Sei sulla pagina 1di 25

France: unemployment, a deep-

rooted problem
Hélène Baudchon

France is plagued by three structural problems – different remedies currently being implemented, and in
chronically high unemployment, eroding part three, we will examine some of the solutions that
competitiveness and fiscal imbalances – that are now have not been tried yet. By reviewing the main
thoroughly entangled. Unemployment is undoubtedly the characteristics and reasons behind unemployment in
longest standing and most deeply enrooted of the three. France, and by highlighting the measures that have
Plus, the jobless rate is a key indicator of an economy’s been introduced recently, our goal is to provide a better
health, which is fairly poor as far as France is understanding of the problem, the adequacy of current
concerned. Special attention is being paid to this solutions and to explore additional changes that are still
indicator, since it is almost the only gauge that will be needed.
used to measure the economic recovery, as well as the In brief, our overview of the troubles of the French
success of the government’s current supply-side policy. job market shows that since the mid-1980s the jobless
In other words, there will be no true economic recovery rate has fluctuated around 9% on average. This sole
until the jobless rate begins to trend downwards. figure reveals the extent of the problem. Unemployment
This key indicator was given even more is chronically high. Among other characteristics, we note
importance when French president François Hollande, the high level among youth, low-skilled workers and
in a speech in early September 2012, promised to seniors; the long duration of unemployment, and the
reverse the unemployment curve, representing the high level of underemployment, which is nearly double
number of jobseekers registered with the national the conventional unemployment rate. The French labour
employment office (Pôle emploi), by September 2013. market can also be characterised by its duality, with
Yet the curve was not reversed in 2013, nor even by precarious jobs on the one hand and stable employment
the end of 2014. Despite this setback, the president on the other. The mismatching of labour supply and
pushed expectations to high levels after announcing demand and imperfect wage adjustments with regard to
that he would not seek re-election in 2017 if the French unemployment rate are two other indicators
unemployment had not begun to fall by then. The most of France’s malfunctioning labour market.
likely scenario is that this unemployment decline will It is also important to note that these rigidity factors
have begun by then. But this does not mean that are interdependent: precarious employment reduces the
France will have won the battle against mass chances for adequate training, and the lack of training is
unemployment. That will take much longer to assess, a source of precariousness. The same can be said for
and to achieve this goal, more reforms will be needed the relative inertia and high cost of labour and job
than those introduced so far. protection, notably for low skilled workers. All of this
Mass unemployment is no easy problem to solve, shows the extent to which the numerous roots of
otherwise we would not be fighting this plague so unemployment are deeply embedded and intertwined.
assiduously, especially considering all the measures Clearly there is no single, miracle cure for the problem.
that have been tried so far. In the first part of this article, To resolve mass unemployment, it is not enough to
we will show why mass unemployment is such a hard simply reduce the cost of labour, for example.
nut to crack, by looking at the scope of unemployment Unemployment is a systemic problem that requires a
and its numerous aspects. In part two, we will look at the systemic response.

February 2015 Conjoncture 3


The measures currently being implemented address 1970s during the two oil shocks and the rapid surge in
several aspects of the problem at the same time, in a unemployment, which rose from 3% in early 1975 to 8%
generally appropriate manner. They are designed to ten years later (data for mainland France, for which
inject greater flexicurity into the job market; to provide there is long-term historical series). Thereafter, the
better job insertion and employability of youth, low jobless rate in mainland France never fell significantly
skilled workers, seniors and the unemployed, notably below 8% for any real length of time (see chart 1).
the long-term unemployed; and to strengthen incentives
to return to work and to foster growth in general. France: Unemployment rate
Although progress is clearly being made, these
measures do not seem to be bold enough to come to 12 %
grips with mass unemployment. With its step-by-step 11
10
approach, the government is pursuing smooth reforms, 9
1985-2014 average

but they do not go deeply enough. What more can be 8


done to fight unemployment? One response is to push 7
existing reforms even further, notably in terms of 6

flexicurity, to reduce the duality of the job market. For


5 Mainland France France
4
example, there is still ample room to develop the internal 3
flexibility of HR management; to lower the cost of 2
employment protection by reducing the legal insecurity 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015

companies face during redundancy procedures; to Chart 1 Source: INSEE

improve the performance of job training programmes;


France: Structural unemployment rate
and to optimise the unemployment insurance system.
Strengthening existing measures does not mean that
14 %
new measures cannot be introduced. Several solutions
are often mentioned but have not been tested yet, 12

notably the simplification of workforce thresholds, the 10


easing of the 35-hour workweek and a reform of the 8
minimum wage. We welcome current efforts to deal with 6 Observed unemployment
the first of these three politically and economically 4
sensitive issues. 2
Structural unemployment

0
1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015

Overview of the problem Chart 2 Source: European Commission (AMECO)

France is confronted with high, chronic


Let us begin by making a broad assessment of the unemployment. It is experiencing what is known in
situation, focusing on indicators that illustrate the depth economics as hysteresis, which is to say a kind of
of the unemployment problem and the most frequently lagging effect or memory in which high levels of
identified shortcomings of the French labour market. unemployment tend to be perpetuated, increasing the
structural unemployment rate (see chart 2). More simply
Unemployment by the numbers, major trends and put, unemployment breeds unemployment. This
general characteristics contributes to the small gap between observed
unemployment and the estimated structural
Since the mid-1980s, the unemployment rate in unemployment rate. For the most part, French
France has fluctuated within a corridor ranging between unemployment seems to be structural by nature.
a low of 7% and a high of 10.5% of the labour force, with Yet the French unemployment rate has not only risen.
an average for the period of roughly 9% 1 . The mid- It has experienced two distinct phases of decline, from
1980s was not chosen as a random benchmark: it late 1999 to mid-2001, and again just a few years later,
marks the emergence of mass unemployment in France. between 2006 and 2008. Both periods correspond to the
To be more exact, the expression was first coined in the end of cyclical upturns after years of strong growth. In

February 2015 Conjoncture 4


early 2008, the unemployment rate in mainland France lags far behind the German benchmark of 67%. Yet this
even fell below 7% for the first time since the early 1980s. improvement must be kept in perspective, given the
Yet the Great Recession of 2008-2009 drove concomitant increase in the jobless rate for the over 49
unemployment back up again, by about 2.5 points. The age group, and the decline in the employment rate for
brief economic rally of 2010 failed to make up for lost youth (28% in 2014 down from 31% in 2009). Here
ground. Unemployment declined by only half a point again, the crisis is partly to blame: young workers
before rising again as of mid-2011, and the French lacking experience are more sensitive to cyclical
economy has been mired in an extended phase of downturns than other age groups. Moreover, in a
stagnation ever since. In late 2014, unemployment sluggish job market with only a limited number of job
approached 10.5%, and it is highly likely that it will creations, the problems of youth insertion in the job
continue to rise in 2015. It is hard to foresee a sharp market are only compounded by the extended working
decline in unemployment anytime soon, and the return to years of seniors, which means that fewer posts open up,
full employment, estimated at between 5% and 6%, especially when job profile correspond to both youth and
seems to be an even more distant prospect. seniors.
As to the main characteristics of French
unemployment, the most prominent one is that it is France: one positive trend and three negative ones
concentrated primarily on youth, low-skilled workers and
seniors. The situation is particularly tough for those who Employment and jobless rates Employment and jobless rates
accumulate several of these attributes. The category of 60
for the 50-64 age group (%)
10 35
for the 15-24 age group (%)
30

youth with little or no qualifications has been particularly


Employment Employment
Unemployment Unemployment
hard hit 2. The unemployment rate in the 15-24 age group
reached 24% in 2013. This is similar to the eurozone
25

average (which has an upward bias due to the troubles in 55 5 30

the southern European countries), and is much higher than 20

the OECD average of 16%. Germany is in a whole different


league with a youth jobless rate of only 8% (only Japan has
a lower rate, at 7%) 3. The unemployment rate for youth
50 0 25 15
2003 2007 2011 2015 2003 2007 2011 2015

without a diploma was close to 14% in France in 2012 (near Chart 3 Source: INSEE
the OECD average), but was only 5% for the most highly
educated segment. The unemployment rate for seniors (55- Another key characteristic of French unemployment
64 age group) was 7% in France in 2013, compared to an is the high number of long-term unemployed.
OECD average of 5.6%. Unemployment is considered to be long term when an
We can also see that since 2008, the unemployment individual has been without any work for a period of
rate for the over 49 age group has increased as much as more than 12 consecutive months. In France, the
total unemployment in mainland France. During past percentage of long-term unemployed is now very high
recessions, in 1974-1975 and in 1993, unemployment did at 40%, which is 5 points higher than the OECD
not rise as quickly in this age group as the total average. According to statistics from Pôle emploi, the
unemployment rate. This age group is less resilient today category of job seekers who have not worked for more
than in the past in part because of the severity of the 2008- than a year as a share of total job seekers was roughly
2009 recession and the protracted period of stagnation that the same, at 43% at year-end 2014. This figure can be
has followed. Yet it is also due to the pension reform of broken down as follows: 20% have been registered for
2010, which resulted in seniors remaining in the active 1 to 2 years, 10% for 2-3 years and 13% for more than
population for a longer period, be they employed or three years. This is the highest level since 1996, when
unemployed. the series began. The sharp increase in the
As a result of pensions’ reforms, the employment percentage of long-term unemployed since 2009 is
rate 4 for the 55-64 age group increased significantly, even more alarming considering that is was then 30%.
from 39% in 2009 to 47% in 2014. This was the Moreover, it has been accompanied by a major
intended effect, and it is the positive trend indicated in extension in the average duration of unemployment:
chart 3. The employment rate is therefore gradually from 391 days in 2009 to a record high of 538 days in
nearing the European average of 54%, though it still November 2014.

February 2015 Conjoncture 5


Each type of job seeker has its own specific category
Box 1: Definitions of unemployment Number of
The unemployment rate expresses the number of unemployed Category registered Requirements Characteristics
individuals as a percentage of the labour force, which in turn is defined job-seekers
as the sum of actively working individuals age 15 and over and the Did not work for
A 3,488,300
unemployed. According to the definition of the International Labour the past month
Office (ILO), individuals are considered to be unemployed if they are Performed short-
members of the active population age 15 and over and meet the Must be term reduced work
B 672,300
following three criteria: to be out of work, available to work (can begin actively (i.e. no more than
working within the next two weeks) and actively seeking work (having seeking 78 hours)
carried out specific procedures during the past four weeks). The work Performed long-
INSEE uses ILO standards. term reduced work
C 1,015,700
(i.e. more than 78
France: number of unemployed, mainland France hours)
Not working
3600 Thousands (due to training,
D 280,000
an internship or
3400 Category A jobseekers Not required
illness)
3200 to actively
Number of unemployed (INSEE/ILO) Employed (via a
3000 seek work
subsidised job
2800 E 384,400
contract, for
2600 example)
2400 ABC 5,176,300
2200 ABCDE 5,840,700
2000 Table Source: DARES-Pôle Emploi,
1800 November 2014 data for mainland France
1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014
Chart A Sources: INSEE/ILO, Pôle emploi We would like to highlight one final characteristic of
The ILO definition of unemployment is not exactly the same as the French unemployment: the scope of the problem arising
concept of “category A jobseekers” used by the national employment through underemployment and the “unemployment halo”
office (Pôle Emploi), which leads to significant differences in popularised by Jacques Freyssinet 6 . Unemployment
unemployment trends (see chart A). The number of jobseekers at the
end of the month (DEFM) is broken down into five categories depending cannot be summarised as simply “not having work”. It
on whether the individual worked during the month and carried out corresponds to a precise definition (see box 1). Yet,
specific job hunting procedures (see table). Category A comprises those there are various forms of inactivity, and a lot more
who have not worked at all during the past month and are actively people can be considered “unemployed” than those
seeking work. Jobseekers registered in this category are not necessarily
considered unemployed unless they are available to work immediately measured by the statistics of the national employment
and/or if they are not actively seeking work according to the ILO criteria. office or by the INSEE’s conventional unemployment
The analysis of unemployment is not facilitated by the variety of rate.
statistics, which continue to fuel debates on the “right” measure for Various economic crises and transformations have
unemployment 5. Although changes of methodology are necessary, they
do not help matters either. For instance, the overhaul of the INSEE job helped create intermediary situations with overlapping
survey in early 2014 led to a notable downward shift in the boundaries between unemployment, employment and
unemployment rate, which averaged about 0.4 points (see chart B). inactivity. In chart 4, zone 2 corresponds to the different
France: new unemployment rate vs former forms of underemployment (such as involuntary part-
time workers, partial unemployment and very short-term
12 % contracts). Zone 3 covers people who are in mixed
New methodology situations of both inactivity and unemployment. This
11 Old methodology includes people who want to work more but are not
counted as unemployed: either they have been
10
exempted from looking for work since their chances of
9 finding a job again are so small, or else they have
become discouraged and have given up on job hunting.
8
Zone 1 is comprised of individuals who have decided to
7 work less. Lastly, zone 4 is comprised of clandestine
1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 workers and undeclared employees, who are not taken
Chart B Source: INSEE into account in the other three zones.

