Sei sulla pagina 1di 186

2014 Energy Risk Professional

ERP Exam Course Pack

READINGS THAT ARE FREELY AVAILABLE ON THE GARP WEBSITE

Readings for Oil, Gas and Coal Markets

In addition to the published readings listed, the Oil, Gas, and Coal Markets section of the 2014 ERP
Study Guide includes several additional readings from online sources that are freely available on
the GARP website (link to 2014 Online Readings). These readings include learning objectives that
cover specialized topics or current trends in global oil, gas, and coal markets that are unavailable in
traditional text books.

The 2014 ERP Examination will include questions drawn from the following AIMs for each reading:

Crude Oil Benchmarks, Global Pricing and Market Transactions


1. William Bailey, Benoit Couet, Ashish Bhandari, Soussan Faiz, Sunaram Srinivasan and
Helen Weeds. Unlocking the Value of Real Options. (Oilfield Review, 2004).
• Understand and apply a net present value (NPV) calculation to make investment
decisions in a gas/oil field.
• Explain how a binomial lattice is used in the valuation of an asset or option and be
able to calculate the value of an up or down move.
• Describe of the use of real options in circumstances such as switching or salvage
decisions with an existing oil or gas project.

2. Bassam Fattouh. An Anatomy of the Crude Oil Pricing System.


(The Oxford Institute for Energy Studies). (Sections 3 to 9 only)
• Summarize the process used to determine price differentials and identify factors that
influence the price differential including the equivalence to the buyer principle.
• Describe the role of price reporting agencies (PRAs) in price identification; summarize
the methodologies used by PRAs to assess commodity prices, and identify criticisms
of PRA price assessment.
• Understand the mechanics and specifications of the 21-day BFOE (Forward Brent), the
Brent Futures, the Exchange for Physical (EFP) and the Dated Brent/BFOE contracts.
• Define Contracts for Differences (CFDs) and understand its application when hedging
basis risk associated with Forward Brent contracts or deriving forward prices from a
combination of Dated Brent prices and CFDs.
• Understand the relationship between futures contracts and physical supply.
• Compare and contrast the Brent, WTI, and Dubai-Oman crude oil benchmarks in terms
of liquidity, price transparency, and available financial products.
• Summarize the mechanics of WTI futures contracts including related delivery require-
ments, and compare WTI Posting-Plus (P-Plus) pricing to NYMEX CMA pricing.
• Understand the logistical challenges that can impact the effectiveness of WTI as a
global crude oil benchmark.
• Explain how the Dubai benchmark price can be calculated using swaps.

© 2014 Global Association of Risk Professionals. All rights reserved.


2014 Energy Risk Professional
ERP Exam Course Pack

READINGS THAT ARE FREELY AVAILABLE ON THE GARP WEBSITE

Readings for Oil, Gas and Coal Markets

Petroleum Refining
3. Brent Yacobucci. Analysis of Renewable Identification Numbers (RINs) in the Renewable
Fuel Standard. (Congressional Research Service, July 2013).
• Describe Renewable Identification Numbers (RINs) and explain how RINs are
produced and traded.
• Summarize the mechanics of the Renewable Fuels Standard (RFS) and describe the
classes and categories of RINs which can be used to meet biofuel requirements as
part of the RFS.
• Describe factors which can impact the market prices of RINs.

The Global Natural Gas Market


4. International Gas Union. Wholesale Gas Price Formation—A Global View of Price Drivers
and Regional Trends. (Sections 1 to 5 and 8 to 10 only)
• Understand and apply the following natural gas pricing terms: wellhead price,
border/beach price, hub price, citygate price, end user price and netback price.
• Describe potential short, medium and long-term supply-side and demand-side drivers
for natural gas prices.
• Summarize the eight key mechanisms for pricing gas and identify the geographic
regions where each mechanism is most prevalent.
• Describe the relationship between a local gas pricing mechanism, the observed
market price and the hypothetical market-clearing price.
• Identify the factors that influence the volatility of natural gas prices, including
oil-linked prices.
• Assess the relationship between price volatility and natural gas supply across various
hypothetical price levels.

© 2014 Global Association of Risk Professionals. All rights reserved.


2014 Energy Risk Professional
ERP Exam Course Pack

READINGS THAT ARE FREELY AVAILABLE ON THE GARP WEBSITE

Readings for Oil, Gas and Coal Markets

Global Coal Markets


5. Richard Morse and Gang He, “The World's Greatest Coal Arbitrage: China's Coal Import
Behavior and Implications for the Global Coal Market.” (PESD Stanford, August 2010).
• Understand the basic economics of the Chinese coal market; compare domestic
reserves to domestic demand.
• Explain the arbitrage opportunities available to coal buyers in southern China.
• Describe the role of freight costs in setting coal market prices.
• Explain how Chinese arbitrage has impacted prices on the global coal market.

© 2014 Global Association of Risk Professionals. All rights reserved.


Unlocking the Value of Real Options

Management often has flexibility in carrying out projects, capitalizing on new


information and new market conditions to improve project economics. Real-options
analysis provides a means to determine the value of flexibility in future activities.

William Bailey In the early 1990s, Houston-based Anadarko possibly hidden or even invisible when DCF is
Benoît Couët Petroleum Corporation outbid competitors for used alone. Some companies that use ROV are
Ridgefield, Connecticut, USA the Tanzanite block in the Gulf of Mexico. It reluctant to divulge parameter details of their
found oil and gas there in 1998 and was produc- models because of fears that revealing those
Ashish Bhandari ing within three years. The Tanzanite discovery details gives away a competitive advantage.
El Paso Corporation
is significant not so much for an abundance of ROV is not on the verge of displacing DCF.
Houston, Texas, USA
oil and gas, but that in bidding for it Anadarko In fact, real-options valuation employs DCF as
Soussan Faiz broke with industry tradition. Rather than using one of its tools. In practice, ROV combines and
Strategic Management Consultant only conventional discounted cash flow (DCF) to integrates the best of scenario planning,
Walton on Thames, Surrey, England help it decide what the block was worth and how portfolio management, decision analysis and
much to bid for the lease, the company opted for option pricing.
Sundaram Srinivasan a new technique called real-options valuation This article reviews DCF and describes how
Sugar Land, Texas (ROV). ROV gave Anadarko the confidence to ROV overcomes some, but not all, of its short-
outbid others because it suggested that there comings. After explaining the parallels and
Helen Weeds was more to Tanzanite than met the eye. 1 differences between financial options and real
University of Essex Anadarko now routinely uses ROV when making options, it examines two of the many methods of
Colchester, England
investment decisions. valuing options, the Black-Scholes formula
Options embedded in, or attached to, physi- and binomial lattices. ROV is illustrated by a
cal or real assets are real options. These are case study of a liquefied natural gas (LNG)
distinct from options relating to financial transport option. A series of linked, synthetic
assets—securities and other financial claims. examples describes several simple forms of
ROV is a process by which a real or tangible binomial lattices.
asset with real uncertainties can be valued in a
coherent manner when flexibility—or potential Discounting Cash Flows
for options—is present. Discounted cash flow analysis is relatively
Most oil companies still use DCF to appraise simple. It predicts a stream of cash flows, in and
potential investments. This method has served out, over the expected life of a project, then dis-
them well. Increasingly, however, companies are counts them at a rate—typically the weighted
asking whether ROV might be used to comple- average cost of capital (WACC)—that reflects
ment DCF. ROV supporters argue that it gives a both the time value of money and the riskiness
truer value than DCF only because the ROV of those cash flows. The time value of money
model more closely reflects the variability and indicates that money held in the future is worth
uncertainty in the world. ROV often can high- less than money held now, because money we
light extra value in projects, value that is

4 Oilfield Review
Oil price

Time

have in hand can be invested and earn interest, Time n Cash flow Discount Present value
whereas future money cannot.2 factor of cash flow
The crucial item in any DCF calculation is Present 0 –5000 1.0000 –5000
net present value (NPV), the present value of One year 1 +4500 0.9091 +4091
cash inflows minus the present value of cash Two years 2 +3000 0.8264 +2479
outflows, or investments (right). A positive NPV Undiscounted cash flow +2500
indicates that the investment creates value. A Net present value +1570
negative NPV indicates that the project as Discount factor = 1/(1+Discount rate) .
n

planned destroys value. > Net present value (NPV) calculation. A discount factor—based on a 10%
A DCF analysis provides clear, consistent discount rate—applied to future cash flows indicates the greater value of cash
decision criteria for all projects (see “Working in hand compared with future cash. In this case, the difference between the
Out Net Present Value,” page 6). However, it also NPV and undiscounted cash flow is almost a thousand, regardless of the
currency used.
has limitations:3
• DCF is static. It assumes that a project plan is
frozen and unalterable and that management
is passive and follows the original plan irre-
spective of changing circumstances. However,
management tends to modify plans as circum- For help in preparation of this article, thanks to Steve 2. Hussey R (ed): Oxford Dictionary of Accounting.
Brochu, BP, Houston, Texas. Oxford, England: Oxford University Press (1999): 131.
stances change and uncertainties are
ECLIPSE is a mark of Schlumberger. In a deflationary economy, money in the future may not
resolved. Management interventions tend to 1. Coy P: “Exploiting Uncertainty,” Business Week be worth less than money held now.
add value to that calculated by DCF analysis. (US edition) no. 3632 (June 7, 1999): 118–124. 3. Mun J: Real Options Analysis: Tools and Techniques for
Valuing Strategic Investments and Decisions. New York,
New York, USA: John Wiley & Sons (2002): 59.

Winter 2003/2004 5
A Synthetic-Reservoir Example
Working Out Net Present Value

A series of examples using a fictitious field


and simple synthetic models is presented in
this article to illustrate some key valuation
concepts. This section sets up the case and
Period Time, years Total development cost,
determines the net present value (NPV). million $
The fictitious Charon field in the Sargasso 1 0.6 50.0
Sea is an anticline, divided into two blocks by 2 1.2 75.0
a fault. The reservoir interval consists of shal- 3 1.8 107.5
low marine sediments up to 200-ft [61-m] 4 2.4 150.0
thick, capped by a sealing shale. The operator, 5 3.0 177.5
Oberon Oil, has devised a development plan to
> Investment schedule for the synthetic Charon
obtain first oil in three years. The plan calls
field. The three-year construction schedule is
for drilling six wells tied back to a dedicated broken into five equal-length time periods. These
production platform that can handle 50 mil- five time steps are used in later examples.
lion scf/D [1.4 million m3/d] of produced gas
from the live oil. Expected development costs
will be $177.5 million spread over three years
(above right).
Company experts assign values to key
reservoir properties, such as porosity and per-
meability, based on probability distributions
Well 1 Well 5
(below right). The oil/water contact is not
Well 2 Well 4
known precisely, which impacts the estimate
of oil in place. Several geological realizations Well 6
are constructed and used for simulation mod- Well 3

els. Hydrocarbon resources are computed for


low, median and high estimates—considered
representative of the oil in place occurring at
the 5%, 50% and 95% values of the probability
distribution (next page, top).
Decision-making is based on these three
representative scenarios. ECLIPSE oil produc-
tion predictions are made for each realization
(next page, bottom). Oil production decline
with time for this fictitious case can reason-
ably be modeled as a hyperbolic function,
making the results easier to use for predic-
tion. A standard discounted cash flow (DCF)
model computes project NPV. The oil price is
assumed to be $25/bbl at the start of the pro-
Oil saturation
ject and to increase 1% per year, with a tax
rate of 33% for net positive revenue and no 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8
tax paid for negative net revenue. In this sce- > Reservoir model of the synthetic Charon field. This ECLIPSE reservoir model provided input for
nario, the median-case NPV for Charon field obtaining production predictions, using a large number of simulations with geostatistically
is $236.3 million. derived porosity and permeability values.

6 Oilfield Review
• DCF assumes future cash flows are predictable
and deterministic. In practice, it is often
difficult to estimate cash flows, and DCF can
often overvalue or undervalue certain types
Oil/water Field-wide average, Average Original oil Initial oil
contact ratio of net-to- porosity in place, production,
of projects.
depth, ft gross thickness million BOE B/D • Most DCF analyses use a WACC discount fac-
Low 9625 0.65 12.5% 138.6 25,384 tor. But instead of a WACC, companies often
Median 9650 0.75 14.4% 228.2 27,930
use a company-wide hurdle rate that may be
unrepresentative of the actual risks inherent
High 9675 0.85 16.3% 350.4 28,225
in a specific project.
> Results of model realizations. Three models represent the low (5%), median The first two limitations relate to circum-
(50%) and high (95%) production predictions in Charon field. stances changing after a project begins. A new
DCF analysis can be performed to reflect the new
circumstances, but it may be too late to influence
basic project decisions, since the project is
already under way. The third limitation above
results from companies adopting a company-wide
hurdle rate for consistency rather than carefully
30,000 recalculating a WACC for each project.
A sensitivity analysis can enhance information
25,000 provided by DCF analysis. The consequences of
possible changes to key variables—for example,
Production rate, B/D

20,000 interest rates, cash flows and timing—are evalu-


ated to determine the results of a number of
15,000 “what if” scenarios. However, the choice of which
High
variables to alter and how much to alter them is
10,000 subjective.4 Sensitivity analysis makes assump-
Median
Low tions about future contingencies, rather than
5,000 incorporating those contingencies as they occur.

0 Embracing Uncertainty and Adding Value


0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 4000 4500 5000 5500 6000
Time, days
Unlike DCF, ROV assumes that the world is
characterized by change, uncertainty and
competitive interactions among companies. It
250 also assumes that management has the flexi-
236.3
200 bility to adapt and revise future decisions in
150 response to changing circumstances. 5 Uncer-
tainty becomes another problem component to
Present value, million $

100
Median case be managed. The future is regarded as one that
50 is full of alternatives and options, both of which
0 may add value.
The word option implies added value. When
–50
we speak of keeping our options open, having
–100 more than one option, or not foreclosing on our
–150 options, the underlying implication is that just
holding the option usually has value, whether or
–200
0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 3000 3500 4000 4500 5000 5500 6000 not we exercise it. The same is true of real options.
Time, days
4. Bailey W, Couët B, Lamb F, Simpson G and Rose P:
“Taking a Calculated Risk,” Oilfield Review 12, no. 3
> Calculation of Charon net present value (NPV). Production begins in the third year of the project
(Autumn 2000): 20–35.
and declines (top). The low (5%), median (50%) and high (95%) probability model predictions are 5. Trigeorgis L: “Real Options: A Primer,” in Alleman J
shown. The project’s cumulative cash flow for the median case shows the expenditures in the and Noam E (eds): The New Investment Theory of Real
first three years followed by income over the remainder of the project (bottom). The median-case Options and Its Implications for Telecommunications
NPV of the project is $236.3 million. Economics. Boston, Massachusetts, USA: Kluwer
(1999): 3.

Winter 2003/2004 7
Real-options analysis draws heavily on the ROV allows managers to evaluate real Money spent on seismic surveys and exploration
theory of financial options.6 Financial options options to add value to their firms, by giving drilling is analogous to the exercise price; the
are derivatives; they derive their value from managers a tool to recognize and act upon resources are analogous to the stock. An explo-
other underlying assets, such as shares of a com- opportunities to amplify gain or to mitigate loss.9 ration option expires the day the lease terminates.
pany stock. A financial option is the right, but While many managers are not accustomed to Once the company has exercised its option to
not the obligation, to buy or sell a share on (or evaluating real options, they are familiar with explore, it is in a position to decide whether to
sometimes before) a particular date at a particu- the concept of project intangibles. ROV gives exercise a second option, the option to develop
lar price. The price at which a share can be managers a tool to move some of those intangi- the field. This gives the company the right, but
bought or sold, if the option holder chooses to bles into a realm where they can be dealt with in not the obligation, to develop the resources at
exercise the right, is known as the exercise, or a tangible and coherent fashion. any time up to the relinquishment date of the
strike, price. The two main kinds of options are a Petroleum developments and mining opera- lease for an amount of money given by the cost
call option—to buy the share at the exercise tions were among the first examples used by of development. If the company exercises the
price—and a put option—to sell the share at ROV pioneers to demonstrate the parallels development option, it obtains hydrocarbon
the exercise price (below right). between real and financial options (see “How Oil resources that are ready to be produced.
If the share price exceeds the exercise price, Companies Use Real-Options Valuation,” next The final option is the option to produce. The
a call option is said to be in the money. If it page).10 The exploration, development and pro- company now has the right, but not the obliga-
exceeds it by a large amount, it is termed deep duction stages of an oilfield project can be seen tion, to spend money on extracting the oil and gas
in the money. If the share price fails to reach as a series of linked options.11 from the ground and sending it to market. It will
the exercise price, the option is said to be out of At the exploration stage, the company has do so only if a number of uncertainties are
the money. An investor would not exercise an the option to spend money on exploration and, resolved, most notably that the oil price is likely
out-of-the-money option since doing so would in return, receive prospective oil and gas to reach a level that makes production profitable.
cost more than the market price for the share. resources. This is like a stock option, which This series of options is called a sequential
This is where the caveat that the option holder gives the holder the right, but not the obligation, or compound option because each option
has the right but not the obligation to buy the to pay the exercise price and receive the stock. depends on the earlier exercise of another one.12
share at the exercise price is important. The
investor allows the option to lapse if exercising
it would not be beneficial.
Financial options can be further subdivided
into many types.7 Two of the most common are
European and American options. A European Call option—the right, but not the obligation, to buy shares at the exercise price within
option can be exercised only on the expiration a given time period.
date specified in the option contract. An Put option—the right, but not the obligation, to sell shares at the exercise price within a
American option may be exercised at any time given time period.
up to and including the expiration date. Widgets, Inc., has a moderately volatile share price with a current price of $100. For a
Options have two important features. First, small fee, an investor may buy a call option with an exercise price of $110. If the share
they give an option holder the possibility of a price subsequently rises to $120, the option holder would exercise the option to buy the
large upside gain while protecting from down- shares for the agreed exercise price of $110 and sell them on the open market for $120,
making a profit of $10 per share less the option-purchase fee.
side risk. Second, they are more valuable when
uncertainty and risks are higher. Alternatively, if the investor has a put option with an exercise price of $90 and shares of
Widgets, Inc. fall below $90, it will benefit the option holder to buy shares from the open
market at the lower price and exercise the option to sell them at $90. Both examples
Financial and Real Options ignore the usual transaction fees paid to a broker.
Real-options valuation applies the thinking
behind financial options to evaluate physical, or > Call and put options.
real, assets. By analogy with a financial option, a
real option is the right, but not the obligation, to
take an action affecting a real physical asset at a
predetermined cost for a predetermined period
of time—the life of the option.8 While real and
6. Bishop M: Pocket Economist. London, England: Profile 9. Brealey R and Myers S: Principles of Corporate Finance,
financial options have many similarities, the Books in association with The Economist Newspaper 6th Edition. Boston, Massachusetts, USA: Irwin/
analogy is not exact. (2000): 197. McGraw-Hill (2000): 619.
7. Wilmott P: Paul Wilmott on Quantitative Finance, 10. Paddock J, Siegel R and Smith J: “Option Valuation of
vol 1. New York, New York, USA: John Wiley & Sons Claims on Real Assets: The Case of Offshore Petroleum
(2000): 217. Leases,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 103, no. 3
8. An option may be attached to a real asset or to cash (August 1988): 479–485.
flows associated with that asset. Stewart Myers first 11. This simple series of linked options ignores any
coined the term “real options” in 1985. For more informa- contractual obligations to drill or develop that may
tion: Copeland T and Antikarov V: Real Options: A accompany a lease.
Practitioner’s Guide. New York, New York, USA: Texere 12. Copeland and Antikarov, reference 8: 12–13.
(2001): 5.

8 Oilfield Review
How Oil Companies Use Real-Options Valuation

Companies as diverse as BP, ChevronTexaco, Corporation, to hold its interests in 9500 wells stage, uncertainties about the amount of oil
Statoil, Anadarko and El Paso have shown an spread across more than 300 fields. Apache and gas in place had been resolved. In the
interest in real-options valuation (ROV). They indicated interest in obtaining the properties, development phase, the operator could decide
usually regard it as complementary to tech- but Iraq’s invasion of Kuwait in the spring of to develop the field using conventional means
niques like discounted cash flow (DCF) and that year had pushed oil prices to historic or wait and develop the field using new subsea
decision-tree analysis rather than as a stand- heights while increasing price uncertainty. completion technology that at that time was
alone method of valuation. Amoco and Apache agreed on most of the still at the research and development stage.
In the mid-1990s, the executive manage- provisions for the MW Petroleum transaction, Conventional analysis neglecting the value
ment of Texaco (now ChevronTexaco) was but disagreed on oil-price projections. The gap of flexibility showed that development of the
split over what to do with a significant lease- was about 10 percent. The two companies field using current technology would yield a
holding in a developing country. The lease found common ground by agreeing to share value of $4 million. Including the flexibility
included several existing oil discoveries and the risk of future oil-price movements. Amoco associated with being able to wait until new
many other substantial undeveloped discover- gave Apache a guarantee that if oil prices fell technology was available—using a deferral
ies. It was at an early stage of exploitation.1 below an agreed price-support level in the option and waiting until the new technology
Part of the management team wanted to sell first two years after the sale, Amoco would was ready—increased the value to $50 million.
the asset, using the proceeds for more capital- make compensating payments to Apache. For
efficient projects, while others on the team its part, Apache would pay Amoco if oil or gas 1. Faiz S: “Real-Options Application: From Successes in
Asset Valuation to Challenges for an Enterprise Wide
felt it could lead to other lucrative follow-up prices exceeded a designated price-sharing Approach,” paper SPE 68243, Journal of Petroleum
opportunities and the development of valu- level. The MW Petroleum portfolio included Technology 53, no. 1 (January 2001): 42–47, 74. This
paper was revised for publication from paper SPE
able relationships in the region. 121 million barrels of oil equivalent (BOE) 62964, originally presented at the SPE Annual Techni-
The company management used ROV to [19.2 million m3] of proven oil and gas cal Conference and Exhibition, Dallas, Texas, USA,
October 1–4, 2000.
decide which action would be better for the reserves, plus 143 million BOE [22.7 million 2. Faiz, reference 1.
company. Results from the ROV substantiated m3] of probable and possible reserves. 3. Chorn L and Sharma A: “Project Valuation: Progressing
parts of both viewpoints. Even after key This transaction was reexamined by inde- from Certainty through Passive Uncertainty to Active
Project Management,” paper SPE 77585, presented at
options values had been included, the ROV pendent analysts in 2002. They compared a the SPE Annual Technical Conference and Exhibition,
indicated the asset was far less valuable than deterministic DCF valuation of MW Petroleum San Antonio, Texas, USA, September 29–October 2,
2002.
suggested by DCF. However, there was suffi- assets with a real-options valuation. The DCF 4. Tufano P: “How Financial Engineering Can Advance
cient value to convince Texaco to retain the value of $359.7 million was $80 million less Corporate Strategy,” Harvard Business Review 74,
no. 1 (January–February 1996): 143–144.
asset until some of the uncertainties were than the ROV result of $440.4 million, indicat-
5. In its 2001 annual report, Anadarko says that it “seeks
resolved, but to be prepared to sell if the price ing additional value in the assets not included to maximize enterprise value by maintaining a strong
was right. Moreover, ROV enabled a major in the DCF analysis.4 In comparison, the pur- balance sheet and applying option theory to assist
investment decision-making.”
restructuring of the base plan. Texaco believed chase price agreed on by Amoco and Apache 6. Rutherford SR: “Deep Water Real Options Valuation:
that ROV helped its executives reach a better was $515 million plus 2 million shares of Waiting for Technology,” paper SPE 77584, presented
at the SPE Annual Technical Conference and Exhibi-
strategic understanding of its holding.2 stock. Both methods gave values short of the tion, San Antonio, Texas, USA, September 29–October
A recent analysis of a transaction that took actual price, but the ROV valuation was much 2, 2002.
place in the early 1990s involving Amoco closer than the DCF one.
(now BP) and independent oil and gas com- In a third example, Anadarko, a Houston-
pany Apache Corporation showed how based independent, is an enthusiast for ROV.5
real-options analysis can disclose value that is A recent ROV analysis by the company exam-
not apparent when using DCF analysis alone.3 ined the impact of deferring a project until
In 1991, after a strategic review, Amoco new technologies became available.6
decided to dispose of some marginal oil and Anadarko had a deepwater development
gas properties in the United States. It formed opportunity that the company approached in
a new, separate company, MW Petroleum two stages. At the end of the first, exploration

Winter 2003/2004 9
The extraction option is contingent on exercis- normally fixed. For a real option, this price is The insight of Fischer Black, Myron Scholes
ing the development option, which is contingent associated with development costs, and may be and Robert Merton, who derived the Black-
on exercising the exploration option. At each volatile, fluctuating with market conditions, Scholes-Merton formula—more commonly
stage, a company obtains information to deter- service company prices and rig availability. In the referred to as Black-Scholes—was that options
mine whether the project should be taken to the E&P industry, volatility is usually a consolidated could be priced using the arbitrage principle
next stage. value comprising the uncertainty involved in with a portfolio that is constructed to be risk-
many things, including oil prices and production free, overcoming the need to estimate
Comparing Financial- and rates. Determining volatility in real options can distributions of returns at all.16 They showed that
Real-Option Parameters be difficult. it was possible to establish the value of an
The variables used to value a financial option can Another key difference between financial option by constructing a replicating portfolio,
be compared with their analogs in real options. and real options lies in uncertainties surround- which consists of a number of shares in the
An option to develop oil reserves, for example, is ing an option’s underlying asset. With a financial underlying asset and a number of risk-free
similar to a financial call option (below). option the uncertainty is external. The option is bonds. The portfolio is constructed in such a way
The NPV of the developed hydrocarbon an arrangement between two outsiders— that its cash flows exactly replicate those of the
reserves—what they would be worth at today’s the option writer and the option purchaser— option. Prices of bonds and of underlying shares
prices—is similar to the price of the underlying neither of whom can influence the rate of return are directly observable in the financial market,
stock, S, in a financial option. The NPV of the on the company’s shares.13 In contrast, a com- so the value of the replicating portfolio is known.
expenditure needed to develop the reserves is pany that owns a real option can affect the If the option were sold for a price that is differ-
like a financial option’s exercise price, X. The underlying asset—for example, by developing ent from that of the replicating portfolio, there
time left on an exploration and production new technologies for the asset—and the actions would be two identical assets—the option and
(E&P) lease is equivalent to the time to expira- of competitors—for example, by developing an the replicating portfolio—selling for different
tion of a financial option, T. The risk-free rate of adjacent property first, as described later in this prices at the same time. Any investor would then
return, rf —the rate of return on a guaranteed article—which in turn can affect the nature of use the strategy of arbitrage, buying the cheaper
asset, such as a government bond—is identical the uncertainty that the company faces.14 of the two and selling the more expensive to
for both financial and real options. The volatility profit from the unequal prices.
of cash flows from an E&P project, including Black-Scholes Option Valuation The existence of the replicating portfolio
hydrocarbon price uncertainty, is analogous to Real options often are valued using financial- implies that there is a combination of the option
the volatility of stock prices, σ. Finally, profits option pricing techniques. However, real-option and the underlying asset that is risk-free. In
foregone because production has been delayed valuation can be extremely complex, so any effect, the risk-free rate is used as the discount
are like the lost dividends in the financial financial-option technique can provide only a rate during the option-pricing calculation and is
option, δ. As long as management holds an unex- rough valuation. Two approaches are discussed usually taken to be the interest rate on a govern-
ercised option to invest in a project, it foregoes in this article: the Black-Scholes formula (a ment-guaranteed financial instrument like a US
the money that would have flowed from it had closed-form solution) and binomial lattices. Treasury Bond.17
the project been producing revenue. Early attempts to use DCF to value options The Black-Scholes formula has fairly limited
The analogies between real and financial foundered on the appropriate discount rate to applicability. The formula is a closed-form solu-
options are not exact. Trying to force real use and in calculating the probability distribu- tion to a more general expression—the
options into a conventional financial-options tion of returns from an option. An option is Black-Scholes partial differential equation—
framework may result in misleading outcomes. generally riskier than the underlying stock but for the case of European puts and calls, which
One key difference in the two options types is nobody knows by how much.15 can be exercised only on their maturity date.
that the exercise price of a financial option is Most real options are not analogs of European
options. However, the Black-Scholes partial
differential equation itself has far wider
applicability. With appropriate boundary
Financial and Real Options Compared conditions, this partial differential equation can
Financial call option Variable Real option to develop hydrocarbon reserves be solved—usually numerically—to evaluate
Stock price S Net present value of developed hydrocarbon reserves
many types of options, such as American and
Exercise price X Present value of expenditure to develop reserves
compound options.
Time to expiration T For example, time remaining on lease, time to first oil or gas
A numerical method using binomial lattices
Risk-free interest rate rf Risk-free interest rate
is applicable across a wide range of options.
Volatility of stock price σ Volatility of cash flows from hydrocarbon reserves
Since this process of valuation can be visualized
Dividends foregone δ Revenue or profits foregone
in a diagram, lattices are comparatively easy to
understand, although actual problems typically
> Comparison of financial and real options. The variables of a financial call option can be are more complex than the simple lattices
related to similar variables for a real option to develop oil reserves. shown in this article.

10 Oilfield Review
0 1 2 3 4 5

Probability distribution of
S0u5 future assets

S0u4

S0u3 S0u4d1

S0u2 S0u3d1

S0u1 S0u2d1 S0u3d2

S0 S0u1d1 S0u2d2 Large Lattice


1 1 2
S0d S0u d S0u2d3

S0d2 S0u1d3

S0d3 S0u1d4

Price
u = exp(σ √∆T ) S0d4
d= 1
u S0d5

Probability
> Construction of a lattice of the underlying asset. The deterministic value for the asset today, such as a stock price, goes into the
left-most lattice node (left). In the first time step, this value can increase by a multiplicative factor, u, which is based on the volatility,
σ, and length of the time step, ∆T, or it can decrease by the inverse of that factor, d. Each node in subsequent time steps can similarly
increase or decrease, resulting in an expanding lattice. Results from a five-step lattice are coarse. As the number of steps increases,
∆T becomes smaller and the resolution increases as the lattice becomes larger. A probability distribution of future assets (green
curve) can be obtained from the values in the right-hand column of a lattice with thousands of steps (right). The assumptions
governing the definition of u and d factors always give rise to a log-normal distribution of asset value at expiration—this is a basic
assumption of the Black-Scholes model.

Binomial-Lattice Option Valuation decreases by a multiplicative factor d (between 13. The case of company executives who are given share
Binomial lattices allow analysts to value both 0 and 1), represented as a step up or a step options as an incentive to improve company value is
an exception.
European and American-type options. 18 This down the lattice (above). The factors u and d,
14. Copeland and Antikarov, reference 8: 111–112.
section describes how to construct a lattice for a which determine the upward and downward 15. Ross S and Jaffe J: Corporate Finance. Boston,
simple European call option. movements at each node, are functions of the Massachusetts, USA: Irwin (1990): 576.
A lattice is a way to show how an asset’s volatility of the underlying asset and the length 16. The Black-Scholes formula estimates the value of a call
option, C:
value changes over time, given that the asset has of time between the periods under considera- C = S * e – δ T * {N(d 1)} – Xe – rf T * {N(d 2)},
a particular volatility. A binomial lattice has only tion. The right-hand nodes of the lattice –
where d 1 = {ln(S/X) + (rf - δ + σ2/2) T}/ (σ * √T),

two possible movements in each time step—up represent the distribution of possible future d 2 = d 1 - σ * √T,
and where N(d) = cumulative normal distribution func-
or down. It looks like a fan laid on its side. ROV asset values. tion, ln is the natural logarithm and other terms are
uses two lattices, the lattice of the underlying The most difficult issue in constructing the defined in the text.
asset and the valuation lattice. lattice of the underlying asset is estimating 17. Rogers J: Strategy, Value and Risk—The Real Options
Approach. Basingstoke, England: Palgrave (2002): 61.
Lattice of the underlying asset—The under- volatility. This value must reflect the uncertain- 18. In a European option, uncertainty is assumed to be fully
lying asset pricing lattice, also known simply as ties, both economic and technical, in the value resolved at expiration. However, valuation of American-
type options can be more complex and caution is
the lattice of the underlying, is read from left to of the underlying asset, and the way in which required. An American option can be exercised at any
right and indicates how possible future asset these uncertainties evolve over time.19 Methods time prior to expiration, but that does not mean that all
uncertainty has been resolved at the time the decision is
values could evolve. The value of the left-most for estimating volatility are nontrivial, and a made. New information about project uncertainties is
node is the NPV of the underlying asset, as cal- discussion of these methods is beyond the scope likely to be streaming in all the time, so the decision is
based on incomplete information. Unless all pertinent
culated from the DCF model. In each time of this article. uncertainty has been resolved, it might be prudent to
interval, the value of the asset increases by a wait until the last moment to decide on the option.
multiplicative factor u (greater than 1), or 19. Some ROV specialists argue that it is better to keep
technical and market uncertainties separate, especially
when managerial decision-making is tied to the resolution
of technical uncertainty.

Winter 2003/2004 11
Excercise cost
X = $100
0 1 2 3 4 5
Stock price, S, Synthetic-Reservoir Development Guarantee
Maximum (S–X, 0)
at expiration
Salvage an Investment
$80 $180
A
$67.66
C
$50 $150 Oberon, operator of the fictitious Charon
B field, has reservations about the eventual
economic viability of the field. To protect
$20 $120 itself from a negative result, the company
Option has entered into negotiations with Thalassa
Value
Energy, which is eager to add Sargasso Sea
$0 $90 assets to its portfolio. Thalassa offers
Oberon, for an up-front premium of $45 mil-
lion, a guarantee to take over the Charon
C = [ p*A+(1-p)*B]*exp (-rf*∆T ) $0 $60 field and reimburse Oberon all development
exp(rf*∆T )-d
costs incurred up to the exercise date, if
p= Oberon chooses to exercise the option. The
u-d
$0 $30
salvage value at any time is assumed to be
the amount invested at that point. Oberon
> Construction of a valuation lattice. Nodes in a valuation lattice are constructed from right to left. performs a real-options valuation (ROV) to
The asset value, such as a stock price, S, at expiration is taken from the lattice of the underlying determine whether the flexibility to recoup
asset. The exercise cost, X, is known in advance. The nodes in Column 5 contain the difference development expenses is worth the price
between stock and exercise price, unless that difference is negative, in which case the node contains asked by Thalassa.
zero. The value in the node labelled C comes from the two adjacent Column 5 nodes, A and B, and
The ROV involves four steps: identifying
uses the risk-neutral probability, p, as shown in the formula (bottom left). Remaining nodes and columns
are constructed similarly, from right to left. The single node on the left contains the value of the option. the underlying asset, determining its volatil-
ity, constructing the lattices and interpreting
option value.
Oberon identifies the underlying asset as
Charon’s project NPV. This NPV exhibits a
log-normal probability distribution, so the
In summary, the lattice of the underlying induction—to obtain an option value at the far- volatility of the underlying asset is based
illustrates the possible paths that an underlying thest left node of the lattice. Backward on the logarithm of the future cash flows.
asset value—like a stock’s price, and similarly induction relies on a factor p, the risk-neutral Monte Carlo simulation on the DCF model
designated as S—will take in time, given that it probability of a movement in the price of the indicates that the implied annual volatility
has a certain volatility. underlying asset. This is the probability that is 66.41%, including both private and public
Valuation lattice—The valuation lattice has would prevail in a world in which investors were uncertainties.
exactly the same number of nodes and branches indifferent to risk. Applying this to each pair of The engineers construct a lattice of the
as the lattice of the underlying asset (above). vertically adjacent nodes in the lattice provides underlying asset with 0.6-year time steps
Analysts work backward from the values in the the real-option value at the farthest left node of using a five-step binomial lattice (next page).
terminal nodes at the right side to the left side of the lattice. The asset value, S, or Oberon’s NPV for the
the lattice. The value placed in each terminal Binomial lattices are often referred to as project without any flexibility from salvage
node is the maximum of zero and the difference binomial trees. However, the two methods potential, is $236.3 million (see “Working Out
between value S and exercise price X, MAX(S – X, operate differently. Trees require an analyst to Net Present Value,” page 6). The risk-free
0). Disallowing negative values reflects the specify probabilities and appropriate discount rate for the three-year period under consider-
holder’s right to refuse to exercise an option with rates at each node, which can be highly subjec- ation is 5% per year. The valuation and
negative value. tive. ROV, embodying ideas such as risk-neutral decision lattices are identical in form to that
From these starting values in the terminal probability for financial uncertainty and risk- of the lattice of the underlying asset.
nodes, it is possible to work backwards through free rate of interest, is less subjective.20
the lattice—using a process called backward
20. Mun, reference 3: 242–245.

12 Oilfield Review
These lattices allow Oberon to interpret
Input Parameters Lattice of the underlying asset 5
option value. The added flexibility provided 3093.3
σ = 66.41% 4
by the Thalassa contract increases Charon’s
∆T = 0.6 3 1849.4
NPV to $285.5 million. This is the value a
u = exp(σ√∆T ) 1105.7
rational, frictionless, free market would, 2 1105.7
= exp(0.6641*√0.6)
given the same information, assign to the = 1.67265 661.0 661.0
1
project. It is $49.3 million more than the NPV
395.2 395.2 395.2
without flexibility—simply because of the d= 1 = 1
u 1.67265
presence of the salvage option. 236.3 236.3 236.3
= 0.59785
An offer to provide this flexibility for $45 141.3 141.3 141.3
million should be accepted by Oberon man- exp(rf *∆T)-d
p= 84.4 84.4
agement since it appears that Thalassa u-d
50.5 50.5
underpriced the option by $4.3 million, the = exp(0.05*0.6)-0.59785
1.67265-0.59785
difference between the option value and the 30.2
= 0.40250
premium price. This apparent underpricing 18.0
indicates that Thalassa has a different per-
ception of risk and uncertainty than Oberon.
Salvage Value Valuation and decision lattice 5
3093.3
Period Years Value, 4 retain
million $ 1849.4
1 0.6 50.0 3 continue

1105.7 1105.7
continue
2 1.2 75.0 2 retain

668.1 661.0
3 1.8 107.5 1 continue continue

420.6 407.4
continue
395.2
continue retain
4 2.4 150.0
> Real option for salvage. The lattice of the 285.5
start
275.3 257.3
continue continue
underlying asset begins with the project net 5 3.0 177.5 209.1 200.4
continue continue
177.5
salvage
present value in the left node and projects
potential future values to the right (top right). 175.2
continue
172.3
continue
The up and down multiplying parameters, u 167.2 177.5
continue salvage
and d, are calculated from the inputs of
volatility, σ, and the time step size, ∆T (top 172.3
continue
left). The salvage value is based on invest-
177.5
ment to date (middle left). The valuation and salvage

decision lattice has the same form as the lat-


tice of the underlying, but it is constructed Work from right to left
from right to left (middle right). The last col- Salvage if < 177.5
umn of the valuation lattice is constructed by 3093.3 Retain ownership 3093.3
comparing the equivalent node in the lattice
of the underlying with the salvage value at Example: backward-induction 1849.4
the final time step (bottom right). If the sal- calculation
vage value is greater, that amount is entered 1105.7 Retain ownership 1105.7
and the salvage decision is noted. Otherwise,
[ 3093.3 * p+ 1105.7 * (1-p)] * exp(- r f* ∆ T )
= 1849.4
the value from the node in the lattice of the 661.0
underlying is used for the valuation-lattice
node, and the decision is to retain owner- 395.2 Retain ownership 395.2
ship. The value in the node in the next column
to the left comes from back-regression from 257.3
two adjacent nodes, as indicated by the
arrows. That value involves the risk-neutral 177.5 Salvage 141.3
probability, p, the risk-free interest rate, rf,
and the time step size, ∆T (bottom left).
172.3

177.5 Salvage 50.5

172.3

177.5 Salvage 18.0

Valuation and decision lattice Lattice of underlying

Winter 2003/2004 13
Types of Real Options Option to switch to another plan—A switch- The base case for this ROV involves trans-
Analysts generally classify real options by the ing option can provide a hedge against the porting LNG from a terminal in Trinidad, West
type of flexibility they give the holder. 21 The likelihood that another technology or project Indies, to the company’s Elba Island facility. The
options may occur naturally, or may be built into will be more economic sometime in the future LNG producer in Trinidad would pay for infras-
a project. Management can defer investment, (see “Switch Option,” page 16). tructure costs to enable this base-case trade and
expand or contract a project, abandon for sal- Sequential or compound options—Real would in turn receive the netback gas price,
vage or switch to another plan. Compound options may lead to additional investment which is the gas price at Elba Island less the
options also can be created.22 opportunities when exercised. The process of cost of shipping and regasification and less the
Option to defer investment—An opportunity exploration, development and production margin paid to El Paso. For example, for the
to invest at some point in the future may be described earlier in this article was a sequen- analysis presented here this margin was
more valuable than an opportunity to invest tial option. assumed to be $0.20/MMBtu [$0.19/million J].
immediately. A deferral option gives an investor This list of options is not exhaustive. Many The NPV of this business over 20 years was
the chance to wait until conditions become other types of options are available. El Paso Cor- $176.7 million.
more favorable, or to abandon a project if condi- poration, the largest pipeline company in North The first option evaluated included diversion
tions deteriorate. An E&P lease, for example, America and a leading provider of natural gas flexibility—adding a second destination termi-
may enable an oil company to wait until present services, used a location spread option—relying nal offshore New York, New York, USA. El Paso
uncertainties about oil and gas prices and about on a difference in a price between different loca- evaluated both intrinsic and extrinsic values for
development technology have been resolved. tions—to evaluate a new line of business. Various this option. The intrinsic value of this spread
The company would invest in exploration and other spread options are possible, for example option represents the difference in price—the
development only if oil price increased enough based on different prices at different times or at basis spread—between the Georgia and New
to ensure that developed acreage on the lease different stages of commodity processing. York markets (next page). The extrinsic value
would be profitable. If prices declined, the com- includes the effects of time and reflects the
pany would allow the lease to lapse or would sell Real Options for LNG Transport probability that the basis spread will change
the remainder of the lease to another company. El Paso owns a liquefied natural gas (LNG) over the 20-year period of the analysis.
The exercise price of the option is the money terminal at Elba Island, Georgia, USA, one of In this spread option, El Paso would buy
required to develop the acreage. only four land-based terminals in the USA. The the LNG on the basis of the Elba Island price
Option to expand or contract a project— company investigated purchasing transport and sell it at the New York price, when that
Once a project has been developed, management vessels and expanding into the LNG transport choice adds value. Otherwise, El Paso would sell
may have the option to accelerate the produc- business. Each tanker, outfitted specifically for at Elba and receive no incremental value. With
tion rate or change the scale of production. In use in LNG transport with a regasification capa- an average basis spread of $0.62/MMBtu
an oil or gas field, there might be the option to bility for downloading at offshore buoys called [$0.59/million J], the total intrinsic value of this
increase production by investing in an enhanced energy-bridge buoys, costs several hundred mil- spread option is $558.7 million. In this model,
oil recovery plan or by drilling satellite wells. lion US dollars. El Paso would assume the costs for converting
The original investment opportunity is defined The essence of the problem facing the evalua- the terminals and purchasing an additional ship
as the initial project plus a call option on a tion team was how to value shipping and to effect this option. The net value of the option
future opportunity. diversion flexibility. The company had a variety of after those expenses is $68.5 million. Including
Option to abandon for salvage—If oil and potential LNG sources and destinations, and the the variability over time gives an additional
gas prices go into what seems likely to be a evaluation was intended to determine how many extrinsic value of $101.7 million.
prolonged decline, management may decide to tanker ships El Paso should purchase. The company then added in the value of hav-
abandon the project and sell any accumulated El Paso felt DCF was deficient for this analy- ing multiple choices of source and destination,
capital equipment in the open market. Alterna- sis. The LNG market and its related shipping termed a rainbow option. The value of a rainbow
tively, it may sell the project, or its share in the were relatively new ventures for El Paso, and the option increases with increased price volatility
project, to another company whose strategic company had no history for forecasting the rev- at the individual locations, and it also increases
plans make the project more attractive (see “Sal- enues and costs required by DCF. Even if those when the cross-correlations between prices are
vage an Investment,” page 12). Selling for forecasts had been available, the DCF technique low. With two additional destination options, off-
salvage value would be similar to exercising an does not have the flexibility necessary to reflect shore New York and Cove Point, Maryland, USA,
American put option. If the value of the project the additional value of a price difference between there is an additional value of $14.8 million,
falls below its liquidation value, the company can delivery locations that occurs only for a brief time even though the price correlations between
exercise its put option. period. The team tried to model the simple case these pairs of locations are high. The rainbow
of a fixed source and destination using DCF, but option value increases when there is more flexi-
21. Rogers, reference 17: 49; and Trigeorgis, reference 5: the model could not correctly value inbuilt bility in source and destination locations. In
5–10.
22. A project with many embedded options can be difficult options allowing El Paso not to sell if the LNG certain scenarios with additional sources in the
to evaluate using the simple forms of the Black-Scholes delivery price did not cover variable expenses.
and lattice models presented in this article.

