Sei sulla pagina 1di 10

Possibilism - Man changed Environment, Examples

Thursday, 9 May 2019 20:45 by ZunairaMajeed

The term Possibilism means that the environment only limits the number of choices that a person has. At its heart,
possibilism follows the notion that humans have the commanding power over their environment, albeit within certain limits.

In simple words, Possibilism denies the influence of environmental factors in a human’s life. The man who started the idea
of Possibilism was David Le Da Blanche – a French Geographer. He stated that the environment does not completely
define culture, rather it only limits the number of choices people have. By 1950, Environmental Determinism was
completely replaced by the Environmental Possibilism.

Man Has Changed the Environment – Examples Of Possibilism:


Man has brought changes to the environment by increasing its capacity to meet his needs and demands. The most visible
and common examples in this regard are the:
Industrial Revolution
Agricultural Advancement
Technological revolution

Industrial Revolution:
The industrial revolution began in the 18th century in Great Britain & it truly changed the way people lived. It was not an
overnight phenomenon but rather was the end result of series of inventions. It originated in Great Britain in 1750 and from
there it spread to North America and Europe during the19th century. The invention of the steam engine gave a boost to
the iron and textile industries. The invention of coke further modernized the production means. Now industries have a
share of more than thirty percent in the world’s GDP.

Agricultural Advancement:
The Green revolution, Invention of fertilizers and pesticides, the modern irrigation methods and the organic farming
methods have also contributed to the high output of crops and other products related to agriculture to meet the high food
demands across the world. All these efforts were done by humans to meet their increased demands indicating the
influence of Possibilism.

Technological revolution:
Modern means of communication such as , computers, internet, mobiles, cable TV has changed the world into a global
village. The Nano technology has given birth to revolutionary inventions which have made the life of a person easy and
complicated as well. Now within seconds, you can see and talk to your loved ones who are thousands of miles away from
you. These revolutions have helped humans to make their lives easy and comfortable. These revolutions very clearly
show that human activities affect the natural environment.
Environmental determinism: Does climate control our
destiny?

Environmental determinism is the theory that the physical discipline back peddled, ashamed by geography’s
environment, including the climate, sets hard limits on enthusiastic service to imperialism.
human society. Scholars and authors who subscribe to this
theory,argue that we can look to patterns of environmental The embarrassment meant that environmental determinism
change or geographical difference as a way to understand was largely ignored rather than buried, and as a result it
trajectories of human and social development and, by so has mounted a surprising comeback in recent years. Blame

doing, explain why some societies flourish while others Sachs and Diamond for this. Sachs, while an economist at
languish in poverty or even collapse. Harvard, repackaged old-fashioned environmental
determinism as the “ecology of underdevelopment.”
Tread carefully around such arguments.
As he wrote in a 1999 article in The Economist, “If it were
It’s a compelling and seemingly intuitive argument but, like true that the poor were just like the rich but with less
Social Darwinism for example, it is not the science it makes money,” he wrote, “the global situation would be vastly
itself out to be. As geographer Dick Peet has described it, easier than it is. As it happens, the poor live in different
environmental determinism is not rigorous scholarship but ecological zones, face different health conditions and must
rather the “ideology of an imperial capitalism.” overcome agronomic limitations that are very different from
those of rich countries. Those differences, indeed, are often
Environmental determinism plagued academic disciplines a fundamental cause of persisting poverty.”
such as anthropology, economics and geography in the
nineteenth and early twentieth centuries where, according Here Sachs, a key advisor to United Nations Secretary-
to the late geographer Neil Smith, it “had an obvious appeal General Ban Ki-Moon, makes the crackpot but
as a kind of royal shortcut to human science.” quintessential environmental determinist argument: the
redistribution of wealth won’t resolve global inequality.
Its adherents found success as the willing tools of empire Why? Because the geographical and unequal distribution of
happily explaining away the poverty and misery of affluence and poverty is not a result of unequal power
imperialism (and its privileges) as a function of natural relations but rather is a function of complex geographic and
processes. Cold northern climates produce hardy and thrifty climatic dynamics that have nothing whatsoever to do with
people who therefore flourish. Meanwhile, the unrelenting histories of colonial conquest and capitalist expansion. The
heat along the equator produces lazy people condemned to argument, of course, relies on a premise that ignores
forever languish in patterns of poverty as predictable as the histories of conquest— what Karl Marx, in reference to
trade winds. colonialism, called primitive accumulation.