February 2015 Conjoncture 6


The unemployment halo Compared levels of unemployment rates

13 %
Germany France Eurozone
12
Employment 11
1 10
9
2 4 Inactivity 8
3 7
6
Unemployment
5
4
1991 1995 1999 2003 2007 2011 2015
Chart 4 Chart 5 Source: Eurostat

Underemployment, as defined and measured by First, growth is much weaker in France. Between 2010
the INSEE, comprises people working part time who and 2014, the average annual growth rate was twice as
want to work more, as well as those involuntarily high in Germany (2%) than in France (1%). In France, this
working less than they usually do (notably due to pace of growth is too sluggish to bring down the
partial unemployment). The unemployment halo is unemployment rate. This is especially true if we narrow the
comprised of people who could be considered as observation period to 2012-2014, when average annual
unemployed but who are not counted as such growth was only 0.4%, compared to 0.7% in Germany.
because they do not fulfil all of the criteria of the Recent trends in French unemployment can be retraced
International Labour Office (ILO), i.e. to be fairly accurately using a simple version of the Okun law 7,
unemployed, actively seeking work and available to which links unemployment to growth according to the
work. Some might not be available to work following equation: ∆𝑢𝑢 = 0.5 − 0.4∆𝑦𝑦, where ∆𝑢𝑢 is the
temporarily due to family or personal reasons, or change in the unemployment rate over a year, and ∆𝑦𝑦 is
might not be seeking work (notably seniors who think the year-on-year growth rate (see chart 6).
they will no longer be able to find a job).
In mainland France at the end of 2014, the INSEE An illustration of the Okun law in France
counted 1.7 million underemployed persons (vs.
1.3 million ten years earlier) and 1.4 million inactive 12 Unemployment rate, %
persons in the unemployment halo (vs. 1.2 million ten 11
years earlier). These figures must be added to and Estimated Observed (mainland France)

compared with the 2.8 million unemployed in the 10

strict sense of the term, and the total looked at in 9


relation to a labour force of about 28 million. 8
Measured using this looser definition, the
unemployment rate in France comes to 21%, which is 7

more or less double the conventional unemployment 6


rate. 1999 2002 2005 2008 2011 2014
Chart 6 Source: INSEE

Overview of the dysfunctions, obstacles, imperfections Changes in the labour force also play a role. The
and other problems of the French labour market labour force in France has grown nearly twice as fast as
To answer the question “Why does France suffer its German counterpart, at an annual average of 0.6%
from such high unemployment?”, we can grasp the first and 0.3%, respectively, for the period 2010 to 2014.
notions of a response by asking “Why does Germany Although potentially a favourable trend, under current
benefit from such low unemployment today?” What are circumstances the demographic momentum in France
the broad traits that distinguish the two job markets strains unemployment statistics, because once again
and explain the wide gap in their unemployment rates growth is too weak to employ all of the new entrants to
since 2009 (see chart 5)? the job market.

February 2015 Conjoncture 7


Lastly, and most importantly, there is the functioning thresholds; and the mismatching of labour supply and
of the job market. Briefly summarised, Germany is demand. In the following pages, we will review some
benefiting from the Hartz reforms introduced between of these factors of rigidity, starting with the duality of
2003 and 2005 8, and from the intensive use of “internal the labour market.
flexibility” by German companies, which is much less This duality reflects the segmentation of the French
common in France. Internal flexibility includes partial labour market into two groups:
unemployment, “working time savings accounts” and - “insiders” with open-ended CDI job contracts, who
employment & competitiveness pacts. Compared to enjoy stable, protected jobs and little exposure to
Germany, the French labour market looks much more unemployment. They tend to have more skills and
rigid. qualifications, which a priori means they can find a new
This rigidity encompasses several factors that go job rather easily;
far beyond the question of the mandatory 35-hour - “outsiders” with fixed-term CDD job contracts,
workweek. They include the duality of the labour including temporary work for employment agencies,
market, i.e. the strong segmentation between regular involuntary part-time work and other short-term work
open-ended job contracts (CDI) and short fixed-term schemes. Employment is precarious. Workers in this
contracts (CDD); the relative inertia of real wages, category tend to have little or no qualifications and to have
notably due to the minimum wage indexation system; few opportunities for training. They are thus exposed to
a conflictual social dialogue; the weight and protracted periods of unemployment or recurrent periods of
complexity of labour laws and red tape; workforce unemployment alternating with short periods of employment.

Employment protection
(scale of 0 to 6: the higher the number, the stricter the employment protection for each case)

Regular contracts Temporary contracts Collective dismissals


12 12

10 10

4.1
8 8
3.4 3.4 3.8

3.6 3.8
6 3.1 6
3.6
2.5
3.6 2.5
4 3.6 3.6 3.3 4
2.0 1.1 2.6 2.0 1.4
0.8
2.9 2.9
2 2
2.9 2.9
2.7 2.9 2.8 2.5 2.7
2.3 2.4 0.3 0.4 2.4 2.0 2.6
0.3 0.3 1.0 1.0
0 0.3 0,3. 0
2000 2013 2000 2013 2000 2013 2000 2013 2000 2013 2000 2013 2000 2013
France USA UK Germany Spain Italy Sweden
Chart 7 Source: OECD

According to the employment protection indicator protection and the level of unemployment: there is no
compiled by the OECD 9 , the degree of protection for obvious empirical correlation nor a proven causal link
open-ended CDI job contracts is relative high in France (Blanchard and Tirole, 2003).
(see chart 7). Yet it is not the highest of the countries The French problem probably arises more from the
under review. Plus employment protection has been stark contrast between the two groups, with precarious
trending downwards (in 2009, although the decline only employment on the one hand, and stable jobs on the
partially erases the gains in 2003). Moreover, the next other. This can be seen in the way these job contracts
trend is likely to be downwards as well thanks to flexicurity are terminated. Termination is an inherent part of fixed-
measures introduced in the job securitisation agreement term CDD contracts, whereas exiting an open-ended
of January 2013 (see below). Above all, there is still CDI contract implies a “rupture”. Any dismissals must be
ongoing debate over the correlation between employment justified by a “real, serious” cause. This is not

February 2015 Conjoncture 8


necessarily obvious and is open to dispute, which can The end result is a labour market that does not
be costly. The high cost of dismissing workers is due facilitate job insertion and that is paradoxically both rigid
less to the “direct” payment of compensation than to the (via open-ended CDI contracts) and flexible (via fixed-
“indirect” costs of lengthy, drawn out procedures and red term contracts). The much-needed flexibility of CDDs is
tape 10. It is worth nothing, however, that according to a exacerbated by the lack of flexibility of the vast majority
DARES report (2015), it is not unusual for regular, open- of job contracts. CDDs are also a source of
ended CDI contracts to be terminated within the first precariousness that makes lasting job market insertion
twelve months. In 2011, 36.1% of CDIs were terminated difficult to achieve. The low job loss and unemployment
before their first anniversary (vs. 33.6% in 2007). The exit rates 12 illustrate the duality of the labour market in
main reason given was resignation by the employee, complementary ways, between those with secure jobs
followed by the expiration of the probation period. and those on unemployment: although it is not easy to
The contrast between the two groups is particularly lose a job in France, it is harder to exit unemployment.
stark because it is hard to shift from a fixed-term This lack of fluidity contributes to the French labour
contract to a more secure open-ended one. The CDD to market’s low capacity to absorb shocks as well as to the
CDI transformation rate was only about ten percent 11. development of unemployment.
For the most part, this is probably due to a big threshold The co-existence of high unemployment and job
effect, i.e. the increase in employment protection costs vacancies is also problematic. Although there is nothing
when transferring from a CDD to a CDI. In addition, the unusual about job vacancies, what is abnormal is when
first group serves as an adjustment variable for the job their number is chronically high. In France, the big
market during the different phases of the business cycle. debate is over the size of the problem (estimates range
The flexibility of short-term contracts is in high demand widely from 100,000 to 300,000, and even 1 million 13),
despite the high level of employment protection integrated not whether it exists.
in these contracts (which is one of the bigger paradoxes), This situation can be illustrated by the Beveridge
as illustrated by the growing share of CDD contracts in curve. It traces the inverse relationship between the
new hiring (84% in mid-2014, vs. 68% in 2000) and as a unemployment rate (x axis) and the job vacancy rate (y
share of total employment (8.5% in 2012 vs. 4% in 1982) axis). A high vacancy rate and a low unemployment rate
(see chart 8). The boom in these contracts can also be are signs of a healthy job market. Inversely, when job
attributed to a series of job policy reforms, which market conditions deteriorate, high unemployment goes
deliberately sought to make CDDs more attractive. Their hand in hand with a low job vacancy rate. The more or
flexibility helps offset the fixity of CDI contracts, which less smooth functioning of the labour market (in terms of
continue to predominate and have held rather steady over the matching of labour supply and demand) can be
the years, at 77% of the work force. Instead, the surge in measured by the position on the curve in relation to the
short-term contracts (CDD and temporary employment two axes. A rightward shift is a bad sign since it
services) has come at the expense of non-payroll indicates a higher unemployment rate for the same
employees, whose share of total employment has percentage of job vacancies, which signals a
declined. mismatching of labour supply and demand and
presumably a higher structural unemployment rate.
Specific types of employment Lacking a long data series on the job vacancy rate to
in % of total employment (mainland France) create a true Beveridge curve for France, we have used a
In 1982 In 2012
proxy based on the percentage of companies reporting
hiring difficulties (taken from the INSEE quarterly business
4.0 0.5 8.5
0.8 11.5 2.0
17.9 1.5
confidence survey). The resulting curve has clearly shifted
to the right over time, and has also steepened (see charts
9 and 10). This shift can be attributed to several factors:
the low geographic mobility of workers in general and the
unemployed in particular 14; their employability (notably for
76.9 76.6
the long-term unemployed) and their qualifications and
training, which are not or no longer suitable. We must also
Fixed-term contracts Temp work Apprentices Open-ended contracts Non-salaried look at the cost of labour, its rigidity and the excessive
Chart 8 Source: INSEE cost of low skilled labour.