14 Oilfield Review
Middle East and Africa and additional destina-
tions in Europe and North America, El Paso Land-based terminal
found the rainbow option added more than $100 Offshore transfer buoy
million to the value of each ship. Base-case trade route
The evaluation team provided a caveat to the Spread-option trade routes
company. Spread options tend to overestimate
available flexibility, because contractual obliga-
tions would have to be maintained. In addition,
USA New York City
the effects of price shifts caused by any reduc-
tion in supply were not included in the analysis. Cove Point
Although real-options analysis indicated a Elba Island
positive value to a business model based on LNG
imports to the USA and to diversion flexibility as
a value-maximizing technique for shipping, El
Paso made a strategic business decision not to
enter this market.
TRINIDAD
Alternatives and Options 0 1000 2000 3000 km
In the English language the word option may be
0 500 1000 1500 2000 miles
used in two technically different senses. In ROV
the term option (or real option) is used to > Liquified natural gas (LNG) transport routes in a spread option. El Paso
denote a decision that may be deferred to some Corporation evaluated the LNG transport business using a base case between
time in the future, and that is accompanied by Trinidad, West Indies, and its terminal at Elba Island, Georgia, USA. The
company considered purchasing transport ships with regasification
some uncertainty that can be resolved. On the capabilities to give it the capability to transport gas to other locations, such
other hand, in common parlance, an option can as Cove Point, Maryland, USA, or New York, New York, USA. This rainbow
simply be an operational alternative, which is a option increased the value of the business opportunity.
decision that is to be made today and for which
there is no future recourse.
For example, a company may decide to drill a
well in a certain location. If the well is dry, then
the company has lost the cost of drilling. The
well location was an operational alternative, a tives may often be evaluated using simpler meth- Real-World Complications
decision that had to be made there and then. ods that automatically average out the A real-options methodology attempts to model
However, if there were another party guarantee- possibilities. For example, a forward contract, behaviors of real properties. However, the many
ing some minimum return on the well, the which obligates the holder of the contract to buy possibilities created by human ingenuity limit
company drilling the well would have a real or sell an asset for a predetermined price at a any such modeling. Actual situations typically
option, because it could decide in the future predetermined time in the future, may be valued have many embedded options, making any anal-
whether to call on that guarantee, thereby mini- simply, without the volatility assumption that is ysis complicated. The few examples discussed in
mizing any downside risk and maximizing any required in the Black-Scholes or lattice valua- this section illustrate a few types of complica-
upside potential. tion of a European option. tions that may have to be dealt with in using
A project containing an option is always Within the class of options there are many dis- real options.
worth more than one with just a corresponding tinctions. One is the distinction between financial The holder of a financial option is guaran-
alternative. This is because deferral allows an and real options that has been discussed. Another teed that the option may be held until the
owner to eliminate unfavorable outcomes while is that between options that are purely inter- expiration date and, apart from general market
retaining favorable ones. This is often referred nal—residing solely within the company movement, its value cannot be undermined by
to as optionality. A project having only a set of itself—and ones in which an outside party pro- the actions of other individuals. In most real
alternatives has no such cushion. The decision, vides flexibility for some agreed up-front options, there is no such guarantee.
which must be made today, is effectively irre- payment. Many real options possess just an inter- Two oil companies might hold identical
versible. The estimated NPV must average over nal character, while financial derivatives normally leases on adjoining blocks. In effect, they would
all outcomes, both favorable and unfavorable. exist in the presence of a contracted external both have identical options to spend money on
Both options and alternatives can be party. Fortunately, all these option types can be exploration and receive undeveloped resources
computed using standard lattice-type method- computed using the same techniques, most in return.
ologies (see “True Option and an Alternative notably standard lattice-type methodologies. (continued on page 18)
Valued under Uncertainty,” page 18). Alterna-

Winter 2003/2004 15
Synthetic-Reservoir Surface-Separator Decision
Switch Option

At this time, the design criteria for the fictitious


Charon field project have been established
and a three-year development phase is about
to begin. A critical technical issue is the gas-
throughput capacity of a surface separator.
Case 50 Case 60
Economic analysis suggests a maximum
separator capacity of 50 million scf/D Throughput, million scf/D 50 60
[1.4 million m3/d]. A facilities contractor, 66.41%
Volatility 71.28%
Proteus Fabrication Inc., has been commis-
sioned to design, fabricate and install it. NPV, million $ 236.27 228.99
Although a 50 million scf/D throughput > Comparison of volatility and net present value (NPV) for two surface
design—termed Case 50—is deemed ade- separator cases in the synthetic Charon example.
quate, an upside production potential of an
extra 10 million scf/D [286,000 m3/d] is possi-
ble. A 60 million scf/D [1.7 million m3/d]
separator—Case 60—would be more expen-
sive, and Charon might not have enough
production potential to utilize it fully. The com-
pany would like to delay the design-capacity 4.0
decision for as long as possible.
3.5
Proteus can implement this design change
Switching option value, million $

within the first year of construction, but can- 3.0


not make changes after the first year. The 2.5
implementation cost to switch from a smaller Switching option value for
2.0 200-step
to a larger design, set at $17.72 million, is 200-step lattice is 1.653
lattice
equivalent to an option exercise price, X. 1.5
In addition to this exercise price, Proteus Switching option value for
1.0
five-step lattice is 1.305 Five-step
insists on an additional up-front nonrefund- lattice
0.5
able payment. This up-front payment
17.72
accommodates changing the initial design to 0.0
0 5 10 15 20 25
allow for later expansion and covers a possible Switching cost, million $
overrun on the agreed exercise price. Oberon
initiates a simple switching-option study to > Effect of lattice size on option valuation. The coarse, five-step lattice has
been used for illustrative purposes only, yielding a less accurate option value
determine what the initial payment to Proteus
than the more refined 200-step lattice. At the $17.72 million switching cost,
should be. that finer lattice indicates the option value is $1.653 million.
Case 50 and Case 60 are independent cases
with different cash-flow NPVs and volatilities.
ECLIPSE modeling establishes the static NPV,
excluding switching costs, and associated
volatility of the two cases (top right).
Values for Case 60 are obtained in manner correlated—each step up or down in one the last column of the Case 60 lattice, compar-
similar to Case 50, the base case used in the underlying lattice corresponds with the same ing this to the last column of the Case 50
previous examples. step in the other. In this way, nodes in the two lattice, and selecting the larger value at each
A switching option can be analyzed by con- cases can be directly compared to construct a node. This reflects Oberon’s right to choose
structing two lattices, one for each of the two valuation lattice for the upgrade. the better of the two cases in any eventuality.
underlying assets (next page). The simplest The valuation lattice is obtained by sub- The option value is then computed by back-
case assumes these two lattices are completely tracting the upgrade cost, $17.72 million, from ward induction using the Case 50 risk-neutral
probabilities, p.

16 Oilfield Review
< Lattices for synthetic Charon sur-
0 1 2 3 4 5
face separator cases. Case 50 and
(Now) (0.2 year) (0.4 year) (0.6 year) (0.8 year) (1.0 year)
Case 60 have different lattices of
the underlying asset, but the lattice
Case 50 Underlying Lattice 1,043.10
structure is the same, allowing a
775.07 node-by-node comparison between
575.91 575.91 them (top). Nodes in Case 60 are
427.93 427.93 greyed out, except for the final col-
317.97 317.97 317.97 umn, to indicate that no decision is
236.27 236.27 236.27 made until the end of one year. The
175.56 175.56 175.56 last column of the valuation lattice
130.45 130.45 is constructed by comparing the
96.93 96.93 value of Case 50 to equivalent node
72.02 value of Case 60 minus the imple-
mentation cost of $17.72 million
53.52
(bottom). This also provides the
decision to keep Case 50 or switch
Case 60 Underlying Lattice 1,127.26 to Case 60. The other nodes of the
819.57 valuation lattice are constructed by
595.86 595.86 back-regression, using the risk-neu-
433.21 433.21 tral probabilities from Case 50, the
314.96 314.96 314.96 base case. The value of the project
228.99 228.99 228.99 with the switch option is
166.48 166.48 166.48 $237.57 million.
121.04 121.04
88.00 88.00
63.98
46.52

0 1 2 3 4 5
(Now) (0.2 year) (0.4 year) (0.6 year) (0.8 year) (1.0 year)
MAX(Case 50,
Case 60-17.72)
Decision and Valuation Lattice
1,109.64
805.44 Switch to Case 60
continue
589.77 578.14
continue
434.24 428.91 Switch to Case 60
continue
continue
320.85 318.40 317.97
continue
continue
237.57 236.46 236.27 Keep Case 50
Start continue continue
175.64 175.56 175.56
continue continue
130.45 130.45 Keep Case 50
continue continue
96.93 96.93
continue
72.02 Keep Case 50
continue
53.52
Lattice node values, million $ Keep Case 50

Changing the cost to upgrade affects the premium for the option to switch in the first accelerated cash and throughput from reser-
value of the upgrade option (previous page, year at the stated upgrade price. In an actual voir production, if conditions warrant. Proteus
bottom). In this case, the five-step lattice is case, final decisions would be based on finer gets an up-front premium of $1.653 million
too coarse, resulting in an unrealistic kink in lattices than the five-step lattices used in and a locked-in payment of $17.72 million if
the result. A finer 200-step lattice resolves the these illustrations. Oberon chooses to upgrade the facility. Pro-
kink and indicates that it would be appropri- With this arrangement Oberon gains the teus has a cash incentive to explore more
ate for Oberon to pay Proteus a $1.653 million ability to demand a design change resulting in cost-effective and efficient design solutions
for the upgrade.

Winter 2003/2004 17
Actions of one company can affect the busi-
ness results of the other. Most governments now
insist on unitization, an arrangement that
requires parties on both sides to jointly develop Synthetic-Reservoir Intervention
reserves located on more than one lease or auc-
True Option and an Alternative Valued under Uncertainty
tioned tract. Each party pays a share of the costs
and receives a proportionate amount of the
revenues. In a sense, when governments do
this, they are ensuring the purity of the real The fictitious Charon field, operated by irreversible. This arrangement is an alternative,
options involved. Oberon Oil, has been producing for a few not an option in the sense discussed in this
It is possible to conceive of circumstances— years. Production is declining and water cut article. A valuation lattice for this alternative
such as constructing a pipeline to an area where is increasing in some of the wells. Engineers differs from an ROV lattice in that the right-
only one is needed—in which if Company A took propose a production-enhancement operation hand terminal nodes of the valuation lattice
up the option to invest, it would preempt Com- involving water shutoff on one of the wells. contain the simple term, S-X, rather than the
pany B from doing so, rendering B’s option Their analysis has determined what conventional terms used in those nodes, that
worthless, or certainly worth less. The real- incremental production is likely to be is, the maximum of zero and S-X—MAX(S-X,0)
options approach attaches a positive value to from this intervention. (next page).
delay, but in instances such as this one, delay With DCF, the expected NPV of the incre- The difference between the alternative and
can undermine value.23 mental cash flow, which is the option asset real-option lattices—$8,198—represents the
Finally, the parameters used in real-options value S, is $1,280,000, excluding the actual premium the service provider should theoreti-
calculations can be difficult to determine. There intervention cost. The cost of the intervention, cally demand in order to agree to a contracted
is no simple road map to computing volatility or exercise price X, is $750,000. The resulting cost-reimbursement provision. It is small in
and there is still debate over the correct NPV is $530,000. this case because there is a small likelihood
approach to finding this value. Obtaining an esti- Analysts estimate a 40% volatility of the that the provision would be required and the
mate often entails performing a Monte Carlo incremental cash flow subject to oil price and option would be exercised.
simulation on the existing DCF model and exam- technical uncertainties, and use a 5% risk-free The NPV of $530,000 undervalues this pro-
ining the standard deviation of the natural rate of interest. ject. Even with no reimbursement provision,
logarithm of the cash-flow returns. The cost of The service provider offers Oberon two the value added to the asset from the inter-
deferment requires knowledge of the profits choices: vention is $36,578 more than the NPV. This
foregone during the period prior to exercising an 1. Pay the $750,000 job cost up-front and additional value emerges solely because of the
option, but the value of the missed cash flows accept whatever may happen. presence of volatility in the underlying asset.
may be poorly known. 2. Pay an additional up-front premium to the Adding the revenue reimbursement provision
Financial-option pricing relies on an assump- service provider for the right to claim back increases this net value by $44,776 beyond the
tion that the underlying asset can be traded, some or all the job cost if the incremental NPV calculation.
meaning there is a large liquid market for the net revenue generated from this interven-
asset. This is often not true for real options. Fac- tion is negative after one year.
tors affecting the prices of financial options are The second choice provides Oberon with
also easier to determine—that is, more trans- protection from downside risk, up to the cost
parent—than those for real options. of the job, but the intervention would still
The simplified discussion in this article is have an unlimited upside potential. For exam-
intended only to introduce the concept of real ple, if after one year the net incremental cash
options. It uses simple examples that correlate flow (after job cost) were negative $100,000,
with financial options. Use for an actual case is then the service provider would reimburse
typically more complicated, with an expanding Oberon that sum. Oberon’s net incremental
array of possible options available, as demon- cash flow from this operation would be zero.
strated in the El Paso LNG case. Ultimately, real In effect, this option offered by the service
options are not financial options. The tech- provider provides a cost-reimbursement guar-
niques of financial options provide a basis for antee for an agreed up-front premium. Oberon
wants to calculate what a reasonable value for
23. For a discussion of such investment behavior: Weeds H: this up-front premium should be.
“Strategic Delay in a Real Options Model of R&D Compe-
tition,” Review of Economic Studies 69 (2002): 729–747. The first choice is a pure operational alter-
24. Trigeorgis, reference 5: 3. native—to intervene or not to intervene. If
Oberon takes this choice, then any job cost is
sunk; the decision to spend money on the job is

18 Oilfield Review
evaluating real options, but an expert in ROV
should be consulted to assure the techniques
are properly applied.
These complications should not dissuade a
company from using real options. Valuation
experts can determine when ROV should be
used, and when other methods, such as decision
trees incorporating Monte Carlo simulation, are
0 1 2 3 4 5 more appropriate. Working with managers and
(Now) (0.2 year) (0.4 year) (0.6 year) (0.8 year) (1.0 year) experts in other disciplines, valuation experts
can help place a value on the options inherent in
Lattice of the underlying asset 3,130,796 many projects.
2,617,977
2,189,157 2,189,157
1,830,577
The Real-Options Mindset
1,830,577
1,530,731 1,530,731 Actually recognizing options that are embedded
1,530,731
1,280,000 1,280,000 1,280,000 in a project takes practice. Managers often learn
1,070,338 1,070,338 1,070,338 to discern options simply by brainstorming with
895,019 895,019 one another about the project.
748,416 748,416 In many ways, having a real-options mindset
625,827
is as important as using the mathematics. Real-
523,317
options thinking emphasizes and values
management flexibility. It recognizes that in a
Valuation lattice with true option Max(S-X, 0)
world characterized by change, uncertainty and
2,380,796
competitive interactions, management can be
1,875,439
1,454,008 1,439,157 active. It can alter and modify plans as new
1,088,039 information becomes available or as new possi-
1,102,742
810,248 795,582 780,731 bilities arise.24 It can be reactive to changing
574,776 552,378 537,463 circumstances or proactive—intervening to take
365,671 334,604 320,338 advantage of possibilities that may improve the
198,119 153,291
value of the project. If management understands
73,335 0
0
that flexibility is valuable, it will look for that
0 flexibility in its projects and capitalize on it to
increase shareholder value. —MB, MAA
Valuation lattice with alternative S-X
2,380,796
1,875,439
1,454,008 1,439,157
1,102,742 1,088,039
810,139 795,582 780,731
566,578 552,166 537,463
349,746 335,189 320,338
167,184 152,481
13,267 –1,584
–116,711
Lattice node values, $ –226,683

> Comparison of an option and an alternative. The lattice method can be used to
value an alternative. Both use the same lattice of the underlying (top). For an
option, the right-hand column is the maximum value of zero and the difference
between the underlying value and the $750,000 implementation cost (middle).
The values for an alternative can be negative, because the function is simply the
difference between the value and the implementation cost (bottom). This leads to
an $8,198 difference in value between the option, valued at $574,776, and the
alternative, valued at $566,578.

Winter 2003/2004 19
An Anatomy of the Crude Oil Pricing
System

Bassam Fattouh1

WPM 40

January 2011

1
Bassam Fattouh is the Director of the Oil and Middle East Programme at the Oxford Institute for Energy Studies;
Research Fellow at St Antony‟s College, Oxford University; and Professor of Finance and Management at the
School of Oriental and African Studies, University of London. I would like to express my gratitude to Argus for
supplying me with much of the data that underlie this research. I would also like to thank Platts for providing me
with the data for Figure 21 and CME Group for providing me with the data for Figure 13. The paper has benefited
greatly from the helpful comments of Robert Mabro and Christopher Allsopp and many commentators who
preferred to remain anonymous but whose comments provided a major source of information for this study. The
paper also benefited from the comments received in seminars at the Department of Energy and Climate Change, UK,
ENI, Milan and Oxford Institute for Energy Studies, Oxford. Finally, I would like to thank those individuals who
have given their time for face-to-face and/or phone interviews and have been willing to share their views and
expertise. Any remaining errors are my own.

1
The contents of this paper are the authors’ sole responsibility. They do not
necessarily represent the views of the Oxford Institute for Energy Studies or any of its
members.

Copyright © 2011

Oxford Institute for Energy Studies

(Registered Charity, No. 286084)

This publication may be reproduced in part for educational or non-profit purposes without special
permission from the copyright holder, provided acknowledgment of the source is made. No use of this
publication may be made for resale or for any other commercial purpose whatsoever without prior
permission in writing from the Oxford Institute for Energy Studies.

ISBN

978-1-907555-20-6

2
Contents
Summary Report ........................................................................................................................................... 6
1. Introduction ......................................................................................................................................... 11
2. Historical Background to the International Oil Pricing System .......................................................... 14
The Era of the Posted Price ..................................................................................................................... 14
The Pricing System Shaken but Not Broken .......................................................................................... 14
The Emergence of the OPEC Administered Pricing System .................................................................. 15
The Consolidation of the OPEC Administered Pricing System.............................................................. 16
The Genesis of the Crude Oil Market ..................................................................................................... 17
The Collapse of the OPEC Administered Pricing System ...................................................................... 18
3. The Market-Related Oil Pricing System and Formulae Pricing ......................................................... 20
Spot Markets, Long-Term Contracts and Formula Pricing ..................................................................... 20
Benchmarks in Formulae Pricing............................................................................................................ 24
4. Oil Price Reporting Agencies and the Price Discovery Process ......................................................... 30
5. The Brent Market and Its Layers ........................................................................................................ 36
The Physical Base of North Sea .............................................................................................................. 37
The Layers and Financial Instruments of the Brent Market ................................................................... 39
Data Issues .......................................................................................................................................... 39
The Forward Brent .............................................................................................................................. 40
The Brent Futures Market ................................................................................................................... 43
The Exchange for Physicals ................................................................................................................ 44
The Dated Brent/BFOE....................................................................................................................... 45
The Contract for Differences (CFDs) ................................................................................................. 45
OTC Derivatives ................................................................................................................................. 48
The Process of Oil Price Identification in the Brent Market ................................................................... 50
6. The US Benchmarks ........................................................................................................................... 52
The Physical Base for US Benchmarks .................................................................................................. 52
The Layers and Financial Instruments of WTI ....................................................................................... 55
The Price Discovery Process in the US Market ...................................................................................... 56
WTI: The Broken Benchmark? ............................................................................................................... 58
7. The Dubai-Oman Market .................................................................................................................... 61
The Physical Base of Dubai and Oman .................................................................................................. 61
The Financial Layers of Dubai................................................................................................................ 62

3
The Price Discovery Process in the Dubai Market ................................................................................. 64
Oman and its Financial Layers: A New Benchmark in the Making?...................................................... 66
8. Assessment and Evaluation................................................................................................................. 70
Physical Liquidity of Benchmarks .......................................................................................................... 70
Shifts in Global Oil Demand Dynamics and Benchmarks ...................................................................... 71
The Nature of Players and the Oil Price Formation Process ................................................................... 73
The Linkages between Physical Benchmarks and Financial Layers....................................................... 74
Adjustments in Price Differentials versus Price Levels .......................................................................... 74
Transparency and Accuracy of Information ........................................................................................... 76
9. Conclusions ......................................................................................................................................... 78
References ................................................................................................................................................... 81

List of Figures

Figure 1: Price Differentials of Various Types of Saudi Arabia‟s Crude Oil to Asia in $/Barrel .............. 21
Figure 2: Differentials of Term Prices between Saudi Arabia Light and Iran Light Destined to Asia (FOB)
(In US cents) ............................................................................................................................................... 23
Figure 3: Difference in Term Prices for Various Crude Oil Grades to the US Gulf (Delivered) and Asia
(FOB) .......................................................................................................................................................... 24
Figure 4: Price Differential between Dated Brent and BWAVE ($/Barrel) ............................................... 26
Figure 5: Price Differential between WTI and ASCI ($/Barrel) (ASCI Price=0) ....................................... 26
Figure 6: Brent Production by Company (cargoes per year), 2007 ............................................................ 37
Figure 7: Falling output of BFO ................................................................................................................. 38
Figure 8: Trading Volume and Number of Participants in the 21-Day BFOE Market ............................... 42
Figure 9: Average Daily Volume and Open Interest of ICE Brent Futures Contract ................................. 44
Figure 10: Pricing basis of Dated Brent Deals (1986-1991); Percentage of Total Deals ........................... 45
Figure 11: Reported Trade on North Sea CFDs (b/d) ................................................................................. 46
Figure 12: US PADDS ................................................................................................................................ 52
Figure 13: Monthly averages of volumes traded of the Light Sweet Crude Oil Futures Contract ............. 55
Figure 14:Liquidity at Different Segments of the Futures Curve (October 19, 2010) ................................ 56
Figure 15: Spot Market Traded Volumes (b/d) (April 2009 Trade Month) ................................................ 57
Figure 16: Spread between WTI 12-weeks Ahead and prompt WTI ($/Barrel) ......................................... 59
Figure 17: WTI-BRENT Price Differential ($/Barrel)................................................................................ 60
Figure 18: Dubai and Oman Crude Production Estimates (thousand barrels per day) ............................... 62
Figure 19: Spread Deals as a Percentage of Total Number of Dubai Deals ............................................... 63
Figure 20: Oman-Dubai Spread ($/Barrel) ................................................................................................. 64
Figure 21: Dubai Partials Jan 2008 - Nov 2010 .......................................................................................... 65
Figure 22: daily Volume of Traded DME Oman Crude Oil Futures Contract ........................................... 67
Figure 23: Volume and Open Interest of the October 2010 Futures Contracts (Traded During Month of
August)........................................................................................................................................................ 68

4
Figure 24: OECD and Non-OECD Oil Demand Dynamics........................................................................ 71
Figure 25: Change in Oil Trade Flow Dynamics ........................................................................................ 72
Figure 26: The North Sea Dated differential to Ice Brent during the French Strike ................................... 76

5
Summary Report
The view that crude oil has acquired the characteristics of financial assets such as stocks or bonds has
gained wide acceptance among many observers. However, the nature of „financialisation‟ and its
implications are not yet clear. Discussions and analyses of „financialisation‟ of oil markets have partly
been subsumed within analyses of the relation between finance and commodity indices which include
crude oil. The elements that have attracted most attention have been outcomes: correlations between
levels, returns, and volatility of commodity and financial indices. However, a full understanding of the
degree of interaction between oil and finance requires, in addition, an analysis of interactions, causations
and processes such as the investment and trading strategies of distinct types of financial participants; the
financing mechanisms and the degree of leverage supporting those strategies; the structure of oil
derivatives markets; and most importantly the mechanisms that link the financial and physical layers of
the oil market.
Unlike a pure financial asset, the crude oil market also has a „physical‟ dimension that should anchor
prices in oil market fundamentals: crude oil is consumed, stored and widely traded with millions of
barrels being bought and sold every day at prices agreed by transacting parties. Thus, in principle, prices
in the futures market through the process of arbitrage should eventually converge to the so-called „spot‟
prices in the physical markets. The argument then goes that since physical trades are transacted at spot
prices, these prices should reflect existing supply-demand conditions.
In the oil market, however, the story is more complex. The „current‟ market fundamentals are never
known with certainty. The flow of data about oil market fundamentals is not instantaneous and is often
subject to major revisions which make the most recent available data highly unreliable. Furthermore,
though many oil prices are observed on screens and reported through a variety of channels, it is important
to explain what these different prices refer to. Thus, although the futures price often converges to a „spot‟
price, one should aim to analyse the process of convergence and understand what the „spot‟ price in the
context of the oil market really means.
Unfortunately, little attention has been devoted to such issues and the processes of price discovery in oil
markets and the drivers of oil prices in the short-run remain under-researched. While this topic is linked to
the current debate on the role of speculation versus fundamentals in the determination of the oil price, it
goes beyond the existing debates which have recently dominated policy agendas. This report offers a
fresh and deeper perspective on the current debate by identifying the various layers relevant to the price
formation process and by examining and analysing the links between the financial and physical layers in
the oil market, which lie at the heart of the current international oil pricing system.
The adoption of the market-related pricing system by many oil exporters in 1986-1988 opened a new
chapter in the history of oil price formation. It represented a shift from a system in which prices were first
administered by the large multinational oil companies in the 1950s and 1960s and then by OPEC for the
period 1973-1988 to a system in which prices are set by „markets‟. First adopted by the Mexican national
oil company PEMEX in 1986, the market-related pricing system received wide acceptance among most
oil-exporting countries. By 1988, it became and still is the main method for pricing crude oil in
international trade after a short experimentation with a products-related pricing system in the shape of the
netback pricing regime in the period 1986-1987. The oil market was ready for such a transition. The end
of the concession system and the waves of nationalisation which disrupted oil supplies to multinational oil
companies established the basis of arm‟s-length deals and exchange outside the vertically and
horizontally integrated multinational companies. The emergence of many suppliers outside OPEC and
many buyers further increased the prevalence of such arm‟s-length deals. This led to the development of a
complex structure of interlinked oil markets which consist of spot and also physical forwards, futures,
options and other derivative markets referred to as paper markets. Technological innovations which made
electronic trading possible revolutionised these markets by allowing 24-hour trading from any place in the

6
world. It also opened access to a wider set of market participants and allowed the development of a large
number of trading instruments both on regulated exchanges and over the counter.
Physical delivery of crude oil is organised either through the spot (cash) market or through long-term
contracts. The spot market is used by transacting parties to buy and sell crude oil not covered by long
term contractual arrangements and applies often to one-off transactions. Given the logistics of
transporting oil, spot cargoes for immediate delivery are rare. Instead, there is an important element of
forwardness in spot transactions. The parties can either agree on the price at the time of agreement, in
which case the sport transaction becomes closer to a „forward‟ contract. More often though, transacting
parties link the pricing of an oil cargo to the time of loading.
Long-term contracts are negotiated bilaterally between buyers and sellers for the delivery of a series of oil
shipments over a specified period of time, usually one or two years. They specify among other things, the
volumes of crude oil to be delivered, the delivery schedule, the actions to be taken in case of default, and
above all the method that should be used in calculating the price of an oil shipment. Price agreements are
usually concluded on the method of formula pricing which links the price of a cargo in long-term
contracts to a market (spot) price. Formula pricing has become the basis of the oil pricing system.
Formula pricing has two main advantages. Crude oil is not a homogenous commodity. There are various
types of internationally traded crude oil with different qualities and characteristics which have a bearing
on refining yields. Thus, different crudes fetch different prices. Given the large variety of crude oils, the
price of a particular type is usually set at a discount or at a premium to marker or reference prices, often
referred to as benchmarks. The differentials are adjusted periodically to reflect differences in the quality
of crudes as well as the relative demand and supply of the various types of crudes. Another advantage of
formula pricing is that it increases pricing flexibility. When there is a lag between the date at which a
cargo is bought and the date of arrival at its destination, there is a price risk. Transacting parties usually
share this risk through the pricing formula. Agreements are often made for the date of pricing to occur
around the delivery date.
At the heart of formulae pricing is the identification of the price of key „physical‟ benchmarks, such as
West Texas Intermediate (WTI), Dated Brent and Dubai-Oman. The benchmark crudes are a central
feature of the oil pricing system and are used by oil companies and traders to price cargoes under long-
term contracts or in spot market transactions; by futures exchanges for the settlement of their financial
contracts; by banks and companies for the settlement of derivative instruments such as swap contracts;
and by governments for taxation purposes.
Few features of these physical benchmarks stand out. Markets with relatively low volumes of production
such as WTI, Brent, and Dubai set the price for markets with higher volumes of production elsewhere in
the world. Despite the high level of volumes of production in the Gulf, these markets remain illiquid:
there is limited spot trading in these markets, no forwards or swaps (apart from Dubai), and no liquid
futures market since crude export contracts include destination and resale restrictions which limit trading
options. While the volume of production is not a sufficient condition for the emergence of a benchmark, it
is a necessary condition for a benchmark‟s success. As markets become thinner and thinner, the price
discovery process becomes more difficult. Oil price reporting agencies cannot observe enough genuine
arms-length deals. Furthermore, in thin markets, the danger of squeezes and distortions increases and as a
result prices could then become less informative and more volatile thereby distorting consumption and
production decisions. So far the low and continuous decline in the physical base of existing benchmarks
has been counteracted by including additional crude streams in an assessed benchmark. This had the
effect of reducing the chance of squeezes as these alternative crudes could be used for delivery against the
contract. Although such short-term solutions have been successful in alleviating the problem of squeezes,
observers should not be distracted from some key questions: What are the conditions necessary for the
emergence of successful benchmarks in the most physically liquid market? Would a shift to assessing

7
price in these markets improve the price discovery process? Such key questions remain heavily under-
researched in the energy literature and do not feature in the consumer-producer dialogue.
The emergence of the non-OECD as the main source of growth in global oil demand will only increase
the importance of such questions. One of the most important shifts in oil market dynamics in recent years
has been the shift in oil trade flows to Asia: this may have long-term implications on pricing benchmarks.
Questions are already being raised whether Dubai still constitutes an appropriate benchmark for pricing
crude oil exports to Asia given its thin physical base or whether new benchmarks are needed to reflect
more accurately the recent shift in trade flows and the rise in prominence of the Asian consumer.
Unlike the futures market where prices are observable in real time, the reported prices of physical
benchmarks are „identified‟ or „assessed‟ prices. Assessments are needed in opaque markets such as crude
oil where physical transactions concluded between parties cannot be directly observed by outsiders.
Assessments are also needed in illiquid markets where there are not enough representative deals or where
no transactions are concluded. These assessments are carried out by oil pricing reporting agencies
(PRAs), the two most important of which are Platts and Argus. While PRAs have been an integral part of
the oil pricing system, especially since the shift to the market-related pricing system in 1986, their role
has recently been attracting considerable attention. In the G20 summit in Korea in November 2010, the
G20 leaders called for a more detailed analysis on „how the oil spot market prices are assessed by oil
price reporting agencies and how this affects the transparency and functioning of oil markets‟. In its latest
report in November 2010, IOSCO points that „the core concern with respect to price reporting agencies is
the extent to which the reported data accurately reflects the cash market in question‟. PRAs do not only
act as „a mirror to the trade‟. In their attempt to identify the price that reflects accurately the market value
of an oil barrel, PRAs enter into the decision-making territory which can influence market structure.
What they choose to do is influenced by market participants and market structure while they in turn
influence the trading strategies of the various participants. New markets and contracts may emerge to
hedge the risks arising from some PRAs‟ decisions. To evaluate the role of PRAs in the oil market, it is
important to look at three inter-related dimensions: the methodology used in indentifying the oil price; the
accuracy of price assessments; and the internal measures that PRAs implement to protect the integrity and
ensure an efficient assessment process. There is a fundamental difference in the methodology and in the
philosophy underlying the price assessment process between the various PRAs. As a result, different
agencies may produce different prices for the same benchmark. This raises the issue of which method
produces a more accurate price assessment. Given that assessed prices underlie long-term contracts, spot
transactions and derivatives instruments, even small differences in price assessments between PRAs have
important implications on exporters‟ revenues and financial flows between parties in financial contracts.
In the last two decades or so, many financial layers (paper markets) have emerged around crude oil
benchmarks. They include the forward market (in Brent and Dubai), swaps, futures, and options. Some of
the instruments such as futures and options are traded on regulated exchanges such as ICE and CME
Group, while other instruments, such as swaps, options and forward contracts, are traded bilaterally over
the counter (OTC). Nevertheless, these financial layers are highly interlinked through the process of
arbitrage and the development of instruments that links the various layers together. Over the years, these
markets have grown in terms of size, liquidity, sophistication and have attracted a diverse set of players
both physical and financial. These markets have become central for market participants wishing to hedge
their risk and to bet on oil price movements. Equally important, these financial layers have become
central to the oil price identification process.
At the early stages of the current pricing system, linking prices to benchmarks in formulae pricing
provided producers and consumers with a sense of comfort that the price is grounded in the physical
dimension of the market. This implicitly assumes that the process of identifying the price of benchmarks
can be isolated from financial layers. However, this is far from reality. The analysis in this report shows
that the different layers of the oil market form a complex web of links, all of which play a role in the price
discovery process. The information derived from financial layers is essential for identifying the price

8
level of the benchmark. In the Brent market, the oil price in the forward market is sometimes priced as a
differential to the price of the Brent futures contract using the Exchange for Physicals (EFP) market. The
price of Dated Brent or North Sea Dated in turn is priced as a differential to the forward market through
the market of Contract for Differences (CFDs), another swaps market. Given the limited number of
physical transactions and hence the limited amount of deals that can be observed by oil reporting
agencies, the value of Dubai, the main benchmark used for pricing crude oil exports to East Asia, is often
assessed by using the value of differentials in the very liquid OTC Dubai/Brent swaps market. Thus, one
could argue that without these financial layers it would not be possible to „discover‟ or „identify‟ oil
prices in the current oil pricing system. In effect, crude oil prices are jointly or co-determined in both
layers, depending on differences in timing, location and quality of crude oil.

Since physical benchmarks constitute the pricing basis of the large majority of physical transactions,
some observers claim that derivatives instruments such as futures, forwards, options and swaps derive
their value from the price of these physical benchmarks, i.e., the prices of these physical benchmarks
drive the prices in paper markets. However, this is a gross over-simplification and does not accurately
reflect the process of crude oil price formation. The issue of whether the paper market drives the physical
or the other way around is difficult to construct theoretically and test empirically and requires further
research.

The report also calls for broadening the empirical research to include the trading strategies of physical
players. In recent years, the futures markets have attracted a wide range of financial players including
swap dealers, pension funds, hedge funds, index investors, technical traders, and high net worth
individuals. There are concerns that these financial players and their trading strategies could move the oil
price away from the „true‟ underlying fundamentals. The fact remains however that the participants in
many of the OTC markets such as forward markets and CFDs which are central to the price discovery
process are mainly „physical‟ and include entities such as refineries, oil companies, downstream
consumers, physical traders, and market makers. Financial players such as pension funds and index
investors have limited presence in many of these markets. Thus, any analysis limited to non-commercial
participants in the futures market and their role in the oil price formation process is incomplete and also
potentially misleading.

The report also makes the distinction between trade in price differentials and trade in price levels. It
shows that trades in the levels of the oil price rarely take place in the layers surrounding the physical
benchmarks. We postulate that the price level of the main crude oil benchmarks is set in the futures
markets; the financial layers such as swaps and forwards set the price differentials depending on quality,
location and timing. These differentials are then used by oil reporting agencies to identify the price level
of a physical benchmark. If the price in the futures market becomes detached from the underlying
benchmark, the differentials adjust to correct for this divergence through a web of highly interlinked and
efficient markets. Thus, our analysis reveals that the level of the crude oil price, which consumers,
producers and their governments are most concerned with, is not the most relevant feature in the current
pricing system. Instead, the identification of price differentials and the adjustments in these differentials
in the various layers underlie the basis of the current crude oil pricing system. By trading differentials,
market participants limit their exposure to the risks of time, location grade and volume. Unfortunately,
this fact has received little attention and the issue of whether price differentials between different markets
showed strong signs of adjustment in the 2008-2009 price cycle has not yet received due attention in the
empirical literature.

But this leaves us with a fundamental question: what determines the price level of a certain benchmark in
the first place? The pricing system reflects how the oil market functions: if price levels are set in the
futures market and if market participants in these markets attach more weight to future fundamentals
rather than current fundamentals and/or if market participants expect limited feedbacks from both the

9
supply and demand side in response to oil price changes, these expectations will be reflected in the
different layers and will ultimately be reflected in the assessed spot price of a certain benchmark.

The current oil pricing system has survived for almost a quarter of a century, longer than the OPEC
administered system. While some of the details have changed, such as Saudi Arabia‟s decision to replace
Dated Brent with Brent futures in pricing its exports to Europe and the more recent move to replace WTI
with Argus Sour Crude Index (ASCI) in pricing its exports to the US, these changes are rather cosmetic.
The fundamentals of the current pricing system have remained the same since the mid 1980s: the price of
oil is set by the „market‟ with PRAs making use of various methodologies to reflect the market price in
their assessments and making use of information in the financial layers surrounding the global
benchmarks. In the light of the 2008-2009 price swings, the oil pricing system has received some
criticism reflecting the unease that some observers feel with the current system. Although alternative
pricing systems could be devised such as bringing back the administered pricing system or calling for
producers to assume a greater responsibility in the method of price formation by removing destination
restrictions on their exports, or allowing their crudes to be auctioned, the reality remains that the main
market players such as oil companies, refineries, oil exporting countries, physical traders and financial
players have no interest in rocking the boat. Market players and governments get very concerned about oil
price behaviour and its global and local impacts, but so far have showed much less interest in the pricing
system and market structure that signalled such price behaviour in the first place.

10
3. The Market-Related Oil Pricing System and Formulae Pricing
The collapse of the OPEC administered pricing system in 1986-1988 ushered in a new era in oil pricing in
which the power to set oil prices shifted from OPEC to the so called „market‟. First adopted by the
Mexican national oil company PEMEX in 1986, the market-related pricing system received wide
acceptance among most oil-exporting countries and by 1988 it became and still is the main method for
pricing crude oil in international trade. The oil market was ready for such a transition. The end of the
concession system and the waves of nationalisations which disrupted oil supplies to multinational oil
companies established the basis of arm‟s-length deals and exchange outside the vertically and
horizontally integrated multinational companies. The emergence of many suppliers outside OPEC and
more buyers further increased the prevalence of such arm‟s-length deals. This led to the development of a
complex structure of interlinked oil markets which consists of spot and also physical forwards, futures,
options and other derivative markets referred to as paper markets. Technological innovations that made
electronic trading possible revolutionised these markets by allowing 24-hour trading from any place in the
world. It also opened access to a wider set of market participants and allowed the development of a large
number of trading instruments both on regulated exchanges and over the counter.
Spot Markets, Long-Term Contracts and Formula Pricing
Physical delivery of crude oil is organised either through the spot (cash) market or through long-term
contracts. The spot market is used by transacting parties to buy and sell crude oil not covered by long-
term contractual arrangements and applies often to one-off transactions. Given the logistics of
transporting oil, spot cargoes for immediate delivery do not often take place. Instead, there is an important
element of forwardness in spot transactions which can be as much as 45 to 60 days. The parties can either
agree on the price at the time of the agreement, in which case the sport transaction becomes closer to a
„forward‟ contract.19 More often though, transacting parties link the pricing of an oil cargo to the time of
loading.

Long-term contracts are negotiated bilaterally between buyers and sellers for the delivery of a series of oil
shipments over a specified period of time, usually one or two years. They specify, among other things, the
volumes of crude oil to be delivered, the delivery schedule, the actions to be taken in case of default, and
above all the method that should be used in calculating the price of an oil shipment. Price agreements are
usually concluded on the method of formula pricing which links the price of a cargo in long-term
contracts to a market (spot) price. Formula pricing has become the basis of the oil pricing system.
Crude oil is not a homogenous commodity. There are various types of internationally traded crude oil
with different qualities and characteristics. Crude oil is of little use before refining and is traded for the
final petroleum products that consumers demand. The intrinsic properties of crude oil determine the mix
of final petroleum products. The two most important properties are density and sulfur content. Crude oils
with lower density, referred to as light crude, usually yield a higher proportion of the more valuable final
petroleum products such as gasoline and other light products by simple refining processes. Light crude
oils are contrasted with heavy ones that have a low share of light hydrocarbons and require a much more
complex refining process such as coking and cracking to produce similar proportions of the more valuable
petroleum products. Sulfur, a naturally occurring element in crude oil, is an undesirable property and
refiners make heavy investments in order to remove it. Crude oils with high sulfur are referred to as sour
crudes while those with low sulfur content are referred to as sweet crudes.
Since the type of crude oil has a bearing on refining yields, different types of crude streams fetch different
prices. The light/sweet crude grades usually command a premium over the heavy/sour crude grades.
Given the large variety of crude oils, the price of a particular crude oil is usually set at a discount or at a

19
Although spot transactions contain an element of forwardness, they are considered as commercial agreements
under US law and are not subject to the regulation of the Commodity Exchange Act.

20
premium to a marker or reference price. These references prices are often referred to as benchmarks. The
formula used in pricing oil in long-term contracts is straightforward. Specifically, for crude oil of variety
x, the formula pricing can be written as
Px = PR ± D
where Px is the price of crude x; PR is the benchmark crude price; and D is the value of the price
differential. The differential is often agreed at the time when the deal is concluded and could be set by an
oil exporting country or assessed by price reporting agencies.20 It is important to note that formula pricing
may apply to all types of contractual arrangements, be they spot, forward or long term. For instance, a
spot transaction in the crude oil market, is - pricing wise - an agreement on a spot value of the differential
between the physical oil traded and the price of an agreed oil benchmark, which fixes the absolute price
level for such trade, normally around the time of delivery or the loading date.

Differences in crude oil quality are not the only determinant of crude oil price differentials however. The
movements in differentials also reflect movements in the Gross Products Worth (GPW) obtained from
refining the reference crude R and the crude x.21 Thus, price differentials between the different varieties of
crude oil are not constant and change continuously according to the relative demand and supply of the
various crudes which in turn depend on the relative prices of petroleum products. Figure 1 plots the
differential that Saudi Arabia applied to its crude exports to Asia for its different types of crude oil
relative to the Oman/Dubai benchmark during the period 2000-2010 (January). As seen from this figure,
the discounts and premiums applied are highly variable. For instance, at the beginning of 2008, the
differentials between Arab Super Light and Arab Heavy widened sharply to reach more than $15 a barrel;
fuel oil, a product of heavy crude, was in surplus while the demand for diesel, a product of lighter crudes,
was high. In the first months of 2009, the price differential between heavy and light crude oil narrowed to
very low levels as the implementation of OPEC cuts reduced the supply of heavy crude and increased the
relative value of heavy-sour crudes.

Figure 1: Price Differentials of Various Types of Saudi Arabia’s Crude Oil to Asia in $/Barrel

+10.00
+8.00
+6.00
+4.00
+2.00
0.00
-2.00
-4.00
-6.00
-8.00
-10.00
Sep-04
Sep-00

Sep-01

Sep-02

Sep-03

Sep-05

Sep-06

Sep-07

Sep-08

Sep-09
May-00

May-01

May-02

May-03

May-04

May-05

May-06

May-07

May-08

May-09
Jan-00

Jan-01

Jan-02

Jan-03

Jan-04

Jan-05

Jan-06

Jan-07

Jan-08

Jan-09

Jan-10

Arab Super Light-50 Arab Extra Light-37 Arab Light-33


Arab Medium -31 Arab Heavy-27

Source: Petroleum Intelligence Weekly Database

20
Official formula pricing refers to the process of setting the differential in relation to a benchmark with the
resultant price known as official formula prices. This should be distinguished from official selling prices in which
the government sets the price on an outright basis.
21
Individual crudes have a particular yield of products with a gross product worth (GPW). GPW depends both on
on the refining process and the prices at which these products are sold.

