9:30

10:00

10:30
-2% experimental groups; peak price elasticity of demand is very
low.
-4%
 Similar levels of off-peak conservation, but off-peak conserva-
-6% tion does vary with price; households on average took advan-
tage of lower off-peak prices.
-8%
 Variation in response around the peak/off-peak boundary,
Fig. 3. Average year-on-year % change in daily evening-peak consumption. with a relatively large average increase in consumption off-
peak.
 Response to price varies with the floor area of the house,
equation measures the average percentage difference in con- household income, household size, the amount of time the
sumption during TOU pricing in 2009 from that in 2008 in each household spends away from home and whether the house-
half hour of the evening peak. We expect these differentials to be hold heats water with electricity.
negative prior to the 7:00 pm price change (households use less
during the high-priced peak period), and positive after (house- Of interest is the extent of winter-time conservation. Overall
holds take advantage of lower prices off peak). demand peaks in winter, so a drop of 10–15% could significantly
The results are shown in Fig. 3. The figure indicates precisely decrease stress on the supply system. This conservation could
the expected pattern of load shifting in response to TOU pricing: result from the rather modest and low-cost information provided
consumption was lower in 2009 relative to 2008 prior to and to participant households, or it might be the result of a so called
higher after 7:00 o’clock (standard errors are about 3%). Relevant ‘Hawthorne’ effect, a response that occurs simply as a reaction to
is that that all three groups with a price differential respond participating in the experiment. While we are in the usual
similarly. The magnitude of the price differential did not affect the situation of not being able to give a definitive answer to this
size of the shift. Again, the absolute magnitude of the price dilemma we do know that recent reevaluations of Hawthorne
response is modest, but meaningful; consumption increased by effects show that they while they seem unpredictable they are
an average of about 6% relative to the 6:30 peak. usually quite small (Merrett, 2007). Also, the effects we detect are
We also conducted a similar analysis of half-hour data around occurring nearly a year after the onset of the experiment, a lag
the morning off-peak/on-peak price boundary. Here the pattern of long enough to expect Hawthorne effects to have dissipated.
changes around the morning boundary is less tidy, but there is a From a policy perspective, the information conventionally pro-
significant 7% drop in consumption between 7:00 and 7:30, again vided to households with regard to electricity prices, costs and
indicating a significant and meaningful response to higher peak consumption seems remarkably limited. The typical monthly bill
prices. provides essentially no information about daily consumption pat-
terns. All households know is that they consume more in winter (as
evidenced by the larger bill). The additional information provided to
8. Conclusions and implications these participant households costs little to supply (given half-hour
meter readings): a simple bar chart showing peak and off-peak
To summarize, Mercury Energy recruited 400 households to consumption each day of the month. Yet this modest amount of
participate in an experiment in time-of-use pricing. The sample extremely low-cost information appears to have encouraged sig-
households opted-in to the experiment. The demographic char- nificant conservation during the months of most stress on the
acteristics of the sample households are not nationally represen- supply system. This seems likely to represent ‘low-hanging fruit’;
tative: they are on average older, wealthier, and live in better households who have not given much thought to electricity con-
insulated houses. Each sample household received a list of sumption that does not demand a large part of their household
energy-conservation tips and a chart in their monthly bill show- budget apparently give it some thought.
ing daily peak and off-peak consumption. Peak to off-peak price A surprise is that substantial percentage variation in peak
ratios varied from 1.0 (no differential) to about 3.5, with the prices (from 18b to 28b/kW h) has no effect, on average, across
average of the peak and off-peak prices equal to the non-TOU participant groups. This appears to suggest that TOU pricing is
price (so average peak price ranged from 18 to 28b/kW h and off- ineffective as a demand management instrument. To understand
peak price ranged from 8 to 18b/kW h). The control group consider the situation of a typical sample household in winter. To
consists of households chosen at random from the same neigh- keep the arithmetic simple, but still relevant, assume that prior to
borhood who had no knowledge of the experiment. The experi- the experiment an individual household might have paid $200 for
ment ran for one year, beginning in mid-winter. energy (excluding the fixed daily charge) per winter month at
With respect to effect of the experimental conditions on 20b/kW h and consumed 600 kW h during peak ($120 total) and
electricity consumption, analysis of the data indicates: 400 off-peak ($80). Next assume that participation in the experi-
ment combined with better information encouraged peak con-
 Variation in average daily electricity consumption is explained servation of 10% (the low-hanging fruit). If peak price during the
by house and household characteristics, as expected, though experiment is 30b/kW h, then the peak bill rises to $162/month.
we largely fail to explain variation in the proportion of If the household takes advantage of the 10b/kW h off-peak price
electricity consumed off-peak. Of interest is that households by not conserving at all (or, more likely, by conserving on low-
who profess environmental values on average consume less value consumption – the low-hanging fruit – and enjoying
electricity, other characteristics held constant. additional high-value consumption), then the off-peak bill falls
560 P. Thorsnes et al. / Energy Policy 49 (2012) 552–561