February 2015 Conjoncture 9


An illustration of the Beveridge curve for France Moreover, the slope has distinctly flattened since the
from 1975 to the end of the 80s... mid-1990s (see charts 13 and 14). When wage growth
is adjusted for inflation, the correlation seems to be even
Share of companies reporting

60
50 looser, verging on the horizontal (see chart 15): real
hiring problems, %

40
wages seem to be virtually insensitive to job market
conditions. This can be attributed to the downside
resilience of nominal wage growth and its incomplete
30 1988
1976 1980
20 adjustment to slowing inflation (see chart 16).
10
1985
0 France: Phillips curve over the long-term
3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 (1986-2014)
Unemployment rate, mainland France, %

Nominal monthly wage growth,


Chart 9 Source: INSEE 5.5 6

5.0 5

4.5

y-o-y % change
5

... and from the end of the 80s to nowadays 4.0 4

3.5 4

3.0 3

2000
Share of companies reporting

60 2.5 3

2.0 2

50 1990 1.5
hiring problems, %

2008 2

40 1.0 1

7 8 9 10 11 12 13
30
1989 2014 Unemployment rate, %
20 Chart 12 Source: INSEE
1997
10 2010
1994
0 France: a rather steep curve through the mid-90s...
3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11
Unemployment rate, mainland France %
Nominal monthly wage growth,

Chart 10 Source: INSEE 5.5 5,5

5.0 5,0

4.5 4,5
y-o-y % change

4.0 4,0

France: inverse relationship between the unemployment


3.5 3,5

rate & nominal growth of the monthly base wage 3.0 3,0

y-o-y % change % 2.5 2,5

6% Monthly base wage


5 2.0 2,0

Unemployment rate, mainland France (inverted scale) 1.5 1,5

5% 6 1.0 1,0
6,5 7,0 7,5 8,0 8,5 9,0 9,5 10,0 10,5

7 6.5 7.0 7.5 8.0 8.5 9.0 9.5 10.0 10.5


4% Unemployment rate, mainland France, %
8 (Q1 1986 - Q4 1994)
3%
9 Chart 13 Source: INSEE
2%
10
1% 11 France: ...a rather flat curve since then
0% 12
1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014
5.5
Nominal monthly wage growth,

5,5

Chart 11 Source: INSEE


5.0 5,0

4.5 4,5
y-o-y % change

4.0
This brings us to the third characteristic of the
4,0

3.5 3,5

malfunctioning of the French labour market: the 3.0 3,0

imperfect or non-existent adjustment of wages to 2.5 2,5

2.0
the unemployment rate. To be more precise, we can
2,0

1.5 1,5

see the expected inverse relationship, as described by 1.0


6.5
1,0
6,5 7,0 7,5 8,0 8,5 9,0

7.0 7.5 8.0 8.5 9.0 9.5 10.0 10.5


9,5 10,0 10,5

the original Phillips curve, between the unemployment Unemployment rate, mainland France, %
rate and the nominal increase in the monthly base (Q1 1995 - Q3 2014)
wage 15, but the slope is feeble (see charts 11 and 12). Chart 14 Source: INSEE

February 2015 Conjoncture 10


France: loose ties between the unemployment rate & seem, considering the squeeze on corporate margins
real growth of the monthly base wage and the high unemployment rate, which to the contrary
2.5
2,5
encourages wage moderation.
Real monthly wage growth,

The authors cite other explanatory factors: “the way


2.0
minimum wages are defined (national minimum wage
2,0
y-o-y % change

1.5
1,5 and sector agreements) and the financing of
employment protection”, which encumber and drive up
1.0
wage costs in France, independently of the cyclical
1,0

0.5
0,5
environment. Recently, a “composition effect” has also
0.0
0,0 added upward pressure: job losses mainly affect the
7 8 9 10 11 12 13 least qualified and thus lowest paid workers, and by
Unemployment rate, % (1986-2014)
leaving the labour pool they help raise the average
Chart 15 Source: INSEE
wage rate.
When low inflation is added to these various factors,
France: downward resistance and incomplete
adjustment of wages to headline inflation
real wages, and thus the overall cost of labour, tend to
rise faster than productivity gains (which are fairly
5% y-o-y % change
lacklustre as well). The increase in real wages is
4% Inflation Nominal monthly base wage certainly good news for household purchasing power,
3%
and a support factor for consumption. For employers,
however, it is more problematic since they must deal
2%
with higher real unit labour costs, which discourages
1% labour demand, leads to less hiring, strains growth and
0% maintains unemployment.
While there is not much debate over the duality of
-1%
1991 1995 1999 2003 2007 2011 2015 the labour market and the lack of wage adjustments to
Chart 16 Source: INSEE unemployment, discussions become much more heated
and less conclusive when it comes to the role of three
Why aren’t wages playing more of a role as a labour other characteristics of the French labour market: the
market adjustment variable? Shouldn’t they slow more 35-hour workweek, relatively generous unemployment
during a period of high unemployment? Following the benefits and workforce thresholds. We provide a short
Enderlein-Pisany-Ferry (2014) report, several possible summary of the problem of workforce thresholds in the
explanations for this rigidity come to mind: mandatory box below and discuss the impact of the 35-hour
annual wage negotiations at the company level, which workweek in the appendix. In the third part of this article,
put upward pressure on wages even when there is no we will look at unemployment insurance from the angle
revenue growth to be distributed; the low unemployment of possible reform ideas.
rate for the most qualified workers, which drives up their
wages; and the partial indexation of the minimum wage
Box 2: Workforce thresholds, a real but minor problem
to the average hourly wage, which does not take into
In early October 2014, employers and employees’ unions (the so-
account productivity trends.
called social partners) started negotiations on modernising the rules
According to research by the Conseil d’Analyse for social dialogue and employee representation. Having failed to
Economique (2013), wage momentum in France is also reach an agreement before the mid-December deadline, the talks
shaped by companies who are reluctant to change their were extended into January 2015, but in vain. As a result, the
government has stepped in again and will propose a new reform
wage practices, even during a crisis. “To preserve
project.
employee motivation and the social climate – two key There is fierce debate and dissension over workforce thresholds,
determinants of productivity – companies prefer to scale the levels at which companies are subject to a series of fiscal and
back employment rather than wages,” thereby protecting social obligations, such as better union representation for employees.
insiders, i.e. those with jobs, to the detriment of The multiplicity and complexity of these official, time-consuming rules
are deplored, as well as their supposedly negative impact on business
outsiders, i.e. those outside of the job market. Using the development and employment. The magic numbers are 10, 20 and 50
CICE job competitiveness tax credit to raise wages employees. Below we have listed some of the obligations tied to these
follows the same logic, as paradoxical as that may thresholds:

February 2015 Conjoncture 11


- the transition from 9 to 10 employees obliges companies to and foster job-rich growth. The most notable measures are:
switch to the payment of social security contributions on a monthly
employers’ contributions cuts on low wages; subsidised job
basis, to offer transport subsidies and to set aside a higher percentage
of the total payroll for vocational training, (1.05% instead of 0.55%); contracts; the development of short-term contracts;
- the transition from 10 to 11 employees obliges companies to incentives to leave the workforce (early retirement), to
pay a minimum compensation of 6 months of wages in case of return to work (EITC-type tax credit and RSA minimum
dismissal without real or serious grounds and to organise elections for income allowance) and to extend working life (postponing
an employee representative (without obligation of results). The
company is no longer fully exempt from paying charges on payments the age of retirement, eliminating the dispensation to search
to apprentices; for work for the unemployed over age 55), and the
- the transition from 19 to 20 employees obliges companies to reduction in the workweek. More recently, two innovative
enact bylaws, hire a certain percentage of employees with disabilities, mechanisms have been introduced to facilitate the
increase funds set aside for vocational training to 1.6% of the total
payroll 16 , and establish mandatory compensatory rest for overtime
functioning of the labour market, which are very popular: 1)
work; the creation of a self-employed status (auto-entrepreneur)
- the transition from 49 to 50 employees obliges companies to set as part of the Economy Modernisation Law (LME) of
up a hygiene and safety committee (CHSCT), a works council August 2008; and 2) the termination of job contracts by
financed by the employer, and an employee profit-sharing plan; to mutual consent (rupture conventionnelle 17), as part of the
implement an employment safeguard plan in case more than 10
employees are dismissed in less than 30 days; to hold annual June 2008 law on modernising the labour market.
negotiations on wages, working hours, employee savings plans and Obviously there is no one miracle cure. But why haven’t
professional equality; and to make monthly declarations of labour these attempts met with greater success? The reasons are
migration to the ministry of labour. numerous. It is beyond the scope of this article to explore
By looking simply at the number of companies on the verge of
these thresholds, we can see a net discontinuity (see chart). But them in detail, but one reason is the sequential nature of
according to INSEE research (2011) and the calculations of F. Gourio the approach used to fight unemployment, one small step
and N. Roys (2014), the impact of these workforce thresholds on the after another. The very large number of job policy players 18
size of companies and on employment, though statistically significant, and the predominance given to the obligation of means
is relatively small. As minor as the benefits may be, however, it would
still be worth simplifying and easing these thresholds and improving over results, may also have hurt the effectiveness of these
the social dialogue. Such a reform would have a positive symbolic measures. This piecemeal approach to measures and
impact. participants brings us back to the question of how difficult it
is to make the right diagnosis and to apply the most suitable
France: number of companies (thousands)
by number of employees policy. The response will not be the same, depending on
whether France is suffering from classic unemployment (due
55.4
to a labour supply mismatch) or Keynesian unemployment
(due to insufficient demand). Yet this diagnosis is not only
hard to make, it varies over time. Today, it is the first
42.3
36.9
34.5
interpretation that prevails, but that was not always the case.
There is no unanimity over the current policy line either.
18.3 Faced with the unemployment problems identified in the
13.6 12.6
10.5
7.6 6.9 7.0 7.2
first part of this article, François Hollande has deployed a
4.3 3.5 3.3
3.2
1.2 1.2 1.5 1.6 0.6 0.5 0.5 0.5
“toolbox” that tries to be as complete as possible, including
6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53
measures aiming at employment and unemployment for both
Chart C Sources: INSEE, Les Echos youth (particularly those with little or no skills) and seniors, via
emplois d’avenir and contrats de génération subsidised job
contracts and youth guarantees. Other measures aim to
A panoply of remedies already reduce job market rigidity through the employment security
agreement; to boost sluggish growth and low
tested or currently underway competitiveness through the national pact for growth,
competitiveness and employment (PCCE), which was
In 1993, François Mitterrand declared that “in the fight strengthened by the Responsibility and Solidarity Pact and
against unemployment, we’ve tried everything,” admitting at the proposed Macron draft law for growth and business; to
the time just how difficult it is to solve mass unemployment. overhaul the training system to better optimise job training
Just over 20 years later, the problem remains intact, despite resources; and to create incentives to return to work with
a long list of measures implemented to fight unemployment the new unemployment insurance agreement. In addition to