21
The differential to a benchmark is independently set by each of the oil-producing countries. For many
countries, it is usually set in the month preceding the loading month and is adjusted monthly or quarterly.
For instance, for the month of May, the differential is announced in the month before, i.e. April based on
information and data about GPW available in the month of March.22 Since the process of setting price
differentials involves long time lags and is based on old information and data, the value of the price
differential does not often reflect the market conditions at the time of loading and much less so by the
time the cargo reaches its final destination. In the case of multiple transactions under a long-term contract,
buyers can be compensated by sellers by adjusting downwards the differential in the next rounds if the
price proves to be higher than what is warranted by market conditions at the time of loading or at
delivery. This continuous process of adjusting differentials is inevitable given that setting the differential
is based on lagged data and if oil exporters wish to maintain the competitiveness of their crudes.
In other countries such as Abu Dhabi and Qatar, the governments do not announce price differentials, but
rather an outright price known as the official selling price (OSP). These are, however, strongly linked to
Dubai-Oman benchmark and thus, one can assume that outright prices contain an implicit price
differential and hence are close to formula prices (see Horsnell and Mabro, 1993; Argus, 2010).23
In setting the differential, an oil-exporting country will not only consider the differential between its crude
and the reference crude, but has also to consider how its closest competitors are pricing their crude in
relation to the reference crude. This implies that the timing of setting the differential matters, especially in
a slack market. Oil-exporting countries that announce their differentials first are at the competitive
disadvantage of being undercut by their closest competitors. This can induce them to delay announcement
of the differential or, in the case of multiple transactions, compensate the buyers by adjusting the
differential downward in the next rounds. Competition between various exporters implies that crude oils
of similar quality and destined for the same region tend to trade at very narrow differentials. Figure 2
below shows the price differential between Saudi Arabia Light (33.0 API) and Iranian Light (33.4 API)
destined to Asia. As seen from this graph, the differentials are narrow not exceeding 30 cents most of the
time although on some occasions, the differentials tend to widen. Such large differentials do not tend to
persist as adjustments are made to keep the crude oil competitive. In the mid 1990s, Saudi Arabia Light
was trading at a premium to the Iranian Light, but this premium turned into discount in the slack market
conditions of 1998. In the period 2002 to 2004, the two types of crude oil were trading almost at par, but
since 2007, Saudi Arabian Light has been trading at a discount, making its light crude more competitive
compared to the Iranian Light, perhaps in an attempt by Saudi Arabia to maximise its export volume to
Asia or due to mispricing on the part of the Iranian National Oil Company.
The above discussion focused only on the pricing mechanism implemented by an oil exporting country
via its national oil company. The value of the differential does not need not to be set by an oil producing
country and can be assessed by price reporting agencies.

22
For details see Horsnell and Mabro (1993).
23
Abu Dhabi and Qatar set the OSP retroactively so that the OSP announced in the month of October applies to
cargoes that have already been loaded in the month of September while Oman and Dubai dropped retroactive pricing
when they moved from Platts Oman-Dubai to DME Oman in August 2007.

22
Figure 2: Differentials of Term Prices between Saudi Arabia Light and Iran Light Destined to Asia
(FOB) (In US cents)

0.50
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
0.00
-0.10
-0.20
-0.30
-0.40
-0.50
Jun 95
Nov 95
Apr 96

Jul 97

Aug 99
Jan 00
Jun 00
Nov 00
Apr 01

Aug 04

Jun 05
Nov 05
Apr 06

Aug 09
Jan 95

Jul 02

Jan 05

Jul 07

Jan 10
Sep 96
Feb 97

Mar 99

Sep 01
Feb 02

Mar 04

Sep 06
Feb 07

Mar 09
Dec 97
May 98
Oct 98

Dec 02
May 03
Oct 03

Dec 07
May 08
Oct 08
Source: Oil Market Intelligence Database
The „equivalence to the buyer‟ principle, which means that in practice prices of crudes have equivalent
prices at destination, adds another dimension to the pricing formulae. The location in which prices should
be compared is not the point of origin but must be closer to the destination where the buyer receives the
cargo. Since the freight costs vary depending on the export destination, some formulae also take into
account the relative freight costs between destinations. Specifically, they allow for the difference between
the freight costs involved in moving the reference crude from its location to a certain destination (e.g.
Brent from Sollum Voe to Rotterdam) and the costs involved in moving crude x from the oil country‟s
terminal to that certain destination (e.g. Arabian Light from Ras Tanura to Rotterdam). In such cases, the
sale contract is close to a cost, insurance and freight (CIF) contract. This is in contrast to a free on board
(FOB) contract which refers to a situation in which the seller fulfils his obligations to deliver when the
goods have passed over the ship‟s rail. The buyer bears all the risks of loss of or damage to the goods
from that point as well as all other costs such as freight and insurance.
A major advantage of formula pricing is that the price of an oil shipment can be linked to the price at the
time of delivery which reflects the market conditions prevailing. When there is a lag between the date at
which a cargo is bought and the date of arrival at its destination, there is a big price risk. Transacting
parties usually share this risk through the pricing formula. Agreements are often made for the date of
pricing to occur around the delivery date. For instance, in the case of Saudi Arabia‟s exports to the United
States up to December 2009, the date of pricing varied between 40 to 50 days after the loading date. The
price used in contracts could be linked to the price of benchmark averaged over 10 days around the
delivery date, which rendered the point of sale closer to destination than the origin. In 2010, Saudi Arabia
shifted to Argus Sour Crude Index (ASCI) and it currently uses the trade month (20 day minimum)
average of ASCI prices for the trade month applying to the time of delivery.
Oil exporters may have different pricing policies for different regions. For instance, for Saudi exports to
the US, the price that matters most is the cost of shipment at the delivery point. For its exports to Asia, the
pricing point is free on board and hence the price that matters most is the price at the loading terminal.
Figure 3 below shows the price difference between crude delivered to the US Gulf Coast and the price
sold at FOB to Asia for different variety of crude oils. As seen from this graph, the price differential is
highly variable depending on the relative demand and supply conditions between these two markets and
the degree of competition from alternative sources of supply. While in the US, Saudi Arabia faces tough
competition from many suppliers including domestic ones and hence its crude has to be competitive at

23
destination, the strong growth in Asian demand and the limited degree of competition in Asia give rise to
an „Asian premium‟. Hence, in some occasions the price of a cargo delivered to the US is less than the
FOB price to Asia despite the fact that it takes longer for a cargo to reach the US.
Figure 3: Difference in Term Prices for Various Crude Oil Grades to the US Gulf (Delivered) and
Asia (FOB)

15.00

10.00

5.00

0.00

-5.00

-10.00

Jan 07
Jan 00

Sep 00
Jan 01

Jan 02

Jan 03

Jan 04

Jan 05

Jan 06

Sep 06

Jan 08

Jan 09

Jan 10
Sep 01

Sep 02

Sep 03

Sep 04

Sep 05

Sep 07

Sep 08

Sep 09
May 00

May 01

May 02

May 03

May 04

May 05

May 06

May 07

May 08

May 09
Saudi Arabia Saudi Arabia Saudi Arabia
Light-33.0 Arab Medium-3.5 Arab Heavy-27.6

Source: Oil Market Intelligence

Benchmarks in Formulae Pricing


At the heart of formulae pricing is the identification of the price of key „physical‟ benchmarks, such as
West Texas Intermediate (WTI), the ASCI price, Dated Brent (but also called Dated North Sea Light,
North Sea Dated, Dated BFOE)24 and Dubai. The prices of these benchmark crudes, often referred to as
„spot‟ market prices, are central to the oil pricing system. The prices of these benchmarks are used by oil
companies and traders to price cargoes under long-term contracts or in spot market transactions; by
futures exchanges for the settlement of their financial contracts; by banks and companies for the
settlement of derivative instruments such as swap contracts; and by governments for taxation purposes.25
Table 1 below lists some of the various benchmarks used by key oil exporters. As seen from the table,
countries use different benchmarks depending on the export destination. For instance, Iraq uses Brent for
its exports to Europe, a combination of Oman and Dubai for its exports to Asia, and until very recently
WTI for its exports for the US. In 2010, Saudi Arabia, Kuwait and Iraq switched to the Argus Sour Crude
Index (ASCI) for exports destined to the US. Mexico uses quite a complex formula in pricing its exports
to the US which includes a weighted average of the prices of West Texas Sour (WTS), Louisiana Light
Sweet (LLS), Dated Brent, and High Sulfur Fuel Oil (HSFO). For its exports to Europe, Mexico uses both
high and low sulfur fuel oil (FO) and Dated Brent.

24
Platts continues to call the physical market Dated Brent or Dated North Sea Light while Argus calls it North Sea
Dated. As shall be discussed later, the continued use of the term „Dated Brent‟ by Platts and much of the industry is
not an arcane point, because the price of physical Dated Brent cargoes will be different from its „Dated Brent‟ price.
The prices of physical Brent, Forties and Oseberg all differ from the (Argus) North Sea Dated/(Platts) Dated Brent
value.
25
Some governments (Oman, Qatar, Abu Dhabi, Malaysia, and Indonesia) do not use benchmarks at all and instead
set their own official selling prices (OSPs) on a monthly basis. These can be set retroactively or retrospectively.

24
Table 1: Main Benchmarks Used in Formula Pricing

Asia Europe US
ASCI from
BWAVE from Jul.'00, Dated Brent
Saudi Arabia Oman and Dubai Jan.2010, WTI
Until Jun.'00
until Dec.'09
BWAVE from Jan.'01, Dated
Iran Oman and Dubai
Brent Until Dec.'00
ASCI from
BWAVE from Jul.'00, Dated Brent
Kuwait Oman and Dubai December 2009 ;
Until Jun.'00
Previously WTI
ASCI from April
Iraq (Basrah 2010, Previously
Blend) WTI Second
Oman and Dubai Dated Brent Month
Nigeria Dated Brent Brent

Dated Brent x0.527 WTS x0.4


Mexico (Maya + 3.5%HSFO x0.467 + 3%HSFO x0.4
Blend) - 1%FO x.25 + LLS x0.1
+ 3.5%FO x0.25‟ + Dtd.Brent x0.1

The pricing may be based on „physical‟ benchmarks such as Dated Brent or on the financial layers
surrounding these physical benchmarks such as the Brent Weighted Average (BWAVE), which is an
index calculated on the basis of prices obtained in the Brent futures market. Specifically, the BWAVE is
the weighted average of all futures price quotations that arise for a given contract of the futures exchange
during a trading day, with the weights being the shares of the relevant volume of transactions on that day.
Major oil exporters such as Saudi Arabia, Kuwait and Iran use BWAVE as the basis of pricing crude
exports to Europe. As seen from Figure 4 below, the price differential between Dated Brent and BWAVE
is quite variable with the differential in some occasions exceeding plus or minus three dollars per barrel.
This is expected as BWAVE is considerably less prompt than Dated Brent and thus variability between
the two should consider this time basis issue.26 Therefore, the choice of benchmark has serious
implications on government revenues. This is perhaps most illustrated in the recent shift from WTI to
ASCI by some Gulf exporters. Figure 5 plots the price differential between the two US benchmarks WTI
and ASCI. WTI traded at a premium to ASCI through most of this time but occasionally (four significant
times) WTI moved to a discount when WTI collapsed versus other world benchmarks, with the WTI
discount to ASCI reaching close to $8/barrel on 12 February 2009. The January/ February events
prompted Saudi Arabia to consider alternatives to Platts WTI cash assessment.

26
Furthermore, as volatility is strongly backwardated itself along its own forward curve for most markets, this is
also a relevant factor.

25
Figure 4: Price Differential between Dated Brent and BWAVE ($/Barrel)

4.00
3.00
2.00
1.00
...
-1.00
-2.00
-3.00
-4.00
-5.00

Source: Petroleum Intelligence Weekly

Figure 5: Price Differential between WTI and ASCI ($/Barrel) (ASCI Price=0)

8.00
6.00
4.00
2.00
0.00
-2.00
-4.00
-6.00
-8.00
-10.00

ASCI WTI vs ASCI

Source: Argus
Given the central role that benchmarking plays in the current oil pricing system, it is important to
highlight some of the main features of the most widely used benchmarks. First, unlike the futures market
where prices are observable in real time, the reported prices of physical benchmarks are „identified‟ or
„assessed‟ prices. These assessments are carried out by oil pricing reporting agencies, the two most
important of which are Platts and Argus.27 Assessments are needed in opaque markets such as oil where
physical transactions concluded between parties cannot be directly observed by market participants. After
all, parties are under no obligation to report their deals. Assessments are also needed in illiquid markets

27
There are other PRAs but these are often more specialised such as OMR (focus on Germany, Austria, and
Switzerland), APPI (focus on Asia), RIM (focus on Asia), ICIS-LOR (focus on petrochemicals) and OPIS (focus on
US). In December 2010, Platts announced an agreement to acquire OPIS. The acquisition is expected to be
completed in the first half of 2011, subject to regulatory approval.

26
where not enough representative deals or where no transactions take place. Oil reporting agencies assess
their prices based on information on concluded deals which they observe, or bids and offers, and failing
that on market talk, other private and public information gathered by reporters, and information from
financial markets. It is important to note that PRAs do not use in all markets a hierarchy of information
cascading down from deals to bids and offers, which would imply that deals are the best price discovery
and bids/offers are a poorer alternative. The methodology may vary from market to market in accordance
with the published methodology for that market. In some markets, bid/offer information takes precedence
over deals in identifying the published price – e.g. if the deal is either not representative of the market as
defined in the methodology, or was done earlier or later in the day to the prevailing depth of market. In
other markets, price identification relies on observed deals. For instance, Argus‟ main benchmark ASCI is
entirely deal based. Most however accept that a done deal does represent the highest form of „proof‟ of
value, unless there is a supervening issue with the trade‟s conduct. If assessments are intended to
represent an end-of day price, analogous to a futures „settlement „ however, a fully evidenced bid/offer
spread at a later point when markets have clearly moved in value is an acceptable proxy in the absence of
a trade .

Sometimes a distinction is made between prices identified through observed deals or transactions using a
direct mathematical formula such as volume-weighted average (referred to as an index) and prices
identified through a process of interpretation based on bids and offers, market surveys, and other
information gathered by reporters (referred to as price assessment) (see Argus, 2010). The choice of the
method varies across markets and depends on the structure of market, particularly on the degree of market
opaqueness and liquidity. While an index is suitable for markets with high trading liquidity and
transparency, assessments are more suitable in opaque and illiquid markets. In this paper, we do not make
this distinction and refer to both categories as price assessment. However, regardless of the method used,
there is an important element of subjectivity involved as the methodology has to be decided by managers
and editors. The choice of methodology (the time window in which the price is assessed, the grade
specification, location) in an index based system is just as subjective as price assessment. In that respect,
one approach (index or assessment) is no more subjective than the other.

Second, these agencies do not always produce the same price for the same benchmark as these pursue
different methodologies in their price assessments. Even if price quotations are based on a mechanical
methodology of deals done, two price reporting services could publish different prices for the same crude
because their price identification process and the deals they include in the assessment could be different.
For example, one PRA might use a volume weighted average of transactions between 9.00am and 5.00pm
while another PRA might use last trade or open bid/offer at specified period of time. Or one PRA might
include transactions within a 10-21 day price range and another includes transactions in a 10-15 day price
range. Or one PRA might only include fixed-price transactions and another include fixed-price and
formula-related transactions.

Third, the nature of these benchmarks tends to evolve over time. Although the general principle of
benchmarking has remained more or less the same over the last twenty-five years, the details of these
benchmarks in terms of their liquidity and the type of crudes that are included in the assessment process
have changed dramatically over that period. The assessment of the traditional Brent benchmark now
includes the North Sea streams Forties, Oseberg and Ekofisk (BFOE) and that of Platts Dubai price
includes Oman and Upper Zakum. These streams are not of identical quality and often fetch different
prices. Thus, the assessed price of a benchmark does not always refer to a particular „physical‟ crude
stream. It rather refers to a constructed „index‟28 which is derived on the basis of a simple mathematical
formula which takes the lowest priced grade of the different component crudes to set the benchmark.

28
This may take the form of a matrix of closely-related prices which use the total physical liquidity by engineering
price floors and caps to reduce or eliminate the possibility of price distortion or skews.

27
Table 2 below summarises some basic statistics of the main international benchmarks: BFOE in the North
Sea, WTI and ASCI in the US, and Dubai-Oman in the Gulf. In terms of production, the underlying
physical base of the benchmark amounts to slightly more than 3 million b/d, i.e., around 3.5% of global
production. In terms of liquidity, there is wide difference across benchmarks. While in the US the number
of spot trades per calendar month is close to 600, the number of spot trades does not exceed three per
month in the case of Dubai. The divergence in liquidity across benchmarks reflects the low underlying
physical base and the different nature of benchmarks where US crudes are pipeline crudes with small
trading lots whereas Brent and Dubai are waterborne crudes with large trading lots. Table 2 also shows
that the degree of concentration in traded volumes varies considerably across markets. From the sellers‟
side, Dubai, Oman and Forties exhibit a high degree of concentration in the total volume of spot trades
especially when compared to US markets. From the buyers‟ side, Dubai and Forties exhibit a high degree
of concentration whereas Oman compares favourably with other benchmarks.
Table 2: Some Basic Features of Benchmark Crudes

First-quarter 2010 averages WTI CMA


by Argus ASCI + WTI P- Forties BFOE Dubai Oman
Plus

Production (MBPD) 736 300-400 562 1,220 70-80 710

Volume Spot Traded (MBPD) 579 939 514 635 86 246

Number of Spot Trades per


260 330 18 98 3.5 10
Cal Month

Number of Spot Trades Per


13 16 <1 5 <1 <1
Day

Number of Different Spot


26 27 7 10 3 5
Buyers per Cal Month

Number of Different Spot


24 36 6 9 3 6
Sellers per Cal Month

Largest 3 Buyers % of Total


43% 38% 63% 72% 100% 50%
Spot Volume

Largest 3 Sellers % of Total


38% 51% 76% 56% 100% 80%
Spot Volume

Source: Argus
Notes: Daily statistics are per trade day, except production which is per calendar day; Forties: The physical grade
usually sets North Sea Dated/Dated Brent; BFOE: Forward cash contracts deliverable as physical BFOE cargoes,
used in setting the flat price against which North Sea Dated is calculated; Oman: Excludes physical deliveries
through DME. Estimated deliveries on DME contacts are 300,000-400,000 barrels per day; WTI: Includes cash
market trade for WTI Calendar Month Average and WTI P-Plus. Cash market at Cushing no longer trades except at
last three days of trade month as spread for 2 nd month. Roll trades are not included here. Also does not include any
volumes on CME Nymex futures.

Finally, in the last two decades or so, many financial layers (paper markets) have emerged around these
benchmarks. These include the forward market (in Brent), swaps, futures, and options. Some of the

28
instruments such as futures and options are traded on regulated exchanges such as ICE and CME Group,
while other instruments, such as swaps and forward contracts, are traded bilaterally over the counter
(OTC). Nevertheless, these financial layers are highly interlinked through the process of arbitrage and the
development of instruments that link the various markets together such as the Exchange of Futures for
Swaps (EFS) which allow traders to roll positions from futures to swaps and vice versa. Over the years,
these markets have grown in terms of size, liquidity, sophistication and have attracted a diverse set of
players, both physical and financial. These markets have become central for market participants wishing
to hedge their risk and to bet (or speculate) on oil price movements. Equally important, these financial
layers have become central to the oil price identification process. In Sections 5, 6 and 7, we discuss the
main benchmarks used in the current oil pricing system and the financial layers surrounding these
benchmarks.

29
4. Oil Price Reporting Agencies and the Price Discovery Process
The oil price reporting agencies (PRAs) are an important component of the oil industry. The prices that
these agencies identify or assess underlie the basis of long-term contracts, spot market transactions,
futures markets contracts and derivatives instruments. Some PRAs argue that through their
methodological structure for reporting physical transactions, they act as „a mirror to the trade‟ and provide
„transparency on what would otherwise be a collection of bilateral deals‟.29 However, as argued by
Horsnell and Mabro (1993:155) oil PRAs are
far more than mere observers of crude oil and oil product markets. If they were, then their only
role would be to add to the price transparency of the market. However, deals worth hundreds of
millions of dollars per day ride on published assessment and the nature and structure of oil
reporting create trading opportunities and new markets and affect the behaviour of oil traders.
Price reporting does more than provide a mirror for oil markets; the reflection in the mirror can
affect the image itself.
Indeed, in their attempt to identify the price that reflects accurately the market value of the oil barrel,
PRAs enter into the decision-making territory that can influence market structure. For instance, Platts
decides on the time of pricing of oil (the time stamping), the width of the Platt‟s window, the size of the
parcel to be traded, the process of delivery, and the time of delivery of the contract. PRAs make these
decisions on the basis of regular consultations with the industry. In return, PRAs influence the trading
strategies of the various participants and their reporting policies. In fact, new markets and contracts may
emerge to hedge the risks arising from some of the decisions that PRAs make. Even when price
assessments are based on observed transactions and mathematical formula, there is still an important
element of decision-making involved as this entails the choice about the assumptions behind the
methodology. Editors and managers in PRAs choose how to build the index (in the case of Argus) and
how to allow for non-deals-based methodologies in case of a lack of deals.
While PRAs have been an integral part of the crude oil market especially since the shift to the market-
related pricing system in 198630, their role has recently been attracting considerable attention. In the G20
summit in Korea in November 2010, the G20 leaders called on „the IEF, IEA, OPEC and IOSCO to
produce a joint report, by the April 2011 Finance Ministers‟ meeting, on how the oil spot market prices
are assessed by oil price reporting agencies and how this affects the transparency and functioning of oil
markets „.31 In its latest report in November 2010, IOSCO points that „the core concern with respect to
price reporting agencies is the extent to which the reported data accurately reflects the cash market in
question‟.32 As discussed below, the accuracy of price assessments heavily depends on large number of
factors including the quality of information obtained by the PRA, the internal procedures applied by the
PRAs and the methodologies used in price assessment.
To evaluate the role of PRAs in the oil market, it is important to look at three inter-related dimensions: the
methodology used in identifying the oil price; the accuracy of price assessments;33 and the internal
measures that PRAs implement to protect their integrity and ensure an efficient price assessment process.
There is a fundamental difference in the methodology and in the philosophy underlying the price
assessment process between the various pricing reporting agencies. As a result, different agencies may
produce different prices for the same benchmark. Even if price quotations are based on a mechanical
methodology of deals done, two price reporting services could publish different prices for the same crude

29
Argus Response to the „Report of the Working Group on the Volatility of Oil Prices‟ chaired by Professor Jean-
Marie Chevalier, p.5.
30
PRAs assessment were already widely used in the price formation process for refined products prior to 1986.
31
G-20 Seoul Summit 2010, THE SEOUL SUMMIT DOCUMENT, Paragraph 61.
32
IOSCO (2010), Task Force on Commodity Futures Markets: Report to the G20, November 2010, p. 17.
33
Though other attributes such as representativeness and usefulness could also be included.

30
because their mechanical price identification process could be different. This raises the issue of which of
the methods generates a more accurate price assessment. Given that assessed prices underlie long-term
contracts, spot transactions and derivatives instruments, even small differences in price assessments
between PRAs have serious implications for exporters‟ revenues and financial flows between parties in
financial contracts.
PRAs use a wide variety of methods to identify the oil price which may include the volume weighted
average system, low and high deals done, and market-on-close (MOC). In January 2001, Platts stopped
using the volume-weighted average system and replaced it with the MOC methodology.34 In this system,
Platts sets a time window, known as the Platts window, and only deals transacted within this time window
are used to assess the oil price.35 The price is assessed on the basis of concluded deals, or failing that, on
bids and offers. Assessment will also make use of information from financial layers about spreads and
derivative „to help triangulate value‟.36 Thus, the MOC can be thought of a structured system for
gathering information on the basis of which Platts assesses the daily price of key physical benchmarks. In
a way, it is similar to a futures exchange where traders make bids and offers, but with two major
differences: the parties behind the bids and offers are known, and Platts decides on the information to be
considered in the assessment, i.e., the information passes through the Platts filter. These price assessments
are then transmitted back to the market through a variety of channels. The reason for the shift to MOC is a
concern that „an averaging system for price determination could result in assessments that lag actual
market levels as deals done early in an assessment period at a level that is not repeatable, could
mathematically drag prices down or up‟ (Platts, 2010a:7).37 Thus, Platts emphasises the time sensitivity of
its assessed prices which are „clearly time-stamped‟ on a daily basis.38 Time stamping not only allows for
an accurate reflection of price levels at particular point in time, but also for accurate assessment of time
spreads and inter-crude spreads.
Both the volume-weighted average method and the MOC have received their share of criticism. While the
volume-weighted average method allows the inclusion of a large number of deals and hence is more
representative, the method has been criticised as it

34
In the US, Platts used a volume weighted average for domestic crude. But for products, it has always used a low
and high of deals done. In the WTI crude market prior to 2001 Platts used a volume weighted average of a 30-
minute window. In Asia, Platts used the window or page 190, its first „market on close‟, also before 2001. The
market on close went global for Platts in 2001.
35
It is important to note that the window opens all day and Platts will accept trades, bids and offers at any time of
the day. But only deals transacted within a specified period of time (for instance from 4:00 to 4:30 for European
crudes) are considered for assessing the price for that day. Some argue that this may encourage traders to present
their bids/offers to Platts during this time window in order to maximize their impact on prices.
36
Thorne, S. (2010), „A User guide to Platts Assessment Processes‟, Presentation at the Platts Crude Oil
Methodology Forum 2010, London, May.
37
Platts (2010a), Methodology and Specifications Guide: Crude Oil, The McGraw Hill Companies, October.
38
Some commentators consider that through its window, Platts is able to establish the marginal price of oil, which in
principle should set price for the rest of the market. It is not clear what is meant by the marginal price, but in terms
of theory, the closest one can think of the Platts‟ window is in terms of the Walrasian auctioneer. The Walrasian
auctioneer is a fictitious construct who aggregates traders‟ demand and supplies to find a market clearing price,
through a series of auctions. While Platts window resembles the Walrasian auctioneer, it differs fundamentally in
many respects such as the existence of transactions costs, barriers to entry and the fact that the auctioneer does not
perform a passive role in the market. It decides who enters the market and when to the set the price. It has also been
long realised that trading has a timing dimension. While over time, the number of buyers and sellers may be equal,
at any particular the time, this is not guaranteed in which case it is not possible to find a market clearing price
(Demsetz, 1968). This could be overcome by participants paying an immediacy premium in which case the
equilibrium will be characterised by two demand and supply curves and two prices. Furthermore, the literature
shows that market structure such as the number of players, their size, the timing of entry matters and could affect the
trading price. Therefore, the actual mechanism used to set the price is not simply a channel, but is an input into the
price and as such cannot be ignored (see O'Hara, 1997).

31
may result in an index that is out of step and not reflective of the actual market price prevailing at the
close of the day. This would especially be the case on days with high volatility. Trade- weighted
averages may also be distorted by the pattern of trading liquidity over the day…. A key weakness in
all trade-weighted average assessments is that they will lag the market price. They always reflect a
price that „was‟ rather than the price that „is.‟ (Platts, 2010b:6).39
The main criticism of the MOC methodology is that the Platts window often lacks sufficient liquidity and
may be dominated by few players which may hamper the price discovery process. For instance, Argus,
Platts‟ main competitor, argues that in US crude markets
MOC methodology would work if the industry poured liquidity into the window. Without this
liquidity, the methodology is left to assess the value at the close based on bids, offers and other
related factors. This means that the price derived from an MOC assessment can diverge widely
from a weighted average of all deals done in the trading day.40
This divergence is expected given that the average price is different from the stamped price and the
convergence of the two is just a statistical accident if it ever happens.
Argus conducted a study on the US crude oil market in 2007 which compares the spot market traded
volume inside the window with the volume traded during the entire day. The study finds that the volume
traded within the Platts window constitutes only a very small fraction of daily traded volumes, as seen in
Table 3 below. This applies to a wide variety of US crudes. Argus argues that such low liquidity and
„complete lack of participant breadth‟ raise „serious questions about the efficiency of price discovery‟ in
the US oil market.41
Table 3: Spot Market Traded Volumes in May 2007 (May traded during May Trade Month)

Window Entire Day (Argus) Window % of Total


LLS 0 446,920 0%
WTI Diff to CMA 26,425 378,445 7%
Mars 5,418 185,252 3%
WTS 1,000 154,706 1%
WTI Midland 3,000 138,470 2%
HLS 1,000 100,032 1%
WTI P-Plus 1,000 88,802 1%
Eugene Island 0 40,044 0%
Poseidon 0 73,857 0%
SGC 0 22,100 0%
Bonito 0 9,140 0%
37,843 1,637,768 2.31%
Source: Argus (2007)

One response to such a criticism is that if some market participants think that prices in the window are not
reflecting accurately the price of an oil barrel at the margin, then those participants should enter the
39
Platts (2010 b), Platts Oil Pricing and MOC Methodology Explained, The McGraw Hill Companies, June.
40
Argus Global Markets (2007), Liquidity and Diversity Prevail, 24 September, p. 15.
41
There are other markets, such as Asian products which would show in contrast very high % figures for Platts
„window‟ trades. Ultimately market participants decide upon which and whose pricing system and by implication,
methodology, they wish to use. However, once a critical mass of players is using one in a market or series of
markets, it is difficult and expensive to make a switch.

32
window and exert their influence on the price. However, in some markets, there might be barriers to entry
preventing such an adjustment mechanism from taking place. For instance, in the context of Dubai, Binks
(2005) argues that „participation (in the window) requires knowledgeable and experienced trading staff.
And many of the national oil companies that represent end-users in Asia are not allowed to participate in
speculative trading. For the same reason, Middle East producers will not participate in the partials market.
Even independent commercial buyers without these restraints in Asia feel reluctant to participate in the
partials trade out of concern that doing so could threaten their relations with Middle Eastern producers‟.42
It is important to note that while some barriers such as having experienced and professional staff and
qualified companies with the necessary logistics to execute physical trades can be considered as „natural
barriers‟, others barriers arise due to policy and strategic choices which limit the trading activity in the
window to a small group of what so called „professionals‟.43
Market participants are under no legal or regulatory obligation to report their deals to PRAs or any other
body for that matter. Whether participants decide to share information depend on their willingness, their
reporting policies, and their interest in doing so. In the US, the system is voluntary, but one potential
interpretation of the Sarbanes-Oxley legislation is that companies must report all or nothing, and cannot
„selectively‟ disclose information.44 Many companies have reporting policies that only bind them to report
deals that take place at a certain time of day, or in certain regional markets. In some markets such as the
US, confidentiality concerns dictate that some PRAs do not publish the names of the counterparties to a
deal. To ensure enough reporting takes place, PRAs such as Argus sign confidentiality agreements to
facilitate deal reporting in the US though companies may have the incentive to report prices without such
agreements. Since market participants have different interests and different positions, some traders may
have the incentive to manipulate prices by feeding false information to reporters though there have been
regulatory efforts to limit such behaviour. In the US, the Commodity Futures Trading Commission
(CFTC)45, the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC), and the Federal Trade Commission
(FTC)46 have passed regulations that prohibit false reporting. In the EU, the Market Abuse Directive is

42
Some interviewees also pointed to the high subscription cost involved in the entry of E-window, by which Platts is
assessing larger number of markets.
43
One interviewee considers this aspect as necessary otherwise enlarging the base of participants may create
logistical and serious performance issues, including safety issues.
44
Initially a law/regulation was passed in 2000 by the SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION (SEC)
known as Regulation FD (Fair Disclosure). This came out of and expands upon the Insider Trading law framework
and pertains to equities reporting. Sarbanes-Oxley Act expanded on this regulation. The Act deals with voluntary
reporting areas. The obligation is stated that should you volunteer to report information, the obligation is to report
that information fully. However, companies are not required to report trades to the PRAs. Lobo and Zhou (2006)
investigated the change in managerial discretion over financial reporting following the Sarbanes-Oxley Act and find
an increase in conservatism in financial reporting.
45
On November 3, 2010, the CFTC and the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) proposed rules under the
new anti-manipulation and anti-fraud provisions of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection
Act. One of the proposed rules states that, “It shall be unlawful for any person, directly or indirectly, in connection
with any swap, or contract of sale of any commodity in interstate commerce… to intentionally or recklessly:…..
make, or attempt to make, any untrue or misleading statement of a material fact or to omit to state a material fact
necessary in order to make the statements made not untrue or misleading…. deliver or cause to be delivered….by
any means of communication whatsoever, a false or misleading or inaccurate report concerning crop or market
information or conditions that affect or tend to affect the price of any commodity in interstate commerce, knowing,
or acting in reckless disregard of the fact that such report is false, misleading or inaccurate. Source:
http://www.cftc.gov/ucm/groups/public/@lrfederalregister/documents/file/2010-27541a.pdf
46
The Energy Independence and Security Act (Energy Act) signed into law December 19, 2007, gives the Federal
Trade Commission (FTC) new authority to police “market manipulation” and “false reporting” in the petroleum
industry joining the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) and the U.S. Commodity Futures Trading
Commission (CFTC) in this role. In section 812, the FTC is given the authority to act against false reporting in the
petroleum industry. FTC‟s authority however is limited to the false reporting of wholesale transactions and those “to

33
also meant to perform a similar role, though its impact on price reporting is not yet clear. As discussed
above, Platts relies on a more structured system for gathering information. However traders can undertake
some anomalous deals in the Platts window by accepting high offers or underselling by delivering into
low bids in an attempt to influence the assessed price. The losses made by such transactions can be more
than compensated by entering into other contracts such as swaps. Thus, PRAs must ensure that the
information received is correct and accurate and that deals done in the window are genuine, otherwise the
whole price discovery process will be undermined. For instance, Platts will not knowingly publish any bid
or offer that is not within the market range. In addition, when offers are lifted or bids are hit, there is a
secondary process to ensure that there is no gapping and if such gapping is detected to ensure that price
assessment process is not affected by it. There are also other mechanisms to avoid the influence of non-
repeatable deals.
In a liquid market, false reporting can be less of a problem as reporters could observe concluded deals and
confirm the information they obtain from both parties. At the same time, reporters will make use of the
regular flow of information originating from the futures and OTC markets. In contrast, in illiquid markets,
a small number of reported deals or a few bids and offers can heavily influence the price assessment
process. In days when reporters cannot observe active buyers, sellers or transactions to determine the
price or simply when such deals do not exist, 47 PRAs rely on a variety of sources of information sources
or market talk to make „intelligent assessments‟.48 In such circumstances, the reporter will look at bids
and offers from other markets, draw comparisons with similar crudes but with higher trading activity,
analyse forward curves, survey market participants‟ opinions, and assess spread across markets to reach a
price assessment. In fact, in some instances, as in illiquid markets, the price assessment could be more
accurate in the absence of transactions, if these transactions were intended to manipulate the oil price.
In some instances, a PRA can retrospectively correct previously unidentified assessment errors. There are
some instances in which traders may dispute the assessed price reached by a PRA. There is no evidence to
suggest that this problem is widespread, but from time to time these disputes filter into media reports. For
instance, in 29 April 2010, Platts assessed the value of the June and July cash BFOE spread at minus
$0.68 a barrel. Some brokers in the market claimed that Platts assessment of the differential is inaccurate.
Based on information from the futures market and the EFP, these brokers claimed that the value of the
differential should have been minus $0.94 a barrel.49 Regardless of which value is more accurate, what is
important to note that if such disputes over price assessments ever arise there is no supervisory or
regulatory authority which would look into these claims and counter-claims.
In order to safeguard the price assessment process, PRA seek to verify the accuracy of the information
they receive and when they are unable to do so they retain the right to exclude data and information. In
this way, they guard against false data distorting their assessments. They also undertake many procedures,
both within their own organisations as well as in relation to outside participants. For instance, Platts has
control on the parties that can participate in the window. The companies behind every bid and offer must
be clearly identified with a track record of operational and financial performance and be recognisable in
the market. Trading is closely monitored and those participants that fail to meet editorial standards and/or

a Federal Department or agency.” It remain unclear if the Energy Act encompasses the reporting of false or
misleading information publicly into the market or to private organizations or PRAs.
47
It should be noted that when this is the case, companies who sign contracts linked to PRA prices tend not to use
pricing centres that are illiquid. They know that no matter how well the PRA does their job the price may be volatile
or unresponsive. In many cases, the PRA chooses not to assess a crude or product because the market is too illiquid,
or there are insufficient parameters available to make an assessment based on correlative data points.
48
Intelligent assessment refers to the process of assessing prices in illiquid markets where transactions are not
observable to reporters.
49
Paddy Gourlay “Dated Brent Assessment Sparks Calls For Methodology Change”, Dow Jones Newswires, 30
April 2010

34
make spurious offers and bids are expelled from the window.50 Concluded transactions between parties
are sometimes subject to verification by the various price reporting agencies; spurious deals are excluded
from the assessment process. PRAs may request documentation for concluded deals such as contract
documentation or other supporting materials such as loading and inspection documents.51
Another important dimension is compliance procedures within PRAs. The accuracy of the price
assessment will depend primarily on the policies, procedures and training put in place by the PRA. Such
procedures are needed to ensure both internal and external independence and to ascertain that reporters
are following the same rules, reporting procedures and methodology as set out by the RPA. All the
regulations and compliance procedures are designed and enforced internally without being subject to
governments‟ regulations or supervisory oversight. However, in theory, the incentive to self-regulate is
very strong. Any reputational damage due to error of design, fraud, use of insider information, or a market
perception that PRAs are herded by one party would imply a loss of confidence and would eventually
lead to their demise. If PRAs produce regularly inaccurate prices, they will cease to exist because their
subscribers will shift to another service.52

50
Nevertheless, concerns still arise that such procedures will not stop companies from using the Platts window as a
way of executing a wash trade, or trading only to set the index on index-related deals done earlier in the day. Platts
cannot track every deal down to the contract level and ask for documentary bona fides.
51
It is highly unlikely however that a PRA requesting this information would always receive it, and certainly not in
a timely enough manner to have any impact on price assessments on a given day.
52
One anonymous interviewee noted that in theory this may be true in a competitive environment but not in the case
of oil PRAs where the market is characterised by almost a duopoly.

35
5. The Brent Market and Its Layers
The Brent market in the North Sea assumes a central stage in the current oil pricing system. The prices
generated in the Brent complex constitute the main price benchmarks on the basis of which 70 percent of
international trade in oil is directly or indirectly priced. In the early 1980s, the Brent market only
consisted of the „spot‟ market (known as Dated Brent) and the informal forward physical market. Since
that time, the Brent market has grown in complexity and is currently made up of a large number of layers
including a highly liquid futures and swaps markets in which a variety of financial instruments are
actively traded by a wide range of players. As noted by Horsnell (2000), the Brent market was not pre-
designed and grew more complex according to the needs of market participants.
A number of special features favoured the choice of Brent as a benchmark. The geographic location of the
North Sea which is close to the refining centres in Europe and the US gives it an advantage over other
basins. Brent is waterborne crude and is transferred by tankers to European refiners or, when arbitrage
allows, across the Atlantic Ocean to the US. The introduction of tax regulations on the UK North Sea in
1979 provided oil companies with the incentive to trade and re-trade their output in the spot market which
gave rise to an actively-traded spot market in Brent.53 Furthermore, in the mid 1980s, the volume of
production of the Brent system was quite large (around 885,000 b/d in 1986) which ensured enough
physical liquidity for trading. But similar bases of physical liquidity could also be found in other regions
of the world, especially in Gulf countries which constitute the largest physical base in the crude oil
markets. Thus, the volume of production, although important, is not the determining factor for a crude oil
to emerge as an international benchmark. An important determinant is the legal, tax, and regulatory
regime operating around any particular benchmark. Brent has the UK government overseeing it and a
robust legal regime. Horsnell and Mabro (1993) identify additional determinants, the most important of
which is ownership diversification. The commodity underlying the forward/futures contracts should be
available from a wide range of sellers. Monopoly of production increases the likelihood of squeezes and
manipulation, increasing in turn the risk exposure of buyers and traders who would be reluctant to enter
the market in the first place (Newbery, 1984). Most countries in OPEC are single sellers and hence OPEC
crudes did not and still do not satisfy this criterion of ownership diversification. Monopoly of production
also prevented the development of a complex market structure in other markets with a larger physical
base such as Mexico. This is in contrast to the Brent market which has always been characterised by a
large number of companies with entitlement to the production of Brent (see Figure 6). The widening of
the definition of the benchmark to include other crude streams over the years has reinforced this aspect
and resulted in an even higher degree of ownership diversification. Another important aspect is the degree
of concentration in the physical delivery infrastructure. Here the degree of concentration is much higher.
For instance, the Forties Pipeline System (FPS) which collects oil and gas liquids from over 50 fields
through a complex set of pipelines is 100% BP-owned.54

53
See Argus (2010), Argus Guide to Crude and Oil Products Markets, January.
54
BP Website: https://www.icmmed0ty.com/fps/content/brochure/brochure.asp?sectionid=1

36
Figure 6: Brent Production by Company (cargoes per year), 2007

4 2
1
1 31 1
23 4

38
53
3
2
2 35
2 5
10 1

AGIP (ENI) Amerada HESS BGGROUP BPPLC


CHALLENGER CHEVRONTEXACO CNR DANA
DYAS EXXONMOBIL ITOCHU LUNDIN
MARUBENI MITSUBISHI PALACE E&P SHELL
STATOIL ASA TFE

Source: Bossley, L. (2007), Brent: A User‟s Guide to the Future of the World Price Marker, London: CEAG, p.83.

The Physical Base of North Sea


Crude oil in the North Sea consists of a wide variety of grades which include Brent, Ninian, Forties,
Oseberg, Ekofisk, Flotta, and Statfjord just to mention few. In the early stages of the current oil pricing
system, Brent acted as a representative for North Sea crude oil and price reporting agencies relied on the
trading activity in this grade to identify the price of the benchmark. The Brent is a mixture of oil produced
from separate fields and collected through a main pipeline system to the terminal at Sullom Voe in the
Shetland Islands, UK. From the mid 1980s, the production of Brent started to decline, falling from
885,000 b/d in 1986 to 366,000 b/d in 1990 (see Table 4 below). Low physical production caused
distortions, manipulation, and squeezes leading the Brent price to disconnect from the rest of grades with
far-reaching effects.55 To avoid potential distortions and squeezes, the Brent system was comingled with
Ninian in 1990 leading to the creation of a new grade known as the Brent Blend while Ninian ceased to
trade as a separate crude stream. The co-mingling of the Brent and the Ninian systems alleviated the
problem of declining production level with the combined production reaching 856,000 b/d in 1992, as
shown in the table below. Thereafter, however, the production of Brent Blend started to decline, falling to
around 400 thousand b/d in 2001. In terms of cargoes, this represented around 20 per month, or less than
one cargo per day.
Table 4: Oil Production By Brent and Ninian System (Thousand Barrels/Day)

1986 1987 1988 1989 1990(a) 1990(b) 1990 1991 1992


Brent System 885 791 734 503 450 320 396 450 547
Ninian System 346 302 373 374 366 345 357 324 309
Total Blend 885 791 734 503 450 665 540 773 856
Notes:
(a) January 1 to July 31 1990 before comingling
(b) August 1 to December 31 1990 after co-mingling
Source: Horsnell and Mabro (2003)

55
See for Instance, Liz Bossley (2003), Battling Benchmark Distortions”, Petroleum Economist, April.

37
In July 2002, Platts broadened its definition of the benchmark Dated Brent to include Forties (UK North
Sea) and Oseberg (Norway) for assessment purposes and as deliverable grades in the Brent Forward
contract. Forties is a mixture of oil produced from separate fields and collected by pipeline to the terminal
in Hound Point in the UK. Oseberg is a mixture of oil produced from various Norwegian fields and
collected to the Sture terminal in Norway. The new benchmark was known as Brent-Forties-Oseberg
(BFO). The inclusion of these two grades increased the production volume of the benchmark. It also
resulted in the distribution of cargoes over a wider range of companies with none having a dominant
position. However, as seen from the graph below, the production of BFO started its decline, falling from
63 cargoes a month in August 2004 to around 48 cargoes in the first months of 2007. In early 2007, BFO
production amounted to less than 30 million barrels a month, distributed over more than 55 companies.
Figure 7: Falling output of BFO

Source: Joel Hanley, Assessing the Benchmarks, Platts Presentation, January 31, 2008.

In 2007, a new grade, Ekofisk, was added to the complex which led to the creation of the current
benchmark known as BFOE, though it is still commonly referred to as Brent or North Sea. Ekofisk is a
mixture of crude oil produced from different North Sea fields and is transported to the Teesside terminal
in the UK. The bulk of BFOE output is traded on the spot market or transferred within integrated oil
companies where only about one out of seven BFOE cargoes is sold on long-term basis.56 This feature
combined with the highly diversified ownership gave rise to an active trading activity around BFOE. The
inclusion of this new stream increased the physical base of the benchmark to around 45 million barrels a
month in early 2007 but since then it has been in gradual decline. Production of BFOE is expected to
decline to less than 1 million b/d by 2012. As noted by Platts (2010a:3), further changes to the
benchmarks can‟t be ruled out, especially „if production of the key grades is deemed too low or if their
qualities were to deviate significantly from the norm‟. In fact such a change might occur sooner rather
56
Argus (2010), Argus Guide to Crude and Oil Products Markers, January.