to $40/month, for a total of $202/month, essentially no change in Table A1


the monthly bill. Sample six-week average % difference from control in weekday consumption.
While our results indicate very modest responses to our TOU
Peak Off-peak
pricing experiment we do not believe that it is the end of the
story. Our experiment was relatively short and those who were Info-only 0.201 (0.0226) 0.111 (0.0232)
inclined to economize did what they could regardless of the price Low 0.518 (0.0225) 0.418 (0.0231)
differential. Existing evidence indicates that price elasticities Medium  0.122 (0.0221)  0.0616 (0.0227)
m  0.135 (0.0222)  0.230 (0.0228)
grow over time. If the household had committed to this pricing dTOU 0.131 (0.0251) 0.120 (0.0257)
plan, over time one would expect to see alterations in both dTOU  info-only  0.140 (0.0316)  0.139 (0.0323)
behavior – such as changes in work schedules – and investments dTOU  medium  0.0951  (0.0308)  0.111 (0.0316)
in technology – such as more energy-efficient appliances dTOU  low  0.124 (0.0314)  0.0888 (0.0322)
dTOU  high  0.105 (0.0310)  0.0677 (0.0318)
equipped with timers – that help the household avoid relatively
Temp at 7 pm/am  0.00938 (0.00258)  0.0222 (0.00263)
high peak prices. As noted earlier, we cannot and would not want Constant 2.474 (0.0355) 2.604 (0.0364)
to try to generalize our findings to the country as a whole. As a N 16,962 16,989
demand management technique, time-of-use pricing could be
introduced as a market led product that could be developed to
appeal to a segment of the population, or it could be introduced
on a compulsory basis. The political complexion of New Zealand The estimates on the variable dTOU represent the average
currently suggests that the former is more realistic than the latter percent difference in consumption by households in the control
and would avoid issues around the social consequences of forcing group in 2009 relative to 2008. Consumption rose significantly in
change upon consumers who may lack the ability to respond to 2009 due to lower average winter temperatures.
time-varying prices. In that context generalisabilty to the total The coefficients on the four interaction terms are of most
population is not an issue and our sample is likely to be interest. They represent the average percent difference from
representative of the segment that is the prime target for time- control in the average year-on-year difference consumption. All
of-use pricing options by retailers. of the coefficients are negative and significant, indicating con-
Of interest is the large variance across the sample in when servation during the experiment relative to control. The extent of
households consume electricity. We had a singular lack of success conservation during the peak period does not vary significantly
in explaining this compared to overall use. When averaged our across the three groups; the groups facing higher peak prices do
sample did yield the recognized pattern of diurnal peaks in the not conserve more than those facing lower peak prices. The extent
morning and evening with the expected seasonal change from of conservation does vary off-peak; lower prices encourage less
summer to winter. However, examining individual households conservation, as might be expected.
reveals hardly a single dwelling that conforms closely to the The coefficients on temperature are negative, as expected:
aggregated pattern. There is seemingly little uniformity in the consumption decreases as temperature increases.
way people live, even in a fairly modern and homogeneous The number of observations differs slightly due to omissions of
Auckland suburb. This is a feature that reinforces the point made observations flagged by the retailer as unreliable (due to technical
in the previous paragraph that as a policy instrument TOU pricing problems).
could be politically difficult to implement in a uniform way across The dependent variable is the natural log of weekday peak
a whole population, and certainly research is needed to better or off-peak electricity consumption. Standard errors appear in
understand the influences of electricity usage by time of day. parentheses. Observations come from the six weeks prior
to the end of July (i.e., correspond to the last data point in
Figs. 1 and 2).