February 2015 Conjoncture 12


these innovative measures, the toolbox also offers a certain both a young person and a senior were recruited at the
comprehensive approach. Yet the effectiveness of most of same time. To avoid any windfall effects, companies are
these tools seem rather limited, and thus insufficient for all not eligible for subsidies if they have reported any layoffs
that is at stake. for economic reasons in the six months prior to the new
recruitment. Large companies with more than 300
Job policy does not abandon the classic solution of employees do not benefit from reduced charges, but must
subsidised job contracts set recruitment targets or pay a penalty. The government
intends to create 500,000 generation contracts by 2017,
Like his predecessors, François Hollande has resorted an ambitious target that is far from being reached
to subsidised job contracts, but he has added his own according to the most recently available tally: only about
personal touch by creating two new programmes. 30,000 contracts had been signed as of October 2014,
The first, jobs for the future (emplois d’avenir), with a 2015 target of 40,000 contracts. This programme’s
targets job insertion for youth in difficult situations through poor performance is largely due to the economic slump.
the creation of 150,000 subsidised job contracts. Decreed
in October 2012, the law reached its goal by September Job policy also focuses on flexicurity…
2014. Given the presumed success of the programme, it
was extended into 2015. These job contracts are reserved The Employment Security Agreement or ANI was
for youth in the 16-25 age group with little or no reached between the social partners in January 2013 and
qualifications living in disadvantaged areas. Job positions enacted into law on 14 June 2013. It fits within the
are available essentially in the public sector, in activities category of structural reforms. This agreement is
with “a proven social benefit and sustainable recruitment important for both its form and content. First, it was the
prospects”. To boost the programme, the conditions were fruit of compromise and social dialogue, which is perfectly
eased for creating more jobs in the private sector. The in keeping with the Larcher law of 2007. This law marked
contracts are fixed-term CDD lasting at least a year and a the comeback of the tri-party social regulation of
maximum of three years, or open-ended CDI contracts employment, by giving new meaning and importance to
paying the minimum wage. The state pays 75% of wages social dialogue: social partners were placed at the centre
for three years (35% in the private sector). This of the negotiating table alongside the state 19. Second, by
programme offers several innovations and advantages: its extending the 25 June 2008 law on the “modernisation of
target group, open-ended contracts and the accent placed the job market”, the ANI of January 2013 defines the
on training new recruits. As a result, this programme is contours of French-style flexicurity.
less exposed to the criticism of traditional subsidised job For employees, the agreement contains diverse
contracts and should serve as a less flimsy springboard measures to promote job security: generalisation of
towards the job market. complementary healthcare, reframing of part-time work,
The generation contract (contrat de generation), rechargeable rights to unemployment insurance, personal
enacted in March 2013, is the government’s second star training accounts, and the right to a period of secured
measure for handling the social aspects of voluntary mobility (see below for more information on these
unemployment. It has two goals: to hire young people last three measures). It also introduces a surcharge applied
under age 26 via opened-ended CDI contracts and to to fixed-term CDD contracts of less than 3 months,
match them with seniors over age 57, preserving their increasing unemployment insurance contributions (from 4%
employment so they can play a tutoring role. One interest to 7% for CDD of less than 1 month and to 5.5% for 1- to 3-
of this programme resides in the transmission of month contracts) 20. In addition to this surcharge, charges
knowledge. The scheme differs depending on whether the are exonerated for the first three months for young
company employs more than 300 employees. Small and individuals under age 26 hired under an open-ended CDI
mid-sized companies with less than 300 employees contract. The measure seeks to discourage abuse and to
benefit from a reduction in charges of EUR4000 a year, encourage companies to recruit more individuals using CDI
distributed in two halves for each member of the contracts. It is hard to obtain this result in the current
intergenerational couple. Aid is granted over a 3-year environment of economic stagnation, and given the
period for the young worker and up to the senior’s tenuous prospects of recovery. Moreover, fixed-term
retirement age. On 1 September 2014, the amount of contracts of less than 3 months cannot be substituted for
government subsidies was increased to EUR8000 when open-ended CDI contracts.

February 2015 Conjoncture 13


For companies, the main flexibility measures are: the jobseekers by the national employment office 21, job security
simplification of the partial unemployment system and “job contracts (contrat de sécurisation professionnelle, CSP) 22,
preservation” plans. These latter mark real progress. and operational preparation for employment (préparation
Companies facing “severe economic troubles” would be opérationnelle à l’emploi, POE) 23.
able to maintain employees by negotiating for a maximum As to targeting training efforts to a specific public, a
of 2 years the adaptation of working hours and/or training plan for the unemployed was announced in
compensation. The simplification of group redundancy summer 2013 that specifically promotes jobs labelled as
procedures and the reduction in legal risks are also vacant. At least 30,000 jobseekers are thought to have
expected to facilitate hiring (it is easier to hire if it is also benefited from this programme by the end of 2013 and
easy to lay off workers). another 100,000 in 2014. The Ministry of Labour expressed
This agreement reduces certain rigidities in the French its satisfaction with the measure. Another programme for
labour market. But the positive effects are expected to be the long-term unemployed is the “path to job insertion
small. The problem of labour market duality and through economic activity”, which the government would
segmentation by job contract is barely addressed. The like to support. Participants are placed in professional
agreement adds even more complexity to the labour code situations and the companies train them directly.
and raises labour cost (via the surcharge on fixed-term Lastly, there is the new youth guarantees (garantie
CDD contracts of less than 3 months and the generalisation jeunes), which targets individuals in the 18-25 age group
of complementary healthcare). The flexibility provided by who are Not in Education, Employment or Training
job preservation agreements is highly regulated and (NEET). This particular group is very large (nearly 2
defensive by nature. For the moment, the scheme has not million youth, or 17% of the age group under
been very successful. consideration 24) and did not benefit from the least aid in
the past. This shows the full interest of the measure,
Priority on training which is part of the multiannual plan to fight poverty and
promote social inclusion, adopted in January 2013. It
Qualifications have been shown to be a key factor in job comes on top of the emplois d’avenir and contrats de
insertion and preservation. Consequently, numerous génération government subsidised job contracts geared
measures have been devoted to improving skills. The pact for specifically to youth. This 1-year enhanced support
growth, competitiveness and employment (PCCE) proposes programme promotes employment or training by having
to strengthen the ties been schools and companies, notably participants work closely with local missions 25 . They
as part of technical and professional curriculums; the receive a monthly allowance of about EUR450. This
development of apprenticeships; greater international mobility system fits within the European youth guarantee scheme.
for students; the creation of a new public service for career Rolled out in November 2013, it was initially tested in
orientation and training; and personal training accounts about ten regions and is now being generalised. At the
(compte personnel de formation). Personal training accounts, Social Summit in July 2014, Manuel Valls announced a
introduced by the ANI employment security agreement of target of 50,000 beneficiaries of youth guarantees in
January 2013, are a new right for employees. They are 2015, and 100,000 in 2017.
universal, can be activated at any time during one’s career, The vocational training reform approved in
are open to the employed and unemployed and can be December 2013 and enacted in March 2014 generally aims
transferred when changing jobs. to achieve a better allocation of the enormous training
The ANI of January 2013 also introduces a period of budget (more than EUR30bn), so that it benefits those who
secured voluntary mobility (mobilité volontaire sécurisée) are most in need, namely the unemployed. Currently this is
that enables employees to prepare for a possible career not the case, since the system benefits active employees
change by entering a fixed-term CDD contract with another most, especially those already with the highest
company, with the consent of his or her initial employer. At qualifications 26. Social partners have both expressed their
the end of the fixed-term contract, the employee has the satisfaction with this reform, which is a good thing in itself.
option to resign from the initial post or to return to the initial The reform seeks to increase the responsibility of each of
company with at least the same wages. The ANI of January the system’s stakeholders, and to simplify funding. This
2013 also seeks to encourage greater use of other effective should make vocational training more effective. The reform
means of improving employability based on career support also officially introduces personal training accounts, effective
and training, including different levels of supervision for 5 January 2015, which is a significant step forward.

February 2015 Conjoncture 14


The government also lent its support, albeit in a aims to turnaround employment while at the same time
confusing manner, to apprenticeships, which are known restoring competitiveness. Yet the pact does not specify
to be an efficient means of job insertion for young people, which objective should be given the highest priority. By
even though the French system is underdeveloped and using a single instrument (reducing labour costs) to try to
functions poorly 27 . Faced with a sudden decline in the attain two antagonistic objectives (turning around
number of new apprenticeships (-8% in 2013 28), several competitiveness requires, among other things, an upturn in
measures were announced at the Social Summit of July productivity gains), the PCCE risks failing to meet either
2014 and the Apprenticeship Congress of September satisfactorily.
2014, including the unblocking of new funding (up to It is worth noting, however, that according to the
EUR200 million as of 2015) and a new hiring bonus. The INSEE Mesange macroeconomic model, a EUR20bn
government reaffirmed its target of 500,000 cut in employers’ contributions would reduce the
apprenticeships in 2017 (vs. 365,000 in September 2014). unemployment rate by one point 31 , a non-negligible
theoretical effect that would get an additional boost from
Boosting the return to work the measures in the responsibility pact.
The responsibility pact, announced in January
Social partners had more trouble reaching a deal 2014, reinforces the supply-side policies initiated by the
during the renegotiation of the unemployment insurance PCCE. It contains a cumulative total of EUR24bn in
agreement in the first months of 2014. The challenge was reductions in corporate taxes and contributions (on top of
to reduce the UNEDIC unemployment insurance deficit, the CICE tax credit), spread out over time through 2020,
which neared an estimated EUR4bn in 2014 29 (the same in exchange for hiring. This hiring condition differentiates
level as in 2013), without increasing unemployment the responsibility pact from the PCCE, which does not
insurance contributions (which would hurt efforts to contain any such commitments. Although this marks a
turnaround competitiveness) or cutting benefits (given the step forward, it will be hard to implement: in the absence
high level of unemployment), while at the same time of growth, companies are finding it difficult to make hiring
improving incentives to return to work. The new commitments. The pact was counting on sector
agreement that was finally reached on 14 May 2014 does agreements, but they have only trickled in.
contain measures that tighten certain benefits rules to Another particularity of the responsibility pact is that the
generate budget savings, as well as a few changes to reduction of charges is spread out over time and the cuts are
help improve incentives to return to work, including of different nature, which tends to reduce their impact. In
rechargeable rights 30. For employees returning to work 2015, the EUR4.5bn reduction in employers’ contributions to
after a period of unemployment, this mechanism lets them the URSSAF, the organisation that collects social security
hold on to all or part of their unused jobless benefits, and and family benefits contributions, targets low wage earners
to add them to any new rights acquired during the new (between 1 and 1.6 times the minimum wage). Minimum
period of activity, in case they become unemployed again. wage earners will no longer be even subject to this type of
charge 32. This is a direct support measure for low-skilled
Stimulating growth labour, while the other measures are more generally and
indirectly aimed at supporting companies and employment.
The competitiveness pact and the responsibility pact This is the case for the EUR1bn reduction in family welfare
have a broad vocation of stimulating growth, which is contributions for the self-employed and tradesmen, and the
expected to have a positive impact on the labour market. 3-year elimination of the company social solidarity
The competitiveness pact announced in November 2012 contribution (Contribution Sociale de Solidarité des
was the first set of reforms engaged by François Hollande Sociétés, EUR5.5bn, including EUR1bn in 2015). As of
to turnaround the French economy and its growth potential. 2016, companies will benefit from an additional EUR4.5bn
This pact aims to provide a comprehensive response to the in reductions in family allowance contributions, and the
country’s competitiveness deficit by acting on price target group will be expanded to include workers earning up
competitiveness (with the EUR20bn CICE tax credit) and to 3.5 times the minimum wage. The corporate tax
non-price competitiveness (measures to support innovation, surcharge will also be eliminated that year, reducing
SME financing, to make the country more attractive and to corporate taxes by EUR2.5bn. In 2017, the normal
reduce red tape). As its full name indicates (national pact corporate tax rate of 33.3% will be cut to 32%, and then to
for growth, competitiveness and employment), the PCCE 28% by 2020 (the equivalent of EUR6bn in tax relief).