38
than later. A recent article warns that „unless the contract is enlarged, it faces the risk of serial squeezes
and distortions‟.57
Given that these various grades are not of similar quality as shown in Table 5 below, the widening of the
definition of the North Sea benchmarks has implications on the price assessment process. In particular,
the start-up of the Buzzard field in 2007 increased the viscosity and the sulfur content of Forties Blend
making Forties the least valuable among the various crudes in the BFOE benchmark. Since any of the
four varieties can be delivered against a BFOE contract, sellers often tend to deliver the cheapest grade
and hence it is Forties that sets the price for the BFOE benchmark.58 This problem becomes more acute
during periods when other fields in the Forties system are shut down for maintenance. As a result of
including the Buzzard stream, Platts had to introduce a quality „de-escalator‟ in July 2007 which applies
for deliveries above the base standard of 0.60% sulfur: the higher the sulfur content, the bigger the
discount that the seller should give. Currently, a de-escalator of 60 cents/barrel applies for every 0.10 per
cent of sulfur specified above the base standard. Prior to this „innovation‟, the market was not sure on
how to deal with the sulfur issue and in some periods in 2007 there were no trades in the Platts window.59
This episode almost brought the physical market to a standstill with traders complaining that Platts
changes to its pricing assessment process had paralysed the market.60

Table 5: API and Sulfur Content of BFOE Crudes

Forties Before Buzzard Brent Oseberg Ekofisk


Buzzard
API 44.1 32.6 38.1 37.7 37.5
Sulfur Content 0.19 1.44 0.42 0.23 0.23
wt.
Source: Bossley, L. (2007), Brent: A User‟s guide to the Future of the World Price Marker, London: CEAG, Table
5.

The Layers and Financial Instruments of the Brent Market


Around the Brent/BFOE physical benchmark, a number of layers and instruments have emerged, the most
important of which are: Brent Forwards, Contract for Differences (CFDs), Exchange for Physicals
(EFPs), and Brent futures, Brent options and swaps. Some of the instruments such as futures are traded on
regulated exchanges such as ICE while others such as swaps are traded bilaterally over-the-counter
(OTC). Nevertheless, these layers are highly inter-linked and are essential for the risk management and
the price discovery functions.

Data Issues
In the Brent complex, data about the different layers such as the volume of trading, the number of
concluded deals, the composition of participants and the degree of concentration are not publicly
available. Oil PRAs are under no legal obligation to report or publish such data although oil trading data
gathered by PRAs are made available to subscribers at a price. This section relies on data provided by
Argus. While this is one of the best sources for data on the Brent complex, the data suffers from some
limitations. There are no legal or regulatory obligations on participants in the Brent market to report their
deals and thus the coverage depends on the willingness of participants to provide information to the oil

57
Kemp, J. (2011), Falling Output Imperils Brent Benchmark, Reuters, 19 January 2011.
58
For instance on May 25 2010, Forties was assessed at $67.57-67.59, Oseberg at $68.49-68.52, Ekofisk at $68.29-
68.32, and Brent at $68.02-68.05 by Platts. The BFOE or North Sea Light was assessed at 67.57-67.59, the same as
the assessment of the value of Forties.
59
FT.com/Alphaville (2010), „Brent‟s Got Its Problems Too‟, September 2010.
60
Reuters (1997), Platts to modify new oil price system after turmoil, 19 June.

39
pricing reporting agencies. This has a number of important implications. First, since there is OTC trade
that goes unreported, the volume of market activity reported by Argus is likely to be a fraction of the total
volume of trade conducted in the various Brent layers. Nevertheless, it is representative of the market
activity and hence any proportions based on this „sample‟ such as the relative sizes of OTC markets and
the shares held by different companies are likely to represent fairly accurately the structure of the market.
Second, when analysing trends over a period of time, changes in statistics related to liquidity or to the
number of reported deals may reflect changes in coverage by the price reporting agency rather than
underlying changes in the statistic. Third, other problems arise when making comparisons across the
different Brent layers. For instance, in the futures markets, every deal is reported and the size of the
contract is 1000 barrels. In some layers such as Dated Brent and 21 Day BFOE, players can end up with a
ship full of crude which limits the attractiveness of these markets to a large number of participants.
Hence, one should be careful when comparing across markets as although these are all part of the Brent
complex, they differ in nature and function. Furthermore, the nature of trading can be different across
markets. For instance, in Dated Brent and 21 Day BFOE, trade in outright differentials or spreads is the
norm though 21 Day BFOE can also trade on a fixed price basis. In the futures and options, trade in
differentials also constitutes an important component of trade between months. This involves buying a
contract in one month (say a June contract) and selling a contract in another month (say a July contract).
In terms of reporting, each of the two legs of the transaction is reported as an outright deal. Thus, any
comparisons across markets should adjust for the volume of such trade in spreads.

The Forward Brent


The Forward Brent is one of the first layers to emerge in the Brent complex. The forward Brent is also
referred to as 21-day Brent, 21-day BFOE or simply as paper Brent. Forward Brent is a forward contract
that specifies the delivery month but not the particular date at which the cargo will be loaded. Forward
Brent price is often quoted for three months ahead. For instance, on 25th May, the Forward Brent is
reported for the months of June, July and August. These price quotations represent the value of a cargo of
physical delivery in the month specified by the contract.
In order to understand the nature of the Forward Brent market, it is important to look at the precursor of
the 21-day Brent, the 15-day Brent market. The incentive for oil companies to engage in tax spinning
through the forward market was the main factor responsible for the emergence of the forward 15-Day
Brent market (Mabro et al. 1986; Horsnell and Mabro, 1993; Bacon, 1986). The valuation of oil for UK
fiscal purposes was based on market prices. In an arm‟s-length transaction, market prices were obtained
from the realised prices on the deal.61 If oil was merely transferred within a vertically integrated system,
then the fiscal authorities would assign an assessed price to the transaction based on the prices of
„contemporary and comparable‟ arm‟s-length deals. Until 1984, these followed the official British
National Oil Corporation (BNOC) price. Because of the differential rates of taxation between upstream
and downstream with the tax rate being lower in the latter, the impact of the fiscal regime was not neutral
and affected a vertically integrated oil company‟s decision to sell or retain crude oil.62 When the spot
price was lower than the official BNOC price, integrated oil companies had the incentive to sell their own
crude arm‟s-length and buy the crude needed for their own refineries from the market. When the spot
price was higher than the assessed price, oil companies had the incentive to keep the oil for use in their
own refineries. In doing so, the oil companies would achieve higher after-tax profits. After the abolition
of BNOC, the assessment process of transactions within the firm became more complex. The market
value of non-arm‟s-length transactions was based on the average price of contracts (spot and forward)

61
The fiscal authorities specified a number of conditions before a contract could qualify as arm‟s length including
the condition that the deal is not made back to back.
62
Tax spinning refers to this situation in which for fiscal reasons oil companies would resort to buying and selling
crude oil in the market though it would have been more convenient and cheaper to internalize the transaction
(Horsnell and Mabro, 2003:63).

40
preceding the deal. This encouraged oil companies whether vertically integrated or not to engage in tax
spinning through the forward market.63
Although tax spinning continued to provide a motive for trading in these markets, its importance has
declined as tighter regulations, introduced later in 1987, made it more difficult and much less predictable.
But by then, the 15-day forward market was well established and expanding fast as various market
participants including oil companies, traders, and refiners began to trade actively in this market for risk
management and speculative purposes.
The 15-day Brent market largely evolved in response to the peculiar nature of the delivery schedule of
Brent. Companies producing crude oil in the Brent system nominated their preferred date for loading at
the relevant month by the 5th of the preceding month. The loading programme was then organised and
finalised by the 15th of the preceding month. Until the schedule was completed, producers did not know
the exact date when their crude oil would be available for delivery. But these producers may have already
entered into forward contracts in which they agreed to sell their cargoes for forward delivery for a
specified price. Under the 15-day contract, sellers were required to give the buyer of the forward contract
at least 15 days notice of the first date of a three-day loading window. Under the 21-day BFOE contract,
the seller is required to provide the purchaser at least 21 days notice as to when the cargo will be loaded.
For instance, assume that on the 10th of May, the producer enters into a 21-day BFOE contract for
delivery in July. On that day the seller does not know when its crude oil will be available for delivery. In
the month prior to delivery, i.e. in June, the loading schedule is published. The seller is given a 3-day
window between the 22nd and 24th of July in which he can load the oil into tankers. The seller has to
nominate the buyer at the latest by the 1st of July which is the period required to give the buyer notice to
take delivery. Depending on the market conditions at the time of nomination, the original buyer may or
may not want actual possession of the cargo. In fact, it is likely that the original cargo purchaser has
already sold another 21-day contract (i.e. booked out his position)64, in which case he must give notice to
the new buyer to take the cargo at least 21 days in advance. In this way, the 21-day BFOE contract can
transfer hands between buyers and sellers through a daisy chain of notices until a purchaser is ready to
accept delivery or the 21-day period expires and/or the holder of the forward can no longer provide notice
for any more buyers.65 Once the notice period is expired, the oil to be loaded on a specific date is
classified and traded as Dated Brent. For instance, on the 5th of July, the cargo is traded as Dated Brent
where the delivery date is known (17-19 days ahead).
The 21-day BFOE can be either cash-settled by traders offsetting their position in the daisy chain or can
be physically settled. However, only a small percentage of forward contracts are physically settled. Figure
8 below shows the average daily traded volume on a monthly basis and the number of participants in the
21-day BFOE market. As seen from this graph, the number of players during one month is small between
four and 12 players. Furthermore, the traded volume is low not exceeding 600,000 b/d. Between
September 2007 and August 2008, liquidity in the forward market declined at a fast rate reaching the very
low level of less than 50,000 b/d in August 2008. However, liquidity recovered in 2009 and 2010 with
daily average liquidity in the first half of 2010 reaching more than 400,000 b/d. This is less than one
cargo a day compared to around 30 cargoes a day at the heyday of the 15-day Brent market during the late
1980s. Features such as the large size of the cargoes, clocking and the daisy chain games make trading in
forward Brent a risky proposition and the domain of few players. This has pushed the industry to find

63
For details on how tax spinning can be transacted through trading in the forward market, see (Horsnell and Mabro,
1993, Chapter 6 and Bacon, 1986).
64
Book out is used to describe the process whereby a daisy chain of forward transactions having been identified
(such as creating a circle in which A sells to B who sells to C who sells to A) is closed by financial settlements of
price differences rather than physical delivery.
65
In trading terms, the holder of the contract who is unable to require another purchaser to take delivery is said to
have been „five-o‟clocked‟.

41
alternative ways to manage their risk without trading in the forward market, which can explain the decline
in its trading activity. The futures market has provided such an alternative. Given the central role that the
forward market assumes in the Brent complex, ensuring that there is enough liquidity in the 21-day BFOE
is crucial to the price discovery process. This is especially the case as the settlement mechanism of the
ICE futures Brent contract is based on trading activity in the forward Brent market.
Figure 8: Trading Volume and Number of Participants in the 21-Day BFOE Market
14 600,000

12
500,000

10
400,000

8
300,000
6

200,000
4

100,000
2

0 0
Jul-07 Dec-07 May-08 Oct-08 Mar-09 Aug-09 Jan-10 Jun-10

Participants Liquidity (b/d)

Source: Argus
There are few participants in the 21-day BFOE. Unlike the futures market, the forward contract involves
trading in 600,000 barrels which is beyond the capability of many small players and hence the
composition is not as diverse as in the futures market. Table 6 below shows the various participants in the
Brent forward market and their total volume of trading during the period 2007 and 2010 (September). On
the sales side, the main players include oil companies with equity interest such as BP, Shell, Conoco
Phillips and Total and some of their trading arms such as Totals‟ TOTSA and physical traders such as
Vitol, Phibro and Mercuria. On the purchase side, these same companies also dominate the trading
activity. For instance, in 2010, Shell was the most important seller and the third important purchaser
while Totsa was the second important seller and the second important buyer. On the purchase side, the
four top players Vitol, Mercuria, Totsa, and Shell captured more than 70% of the observed volumes by
Argus. On the sales side, these companies captured more than 60% of the trading volumes in 2010. The
degree of concentration varies across months and in certain months few players capture the bulk of traded
volumes.

42
Table 6: Participants in the 21-Day BFOE Market and their Shares in Trading Volume

Sales (b/d) Purchases (b/d)


2007 2008 2009 2010 2007 2008 2009 2010
Arcadia 0 0 0 0 485 0 0 0
BP 23,786 3,005 13,699 29,545 25,243 273 10,959 12,662
Chevron 0 273 274 0 0 273 0 0
ConocoPhillips 18,447 11,749 12,329 32,143 6,311 5,464 12,329 29,545
Glencore 0 0 274 0 0 546 548 0
Hess 0 0 9,315 37,338 0 0 10,137 20,779
Hetco 0 0 822 7,143 0 0 1,096 974
Mercuria 12,136 12,842 64,658 79,545 13,107 24,863 54,247 89,286
Morgan
Stanley 0 0 274 28,896 0 0 3,014 19,805
Noble 0 0 548 6,494 0 0 822 5,844
Phibro 46,602 19,126 25,479 23,377 36,408 23,770 36,164 14,935
Sempra 15,534 18,306 13,151 8,766 18,447 19,672 13,699 7,792
Shell 34,951 62,022 125,205 91,883 46,117 32,787 73,151 75,000
StatoilHydro 0 273 0 0 0 0 0 0
Total 0 0 0 649 0 0 0 2,273
Totsa 31,068 16,667 53,425 62,987 61,650 28,962 108,767 83,442
Trafigura 0 0 0 16,234 0 0 0 10,714
unknown 0 273 0 0 0 273 0 0
Vitol 68,447 12,842 48,219 56,818 43,204 20,492 42,740 108,766
252,978 159,386 369,681 483,828 252,979 159,383 369,682 483,827

The Brent Futures Market


The Brent futures contract was initially launched on the International Petroleum Exchange (IPE), now
known as the InterContinental Exchange (ICE), in London in June 1988 after a number of failed attempts.
As in the case of other futures contracts, the ICE Brent Futures contract‟s terms and conditions are highly
standardised, which facilitate trading in these contracts. The futures contract specifies 1,000 barrels of
Brent crude oil for delivery in a specified time in the future. The contract expires at the end of the
settlement period on the business day immediately preceding the 15th day of the contract month, if such
15th day is a business day. For instance, a December contract will expire on the 15th of November if it is a
business day. The ICE Brent Crude futures contract is cash settled with an option of delivery through
Exchange for Physicals (EFP). The trading takes place through an electronic exchange which matches
bids and offers between anonymous parties.
The ICE Brent crude oil futures market has grown dramatically in the last two decades; in 2010, the daily
average volume traded exceeded 400,000 contracts or 400 million barrels, more than five times the
volume of global oil production (see Figure 9 below). Initially, the features of the Brent futures contract
attracted small players but after few years of its development, it started attracting large physical players
who enter the market to manage their risk, hedge their positions as well as bet on oil price movements.
The futures market has also attracted a wide range of financial players including swap dealers, pension
funds, hedge funds, index investors, and technical traders.

43
Figure 9: Average Daily Volume and Open Interest of ICE Brent Futures Contract

Source: ICE

An interesting feature of the Brent futures contract is that at expiry it cash settles against the ICE Brent
Futures Index, also known as the Brent Index which is calculated on the basis of transactions in the
forward Brent market. In other words, unlike other futures contracts whose price converges to spot price
at expiry, the Brent futures contract converges to the price of forward Brent. Specifically, the Brent index
is calculated on the basis of weighted average of first-month and second-month cargo trades in the 21-day
BFOE plus or minus average of the spread trades between first and second months as reported by oil price
reporting agencies. At expiry, the Brent futures contract relies on the forward market for cash settlement.
Thus, the effectiveness of the futures market in the role of price discovery relies on the liquidity of the
forward market which as discussed previously is quite variable and concentrated in the hand of few
players. This feature of the Brent futures contract is the result of historical events where the development
of the forward market preceded that of the futures market plus the fact that no producer in the North Sea
would back a physically delivered contract. This meant that for any Brent futures contract to succeed, it
has to be strongly linked to the forward market.

The Exchange for Physicals


Although the Brent futures contract is not physically settled, the Exchange for Physicals (EFPs) market
allows participants to swap a futures position (a financial position) with a physical one. Specifically, by
executing an EFP, a party can convert a futures position into Brent Forward or a 21-day BFOE cargo.66
EFPs are carried outside the exchange and at a price agreed between the parties. The way the EFP works
is straightforward. Party A with a futures position sells the futures contract and buys the physical
commodity. His counterparty B buys the futures position from A and sells the physical commodity to A.
Through this process, A is able to gain physical exposure to the underlying commodity while B has
swapped his physical exposure for a financial one. Such trades can be transacted at any prices agreed
between A and B and are often different from the price prevailing in the futures market. EFPs are often
quoted as differentials to the Brent futures price but usually do not exceed it by more than a few cents.

66
It is important to note that Brent EFPs are not qualitatively equivalent to physically delivered contracts such as
WTI. EFP is optional while for WTI contract, the trader has no choice but to close the position or make or take
delivery.

44
Parties need to notify the Exchange about their agreement so it can close A‟s position and open B‟s
position. Thus, the importance of EFP is that it provides a link between the futures market and the
physical dimension of the Brent market. As discussed below, in periods of thin trading activity in the
forward Brent market, the EFP provides the necessary link to identify the price of forward Brent.

The Dated Brent/BFOE


Dated Brent/BFOE, also known as Dated North Sea Light (Platts) or Argus North Sea Dated refers to the
sale of cargo with a specific loading slot. It is often referred to as the spot market of Brent.67 A spot
transaction is often thought of as a transaction in which oil is bought or sold at a price negotiated at the
time of agreement and for immediate delivery. However, Dated BFOE contracts contain an important
element of forwardness as traders rarely deal with cargoes bought and sold for immediate delivery.
Instead, cargoes are sold and bought for delivery for at least 10 days ahead. To reflect this fact, the price
of Dated BFOE is quoted for delivery 10 to 21 days ahead. For instance, on 25th May, the price of Dated
BFOE reflects the price of delivery for the period between the 4 th of June and the 15th of June (11 days).
On 26th May, the price of Dated BFOE rolls forward one day to cover the period between the 5th and 16th
of June (11 days), and so on. This element of forwardness in Dated BFOE also implies that there is a price
risk between the time when a Dated BFOE cargo is bought and the time when it is delivered. Formula
pricing can mitigate part of this risk by pricing the cargo of Dated BFOE on the time of delivery or by
using the average of prices around the loading date, such as three days before and after the loading date.
One interesting feature of the Dated BFOE market is that very few deals are done on an outright basis.
Instead, since 1988, actual deals for physical cargoes of BFOE, including Brent, are priced as a
differential to forward Brent or Dated Brent/ North Sea Dated. As seen from Figure 10 below, by 1991,
deals based on outright prices became negligible. Thus, while the forward Brent sets the price level, the
Dated BFOE market sets the differential to the forward market. More recently, forward Brent itself is
been priced as a differential to the Futures Brent.
Figure 10: Pricing basis of Dated Brent Deals (1986-1991); Percentage of Total Deals

90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991

Outright Price Differential Price to Forward Brent


Differential Price to Dated Quotations Differential Price to other North Sea
Differential Price to WTI Differential Price to Other

Source: Horsnell and Mabro (1993)

The Contract for Differences (CFDs)


The Contracts for Differences (CFDs) have become an integral part of the Brent market and as discussed
in detail in Box 1 provide the link between the forward Brent market and Dated BFOE. CFDs are swaps
contracts which allow the buyer and seller to gain exposure to the price differential between Dated BFOE

67
It is important to note however that physical Brent or Brent/Ninian Blend trades at a differential to the Dated
Brent or North Sea Dated Price.

45
and Forward Brent. These CFDs can be traded in Platts window or negotiated bilaterally outside the
window or the exchanges. The high volatility in the above differential increased the risk exposure for
physical players, pushing them to hedge using CFDs. This in turn created an important niche for market
makers. Figure 11 below reports the daily volumes of traded CFDs which vary from as low as 250,000
b/d in March 2008 to as high as 1.4 million b/d in April 2010. However, these figures seem to understate
the actual volume of CFD trade with some market participants indicating that the volume of traded CFDs
is much higher.

Figure 11: Reported Trade on North Sea CFDs (b/d)

1,600,000

1,400,000

1,200,000

1,000,000

800,000

600,000

400,000

200,000

Source: Argus

The players in this market are quite diverse and include a large number of companies as seen in the table
below. On the sales side, the dominant players are equity producers such as BP, Chevron, Shell, Statoil;
banks such as Morgan Stanley and physical traders such as Vitol, Mercuria and Phibro. On the buying
side, these companies are also dominant. There are many companies that occasionally enter the market
and trade small volumes mainly for hedging purposes.

Table 7: Participants in the CFD Market and their Trading Volumes

Sales (b/d) Purchases (b/d)


2007 2008 2009 2010 2007 2008 2009 2010
Addax 0 0 411 0 0 0 740 812
Arcadia 23,301 4,918 4,658 14,448 6,553 10,109 6,575 17,208
Astra 0 0 0 0 2,427 1,298 0 0
BNP Paribas 0 0 548 5,519 0 0 2,192 4,221
BP 26,214 55,601 74,085 76,948 43,083 37,432 24,397 75,010
Cargill 485 1,913 411 0 485 4,918 274 1,136
Chevron 17,233 26,093 70,699 84,659 43,811 47,541 53,863 73,195
Chinaoil 0 0 0 0 0 0 1,233 0

46
ConocoPhillips 485 10,410 23,041 33,766 728 24,863 28,630 60,065
Glencore 1,456 1,940 14,219 24,968 485 4,372 9,863 26,299
Gunvor 0 7,240 13,151 3,571 1,942 5,464 3,836 1,299
Hess 971 273 2,192 22,240 0 0 2,192 17,532
Hetco 0 0 0 3,571 0 0 1,096 974
IPC 0 273 2,055 325 0 1,481 3,068 1,786
Iplom 0 0 548 0 0 1,093 548 1,136
Itochu 0 546 7,671 7,253 0 6,126 11,041 10,844
JP Morgan 9,223 11,380 9,153 7,792 1,456 29,358 54,973 14,935
Koch 33,010 36,284 23,556 3,247 11,165 37,205 34,849 32,305
Lukoil 971 13,798 28,559 24,513 485 7,049 20,411 21,753
Maesfield 0 0 1,644 1,136 0 0 0 1,623
Marathon Oil 0 0 0 0 11,408 9,699 548 6,494
Masefield 0 273 1,233 3,247 0 3,825 685 0
Mercuria 34,345 46,809 59,726 79,471 31,311 68,415 99,841 117,156
Merrill Lynch 1,942 4,781 1,918 1,299 7,646 4,645 0 0
Mitsubishi 0 0 0 0 0 0 3,014 0
Mitsui 0 273 0 0 1,456 546 0 0
Morgan Stanley 20,388 24,317 57,882 100,487 20,146 17,760 51,238 88,377
Murphy 0 0 0 0 0 410 0 0
Natixis 0 0 42,033 19,968 0 0 36,849 27,110
Neste 971 4,372 2,740 0 0 3,005 822 1,623
Nexen 1,942 4,577 4,003 6,951 2,427 2,691 5,189 11,685
Noble 0 0 822 14,286 0 0 548 8,442
OMV 1,485 0 14,562 28,545 0 5,787 36,995 48,880
ORL 0 1,093 0 0 0 2,186 0 0
Petraco 0 820 1,644 974 0 1,735 2,192 0
Petrodiamond 0 0 0 1,948 0 0 822 0
Petroplus 5,583 3,825 1,918 0 1,942 0 1,644 0
Phibro 20,146 48,656 68,923 82,867 36,772 52,117 34,400 50,487
Pioneer 0 0 0 0 0 0 137 0
Plains 0 2,732 0 0 0 0 2,466 1,299
Preem 0 0 685 0 0 0 3,562 0
Sempra 971 7,978 9,644 2,273 4,854 15,929 15,616 2,922
Shell 47,694 131,929 132,079 149,221 52,699 39,727 83,995 129,545
Sinochem 0 0 0 1,136 0 273 603 974
Sinopec 0 0 1,932 2,597 0 0 2,800 1,867
Socar 0 0 0 25,000 0 0 0 9,091
Sonatrach 0 0 274 974 0 0 7,260 8,279
Standard Bank 0 0 932 5,575 0 0 548 5,195
Statoil 6,796 2,186 8,630 108,224 4,369 273 8,630 118,130
StatoilHydro 14,563 77,945 59,233 0 6,796 54,781 61,863 325
Totsa 19,782 23,087 45,260 25,974 14,078 46,325 47,397 60,575
Trafigura 971 16,940 29,315 27,955 3,641 13,798 28,877 32,649
Unipec 8,738 7,377 4,521 8,955 0 12,432 29,170 11,578
Valero 1,456 546 1,096 0 9,951 14,208 19,726 54,545
Veba 0 0 0 0 0 1,093 0 0
Vitol 36,044 58,579 132,060 245,692 15,049 49,795 112,447 98,214
339173 641772 961675 1259585 339172 641772 961674 1259585
Source: Argus

47
OTC Derivatives
In addition to the above layers, a whole set of financial instruments that link to the Brent complex are
currently traded over the counter (OTC). These OTC contracts are customised and until recently have
been negotiated bilaterally between parties either face-to-face or through brokers. However, as the use of
OTC became more widespread, OTC contracts became more standardised and part of the OTC activity
has shifted to electronic OTC exchanges. Furthermore, after being matched, counterparties can use the
clearing facilities of exchanges such as ICE and the CME Group. The landscape has become less benign
in a number of ways for bilateral uncleared OTC, and so there has been a shift toward clearing OTC
contracts except for those with either impeccable credit/ unimpeachable credit lines, or those who simply
cannot afford the cash flow/cash flow volatility of a cleared environment (such as airlines). IOSCO
(2010) reports that market participants conduct 55% of their trades in financial oil (crude oil and refined
products) using exchange-traded instruments and hence are subject to clearing. The remaining part of the
business is conducted through OTC. A large part of this OTC trade is now being cleared where 19% of
survey participants‟ trades are being cleared. Only 27% of the total volume traded remains un-cleared.68
The growing similarity between more standardised OTC and exchange-traded instruments has raised the
issue of disparity in supervision and oversight between markets and is at the heart of current plans to
strengthen the regulation of commodity derivatives markets. Exchange clearing of OTC has aided their
transparency already, as they make available daily settlement figures to those clearing the instruments.
The large variety of OTC instruments and the limited information on these instruments precludes an
extensive analysis of OTC markets. ICE lists more than 30 financial contracts (for crude oil alone) that
are cleared on their exchange. These contracts are used primarily for hedging, but also for speculative
purposes and are an integral part of the Brent complex. Using these instruments one can hedge between
the various layers such as between Dated Brent and futures Brent or between further away markets such
as Dubai and futures Brent or between Dated Brent and WTI. One important and active market discussed
above is CFDs. Another active swaps market is the Brent Dated-to-Frontline (DFL) market which trades
the difference between Platts‟ Dated Brent assessments and the ICE first month futures contract. Another
related but less liquid market has emerged which trades the difference between Dated Brent and the daily
trade-weighted Brent average reported by the ICE. Through these customised contracts, traders can
establish a series of inter-linkages not only between the different layers of the Brent market, but also
between Brent and the different benchmarks and hence are likely to influence the price formation and
price discovery processes.

BOX 1: CFD Explained with an Example

To explain the rationale behind CFDs and how it works, it would be useful to provide a simple example,
but based on real data. A refiner bought a cargo of BFOE on 19th March 19 for loading on 21st-23rd of
April. The refiner has accepted to buy the cargo at the Dated Brent price averaged over five days around
the loading date (i.e. 19th-23rd April). The refiner observes that the current value of Dated Brent is $77.88.
He is concerned that by the time of loading the price of Dated Brent could increase: he would like to
hedge his risk. In principle, he could use the April Forward contract to hedge the risk. However, this
hedge is far from perfect because there is the risk that the price of the April Forward may not follow the
movements of Dated Brent at the time of loading. This risk, referred to as the basis risk, constitutes the
main rationale for CFDs.
To hedge the basis risk, the refiner could buy (a) a second-month Forward contract (i.e. a May contract in
our example) and (b) CFDs for the week of 19th-23rd April. The price for the Forward May contract on the

68
These figures however should be treated with caution and some market participants have indicated very different
numbers. The fact remains that the size of the OTC market is not known and less so the percentage of OTC that goes
to clearance.

48
19th of March stood at $79.53 while the CFD for the week 19th-23rd April was at -$0.57. By buying the
second-month forward contract and CFDs, the refiner is able to lock the price of his cargo at $79.53.
So how does the hedge work? Somewhere between 19th-23rd April (say 22nd of April) i.e. when the cargo
is being loaded, the refiner sells the Forward May contract. On the 22nd of April, the BFOE May contract
settled at a price of $84.78. Thus, the refiner has made a profit on his forward position of $5.25: he bought
the forward contract at $79.53 and sold it at $84.78. What about the gain and losses on the CFD position?
The easiest way to think of a CFD is that it is a swap in which the refinery agrees to receive the price of
Dated Brent and agrees to pay the Forward price. Assuming that the refinery unwinds his CFD over the
week, we can calculate the net gain or loss on the CDF as illustrated in the Table below.
CFD Explained

Date Dated Brent BFOE MAY Loss/Gain CFD Loss/Gain CFD


19/04/2010 83.19 83.53 0.2×(83.19-83.53) -0.068
20/04/2010 84.74 84.86 0.2×(84.74-84.86) -0.024
21/04/2010 84.47 84.62 0.2×(84.47-84.62) -0.03
22/04/2010 84.64 84.78 0.2×(84.64-84.78) -0.028
23/04/2010 86.49 86.43 0.2×(86.49-86.43) 0.012
Total
Loss/Gain -0.138

The refinery‟s final position as of 23rd of April 2010 is shown in the table below. The high price paid for
the cargo in April has been compensated for by the gain in forward position. In this example, the refiner
has lost on his CFD position.69

Example of CFD (continued)

Refinery’s Final Position


(23rd of April 2010)
Price Paid for the Cargo
(Average Dated Brent over the period April 19-April 23) 84.706
Gain on Forward Position 5.25
Loss on CFD -0.138
79.594

Notice from the above example that the CFD allows us to derive in March the Forward price for Dated
Brent for the week 19th-23rd April. The Forward Dated Brent is simply the CFD plus the second month
forward i.e.

Forward Dated Brent = CFD + Second Month Forward Brent

Thus, the CFD is not the price differential between the current price of Dated Brent and the Forward
Brent Contract. It is rather the difference between the Dated Brent at some stated point in the future and

69
Notice that the refinery‟s position is not perfectly hedged. In the above example, the May Brent is sold in one day
and is not being closed over the five day period. The average of the BFOE May over 19th-23rd April period is
$84.884 in which case the refiner would have made a profit of $5.314 on his forward position. This will yield
$79.53, the price of the original hedge.

49
the Second Month Forward Brent.70 Since CFDs are reported for eight weeks ahead, it is possible to
derive the price of Forward Brent for eight weeks ahead. Platts refers to these forward prices as BFOE
swaps. These prices provide the vital link between the 21-Day BFOE and Dated Brent and are central for
the price discovery process in the Brent market.

The Process of Oil Price Identification in the Brent Market


Trades in the levels of the oil price rarely take place in the various layers that link the physical dimension
of Brent with the Brent futures. Instead, oil price reporting agencies such as Platts and Argus infer or
identify the oil price level for a wide variety of crudes by exploiting the linkages and the information
derived from the various layers of the Brent market. The process starts by identifying the price of
Forward Brent/BFOE. The price quotation will represent the value of a cargo for physical delivery within
the month specified by the contract. These price quotations are produced daily for three months ahead. Oil
price reporting agencies derive the forward Brent price from deals reported to them by brokers and traders
in the forward market (Argus) or based on deals conducted in the window (in the case of Platts).
However, movements on ICE futures Brent market can also be factored into the assessment.
Furthermore, spread values and EFPs could also be considered. Thus, oil reporting agencies often rely on
information from the futures market to derive the price of Forward Brent, especially at times when the
forward market is suffering from thin liquidity and is dominated by few deals.
The contract that links the futures Brent and the forward Brent is the Exchange for Physicals (EFPs). Oil
PRAs have increasingly relied on EFPs to derive the Forward Brent price. These are often priced as
differential to the Brent futures price. The Brent futures prices and the EFP for a particular month allow
the identification of the forward Brent price for that month. The formula can be as simple as adding the
value of EFP in a particular month (say July) as assessed by the oil reporting agency or generated by the
futures exchanges to the closing price of the July contract in the futures market i.e.
Forward Brent (July) = Futures Price (July) + EFP (July)
Having derived the price level for Forward Brent, the next step is to derive the price of Dated Brent. As
discussed above, the price of Dated Brent is important to the oil price discovery process as it is considered
as the spot market for Brent and should closely reflect the physical conditions in the oil market. As in the
case of Forward Brent however, the price of Dated Brent needs to be identified with the help of another
layer: the OTC market of Contract for Differences (CFDs). The CFD allows us to derive the Forward
Dated Brent using the following formula
Forward Dated Brent = CFD plus Second Month Forward
Given that CFDs are reported for eight weeks ahead,71 the Forward Dated Brent can be derived for 8
weeks into future which give us the „Forward Date Brent Curve‟. For each of the weeks, the price of
Dated Brent/BFOE swaps is reported.
Based on the derived Forward Dated Brent Curve, it is possible to calculate the average of the Forward
Dated Brent from day 10 to day 21. These days are the ones assessed for physical delivery. For instance,
if today is 21st May, the 10-21 day cargoes refer to 6th -17th June. Argus reports this as the „Anticipated
Dated Average for the 10-21 days Forward‟ while Platts uses the term „North Sea Dated Strip‟ or the
„Forward Dated Brent‟. These are reported as an outright price.
Since BFOE is comprised of four different crudes, these blends of individual crudes often trade as
differentials to the 10-21 average of the Forward Dated Brent or North Sea Dated Strip. Based on an

70
An alternative way to understand the equation above is to go through the above example. By buying a Forward
contract and CFDs, the trader is able to lock today the price for Dated Brent for delivery at a certain time in the
future.
71
In essence CFDs can be traded for any week that is needed to trade, but are only reported for 8-weeks ahead.

50
assessment of these differentials through MOC process or observed deals, it is possible to calculate the
price of Dated Brent/BFOE or Dated North Sea Light (Platts) or Argus North Sea Dated (Argus) for the
day.72 Specifically, the price of Dated Brent will settle on the most competitive crude among the BFOE
combination which is usually Forties.73
The above discussion implies that during the last three decades the Brent market has evolved into a
complex structure consisting of set of interlinked markets which lie at the heart of the international oil
pricing system. The Brent market is multi-layered with the various layers being strongly interconnected
by the process of arbitrage. Thus when referring to Brent, it is important to specify what Brent is being
referred to: Dated Brent, 21-Day Brent, Brent futures, Brent CFDs or even to Brent altogether as the
continuous decline in the physical liquidity meant the Brent Blend has become less important in the North
Sea physical complex. These layers and links are central for the price discovery process as identifying the
oil price relies heavily on information derived from the financial layers. The implications of these
linkages on the oil price formation process are discussed in details in Section 8.

72
Alternatively, one can take a simple average of the four crudes which would result in Platts‟ North Sea Basket.
73
As an example, on May 25, 2010, North Sea Dated Strip was priced at 68.13-68.14. This value was derived from
the Dated Brent Swap based on the average of 10- 21 window. Each of the four crudes is priced as a differential to
the forward Dated Brent. On May 25, 2010, Brent was priced at -0.11/-0.09; Forties at -0.56/-0.55, Oseberg at
0.36/0.38 and Ekofisk at 0.16/0.18. These differentials are obtained from concluded deals and failing that on bids
and offers. Since Forties is the most competitive crude, the Dated Brent/BFOE is obtained by applying the Forties
differential. Specifically Dated Brent/BFOE=North Sea Dated Strip (68.13-68.14) + Differential (-0.56/-0.55) =
67.57-67.59.

51
6. The US Benchmarks
West Texas Intermediate (WTI) is the main benchmark used for pricing oil imports into the US, the
world‟s largest oil consumer. More crude oil is priced-off the Brent complex, but the Light Sweet Crude
Oil Futures Contract, which is based on WTI,74 is one of the most actively traded commodity futures
contract. While WTI is the most widely known US crude stream, other crude streams exist alongside
WTI. One such is the Light Louisiana Sweet (LLS) crude which has become the local benchmark for
sweet crude in the US Gulf Coast. Other important streams include the US-Gulf Coast Sour and Medium
crudes such as Mars and Poseidon (produced offshore Louisiana) and Southern Green Canyon (produced
offshore Texas). On the basis of transactions in these three crude streams, Argus derives ASCI. Platts
publishes a similar index known as America‟s Crude Marker which incorporates the value of the four sour
grades: Mars, Poseidon, SGC and Thunder Horse (produced offshore Louisiana).

The Physical Base for US Benchmarks


The US constitutes the largest oil market in the world. In 2009, US consumption accounted for almost a
quarter of global consumption. The US is also an important producer, its production reaching 5.3 million
b/d or about 5% of the global production in 2009. The US is also an important refining centre with an
operable refining capacity exceeding 17 million b/d in 2009.
Central to understanding the physical base of US benchmarks is the „Petroleum Allocation for Defense
Districts‟ (PADD) regional definitions. The US is divided into five regions or PADDs as seen from the
map below. The most important district in terms of production is PADD III where in 2009 it produced
more than 3 million b/d out of total US‟s production of 5.3 million b/d (see Table 8 below). PADD III is
also the most important refining centre in the US, with refining operable capacity of around 8.5 million
b/d accounting for almost half of operable refining capacity in the US (see Table 9).
Figure 12: US PADDS

Source: EIA

74
The Light Sweet Crude Oil Futures contract is also referred to as the WTI futures contract.

52
Table 8: US Oil Production by District

2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009


U.S. 5,419 5,178 5,102 5,064 4,950 5,361
PADD 1
(East Coast) 19 23 22 21 21 18
PADD 2
(Midwest) 435 443 458 470 538 591
Kansas 93 93 98 100 108 108
North Dakota 85 98 109 123 172 218
Oklahoma 171 170 172 167 175 184
PADD 3
Gulf Coast) 3,016 2,804 2,838 2,828 2,699 3,121
Louisiana 228 207 202 210 199 189
Texas 1,073 1,062 1,088 1,087 1,087 1,106
Federal
Offshore
(PADD 3) 1,453 1,282 1,299 1,277 1,152 1,559
PADD 4
(Rocky
Mountain) 309 340 357 361 357 357
Wyoming 141 141 145 148 145 141
PADD 5
(West Coast) 1,640 1,569 1,426 1,385 1,336 1,274
Alaska 908 864 741 722 683 645
North Slope 886 845 724 707 670 638
California 656 631 612 594 586 567
Source: EIA Website

Table 9: Operable Refining Capacity by District

2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009


U.S. 16,974 17,196 17,385 17,450 17,607 17,678
PADD 1 1,736 1,717 1,713 1,720 1,722 1,723
PADD 2 3,526 3,569 3,583 3,595 3,670 3,672
PADD 3 7,967 8,159 8,318 8,349 8,416 8,440
PADD 4 582 589 596 598 605 622
PADD 5 3,164 3,162 3,175 3,187 3,195 3,222
Source: EIA Website

While PADD III constitutes the major production and refining centre in the US, PADD II assumes special
importance as it is the main centre for crude oil storage and the delivery point at the expiration of the

53
Light Sweet Crude Oil Futures contract. Cushing, Oklahoma located in PADD II is a gathering hub with
large storage facilities: an estimated operable crude storage capacity of 45.9 million barrels and nameplate
storage capacity of 55 million barrels.75 PADD II itself can be divided into two sub regions: the
Midcontinent and the Midwest (Purvin and Gertz, 2010). Cushing is located in the Midcontinent. It
collects crude oil from Texas, surrounding Oklahoma and other imported crude. It links to major
refineries centres both in the Midcontinent, the Midwest (PADD II) and PADD III through a complex set
of pipelines.76 Historically, the refineries in the Midcontinent relied on domestic crude for their runs.
However, with the decline in domestic production, refineries in the Midcontinent increased their reliance
on foreign imports and Canadian crude delivered into Cushing and the broader region. A similar picture
also emerged for the Midwest where historically it has relied heavily on domestic production. However,
given the decline in production and its proximity to Canada, Canadian crude started to rise in importance
displacing domestic production and imports from outside Canada, a trend which is likely to continue. As
seen in Table 10 below, in 2009 Canadian imports accounted for 90% of total oil imports into PADD II.
In contrast, refineries in PADD III have access to a wide variety of crude oil with offshore imports from
OPEC constituting the bulk of total imports.

Table 10: Total Imports by District from OPEC and Canada (Million b/d)

2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009


PADD1 (Total) 1,549 1,605 1,497 1,495 1,421 1,244
OPEC 764 893 844 936 807 587
Canada 197 215 210 263 260 215
PADD 2 (Total) 1,584 1,516 1,514 1,497 1,517 1,407
OPEC 370 323 300 345 297 154
Canada 1,054 1,039 1,150 1,125 1,176 1,222
PADD 3 (Total) 5,768 5,676 5,656 5,611 5,375 5,090
OPEC 3,448 3,131 3,147 3,533 3,521 3,013
Canada 18 20 59 96 106 126
PADD 4 (Total) 260 271 278 278 264 232
Canada 260 271 278 278 264 232
PADD 5 (Total) 926 1,057 1,173 1,149 1,206 1,040
OPEC 460 469 493 574 790 601
Canada 87 88 105 126 151 148

Source: EIA

Although a wide variety of crude oils is produced in the US, WTI assumes special importance in the
global oil and financial markets since WTI underlies the Light Sweet Crude Oil futures contract, one of
the largest traded commodity futures contract. It should be noted however though that trade around
Cushing, and a forward market around that trade, existed prior to the establishment of the futures market.

75
Storage operators keep 41pc of tank space for their own use and lease 59pc to third parties. Plains and Magellan
plan to add a combined 8.25mn bl of new storage at Cushing next year. See Argus Global Markets (2010), EIA
Reveals Cushing Tank, 6 December
76
For details see Purvin and Gertz, 2010.

54
That forward market existed in parallel to the futures market through the late 80s and early 90s. However,
unlike the Brent market, as futures volumes grew, it eventually eliminated the need for the forward
market. This forward market was knows as the „WTI Cash Market‟. Its last vestige exists now only in the
3 days between futures expiry and pipeline scheduling on the 25th of each month, discussed in details
below.
WTI is a blend of crude oil produced in the fields of Texas, New Mexico, Oklahoma and Kansas. It is a
pipeline crude and deliveries are made at the end of the pipeline system in Cushing, Oklahoma. As in the
case of Brent, the WTI market is also characterised by a large number of independent producers who sell
their crude oil to large number of gatherers. However, unlike Brent which is waterborne crude, WTI is
pipeline crude and thus is subject to problems of logistical and storage bottlenecks. Brent is exportable
which makes it more flexible and more responsive to trading conditions in the Western Hemisphere.
Furthermore, as discussed later in this section, WTI can show serious dislocations from other markets in
some occasions, reducing its attractiveness as a global benchmark or even as a US benchmark.

The Layers and Financial Instruments of WTI


Very few layers emerged around the WTI, the most important of which are the futures and option contract
and OTC derivatives. The Light Sweet Crude Oil Futures contract has been trading on the New York
Mercantile Exchange (now part of the CME Group) since 1983. Figure 13 below shows the monthly
averages of volumes traded of the Light Sweet Crude Oil Futures Contract for the last 15 years. Between
1995 and 2010 (January-September), the monthly volumes of traded contracts grew at an average annual
rate of 15%. As seen from the graph below, the increase in traded volume between 2006 and 2010 has
been phenomenal with the average annual growth rate during the period 2007 and 2010 reaching 27%. In
2010, the monthly average volume exceeded 14 million contracts or 14 billion barrels. On a daily basis
this amounts to more than 475 million barrels of oil, around 6 times the size of the daily global oil
production. Most of the trading takes place through the electronic platform (known as GLOBEX) which
provides ease of access from virtually anywhere in the world almost 24 hours a day. A wide range of
players are attracted to the futures market including commercial enterprises such as producers, marketers,
traders as well as speculators and variety of financial investors such as institutional and index investors.

Figure 13: Monthly averages of volumes traded of the Light Sweet Crude Oil Futures Contract

16000000

14000000

12000000

10000000

8000000

6000000

4000000

2000000

0
1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

Source: CME Group

55
Unlike the Brent futures contract (where delivery is elective via the EFP mechanism), the Light Sweet
Crude Oil Futures contract is fully physically delivered for every contract left open at expiry by default.
It specifies 1,000 barrels of WTI to be delivered at Cushing, Oklahoma. The contract also allows the
delivery of domestic types of crude (Low Sweet Mix, New Mexican Sweet, North Texas Sweet,
Oklahoma Sweet, and South Texas Sweet) and foreign types of crude (Brent Blend, Nigerian Bonny
Light and Qua Iboe Norwegian Oseberg Blend and Colombian Cusiana) against the futures contract. It is
important to note though that only a small percentage of the volume traded is physically settled with most
of the physical settlement occurring through the EFP mechanism. EFP provides a more flexible way to
arrange physical delivery as it allows traders to agree on the location, grade type, and the trading partner.
Crude oil futures contracts are traded for up to nine years forward. However, liquidity tends to decline
sharply for far away contracts (see Figure 14). For instance, on October 19, 2010 the bulk of the trading
activity concentrated on the December 2010 contract. There is some liquidity up to one year ahead, but as
we move towards the back end of the futures curve, liquidity tends to decline sharply. For instance, on
October 19, 2010, the traded volume of December 2017 and December 2018 contracts stood at 33 and 4
contracts respectively.
Figure 14:Liquidity at Different Segments of the Futures Curve (October 19, 2010)

500000
460127
450000

400000

350000

300000

250000

200000

150000

100000

50000 20991
4
0
Feb-11

Feb-12

Feb-13

Feb-14

Feb-15

Feb-16

Feb-17

Feb-18
May-11

May-12

May-13

May-14

May-15

May-16

May-17

May-18
Nov-10

Aug-11
Nov-11

Aug-12
Nov-12

Aug-13
Nov-13

Aug-14
Nov-14

Aug-15
Nov-15

Aug-16
Nov-16

Aug-17
Nov-17

Aug-18
Source: CME Group Website Nov-18

In addition to the futures and option contracts, a group of OTC financial instruments link to the WTI
complex, allowing participants to use more customised instruments than those available in the futures
market. As discussed in the case of Brent, a large fraction of OTC deals linked to WTI are using the
clearing facilities of the CME Group or ICE. The CME group lists more than 90 OTC financial contracts
for crude oil that are cleared on its exchange. Contracts such as the WTI-Brent (ICE) Calendar Swap
Futures and the WTI Calendar Swap Futures are more customised and are traded OTC but cleared
through the exchange.