The theory lost its luster in the early to mid-twentieth “In times long gone-by,” wrote Marx in Capital, Volume I, in
century as decolonization scholars launched attack after a brilliant parody of determinist apologia, “there were two
attack. The intellectual backlash focused on geography, the sorts of people; one, the diligent, intelligent, and, above all,
discipline most closely associated with environmental frugal elite; the other, lazy rascals, spending their
determinism. Ivy league institutions in particular, substance, and more, in riotous living…. Thus it came to
embarrassed by such obvious associations with imperialism pass that the former sort accumulated wealth, and the latter
(they prefer their associations to be less transparent), sort had at last nothing to sell except their own skins. And
dropped geography departments en masse. Chastened, the from this original sin dates the poverty of the great majority
that, despite all its labor, has up to now nothing to sell but
itself, and the wealth of the few that increases constantly thoughtful and fascinating body of evidence to an
although they have long ceased to work.” explanatory dead horse.”

For Marx, the unequal distribution of wealth was historically But Robbins was just being clever. He knew full well that
created in ruthless patterns of capitalist accumulation. In you can’t beat a dead horse. Academics attacked
addition, as the quote above so sarcastically implies, the arguments such as those by Sachs and Diamond because
social relations that sustain this inequality require elaborate the cruel logic of environmental determinism is,
ideologies capable of explaining away plunder as the work unfortunately, anything but dead. And, in a troubling
of nature. Enter environmental determinism. development, it has found purchase recently among climate
change scientists.
And so we get people like Sachs, who see “the poor” as an
ecological category living far off in a strange land instead of, Environmental determinism, it seems, has found a new
as Marx sees it, as a social relation. In Sachs’ world, the home. No longer housed in geography departments, it has
poor were always bound to be poor while the rich were taken up residence in geology, environmental science and
bound to be rich. earth science departments.

Sachs was able to make this argument because Jared This new “scientific” version of climate determinism took
Diamond had more recently parlayed it into a Pulitzer prize center stage at last month’s annual meeting of the
in his 1997 book Guns, Germs and Steel. Here he argued American Geophysical Union in San Francisco. There
that we need not look to histories of colonialism to researchers from West Virginia University described the
understand “the Fates of Societies,” (his subtitle for the results of recent tree ring data from Asia in which, they
book), but rather we must focus on physical geography and argued, a particularly wet period in the thirteenth century
climate if we hope to understand why the world is divided corresponded to the rise of Ghengis Khan and the spread
into rich and poor. of the Mongols. According to researchers, wet conditions
would have been particularly advantageous to nomadic
In his hands Europe’s ability to subjugate and colonize Mongol herders.
Africa was merely an accident “of geography and
biogeography—in particular to the continents’ different Well maybe, but more likely the rise of the Mongols had
areas, axes, and suites of wild plant and animal species. something to do with the enormous size of Khan’s army.
This is, the different historical trajectories of Africa and
Europe stem ultimately from differences in real estate” (p. But no matter, apparently the past is littered with the
401). wreckage of history’s climate victims. A host of recent
studies have linked civilization collapse in Asia, South
In a funny way, Diamond is right. Though his glib reduction America and Africa to climate change.
of the history of violent colonialism to mere “real estate” is
meant to draw the reader’s attention away from history and Just as in the past, we’d best tread carefully around such
toward nature, to the careful reader the reference does the arguments.
opposite. Real estate is not a natural category. It is a thing
For starters there may be a more useful correspondence to
of value only because it exists as private property. And
consider: the prevalence of claims by climate scientists of a
property, of course, is all about the power to exclude,
link between climate and the collapse of past civilizations
forever enforcing the unequal distribution of resources as a
corresponds to the return of environmental determinist
way to preserve class difference.
explanation in the mid-1990s.
In a scathing review in the journal Antipode in 2003, a host
In 1995, around the same time that Diamond found success
of prominent human geographers pilloried Diamond’s work.
peddling his determinist snake oil, researchers reported in
Andrew Sluyter called it “junk science.” Paul Robbins, more
the prestigious journal Nature that population growth and
kind than Sluyter, chided Diamond for harnessing “a
drought was a likely cause of the demise of the Maya
civilization. This work kicked off a cottage industry among movement to interrupt current patterns of global
climate scientists who suddenly found correspondences greenhouse gas emissions.
everywhere they looked: Mesopotamia, west Asia, Egypt,
the Maghreb. There are two problems with this thinking.