February 2015 Conjoncture 15


Macron Draft Law for Growth and Business
Measure Objectives Impact
Deregulation
Revise fee schedules for regulated legal Lower fees by gearing them more towards the real costs incurred by Purchasing
professions the legal profession power
Remedy the negative effects of the current situation: limitations on
Simplify start-up conditions for legal Activity –
services, regional inequalities, unequal access, obstacles to career
professions employment
development, notably for women, and an aging profession
Expand the scope of candidatures for Restore the system’s logic and effectiveness; reduce costs for the Purchasing
lawyers appearing before the Court of Appeals French power
Create a corporate lawyer status Employment
Open up capital between legal and Increase resources for professionals to start a business, relocate, join Activity –
accounting professionals forces and develop employment
Activity –
Offer French passengers a complementary transport alternative to
employment –
Deregulate bus transport services the train and car: facilitate mobility, make travel less costly and more
purchasing
environmentally friendly
power
Cap the increase in motorway tolls; guarantee construction
Strengthen regulations on road-related Purchasing
companies, notably SME, better access to motorway construction
businesses power – activity
contracts by expanding tendering requirements
Purchasing
Reduce the turnaround time and cost of Reduce the associated turnaround times and costs; facilitate access
power –
obtaining a drivers’ license to drivers’ licenses to increase social and professional mobility
employment
Boost expertise in commercial urban
development to lift barriers to competition Lift barriers to competition in commercial urban development for Purchasing
between stores and to provide consumers better installation of retail areas power – activity
more choice
Make the different tools for intermediate “affordable” housing more
Activity –
coherent and easier to understand to increase supply (increase
Meet the demand for intermediate employment –
constructability), support the construction industry, provide easier, more
housing purchasing
affordable access to housing for middle class households (greater
power
mobility), and reduce pressures on low-income housing
Investment
Stimulate investment and accelerate Simplify regulatory procedures, notably to meet targets for issuing
major industrial and urban development building permits within 5 months; support the construction and public Activity
projects to promote growth works industry
Encourage companies to develop Facilitate the allocation of share warrants for company founders
employee shareholding plans and to promote (bons de souscription de parts de créateurs d’entreprise, BSPCE) and Activity
an entrepreneurial culture free shares (attributions gratuites d’actions, AGA)
Simplify employee savings plans to
enhance their development, on behalf of Activity
financing the real economy
Revitalise active management of
government shareholdings (disposal of Activity
government owned stakes)
Employment
Facilitate Sunday and evening working Activity –
Simplify, clarify and make more equitable the system in special
hours, on a voluntary basis, with all employment –
tourism areas (currently no wage compensation is planned and work is
companies, regardless of size, obliged to pay purchasing
mandatory) and PUCE (wage compensation; voluntary basis)
wage compensation power
Make labour arbitration procedures (Prud’homme) faster, simpler,
Reform judicial procedures for labour Employment
more predictable and effective
Enable ailing businesses to continue operating in order to safeguard
Strengthen protections of collective as many jobs as possible; restore an equilibrium in the social dialogue Employment
actions between creditors, employees and shareholders; create specialised – activity
commercial courts for ailing corporate giants
Decriminalise “obstructionism” (délit
d’entrave)

February 2015 Conjoncture 16


Lastly, the Macron draft law for growth and agreement work in this direction. The Macron law also
business, named after the current Economy Minister, calls for the labour arbitration tribunals (Prud’hommes) to
was presented before the Council of Ministers on 10 be reformed and aims to make redundancy procedures
December 2014. This law takes a different but less costly. But there is room to go further to reduce the
complementary angle of attack from the measures in the legal insecurity facing companies, due to protests and
two pacts. This law seeks to lift a number of obstacles the lengthy process of redundancy procedures. For
hampering business and employment in numerous example, it would help if the criteria for justifying layoffs for
sectors, to encourage competition and by doing so to economic reasons was less restrictive, notably by making
free up purchasing power. This mixed bag of measures the notion of “safeguarding corporate competitiveness”
targets several regulated professions, Sunday work, less subject to interpretation. This kind of measure would
drivers’ licenses, intermediary housing, ground help companies gain external flexibility, and would reduce
transport, employee savings plans and the labour the cost of layoffs, which is often mentioned as an
arbitration tribunals (Prud’hommes) (see table). The obstacle for offering open-ended CDI job contracts. A
proposed changes are significant, and could have rapid, broad simplification of the labour code would help in the
visible effects, although the overall impact will be rather same vein.
mild, assuming the law is enacted in its original form and When examining the question of unemployment and
in a timely manner (currently planned for summer 2015). what new or different measures could be used to
Yet the draft law risks being watered down after resolve the problem, we cannot help but refer to the
triggering fierce protests from some of the targeted 2003 CAE report by Blanchard and Tirole. The first big
professions and opposition from deputies as well. idea defended by the two economists is the introduction
of a corporate economic redundancy tax (taxation
des licenciements économiques des entreprises), based
What else? on the “polluter pays” principle used for environmental
issues, or the bonus-malus system in the insurance
sector 34 . The advantage of this system is that
Although the latest measures to fight unemployment companies internalise the cost engendered by their
are a step in the right direction, they can be criticised layoffs for the unemployment insurance fund. This
mainly for their lack of boldness as well as for makes them directly responsible financially, which
procedures that are often confusing or even should lead to fewer layoffs and more secure jobs.
contradictory. The remedies currently being tested are Above all, with this financial responsibility, judges would
far from a shock therapy. Consequently, it is hard to no longer need to rule on the economic justification of
expect them to have much more than a limited impact, redundancy procedures. Dismissal decisions would be
diluted over time. left to business leaders, who assume the cost directly.
A lot more still needs to be done, even though the Their judgement would prevail and the administration
executive branch sometimes gives the impression that would have no reason to step in and intervene. Yet such
what it has put in place so far will suffice. But this is not a tax would not only be hard to calibrate, it would be
the case. There is room to improve current actions, difficult to implement as well. According to the authors,
notably in terms of flexicurity. Internal flexibility, for however, the expected benefits of this measure are
example, could be taken further by facilitating the use of enormous: the tax would “kill four birds with one stone”
partial unemployment and job preservation agreements, by helping reduce unemployment, excessive judicial
via less rigid application conditions. In general, under the intervention in redundancy procedures, the
flexicurity guidelines recommended by the European unemployment insurance deficit and the duality of the
Commission, France still has room to progress by easing labour market.
the legal restrictions on collective dismissals, enhancing Duality would be reduced by diminishing the
the performance of its vocational training system, threshold effect between the lower cost of fixed-term
increasing the effectiveness of its employment policy and CDD contracts and the higher cost of open-ended CDIs.
optimising the unemployment insurance system 33. By internalising the cost of layoffs (or without going that
There needs to be a significant reduction in the far, by making this cost more predictable), CDI contracts
regulations and costs surrounding collective dismissals. would seem less repulsive and CDD contracts less
Some of the measures in the January 2013 job security attractive. Taking this logic to the extreme in order to

February 2015 Conjoncture 17


totally eradicate labour market duality, Blanchard and from 50; change the rule of 1 day of benefits for 1 day of
Tirole’s second big idea is to return to a unique job contributions; cap the net replacement rate (and not the
contract. This fashionable solution is often brandished gross rate like today); strengthen penalties for
as the panacea for French unemployment. Yet as insufficient job hunting and correct the perverse effects
radical as it may be – and assuming it is feasible – it of the reduced activity allowance. 36
would only be one reform among several others that To be fully efficient, however, more needs to be
need to be launched. done to reform the unemployment insurance system
Blanchard and Tirole advocate a modular unique job than simply tweaking a few parameters. The system
contract, one that plays on the notion of a probation must be reconsidered in its entirety 37, its financing must
period and gradually increases workers’ rights and be restored, its resource base diversified and
company obligations, based on seniority and the expanded 38, and its governance overhauled.
employee’s recent experience in the job market. It is
interesting to note that this closely resembles the Jobs
Act currently proposed by Matteo Renzi in Italy. The law Box 3: The unemployment benefit system in Germany
aims precisely at reducing the segmentation between
The Hartz labour market reforms were implemented
CDD and CDI job contracts by changing the nature of
between 2003 and 2005. The unemployment benefit system
the CDI: job protection is gradually increased in keeping has undergone numerous reforms based on the principle of
with seniority, and redundancy procedures are “incentives and demands”. The goal is to reduce the duration
simplified. As to CDD’s, they are extended to up to three of unemployment through stronger incentives to actively
years. For the same reasons, Spain has also made search for work and through more effective job placement.
major changes to redundancy conditions, which were Hartz I, which took effect on 1 January 2003, strengthened
tightened for CDD and loosened for CDI. the eligibility requirements for jobless benefits. It was now up
For France, what all this means is that it needs to to jobseekers, and not the employment services, to prove that
attack the problem of job market rigidity “from both a refused job offer was unacceptable. Acceptability conditions
are gradually tightened over the duration of unemployment.
ends”, i.e. by removing some of the rigidity in CDI and Benefits are reduced each time an acceptable offer is refused.
by no longer adding flexibility primarily via CDD. Vocational training and job placement services for the
Another component of flexicurity is the unemployed were also improved.
unemployment insurance system, where a more Hartz II, which took effect on 1 April 2003, triggered a
optimal compromise needs to be found between boom in mini-jobs and midi-jobs, two low-paying job categories
protection for beneficiaries and incentives for returning with few charges. A new subsidy was created to facilitate
to work. There are numerous proposals for reform. The business start-ups by the unemployed.
most recent negotiations on unemployment insurance Hartz III, which took effect on 1 January 2004, focused on
did not change things much. The talks had barely reorganising public employment services and increasing the
efficiency of job placement for the unemployed.
ended before comments were already being made on Hartz IV, which took effect on 1 January 2005, tightened
the next round of negotiations (scheduled for early further the eligibility conditions for unemployment benefits,
2016) on tightening the conditions for receiving notably for the long-term unemployed. After twelve months of
benefits in order to facilitate the return to work. In this unemployment, they were transferred out of the
respect, the German model might not be easily unemployment insurance system and switched to an
replicated, and might not even be the right one to unemployment assistance scheme, offering lower benefits and
follow. Still, the broad scope and apparent success of the obligation to accept employment, even if it does not
the changes introduced under the Hartz reforms correspond to qualifications or is far from the home place. The
provide food for thought (see box 3). minimum affiliation period to qualify for benefits was reduced
to 12 months of contributions over the past two years from
In France, there are several leverages that could be three years previously. The fourth reform package introduced
activated to accelerate the return to work and lower “1-euro jobs”, small jobs geared towards the hardest to find
unemployment: 35 reduce the maximum duration of work. Later, in February 2006, the maximum duration of
unemployment benefits and/or lower the ceiling on unemployment benefits was shortened from 32 months to 18
compensation; extend the period of affiliation before months for the over-55 age group and from 26 months to 12
being eligible for rights; introduce digressive jobless months for the other age groups. On 1 January 2008, the
benefits; postpone the age at which seniors benefit from duration was extended again to 24 months for the over-58 age
more favourable compensation conditions to age 52 group.