The Price Discovery Process in the US Market


Unlike the Brent market, trading in the US pipeline market is of smaller volumes typically around 30,000
barrels compared to 600,000 barrels in the Brent market. Trade in small volumes has increased the
diversity and number of players who find it easier to obtain the necessary credit and storage facilities to
participate in the US market. Furthermore, the US market has maintained its liquidity despite the decline

56
in physical production and consolidation within the industry. In 2009, the combined spot-market traded
volume for twelve US domestic grades (for the month of April) stood at more than 1.8 mb/d77 (see Figure
15) which is much higher than other benchmarks including BFOE, Oman and Dubai.
Figure 15: Spot Market Traded Volumes (b/d) (April 2009 Trade Month)

450,000
400,000
350,000
300,000
250,000
200,000
150,000
100,000
50,000
0

Source: Argus (2009), „Argus US Crude Prices Explained‟, 24 September


Most of those crudes imported into the US and sold in the spot market are linked to WTI with some
exceptions such as Iraq, Kuwait and Saudi Arabia‟s sales to the US which are linked to ASCI; some
imports from West Africa and the North Sea which are linked to Dated Brent; and some Canadian East
Coast crudes which also link to Dated Brent. While producers still use the „assessed‟ prices of WTI in
their pricing formula, those assessments are often made as a differential to the settlement price in the
futures market. In other words, it is the futures market that sets the price level while „assessed‟ prices by
oil price reporting agencies set the differentials.

The physical delivery mechanisms complicate the price assessment process. In the futures market, trading
in the current delivery month expires on the third business day prior to the twenty-fifth calendar day of
the month preceding the delivery month. For instance, the March WTI futures contract expires on the 22nd
of February. Under the terms of the futures contract, delivery should be made at any pipeline or storage
facility in Cushing, Oklahoma and must take place no earlier than the first calendar day of the delivery
month (March) and no later than the last calendar day of the delivery month (March). At expiration, three
business days are needed for pipeline scheduling to organise the physical delivery in March. The three-
day window between the expiration of the monthly NYMEX WTI contract and the deadline for
completing the shipping arrangements (i.e. between the 22nd and 25th of February in our example) is
known as the roll period. During this period, the March WTI futures contract has already expired while
the spot (physical) month is still March.78 To derive the spot price of WTI March, PRAs assess the cash
roll which is the cost of rolling a contract forward into the next month without delivering on it. This
transaction can also simply be a purchase/sale of current month supply valued at an EFP to next month
futures. On the 26th of February, the physical front month becomes April which can then be linked to the
April WTI futures contract.

77
Argus (2009), “Argus US Crude Prices Explained”, 24 September.
78
In our example, the physical month extends in our example from 26th January through February 25th.

57
Historically, a large number of independent producers used to sell their crude oil to gatherers based on
WTI posting plus (P-Plus), which is the sum of the wellhead posted prices plus delivery costs into
Cushing. Nowadays the P-Plus market is widely used with its sister market, the differential to Nymex
Calendar Monthly Average (CMA) market. The P-Plus market used the Koch posting only as a basis up
until about 3 years ago when Koch stopped publishing that. Now companies tend to transact versus the
ConocoPhillips posting. The value that the differential to Postings (P-Plus) represents is the value for
delivery into Cushing in the current calendar month, assuming a certain cost to move the barrels to
Cushing. ConocoPhillips is known to use the Nymex settlement price, adjusted by the cost of moving the
barrel to Cushing, to set the price of the posting. This way the CMA and P-Plus markets are
mathematically connected and never too far out of synchronisation. The CMA market has been gaining
liquidity and is increasingly being used to value prompt crude oil in the US. It is the most active market in
terms of volumes of spot trade as seen from Figure 15. It is important to note that CMA is an extension to
the futures market. The CMA market does not trade price levels, but often trades at a differential to the
WTI futures contract settlement price. CMA and P-Plus have replaced the WTI Cash Window.79

Platts uses its window to assess WTI differential to CMA and other domestic crudes. While the CMA
market is quite liquid with large and diverse number of players, the percentage of transactions in the
Platts‟ window is only a small fraction of total transactions during the day.80 In June 2007 for instance,
total window trade amounted only to 4% of entire day trade observed by Argus. For all US crudes, total
window trade amounted to 2.4% of all spot trade.81 Some crude streams such as Mars show 19 days of no
trade in June 2007 and prices were assessed based on bids and offers. 82 Furthermore, despite the diversity
of players in the market, the degree of concentration in the window is quite high with a few players
dominating the trading activity.83 Given these concerns and the fact the CMA is priced as a differential to
the price in the futures market, it is surprising that producers do not more widely use futures prices
directly into their pricing formula.84 The WTI futures contract is a physical one and the price of the
futures contract converges to the spot price at the expiration of the contract. Hence, in the case of WTI,
the use of the futures price instead of assessed prices in the pricing formulae would make little difference.
The depth and the high liquidity of the futures market surrounding WTI and the diversity of its market
participants should incentivise buyers and sellers to use the futures price in their formula pricing. In
practice, there is some evidence that the front-month WTI futures price can exhibit high volatility around
the expiry date in some instances, which may partly explain the preference of some traders to stick to
assessed WTI prices. Furthermore, both the P-Plus and CMA are means of valuing WTI that is one month
prompter than the promptest futures contract.
WTI: The Broken Benchmark?
It has been recognised that the links between the WTI benchmark and oil prices in international markets
can be at times dictated by infrastructure logistics. In the past, the main logistical bottleneck has been how
to get enough oil into Cushing, Oklahoma. In many instances, this resulted in dislocations with WTI
rising to high levels compared to other international benchmarks such as Brent. The problem has recently
been reversed. While the ability to get oil into Cushing has increased mainly through higher Canadian
imports, the ability to shift this oil out of the region and to provide a relief valve for Cushing is much
more constrained as the storing in Cushing is inaccessible by tanker or barges with few out-flowing

79
The WTI Cash Window, which was/is a Platts mechanism for setting the price of WTI at 3:15 EST after the close
of the Nymex at 2:30 EST, has not traded for about 3 years. It is no longer an operative index because very few
companies use it for price reference.
80
Argus Global Markets (2007), “Liquidity and Diversity Prevail”, 24 September.
81
Argus, “State of the Market Report: US Domestic Crude”, Argus White Paper.
82
Ibid.
83
Ibid.
84
It is important to note though that many companies do use the NYMEX settlement as a pricing index.

58
pipelines, especially southbound towards the US Gulf major refining centre. In some occasions, this has
led to a larger than expected build-up of crude oil inventories in Cushing. For instance, in 2007, due to
logistical bottlenecks, there was a large build-up of inventories as a result of which the WTI price
disconnected not only from the rest of the world, but also from other US regions. In 2008, the build-up of
inventories in Cushing due to a deep contango and reduction in demand induced by the credit crunch
caused a major dislocation of WTI from the rest of the world.
Given the major role that WTI plays in the pricing of US domestic crude, imported oil into the US and
global financial markets, the price effects of such logistical bottlenecks are widespread. First, dislocations
result in wide time spreads as reflected in the large differential between nearby contracts and further away
contracts as seen in Figure 16 below. For instance, in January 2009, the spread between a twelve-week
ahead contract and prompt WTI reached close to $8 with implications on inventory accumulation.
Figure 16: Spread between WTI 12-weeks Ahead and prompt WTI ($/Barrel)

+10.00
+8.00
+6.00
+4.00
+2.00
...
-2.00
-4.00
-6.00
Jan 01
May 01
Sep 01
Jan 02

Sep 02
Jan 03

Sep 03
Jan 04

Sep 04
Jan 05

Sep 05
Jan 06

Sep 06
Jan 07

Sep 07
Jan 08

Sep 08
Jan 09

Sep 09
Jan 10
May 02

May 03

May 04

May 05

May 06

May 07

May 08

May 09
Source: Oil Market Intelligence

Dislocations also have the effect of decoupling the price of WTI from that of Brent, as reflected in the
large price differential between the two international benchmarks (see Figure 17). For instance, in
February 2009, the differential exceeded the $8/barrel mark. Similar episodes occurred in May and June
of 2007. Such behaviour in price differentials however does not imply that the WTI market is not
reflecting fundamentals. On the contrary, price movements are efficiently reflecting the local supply-
demand conditions in Cushing, Oklahoma. The main problem is that when local conditions become
dominant, the WTI price can no longer reflect the supply-demand balance in the US or in the world and
thus no longer acts as a useful international benchmark for pricing crude oil for the rest of the world. It
has also become less useful as a means of pricing crude in other US regions such as the Gulf coast.

59
Figure 17: WTI-BRENT Price Differential ($/Barrel)

+9.00
+7.00
+5.00
+3.00
+1.00
-1.00
-3.00
-5.00
-7.00
-9.00

Source: Petroleum Intelligence Weekly

Most Latin American producers85 and until recently also some Middle East producers used WTI in their
pricing formula in long-term contracts. In 2010, Saudi Arabia decided to shift to an alternative index
known as the Argus Sour Crude Index (ASCI) for its US sales. Kuwait and Iraq soon followed suit. ASCI
is calculated on the basis of trade in three U.S. Gulf of Mexico grades: Mars, Poseidon and Southern
Green Canyon. Unlike WTI and LLS which are sweet and light, the ASCI benchmark is a medium sour
index. These sour crudes also do not seem to suffer from infrastructure problems and the occasional
logistic bottlenecks that affect WTI, although disruptions could take place as they exposed to potential
hurricanes, as Hurricanes Rita and Ivan illustrated. Their physical bases have benefited from the increased
production in the Gulf of Mexico and as a result the volume of spot trade in the underlying crudes is
sizeable. It is important to note that like other local US benchmarks, ASCI is linked to WTI and currently
trades as differential to WTI. In a way, the „WTI Nymex price is the fixed price basis for the index‟ and
thus ASCI is not intended „to replace WTI as fixed price but instead works in conjunction with other
markets to provide a tool for valuing sour crude at the Gulf Coast‟ (Argus, 2010:3). This explains why
newly listed derivatives instruments such as futures, options and over the counter (OTC) around ASCI did
not gain any liquidity as most of the hedging can be done using the WTI contract.86

85
Mexico‟s formula for sales to the USA is much more complex. It may include the price of more than one
reference crude (WTI, ANS, West Texas Sour (WTS), Light Louisiana Sweet (LLS), Dated Brent and may be linked
to fuel prices.
86
Another potential reason as to why ASCI OTC has not gained volume is because the users of the
Saudi/Kuwaiti/Iraqi crude are also often producers of the ASCI grades and as such they are internally hedged
through their own activities.

60
7. The Dubai-Oman Market
Currently most cargoes from the Gulf to Asia are priced against Dubai or Oman or combination of these
crudes where around 13.1 mb/d or 94% of Gulf exports destined to Asia are priced of Platts‟ assessment
of Dubai/Oman (Leaver, 2010). With oil starting to flow from East Siberia to Asia in 2009 through the
East Siberia-Pacific Ocean Pipeline (ESPO), one could argue that Dubai‟s role has now expanded into
Russia, as ESPO currently trades as a differential to Dubai. Dubai became the main price marker for the
Gulf region by default in the mid 1980s when it was one of the few Gulf crudes available for sale on the
spot market. Also unlike other countries in the Gulf such as Iran, Kuwait, and Saudi Arabia, until very
recently Dubai allowed oil companies to own equity in Dubai production. Up until April 2007, the major
producing offshore oil fields of Fateh, SouthWest Fateh, Rashid, and Falah were operated by the Dubai
Petroleum Company (DPC), a wholly owned subsidiary of Conoco-Phillips. DPC acted on the behalf of
the DPC/Dubai Marine Areas Limited, a consortium comprised of Conoco-Phillips (32.65%), Total
(27.5%), Repsol YPF (25%), RWE Dea (10%), and Wintershall (5%). In April 2007, the concession was
passed on to a new company, the Dubai Petroleum Establishment (DPE), a 100% government owned
company while the operations of the offshore fields were passed to Petrofac which acts on the behalf of
DPE. The Dubai market emerged around 1984 when the spot trade in Arabian Light declined and then
ceased to exist. When the Dubai market first emerged, few trading companies participated in this market
with little volume of trading taking place. This however changed during the period 1985-1987 when many
Japanese trading houses and Wall Street refiners started entering the market. The major impetus came in
1988 when key OPEC countries abandoned the administered pricing system and started pricing their
crude export to Asia on the basis of the Dubai crude. Over a short period of time, Dubai became
responsible for pricing millions of barrels on a daily basis and the Dubai market became known as the
„Brent of the East‟ (Horsnell and Mabro, 1993).
Dubai is not the only benchmark used for pricing cargoes in or destined to Asia-Pacific. Malaysia and
Indonesia set their own official selling prices. Malaysia‟s sales are set on a monthly-average of price
assessments by panel Asia Petroleum Price Index (APPI) plus P-Factor premium which is determined by
the national oil company Petronas. Indonesia sells its cargoes on the basis of the Indonesian Crude Price
(ICP) which is based on a monthly average of daily spot price assessments. While some cargoes are
priced as a differential to Indonesian Minas and Malaysian Tapis, these benchmarks have fallen in favour
with Asian traders. Since APPI and ICP are often used to price sweet crudes, trading against Dated Brent
for sweet crudes has been on the increase in Asia, a trend which is likely to consolidate as the physical
liquidity of the key Asian benchmarks Tapis and Minas continues to decline. This should be of concern to
producers and consumers as the Dated Brent benchmark may not necessarily be fully reflective of
supply/demand fundamentals in East of Suez markets. Abu Dhabi, Qatar and Oman also set their own
official selling prices. The former two countries set their OSP retroactively. For instance, the OSP
announced in October refers to cargoes that have already been loaded in September. To reflect more
accurately market conditions, spot cargoes traded in October or November are often traded as differentials
to OSP. Dubai and Oman shifted from a retroactive pricing system to a forward pricing system based on
the DME Oman Futures contract. The pricing off the DME contract however still comprise only a small
percentage of Gulf crude exports to Asia.
The Physical Base of Dubai and Oman
In the early stages of the current oil pricing system, Dubai benchmark only included crude oil produced in
Dubai‟s fields. The volume of Dubai crude production has dropped from a peak of 400,000 b/d in the
period 1990−95 to under 120,000 b/d in 2004, with production hovering around 90,000 b/d in 2009 i.e.
there are about six cargoes of Dubai available for trade in every month (See Figure 18). The most recent
(unofficial) figures suggest that Dubai‟s production may have fallen further to 60,000 b/d i.e. less than
four cargoes a month with few of these cargoes sold under long-term contracts. Thus, though Dubai
cargoes may be offered sporadically on the spot market for sale, it rarely if ever does trade. The

61
government‟s decision not to renew the oil concession in 2007 also meant that Dubai no longer satisfies
the ownership diversification criterion. The low volumes of production and thin trading activity render the
process of price discovery on the basis of physical transactions not always feasible. In a sense, Dubai has
turned into a brand or index which represents a sour basket of mid sour grades.87
The rapid decline in Dubai output has increased the importance of Oman in pricing crude oil in the East
of Suez. Oman has some of the characteristics to enable it to play the role of a benchmark such as the
volume of physical liquidity. In 2009, Omani crude oil production reached 815,000 b/d compared to an
average of 760,000 b/d in 1990-1995. The production is not subject to OPEC quotas as Oman is not a
member of OPEC and there are no destination restrictions. On the other hand, Omani crude oil production
is almost totally controlled by PDO, an upstream operating company which is responsible to all the equity
producers for optimising production and delivery through Mina Al Fahal. PDO is owned by the Omani
government (60%), Shell (34%), Total (4%) and Partex (2%). This structure has remained stable since
1977. There is an array of foreign and private domestic oil companies operating outside PDO, but these
constitute a small share of total oil output. In 2009, PDO accounted for more than 90% of the country‟s
total crude oil production.
Figure 18: Dubai and Oman Crude Production Estimates (thousand barrels per day)

1000
900
800
700
600
500
400
300
200
100
0
1990-1995 1999 2004 2005 2009

Dubai Oman

Source: Leaver, T. (2010), DME-Oman: Transparent Pricing and Effective Risk Management in a New Era,
Presentation at the Asia Oil and Gas Conference, Kuala Lumpur, June.

The Financial Layers of Dubai


Unlike Brent, very few financial layers have emerged around Dubai. Attempts to launch a Dubai futures
contracts in London and Singapore were made in the early 1990s, but such attempts did not succeed.
Instead, the informal forward Dubai market remained at the centre of the Dubai complex. In the early
stages of its development, producers with entitlement to production used to place their cargoes in the
forward market. Being a waterborne crude, Dubai shared many of the features of the forward Brent
market with some institutional differences such as the process of nomination, the announcement of the
loading schedule, and the duration of the book-out process (for details see Horsnell and Mabro, 1993).
87
One observer argues that the actual production or even non-existent of Dubai crude oil is irrelevant. What is of
relevance is that by buying the Dubai brand or index one can obtain physical oil and by selling the Dubai index one
has the obligation to deliver physical oil.

62
Currently, the two most important layers surrounding the Dubai market are the Brent/Dubai Exchange of
Futures for Swaps (EFS) and the Dubai inter-month swaps markets. The Brent/Dubai EFS is similar to the
EFP discussed above but where a trader converts a Brent futures position to a forward month Dubai Swap
plus a quality premium spread. This market allows traders to convert their Dubai price exposure into a
Brent price exposure which is easier to manage given the high liquidity of the Brent futures market. As in
the case of an EFP, the EFS is reported as a differential to the price of ICE Brent. It was not possible to
obtain data on EFS volumes, but sources estimate that the volumes of Brent-Dubai EFS and Brent-Dubai
swaps in total are about 1,000-2,000 lots on an average day (i.e. about 1 million-2 million b/d) and can
easily exceed 2,000 lots on a relatively busy day. The Dubai inter-month swap reflects the price
differential between two swaps and thus is different from cash spreads. It allows traders to hedge their
position from one month to the next. Dubai inter-month swaps are actively traded in London and
Singapore and are central to the determination of the forward Dubai price. The actual volumes of inter-
month Dubai is also not available, but traders reckon that about 2,000 lots of Dubai swaps (which
includes Dubai outright swaps and inter-month Dubai swaps) trade on an average day. Other sources
suggest a higher estimate with the volume of total Dubai swap (the swap leg of Brent-Dubai and
intermonth combined) in the range of 8000-10000 lots per day of which around 60% is cleared by ICE or
CME. The participants in these markets are quite diverse. Apart from some Japanese refiners, the main
players include banks (Merrill Lynch BoA, JP Morgan, Morgan Stanley, Societe Generale), refiners (BP,
Shell), trading firms (Mercuria, Vitol) and Japanese firms (Mitsui, Sumitomo).
Since 1989, spread deals in Brent-Dubai and inter-month Dubai differentials have dominated trading
activity. As seen from Figure 19, while in 1986 outright deals constituted the bulk of the deals in Dubai,
by 1989 these had declined to low levels. By 1991, spread deals constituted around 95% of the total
number of deals in Dubai with the Brent-Dubai trades playing a central role. In 1991 Brent-Dubai trades
accounted for one third of the liquidity and half of the concluded deals with the Brent market providing
the Dubai market with the bulk of its liquidity. Given the links with the Brent market, Horsnell and
Mabro (1993) argue that „Dubai has become close to being little more than another Brent add-on market‟.

Figure 19: Spread Deals as a Percentage of Total Number of Dubai Deals

100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1986 1986 1986 1986 1987 1987 1987 1987 1988 1988 1988 1988 1989 1989 1989 1989 1990 1990 1990 1990 1991 1991 1991 1991
Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4

Notes: Spread deals include Dubai one-month spread, Dubai two-month spreads, and Dubai-Brent and Dubai-WTI
Spreads.

63
The Price Discovery Process in the Dubai Market
The two main oil pricing reporting agencies Platts and Argus follow very different methodologies in their
assessment of the Dubai price which on many occasions may result in different Dubai prices. Over the
years, the declining production of Dubai has pushed Platts to search for some alternatives to maintain the
viability of Dubai as a global benchmark. In 2001, it allowed the delivery of Oman against Dubai
contracts. In 2004, Platts introduced a mechanism known as the partials mechanism, to counteract the
problem of Dubai‟s low liquidity.88 The partials mechanism has the effect of slicing a Dubai cargo (as
well as Oman) into small parcels that can be traded. The smallest trading unit was set at 25,000 barrels.
Since operators do not allow the sale of cargoes of that volume, it has meant that a seller of a partial
contract is not able to meet his contractual obligation. Thus, delivery will only occur if the buyer has been
able to trade 19 partials totalling 475,000 barrels with a single counterparty.89 Any traded amount less
than 475,000 barrels is not deliverable and should be cash settled (Platts, 2004).90 Platts allows for the
delivery of Omani crude oil or Upper Zakum against Dubai in case of physical convergence of the
contract. In other words, the buyer has to accept the delivery of a usually higher-value of an Oman cargo
or an Upper Zakum against the Dubai contract. The addition of Oman has created problems of its own. In
the Dubai-Oman benchmark, Oman crude has lower sulfur content and higher gravity than the Dubai
crude. In some periods depending on the relative demand and supply for the various crudes, the price gap
between the two types of crude tends to widen. As seen in Figure 20, the differential is quite variable
reaching more than $1.50 in some occasions. As a result of this divergence, many observers have called
for the inclusion of another type of crude in the Dubai assessment process which is closer to Dubai than it
is to Oman.91
Figure 20: Oman-Dubai Spread ($/Barrel)

+2.00

+1.50

+1.00

+0.50

...

-0.50

-1.00

-1.50
Nov 95

Nov 96

Nov 97

Nov 98

Nov 99

Nov 00

Nov 01

Nov 02

Nov 03

Nov 04

Nov 05

Nov 06

Nov 07

Nov 08

Nov 09
May 95

May 96

May 97

May 98

May 99

May 00

May 01

May 02

May 03

May 04

May 05

May 06

May 07

May 08

May 09

Source: Oil Market Intelligence


The price of Dubai is assessed based on concluded deals of partials in the Platts window, failing that on
bid and offers and failing that on information from the swap markets surrounding Dubai. Thus, despite
the fact that NOCs in the Gulf have large physical liquidity which in principle allows them to set the oil
88
A market was developed in the 1980s to trade Brent partials but with the development of the Brent futures market,
the market became redundant. But trade in partials is still used by Platts to assess North Sea and Dubai crudes.
89
This is equivalent to a full 500,000-barrel cargo with an implied operational tolerance of minus 5%.
90
Settlement of cash differences that result from undeliverable partials uses the last price assessment of the trading
month.
91
The pricing of a crude off Dubai-Oman requires setting two coefficients of adjustment (one off Dubai and one off
Oman) and then taking some average between the two coefficients.

64
price, oil exporting countries have avoided assuming this role, shifting the power to set the price to few
traders that participate in the Platt‟s window. Oil exporting countries do not participate in the window;
they simply take Platts assessment of Dubai and use it in their pricing formula. This transfer of the pricing
discovery role to Platt‟s window achieves an important objective as oil exporters do not want to be seen
as influencing oil prices: it is the market that sets the oil price, and not oil exporters. On other hand, this
transfer of power creates some sort of mistrust in the trading activity in the Platts window.
Initially, the shift to partial trading in 2004 has produced encouraging results, increasing the volume of
trading activity and hence improving the efficiency of price discovery, reducing the bid/offer spreads, and
attracting new players to the market (Montepeque, 2005). However, in recent years, the liquidity in Platts‟
Dubai window has declined to a point when only few deals are concluded during a month (Figure 21). In
many days, there is no execution of partial trades. In fact, since October 2008, there has been no
execution of partial trades in 50% of trading days (Leaver, 2010). This however does not preclude Platts
from producing a value for Dubai, which can be based on bids and offers and/or information from the
value of derivatives. Only a few players such as Sietco, Vitol, Glencore, and Mercuria dominate the Platts
Dubai window at any one day. On the sell side, large Asian refineries such as Unipec and SK have been
dominant. The concentration of trading activity in the hands of few players in the Platts partials market
has raised serious concerns that some traders by investing as little as in a 25,000-barrel partial contract
can influence the pricing of millions of barrels traded everyday (Binks, 2005). However, market
participants who think that prices are being manipulated by a few players have the incentive to enter
Platts window and exert their influence on the price. Critics argue that barriers to entry can prevent such
an adjustment mechanism from taking place.
Figure 21: Dubai Partials Jan 2008 - Nov 2010

250

200

150

100

50

0
January May September January May September January May September

Source: Platts
The way that Argus derives the Dubai price sheds some light on the links between the various financial
layers surrounding Dubai. Argus‟ approach for assessing Dubai is based on deriving information from
various OTC markets, the most important of which is the Exchange for Swaps (EFS) and the inter-month
Dubai spread contracts. The EFS price is reported as a differential to the ICE Brent futures contract. This
allows Argus to identify a fixed price for Dubai in a particular month referred to as the price of Dubai
Swap. But since Dubai is loaded two months ahead, the assessed price of Dubai say in the month of

65
December is the forward price of Dubai in February i.e. it is price for delivery of Dubai in the month of
February (call it x)92. But buyers and sellers are interested in the price of Dubai in December. To derive
the price of Dubai in December, the information from the inter-month Dubai spread market is used.
Specifically, the January-February Dubai swap price differential is subtracted from x which gives the
price of delivery of Dubai in January (call it y).93 The January-December Dubai swap price differential is
next subtracted from y to give us the price of Dubai for the month of December.94
Once the price of Dubai is identified, the derivation of the Oman price follows in a rather mechanical
way, mainly by exploiting information about Dubai-Oman spreads. If Oman partials are traded in the
window, Platts uses the price of concluded deals or bids/offers to derive the Oman price. When this is not
feasible, the Oman value will be assessed using the Oman-Dubai swaps spread95, a derivative contract
which trades the differential between Oman‟s OSP and Dubai for the month concerned. The contract is
traded over the counter and does not involve any physical delivery. The Dubai-Oman swap price
differential will then be used in a formula which links it to the value of Dubai. Similarly, Argus assesses
the value of Oman by comparing the value of Oman with that of Dubai. Argus first calculates the
differential to Dubai swaps and then adds it or subtracts it from Dubai outright swap to get the Oman
forward price. So currently, the assessment of Oman price by PRAs is a simple extension of the Dubai
market, where the Dubai/Oman spread provides the necessary link.
The above price derivation shows clearly that the Brent futures market sets the price level while the EFS
and the inter-month Dubai spread market set the price differentials. These differentials are in turn used to
calculate a fixed price for Dubai. In a sense, the price of Dubai need not have a physical dimension. It can
be derived from the financial layers that have emerged around Dubai. This has raised some concerns as
„calls to use swaps as pricing benchmarks for physicals are at best uninformed as swaps are derivatives of
the core physical instruments‟ (Montepeque, 2005). But this neglects the fact that liquidity in Platts
Dubai‟s window is thin. In addition, the argument against using swaps is inconsistent with Platts‟ use of
swaps (CFDs) in identifying the price of Dated Brent. It is also inconsistent with the fact that at times
when no partials are trading, Platts has no alternative but to use the EFS to identify the Dubai price.
Another concern is that unlike the WTI-Brent differential which reflects the relative market conditions in
Europe and the USA, Horsnell and Mabro (1993) argue that the Brent-Dubai differential does not usually
reflect the trading conditions of Asian markets except on some rare occasions such as the Iraqi invasion of
Kuwait. In normal times, Dubai crude is more responsive to trading conditions in Europe and the US than
the Far East. Specifically, the authors argue that the Brent-Dubai differential reflects better the
relationship between prices of sweet and sour crudes. In support of this hypothesis, they argue that when
OPEC decides to cut production, these cuts affect the production of heavy sour crudes. As a result, the
price of these crudes will strengthen relative to sweet crudes leading to the strengthening of Dubai prices
relative to Brent. The recent growth of the Asia-Pacific market and the wide entry of Asian players may
have changed these dynamics with the Dubai-Brent spread currently responding more closely to Asia‟s
trading conditions making Brent-related cargoes either more attractive (small Brent premium) or less
attractive (large Brent premium) to Asia-Pacific buyers, but this need further empirical investigation.

Oman and its Financial Layers: A New Benchmark in the Making?


In June 2007, the Dubai Mercantile Exchange (DME) launched the Oman Crude Oil Futures Contract to
serve as a pricing benchmark of Gulf exports to Asia and as a mechanism to improve risk management.
Figure 22 below shows the daily volume of DME Oman futures contracts traded between June 2007 and
September 2010. The figure suggests that the volume of contracts traded is highly volatile, but remains

92
This is referred to as Dubai Third Forward Month.
93
This is referred to as the Dubai Second Forward Month.
94
This is referred to as the Dubai Swap First Month.
95
Oman swap is a derivative of the Platts‟ cash Oman assessment. However, in the absence of bids and offers for
Oman swaps, Platts uses the information from the structure of the Dubai forward curve for assessing Oman swaps.

66
relatively low. In 2009, the average daily volume of traded contracts amounted to slightly more than 2000
contracts, which is very low especially when compared to the traded volume of WTI or Brent futures
contracts.

Figure 22: daily Volume of Traded DME Oman Crude Oil Futures Contract
9,000
8,000
7,000
6,000
5,000
4,000
3,000
2,000
1,000
-
2nd July 2007

2nd June 2008


30th August 2007

31st July 2008


29th August 2008

31st March 2009


02nd March 2009

28th August 2009

25th August 2010


1st August 2007

30th April 2009


1st October 2007
30th October 2007

29th October 2008

27th October 2009

25th February 2010

27th April 2010


31st January 2008

26th March 2010


1st June 2007

2nd April 2008

27th November 2008*

30th June 2009


30th July 2009

24th December 2009

26th May 2010


25th June 2010
27th July 2010
30th September 2008

29thDecember 2008

28th September 2009

24th September 2010


31st December 2007

3rd March 2008

1st July 2008


1st May 2008

29th January 2009

27th January 2010


29th November 2007

1st June 2009

25th November 2009


Source: CME Group

DME‟s Oman futures contract allows settlement against physical delivery of Oman crude. One interesting
feature of the DME futures contracts is the large number of contracts that converge for physical delivery
in any given month. Figure 23 below traces the evolution of the trading volume and open interest for the
October 2010 Futures contract during the month of August. On 31st August, 2010 the open interest
reached almost 21,000 contracts. This is equivalent to 21 million barrels a month comprising more than
80% of Oman‟s monthly crude oil production. By any standard, these are very large volumes to be
delivered through futures contracts. For instance, physical delivery on the Light Sweet Crude Oil Futures
contract exceeded four million barrels only once in January 1995. Also in contrast with other benchmark
contracts, the open interest on the DME contract tends to increase as contract expiry approaches as shown
in Figure 21. This represents an important anomaly and implies that the DME contract is simply used as a
means to access physical Oman crude oil. This feature sets aside the DME contract from the other
successful futures contracts that have evolved around Brent and WTI.

67
Figure 23: Volume and Open Interest of the October 2010 Futures Contracts (Traded During
Month of August)

25000

20000

15000

10000

5000

0
02-Aug-10
03-Aug-10
04-Aug-10
05-Aug-10
06-Aug-10
07-Aug-10
08-Aug-10
09-Aug-10
10-Aug-10
11-Aug-10
12-Aug-10
13-Aug-10
14-Aug-10
15-Aug-10
16-Aug-10
17-Aug-10
18-Aug-10
19-Aug-10
20-Aug-10
21-Aug-10
22-Aug-10
23-Aug-10
24-Aug-10
25-Aug-10
26-Aug-10
27-Aug-10
28-Aug-10
29-Aug-10
30-Aug-10
31-Aug-10
Volume Open Interest

Source: DME Website


The introduction of the DME contract has changed the pricing mechanism of Omani crude. From its
inception, it was clear that both a retroactive official selling price (OSP) and futures market-related price
undermined the market function of price discovery.96 Thus, it was a matter of time before Oman decided
to change its pricing from a retroactive pricing system to a forward pricing system based on the DME
contract. The OSP for Oman crude for physical delivery is calculated as the arithmetic average of the
daily settlement prices over the month. For instance, the OSP for Oman crude for the month of June is
calculated as the arithmetic average of the daily settlement of price over the month of June for delivery in
two months i.e. in the month of August. The Government of Dubai has also ceased the pricing of its crude
oil sales off its current mechanism and instead utilises DME Oman futures prices providing additional
boost to the contract. Dubai and Oman however have been the exceptions so far. Despite Dubai‟s low
physical liquidity, Platts Dubai/Oman assessments are still the preferred price benchmark used in the
pricing formula for exports to Asia. This raises the question why other Middle Eastern producers have not
been enthusiastic about adopting the DME Oman Crude Oil Futures contract as the basis of pricing crude
oil.
The futures market plays two important roles: price discovery and hedging/speculation or what is termed
as risk management. Liquidity is crucial for the efficient performance of these two functions. Physical
deliverability, which the DME tends to emphasize, is less important. In other words, deliverability is not a
sufficient condition for the success of the DME Oman contract. In fact, physical deliverability can reduce
the chances of the success of a futures contract if market participants have doubts about the likely
performance of the delivery mechanism or if physical bottlenecks around delivery points result in some
serious dislocations although the extensive use of the DME‟s physical delivery mechanism demonstrates
confidence in its performance. Nevertheless, inability to increase trading liquidity while physical
deliverability continues to rise may undermine the contract as the risk of physical delivery tends to rise,
especially for those players that are not interested in physical delivery in the first place. If low liquidity
persists, then the two functions of price discovery and risk management would be undermined and the
contract would fail to attract the attention of market participants.

96
In a retroactive pricing system, the OSP applied to cargoes that have already been loaded. In a forward pricing
system, the price for an oil shipment to be loaded say in May is determined two months before i.e. in March.

68
Asian interest is crucial for the long term success of the contract as the Asia-Pacific region is the main
importer of Middle Eastern sour crude oil. However, big Asian refineries haven‟t so far shown strong
enthusiasm for the contract. As to the financial players/speculators, the DME futures contract can open
new opportunities for trading and risk management. But speculative and hedging activity will not be
attracted to a market with low liquidity. Market participants often prefer to trade only in the most liquid
markets. The recent launch by CME of DME linked swap and option contracts is geared to providing new
risk management tools in the hope of attracting more financial players and Asian refineries into the
market. While Gulf oil producers do not hedge their oil production in the futures market, they have
interest in a sour futures contract for export pricing purposes. Low liquidity however is likely to
discourage the already very cautious Gulf oil exporters from setting their crude price against the DME
futures contracts. So far, none of the big gulf producers such as Saudi Arabia, Kuwait, Qatar, and Iran
have shown much interest in the newly established sour futures contracts. However, there is the
temptation for some Gulf countries to shift part of the global oil trading activity to the region, which may
induce a change in some oil exporters‟ attitude towards the contract. There is also strong interest in the
success of the DME contract as evidenced by the heavy involvement of the CME Group and the various
stakeholders.97 Without this strong interest and support, the contract would have perhaps failed by now.

97
The DME is a joint venture between Tatweer (a member of Dubai Holding), Oman Investment Fund and CME
Group. Global financial institutions and energy trading firms such as Goldman Sachs, J.P. Morgan, Morgan Stanley,
Shell, Vitol and Concord Energy have also taken equity stakes in the DME (Source: Dubai Mercantile Exchange
Website).

69
8. Assessment and Evaluation
Based on the above detailed analysis of the various benchmarks and their surrounding layers, it is possible
to draw some broad implications which can be grouped as follows: the physical liquidity of benchmarks;
the new dynamics of oil trade flows and its implications on pricing benchmarks; the nature of players in
the market; the linkages between physical and financial layers; the process of price adjustment; and
transparency in oil markets.

Physical Liquidity of Benchmarks


An interesting feature of the current oil pricing system is that markets with relatively low volumes of
production such as WTI, Brent, and Dubai-Oman set the oil price for markets with much higher volumes
of production in the Gulf and elsewhere in the world. Despite the high level of volumes of production in
the Gulf, these markets remain illiquid, as there are limited volumes of spot trading, no forwards or swaps
(apart from Dubai), no liquid futures market, and destination restrictions which prevent on-trading in
chains. Furthermore, these markets are characterised by lack of equity diversification.

While adequate physical liquidity is not a sufficient condition for the emergence of benchmarks, it is a
necessary condition for a pricing benchmark‟s long-term success. Some observers have argued that in
principle, there is not a certain level of production below which the integrity of the market is threatened.
Before its substitution by WTI, the Alaskan North Slope (ANS) continued to generate market prices
although the physical base was very narrow. The prices were derived completely from oil price reporting
agencies‟ assessments of traders‟ perceptions about what the price would be if there were actual trade in
cargoes. This argument however is unconvincing because confidence is unlikely to survive for long in
markets with low physical liquidity.98 As markets become thinner and thinner, the price discovery process
becomes more difficult as oil reporting agencies cannot observe enough genuine arms-length deals.
Furthermore, in thin markets, the danger of squeezes and distortions increases and as a result prices could
then become less informative and more volatile thereby distorting consumption and production decisions
(Pirrong, 1996). 99 A squeeze refers to a situation in which a trader goes long in a forward market by an
amount that exceeds the actual physical cargoes that can be loaded during that month. If successful, the
squeezer will claim delivery from sellers (shorts) and will obtain cash settlement involving a premium.
One consequence of a successful squeeze is that the price of the particular crude that has been squeezed
will rise relative to that of other marker crudes. Squeezes also increase the volatility between prices in
different layers such as between the Dated Brent and the forward Brent giving rise to new financial
instruments to manage this risk such as CFDs. Squeezes are made possible by two features: the
anonymity of trade and the huge volume of trading compared to the underlying physical base (Mollgaard,
1997). After all, squeezes are much easier to perform in a thin market (Telser, 1992). This is in contrast
with futures markets where the volume of transactions is quite large and thus there is less room for
squeezes and manipulation, although futures markets are not totally immune.100 Squeezes are also

98
The fact that ANS stopped acting as a benchmark suggests that there is a level below which integrity of the
benchmark is threatened.
99
See for Instance, Liz Bossley (2003), Battling Benchmark Distortions”, Petroleum Economist, April. More
recently, concerns about squeezes arose when one oil trader HETCO took control of the first eight North Sea Forties
crude oil cargoes loading in February 2011 and two Brent cargoes with market observers describing such a move as
a „trading play‟ intended to influence the spot market. Reuters (2011), „Oil Trader Takes Control of 10 North Sea
Oil cargoes‟, January 18.
100
The challenge of the U.S. Federal trade commission to the BP Amoco-Arco merger was partly based on the fear
that by controlling the physical infrastructure, the WTI futures market can be squeezed. The Federal trade
commission notes that „the restriction of pipeline or storage capacity can affect the deliverable supply of crude oil in
Cushing and consequently affect both WTI crude cash prices and NYMEX futures prices‟ (p.7). Then it states that „a
firm that controlled substantial storage in Cushing and pipeline capacity into Cushing would be able to manipulate
NYMEX futures trading markets and they enhance its own positions at the expense of producers, refiners and

70
becoming less prevalent in jurisdictions where regulators enforce the laws against abuse of market power,
and where those laws are clear. Also important is the design or the architecture of the market/contracts in
which PRAs, in consultation with market participants, play a key role in determining its main features and
structures and evolution over time. Regulators have also turned their attention to this issue where some
observers consider that „the proposed spot-month position limit formula seeks to minimize the potential
for corners and squeezes by facilitating the orderly liquidation of positions as the market approaches the
end of trading and by restricting the swap positions which may be used to influence the price of
referenced contracts‟.101
So far the low and the rapid decline in the physical base of existing benchmarks have been counteracted
by including additional crude streams in assessed benchmark. This had the effect of reducing the chances
of squeezes as these alternative crudes could be used for delivery against the contract. Although such
short-term solutions have been successful in alleviating the problem of squeezes, they should not distract
observers from raising some key questions: What are the requisite conditions for the emergence of
successful benchmarks in the most liquid market in terms of production? Would a shift to price
assessment in such markets improve the price discovery process? Such key questions remain heavily
under-researched in the energy literature and do not feature in the producer-consumer dialogue.

Shifts in Global Oil Demand Dynamics and Benchmarks


One of the most important shifts in oil market dynamics in recent years has been the acceleration of oil
consumption in non-OECD economies. Between 2000 and 2009, demand growth in non-OECD outpaced
that of OECD in every year (see Figure 24). During this period, non-OECD oil consumption increased by
around 10.5 million b/d while that of OECD dropped by 2.1 mb/d. At the heart of this growth lies the
Asia-Pacific region which accounted for more than 50% of this incremental change in demand during the
10-year period.

Figure 24: OECD and Non-OECD Oil Demand Dynamics

2500
2000
1500
1000
500
0
1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
-500
-1000
-1500
-2000
-2500
OECD Non-OECD

Source: BP (2010)

traders‟ (p. 7) (United States of America Before Federal Trade Commission in the Matter of BP AMOCO P.L.C. and
Atlantic Richfield Company downloadable from http://www.ftc.gov/os/2000/08/bparco.pdf
101
„Proposed Position Limits for Derivatives‟, Statement of Bruce Fekrat, Senior Special Council, Division of
market Oversight, CFTC, December 16, 2010.

71
The emergence of the non-OECD as the main source of growth in global oil demand has had far reaching
implications on the dynamics of oil trade flows. This is perhaps best illustrated in the shift in the direction
of oil flows from Saudi Arabia and Russia, the two biggest oil producers in the world towards the East.
As shown in Figure 25, in 2002 Saudi Arabia‟s share of oil exports to the US and Europe amounted to
28.2% and 17.9% respectively. In 2009, these shares declined to 17.8% for the US and 10% for Europe.
In 2009 Saudi Arabia abandoned its St Eustatius storage facility in the Caribbean which was mainly used
to feed US markets and instead obtained storage facility in Japan to feed Asian markets.

Figure 25: Change in Oil Trade Flow Dynamics

Composition of Saudi Exports in Composition of Saudi Exports in


2002 2009

15%
28%

US 10%
US
Europe Europe
54%
Others Others
75%
18%

Source: Barclays Capital, Oil Sketches, 23 April 2010

So far, Russia‟s exports have been heavily concentrated towards Europe to which in 2009 it exported
around 7 mb/d compared with 1.17 mb/d to Asia Pacific.102 These dynamics however are changing as
Russia builds new infrastructure in an attempt to shift part of its oil exports towards the Far East. The
inauguration in December 2009 of the first section of the Eastern Siberia Pacific Ocean (ESPO) pipeline
represents a marginal but nonetheless important step in that direction. The first section of ESPO is a 2,757
km long pipeline connecting Taishet in East Siberia to Skovorodino in Russia‟s Far East, near the border
with China. It has a capacity of 600,000 b/d is expected to grow to 1 million b/d by 2012, and potentially
to as much as 1.6 million b/d in 2015. The second stage of the project involved linking Skovorodino to a
new export terminal at Kozmino on the Pacific coast in order to supply some of the rapidly growing oil
demand in Asia. China and Russia then agreed to construct an offshoot from Skovorodino to Daqing in
China with a capacity of 300,000 b/d. It was completed by the close of 2010.

Such changes in trade flow patterns are likely to accelerate as the centre of consumption growth continues
to shift from OECD to emerging economies. The EIA103 predicts that between 2007 and 2035, oil
consumption is expected to increase by around 24 mb/d from 86.1 mb/d to 110.6 mb/d with non-OECD
accounting for almost all of the increase during this period. This shift in the dynamics of trade flows
towards the East is likely to have profound implications on pricing benchmarks. Questions are already
being raised as to whether Dubai, Minas and Tapis still constitute appropriate benchmarks for pricing oil
in Asia given their low liquidity or whether new benchmarks are needed to reflect more accurately the

102
BP (2010), BP Statistical Review of World Energy, June.
103
EIA (2010), International Energy Outlook 2010, US Energy Information Administration, Table A.5.