The recent raft of historical climate collapse stories are First, we may want to ask what kind of contemporary
troubling for a number of reasons. climate politics the rhetoric of collapse engenders. There is,
no doubt, a real urgency to the problem posed by climate
First, what many of these studies refer to as “collapse” is in change. The climate is indeed changing and transforming in
fact a slow population decline over a period of, often, ways not conducive to humans and other beings. The idea
hundreds of years. The “collapse” of the Maya occurred, for of a climate catastrophism, however, so prevalent in the
example, between 750 AD and 900 AD: hundreds of years rhetoric of historical climate change research, displaces and
of decline (what scientists mean by “decline”, by the way, is defers this urgency. If our fate is apocalypse, after all, what
rarely defined in the scientific literature) that overlaps with a good is grassroots organizing?
period of climate change.
Moreover, the false panic of apocalyptic rhetoric provides
“Climate change,” like “collapse” also is frequently ill- the rationale to ignore the current suffering of the
defined; often these “abrupt” shifts in temperature and marginalized and the disenfranchised. When we strip away
precipitation are, in fact, changes that occur over hundreds the apocalyptic rhetoric, we can see that we are not all in
of years and millions of square miles. In the case of the this together. But apocalyptic rhetoric forecloses the
Maya, the period of dramatic climate change occurred possibility of radical democratic politics. It makes politics, in
during a two-hundred year period between 800 AD and fact, impossible. In its place we are forced to entrust our
1,000 AD—a period that marked the driest in the middle futures to a non-democratic techno-managerial elite, to the
Holocene. apparatuses of state bureaucracies, to the military, and
even to the corporations (Kyoto, for example) who profit
In addition, it should be noted that the increase in historical from climate catastrophism.
climate collapse research corresponds to the popularization
of the wide acceptance of contemporary anthropogenic As a result of this state of affairs, catastrophism research
climate change research. Whether researchers are explicit proliferates and finds purchase among a powerful minority
or not, the rationale for historical work on the link between who fear the potential of radical and democratic climate
climate and collapse, particularly among funding agencies change struggle—particularly the possibility that it could
and the general public, has everything to do with the current challenge existing patterns of class and race privilege. And
climate crisis. These are the what’s-in-store-for-us stories they can’t have that.
peddled in the hope that it may galvanize a broad-based

The Geography of Poverty and Wealth

Jeffrey D. Sachs, Andrew D. Mellinger, and John L. Gallup

Why are some countries stupendously rich and others horrendously poor? Social theorists have been
captivated by this question since the late 18th century, when Scottish economist Adam Smith addressed the
issue in his magisterial work The Wealth of Nations. Smith argued that the best prescription for prosperity is
a free-market economy in which the government allows businesses substantial freedom to pursue profits.
Over the past two centuries, Smith's hypothesis has been vindicated by the striking success of capitalist
economies in North America, western Europe and East Asia and by the dismal failure of socialist planning
in eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union.