February 2015 Conjoncture 18


The unemployment insurance system must also be Since the late 1980s and early 1990s, fighting mass
better integrated with other social welfare services, so unemployment has been one of the economic
that it becomes possible to consider reducing the challenges that France has struggled to cope with, so
generosity of jobless benefits in exchange for raising the far without success. The failure to win this battle despite
benefits of other programmes. Jobseekers also need to repeated efforts shows just how difficult this problem is
be provided better support, because the system’s to resolve. This is largely due to its deep and entangled
generosity is in vain if the monitoring of beneficiaries is roots, as we pointed out in the introduction. It is also due
defective. A more effective, less costly unemployment to the mismatch and shortcomings of the solutions set
insurance system could be put to work on behalf of the up so far, amid a general reticence to accept change 40.
supply-side policy currently being promoted. This would Indeed, it can be discomforting to make a clear and net
make it possible to reduce the relatively high cost of cost-benefit analysis on reforms, since the benefits are
unemployment insurance contributions for companies uncertain and not immediately visible, while the costs
and would help lower the cost of labour, as was done in are more easily and rapidly identifiable. This is true
Germany. regardless of the scope of the reform. A priori, the costs
Lastly, among the unexplored but regularly of a small-scale reform will be more limited, but so will
mentioned options for fighting unemployment, there is its benefits. Large-scale reforms come with a higher
the issue of reforming the minimum wage, the level of price tag, but the expected benefits are much higher too.
which and pace of increase both being a source of The current government’s responses to mass
concern. As suggested in the Enderlein-Pisani-Ferry unemployment seems to fit more within the first
report (2014), the formula for calculating the automatic category. Further measures are therefore needed. The
increase in the minimum wage could be changed to government cannot simply make do with what it has
bring it more in line with productivity gains 39. On several already set in place. Granted, it has made some smart
occasions, there has also been talk of differentiating the moves, but they do not go far enough. To win the game,
minimum wage level based on such factors as age, it will clearly have to make some more bold plays.
qualifications, distance from employment, and region. A
differentiated minimum wage should favour
employment, notably for young persons with no
qualifications. Yet training is just as much a relevant 6 February 2015
answer for resolving the unemployment problem in this helene.baudchon@bnpparibas.com
latter category.

 

February 2015 Conjoncture 19


Appendix: the 35-hour workweek, progress or handicap?
The mandatory 35-hour workweek has been a recurrent subject of debate since it was adopted in 2000. Due to
its exceptional nature (no other country in the world has adopted legislation that places such a limitation on working
hours), it is frequently blamed for the French economy’s lack of competitiveness. In contrast, its advocates claim it
not only represents major social progress, but also has a beneficial impact on employment and productivity. In this
appendix, we will make a general overview of the issue, starting with the terms of the Aubry law introducing the 35-
hour workweek, the numerous amendments that followed and its overall economic impact. In the end, we conclude
that the 35-hour workweek has been more harmful than beneficial for the French economy.
The law did generate several hundreds of thousands of job creations, but at the expense of major complications for
businesses, a heavy burden on public finances and mixed social welfare benefits. Even so, it would not be that easy
today to try to backtrack and repeal the 35-hour workweek. No sooner is this idea mentioned, even in passing or just a
simple suggestion, it immediately triggers an outcry of opposition. Fifteen years after it was introduced, the 35-hour
workweek is still a sensitive and divisive subject. Some reject it outright, while others express their firm attachment.
Repealing the Aubry law would engender new complications, whereas the initial shock has already been absorbed. In
any case, the 35-hour workweek as it was initially envisioned has already been largely unravelled.
Nonetheless, as part of efforts to revitalise the French economy, there are grounds for exploring ways to make the
system simpler, more flexible, less costly and less restrictive.
1/ Objectives and implementation
a/ The initial Aubry laws
The introduction of the 35-hour workweek fits within an ongoing movement to reduce working hours initiated early in
the 20th century and which aims to improve the living conditions of payroll employees. In addition to its social welfare
dimension, there are also economic considerations: reducing working hours is an incentive for greater leisure, which
presumably means more consumption. But above all, reducing the workweek was seen as the new spearhead in the
fight against unemployment.
The first law was presented by Martine Aubry, then Minister of Labour, and approved on 13 June 1998. It called for a
gradual reduction in the legal workweek from 39 hours to 35 hours as of 2000 (2002 for small and mid-sized
enterprises). It introduced the reduction in working hours (reduction du temps de travail, RTT), as well as the principle of
mandatory compensatory rest in order to regulate the use of overtime. Incentives were also introduced to support
companies that reduced the number of working hours by 10% before 2000, in exchange for new hiring or job
preservation.
Negotiations following the first law led to a second law that was voted on 19 January 2000. It officially established
the mandatory transition to a 35-hour workweek, and stipulated compensation measures for both companies and
employees:
• greater flexibility in the management of working hours: the legal duration was set at 1600 hours annually, which
made it possible to modulate weekly working hours according to activity;
• financial aid: employer charges were reduced when collective bargaining agreements on RTT were signed and the
number of working hours was effectively reduced (but not conditioned on creating or preserving jobs);
• a mandatory guaranteed monthly pay for employees earning the minimum wage, to avoid a decline in real wages
due to the reduction in the number of hours worked.
The law also created a limit on working days for white-collar workers, which was set at 217 days a year, to allow
greater flexibility in managing their working hours. For the basis of calculations, companies were also authorised to
define the effective duration of work excluding breaks and training. The system of overtime was also modified: a 25%
pay increase is now applied on overtime work up to the 43rd hour of work, and a 50% increase thereafter (within the limit
of the annual ceiling).
Although the second law arose from and complements the first, it follows a different logic 41. Aubry 1 clearly fits within
the notion of job sharing which was supposed to permeate the entire reform: aid was conditioned on the reduction of

February 2015 Conjoncture 20


working hours and on job creations. It had an immediate impact on employment, but at the price of strong wage
moderation. Aubry 2 eliminated the job creation conditions and eased the requirements to reduce working hours (no
more quantified targets, redefinition of effective working hours, modular options). The cost was not as high for
companies, and was offset through productivity gains, which enabled them to maintain wages in exchange for less
hiring. Aubry 2 takes a less restrictive and more traditional approach based on reducing charges to create hiring
incentives.
b/ The successive reforms
Following these two laws, numerous adjustments were made to make the system more flexible, but without calling
into question the principle of restricting legal working hours. The first reform, adopted on 17 January 2003, consisted
mainly in annualising working hours: the standard 35-hour workweek disappeared in favour of a cumulative total of 1600
working hours a year. This reform replaced the principle of automatic compensatory rest for the first four hours of
overtime with a pay increase. It transformed the working time savings accounts into accounts that could receive money
and serve as savings accounts. Management of overtime was delegated to company agreements and the legal annual
contingent was raised from 130 hours to 180 hours (and then to 220 hours following the decree of 9 December 2004).
Reductions in employer charges were separated from the length of working hours so that all companies could benefit
from them, which offset the upward shift in the minimum wage as part of its standardisation, scheduled for 2005.
A second reform, voted on 31 March 2005, covered overtime again, an essential variable making it possible to
adjust working hours without formally calling into question the principle of the 35-hour workweek. Henceforth, employees
can voluntarily exceed the contingent of overtime hours stipulated by law or by collective bargaining agreements (within
the legal limit of 48 hours weekly). The law also allows white-collar management to exchange their leave time for higher
pay, and eases the restrictions on working time savings accounts: the ceiling was removed, the storage of rights was no
longer limited in time, the accounts could accept compensatory rest days, RTT days and leave, and they could be
converted into supplementary wages or savings.
The third reform fits within the framework of the TEPA law on labour, employment, and purchasing power voted on
21 August 2007. Its main goal was to make overtime work tax exempt (exoneration of employee charges and income
taxes for employees, and employer charges for employers) 42.
Lastly, a fourth reform was adopted on 20 August 2008. It allows companies to set the contingencies for overtime
work by company and not by sector agreements, along with the overtime rate and compensatory rest, the conditions for
hourly and daily wage arrangements for white-collar management and measures to smooth working hours over the year.
2/ The impact of the 35-hour workweek on the economy
After this series of reforms, the 35-hour workweek was no longer applied much in the strict sense of the term. The
law clearly helped reduce working hours, but the size of the reduction is still a subject of debate. RTT was also
implemented during very favourable cyclical times, which makes it harder to analyse the impact of the Aubry laws on
employment and competitiveness.
a/ Employment and unemployment
According to an INSEE 43 report, the 35-hour workweek directly generated 350,000 jobs between 1998 and 2002
(compared to a total of 2.1 million jobs created over the period). An OFCE study 44 estimates that the 35-hour workweek
created a total of 480,000 jobs. At the time, the government was counting on the law to create 700,000 jobs. This goal was
not fully met (due to the overestimation of the reduction in working hours and the underestimation of productivity gains), but
the results proved to be positive. Similarly, at the beginning of the 2000s, the observed decline in France’s unemployment
rate was one of the biggest in the developed countries (see chart). The 35-hour workweek surely had something to do with
this success.
Yet the boost was only brief and cyclical. Application of the 35-hour workweek did not improve the structural
functioning of the labour market. Its positive impact on employment diminished over time in part because companies
took advantage of the extra flexibility provided by overtime work (enhanced by its tax exempt status), to the detriment of
hiring new employees 45.

February 2015 Conjoncture 21


Growth and unemployment

a positive figure indicates a decline)


Change in the jobless rate between
8

1997 & 2002, pp (inverted sign:


7 SPA
6 IRL
5
4 FRA
SWE
3 ITA
EMU NLD
2 UK BELPOR
1 GER AUT
USA
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Average annual growth, 1997-2000, %
Sources: INSEE, Eurostat, BEA, ONS

b/ Cost of labour, productivity and competitiveness


One of the main criticisms regularly made against the 35-hour workweek is that it hurt competitiveness by driving up
the cost of labour. The law imposed a reduction in working hours at a constant wage, which automatically increased the
hourly wage cost. Yet the introduction of the 35-hour workweek was accompanied by measures designed specifically to
offset this effect. From the beginning, the law provided a reduction in social charges for companies that reduced working
hours by 10%, which was then extended to all companies that switched to a 35-hour workweek. This measure was to
offset a third of the higher costs engendered by the reduction of working hours. Another third was to be offset by wage
moderation and the remaining third by labour productivity gains. Wage moderation and productivity gains were right on
target 46. The minimum wage, in contrast, was not subject to the same wage moderation. In the end, we do not see an
obvious upsurge in unit wage costs during the years following the introduction of the 35-hour workweek. From this
perspective, it is difficult to blame RTT for the French economy’s loss of competitiveness, even though it occurred at the
same time.
d/ Flexibility and social impact
The main complaint about the 35-hour workweek has less to do with its repercussions on labour costs (which were
offset) and is more about the complications it created, notably for SME. Foremost of these was the rigidity engendered
by the principle of working hours imposed by national law, without taking into account the company level or sector level
specificities. This echoes Raymond Barre’s warning in 1978: “concerning the reduction in working hours, any unilateral
and uniform measure will increase rigidities at a time when a certain flexibility is necessary.”
This is why various reforms were attached to the law to ease the system, so that companies could adjust working
hours according to their activity and its dynamism 47. This hourly flexibility was accompanied by greater organisational
flexibility, both internally (creation of new teams, greater versatility, renewed insourcing of some activities) and externally
(greater use of temporary employment, outsourcing and even delocalisation).
Even so, for many companies who were forced to adopt the system, the lack of flexibility and workplace
disorganisation were still a problem. The situation in hospitals was the most striking and mediatised example. Unable to
adapt, the reduction in working hours was seen as restricting or even destroying business.
As to productivity, the impact of the 35-hour workweek was not all positive. With the intensification of work came
greater pressure and stress, which was also fuelled by the imposition of working hours that were standardised and
controlled (notably in industry), and by demands for greater flexibility, responsiveness and versatility. These factors
ended up deteriorating working relations 48, which were not necessarily offset by the improvement in living conditions
outside of the workplace, since the extra leisure time was offset by wage moderation. All of this strained productivity,
which may be a very localised phenomenon, but nonetheless a real handicap for the companies concerned.
The 35-hour workweek can be considered to have had a positive impact on employment, but from a social
perspective, the results are more mixed, and even nil in two respects: reinvigorating the social dialogue and boosting
consumption. Concerning consumption, a DARES study shows that most of the free time liberated by the reduction in

February 2015 Conjoncture 22


working hours was devoted to family life, rest, home improvements and gardening. These domestic activities do not
necessarily require an upturn in spending, especially at a time when household revenues were under pressure 49.
All of this explains why there are such mixed feelings concerning the 35-hour workweek, which tends to be seen
more as a handicap than true progress.
e/ The cost for the state
Lastly, implementation of the 35-hour workweek placed a very costly burden on public finances. According to the
INSEE, charges were reduced by a total of EUR7.7bn in 2002 50. Reduced spending on jobless benefits and higher tax
revenues due to the increase in employment failed to cover the cost of subsidies. The INSEE estimates the net cost for
the state at EUR1.5bn in 2002. These are only approximate figures because it is impossible to evaluate precisely the
economic gains attributable to the 35-hour workweek. The state may have picked up the tab engendered by the 35-hour
workweek so that companies could boost employment in the short term, but this came at the high price of wider public
deficits, a handicap for the economy as a whole and for long-term employment in particular.
Research for this text was provided by Raphaël Cohen (an Economics Research intern, July-December 2013).