72
shift in trade flows. In this respect, a debate has already started on the suitability of ESPO to act as an
Asian benchmark.104 Since ESPO competes with Mideast crudes, so far ESPO has strengthened the Dubai
benchmark. Since December 2009, Platts has been assessing the value of ESPO but as a differential to
Platts‟ Dubai. In the longer term, ESPO has some of the features that may allow it to assume the role of a
benchmark itself. The pricing point in Northern Asia is particularly attractive. ESPO is close to key
refining centres in China, Japan and South Korea where the sailing time from the loading port of
Kozmino to northeast Asia is just a few days, transforming the Asian market from a long haul to a short
haul market. Furthermore, ESPO volumes are larger than many of the existing benchmark and could
increase in the future. On the other hand, there is uncertainty about the volume that will be available for
sale in the spot market as a considerable amount of it is sold on long-term basis or used in Rosneft
refineries. There is also uncertainty about the quality of ESPO over time. Most importantly, for any
benchmark to emerge, market participants should have confidence that the benchmark is not subject to
manipulation which is yet to be proven. One must consider the legal, tax, and regulatory regime operating
around any particular benchmark. WTI has the US government overseeing it and a robust legal regimen.
Brent has also stable governmental oversight. Distrust of the Russian government is strong in many
companies and hence the reluctance so far to support an ESPO benchmark. Nevertheless, if discontent
with existing benchmarks intensifies, then ESPO could be one of the few options available for the
industry to fall back on.
Regardless of whether or not ESPO will eventually emerge as a benchmark, it is already having an impact
on pricing dynamics in Asia. In a sense, ESPO is likely to become or has become the marginal barrel in
Asia, displacing West African crudes in this role. Gulf suppliers have to monitor ESPO's performance
very closely when setting their price differential in relation to Dubai to maintain their export
competitiveness to Asia. This is likely to cause a decline in the size of the „Asian premium‟ over time.

The Nature of Players and the Oil Price Formation Process


In recent years, the futures markets have attracted a wide range of financial players including pension
funds, hedge funds, index investors, technical traders, and high net worth individuals. Many reasons have
been suggested on why financial players have increased their participation in commodities markets. The
historically low correlation between commodities‟ returns in general and other financial assets‟ returns,
such as stocks or bonds, has increased the attractiveness of holding commodities for portfolio
diversification purposes for some institutional investors. Because commodity returns are positively
correlated with inflation, some investors have entered the commodities market to hedge against inflation
risk and weak dollar. Expectations of relative higher returns in investment in commodities due to
perception of tightened market fundamentals have motivated many investors to enter the oil market.
Finally, financial innovation has provided an easy and a cheap way for various participants, both
institutional and retail investors, to gain exposure to commodities.

The entry and the impact of financial players has been the subject of various empirical studies. Some
examine whether these players had a destabilising effect on commodities futures markets.105 Other studies
focus on the impact of players on the inter-linkages between commodities markets and other financial
markets such as equity.106 While these and other similar studies provide some valuable insights into the
issue of linkages between financial layers and physical benchmarks, it is important to expand the analysis

104
See for instance, J.P. Morgan (2010), “Will EPSO Emerge as a New Pricing Benchmark?”, Presentation at the
Platts Crude Oil Methodology Forum 2010, London, May.
105
See for instance Brunetti and Büyükşahin (2009).
106
For example, Büyükşahin and Robe (2010) find that the composition of traders plays a role in explaining the joint
distribution of equity and commodity returns. Specifically, they find that a subset of hedge funds, those that are
active both in equity and commodity futures market can explain the increase in the commodity-equity correlations.
In contrast, swap dealers, index traders, and floor brokers and traders play no role in explaining cross-correlations
across markets.

73
to the trading strategies of physical players. The fact remains that the participants in many of the OTC
markets such as forward markets and CFDs which are central to the price discovery process are mainly
„physical‟ and include entities such as refineries, oil companies, downstream consumers, physical traders,
and market makers. Financial players such as pension funds, index and retail investors have limited
presence in some of these markets. Thus, any analysis limited to the role of non-commercial participants
in the futures markets in the oil price formation process is likely to be incomplete.

The Linkages between Physical Benchmarks and Financial Layers


At the early stages of the current pricing system linking prices to „physical‟ benchmarks in formulae
pricing provided producers and consumers with a sense of comfort that the price is grounded in the
physical dimension of the market. Suspicion still exists on whether the oil price derived from paper
markets such as the futures market reflects the physical realities of the oil market at the time of pricing.
Sceptics argue that prices in these markets are not determined on the basis of trading in real barrels, but
rather by trading in financial contracts for future delivery (Mabro, 2008).

The latter concern implicitly assumes that the process of identifying the price of benchmarks can be
isolated from financial layers. However, this is far from reality. As our analysis shows, the different layers
in the oil market are highly interconnected and form a complex web of links, all of which play a role in
the price discovery process. 107 The information derived from financial layers plays an important role in
identifying the price level of the benchmark. In the Brent market, the price of Dated Brent is assessed
using information from many layers including CFDs, forward markets, EFPs and futures markets.
Similarly, in the WTI complex, the prices of the various physical benchmarks are strongly interlinked
with the futures markets. The price of Dubai is often derived using information from the very active OTC
Dubai/Brent swaps market and the inter-Dubai swap market. Thus, the idea that one can isolate the
physical from the financial layers in the current oil pricing regime is a myth. Crude oil prices are jointly
or co-determined in both layers, depending on differences in timing, location and quality.

Despite the fact that the price discovery process is influenced by information from paper markets, most
players are still reluctant to adopt futures prices in their pricing formulae although some key producers
such as Saudi Arabia, Kuwait and Iran use BWAVE (futures price) in pricing their exports to Europe.
This can be explained by the fact that since prices in the futures markets reflect the price of oil today for
future delivery, they inject a substantial time basis risk. Currently, this basis risk is eliminated by
referencing against physical benchmarks and managing the price risk by using swaps against the
benchmark price.
The above discussion has also some implications on the pricing of derivatives instruments. Since physical
benchmarks constitute the basis of the large majority of physical transactions, some observers claim that
derivatives instruments such as futures, forwards, options and swaps derive their value from the price of
these physical benchmarks. In other words, the prices of the physical benchmarks drive the prices in paper
markets. However, this is a gross over-simplification and does not accurately reflect the process of crude
oil price formation as the two layers are highly interlinked. The issue of whether the paper market drives
the physical or the other way around is difficult to construct theoretically and test empirically.

Adjustments in Price Differentials versus Price Levels


Our analysis shows the importance of distinguishing between adjustments in price differentials and
adjustments in price levels. Trades in the levels of the oil price rarely take place in the layers surrounding
the physical benchmarks. Instead, these markets trade price differentials which fluctuate based on hedging
pressures and expectations of traders. It is rare (though not unheard of) for companies to take positions on
the basis of an outright price movement – that is whether prices go up or down. This is far too risky for

107
Platts use the word triangulate: “Assessments will use spread relationships and derivative values to help
triangulate value”. See Platts Crude Oil Methodology Forum 2010, May 2010 (London).

74
most participants. Most trade is on spreads of some sort – one regional price against another, one product
price against another, one product price against a crude (feedstock) price, one time period price against
another time period. These arbitrages self-correct by traders‟ actions such as buying in one region, where
there‟s too much oil, and transporting it to another region where there isn‟t enough and where the price is
higher to draw in the oil. This feature of the oil pricing system poses a legitimate question: how can
markets that actively trade price differentials set a price level for a particular benchmark? As noted by
Horsnell and Mabro (1993) in the context of forward Brent,
In spread deals the relationship between specified flat prices and market prices may not be very
tight. And since the focus is to a large extent on relatives, the search for price levels that
correspond to the relevant market conditions becomes less broadly based and less active. The
liquidity in that part of the market which concerns itself with the oil price level has become a
small proportion of the total liquidity of the forward market.
We postulate that the level of the oil price is set in the futures markets; the financial layers such as swaps
and forwards set the price differentials. By trading differentials, market participants limit their exposure to
risks of time, location grade and volume. These differentials are then used by oil reporting agencies to
identify the price level of a physical benchmark. Perhaps this is most evident in the US market. As
explained by Platts (2010b),

physical crude oil assessments are still widely used by the industry, but the „flat‟ price formation
is originated by the New York Mercantile Exchange (NYMEX). The highly liquid sweet crude
futures contract traded on NYMEX provides a visible real-time reference price for the market. In
the spot market, therefore, negotiations for physical oils will typically use NYMEX as a reference
point, with bids/offers and deals expressed as a differential to the futures price…. Therefore,
while NYMEX acts as a barometer of market value, and negotiations for physical oil may
reference the futures value, Platts plays a distinct and complementary role to that of the exchange
(p.3).

To illustrate this last point, the recent strikes in France in October 2010 present a good experiment. As
seen in Figure 26 below, during the strike between the period 11th and 21st of October, the price
differential between Dated Brent and ICE futures Brent widened considerably reaching a peak of -$1.53
dollars per barrel on the 22nd of October.108 The widening of the differential reflected the fact that while
global oil supplies were not affected by the strike, French refineries could not buy more crude oil which
resulted in less overall demand. Oil companies and physical traders holding more oil than originally
planned were forced to clear the ex-ante excess supply by offering larger discounts. Thus, in this episode,
the bulk of the adjustment took place through the changes in price differentials and not the price levels,
perhaps because the market thought the effects of the strike on the oil markets were only temporary.109

108
It is important to note also that there is a good chunk of term structure between prompt Dated Brent and the oil
deliverable under the nearest Brent futures contract.
109
Some consider that such evidence is a clear indication that it is the prompt physical that sets the futures price.
Such natural experiments however don‟t shed light on this issue. One needs to show that these adjustments in
differentials occur in other than crisis situations and they are strong enough to drag down the price level. More
importantly, such evidence doesn‟t provide an answer to the question of how the level of oil price is determined in
the first place. It reinforces the point, however, that the futures markets set the price level and the physical layers set
the differentials, which reflect changes in the underlying fundamentals of the oil market.

75
Figure 26: The North Sea Dated differential to Ice Brent during the French Strike

01 Sep 11 Sep 21 Sep 01 Oct 11 Oct 21 Oct


0.2

0.0 Ice Brent=0


-0.2
Strike
-0.4 officially
ends
-0.6
$/bl

-0.8
French refinery
-1.0 strike begins
-1.2

-1.4

-1.6

-1.8

Source: Argus

Thus, the level of oil price, which consumers, producers and their governments are most concerned with,
is not the most relevant feature in the current pricing system. Instead, the identification of price
differentials and the adjustments in these differentials in the various layers underlie the basis of the
current oil pricing system. If the price in the futures market becomes detached from prompt fundamentals,
the differentials adjust to correct for this divergence through a web of highly interlinked and efficient
markets. The key question is whether the adjustments in differentials are strong and large enough to
induce adjustments in the futures price level. The issues of whether price differentials between different
crude oil markets and between crude and product markets showed strong signs of adjustment and whether
those adjustments affected the behaviour of oil price over the 2008-2009 price cycle have not yet received
their due attention in the empirical literature.110
But this leaves us with a fundamental question: what factors determine the price level of an oil
benchmark? The crude oil pricing system and its components such as the PRAs reflect how the oil market
functions: if oil price levels are set in the futures market and if participants in these markets attach more
weight to future fundamentals rather than current fundamentals and/or if market participants expect
limited feedbacks from both the supply and demand side in response to oil price changes, these
expectations will be reflected in the different layers and will ultimately be reflected in the assessed price.
The adjustments in differentials are likely to ensure that these expectations remain anchored in the
physical dimension of the market.

Transparency and Accuracy of Information


The issue of transparency has gained wide credence in the aftermath of the 2008 financial crisis with
many organisations such as G8, G20, and the IEF calling for improved transparency as key to enhancing

110
In fact, one explanation attributes the upward rise in the crude oil price in the first half of 2008 to the high
demand for very-low-sulfur diesel (Verleger, 2008). This increased the price differential between diesel and crude
oil, which in turn pushed the crude oil price up. Such an explanation points to the importance of integrating products
into the analysis. Due to space constraints, products markets were not discussed in this paper, but are the subject of
current research at the Oxford Institute for Energy Studies.

76
the functioning of the oil market and its price discovery function. Transparency in oil markets however
has more the one dimension. Although improving transparency in the physical dimension of the market is
key to understanding oil market dynamics and enhancing the price discovery function, our analysis shows
that transparency in the financial layers surrounding the physical benchmarks is as important. In this
regards, it is important to emphasize three dimensions to the transparency issue. First, obtaining regular
and accurate information on key markets depends largely on the willingness of PRAs to release or share
information. PRAs are under no legal obligation to report deals to a regulatory authority or to make the
information at their disposal publicly available. Thus, some basic but key information and data on market
structure, trade volumes, liquidity, the players and their nature, and the degree of concentration in a
trading day are not always available to the public, but they are sold to market participants at a price which
makes it worthwhile for PRAs to collect such data.
Second, the degree of transparency varies considerably within the different layers in the Brent, WTI and
Dubai-Oman complexes as well as across benchmarks. Within the Brent complex, the degree of
transparency between the various layers such as the Forward Brent, CFD and Dated Brent and futures
market is different. Similarly, in the Dubai complex, basic data on the Dubai/Brent Swaps market or the
inter-month Dubai swaps are not publicly available though the volumes and open interest of Dubai swaps
cleared through the exchanges are published. Transparency in the futures markets at least when it comes
to prices, open interest and traded volumes is relatively well established. The futures market generates a
set of prices throughout the day which are instantaneously transmitted through a variety of channels
increasing price transparency. On the other hand, a detailed description of the participants in the futures
market and the identity of counterparties to a futures contract are not made publicly available although the
exchange and regulators via the exchange do have detailed data for futures markets on these areas. This is
in contrast to the OTC market where the identities of counterparties to a transaction are known. Some
market players place a high premium on such information and thus prefer to conduct their operations over
the counter.
The third dimension of transparency relates to the extent to which assessed prices are accurate and are
reached through a transparent and efficient process. There are two aspects to this issue. The first relates to
the structural features of the oil market trading which impose certain constraints on these agencies‟ efforts
to report deals and identify the oil price. As mentioned before, traders are under no obligation to report
prices; it is not always feasible to verify reported deals; in opaque and unregulated markets, PRAs may
need to rely on their evaluation of market conditions of specific crudes to reach an „intelligent‟ price
assessment. Thus, an important element of price transparency is the ability of PRAs to collect reliable
information in imperfect and often illiquid markets and analyse the information in an efficient and
objective manner. The second aspect is linked to the internal operations of PRAs. As discussed above, the
methodologies used to assess the oil price differ considerably across agencies. Their access to information
and the type of data used in their assessment process vary across PRAs and across markets. The
procedures applied within each of the organisations to ensure an efficient price discovery process differ as
these are internally driven and are not subject to external regulation or supervision. Thus, the degree of
price transparency is very much interlinked to the activities of PRAs and the reporting standards and other
procedures that they internally set and enforce.

77
9. Conclusions
Based on the above analysis of the current international crude oil pricing system, it is possible to draw the
following conclusions:

 Markets with relatively low volumes of production such as WTI, Brent, and Dubai-Oman set the
price for markets with higher volumes of production elsewhere in the world but with fewer or
none of the commonly accepted conditions to achieve an acceptable „benchmark‟ status. So far
the low and continuous decline in the physical base of existing benchmarks has been counteracted
by including additional crude streams in an assessed benchmark. Such short-term solutions
though successful in alleviating the problem of squeezes should not distract observers from some
key questions: What are the conditions necessary for the emergence of successful benchmarks in
the most liquid market? Would a shift to assessing price to these markets improve the price
discovery process? Such key questions remain heavily under-researched in the energy literature
and do not feature in the producer-consumer dialogue. The emergence of the non-OECD as the
main source of growth in global oil demand will only increase the importance of such questions.
Doubts about the suitability of Dubai as an appropriate benchmark for pricing crude oil exports to
Asia have been raised in the past (Horsnell and Mabro, 1993). This raises the question of whether
new benchmarks are needed to reflect more accurately the recent shift in trade flows and the rise
in importance of the Asian consumer.
 PRAs play an important role in assessing the price of the key international benchmarks. These
assessed prices are central to the oil pricing system and are used by oil companies and traders to
price cargoes under long-term contracts or in spot market transactions; by futures exchanges for
the settlement of their financial contracts; by banks and companies for the settlement of derivative
instruments such as swap contracts; and by governments for taxation purposes. PRAs do not only
act as „a mirror to the trade‟. In their attempt to identify the price, PRAs enter into the decision-
making territory. The decisions they make are influenced by market participants and market
structure while at the same time these decisions influence the trading strategies of the various
participants. New markets and contracts may emerge to hedge the risks that emerge from some of
the decisions that PRAs make. The accuracy of price assessments heavily depends on a large
number of factors including the quality of information obtained by the RPA, the internal
procedures applied by the PRAs and the methodologies used in price assessment.
 The assumption that the process of identifying the price of benchmarks in the current oil pricing
system can be isolated from financial layers is rather simplistic. The analysis in this report shows
that the different layers of the oil market are highly interconnected and form a complex web of
links, all of which play a role in the price discovery process. The information derived from
financial layers is essential for identifying the price level of the benchmark. One could argue that
without these financial layers it would not be possible to „discover‟ or „identify‟ oil prices in the
current oil pricing system. In effect, crude oil prices are jointly co-determined and identified in
both layers, depending on differences in timing, location and quality.

 Since physical benchmarks constitute the basis of the large majority of physical transactions,
some observers claim that derivatives instruments such as futures, forwards, options and swaps
derive their value from the price of these physical benchmarks i.e. the prices of these physical
benchmark drive the prices in paper markets. However, this is a gross over-simplification and
does not accurately reflect the process of crude oil price formation. The issue of whether the
paper market drives the physical or the other way around is difficult to construct theoretically and
test empirically in the context of the oil market.

78
 The report also calls for broadening the empirical research to include the trading strategies of
physical players. The fact remains though that the participants in many of the OTC markets such
as forward markets and CFDs which are central to the price discovery process are mainly
„physical‟ and include entities such as refineries, oil companies, downstream consumers, physical
traders, and market makers. Financial players such as pension funds and index investors have
limited presence in many of these markets. Thus, any analysis limited to non-commercial
participants in the futures market and their role in the oil price formation process is incomplete.

 The analysis in this report emphasises the distinction between trade in price differentials and trade
in price levels. We postulate that the level of the price of the main benchmarks is set in the futures
markets; the financial layers such as swaps and forwards set the price differentials depending on
quality, location and timing. These differentials are then used by oil reporting agencies to identify
the price level of a physical benchmark. If the price in the futures market becomes detached from
the underlying benchmark, the differentials adjust to correct for this divergence through a web of
highly interlinked and efficient markets. Thus, our analysis reveals that the level of oil price,
which consumers, producers and their governments are most concerned with, is not the most
relevant feature in the current pricing system. Instead, the identification of price differentials and
the adjustments in these differentials in the various layers underlie the basis of the current oil
pricing system. By trading differentials, market participants limit their exposure to risks of time,
location grade and volume. Unfortunately, this fact has received little attention and the issue of
whether price differentials between different markets showed strong signs of adjustment in the
2008-2009 price cycle has not yet received its due attention in the empirical literature.

 But this leaves us with a fundamental question: what factors determine the price level of an oil
benchmark in the first place? The crude oil pricing system and its components such as the PRAs
reflect how the oil market functions: if oil price levels are set in the futures market and if
participants in these markets attach more weight to future fundamentals rather than current
fundamentals and/or if market participants expect limited feedbacks from both the supply and
demand side in response to oil price changes, these expectations will be reflected in the different
layers and will ultimately be reflected in the assessed price. The adjustments in differentials are
likely to ensure that these expectations remain anchored in the physical dimension of the market.
 Transparency in oil markets has more than one dimension. Although improving transparency in
the physical dimension of the market is key to understanding oil market dynamics and enhancing
the price discovery function, our analysis shows that transparency in the financial layers
surrounding the physical benchmarks is as important. In this regards, it is important to emphasize
three dimensions to the transparency issue. First, obtaining regular and accurate information on
key markets is not straightforward and depends largely on the willingness of PRAs to release or
share information. Second, the degree of transparency varies considerably within the different
layers in the Brent, WTI and Dubai-Oman complexes as well as across benchmarks. The third
dimension of transparency relates to the extent assessed prices are accurate and are reached
through a transparent and efficient process. There are two aspects to this issue. The first aspect
relates to the structural features of the oil market trading which impose certain constraints on
these agencies‟ efforts to report deals and identify the oil price. The second aspect is linked to the
internal operations of PRAs. Thus, the degree of price transparency is very much interlinked to
the activities of PRAs and the reporting standards and other procedures that they internally set
and enforce.
The current oil pricing system has now survived for almost a quarter of a century, longer than the OPEC
administered system did. While some of the details have changed, such as Saudi Arabia‟s decision to
replace Dated Brent with Brent futures price in pricing its exports to Europe and the more recent move to
replace WTI with Argus Sour Crude Index (ASCI) in pricing its exports to the US, these changes are

79
rather cosmetic. The fundamentals of the current pricing system have remained the same since the mid
1980s i.e. the price of oil is set by the „market‟ with PRAs using various methodologies to reflect the
market price in their assessments and making use of information generated both in the physical and
financial layers surrounding the global benchmarks. In the light of the 2008-2009 price swings, the oil
pricing system has received some criticisms reflecting the unease that some observers feel with the
current system.111 Although alternative pricing systems can be devised (at least theoretical ones) such as
bringing back the administered pricing system or calling for producers to assume a greater responsibility
in the method of price formation by removing destination restrictions on their exports, or allowing their
crudes to be auctioned,112 the reality remains that the main market players such as oil companies,
refineries, oil exporting countries, physical traders and financial players have no interest in rocking the
boat. Market players and governments get very concerned about oil price behaviour and its global and
local impacts, but so far have showed much less interest in the pricing system and the market structure
that signalled such price behaviour in the first place.

111
See, for instance, Mabro (2008). Mabro argues that „the issue is whether the current price regime for oil in
international trade is an appropriate one. Nobody questions it because the vested interests in maintaining it are
extremely powerful. Banks and hedge funds are wedded to it. Some of the major oil companies have trading arms
that operate in these derivative markets like financial institutions. Their trading profits are substantial. OPEC
accepted it because they thought that it would protect them from blame. It didn‟t. And the question always asked is:
What is the alternative? I will simply say that no alternative will ever be found if nobody is looking for one.‟
112
See for instance, Luciani (2010).

80
References
Amuzegar, (1999), Managing the Oil Wealth: OPEC's Windfalls and Pitfalls, London: I.B. Tauris.
Argus (2007), „State of the Market Report: US Domestic Crude‟, Argus White Paper, Argus Media Ltd.
Argus (2009), „Argus US Crude Prices Explained‟, 24 September, Argus Media Ltd.
Argus (2010a), Argus Guide to Crude and Oil Products Markers, London: Argus Media Ltd.
Argus (2010b), Argus Sour Crude Index, White Paper, Argus Media ltd.
Argus Global Markets (2007), „Liquidity and Diversity Prevail‟, 24 September.
Bacon, R. (1986), „The Brent Market: An Analysis of Recent Developments. WPM 10‟, Oxford: Oxford
Institute for Energy Studies.
Barrera-Rey, F. and A. Seymour (1996), „The Brent Contract for Differences (CFD): A Study of an Oil
Trading Instrument, its Market and its Influence on the Behaviour of Oil Prices‟, SP5, Oxford: Oxford
Institute for Energy Studies.
Binks, A. (2005), „Middle East Crude Pricing: The Dubai Debate‟, Middle East Economic Survey, VOL.
XLVIII, No 7, 14-February.
Bossley, L. (2004) „BFO Futures to Be Affected By New Crude Streams, Warns CEAG‟, MEES,
XLVII(17), 26 April.
BP (2010), Statistical Review of World Energy 2010, London: BP.
Brunetti, C. and B. Buyuksahin (2009), Is speculation destabilizing?, CFTC Working Paper.
Buyuksahin, B., and M. A. Robe (2010), „Speculators, Commodities, and Cross-Market Linkages‟,
Working Paper, U.S. Commodity Futures Trading Commission.
Büyükşahin, B., M.S. Haigh and M.A. Robe (2010). „Commodities and Equities: Ever a „Market of
One‟?‟ Journal of Alternative Investments, 12 (3), pp. 75-95.
Commodity Futures Trading Commission (2008), Interagency Task Force on Commodity Markets
Interim Report on Crude Oil, Washington D.C., July.
Danielsen, A. (1982), The Evolution of OPEC, New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.
Demsetz, H. (1968), The Cost of Transacting. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 82: 33-53.
Fattouh, B. (2009), „Oil Market Dynamics through the Lens of the 2002-2009 Price Cycle„, OIES
WPM39, Oxford: Oxford Institute for Energy Studies.
Fesharaki, F. and Hassaan Vahidy (2001), „Middle East Crude Oil Trade and Formula Pricing,‟ Middle
East Economic Survey (MEES) 44(43), October.
Gorton, G. and G. Rouwenhorst (2004), „Facts and Fantasies about Commodity Futures,‟ NBER Working
Papers 10595, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
Horsnell, P. (2000), „Oil Pricing Systems‟, Oxford Energy Comment, Oxford Institute for Energy Studies,
May.
Horsnell, P. and R. Mabro (1993), Oil Markets and Prices: The Brent Market and the Formation of World
Oil Prices, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
IMF (2008), World Economic Outlook (October), Washington: International Monetary Fund.
IOSCO (2010), Task Force on Commodity Futures Markets: Report to the G20, November.

81
Jalali-Naini, A.R. (2009), The Impact of Financial Markets on the Price of Oil and Volatility:
Developments since 2007, OPEC Secretariat, Research Division, April.
Kilian, L. and Murphy, D. (2010), „The Role of Inventories and Speculative Trading in the Global Market
for Crude Oil‟, CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP7753.
Leaver, T. (2010), DME-Oman: Transparent Pricing and Effective Risk Management in a New Era,
Presentation at the Asia Oil and Gas Conference, Kuala Lumpur, June.
Lobo, G. and J. Zhou (2006), „Did Conservatism in Financial Reporting Increase after the Sarbanes-Oxley
Act? Initial Evidence, Accounting Horizons, Vol. 20, No.1, pp. 57-73.
Luciani, G. (2010) „From Price Taker to Price Maker? Saudi Arabia and the World Oil Market‟,
Rahmania Foundation Occasional Papers.
Mabro, R. (1984) „On Oil Price Concepts‟, WPM3, Oxford: Oxford Institute for Energy Studies.
Mabro, R. (1986), „The Netback Pricing System and the Price Collapse of 1986‟, WPM 10, Oxford:
Oxford Institute for Energy Studies.
Mabro, R. (1998), „The Oil Price Conundrum‟, Oxford Energy Forum, Issue 74, August.
Mabro, R. (2000), „Oil Markets and Prices‟, Oxford Institute for Energy Studies, Oxford Energy
Comment, August.
Mabro, R. (2005), „The International Oil Price Regime: Origins, Rationale, and Assessment‟, The Journal
Of Energy Literature, XI(1).
Mabro, R. et al (ed.) (1986), The Market for North Sea Oil, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Mollgaard, H.P. (1997), „A Squeezer Round the Corner? Self-Regulation and Forward Markets‟, The
Economic Journal, 107(440):104−12.
Montepeque, J. (2005), „Sour Crude Pricing: A Pressing Global Issue‟, Middle East Economic Survey,
XLVIII(14), April.
Newbery, D.M.G. (1984), „The Manipulation of Futures Markets by a Dominant Producer‟, Chapter 2 in
Anderson, R.W. (ed.), The Industrial Organization of Futures Markets (Lexington, MA: Lexington
Books).
O'Hara, M. (1997). Market Microstructure Theory. UK:Blackwell.
Parra, F. (2004), Oil Politics: A Modern History of Petroleum, London: IB Tauris.
Penrose, E. (1968), The Large International Firm in Developing Countries: The International Petroleum
Industry, USA: Greenwood Press.
Pirrong, S. (1996), The Economics, Law and Public Policy of Market Power Manipulation, Boston, MA:
Kluwer.
Platts (2004), „Review of the Partial Dubai and Oman Price Discovery Mechanism‟, Platts Discussion
Paper, November. Downloadable from: http://www.platts.com/Oil/Resources/Market%20Issues/
Platts (2010 a) Methodology and Specifications Guide: Crude Oil. The McGraw Hill Companies,
October.
Platts (2010 b), Platts Oil Pricing and MOC Methodology Explained. The McGraw Hill Companies,
June.
Purvin & Gertz (2010), The Role of WTI as a Crude Oil Benchmark, January.

82
Rehaag, K. (1999), „Disappearing Benchmarks: The Demise of the Market Indexed Pricing?‟, IEA
Energy Prices and Taxes, 4th Quarter, downloadable from:
http://data.iea.org/ieastore/assets/products/eptnotes/feature/4Q1999.pdf
Seymour, A. (1990), „The Oil Price and Non-OPEC Supply‟, Oxford Institute for Energy Studies.
Silvennoinen, A., and S. Thorp (2010), „Financialization, Crisis and Commodity Correlation Dynamics‟,
Research Paper Series 267, Quantitative Finance Research Centre, University of Technology, Sydney.
Skeet, I. (1988), OPEC: Twenty Five Years of Prices and Politics, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Soligo, R. and A. Jaffe (2000), „A Note on Saudi Arabia Price Discrimination‟, Energy Journal,
21(1):31−60.
Stevens, P. (1985), „ A Survey of Structural Change in the International Oil Industry 1945-1984‟, in
David Hawdon (ed.), The Changing Structure of the World Oil Industry, USA: Croom Helm Ltd.
Tang, Ke and Wei Xiong. (2010), „Index Investing and the Financialization of Commodities‟, NBER
Working Paper 16385, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
Telser, L.G. (1992), „Corners in Organized Futures Market‟, in Aggregation, Consumption and Trade:
Essays in Honour of H.S. Houththaker (eds. L.Phlips and L.D. Taylor), Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic
Publishers.
Terzian, P. (1985), OPEC: The Inside Story, London: Zed Books.
Thorne, S. (2010), „A User guide to Platts Assessment Processes‟, Presentation at the Platts Crude Oil
Methodology Forum 2010, London, May.
Verleger (2008), „Explaining the 2008 Crude Oil Price Rise‟, July, downloadable from:
http://www.pkverlegerllc.com/TIE0807.PDF
Yergin, D. (2009) ‘It's Still the One’, Foreign Policy, Sept/October.

83
Analysis of Renewable Identification
Numbers (RINs) in the Renewable Fuel
Standard (RFS)

Brent D. Yacobucci
Section Research Manager

November 16, 2012

Congressional Research Service


7-5700
www.crs.gov
R42824
CRS Report for Congress
Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress
Analysis of RINs in the RFS

Summary
The federal Renewable Fuel Standard (RFS) was established in the Energy Policy Act of 2005
(EPAct) and significantly expanded in the Energy Independence and Security Act of 2007 (EISA).
The RFS requires the use of renewable biofuels in transportation fuel. For 2012, the RFS requires
the use of 15.2 billion gallons of renewable fuel. Within the larger mandate, there are sub-
mandates (“carve-outs”) for advanced biofuels, including at least 1 billion gallons of biomass-
based diesel fuel (BBD) in 2012. By 2022, the RFS requires the use of 36 billion gallons of
renewable fuels, including 21 billion gallons of advanced biofuels.

The RFS is a market-based compliance system in which obligated parties (generally refiners
and/or terminal operators) must submit credits to cover their obligations. These credits—
Renewable Identification Numbers, or RINs—are effectively commodities that can be bought or
sold like other commodities. For each gallon of renewable fuel in the RFS program, one RIN is
generated. Each RIN is a 38-digit number, with blocks of digits corresponding to various data,
including the year the RIN was generated, the producer of the fuel, and the type of fuel. RINs are
valid for use in the year they are generated and the following year.

From the beginning of the RFS program, there have been concerns with RIN generation and the
RIN market. As the RINs are essentially numbers in a computerized account, there have been
errors and opportunities for fraud. Because of concerns over transposed digits, invalid characters,
allegations of double-counting (intentional or unintentional) and other errors and inaccuracies,
when EPA finalized rules for the RFS as expanded by EISA (the “RFS2”), EPA also established a
new in-house trading system in an effort to address these concerns. All RIN transactions must be
cleared through this in-house system, called the EPA Moderated Transaction System (EMTS).
From the beginning of the RFS2 EPA has maintained that all due diligence remains the duty of
obligated parties. Under this “buyer beware” system those purchasing or receiving RINs must
certify their validity on their own, and they are responsible for any fraudulent RINs they pass on
to other buyers or submit to EPA for compliance.

In late 2011 and early 2012, EPA issued Notices of Violations (NOVs) to three companies that the
agency alleges fraudulently generated a combined 140 million biodiesel RINs in 2010 and 2011.
Because of these RIN fraud cases, EPA is looking at establishing a system whereby RINs can be
certified by third parties registered with EPA. (EPA may be considering other options but this is
the only one the agency has publicly discussed.) EPA is considering whether such certification
would provide obligated parties with an “affirmative defense” if RINs are later found to
fraudulent—that is, obligated parties would not be liable for penalties under the Clean Air Act for
the use of such RINs. Key questions include whether such an affirmative defense would also
eliminate the requirement to purchase make-up RINs. EPA expects to issue a proposed rule in late
2012 or early 2013, with a final rule some time in mid-2013.

In addition to agency action, at least one bill has been introduced that would amend the
compliance system. H.R. 6444 would require EPA to establish a RIN certification system and
would preclude the agency from later invalidating any certified RINs. Thus, under the bill, any
RIN found subsequently to be fraudulent would still count toward an obligated party’s
compliance, without penalties.

Congressional Research Service


Analysis of RINs in the RFS

Contents
Introduction...................................................................................................................................... 1
Current RFS Requirements .............................................................................................................. 1
The Role of RINs ............................................................................................................................. 3
RINs........................................................................................................................................... 4
EPA Moderated Transaction System (EMTS) ........................................................................... 4
The Market for RINs........................................................................................................................ 6
RIN Prices ................................................................................................................................. 6
RIN Volumes ............................................................................................................................. 8
Fraudulent RINs............................................................................................................................. 11
Effects on Obligated Parties .................................................................................................... 11
Quality Assurance Program ..................................................................................................... 11
Policy Options ......................................................................................................................... 12
Additional Questions ............................................................................................................... 13
What Other Types of RIN Fraud Are Possible? ................................................................ 14
How Likely Is RIN Fraud in the Future? .......................................................................... 14
How Do Various Players Benefit from the Different Policy Options? .............................. 15
Conclusion ..................................................................................................................................... 15

Figures
Figure 1. Nested RFS Mandates for 2012........................................................................................ 3
Figure 2. Simplified Schematic of RIN Trading System ................................................................. 5
Figure 3. Spot Renewable Fuel (Corn Ethanol) RIN Prices ............................................................ 7
Figure 4. Spot BBD RIN Prices ....................................................................................................... 7
Figure 5. Spot Advanced Biofuel RIN Prices .................................................................................. 8
Figure 6. Total RINs Registered 2011.............................................................................................. 9
Figure 7. Total RINs Registered 2012 YTD .................................................................................... 9
Figure 8. Estimated Aggregate RIN Value for 2011 ...................................................................... 10
Figure 9. Estimated Aggregate RIN Value for 2012 YTD ............................................................. 10

Contacts
Author Contact Information........................................................................................................... 16

Congressional Research Service


Analysis of RINs in the RFS

Introduction
The Energy Policy Act of 2005 (EPAct, P.L. 109-58) established a renewable fuel standard (RFS),
requiring the use of biofuels (such as ethanol) in the nation’s fuel supply. The Energy
Independence and Security Act of 2007 (EISA, P.L. 110-140) significantly expanded this
mandate.1 The RFS mandate has been a major impetus to the development of U.S. biofuels
industries, especially the ethanol and biodiesel industries. In 2005, the United States produced 3.9
billion gallons of ethanol and 0.1 billion gallons of biodiesel. In 2011, production had increased
to roughly 14 billion gallons of ethanol and 1 billion gallons of biodiesel.

Covered parties meet their obligations under the RFS by surrendering renewable fuel credits to
EPA equal to the number of gallons in their annual obligation. These credits, known as
Renewable Identification Numbers (RINs), are generated when a batch of biofuel is produced,
and separated from the fuel by obligated parties (generally gasoline and diesel fuel refiners or
blenders). Once separated, these RINs may be traded like other commodities. Recent civil and
criminal action against parties accused of registering and selling fraudulent RINs has raised
questions about the integrity of the RIN market and EPA’s oversight of the market.

This report outlines the RFS and the current RIN system, discusses the current market for various
RINs, and outlines policy considerations to address RIN fraud going forward.

Current RFS Requirements


Currently, the RFS requires the blending of 15.2 billion gallons of renewable fuel in
transportation fuels in 2012, including at least 1 billion gallons of biomass-based diesel
substitutes (BBD). The RFS increases to 36 billion gallons by 2022 with an increasing share
coming from “advanced biofuels”—biofuels produced from feedstocks other than corn starch—
including cellulosic biofuel and BBD fuels. As has been the case in previous years, in 2012 the
vast majority of the mandate is expected to be met with U.S. corn ethanol (and a smaller amount
of biodiesel, as well as sugarcane ethanol from Brazil).

By 2015 corn ethanol’s share of the RFS is effectively capped at 15 billion gallons per year. The
EISA amendments to the RFS specifically mandate the use of cellulosic biofuel (16 billion
gallons by 2022) and biomass-based diesel fuel (at least 1.0 billion gallons annually by 2012).
However, advanced biofuels, especially cellulosic fuels, have been slow to develop and fuel
production lags the EISA’s mandate schedule.2

Within the overall RFS mandate, there are sub-mandates for specific types of fuel. For example,
for 2012 EISA requires the use of 15.2 billion gallons of biofuels, of which 2.0 billion must be
“advanced biofuels.” Within the advanced biofuel carve-out, at least 1.0 billion gallons must be
biomass-based diesel (BBD) fuels and 0.00865 billion gallons must be produced from cellulosic
feedstocks. In the early years of the program, the lion’s share of the mandate is unspecified, and

1
For more information on the RFS, see CRS Report R40155, Renewable Fuel Standard (RFS): Overview and Issues,
by Randy Schnepf and Brent D. Yacobucci.
2
See CRS Report R41106, Meeting the Renewable Fuel Standard (RFS) Mandate for Cellulosic Biofuels: Questions
and Answers, by Kelsi Bracmort.

Congressional Research Service 1


Analysis of RINs in the RFS

the vast majority of this unspecified portion has been—and is expected to be—supplied by corn-
based ethanol largely produced in the Midwest. At the beginning of each year, EPA determines a
percentage standard that all suppliers must meet, which is based on expected total U.S. gasoline
and diesel demand for the prior year. For example, for 2012, the overall biofuel standard is
9.23%, the advanced biofuel standard is 1.21%, the BBD standard is 0.91%, and the cellulosic
biofuel standard is 0.006%.3

The sub-mandates for advanced biofuels are nested together (Figure 1). As noted by the arrows in
the figure, fuel qualifying as one type of biofuel in the RFS qualifies for all levels above it. For
example, a gallon of cellulosic biofuel may be used to meet the cellulosic mandate, the advanced
biofuel mandate, and the overall RFS. A gallon of other advanced biofuel (e.g., sugarcane
ethanol) may be used to meet the advanced biofuel mandate and the overall mandate, but may not
be used to meet the cellulosic or BBD mandates. Corn starch ethanol—the most widely used
biofuel in the United States—may only be used to meet the overall RFS.4

3
The limitation on corn starch ethanol is roughly 8% on gasoline and diesel fuel combined.
4
Thus, the effective cap on corn-based ethanol is 13.2 billion gallons in 2012, based on the difference between the
overall mandate (15.2 billion gallons) and the advanced biofuel mandate (2.0 billion gallons).

Congressional Research Service 2


Analysis of RINs in the RFS

Figure 1. Nested RFS Mandates for 2012


(Not to scale)

Total Renewable Fuel


(15.2 Bgal)

Advanced Biofuel (2 Bgal)

Biomass-Based Cellulosic Biofuel


Diesel (BBD) (1 Bgal) (8.6 Mgal)

Source: CRS.
Notes: As noted by the arrows, fuel qualifying as one type of biofuel in the RFS qualifies for all levels above it.
For example, cellulosic biofuel may also be used to meet the advanced biofuel mandate and the overall RFS
mandate. However, non-cellulosic advanced biofuel (e.g., sugarcane ethanol) may not be used to meet the
cellulosic or BBD mandates. Likewise, corn starch ethanol may only be used to meet the total RFS mandate (and
not the advanced, cellulosic, or BBD mandates).

The Role of RINs


Compliance with the RFS is measured using RINs. When qualifying biofuels are produced, each
gallon is assigned a RIN. Until the biofuels are sold as fuel or blended into conventional fuels, the
RINs are “attached” to the fuel. Once the biofuel has been blended or sold, the RINs are detached,
and can then be bought and sold like other commodities. At the end of each year, fuel suppliers
must multiply the above percentage standards by their total gasoline and diesel sales to calculate
their renewable volume obligations (RVO), which indicate the total number of each type of RIN
that the suppliers must submit to EPA. To the extent that a supplier has excess RINs, that supplier
may sell them to others who may be short, or save them for use in the following year.

Congressional Research Service 3


Analysis of RINs in the RFS

RINs
A RIN is a unique 38-character number that is issued (in accordance with EPA guidelines) by the
biofuel producer or importer at the point of biofuel production or the port of importation.5 Each
qualifying gallon of renewable fuel has its own unique RIN. RINs are generally assigned by
batches of renewable fuel production. (See box at right.)

Under the RFS2 RIN formulation, Code D RIN Codes


identifies which of the four RFS categories— RIN=KYYYYCCCCFFFFFBBBBBRRDSSSSSSSSEEEEEEEE
total, advanced, cellulosic, or biodiesel—the Where
biofuel satisfies. Together, SSSSSSSS and
EEEEEEEE identify the RIN block which K = code distinguishing RINs still assigned to a
gallon from RINs already separated
demarcates the number of gallons of
renewable fuel that the batch represents in the YYYY = the calendar year of production or import
context of compliance with the RFS—that is, CCCC = the company ID
RIN gallons. The RIN-gallon total equals the FFFFF = the company plant or facility ID
product of the liquid volume of renewable fuel
times its energy equivalence value (relative to BBBBB = the batch number
a gallon of ethanol). For example, because RR = the biofuel energy equivalence value
biodiesel has an equivalence value (EV) of 1.5 D = the renewable fuel category
when being used as an advanced biofuel,
SSSSSSSS = the start number for this batch of biofuel
1,000 gallons of biodiesel would equal 1,500
6
RIN gallons of advanced biofuels. If the RIN EEEEEEEE= the end number for this batch of biofuel
block start for that batch was 1 (i.e.,
SSSSSSSS = 00000001), then the end value (EEEEEEEE) would be 00001000, and the RR code
would be RR = 15.

Any party that owns RINs at any point during the year (including domestic and foreign
producers; refiners and blenders; exporters and importers of renewable fuels; and RIN traders)
must register with the EPA and follow RIN record-keeping and reporting guidelines. RINs can
only be generated if it can be established that the feedstock from which the fuel was made meets
EISA’s definitions of renewable biomass, including land-use restrictions. The feedstock
affirmation and record-keeping requirements apply to RINs generated by both domestic
renewable fuel producers and RIN-generating foreign renewable fuel producers or importers.

EPA Moderated Transaction System (EMTS)


All RIN transactions, including generation, trade/sale/transfer, separation, and retirement, must be
cleared through the EMTS. When biofuels change ownership (e.g., are sold by a producer to a

5
For more discussion on RINs see Robert Wisner, “Renewable Identification Numbers (RINs) and Government
Biofuels Blending Mandates,” AgMRC Renewable Energy Newsletter, Agricultural Marketing Research Center, Iowa
State University, April 2009, available at http://www.agmrc.org/renewable_energy/
agmrc_renewable_energy_newsletter.cfm; or Wyatt Thompson, Seth Meyer, and Pat Westhoff, “Renewable
Identification Numbers are the Tracking Instrument and Bellwether of U.S. Biofuel Mandates,” EuroChoices 8(3),
2009, pp. 43-50.
6
Unlike the other biofuel categories, the BBD mandate is a requirement on actual gallons. Thus, the 1.0 billion (actual)
gallons required for the 2012 BBD mandate will generate 1.0 billion BBD RINs, but 1.5 billion advanced
biofuel/renewable fuel RINs.

Congressional Research Service 4


Analysis of RINs in the RFS

blender), any attached RINs are also transferred.7 The Code K status of the RIN is changed at
separation (generally when the fuel is sold from a biofuel producer to an obligated party). (See
Figure 2.)

As noted by EPA in the rule establishing the RFS2 and the EMTS, EPA views the EMTS solely as
a “screening” system, and all due diligence remains the duty of obligated parties.8 Under this
“buyer beware”9 system those purchasing or receiving RINs must certify their validity on their
own, and they are responsible for any fraudulent RINs they pass on to other buyers or submit to
EPA for compliance.