Appendix 1. Sample of results from estimation of Eq. (1)


References
Table A1 shows the results of the last of the 170 regressions
used to build Figs. 1 and 2. The left-hand column of numbers Aigner, D., 1985. The Residential Electricity Time-of-Use Pricing Experiments:
consists of the results from estimating Eq. (1) using observations What Have We Learned? in Social Experimentation, Jerry A. Hausman and
on non-holiday weekday peak consumption in the six weeks to David A. Wise, Eds. The University of Chicago Press and National Bureau of
Economic Research, 11–54. Retrieved from /http://www.nber.org/chapters/
the end of July in 2008 (before the experiment) and 2009 (during c8372S.
the experiment). The right-hand column reports the same thing Archibald, R.B., Finifter, D.H., Moody, C.E., 1982. Seasonal variation in residential
using observations on off-peak consumption. electricity time-of-use pricing experiments: evidence from survey data.
Applied Economics 14 (2), 167–181.
The estimates for the first four variables in the left-hand column Baladi, S.M., Herriges, J., 1998. Residential response to voluntary time-of-use
represent the average percent difference in each experimental group electricity rates. Resource and Energy Economics 20 (3), 225–244.
average consumption from control in 2008. Average consumption Baltagi, B.H., 2005. Econometric Analysis of Panel Data, 3rd Ed John Wiley & Sons,
Chichester.
levels clearly varied across the groups: households in the info-only Bernstein, M., Griffin, J., 2006. Regional Differences in the Price-Elasticity of
and low-price differential groups consumed more, on average, and Demand for Energy. National Renewable Energy Laboratory. Retrieved from
households in the low and medium-price differential groups con- /http://www.nrel.gov/docs/fy06osti/39512.pdfS.
Caves, D., Christensen, L., 1984. Consistency of residential consumer response in
sumed less, on average, than households in the control group. These time-of-use pricing experiments. Journal of Econometrics 26 (1-2), 179–203.
differences may suggest non-random allocation of households to Caves, D., Heririges, J., Kuester, K., 1989. Load shifting under voluntary residential
groups, or it may simply reflect an unusual outcome of a random time-of-use rates. The Energy Journal 10 (4), 83–99.
Dunlap, R.E., Van Liere, K.D., Mertig, A.G., Jones, R.E., 2000. Measuring endorse-
process. Retailer staff allocated households to groups, reportedly
ment of the new environmental paradigm: a revised NEP scale. Journal of
using a random process (Excel random number generator). As a Social Issues 456 (3) 425-422.
practical matter, the distributions in daily consumption and in house EPRI (2008) Price Elasticity of Demand for Electricity: A Primer and Synthesis,
and householder characteristics across groups largely over-lap. The Electric Electricity Research Institute, January. Retrieved from /http://my.epri.
com/portal/server.pt?Abstract_id=000000000001016264S.
differences-in-differences approach treats issues with variation in Faruqui, A., George, S.S., 2002. The value of dynamic pricing in mass markets. The
characteristics across groups. Electricity Journal 15 (6), 45–55, July.
P. Thorsnes et al. / Energy Policy 49 (2012) 552–561 561

Faruqui, A., Hledik, R., Tsoukalis, J., 2009a. The power of dynamic pricing. The Lillard, L.A., Aigner, D.J., 1984. Time-of-day electricity consumption response to
Electricity Journal 22 (3), 42–56, April. temperature and the ownership of air conditioning appliances. Journal of
Faruqui, A., Sergici, S. 2009b. Hosehold Response to Dynamic Pricing of Business and Economic Statistics 2 (1), 40–53.
Electricity—A Survey of Experimental Evidence. The Brattle Group. Retrieved Matsukawa, I., 2001. Household response to optional peak-load pricing of
from /http://www.science.smith.edu/  jcardell/Readings/uGrid/House%20De electricity. Journal of Regulatory Economics 20 (3), 249–261.
mandResp%20Experience.pdfS. Merrett, F., 2007. Reflections on the Hawthorne effect. Educational Psychology 26
Filippini, M., 2011. Short- and long-run time-of-use price elasticities in Swiss (1), 143–146.
residential electricity demand. Energy Policy 39 (10), 5811–5817. NETL (2009) An Investigation into California’s Residential Electricity Consumption,
Herter, K., McAuliffe, P., Rosenfeld, A., 2006. An exploratory analysis of California D DOE/NETL, 2009/1371. Downloaded from /http://www.netl.doe.gov/ener
residential customer response to critical peak pricing of electricity. Energy 32 gy-analyses/pubs/CA_US_elec_consumption_FINAL_July-29-2009.pdfS on 18th
(1), 25–34. September 2011.
Herter, K., 2007. Residential implementation of critical-peak pricing of electricity. Reiss, P.C., White, M.W., 2008. What changes energy consumption? prices and
Energy Policy 35 (4), 2121–2130. public pressure. The RAND Journal of Economics 38 (3), 636–663.

Potrebbero piacerti anche