Smith, however, made a second notable hypothesis: that the physical geography of a region can influence
its economic performance. He contended that the economies of coastal regions, with their easy access to
sea trade, usually outperform the economies of inland areas. Although most economists today follow Smith
in linking prosperity with free markets, they have tended to neglect the role of geography. They implicitly
assume that all parts of the world have the same prospects for economic growth and long-term
development and that differences in performance are the result of differences in institutions. Our findings,
based on newly available data and research methods, suggest otherwise. We have found strong evidence
that geography plays an important role in shaping the distribution of world income and economic growth.

Coastal regions and those near navigable waterways are indeed far richer and more densely settled than
interior regions, just as Smith predicted. Moreover, an area's climate can also affect its economic
development. Nations in tropical climate zones generally face higher rates of infectious disease and lower
agricultural productivity (especially for staple foods) than do nations in temperate zones. Similar burdens
apply to the desert zones. The very poorest regions in the world are those saddled with both handicaps:
distance from sea trade and a tropical or desert ecology.

A skeptical reader with a basic understanding of geography might comment at this point, "Fine, but isn't all
of this familiar?" We have three responses. First, we go far beyond the basics by systematically quantifying
the contributions of geography, economic policy and other factors in determining a nation's performance.
We have combined the research tools used by geographers – including new software that can create
detailed maps of global population density – with the techniques and equations of macroeconomics.
Second, the basic lessons of geography are worth repeating, because most economists have ignored them.
In the past decade the vast majority of papers on economic development have neglected even the most
obvious geographical realities.

Third, if our findings are true, the policy implications are significant. Aid programs for developing countries
will have to be revamped to specifically address the problems imposed by geography. In particular, we have
tried to formulate new strategies that would help nations in tropical zones raise their agricultural productivity
and reduce the prevalence of diseases such as malaria.

The Geographical Divide

The best single indicator of prosperity is gross national product (GNP) per capita – the total value of a
country's economic output, divided by its population. A map showing the world distribution of GNP per
capita immediately reveals the vast gap between rich and poor nations [see map on page 74]. Notice that
the great majority of the poorest countries lie in the geographical tropics – the area between the tropic of
Cancer and the tropic of Capricorn. In contrast, most of the richest countries lie in the temperate zones.

A more precise picture of this geographical divide can be obtained by defining tropical regions by climate
rather than by latitude. The map on page 75 divides the world into five broad climate zones based on a
classification scheme developed by German climatologists Wladimir P. Köppen and Rudolph Geiger. The
five zones are tropical-subtropical (hereafter referred to as tropical), desert-steppe (desert), temperate-snow
(temperate), highland and polar. The zones are defined by measurements of temperature and precipitation.
We excluded the polar zone from our analysis because it is largely uninhabited.

Among the 28 economies categorized as high income by the World Bank (with populations of at least one
million), only Hong Kong, Singapore and part of Taiwan are in the tropical zone, representing a mere 2
percent of the combined population of the high-income regions. Almost all the temperate-zone countries
have either high-income economies (as in the cases of North America, western Europe, Korea and Japan)
or middle-income economies burdened by socialist policies in the past (as in the cases of eastern Europe,
the former Soviet Union and China). In addition, there is a strong temperate-tropical divide within countries
that straddle both types of climates. Most of Brazil, for example, lies within the tropical zone, but the richest
part of the nation – the southernmost states – is in the temperate zone.

The importance of access to sea trade is also evident in the world map of GNP per capita. Regions far from
the sea, such as the landlocked countries of South America, Africa and Asia, tend to be considerably poorer
than their coastal counterparts. The differences between coastal and interior areas show up even more
strongly in a world map delineating GNP density – that is, the amount of economic output per square
kilometer [see illustration on pages 70 and 71]. This map is based on a detailed survey of global population
densities in 1994. Geographic information system software is used to divide the world's land area into five-
minute-by-five-minute sections (about 100 square kilometers at the equator). One can estimate the GNP
density for each section by multiplying its population density and its GNP per capita. Researchers must use
national averages of GNP per capita when regional estimates are not available. To make sense of the data,
we have classified the world's regions in broad categories defined by climate and proximity to the sea. We
call a region "near" if it lies within 100 kilometers of a seacoast or a sea-navigable waterway (a river, lake or
canal in which oceangoing vessels can operate) and "far" otherwise. Regions in each of the four climate
zones we analyzed can be either near or far, resulting in a total of eight categories. The table on the next
page shows how the world's population, income and land area are divided among these regions.