Figure 2. Simplified Schematic of RIN Trading System

Biofuel Producer /
Importer

Attached
RINs
Secondary
EMTS
Market

Renewable
Fuel Separated
RINs Retirement

Obligated Parties (Gasoline & Diesel


Refiners, Blenders, Importers)

Retail Sale

Source: CRS, based on Rakesh Radhakrishnan, Market Considerations—RECs and RINs Overlap, Thompson
Reuters, September 25, 2012, p. 8, http://www.renewableenergymarkets.com/docs/presentations/2012/
Radhakrishnan.pdf.

7
In many cases, the RINs are detached from the actual fuel at the point of initial sale or transfer, and thus RINs may be
detached for fuel that has not yet been blended into motor fuel or sold as motor fuel.
8
EPA, “Regulation of Fuels and Fuel Additives: Changes to Renewable Fuel Standard Program; Final Rule,” 75
Federal Register 14732, March 26, 2010.
9
Ibid., p. 14733.

Congressional Research Service 5


Analysis of RINs in the RFS

Notes: Black lines indicate RINs attached to actual biofuel gallons. Solid blue lines indicate separated RINs that
may be traded among all market participants. Dashed blue line indicates end-of-year submission of RINs by
obligated parties to EPA to meet RFS mandates. Green lines indicate actual biofuel gallons separated from RINs.
Orange lines indicate that all RIN transactions must be cleared through EMTS.

The Market for RINs

RIN Prices
Because RINs may be bought and sold as commodities, there are RIN spot markets. However,
these spot markets may only provide some insight into the actual value of the total pool of RINs
in a given year, as RINs may or may not be traded after they are detached by fuel suppliers.
Because RINs are not completely fungible, their values may or may not be affected by the
markets for other RINs. For example, RINs for conventional ethanol may only be used for the
overall (unspecified) renewable fuel mandate. However, biodiesel RINs may be used to meet the
BBD, advanced biofuel, and/or overall RVOs.

It should also be noted that unlike other commodities, RINs generally may only be used in the
year they are generated or for one additional year, although suppliers may only meet up to 20% of
their current-year obligation with the previous year’s RINs. Thus, RIN values diminish over time
and ultimately have no value in the second year after they are generated.

As there has generally been an excess of corn ethanol (beyond what is allowed for meeting the
unspecified portion of the RFS) in the U.S. market, ethanol RINs have generally traded at much
lower prices than other RINs—generally between one and four cents per gallon, as opposed to a
dollar per gallon or more for other fuels. (See Figure 3, Figure 4, and Figure 5.) Because much
of the advanced biofuel mandate is met using BBD RINs, the advanced biofuel RIN price follows
the BBD RIN price closely when adjusted for energy content. For example, when BBD RIN
prices spiked in September 2011 (Figure 4), advanced biofuel RINs showed a similar spike
(Figure 5); there was no spike at that time in corn ethanol RINs (Figure 3). Similarly, BBD and
advanced biofuel RIN prices dropped in the second half of 2012 (apparently driven by concerns
over the validity of biodiesel RINs), while ethanol RIN prices increased as the 2012 drought
raised concerns over U.S. corn production and its effects on ethanol production.

Congressional Research Service 6


Analysis of RINs in the RFS

Figure 3. Spot Renewable Fuel (Corn Ethanol) RIN Prices

$0.05

$0.04
Price per Gallon

$0.03

$0.02

$0.01

$0.00
1-Jan-11 11-Apr-11 20-Jul-11 28-Oct-11 5-Feb-12 15-May-12 23-Aug-12
2012 2011

Source: “Ethanol and Gasoline Component Spot Market Prices,” OPIS Ethanol & Biodiesel Information Service,
various editions (January 10, 2011-October 29, 2012).
Notes: Weekly average prices for weeks when data are available. The years in the legend refer to the year the
RINs were originally generated. For example, a “2011” RIN was generated some time in calendar year 2011, and
generally may only be used for compliance with the 2011 or 2012 standards. Most biofuels are sold under
contract, and thus spot prices may not reflect the value of all RINs traded at any given time.

Figure 4. Spot BBD RIN Prices

$2.50

$2.00
Price per Gallon

$1.50

$1.00

$0.50

$0.00
1-Jan-11 11-Apr-11 20-Jul-11 28-Oct-11 5-Feb-12 15-May-12 23-Aug-12
2012 2011

Source: “Ethanol and Gasoline Component Spot Market Prices,” OPIS Ethanol & Biodiesel Information Service,
various editions (January 10, 2011-October 29, 2012).
Notes: Weekly average prices for weeks when data are available. The years in the legend refer to the year the
RINs were originally generated. For example, a “2011” RIN was generated some time in calendar year 2011, and
generally may only be used for compliance with the 2011 or 2012 standards. Most biofuels are sold under
contract, and thus spot prices may not reflect the value of all RINs traded at any given time.

Congressional Research Service 7


Analysis of RINs in the RFS

Figure 5. Spot Advanced Biofuel RIN Prices

$1.40

$1.20

$1.00
Price per Gallon

$0.80

$0.60

$0.40

$0.20

$0.00
1-Jan-11 11-Apr-11 20-Jul-11 28-Oct-11 5-Feb-12 15-May-12 23-Aug-12
2012 2011

Source: “Ethanol and Gasoline Component Spot Market Prices,” OPIS Ethanol & Biodiesel Information Service,
various editions (January 10, 2011-October 29, 2012).
Notes: Weekly average prices for weeks when data are available. The years in the legend refer to the year the
RINs were originally generated. For example, a “2011” RIN was generated some time in calendar year 2011, and
generally may only be used for compliance with the 2011 or 2012 standards. Unlike ethanol and BBD RINs, OPIS
only tracks prices for current-year advanced biofuel RINs. Most biofuels are sold under contract, and thus spot
prices may not reflect the value of all RINs traded at any given time.

RIN Volumes
The market for RINs is potentially very large, although the amount of RIN trading that occurs is
unclear. Although EPA reports total RINs registered by month, and the EMTS tracks trades and
RIN prices, EPA does not report these data. Likewise, publicly available data from other sources
are similarly limited.10 Figure 6 and Figure 7 show total RINs registered for 2011 and 2012
(through September). As noted above, by volume the RFS is dominated by ethanol produced from
corn starch. However, based on RIN value (multiplying yearly RIN volumes by average RIN
prices for the year), BBD RINs represented over 70% of the market in 2011 and 2012 (Figure 8
and Figure 9).

10
For example, OPIS reports daily RIN spot prices for four types of RINs, but does not report trading volume.

Congressional Research Service 8


Analysis of RINs in the RFS

Figure 6.Total RINs Registered 2011 Figure 7.Total RINs Registered 2012 YTD
Biomass-Based Advanced
Advanced Biomass-Based
Diesel Biofuel
2011 Biofuel
Jan.-Sept. 2012
1.09 billion Diesel 0.32 billion
0.23 billion 0.90 billion
7% 3%
2% 8%

Ethanol Ethanol
13.6 billion 9.8 billion
91% 89%

Source: EPA, EPA Moderated Transaction System (EMTS). Source: EPA, EPA Moderated Transaction System (EMTS).

CRS-9
Analysis of RINs in the RFS

Figure 8. Estimated Aggregate RIN Value for 2011 Figure 9. Estimated Aggregate RIN Value for 2012 YTD

2011 Jan.-Sept. 2012

Advanced Advanced Ethanol


Biofuel Ethanol Biofuel $0.21 billion
$0.16 billion $0.22 billion
$0.37 billion 13%
8% 19% 14%

Biomass-Based
Biomass-Based Diesel
Diesel $1.18 billion
$1.38 billion 73%
73%

Source: CRS Analysis of data from EPA and OPIS. Source: CRS Analysis of data from EPA and OPIS.
Notes: Aggregate value based on total RIN volume for 2011, multiplied by the Notes: Aggregate value based on total RIN volume for 2012 YTD, multiplied by
mean of weekly average RIN prices reported by OPIS for 2011 ($0.027 for the mean of weekly average RIN prices reported by OPIS for January 2012
ethanol RINs, $1.26 for BBD RINs, and $0.71 for advanced biofuel RINs). through September 2012 ($0.021 for ethanol RINs, $1.32 for BBD RINs, and
$0.70 for advanced biofuel RINs).

CRS-10
Analysis of RINs in the RFS

Fraudulent RINs
As noted above, in late 2011 and early 2012, EPA issued Notices of Violations (NOVs) to three
companies (Clean Green Fuels, LLC, Absolute Fuels, LLC, and Green Diesel, LLC) that the
agency alleges fraudulently generated a combined 140 million biodiesel RINs in 2010 and 2011.11
Subsequently, individuals representing two of these companies have also faced criminal
prosecution.12 Because these investigations involve potentially criminal actions, EPA has limited
the amount of information available to traders and obligated parties who may have purchased
fraudulent RINs. Thus, it is unclear whether any other NOVs will be issued in the future.

The 140 million fraudulent RINs from the three NOVs represent roughly 11% of the biodiesel
RINs generated between mid-2010 and the end of 2011, but less than 1% of the total RINs
generated—as noted above, ethanol produced from corn starch currently dominates the RFS.
However, as noted above, biodiesel RINs trade at considerably higher prices than ethanol RINs.
Thus, the fraudulent RINs represent roughly 8% of the aggregate market value for that time.13

Effects on Obligated Parties


In the regulations establishing the RFS2 and the EMTS, EPA specifically stated that “invalid
RINs cannot be used to achieve compliance with the Renewable Volume Obligations (RVO) of an
obligated party or exporter, regardless of the party’s good faith belief that the RINs were valid at
the time they were aquired.”14 Because of the “buyer beware” nature of the system, obligated
parties who purchased the fraudulent RINs must pay fines for each RIN submitted (EPA and the
companies have generally settled at about $0.10 per RIN), and must submit valid RINs to offset
the fraudulent RINs. Thus, the combined economic costs to the obligated parties may include:
1. the original cost of the fraudulent RINs (spot prices ranged between $0.70 and
$2.00 per RIN over that time);
2. penalties to EPA for Clean Air Act violations ($0.10 per RIN, capped at $350,000
per party);
3. the cost of all make-up RINs (currently trading at roughly $0.50 per gallon); and
4. any legal costs in pursuing restitution from fraudulent actors.

Quality Assurance Program


Because of these RIN fraud cases, EPA is looking at establishing a quality assurance program
whereby RINs can be certified by third parties registered with EPA. EPA intends that such

11
EPA, Civil Enforcement of the Renewable Fuel Standard Program, October 18, 2012, http://www.epa.gov/
enforcement/air/renewable-fuels/fuel-novs.html.
12
On June 25, 2012, Rodney R. Hailey of Clean Green Fuels, LLC was found guilty of 8 counts of wire fraud, 32
counts of money laundering, and 2 counts of violating the Clean Air Act. On August 8, 2012, a Federal Grand Jury
indicted David Gunselman of Absolute Fuels, LLC on wire fraud, money laundering, and violating the Clean Air Act.
13
140 million RINs represent 11% of the BBD market. 11% x 73% (aggregate market share for BBD RINs) = 8% .
14
40 C.F.R. §80.1431(b)(2).

Congressional Research Service 11


Analysis of RINs in the RFS

certification would provide obligated parties with an “affirmative defense” if RINs are later found
to fraudulent—that is, obligated parties would not be liable for civil penalties under the Clean Air
Act for the use of such RINs. As noted by Gina McCarthy, EPA Assistant Administrator for Air
and Radiation, “the affirmative defense would ensure that refiners and other program participants
who meet the conditions of the affirmative defense will not face civil penalties.”15

A key component of a Quality Assurance Program would be the establishment of a quality


assurance plan (QAP). The QAP would serve as the basis for audits by third party verifiers
certified by EPA. However, while EPA has issued draft requirements of what might be included in
a QAP, EPA has not issued proposed rules.16 According to various comments by the agency, EPA
expects to issue a proposal by the end of 2012, with a final rule some time in 2013.

Key questions include whether such an affirmative defense would also eliminate the requirement
to purchase make-up RINs. While refiners and others would prefer to not “pay twice” for RINs,
in general biofuel producers argue that not making up the RINs would undermine the legitimate
RIN market. Simply put, if obligated parties are not required to replace invalid RINs with valid
RINs, the size of the legitimate renewable fuel market is reduced.

Policy Options
There are various policy options to address the issues of RIN fraud. EPA could undertake some of
these under existing Clean Air Act authority, while others would require congressional action. In
general terms, there are at least four options:
1. Do nothing, and let market participants determine the credibility of actors they
trade with;
2. Establish a Quality Assurance Program or some other certification to provide
greater credibility, but do not tie it to EPA’s determination on RIN validity;
3. Establish a certification procedure with an affirmative defense such that
purchasers of invalid RINs are not liable for civil penalties; and
4. Establish a system where all certified RINs are valid for RFS compliance
regardless of subsequent determination that they are fraudulent or otherwise
deficient.
Currently, RIN market participants are acting under the first option. They are independently
determining whether to trust the validity of the RINs they purchase. In many cases, obligated
parties have decided to purchase biodiesel and biodiesel RINs only from the largest producers.17
At the same time, small producers have complained that they are unable to afford the verification
procedures that some obligated parties now require. Others have argued that the RIN fraud
prosecutions have improved the integrity of the market. For example, one witness to a House

15
Letter from Gina McCarthy, Assistant Administrator for Air and Radiation, EPA, to The Honorable Gene Green,
Ranking Member, Ranking Member Subcommittee on Energy and Economy, Committee on Energy and Commerce,
August 14, 2012.
16
EPA, Public Release of Draft Quality Assurance Plan Requirements, EPA-420-B-12-063, Washington, DC, October
31, 2012, http://www.epa.gov/otaq/fuels/renewablefuels/documents/420b12063.pdf.
17
Testimony of various biofuel companies before the House Committee on Energy and Commerce Hearing on “RIN
Fraud: EPA’s Efforts to Ensure Market Integrity in the Renewable Fuels Program.” July 11, 2012.

Congressional Research Service 12


Analysis of RINs in the RFS

Energy and Commerce Committee hearing on RIN fraud stated “[i]n essence, the Wild West of
buying and selling RINs from market participants you don’t know has ended, the wrongdoers are
being rooted out, and everyone now knows that deals that are too good to be true are in fact too
good to be true.”18

Because of substantial remaining uncertainty about the integrity of the market, the National
Biodiesel Board (NBB) and others are working to establish a more formal process for RIN
certification. With the NBB, biodiesel producers have established a RIN Integrity Network where
obligated parties can subscribe to a service where they can receive information on participating
biodiesel producers.19 This and similar efforts are in their early stages, and it is unclear how much
credence RIN purchasers will give these networks. Further, it is unclear whether they will become
the industry standard.

EPA is currently pursuing the third option, where a Quality Assurance Program is established with
third parties auditing RIN generators. In its public communications, EPA has stated that the
agency plans to offer an affirmative defense such that users of certified RINs would not be
subject to civil penalties under the Clean Air Act. It is unclear whether an obligated party would
be required to purchase additional RINs to make up for any certified RINs later found to be
fraudulent. Obligated parties generally would prefer not to “pay twice” for RINs, adding to their
compliance costs. However, eliminating this requirement would effectively shrink the market for
biofuels under the RFS, harming legitimate biofuel producers. As EISA establishes specific fuel
volume requirements, it is unclear whether EPA has the authority under existing statute to waive
that requirement.

In addition to agency action, at least one bill has been introduced that would amend the RIN
system. H.R. 6444 would require EPA to establish a RIN certification system by January 1, 2013.
The bill would preclude the agency from later invalidating any certified RINs. Thus, under the
bill, any RIN found subsequently to be fraudulent would still count toward an obligated party’s
compliance, without penalties. As noted above, refiners and other obligated parties would likely
prefer this to other policy options, while biofuel producers are unlikely to support such blanket
protection. Further, it is unclear whether EPA could issue a final rule for the new system by the
January 1, 2013, deadline specified in the bill.

Additional Questions
The concerns raised above, and proposed policy remedies, raise additional questions about the
potential for RIN fraud in the future, as well as the effects on stakeholders from any policy
solution. These questions include:
1. Beyond the instances of fraud currently being prosecuted, what other instances
are unreported, and what other types of fraud are possible in the future?
2. How likely is fraud in the future, and what are the implications? and
3. How do various players benefit from the different policy options?

18
Joe Jobe, Chief Executive Officer, National Biodiesel Board, Testimony Before the United States House of
Representatives Committee on Energy and Commerce Hearing “RIN Fraud: EPA’s Efforts to Ensure Market Integrity
in the Renewable Fuels Program,” Washington, DC, July 11, 2012.
19
Genscape, Genscape’s RIN Integrity Network, http://info.genscape.com/RIN.

Congressional Research Service 13


Analysis of RINs in the RFS

What Other Types of RIN Fraud Are Possible?


In the three cases of RIN fraud currently reported by EPA, fraudulent RINs were generated for
fuel that did not exist. However, other potential errors or opportunities for fraud include:
1. double counting, where the same RIN (representing a gallon of actual fuel) is
transferred to two different entities;
2. improper split, where a batch of RINs is separated into two or more groups and
sold to different entities, but the total number of RINs somehow changes (an
example of double counting);
3. improper reporting of RIN data (type of fuel, size of batch, etc.);
4. failure to report export (for every gallon of fuel exported any RINs from that
export must be retired, as the fuel was never used as transportation fuel in the
United States).
The EMTS was established in part to address errors of the first three types. However, it is unclear
whether the EMTS completely screens out these errors. Especially as regulations require all
transactions be reported within five business days, the real-time reporting requirements may
potentially lead to errors if entities feel rushed in completing reports and transactions on time. On
the other hand, real-time reporting may make it easier to catch errors and irregularities than under
the previous system, where most data verification was completed on a quarterly basis.

The latter issue, that fuel has been exported without retirement of necessary RINs, has been raised
by some stakeholders.20 RFS regulations are explicit that when renewable fuel is exported that the
exporter must have RINs to offset that volume: “Any party that owns any amount of renewable
fuel, whether in its neat form or blended with gasoline or diesel, that is exported from any of the
regions described in § 80.1426(b) shall acquire sufficient RINs to comply with all applicable
Renewable Volume Obligations under paragraphs (b) through (e) of this section representing the
exported renewable fuel.”21

It is unclear to what extent, or whether, parties have been exporting fuel without securing the
necessary RINs. EPA has not reported any such activity to date. To the extent that this sort of
fraud is occurring, as with other types of fraud, it would lead to lower domestic renewable fuel
use than required under the act. That would likely lead to an oversupply of RINs and a lower RIN
price received by all market participants. However, unlike other types of fraud, actual fuel would
be produced, so the overall level of U.S. biofuel production may not decline.

How Likely Is RIN Fraud in the Future?


To date, all of the reported cases of fraud have occurred in the biodiesel market. There are several
reasons that have been given for this: (1) the market price for BBD RINs is much higher than that
for ethanol RINs, making any transaction (legal or illegal) that much more valuable; (2) in
general biodiesel producers are smaller operations than ethanol producers, and the companies

20
For example, see Jon P Fjeld-Hansen, Managing Director, Musket Corporation, Testimony Before the United States
House of Representatives Committee on Energy and Commerce Hearing “RIN Fraud: EPA’s Efforts to Ensure Market
Integrity in the Renewable Fuels Program,” Washington, DC, July 11, 2012.
21
40 C.F.R. §1430(a).

Congressional Research Service 14


Analysis of RINs in the RFS

involved may be less well known to market participants; and (3) limited verification procedures
exist.

Between actions taken by industry, forthcoming regulations from EPA, and potential
congressional action, the latter two reasons for fraud in the biodiesel RIN market may be fully
addressed. However, the first cause—a high price for some RINs—may continue in the future. By
2022, the RFS requires the use of 36 billion gallons of renewable fuels, more than double the
amount required in 2012. Thus, the absolute volume of the market will be larger in the future.
Further, of the 36 billion gallons required in 2022, 16 billion gallons are required to come from
cellulosic biofuels. Currently, there is very limited production of these fuels, and their production
costs are high. To the extent that cellulosic fuel costs remain high in the future, the aggregate
value of the cellulosic RIN market could be significantly higher than the total RIN market
today.22 The higher value of this market might be a draw to actors looking to circumvent the law.

How Do Various Players Benefit from the Different Policy Options?


As noted above, obligated parties would like any new certification system to include an
affirmative defense against civil penalties if they act in good faith. As noted above, the details of
that affirmative defense will determine who might benefit from policy changes. For example, in
general obligated parties are more likely to benefit from a blanket exemption from both civil
penalties and the requirement to purchase RINs to make up for ones later found to be invalid.23 In
general, biofuel producers are more likely to benefit from a policy that still requires obligated
parties to purchase make-up RINs. Otherwise, the market for RINs—and thus the fuel they
represent—would effectively shrink by the amount of any fraudulent RINs.

Any third-party certification procedures will add to the cost of producing biofuels and RINs.
Various actors may be more or less able to absorb those costs. For example, obligated parties may
be able to pass the additional cost along to gasoline and diesel fuel consumers through higher
pump prices. Further, larger biofuel producers may be able to take advantage of economies of
scale and spread the cost across all gallons of fuel they produce. Smaller producers, however,
may be less able to spread the cost over the fewer gallons they produce and thus their per-gallon
production costs may increase relative to their larger competitors. As noted above, many biodiesel
producers are smaller operations who may feel more of these effects than ethanol producers (who
generally produce larger volumes of fuel). In the future, cellulosic biofuel producers may also
face similar pressures as these plants are expected to be on the smaller side.

Conclusion
The establishment of the Renewable Fuel Standard has created a market for RINs that has grown
both in volume and in value over time and is expected to continue to grow over the next decade.
However, cases of fraud in the early years of the biodiesel RIN market raise questions about the

22
For example, assuming a cellulosic RIN price of $0.50 in 2022, in aggregate cellulosic RINs would be valued at $8
billion, roughly four times the aggregate value of all RINs in 2011. A higher cellulosic RIN price would raise the
aggregate value proportionally.
23
H.R. 6444 would address this by removing EPA’s authority to invalidate (for any reason) a certified RIN later found
to be deficient. Thus, even a deficient RIN could be traded or used to meet a party’s RVO as long as it had been
certified by the agency.

Congressional Research Service 15


Analysis of RINs in the RFS

integrity of RIN markets, as well as EPA’s oversight of the markets. Various policies have been
proposed to address the potential for RIN fraud in the future, and the details of those policies will
affect the potential for fraud in the future as well as the relative benefits to different market
players.

Author Contact Information


Brent D. Yacobucci
Section Research Manager
byacobucci@crs.loc.gov, 7-9662

Congressional Research Service 16


International Gas Union (IGU)
News, views and knowledge on gas – worldwide

Wholesale Gas Price Formation


- A global review of drivers and regional trends
Foreword
Following the successful 24th World Gas Conference in Buenos Aires in October 2009, we have
decided to convert some of the study reports presented at the conference into IGU publications,
including the report “Gas Pricing” written by Study Group B2 of the IGU Strategy Committee
(PGCB).

The IGU Strategy Committee is updating the review for the WGC in June 2012. Some interim
findings have been published in the April 2011 edition of the IGU Magazine and are available on
www.igu.org.

Historically, gas prices have not been in the news to the same extent as oil prices. This is changing.
The share of gas in global energy and fuel consumption has increased and also the share of
internationally traded gas globally is greater than before. LNG is providing intercontinental linkages
that eventually could constitute a global gas market.

Natural gas is an abundant resource, it is clean and cost-competitive, and should therefore play an
important role in the mitigation of climate change. However, the pricing of this valuable commodity
is critical to a sustainable market growth.

It is our hope that this publication can serve as one example of how vital information related to
gas pricing can be shared across borders to the benefit of the global gas industry and also to enable
new gas regions to learn more about the different pricing models that are being used.

June 2011
Torstein Indrebø
Secretary General of IGU

This publication is produced under the auspices of INTERNATIONAL GAS UNION


(IGU) by the Author(s) mentioned. The Author(s) and IGU enjoy joint copyright to
this publication This publication may not be reproduced in whole or in part without
the written permission of the above mentioned holders of the copyright. However,
irrespective of the above, established journals and periodicals shall be permitted
to reproduce this publication or part of it, in abbreviated or edited form, provided
that credit is given to the Author(s) and to IGU.
Sponsored by:
Table of contents
1. Executive Summary.......................................................................................................................................4
2. Introduction....................................................................................................................................................7
Mandate..........................................................................................................................................................7
Why this report?.............................................................................................................................................7
Outline of report.............................................................................................................................................8
Terms and concepts........................................................................................................................................8
3. Gas price drivers...........................................................................................................................................10
Competitive markets....................................................................................................................................10
Short to medium term supply and demand drivers...................................................................................10
Long term supply and demand drivers......................................................................................................11
Current scenarios.......................................................................................................................................13
Other market organisation ...........................................................................................................................13
OECD area................................................................................................................................................13
Non-OECD area........................................................................................................................................14
4. Key gas pricing mechanisms........................................................................................................................15
5. Origins of individual pricing mechanisms...................................................................................................18
Origins of gas or oil market based pricing...................................................................................................18
North America...........................................................................................................................................18
The UK......................................................................................................................................................18
Continental Europe....................................................................................................................................19
Asia Pacific................................................................................................................................................19
Origins of regulated gas pricing...................................................................................................................20
6. Recent gas price developments....................................................................................................................23
OECD area...................................................................................................................................................23
Rest of the world..........................................................................................................................................24
7. Current extensiveness of individual pricing mechanisms............................................................................28
Introduction..................................................................................................................................................28
Price Formation Mechanisms.......................................................................................................................30
Types of Price Formation Mechanism......................................................................................................30
Results..........................................................................................................................................................30
Format of Results......................................................................................................................................30
World Results............................................................................................................................................30
Regional results.........................................................................................................................................34
Wholesale Prices.......................................................................................................................................38
Changes between 2005 and 2007..............................................................................................................40
Conclusions...............................................................................................................................................41
8. Trends in the extensiveness of individual pricing mechanisms...................................................................42
Towards a globalisation of gas pricing?.......................................................................................................45
Bumps in the road toward globalised gas pricing.....................................................................................47
9. Price volatility..............................................................................................................................................51
General.........................................................................................................................................................51
Causes of volatility.......................................................................................................................................52
Volatility associated with gas price increases...........................................................................................53
Volatility associated with gas price declines.............................................................................................53
Volatility of oil indexed prices.....................................................................................................................54
Volatility and LNG.......................................................................................................................................54
10. Towards further changes in the extensiveness of individual pricing mechanisms?.....................................55

Appendix 1 – Price Formation Mechanisms 2005 Survey...........................................................................58
Format of Results......................................................................................................................................58
World Results............................................................................................................................................58
Regional Results........................................................................................................................................61
Wholesale Prices.......................................................................................................................................65
Conclusions...............................................................................................................................................66

“Gas Pricing”; Study group B2 of IGU Programme Committee B (PGC B). The work was coordinated by Runar Tjærsland, Study Group leader
with contributions of Meg Tsuda, Mike Fulwood, Ottar Skagen and Howard Rogers.

June 2011 | International Gas Union  3 


1. Executive Summary countries’ gas demand, and the gas flows from Russia, the
Middle East and Africa to the OECD are expected to further
increase. Several gas exporting non-OECD countries are however
Historically gas prices have not been in the news to the same struggling to sustain, let alone increase, their exports in the face
extent as oil prices. This is changing. The share of gas in of booming domestic gas demand. Domestic demand reflects
global energy and fuel consumption has increased. The share among other things domestic prices. Consequently the outlook
of internationally traded gas in global gas consumption has for domestic gas pricing in these countries is no longer of local
increased. LNG is providing intercontinental linkages that interest only but of global importance.
eventually could constitute a global gas market. With most
gas producing OECD countries struggling to replace reserves This report examines the extensiveness in different parts of the
and sustain production growth, the centre of gravity of gas world of the following gas pricing mechanisms:
production and exports has shifted towards the same regions
and – to some extent – countries that for 40 years have dominated • Gas on gas competition
oil production and exports. Finally, gas prices have increased • Oil price escalation
and become more volatile. • Bilateral monopoly
• Netback from final product
Gas prices are not determined but definitely influenced by • Regulation on a cost of service basis
individual markets’ choices between available price formation • Regulation on a social and political basis
mechanisms. The two main debates in this respect is the • Regulation below cost
one that goes on in Europe and to an extent in Asia between • No pricing
proponents of continued indexation of gas prices to oil prices
and proponents of gas-on-gas competition based pricing, and the Chart 1.1: World gas price formation 2007 - total consumption
one that goes on inside a number of Non-OECD countries – and
between these countries’ governments and entities like the EU World gas price formation 2007 - total consumption
Commission, the IEA and the multilateral development banks
– on the sustainability of the more or less heavy handed price Oil price Gas-on-gas
regulation that prevails in big parts of the Non-OECD world. escalation
20 %
competition
32 %
No price
Arguably the former of these debates is the least important. 1%

Evidence from North America where gas prices are not


contractually linked to oil prices suggests that gas prices Bilateral
Regulation monopoly
nonetheless tend to track oil prices in a fairly stable long term below cost 8%
relationship. Gas and oil prices are linked by interfuel competition 26 % Regulation
Netback from
social and
in the industrial sector. They are also influenced in the same political
Regulation cost final product
of service 1%
manner and to the same extent by the oil and gas industry’s cost 9%
3%
cycles. Finally price deviations may be arrested, eventually, by
changes in oil and gas industry investment priorities.

In periods of ample gas supply, prices have delinked with Globally, in 2007 one third of all gas sold and purchased was
gas becoming significantly cheaper than heavy fuel oil, not priced according to the gas-on-gas competition mechanism.
to mention crude oil or light fuel oil. But in periods of gas Regionally the share of gas transactions in this category varied
market tightness the link has re-emerged with oil product prices from 99% in North America to zero in most of the developing
eventually putting an end to gas price rallies. world.

For the moment – by mid 2009 – the US gas market is exceptionally The second biggest category in 2007 was “Regulation below
well supplied. As a result prices are softer than at any time since cost“ (see Chapter 4 for definitions) with 26% of the global total.
2002 and well below crude oil and refined product prices in The share of gas supplied at prices contractually linked to oil
energy equivalence terms. Possibly this situation will last for a product or crude prices – the dominant mechanism in Continental
while due to the unexpectedly rapid growth in US unconventional Europe and the Asia Pacific OECD countries – was 20%.
gas production. But that does not need to apply to Europe or
Asia. Consequently a radical replacement of oil linked contracts A comparison of the results for 2007 with those of a similar
with gas linked contracts in any or both of these regions – had study carried out two years ago on 2005 data shows an increase
such a thing been politically and practically possible – would in the “Regulation below cost” category in both absolute and
likely have increased gas price volatility but might not have relative terms. 85% of this change can be explained by robust
materially changed long term price trends. gas consumption growth in the Former Soviet Union, particularly
in Russia, where this pricing mechanism remains dominant.
With respect to the latter debate, Non-OECD countries already Only 15% was due to shifts from other pricing mechanisms to
supply high shares of the European and Asian OECD member regulation below cost.

4  International Gas Union | June 2011


The share of gas transactions at prices reflecting “Regulation from the tensions that current pricing mechanisms have given
on a social and political basis” declined from 2005 to 2007 rise to, and from the debates on gas pricing that these tensions
due mainly to changes in pricing mechanism in Brazil and have triggered.
Argentina and also to below average growth in gas production
for the domestic market in Ukraine and in gas consumption The below figure is highly tentative and intended merely to
in Malaysia, two countries where this type of regulation is facilitate a discussion.
widespread.
Chart 1.2: Hypotheses on future changes in the extensiveness
Gas-on-gas competition based pricing gained some ground, of individual pricing mechanisms in individual regions
largely at the expense of oil price escalation – between 2005
and 2007 largely because of growth in Japan’s, Korea’s, 2008 2020
Taiwan’s and Spain’s spot LNG imports, and in the trading Gas-on-gas competition
North America, UK
Gas-on-gas competition
u ro pe
enta l E
on Continental Europe’s emerging gas hubs. Also less UK Oil price escalation
Con tin
Continental Europe,
Oil price escalation
gas was sold into the UK market under oil linked contracts.
Developed Asia

The combined impact of these changes dwarfed Brazil’s shift Bilateral monopoly Bilateral monopoly

towards oil price escalation, and China’s first LNG imports at Netback from final product Select market segments Netback from final product

?
na
oil linked prices, in this period.

hi
,C
ia
Regulation – cost of service Regulation – cost of service

ss
Ru
A striking aspect of recent gas price developments is that prices Regulation – social and political
Select Non-OECD
EC D
Regulation – social and political
N on-O
seem to have become much more volatile. This impression Regulation – below cost
Select
Select Non-OECD Regulation – below cost
may be slightly misleading. In absolute terms price gyrations
have become stronger. In relative terms – i.e., if one takes into No price No price

account that prices in recent years have fluctuated around higher


averages – volatility appears to have been roughly constant
during the 2000s. In the countries where gas-on-gas competition based pricing
prevails, there may be concerns about price volatility, and debates
Some short term price volatility is part and parcel of gas-on- on how to deal with the harmful effects of price spikes and
gas competition based pricing. As such it is typical for North troughs. But there is little talk about a return to more regulation
America, the UK and the short term trading around Continental or a shift to some variation on the market value pricing theme.
Europe’s emerging hubs – but not for the bulk of Continental As such, gas-on-gas seems to be widely perceived as “the end
Europe’s and Asia’s gas transactions. A typical Continental game” without more efficient alternatives.
European gas import contract links the gas price to a basket of oil
product prices in an averaged and lagged way that significantly In Continental Europe the EU Commission is seeking to pave
dampens the impact of oil price fluctuations. A typical Asian the way for a shift from oil price indexation to gas-on-gas
LNG import contract is structured the same way, only with the competition based pricing. The Commission’s priorities are
gas price indexed to a basket of crude oil prices. being shared to varying degrees by the EU member states’
governments depending on their ideological leanings and
However, if some price volatility is inevitable under gas-on-gas prioritisation between efficiency, environmental and gas supply
competition, strong volatility also requires market tightness. security concerns, and by the region’s commercial actors
The last couple of years’ big gas price changes were due to depending on their status as incumbents or new entrants. The
supply and demand intersecting with each other at very steep enthusiasm for this or that mechanism also tends to vary with
segments of either the supply curve or the demand curve or the oil price and with outlook for the ratio between oil linked
both. For the moment markets are loose and volatility as well gas prices and hub gas prices.
as prices are down.
Though oil price escalation is not going to disappear any time
Another aspect of price volatility is that not everybody would soon, gas-on-gas competition based pricing will likely gain
agree that it is a bad thing that should be minimised. While some ground as more hubs mature.
investors pursuing low risk activities with correspondingly low
returns need stable, predictable prices, others thrive on price In the Asia Pacific region, the main LNG importers are sticking
instability because of the arbitrage opportunities associated to crude oil indexation as the dominant imported gas pricing
with a dynamic environment. mechanism. Gas market based pricing is not yet an option since
the Asian gas markets are characterised by limited competition
These findings beg the questions where gas prices and gas and have almost no gas hubs. This could change with market
pricing mechanisms will go in the future. This study was never reforms aimed at introducing third party access to LNG terminals
supposed to conclude with either another set of gas price scenarios and pipelines and competition at the wholesale level.
or precise predictions of the changes in the extensiveness of
individual pricing mechanisms that undoubtedly will occur 1. 1
A more thorough examination of the scope for changes could instead be the subject for
Broad development directions may nevertheless be inferred a follow-up study in the next WGC triennium.

June 2011 | International Gas Union  5 


In addition to the political and regulatory push for liberalisation basis. Another trend seems to be for governments to liberalise
there has been much talk about Henry Hub or the NBP price prices to select, presumably robust, customers, and increasing
becoming benchmarks also for Asian gas buyers. In 2007- remaining regulated prices to the extent politically possible.
08 when Japanese and Korean utilities had to dramatically Typically, households and industries perceived as “strategic”
increase their imports of Atlantic LNG, this prediction gained such as the fertilizer sector continue to enjoy some protection.
credibility. By 2009, however, with demand in decline due to
the financial crisis and with a string of new Middle Eastern and Russia has embarked on a process of aligning domestic prices
Asian LNG trains at – or approaching – the commissioning with opportunity costs, i.e., with the netback to the producers if
stage, the Atlantic-Asian LNG trade looks set for an equally they had exported the gas instead, and there is every reason to
dramatic decline, potentially with a dampening impact on the believe that this process will be completed, if not necessarily on
pace of price globalisation. schedule. Since Russia exports gas on oil linked contracts, this
means an effective gradual introduction of oil price escalation
In the longer term, internal and external forces may well combine in the domestic market.
to erode the position of oil price escalation also in the Asia
Pacific area. For the time being, however, this region looks Russia and other countries that have practiced gas price
set to remain well behind Continental Europe in introducing regulation are also experimenting with gas-on-gas competition.
alternative mechanisms. Gas exchanges intended to serve as safety valves for producers
with surplus gas and consumers with extraordinary needs are
Bilateral monopoly pricing remains important in the Former being established. The volumes traded on such exchanges
Soviet Union and characterises up to 8-9% of gas transactions and their price impact will however be minor unless and until
in the other Non-OECD regions. Bilateral monopoly pricing competition takes hold, and that could take some time.
may be expected to decline in importance – probably to the
benefit of oil indexed pricing – as Russia is negotiating netback China and India face challenges in incentivising the power
prices based on Western European border prices with its near sector to shift from cheap indigenous coal to gas, but there is
neighbours. significant industrial and household demand at much higher
prices. The future will likely see price regulation with a view
The ‘netback from final product’ mechanism will likely prevail to both consumers’ ability to pay, supply costs and the prices of
in certain market segments. For industrial gas users it represents competing fuels. But increasing gas imports will expose these
a way to shift product market risk upstream. For gas sellers countries to gas-on-gas competition too, and affect the pricing
it represents a way to sustain industrial demand in times of environment for the consumers with the highest willingness
potential market destruction. It is however difficult to see this to pay.
mechanism making major inroads into the much bigger shares
of gas transactions characterised by gas-on-gas pricing, oil Middle Eastern countries face challenges in providing for
escalation or regulation. development of non-associated gas reserves in the context of gas
prices that reflect the very low costs of associated gas supply.
Outside the OECD area, gas subsidisation is taking an increasingly But the need for countries like Kuwait, Abu Dhabi, Dubai and
heavy toll. One trend seems to be for countries practicing below possibly Bahrain to start importing gas will introduce new
cost regulation to move towards ad hoc price adjustments with benchmarks to the region and may eventually drive broader
the purpose of keeping prices largely in line with supply costs price reforms. To the small extent it still exists, the ‘no price’
– i.e. what we have termed regulation on a social and political category seems destined for phase-out.

6  International Gas Union | June 2011


2. Introduction These differences between gas and oil are becoming less
pronounced:

• The gas share of the fuel mix has increased world wide;
Mandate • Gas prices have increased;
• Gas prices have become more volatile;
This report is as noted not an attempt to analyse in great • LNG is providing intercontinental gas price linkages that
detail gas price movements around the world in great detail, eventually could constitute a global gas market;
nor to provide another set of gas price forecasts. The mandate • With most gas producing OECD countries struggling to
given to IGU PGC B/SG2 was: replace reserves and sustain production growth, the centre
of gravity of gas production and exports has shifted towards
• To carry out a comprehensive analysis of gas price formation the same regions and to some extent the same countries that
models at regional level: price drivers, indexation, price for 40 years have dominated oil production and exports.
arbitrage, demand elasticity;
• To investigate future trends and the factors which could help Gas prices in North America, Europe and developed Asia are
to minimize price anomalies and contribute to a sustainable being more closely monitored than prices in the rest of the
market growth world. This has several reasons:

The work group has on the basis of this mandate set itself • Historically the OECD area has accounted for the bulk of
the following targets: world gas consumption,
• The world’s leading energy research institutions are located
• Identify the main gas price drivers and discuss how they in the OECD area and sponsored by OECD area governments
operate in the short and longer term; and companies,
• Offer a categorisation of how gas is priced around the world; • While prices in the OECD area are market driven and therefore
• Discuss how individual pricing methods or models have amenable to standard economic theory and models, prices
arisen; in the rest of the world are with a few notable exceptions
• Present the results of a global pricing method mapping politically determined and therefore essentially beyond
exercise; forecasting.
• Examine select trends in the use of individual pricing methods;
• Discuss the roots and consequences of gas price volatility; The validity of the first reason is wearing thin. 2007 world gas
• Offer some views on how the popularity and prevalence of use was split evenly between the OECD countries and the rest
individual methods may change in the years ahead. of the world, and since OECD area consumption is growing
at a slower pace than non-OECD consumption, the latter area
Why this report? will soon have a lead on the former. Moreover, several non-
OECD countries are already playing key roles in determining
Ever since natural gas became a marketable good with an the supply of gas to world markets, and will only become more
economic value, gas pricing principles and price levels have important in this respect in the future. Their domestic gas pricing
attracted producer, consumer, government and general interest. decisions could therefore be strongly felt in the OECD area.
Gas prices have however not been in the news to the same extent
as oil prices. This is because: Russia is a case in point. Eurasian gas balance studies typically
conclude that the call on Russian gas will increase significantly
• Historically gas has been less important than oil in most and that Gazprom, the Russian oil companies and Russia’s
countries’ fuel mix; independent gas producers need to invest massively in the upstream
• On balance gas border or hub prices has been lower, in energy and midstream to stave off shortages. This from time to time
equivalence terms, than crude oil border or hub prices; prompts discussions on the adequacy of budgeted investments.
• Unlike oil, gas has substitutes in its main applications, a fact However, if a gap exists it may be closed by dampening future
that has served to check gas price fluctuations; also the way demand as well as by boosting future supply. The bulk of Russian
gas is indexed to oil in European and Asian contracts has gas – currently almost 70% – is consumed at home. Thus if the
smoothened the gas price curve: pace of growth of Russian domestic gas use can be contained
• Gas has been a regional fuel and hence not in the same way through for instance price increases, budgeted investments in
as oil a matter of global importance; supply may be more than adequate.
• Gas reserves have been more widely distributed than oil
reserves with OECD countries holding a major portion of The Middle East is another case in point. Forecasters tend to
the resource base; thus the divide between producing and vest high shares of the responsibility for supplying world gas
consuming countries has been less clear-cut and gas prices demand in the decades ahead, with this region. But the Middle
less geo-politicised. East’s current and potential gas exporters are currently struggling
to sustain or start exports in the face of stagnant production and
booming domestic demand. The latter aspect of the region’s

June 2011 | International Gas Union  7 


fuel situation is closely linked to its traditionally very low end This chapter also addresses the issue of gas price globalisation.
user prices. As noted, gas prices have historically been regional. Price
formation in one region has largely reflected circumstances
Estimates of the long term impact of gas price changes on within that region only, and has in turn not impacted on price
gas demand vary across countries and time periods. And if it formation in other regions. This is changing, driven by the
is difficult to reach consensus on price elasticities for OECD growth in flexible LNG, and at a more general level by the
countries, it is even harder for regions like the FSU and the commoditization of gas, the better availability of global gas
Middle East. However, although gas consumption per capita may price information and a higher awareness in every corner of
be lower outside than inside the OECD area, gas consumption the world of the value of gas.
per unit of GDP produced in the sectors using gas in the first
place, is typically higher. Hence the fuel switching and savings Chapter 10 offers a view on the sustainability of individual
potential that could be released by gas price increases should pricing models, and a view on where we will most likely see
not be underestimated. changes and where we probably will not see much deviation
from today’s pricing habits.
Outline of report
Finally, Appendix 1 presents the full results of the 2005 mapping
Chapter 3 of this report identifies the gas price drivers at exercise in the same way as Chapter 7 presents the 2007 exercise.
work in different markets and offers some views on how they
may develop in the years ahead. Terms and concepts

There are many prices along pipeline gas or LNG value


Chapter 4 presents and briefly explains eight gas pricing chains. The focus in this study is on wholesale prices, that is,
mechanisms that together capture nearly all gas produced and hub prices or – in the absence of hubs providing reliable price
consumed in the world. signals – border prices.
Chapter 5 discusses the origins and history of each of these
mechanisms, with an emphasis on those in use in the OECD FOB price (LNG)
 Study object is wholesale –
border or hub – price
countries. formation
Border or DES (LNG) price
 Wellhead prices may be
unrepresentative for pricing
The current interest in gas pricing models has a context, and Hub price conditions further down the chain

this context is the gas price turbulence experienced since 2000 Large end user prices
Small
 End user prices reflect, in
addition to wholesale prices,
in big parts of the world. For this reason chapter 6 offers a brief Wellhead
price Citygate
end taxes, downstream margins and
local factors – noise in the big
user
overview of recent price developments inside and outside the price prices picture
 Also, border/hub prices are better
OECD area. documented

Chapter 7 is the core of the report in that it presents the result of


an empirical investigation of the prevalence of individual pricing It is at the level of wholesale prices that battles over pricing
models in individual markets in 2007, and also a comparison of principles are fought. It is this level that is subject to national
the situation in 2007 to that in 2005. A sample of IGU member or supranational regulation.
organisations were asked to estimate the shares of gas sales in
their home countries that belonged to each of the eight pricing Moreover, wholesale pricing principles largely determine end
categories. The member organisations were selected so as to user pricing principles. One cannot have, e.g., gas-on-gas
ensure that all regions and preferably all key countries were competition based hub or border prices and at the same time
covered. The replies were then analysed by SGB2. competing fuel linked citygate or end user prices.