Bibliography
Askenazy Philippe, Catherine Bloch-London and Muriel Roger, 2004, “The reduction in the working week, 1997-2003: construction
of the Aubry acts and first evaluations”, INSEE, Economie et statistique n°376-377.
Askenazy Philippe, Antoine Bozio and Cecilia Garcia-Peñalosa, 2013, “Wage dynamics in the midst of crisis” Les notes du conseil
d’analyse économique, n°5, April.
Baudchon Hélène, 2014, “France: will the unemployment insurance system be tightened soon?”, BNP Paribas EcoFlash
Research n°14-1, 3 November.
Blanchard Olivier and Jean Tirole, 2003, “Employment protection and dismissal procedure”, CAE Report n°044.
Cahuc Pierre, Stéphane Carcillo and Klaus F. Zimmermann, 2013, “Employment of low-skilled youth in France”, Les notes du
conseil d’analyse économique, n°4, April.
Cahuc Pierre and Marc Ferraci, 2014, “Apprenticeships on behalf of employment”, Les notes du conseil d’analyse économique,
n°19, December.
Ceci-Renaud Nila and Paul-Antoine Chevalier, 2011a: “The impact of workforce thresholds of 10, 20 and 50 employees on the
size of French companies” Economie et Statistiques n°437, March.
Ceci-Renaud Nila and Paul-Antoine Chevalier, 2011b, “Workforce thresholds of 10, 20 and 50 employees: limited impact on the
size of French companies”, INSEE Analyses n°2, December.
Cette Gilbert, Nicolas Dromel and Dominique Méda, 2003, “Factors behind employees’ assessment of reduced working hours”,
DARES, Document d’études n°77, November.
Charpentier P., H. Huyghues Despointes, M. Lallement, F. Lefresne, J. Loos-Baroin and N. Turpin-Hyard, 2005, “Reduced
working hours and the organisation of work: impact of the Aubry 2 law”, DARES, Document d’études n°100, May.
Conseil d’Analyse Economique, 2000, Full employment, Report n°030 under the direction of Jean Pisani-Ferry.
Conseil d’Orientation pour l’Emploi, 2013, “Long-term job vacancies and hiring difficulties”, September.
Coquet Bruno, 2013, “Unemployment insurance – a poorly handled problem”, L’Harmattan.
Coquet Bruno, 2014, “Unemployment insurance: six challenges for negotiations”, Policy Paper, Institut de l’Entreprise, January.
Cour des Comptes, 2013, “The labour market: to cope with high unemployment, target policies better”, January.
Enderlein Henrik and Jean Pisani-Ferry, 2014, “Reforms, investment and growth: an agenda for France, Germany and Europe”,
27 November.
Freyssinet, Jacques, 1988, Unemployment, La Découverte.
Freyssinet, Jacques, 2014, Alternatives Economiques, n°333, March.
Gourio François and Nicolas Roys, 2014, “Reforming workforce thresholds would have little impact on employment”, Les Echos,
12 September.
Gubian Alain, Stéphane Jugnot, Frédéric Lerais and Vladimir Passeron, 2004, “The impact of reduced working hours on
employment: from ex ante simulations to ex post evaluations”, INSEE, Economie et statistique n°376-377.
Heyer, Eric and Xavier Timbeau, 2000, “35 hours: a reduced reduction”, OFCE Review n°74, July.
Heyer, Eric, 2011, “Should we roll back tax exemptions for overtime work?”, OFCE, note n°2, 29 September.

February 2015 Conjoncture 23


Klein Caroline and Olivier Simon, 2010, “The MESANGE model, a new version re-estimated using 2000 as the base”, DGTPE
working document, n°2010-02, March.
Martinot, Bertrand, 2013, “Unemployment: inversing the curve”, Manitoba / Les Belles Lettres, Paris.
OECD, 2014, Employment outlook.
Olivennes, Denis, 1994, “The French preference for unemployment”, Note of the Saint Simon Foundation, February.
Paraire, Xavier, 2015, “More than a third of CDI are broken off before one year”, DARES Analyses n°005, January.

NOTES
1 Unless stated otherwise, the unemployment rate for France includes mainland France and the overseas territories, as measured by the INSEE.
2 See Cahuc et alii (2013).
3 The statistics analysed in this paragraph are taken from the OECD Employment outlook, 2014.
4The employment rate is the ratio of employed in a given age group to the working age population. The participation rate is the ratio of the labour

force to the working age population.


5 See Freyssinet (2014).
6 Unemployment, La Découverte, 1988.
7 The Okun law is named after the American economist that formulated it in 1962. It empirically expresses the proportionality between growth and

unemployment. Each point of growth below (or above) the potential growth rate (estimated at 3% at the time) leads to a half-point increase
(decrease) in the unemployment rate.
8 See box 3 below for a summary of these reforms.
9 The OECD employment protection indicators measure the procedures and costs involved in dismissing individuals or groups of workers and the

procedures and costs involved in hiring workers under fixed-term and temporary employment agency job contracts.
10 The real problem is collective layoffs rather than individual dismissals.
11 Source: European Commission, Indicators for monitoring the Employment Guidelines including indicators for additional employment analysis,

2010 compendium.
12 Indicators referred to in the 2000 report on full employment by the French Council of Economic Analysis (CAE). The job loss rate measures the

monthly probability for working individuals to lose their jobs. The unemployment exit rate measures the probability that unemployed individuals will
find work within the next month.
13 This figure was calculated by the Conseil d’Orientation pour l’Emploi (COE) in its September 2013 report on job vacancies.
14 Low geographic mobility is partly a consequence of the major surge in real estate prices since the mid-1990s.
15 The monthly base wage (SMB) is the gross wage before the deduction of social welfare contributions and the payment of social benefits. It does

not include any bonuses or overtime. The amount generally corresponds to the first line on an employee’s pay slip.
16 The 2013 vocational training reform replaced this percentage with a reduced, single contribution of 0.55% for companies with fewer than 10

employees and 1% for the others.


17 A procedure that enables the employer and employees to reach a common, friendly agreement on the conditions for terminating the job

contract, which is only possible with CDI long-term contracts. They cannot be imposed by one party or the other, and are exclusive of dismissals
and resignations.
18 Bertrand Martinot provides a good picture of the tangle of players involved in job policy in his book on reversing the unemployment curve:

“Chômage: inverser la courbe”.


19 Except in urgent situations, this law stipulates that “any reform project planned by the government that pertains to individual or group relations to

labour, employment and vocational training and which fits within the scope of national and inter-professional negotiations” must be the object of
prior consultation with the social partners in the light of any negotiations. Towards this end, the government furnishes an “orientation document
presenting the key points of the diagnosis, the stated goals and the main options.”
20 Temporary employment services and seasonal fixed-term CDD contracts are exempt from this surcharge.
21 Differential monitoring has been operational since January 2013, and sets three levels of support depending on the distance from employment

(reinforced support, guided support or remote support).


22 The professional job security contract (CSP), which took effect in September 2011, is geared towards redundancies for workers who have been

employed at least a year, in companies with less than 1,000 employees. It offers them the possibility of receiving an allowance (paid by the
national employment agency with a contribution from the company) and strengthened job support to help them find work, for a maximum of 12
months.
23 The Operational Preparation for Employment (POE), introduced by the vocational training reform of 2009, enable jobseekers to benefit from

subsidised training necessary for acquiring the skills needed to obtain a job corresponding to a job offer that a company has filed with the national
employment office. This is a good way to bring together job offers and demand, notably for job profiles that are difficult to fill.
24 According to Eurostat data for the 15-24 age group, collected in late 2014, the percentage of young NEET in France is 11.2%, compared to

6.3% in Germany and a eurozone average of 12.8%.


25 Local public organisation dedicated to youth.
26 For more on this subject, see the January 2013 report by the French Court of Audit: “The labour market: to cope with high unemployment, target

policies better”.
27 See Cahuc and Ferraci (2014).
28 Source: DARES.

February 2015 Conjoncture 24


29 January 2015 estimate.
30 For more information on the new agreement, see Baudchon (2014).
31 See Klein and Simon (2010).
32 In other words, they would no longer be required to pay social security contributions, which cover healthcare, maternity leave, disabilities, death,

autonomy solidarity contributions, old age insurance, family allowances, workplace accidents and occupational diseases. They would still be liable
for other mandatory employer contributions, with the exception of social security contributions (including contributions for unemployment
insurance, complementary pensions, the tax on apprenticeships and vocational training).
33 For further information, see Bertrand Martinot, “Chômage: inverser la courbe”.
34 A modulation of employer contributions on unemployment insurance (for all job contracts and not only for very short-term contracts as is

currently the case) would serve the same purpose.


35 We have left aside the parameters whose modification would reduce the UNEDIC deficit (higher contributions, inclusion of civil servant

contributions, adjustable rights in keeping with the unemployment rate).