The breakdown reveals some striking patterns. Global production is highly concentrated in the coastal
regions of temperate climate zones. Regions in the "temperate-near" category constitute a mere 8.4 percent
of the world's inhabited land area, but they hold 22.8 percent of the world's population and produce 52.9
percent of the world's GNP. Per capita income in these regions is 2.3 times greater than the global average,
and population density is 2.7 times greater. In contrast, the "tropical-far" category is the poorest, with a per
capita GNP only about one third of the world average.

Interpreting the Patterns

In our research we have examined three major ways in which geography affects economic development.
First, as Adam Smith noted, economies differ in their ease of transporting goods, people and ideas.
Because sea trade is less costly than land- or air-based trade, economies near coastlines have a great
advantage over hinterland economies. The per-kilometer costs of overland trade within Africa, for example,
are often an order of magnitude greater than the costs of sea trade to an African port. Here are some
figures we found recently: The cost of shipping a six-meter-long container from Rotterdam, the Netherlands,
to Dar-es-Salaam, Tanzania – an air distance of 7,300 kilometers – was about $1,400. But transporting the
same container overland from Dar-es-Salaam to Kigali, Rwanda – a distance of 1,280 kilometers by road –
cost about $2,500, or nearly twice as much.

Second, geography affects the prevalence of disease. Many kinds of infectious diseases are endemic to the
tropical and subtropical zones. This tends to be true of diseases in which the pathogen spends part of its life
cycle outside the human host: for instance, malaria (carried by mosquitoes) and helminthic infections
(caused by parasitic worms). Although epidemics of malaria have occurred sporadically as far north as
Boston in the past century, the disease has never gained a lasting foothold in the temperate zones,
because the cold winters naturally control the mosquito-based transmission of the disease. (Winter could be
considered the world's most effective public health intervention.) It is much more difficult to control malaria
in tropical regions, where transmission takes place year-round and affects a large part of the population.

According to the World Health Organization, 300 million to 500 million new cases of malaria occur every
year, almost entirely concentrated in the tropics. The disease is so common in these areas that no one
really knows how many people it kills annually – at least one million and perhaps as many as 2.3 million.
Widespread illness and early deaths obviously hold back a nation's economic performance by significantly
reducing worker productivity. But there are also long-term effects that may be amplified over time through
various social feedbacks.

For example, a high incidence of disease can alter the age structure of a country's population. Societies
with high levels of child mortality tend to have high levels of fertility: mothers bear many children to
guarantee that at least some will survive to adulthood. Young children will therefore constitute a large
proportion of that country's population. With so many children, poor families cannot invest much in each
child's education. High fertility also constrains the role of women in society, because child rearing takes up
so much of their adult lives.

Third, geography affects agricultural productivity. Of the major food grains – wheat, maize and rice – wheat
grows only in temperate climates, and maize and rice crops are generally more productive in temperate and
subtropical climates than in tropical zones. On average, a hectare of land in the tropics yields 2.3 metric
tons of maize, whereas a hectare in the temperate zone yields 6.4 tons. Farming in tropical rain-forest
environments is hampered by the fragility of the soil: high temperatures mineralize the organic materials,
and the intense rainfall leaches them out of the soil. In tropical environments that have wet and dry
seasons–such as the African savanna–farmers must contend with the rapid loss of soil moisture resulting
from high temperatures, the great variability of precipitation, and the ever present risk of drought. Moreover,
tropical environments are plagued with diverse infestations of pests and parasites that can devastate both
crops and livestock.