36 The success of this measure has been a double-edged sword. The risk is that unemployment benefits would be deviated from their primary

function, i.e. to ensure the replacement of revenue, and that they would be considered as supplementary revenue. The reduced employment
regime also risks confining individuals in short, instable jobs.
37 For the full picture, see Bruno Coquet (2013 and 2014).
38 It would no longer rely solely on the contributions paid on business sector wages as is the case today.
39 Today, France’s minimum wage is automatically increased on 1 January according to a formula that offers two guarantees: purchasing power

(by indexing it to the consumer price index) and participating in the nation’s economic development (by linking it to the change in the purchasing
power of the average hourly wage). If inflation exceeds 2% with regard to the last legal minimum wage hike, an early wage increase is made. The
minimum wage is also given an extra boost from time to time. The most recent one was a 0.6% increase on 1 July 2012, the first since 2006.
Since 2008, a committee of independent experts provides recommendations on minimum wage trends and the opportunity for an extra boost. The
latest report published in December 2014, like previous reports, did not recommend raising the minimum wage, to avoid placing greater strain on
competitiveness and employment. On 1 January 2015, the minimum wage was raised to EUR9.61 an hour, i.e. a gross monthly wage of
EUR1,458 and a net monthly wage of EUR1,136. The French minimum wage is one of the highest in Europe and in the OECD. The automatic
annual increase in the minimum wage is specifically French. The extent of the minimum wage on the distribution of wages is also stronger in
France than in the other OECD countries. France stands out too for the relative level of the minimum wage compared to the median wage, which
at 62% in 2012 is significantly higher than elsewhere in Europe (by about 15 points). Yet thanks to the reduction of charges targeting low-wage
earners, the cost of an employee earning the minimum wage has been reduced to a little more than half of that for a worker paid the median wage.
40 Reticence to change is the idea behind Denis Olivennes’ provocative statement in 1994: “the French preference for unemployment”. The status

quo is implicitly preferred over change, because the first is considered to be less harmful than the second. This suggests a kind of optimum
situation. Yet although we easily admit there is reticence to change, we cannot consider the current situation as optimal. Moreover, it is not change
that is lacking but results.
41 Heyer and Timbeau (2000).
42 Tax exemption was eliminated in July 2012.
43 Gubian et alii (2004).
44 See ibid Heyer and Timbeau.
45 Heyer (2011).
46 See ibid Gubian et alii.
47 Charpentier et alii (2005).
48 Askenazy et alii (2004).
49 Cette et alii (2003).
50 See ibid Askenazy et alii.

February 2015 Conjoncture 25


ECONOMIC RESEARCH DEPARTMENT
● William DE VIJLDER +33.(0)1.55.77.47.31 william.devijlder@bnpparibas.com
Chief Economist
OECD COUNTRIES
● Jean-Luc PROUTAT +33.(0)1.58.16.73.32 jean-luc.proutat@bnpparibas.com
Head
● Alexandra ESTIOT +33.(0)1.58.16.81.69 alexandra.estiot@bnpparibas.com
Deputy Head – Globalisation, United States, Canada
● Hélène BAUDCHON +33.(0)1.58.16.03.63 helene.baudchon@bnpparibas.com
France, Belgium, Luxembourg
● Frédérique CERISIER +33.(0)1.43.16.95.52 frederique.cerisier@bnpparibas.com
Public finance – European institutions
● Clemente De LUCIA +33.(0)1.42.98.27.62 clemente.delucia@bnpparibas.com
Euro zone, Italy - Monetary issues - Economic modeling
● Thibault MERCIER +33.(0)1.57.43.02.91 thibault.mercier@bnpparibas.com
Spain, Portugal, Greece, Ireland
● Caroline NEWHOUSE +33.(0)1.43.16.95.50 caroline.newhouse@bnpparibas.com
Germany, Austria -Supervision of publications
● Catherine STEPHAN +33.(0)1.55.77.71.89 catherine.stephan@bnpparibas.com
United Kingdom, Switzerland, Nordic Countries – Labour market
● Raymond VAN DER PUTTEN +33.(0)1.42.98.53.99 raymond.vanderputten@bnpparibas.com
Japan, Australia, Netherlands - Environment – Pensions
● Tarik RHARRAB +33.(0)1.43.16.95.56 tarik.rharrab@bnpparibas.com
Statistics

BANKING ECONOMICS
● Laurent QUIGNON +33.(0)1.42.98.56.54 laurent.quignon@bnpparibas.com
Head
● Delphine CAVALIER +33.(0)1.43.16.95.41 delphine.cavalier@bnpparibas.com
● Céline CHOULET +33.(0)1.43.16.95.54 celine.choulet@bnpparibas.com
EMERGING ECONOMIES AND COUNTRY RISK
● François FAURE +33.(0)1 42 98 79 82 francois.faure@bnpparibas.com
Head - Russia
● Christine PELTIER +33.(0)1.42.98.56.27 christine.peltier@bnpparibas.com
Deputy Head - China, Vietnam - Methodology
● Stéphane ALBY +33.(0)1.42.98.02.04 stephane.alby@bnpparibas.com
Africa, French-speaking countries
● Sylvain BELLEFONTAINE +33.(0)1.42.98.26.77 sylvain.bellefontaine@bnpparibas.com
Latin America, Turkey - Methodology
● Sara CONFALONIERI +33.(0)1.42.98.74.26 sara.confalonieri@bnpparibas.com
Africa, English and Portuguese speaking countries
● Pascal DEVAUX +33.(0)1.43.16.95.51 pascal.devaux@bnpparibas.com
Middle East – Scoring
● Anna DORBEC +33.(0)1.42.98.48.45 anna.dorbec@bnpparibas.com
CIS, main CEEC countries
● Hélène DROUOT +33.(0)1.42.98.33.00 helene.drouot@bnpparibas.com
Asia
● Johanna MELKA +33.(0)1.58.16.05.84 johanna.melka@bnpparibas.com
Asia

● Michel BERNARDINI +33.(0)1.42.98.05.71 michel.bernardini@bnpparibas.com


Public Relations Officer
OUR PUBLICATIONS

The information and opinions contained in this report have been obtained from, or are based on, public
sources believed to be reliable, but no representation or warranty, express or implied, is made that such
information is accurate, complete or up to date and it should not be relied upon as such. This report does
CONJONCTURE not constitute an offer or solicitation to buy or sell any securities or other investment. Information and
opinions contained in the report are published for the assistance of recipients, but are not to be relied upon
Structural or in the news flow, two issues analysed in as authoritative or taken in substitution for the exercise of judgement by any recipient, are subject to change
without notice and not intended to provide the sole basis of any evaluation of the instruments discussed
depth herein. Any reference to past performance should not be taken as an indication of future performance. To
the fullest extent permitted by law, no BNP Paribas group company accepts any liability whatsoever
(including in negligence) for any direct or consequential loss arising from any use of or reliance on material
contained in this report. All estimates and opinions included in this report are made as of the date of this
EMERGING report. Unless otherwise indicated in this report there is no intention to update this report. BNP Paribas SA
and its affiliates (collectively “BNP Paribas”) may make a market in, or may, as principal or agent, buy or sell
Analyses and forecasts for a selection of emerging securities of any issuer or person mentioned in this report or derivatives thereon. BNP Paribas may have a
financial interest in any issuer or person mentioned in this report, including a long or short position in their
economies securities and/or options, futures or other derivative instruments based thereon. Prices, yields and other
similar information included in this report are included for information purposes. Numerous factors will affect
market pricing and there is no certainty that transactions could be executed at these prices. BNP Paribas,
including its officers and employees may serve or have served as an officer, director or in an advisory
PERSPECTIVES capacity for any person mentioned in this report. BNP Paribas may, from time to time, solicit, perform or
have performed investment banking, underwriting or other services (including acting as adviser, manager,
Analyses and forecasts for the main countries, underwriter or lender) within the last 12 months for any person referred to in this report. BNP Paribas may
be a party to an agreement with any person relating to the production of this report. BNP Paribas, may to
emerging or developed the extent permitted by law, have acted upon or used the information contained herein, or the research or
analysis on which it was based, before its publication. BNP Paribas may receive or intend to seek
compensation for investment banking services in the next three months from or in relation to any person
mentioned in this report. Any person mentioned in this report may have been provided with sections of this
report prior to its publication in order to verify its factual accuracy.

ECOWEEK BNP Paribas is incorporated in France with limited liability. Registered Office 16 Boulevard des Italiens,
75009 Paris. This report was produced by a BNP Paribas group company. This report is for the use of
intended recipients and may not be reproduced (in whole or in part) or delivered or transmitted to any other
Weekly economic news and much more… person without the prior written consent of BNP Paribas. By accepting this document you agree to be bound
by the foregoing limitations.
Certain countries within the European Economic Area:
This report is solely prepared for professional clients. It is not intended for retail clients and should not be
passed on to any such persons. This report has been approved for publication in the United Kingdom by
ECOFLASH BNP Paribas London Branch. BNP Paribas London Branch is authorised and supervised by the Autorité de
Contrôle Prudentiel and authorised and subject to limited regulation by the Financial Services Authority.
Details of the extent of our authorisation and regulation by the Financial Services Authority are available
Data releases, major economic events. Our detailed from us on request.
views… This report has been approved for publication in France by BNP Paribas SA, incorporated in France with
Limited Liability and is authorised by the Autorité de Contrôle Prudentiel (ACP) and regulated by the Autorité
des Marchés Financiers (AMF) whose head office is 16, boulevard des Italiens 75009 Paris, France.
This report is being distributed in Germany either by BNP Paribas London Branch or by BNP Paribas
ECOTV Niederlassung Frankfurt am Main, a branch of BNP Paribas S.A. whose head office is in Paris, France. BNP
Paribas S.A. – Niederlassung Frankfurt am Main, Europa Allee 12, 60327 Frankfurt is authorised and
In this monthly webTV, our economists make sense of supervised by the Autorité de Contrôle Prudentiel and it is authorised and subject to limited regulation by the
Bundesanstalt für Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht (BaFin).
economic news
United States: This report is being distributed to US persons by BNP Paribas Securities Corp., or by a
subsidiary or affiliate of BNP Paribas that is not registered as a US broker-dealer to US major institutional
investors only.BNP Paribas Securities Corp., a subsidiary of BNP Paribas, is a broker-dealer registered with
the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission and a member of the Financial Industry Regulatory Authority
ECOTV WEEK and other principal exchanges. BNP Paribas Securities Corp. accepts responsibility for the content of a
report prepared by another non-U.S. affiliate only when distributed to U.S. persons by BNP Paribas
What is the main event this week? The answer is in Securities Corp.
your two minutes of economy Japan: This report is being distributed to Japanese based firms by BNP Paribas Securities (Japan) Limited
or by a subsidiary or affiliate of BNP Paribas not registered as a financial instruments firm in Japan, to
certain financial institutions defined by article 17-3, item 1 of the Financial Instruments and Exchange Law
Enforcement Order. BNP Paribas Securities (Japan) Limited is a financial instruments firm registered
according to the Financial Instruments and Exchange Law of Japan and a member of the Japan Securities
To receive our publications, please subscribe on our Dealers Association and the Financial Futures Association of Japan. BNP Paribas Securities (Japan)
Limited accepts responsibility for the content of a report prepared by another non-Japan affiliate only when
website. You can read and watch our analyses on distributed to Japanese based firms by BNP Paribas Securities (Japan) Limited. Some of the foreign
securities stated on this report are not disclosed according to the Financial Instruments and Exchange Law
EcoNews, our iPad and Android application. of Japan.
Hong Kong: This report is being distributed in Hong Kong by BNP Paribas Hong Kong Branch, a branch of
BNP Paribas whose head office is in Paris, France. BNP Paribas Hong Kong Branch is registered as a
Licensed Bank under the Banking Ordinance and regulated by the Hong Kong Monetary Authority. BNP
Paribas Hong Kong Branch is also a Registered Institution regulated by the Securities and Futures
Commission for the conduct of Regulated Activity Types 1, 4 and 6 under the Securities and Futures
Ordinance.

Some or all the information reported in this document may already have been published on
https://globalmarkets.bnpparibas.com

© BNP Paribas (2015). All rights reserved.

Prepared by Economic Research – BNP PARIBAS


Registered Office: 16 boulevard des Italiens – 75009 PARIS
Tél : +33 (0) 1.42.98.12.34 – Internet : www.bnpparibas.com
Publisher: Jean Lemierre
http://economic-research.bnpparibas.com Printed in France by: Ateliers J. Hiver SA – February 2015
ISSN 0224-3288 – Copyright BNP Paribas

Potrebbero piacerti anche