Many of the efforts to improve food output in tropical regions–attempted first by the colonial powers and
then in recent decades by donor agencies–have ended in failure. Typically the agricultural experts blithely
tried to transfer temperate-zone farming practices to the tropics, only to watch livestock and crops succumb
to pests, disease and climate barriers. What makes the problem even more complex is that food
productivity in tropical regions is also influenced by geologic and topographic conditions that vary greatly
from place to place. The island of Java, for example, can support highly productive farms because the
volcanic soil there suffers less nutrient depletion than the non-volcanic soil of the neighboring islands of
Indonesia.

Moderate advantages or disadvantages in geography can lead to big differences in long-term economic
performance. For example, favorable agricultural or health conditions may boost per capita income in
temperate-zone nations and hence increase the size of their economies. This growth encourages inventors
in those nations to create products and services to sell into the larger and richer markets. The resulting
inventions further raise economic output, spurring yet more inventive activity. The moderate geographical
advantage is thus amplified through innovation.

In contrast, the low food output per farm worker in tropical regions tends to diminish the size of cities, which
depend on the agricultural hinterland for their sustenance. With a smaller proportion of the population in
urban areas, the rate of technological advance is usually slower. The tropical regions therefore remain more
rural than the temperate regions, with most of their economic activity concentrated in low-technology
agriculture rather than in high-technology manufacturing and services.

We must stress, however, that geographical factors are only part of the story. Social and economic
institutions are critical to long-term economic performance. It is particularly instructive to compare the post-
World War II performance of free-market and socialist economies in neighboring countries that share the
same geographical characteristics: North and South Korea, East and West Germany, the Czech Republic
and Austria, and Estonia and Finland. In each case we find that free-market institutions vastly outperformed
socialist ones.

The main implication of our findings is that policymakers should pay more attention to the developmental
barriers associated with geography–specifically, poor health, low agricultural productivity and high
transportation costs. For example, tropical economies should strive to diversify production into
manufacturing and service sectors that are not hindered by climate conditions. The successful countries of
tropical Southeast Asia, most notably Malaysia, have achieved stunning advances in the past 30 years, in
part by addressing public health problems and in part by moving their economies away from climate-
dependent commodity exports (rubber, palm oil and so on) to electronics, semiconductors and other
industrial sectors. They were helped by the high concentration of their populations in coastal areas near
international sea lanes and by the relatively tractable conditions for the control of malaria and other tropical
diseases. Sub-Saharan Africa is not so fortunate: most of its population is located far from the coasts, and
its ecological conditions are harsher on human health and agriculture.

The World Bank and the International Monetary Fund, the two international agencies that are most
influential in advising developing countries, currently place more emphasis on institutional reforms–for
instance, overhauling a nation's civil service or its tax administration–than on the technologies needed to
fight tropical diseases and low agricultural productivity. One formidable obstacle is that pharmaceutical
companies have no market incentive to address the health problems of the world's poor. Therefore,
wealthier nations should adopt policies to increase the companies' motivation to work on vaccines for
tropical diseases. In one of our own initiatives, we called on the governments of wealthy nations to foster
greater research and development by pledging to buy vaccines for malaria, HIV/AIDS and tuberculosis from
the pharmaceutical companies at a reasonable price. Similarly, biotechnology and agricultural research
companies need more incentive to study how to improve farm output in tropical regions.

The poorest countries in the world surely lack the resources to relieve their geographical burdens on their
own. Sub-Saharan African countries have per capita income levels of around $1 a day. Even when such
countries invest as much as 3 or 4 percent of their GNP in public health–a large proportion of national
income for a very poor country–the result is only about $10 to $15 per year per person. This is certainly not
enough to control endemic malaria, much less to fight other rampant diseases such as HIV/AIDS,
tuberculosis and helminthic infections.

A serious effort at global development will require not just better economic policies in the poor countries but
far more financial support from the rich countries to help overcome the special problems imposed by
geography. A preliminary estimate suggests that even a modest increase in donor financing of about $25
billion per year–only 0.1 percent of the total GNP of the wealthy nations, or about $28 per person–could
make a tremendous difference in reducing disease and increasing food productivity in the world's poorest
countries.

Potrebbero piacerti anche