Chapter 8 addresses the tensions inherent in individual pricing A third reason for focusing on wholesale prices is that city gate
mechanisms, the consequent challenges of sustaining the current and end user prices are influenced by taxes and by local supply
pattern of methods, and the attempts being made by market and demand conditions reflecting in turn local weather patterns,
players, politicians and regulators to introduce new methods, local infrastructural bottlenecks, the level of competition for
typically with a view to shifting prices to more efficient levels. local distribution rights, local regulators’ ability to counteract
attempts at monopoly pricing, etc.
Chapter 9 addresses this issue of gas price volatility. Since the
turn of the decade, gas prices have not only fluctuated around A fourth, related reason is the inherent complexity of end user
(until recently) rising trends, they have also gyrated more prices. Mature markets typically have extensive end user price
violently than typical for the 1980s and 1990s. The reasons for matrices with prices varying by geography, end user segment,
and nature of the post 2000 gas price instability, and whether customer size and interruptibility of supply. Thus, end user prices
the future will bring even more, or less, volatility, are questions studies require a degree of accounting for the local context that
on every gas market player’s mind. is beyond the scope of this study.

8  International Gas Union | June 2011


Finally, in many areas wholesale prices are as a rule better Hub price
documented than other prices.
• The price of gas at a hub, typically a pipeline junction where
There are however exceptions from the latter rule. There are a significant amount of gas sales and purchases takes place
countries with immature gas markets, no hubs, no exports or and where sellers and buyers can also purchase storage
imports and with state companies that do not publish much services
financial information in charge of gas supply – but where one • A hub does not need to be physical, it can be virtual like the
can still find some anecdotal evidence of prices, typically at UK’s National Balancing Point
end user level. In such cases it is necessary to combine what • Serving as marketplaces, hubs are a prerequisite for gas
little information exists into guesstimates of wholesale prices. pricing through gas-to-gas competition
• Hub prices are well documented as they underpin the world’s
The following is an attempt to further define and explain the gas futures markets
pricing terms to be used in this report. • The US’ Henry Hub is the closest thing there is to a world
gas pricing point
Wellhead price • Hub prices are optimal wholesale price indicators
• However, hubs liquid enough to convey reliable price signals
• The value of gas at the mouth of the gas well exist for the moment only in the US, in the UK and to an
• In general the wellhead price is considered to be the sales price extent in the Benelux area
obtainable from a third party in an arm’s length transaction
• Wellhead prices are well documented for the US, less so for Citygate price
other countries with less transparency in the upstream
• The price of gas at a citygate, typically at the inlet to a
Border/beach price low pressure pipeline grid owned and operated by a local
distribution company
• The price of gas at a border crossing or landing point • US citygate prices on a monthly state-by-state and weighted
• US and European natural gas and LNG import prices are average US basis are published by the DOE/EIA
well documented by the US Department of Energy’s Energy • US citygate prices on balance reflect the prices on the hubs
Information Administration (DOE/EIA) and Eurostat, and where the gas is sourced plus transportation costs, but may from
by the International Energy Agency (IEA) in its quarterly time to time due to local supply and demand circumstances
Energy include substantial premiums or discounts
• Citygate prices are not systematically documented anywhere
Prices and Taxes report else

• The reporting on European import prices is incomplete as End user prices


the long term export-import contracts that determine these
prices are as a rule not in the public domain • End user prices are the prices charged to power sector,
• Non OECD/IEA country border or beach prices are not industrial, commercial or residential end users at the plant
systematically compiled and published, but a great deal of gate or the inlet to their individual pipeline connections
information on individual agreements exists • End user prices for the OECD/IEA countries are published
• Since so few countries have hubs providing reliable price by the DOE/EIA, Eurostat and the IEA, and by select private
information, border/beach prices will often be the best market intelligence companies
wholesale price proxies available • End user price information is available for a few non-OECD
countries but not for most of them, and reliability is an issue
FOB and DES LNG prices • End user prices are important insofar as it is at that level
interfuel competition takes place
• FOB (Free On Board) price • However, publishers’ aggregating and averaging make
– The price of LNG at the point of loading onto the vessel. significant price differences disappear, limiting the conclusions
– The FOB breakeven price needs to cover upstream costs (i.e., that can be drawn from published end user price movements
E&D, gas processing and field to plant transportation costs) • Moreover, taxes ad local circumstances can distort the picture
and liquefaction costs, but not shipping and regasification • End user prices should be resorted to only when necessary
costs. due to a lack of wholesale price information
• DES (Delivered Ex-Ship) price
– The price of LNG at the point of unloading off the vessel. Netback price
– The DES breakeven price needs to pay for the same cost
components as the FOB price plus shipping costs • Gas supply chains have multiple links, and for each point of
transfer from one link to another a so-called netback price
may be calculated by deducting from the end user price the
unit costs of bringing the gas from that point to the end user

June 2011 | International Gas Union  9 


• The netback price to the upstream shows the value per unit
of gas produced left for sharing between the producer and
the state after distribution, transmission, storage and – in
the event of LNG – regasification, shipping and liquefaction
costs have been deducted from the end user price, and is as
such a key indicator of project feasibility

3. Gas price drivers


In competitive markets, with multiple sellers facing multiple Chart 3.1: Iberian Peninsula: Hydro reservoir levels and LNG
buyers, prices are driven by supply and demand. Price changes imports
in turn feed back on supply and demand by providing signals
that – in principle – ensures market equilibrium. Since supply and
demand depend on more factors than price and since neither of Iberian Peninsula: Variations in hydro reservoir
level and LNG imports, March 1999 - June 2008
these variables typically move smoothly and precisely between 80 3 500
equilibrium levels but tend to undershoot or overshoot, the

Monthly LNG imports (mill cm)


70
Monthly hydro level (per cent)

3 000
simultaneous price, supply and demand adjustment process 60
2 500
never stops. 50
2 000
40
1 500
Due to the nature of gas as a commodity and to the different 30
Trend lines
1 000
historical origins of national gas industries and markets, gas 20 Recent droughts,
impact on LNG
prices are not everywhere set under competitive conditions. But 10 imports
500

some markets have been liberalised, and others are at various 0 -

stages of introducing gas-on-gas competition and competitively


99

00

01

02

03

04

05

06

07

08
ch

ch

ch

ch

ch

ch

ch

ch

ch

ch
ar

ar

ar

ar

ar

ar

ar

ar

ar

ar
set prices. The factors that drive gas supply and demand, and
M

M
Sources: CERA, IEA
how these factors will evolve and interact in the future, therefore
need to be understood.
Business cycles affect gas demand – especially industrial gas
demand – in the medium term.
Competitive markets
There are also examples of gas supply interruptions boosting
Short to medium term supply and demand drivers gas prices. Such interruptions may be due to extreme weather,
Even modest short term gas supply or demand disturbances accidents or political or commercial tensions. When hurricanes
may boost or depress prices significantly. The impact will Katrina and Rita hit the US Gulf coast the result was a 13,5%
depend on the state of the market at the outset. A tight market drop in US dry gas production from August to September 2005,
where either supply or demand or both are highly inelastic at and a 26% increase in US gas prices as represented by the
intersection will deliver a stronger price response to the same Henry Hub monthly average over the same period (Chart 3.2).
disturbance than a relaxed market.
Chart 3.2: US gas production vs Henry Hub, 1997-2008
There are many examples of gas demand spikes leading to gas
price spikes. Such spikes may occur because of temperature US dry gas production vs Henry Hub
fluctuations. A cold spell during winter or – in places with 1900000
Jan 97 - Oct 08
16,00
much gas going into power generation and much power going
Katrina, Rita 14,00
Production (million cubic feet)

1800000
into air conditioning – an unusually hot summer may boost 12,00
seasonal gas demand and cause a price spike. Droughts may 1700000
HH (USD/MMBtu)

10,00
temporarily cut into hydro power generation capacity, boost 1600000
8,00
demand for thermal power and as a result increase power sector 1500000
6,00
gas demand. Spain’s drought problems since the middle of 1400000
4,00
the current decade have impacted on Atlantic and world LNG 1300000 2,00
demand (Chart 3.1). 1200000 0,00
jan.97

jan.98

jan.01

jan.02

jan.04

jan.05

jan.06

jan.08
jan.99

jan.00

jan.03

jan.07

Source: US DOE EIA

10  International Gas Union | June 2011


Examples of accidents or commercial / political supply cut-offs Long term supply side drivers
driving price spikes are harder to find. Even an incident as serious
as the explosion at the Algerian Skikda LNG plant in January Chart 3.4: Long term marginal supply cost curve (illustration)
2004 that destroyed three trains with a combined capacity of
more than 4 mtpa did not have noticeable consequences for buyer
country prices as Sonatrach managed to quickly rearrange supply.
Long term marginal supply
The Russian-Ukrainian gas conflicts in late 2005 – early 2006 cost curve (illustration)
and again in the beginning of 2009 caused some nervousness in

Border or hub costs


European markets but apparently did not have much impact on

Supply option 15
Supply option114
spot prices. The former conflict occurred at a time when these

Supply option 13
Supply option 12
Supply option 11
Supply option 10
prices had already increased significantly. The dip in Russian

Supply option 9
Supply option 8
Supply option 7
Supply option 6
gas supply may have only marginally aggravated the price

Supply option 5
Supply option 4
Supply option 3
Supply option 2
Supply option 1
spike. The latter conflict apparently did not affect prices on
the North European gas exchanges – which, it should be noted,
are located far away from where the supply interruptions were
Volume
most acutely felt – at all. Prices on these hubs kept fluctuating
around a steadily declining trend during the final quarter of
2008 and into 2009 (Chart 3.3).
Long term marginal supply cost curves show – as Chart 3.4
Chart 3.3: North European gas hub prices seeks to illustrate – the incremental gas volumes that become
available to a given market as supply costs are allowed to
increase. Typically the cheapest supply is indigenous conventional
North European gas hub prices gas delivered via amortised pipelines, and the most expensive
14
Weekly averages, autumn-winter 2008-09 supply high cost LNG, gas imported via long distance, not
13 NBP yet amortised pipelines and unconventional gas. There are
12
Zeebrugge however exceptions from this rule. In the US, the supply areas
TTF
onshore or just offshore the Gulf of Mexico that for decades
USD/MMBtu

11
10 have constituted the backbone of the US gas industry no longer
9 account for the cheapest portion of supply.
8
7
Snapshots of a given country’s long term marginal gas supply
6
cost curve may be inaccurate. Unlike volume and to some extent
price information, cost information is not easily available. Cost
n

n
ct

ov

ov

b
ct

ec

ec
p

Ja

Ja

Fe
Se

D
13

13

27
27

10
10

24
19

08

30

curves therefore tend to be based on assumptions and generic


Source: WGI
data as much as on solid project information. Moreover, the
shape of the curve is bound to change over time. New upstream
Long term supply and demand drivers or midstream technologies may shift some supply options down
Gas prices in competitive markets fluctuate around long term the curve and, by default, other options up the same curve. New
trends determined by, graphically speaking: supply sources may displace existing supply sources. Examples
of such developments abound. Tight gas, shale gas and coal
• The shape of the long term marginal gas supply cost curve bed methane used to be located on the uneconomic portion
• The extent to which the reserves on the marginal gas supply of the supply curve. Today unconventional gas is part of the
cost curve can actually be produced, given the regulatory, mainstream supply in the US and is growing in importance in
geopolitical and other constraints on oil and gas developments other countries. On the other hand, whereas LNG became much
world wide more competitive between the mid 1990s and 2004, since 2005
• Shifts in the demand curve unit costs have rebounded and made new LNG that seemed
economic by a wide margin a few years ago, look marginal.

For these reasons, basing price analysis on static supply curves


is not recommendable.

Marginal cost curves are by definition sloping upwards and


are normally becoming steeper as more supply is brought into
the picture. However, new gas discoveries and technological
progress can ‘flatten’ them and allow demand to shift out for
much longer before hitting the steep portion. Past predictions
of supply costs pushing prices outside their ‘normal’ range on

June 2011 | International Gas Union  11 


a permanent basis have generally proved wrong. Forecasters However, no economy has managed to break the link over an
have failed to take the cyclical nature of the oil and gas business, extended period of time between economic growth and energy
with high prices dampening demand and stimulating E&D and consumption growth.
thereby paving the way for another downturn, as well as the
potential for technological improvements, fully into account. Energy intensity change
The gas price explosion all developed countries experienced in
the years up to the financial crisis broke was widely assumed The energy intensity of a country’s economy refers to the energy
to be of a different, more structural and permanent nature. The and fuel consumed per unit of GDP produced in the country.
price decline in late 2008 – early 2009 put a question mark at Energy intensities change over time. Only in the unlikely events
that assumption. that the income elasticity of a country’s energy demand is stable
at exactly 1, and there is no impact from energy or fuel price
Access to the reserves on the long term marginal supply cost changes, will its energy use per per unit of GDP be the same
curve is another key gas supply determinant. Access may be year after year.
constrained for a number of reasons. Host country governments
may: Moreover, energy intensities tend to trend downwards, due to

• Wish to reserve parts of their gas for future generations • Normal structural changes, i.e. the transfer of resources from
• Wish to reserve their gas, or parts of it, for their national energy heavy to energy light sectors
oil industries, which however may be unable for financial, • Autonomous energy efficiency improvements, meaning
technological or manpower reasons to take on complex progress that happens by itself, so to say, not because of
developments political signals
• Put up environmental restrictions so severe as to effectively • Policy measures to make car manufacturers produce more
block developments fuel efficient cars, households insulate their houses better, etc.
• Present oil and gas companies with fiscal terms too onerous
to allow projects to go forward This does not mean however that energy intensities cannot
increase in certain periods due to for instance temperature
Independently of host government attitudes, countries or regions fluctuations or the advent of new industries or products.
may be inaccessible for long periods of time for geopolitical
reasons or because of local unrest and poor safety conditions Fuel structure change

A related constraint which has slowed liquefaction plant projects Companies and households switch between fuels mostly in
in recent years is the limited capacity of key equipment vendors response to changes in fuel price relationships. Such changes may
and the small number of engineering companies able to manage in turn be market driven or policy – i.e., tax or subsidy – driven.
such projects. This problem is likely cyclical. Some problems
may also be due to the industry pushing its borders with respect The ease with which consumers can switch between fuels in
to project size (the Qatari megatrains) and climatic challenges response to price signals, depends on the flexibility of their
(the Snøhvit and Sakhalin projects), and may go away as plant fuel using equipment. The more dual firing capacity, the more
builders and operators gain experience. But by the autumn of interfuel competition, and vice versa. Consumers that have to
2008 project delays were undoubtedly aggravating gas price replace big parts of their equipment to capitalise on a change
inflation and volatility world wide. in relative fuel prices, need strong incentives and confidence
that the new price relationship will last, to take action.
Long term demand side drivers
In the Atlantic markets gas initially competed mainly against
The price-volume curve representing a country’s gas demand select oil products. Gas prices have therefore tended to move
typically shifts to the right over time in response to economic in tandem with the regional light and heavy fuel oil prices. In
growth, changes in the energy intensity of the country’s Western Europe long term contract prices referenced to oil
economy, and changes in the fuel structure of the country’s have provided an automatic link. In the US competition has
energy consumption. provided a similar though looser link (chart 3.5). Normally gas
in the US traded between heavy fuel oil and gasoil. But since
Economic growth the beginning of 2006 gas appears to have effectively decoupled
from oil products.
Economic growth drives overall energy demand. The impact
which is called the income elasticity of energy demand changes A secondary reason why gas prices tend to shadow oil prices is
with the level of economic development. Emerging, industrialising that gas and oil is produced either in one and the same process
economies are typically characterised by high elasticities. A 1% or at least by the same actors employing the same rigs and other
growth in such a country’s GDP may require a 1+ % growth upstream equipment. Hence gas and oil projects are subject to
in energy use. Advanced, service based economies need less joint feasibility evaluations and are exposed to the same input
incremental energy to support a given economic growth. factor price upturns and downturns.

12  International Gas Union | June 2011


Today, with a growing share of world gas supply going to fire Chart 3.6: US gas consumption
gas power plants, the coal price level is becoming another
important reference.
US gas consumption: History, EIA's 2009
reference projection
Chart 3.5: US natural gas and oil prices 800
700

US natural gas and oil product prices 600


Monthly averages, January 1999 - December 2008 500

Bcm
30 400
US Gulf Coast No. 2 Heating Oil
25 300
US Gulf Coast Residual Fuel Oil 1,0% Sulfur
Henry Hub 200
20
USD/MMBtu

100
15
0
10

90

93

02

05

08

11

20

23

26
96

99

14

17

29
19

19

20

20

20

20

20

20
19

19

20

20

20

20
5
Source: US DOE EIA: Annual Energy Outlook 2009
0
06

07
99

00

01

02

03

04

05

08

The Energy Information Administration of the US Department


n

n
Ja

Ja

Ja

Ja

Ja

Ja

Ja
Ja

Ja

Ja

Sources: US DOE EIA of Oil and Energy expects in its 2009 Annual Energy Outlook
US gas consumption to peak in 2026 (Chart 3.6). Though it
implies an average demand growth expectation for the 2008-30
One development that should favour gas relative to other fossil period of only 0,2% a year, this scenario is more optimistic in
fuels is the emphasis on curbing greenhouse gas emissions. volume terms than its predecessor. The EIA has lowered its long
Two key remedies are fuel consumption taxes differentiated term gas supply cost and price assumptions, with less demand
by carbon contents, and emission trading schemes. Both will destruction as a result.
increase the costs to consumers of all fossil fuels, but leave gas
relatively less affected. Whether the net effect on gas demand will Other market organisations
be positive (because of substitution from other fuels to gas) or OECD area
negative (because energy savings will wipe out the substitution
gains) will depend on how these remedies are designed and A high share of world gas supply is not priced according to gas
implemented and how they come to interact with other policy supply and demand. In Continental Europe and Developed Asia
measures and the forces of the market. small numbers of importers / wholesalers have been dealing
with small numbers of exporting countries typically represented
Current scenarios by their national oil companies.

Will all these factors driving or dampening gas supply and In Europe this structure is breaking up. New entrants are gaining
demand growth sustain prices at or close to the levels obser- access to the incumbents’ infrastructure. Norwegian gas is no
ved in early-mid 2008, or has the financial crises deflated pri- longer sold by a committee dominated by Statoil but by all the
ces on a long term basis? There are as many answers to this actors on the NCS in competition with each other. Gas hubs
question as there are market observers. However, the widely representing spot trading opportunities are popping up. Hubs
held view from a few years back that gas as the obvious brid- need liquidity to be useful for pricing purposes and so far only
ging fuel between the oil intensive 20th century and a cleaner the UK’s NBP fulfil this criterion, but two or three others could
21st century could look forward to several decades of robust be on their way. Existing and new LNG vendors are descending
supply and demand growth, is being challenged. on a growing number of European LNG terminals, and new
piped gas suppliers are awaiting access to Europe via new long
The International Energy Agency presents in its 2008 World distance import pipelines.
Energy Outlook a business as usual scenario where world gas
demand increases by some 1500 bcm between 2006 and 2030, Developed Asia is proceeding at a slower pace, but Kogas is
or by 1,8% a year. The IEA sees US gas consumption peak at no longer the only Korean LNG importer, and the Japanese
about 650 bcm a year in 2015 before declining to about 630 gas market could see the introduction of competitive elements
bcm a year by 2030. All in all this means a 0,1% a year growth in the years ahead.
in demand for the entire 2008-30 period.
Continental Europe’s and Developed Asia’s long term gas import
contracts index the price of the gas to the prices of oil and oil
products. In Europe the indices are mostly light and heavy
fuel oil, in Developed Asia it is crude oil. The contracts have a
price clause that includes a base year price and a formula that
regulates the gas price’s tracking of the prices of the indices.

June 2011 | International Gas Union  13 


The clause also addresses the need for regular revisits to the practice in oil exporting countries struggling to increase oil
formula in response to structural changes in the marketplace. production and witnessing rapid growth in domestic oil use
eroding the oil surplus available for exports.
Continental European and Developed Asian border gas prices
are thus driven by the prices of crude oil and refined products, Regulated gas prices may be adjusted according to some simple
and indirectly by all the factors that drive these prices, rather formula, e.g. by a certain percentage per year. More typical are
than by developments in Continental European and Developed ad hoc adjustments in response to typically conflicting calls for
Asian gas demand or in world gas supply. change from different sides – from the budget, from the macro
economy, from companies involved in the supply of gas to the
This is a simplification insofar as the price signals coming domestic market demanding higher prices, and from industrial
from the spot markets around Europe, from the UK via the and residential consumers demanding lower prices.
Interconnector and from the US via LNG do influence Continental
European and Developed Asian contract prices. Long term The different motives for gas price regulation at below economic
import contracts always have some offtake flexibility. If spot levels are in no way mutually exclusive. More often that not
prices fall significantly below contract prices, buyers will governments that subsidise gas do it in the hope of killing several
respond by offtaking as little as they can under their contracts, birds with one stone – attracting investments in petrochemical
turning instead to the alternatives. This will lift spot prices but and other gas intensive industries, containing inflation, keeping
could also lead to contract renegotiations and eventually some the population happy and sustaining oil exports.
realignment of contract prices with gas market realities.
Participation in international and intercontinental gas trade
The current trend is towards shorter, more flexible import inevitably plays a role in shaping market actors’ views on the
contracts, so the influence from gas supply and demand on sustainability of different pricing models. Trade means the
Continental European and Asian contract prices will likely import and export of price signals. When a country decides to
increase. However, as we will revert to later in this report, there start importing or exporting gas, pressures to align domestic
is currently little to indicate that either Continental Europe or prices with import or export prices will inevitably start to build.
Developed Asia will abandon oil linked pricing any time soon.
Chart 3.7: Impact on domestic pricing of opening for gas
Non-OECD area imports or exports

Outside the OECD area there are many gas consuming countries
Pdomestic Incentives to grow imports => increased
that neither allow gas supply and demand to determine Pinternational
>1 competition in domestic market => domestic prices
depressed towards international level
prices nor practice oil linked pricing. Instead they set prices Gas imports
becoming possible
Pdomestic
administratively according to principles and procedures that
Subsidisation of imported gas or blending with
domestic gas or dual pricing needed to allow uptake
<1
Pinternational => incentives to raise domestic prices to minimise
are not always transparent. budgetary, administrative challenges

Pdomestic If high domestic prices reflect high costs, country’s


>1
Supply costs may be a consideration, but do not always receive Gas exports
Pinternational
gas not competitive in world markets => no exports
take place

systematic attention. If supply costs are taken into account, they becoming possible
Pdomestic
Incentives to reallocate gas from domestic market to
exports => need to either introduce export quotas/
may be defined so as to include both operating, depreciation Pinternational
<1 enforced supply of domestic demand, or raise
domestic prices towards parity in netback terms with

and financial costs and a return on investments, but they may export prices, to restore balance

as well be defined so as to cover operating costs only, leaving


nothing for maintenance not to mention system expansions. The
more supply costs are ignored as a driver, i.e., the further below Gas price regulation that does not take costs fully into account
full cycle supply costs prices are set, the smaller is the role that and involves a degree of subsidisation typically becomes harder
sales revenues play in financing the country’s gas supply. The to sustain when international gas prices are high. This was the
state actor(s) involved then need to be funded directly from situation in 2008. Importing country governments needed if
the state budget. they wished to continue shielding their populations to accept
increasing budget deficits. Producer country governments that
Social and political considerations are probably the most important could export the gas rather than keeping it at home had to accept
regulated price drivers, with the regulators aiming to set prices so increasing growth in export and tax revenues foregone. The latter
as not to hurt industrial consumers’ competitiveness, overburden governments were on the other hand typically also the biggest
residential consumers and potentially trigger political unrest. beneficiaries of the 2008 oil price escalation and therefore able
These criteria are course ambiguous, reflecting what consumers to continue offering cheap gas to the domestic market.
have grown accustomed to rather than objective thresholds. The
same gas bill as a share of a household’s real disposable income In response to such pressures governments typically deregulate
may be acceptable in one country and intolerable in another. prices to some market segments while retaining regulated prices
to other, more vulnerable segments.
In some countries gas prices are regulated at low levels to
stimulate substitution from other fuels to gas. This is common Deregulation may be a long and cumbersome process as the

14  International Gas Union | June 2011


pressures. Delayed responses to imbalances created by trying Chart 3.8: Challenges of price regulation
to keep too many people happy at the same time for too long
may lead to draconian price hikes – and retreats, in response Price
Growing
to popular protests and unrest. Higher cost
Incentives to
contain domestic
dependence on
imported gas =>
of new gas demand to Exposure to
domestic enable gas world gas price
Chart 3.8 seeks to illustrate how a government aiming to production exports fluctuations

introduce gas initially may need to consider and trade off only
a limited number of factors in a reasonably straightforward Time
exercise. However, as time passes and situations change a
consistent line on pricing may become increasingly difficult
Low incomes, drive Drive to shift Price riots,
to define and support. to support domestic domestic fuel use accommodating
gas intensive from oil to gas to leadership
industry sustain oil exports

4. Key gas pricing mechanisms

We propose to distinguish between the following gas pricing Chart 4.1: Pricing under gas-on-gas competition
mechanisms:

• Gas on gas competition Gas-on-gas competition


• Oil price escalation
• Bilateral monopoly Supply =
Marginal Cost
• Netback from final product Price Demand

• Regulation on a cost of service basis


• Regulation on a social and political basis P1 Average
Cost
• Regulation below cost
• No pricing

Gas-on-gas competition is the dominant pricing mechanisms


in the US and the UK. It means that the gas price is determined V1 Volume

by the interplay of gas supply and demand over a variety of


different periods (daily, weekly, monthly, quarterly, seasonally,
annually or longer). Trading takes place at physical hubs, Chart 4.1 illustrates price formation under gas-on-gas competition.
e.g. Henry Hub, or notional hubs such as the NBP in the UK. It is assumed that the price is set so as to clear the market.
Trading is likely to be supported by developed futures markets
(NYMEX or ICE) and online commodity exchanges (ICE or • The demand curve is inelastic at high prices and low prices,
OCM). Not all gas is bought and sold on a short term fixed where there is little scope for fuel-switching, and elastic in
price basis – there are longer term contracts but these rely on the middle range where demand for gas can change readily
gas price indices rather than competing fuel indices for, e.g., depending on relative fuel prices;
monthly price determination. • The supply curve is identical to the long run marginal cost
curve; and
Gas-on-gas competition does not mean that competing fuel prices • The average cost curve cuts the long run marginal cost curve
play no role in determining the gas price. Key groups of gas at its low point, and then the demand curve at a lower price
consumers can switch between gas and oil products, or between than the competitive market price.
gas and coal, in response to price signals. This substitutability
of gas means that the prices of gas oil, HFO and at the low end Under gas-to-gas competition the price in any given period
coal typically frame the range within which gas prices may would presumably be at P1V1.
move. However, this market (as opposed to contractual) link
between the prices of different fuels is neither stable over time Oil price escalation is the dominant pricing mechanism in
nor able to prevent gas prices to move outside their prescribed Continental Europe and Asia. It means that the gas price is
corridor for long periods of time. contractually linked, usually through a base price and an

June 2011 | International Gas Union  15 


escalation clause, to the prices of one or more competing fuels, services that changed hands in the intra-‘East Bloc’ gas trade was
in Europe typically gas oil and/or fuel oil, in Asia typically opaque, with politics playing a major role alongside economics.
crude oil. Occasionally, coal prices are part of the escalation
clause, as are electricity prices. The escalation clause ensures Examples of gas pricing based on bilateral negotiations may
that when an escalator value changes, the gas price is adjusted still be found in countries where one dominant supplier, e.g.,
by a fraction of the escalator value change depending on the the national oil company, faces one or a couple of dominant
so-called pass-through factor. buyers, say, the state owned power company and maybe 1-2
large industrial companies. A number of immature developing
In addition to the link to the prices of competing fuels, it is country gas markets have this structure.
common to include a link to inflation in the escalation clause.
Netback from final product means that the price received by the
Oil price escalation does not mean that gas supply and demand gas supplier reflects the price received by the buyer for his final
play no role in determining the gas price. If Continental European product. For instance, the price received by the gas supplier
or Asian buyers see the oil linked prices they pay for long term from the power sector may be set in relation to, and allowed to
gas or LNG falling out of line with the supply and demand fluctuate with, the price of electricity. Netback based pricing is
driven prices on the gas exchanges that are emerging, or on the also common where the gas is used as a feedstock for chemical
global spot LNG market, customers will switch to short term production, such as ammonia or methanol, and represents the
gas to the extent they can, with contract price adjustments as major variable cost in producing the product.
a possible result.
This mechanism should not be confused with contractual
Chart 4.2 shows the possible prices under the oil price escalation arrangements whereby the price to the producer/wholesaler
mechanism is ‘netted back’ from the wholesale gas prices in countries
further downstream. A netback arrangement such as this would
Chart 4.2: Pricing under oil escalation be categorised depending on how the wholesale gas price in
the downstream country is determined – through gas-on-gas
competition, oil price escalation, etc.
Oil price escalation
Price
Supply = Direct gas price regulation remains widespread. It would however
Demand Marginal Cost
be unhelpful to lump all kinds of regulation together. We need
P2 to distinguish between the principles applied by the regulator.
P1 Average
P3
Cost Under cost of service based regulation the price is determined,
or approved, by a regulatory authority, or possibly a Ministry,
so as to cover the “cost of service”, including the recovery of
investment and a reasonable rate of return, in the same way as
pipeline service tariffs are regulated in the US. Normally, cost
V2 V1 V3 Volume of service based prices are published by the regulatory authority.
Pakistan provides an example of cost of service based prices,
with the wellhead price being the target.
The gas price under oil price escalation will likely be above the
market-clearing price if oil prices are very high, and below if Prices may also be regulated on an irregular social and political
oil prices are very low. Thus by summer 2008, when oil prices basis reflecting the regulator’s perceptions of social needs and/or
were in the $120-130/bbl range, gas prices may have been gas supply cost developments, or possibly as a revenue raising
close to P2, while at low oil prices they could be around P3. If exercise for the government. In all probability the gas company
oil prices are in the fuel-switching range, the oil indexed gas would be state-owned.
prices will presumably be close to P1.
Many Non-OECD countries still practice below cost regulation,
Bilateral monopoly negotiations were the dominant pricing meaning that the gas price is knowingly set below the sum of
mechanism in interstate gas dealings in the former ‘East Bloc’ production and transportation costs as a form of state subsidy to
including the Former Soviet Union (FSU) and Central and the population. Again the gas company would be state-owned.
Eastern Europe. The gas price was determined for a period of
time – typically one year – through bilateral negotiations at In some countries where a substantial proportion of indigenous
government level. There were often elements of barter with gas supply comes from oil fields with gas caps or gas-condensate
the buyers paying for portions of their gas supply in transit fields, the marginal cost of producing this gas may be close to
services or by participating in field development and pipeline zero and as such it could be sold at a very low wholesale price
building projects. and still be ‘profitable’. However, to the extent it is sold below
the average cost of production and transportation it would still
The underlying valuation of the gas, the capital goods and the be included in the regulation below cost category.

16  International Gas Union | June 2011


The extreme form of below cost regulation is to provide the gas Under bilateral monopoly or netback pricing situations the price
free of charge to the population and industry, e.g., as a feedstock could, in theory, be higher or lower than the market-clearing
for chemical and fertilizer plants. Free gas is typically associated price P1. In practice, as will be shown later, prices under these
gas treated as a by-product with the liquids covering the costs mechanisms in 2005 were probably close to the P5 level, i.e.
of bringing the gas to the wellhead. The gas supplier must still just above or below average cost.
somehow finance transportation and distribution costs cross-
subsidising local gas supply from his oil or gas export revenues, With below cost regulation the gas price could be at P4, that
or the government must provide funding from the budget. is, materially below the average cost. Under cost of service
regulation the price would most likely be slightly above the
As hoc and below cost price regulation, and free gas supply, average cost at P5. Regulation on social and political grounds
is only thinkable when domestic gas supply is in the hands of would likely lead to a price somewhere in the range between
one or more state companies. P4 and P5. In all cases, the price is likely to be below the
market-clearing price P1.
Chart 4.3 illustrates pricing under bilateral monopoly negotiations,
with netback pricing and under various types of regulation.

Chart 4.3: Pricing under regulation

Bilateral monopoly, netback pricing,


regulation
Supply =
Demand Marginal Cost
Price

P1 Average
P5 Cost

P4

V1 V5 V4 Volume

June 2011 | International Gas Union  17 


5. Origins of individual pricing mechanisms

The main dividing line with respect to gas pricing runs between shocks, increased wellhead gas prices 15-fold between the
market based pricing where buyers are charged above or in line beginning of the 1970s and 1984. US pipeline companies saw
with supply costs, and regulated pricing where buyers may be opportunities and contracted heavily for new long term supply.
charged below supply costs. However, US gas demand proving unexpectedly sensitive to
higher prices and sluggish economic growth dipped by more
Origins of gas or oil market based pricing than one quarter in the in the 14 years between 1972 and 1986.
The resulting gas ‘bubble’ arrested wellhead prices and pushed
The countries that practice market based gas pricing have them back into the USD 1,60-1,70 per mcf range.
opted for different models because of differences in the level
and degree of concentration of their gas resources, in addition FERC Orders 380 and 436 in the mid 1980s completed the
to different historically and ideologically rooted preferences. liberalisation of the US gas market by allowing first utilities
Countries with significant gas resources dispersed in large and then other customers to contract directly with producers
numbers of fields typically saw the development of com- at market prices, and have the gas transported to their sites on
petitive industries and the early emergence of the physical pipelines subject to third party access regulation.
and institutional preconditions for gas market based pricing.
Countries with limited or zero gas resources of their own The UK
could not as easily develop gas industries with multiple sel-
lers and buyers. These countries instead tended to encourage The UK gas industry was nationalised in 1948. The UK at
the emergence of national or regional import monopolies that that time neither produced nor imported any natural gas.
could interact on an equal footing with a limited number of However, there were more than 1000 manufactured gas com-
major foreign suppliers. Market value pricing was a response panies – some private, the other municipally owned – that
to the need for risk sharing to underpin the building of were vested into 12 so-called area gas boards. In 1959 LNG
markets from scratch with the gas coming from major import imports commenced on a trial basis. In 1964 the government
contracts. started to issue North Sea E&D licences. In 1965 the first
natural gas discoveries were made. In 1966 the government
North America decided to introduce natural gas into the UK fuel mix on a
big scale.
US gas production has always involved a number of compa- The 1972 Gas Act paved the way for further centralisation of
nies, and US gas prices have as a rule been determined com- the industry with the creation of the British Gas Corporation
petitively by supply and demand. For decades prices were (BGC). This entity was until 1986 the sole buyer of UKCS
very low, reflecting producer competition for very limited gas and the sole transmitter and distributor of this gas to UK
local markets. After World War 2 rapid expansion of the US customers. It was also a key upstream player.
pipeline system enabled a gradual absorption of the surplus
reserves. Wellhead prices were in these years set through negotiations
between BGC and the producers. BGC’s legal monopsony on
The Supreme Court Phillips Decision in 1954 ushered in a period UKCS gas purchases, and good grasp on upstream costs thanks
of wellhead price regulation that was to last for 24 years. The to its own UKCS interests, ensured prices that left little rent
regulation applied only to gas traded across state borders. Gas to the producers.
produced and consumed in the same state was not affected by
the decision. The Thatcher years saw a general, ideologically driven shift
from state involvement through major public enterprises in the
The wellhead price controls were of the historic E&D cost plus economy, towards private solutions. The gas sector exemplified
type. They stimulated gas demand but not investment in the this trend.
upstream and eventually led to gas shortages in those parts of
the US that depended on other states for their gas supply. The The 1982 Oil and Gas (Enterprise) Act permitted UKCS gas
Natural Gas Policy Act of 1978 sought to fix the imbalance by producers and major industrial customers to contract directly
deregulating high cost gas prices while retaining most interstate with each other, and ordered BGC to offer third party access
gas under price control and placing also intrastate gas under price to its pipelines. These first steps towards a liberalisation of the
regulation so as to eliminate the particular shortage problems of market failed to boost competition. The customers that producers
the ‘importing’ states. These steps however paved the way for a could now approach directly were too few, and BGC’s grip on
further dismantling of price controls in the years that followed. the market remained too strong. The next steps were however
Deregulation, and the impact of the first and second oil price more forceful. The 1986 Gas Act returned the gas industry to

18  International Gas Union | June 2011


the private sector, transformed BGC to British Gas Plc and customer level, buyers in individual countries were split into
created Ofgas to regulate the industry and protect the interests of individual market segments (typically the residential segment,
consumers. In 1989 Ofgas limited British Gas’ purchase of new the commercial segment, the industrial segment and the power
UKCS gas supply to 90% of full capacity production. During segment), a single price was calculated for each segment in each
the 1990s the right for producers and consumers to deal directly country, a weighted average end user price was calculated for each
with each other was extended first to mid-sized industrial and country, and transmission, storage and distribution costs were
commercial buyers, and then to the entire gas market. factored in to arrive at an initial border price for each country.

Through the 1990s gas prices in the UK were generally lower The initial – or start-up year – border price would be continuously
than gas prices in Continental Europe. Proponents of liberalisation adjusted in response to changes the prices of the fuels assumed
saw this as proof of the efficiency boosting effects of increased to be the closest competitors to gas, and the pricing formula
competition. However, prices were also influenced by a strong itself would be renegotiated from time to time in response to
increase in UKCS gas production that came from new discoveries changes in the relative importance of individual market segments
and steady, technology driven growth in depletion rates. The and other deeper shifts in the market.
relative impact of each of these drivers on price developments
is not easily calculated. While the market value principle placed the price risk in the
Groningen gas sales contracts with the seller, the take or pay
Continental Europe principle – another feature of these contracts – placed the
volume risk with the buyer. These provisions on risk sharing
The market value pricing principle that dominates in Conti- paved the way for rapid growth in Dutch gas exports and for a
nental Europe originated in the Netherlands. The Groningen rapid maturation of European gas markets. The latter effect was
field discovered in 1959 and put on-stream in 1964 presented accentuated when Algeria, Russia and Norway adopted both
the Dutch government with a marketing challenge. Western market value pricing and the TOP principle in their contracting
European gas consumption in 1965 was about 21 bcm a year with European gas buyers. .
. The Dutch themselves consumed a mere 1,8 Bcm a year2.
Continental European cross border gas trade was negligible. Asia Pacific
Thus Groningen had to be sold into a small and immature
market area. The government did not want to sell the field Japan was a 2 bcm a year gas market until 1970 when im-
cheaply, thus giving away value. Delaying its development ported (Alaskan) LNG entered the fuel mix. Import growth
seemed an equally unattractive option. There was a percepti- accelerated in the 1970s and 1980s in response to the first
on of urgency stemming from the emergence of a new source and second oil price shock. South Korea and Taiwan started
of energy – nuclear – that conceivably could shorten the era to import LNG in 1986 and 1990 respectively. Australia and
of fossil fuels. New Zealand – the two developed economies in the region
with indigenous gas reserves – started to exploit these reser-
In 1962 the then Dutch Minister of Economic Affairs suggested ves around 1970.
to base prices not on production costs which were low for
Groningen gas and would have left the government with limited The Asian countries that do not have significant domestic natural
revenues, but on the market or replacement value of the gas to resources and access to international pipeline networks and
individual market segment in individual countries. underground storages like Europe and the US, have come to
rely almost 100% on imported LNG for their natural gas supply.
Specifically, the idea was that the price of Groningen gas to The largest importers, Japanese LNG buyers, are gas and power
a given customer should be based on the price of the best companies carrying out business in an integrated manner,
alternative to Groningen gas – typically heavy fuel or gas oil from procurement and imports to transmission, distribution,
– for that customer. downstream gas and power supply and marketing. When they
first initiated discussions on potential LNG imports, they had
The price of Groningen gas should not be mechanically aligned to emphasize long-term security of supply to make sure that
with the price of the best alternative. On the one hand rebates they would be able to fulfil their supply obligation to end-users.
could be necessary to encourage customers that did not already At the same time, since LNG projects require enormous initial
use Groningen gas to start doing so, and discourage existing investments on the seller’s side, the latter needed security of
customers from switching back to competing fuels. The rebates demand, meaning long-term and stable offtake by buyers. Sellers
to attract new customers might need to be substantial if switching and buyers thus had a common interest in long-term and stable
would require investment in new heating systems. On the other relationships. Commercial LNG projects have been developed
hand, due consideration should be paid to the convenience of based on cooperative arrangements, and this is reflected in the
burning gas compared to oil products, potentially giving rise history of LNG pricing as well.
to a price premium. In 1969 when LNG was first imported into Japan, and through the
Since it is not possible to price discriminate at individual early 1970s, the price was fixed. This suited the suppliers since
they could recover their huge initial investment with certainty.
2
BP Statistical Review of World Energy, 2008
Fixed prices also enabled them to lock in the economics of their

June 2011 | International Gas Union  19 


LNG project, which was an immature business at that time. relied on oil thermal power plants for 70% of their power supply.
Since the price of oil – the main alternative fuel to Japanese Therefore, it was a reasonable decision for them to make LNG
buyers – was rather stable, a fixed pricing system was acceptable pricing competitive against oil. For Japanese gas companies, the
to Japanese LNG buyers as well. main competing fuels were oil products such as kerosene for
After the first oil shock in 1973, however, the oil price surge heating and fuel oil for industrial use. Hence indexation to oil
left the price of LNG significantly lower than that of oil. In was to an extent acceptable to them too. JCC is used as index
response to requirements from suppliers, the price of LNG were since it is calculated from data in Japan Exports & Imports
gradually raised in line with the price of oil. These LNG price Monthly published by Japan Tariff Association, and therefore
increases were, after the second oil shock in 1980, codified into can be considered a credible, transparent and neutral index.
a formula based on the concept of “oil parity pricing”. At that In the 1990s, the generally low oil price environment caused
time, the Government Selling Price (“GSP”) was applied as LNG suppliers to suffer from deteriorating project economics.
index in the formula. Although different crudes were utilized, In response to suppliers’ call for a helping hand, a new pricing
most LNG prices were 100% indexed to the GSP price. mechanism with lower slopes at very low or very high oil
As the OPEC countries’ share of global oil production went into prices – the so-called S-curve – was introduced (Chart 5.2).
decline, oil turned from a strategic product into a commodity. Later, when the LNG industry started to suffer from the impact
In response to that change, some countries started to sell oil of sluggish demand related to the Asian currency crisis in the
at prices that differed from the GSP, and market prices were late 1990s, some buyers obtained price floors and ceilings as
gradually established. Since the GSP was left unmodified, the an extension of the S-curve mechanism.
LNG price indexed to the GSP fell out of line with market
realities. Furthermore, after the 1986 oil price collapse, suppliers Chart 5.2: LNG pricing with S-curve
selling LNG at oil parity prices ran into difficulties securing
the economics of their LNG projects. In order to cope with that
problem, the LNG pricing formula was modified again through LNG indexed to oil: S-curve
negotiations into a new price formula, which became the basis
LNG price
for the current formula. $/MMBTU kink-
Today, most Asian LNG transactions except those that involve points
Indonesian LNG apply the weighted average price of oil imported
into Japan (the Japanese Crude Cocktail, JCC) as index. The
price formula is generally as follows:

Y (LNG price : $/MMBtu) = A x (oil price : $/bbl) + B


?
By applying this type of formula, the LNG price is indexed to ? Oil price
low oil high oil $/BBL
the realized oil price (import price). The exposure to the oil price zone price zone
price (JCC) is reduced to 80 to 90% through “A”, and a con-
stant “B” makes the LNG price more stable than the oil price
(Chart 5.1). It also enables suppliers to secure economics of As oil prices rebounded, LNG contracts with a lower slope became
LNG projects since a certain amount of income are secured hugely advantageous to buyers. At the same time, however, LNG
even when the oil price is low. market tightness resulted in sellers’ market conditions and in
the abolishment of the S-curve in some contracts.
Chart 5.1: LNG pricing with no floor or ceiling
Origins of regulated gas pricing
LNG indexed to oil with no floor, ceiling Regulated gas pricing may mean cost of service based pricing
as well as political pricing where costs may be considered but
LNG price generally play second fiddle to political and social concerns.
$/MMBTU Old price formula
Oil Parity
Regulated gas pricing with long term marginal supply costs
playing a minor role requires as a rule state companies in the
Modified price formula
85-90% indexed to oil lead, at least from the start. Building a gas industry dominated
by private players on the basis of below cost prices would
likely be challenging. There are examples of state oil and gas
companies being part privatised with gas prices to end users
Oil price remaining under below cost regulation, but such combinations
$/BBL tend to create tensions and lead to calls – from, among other
quarters, the part privatised companies in charge – for price reform.
In Japan, LNG was introduced in order to reduce an at that Cost-plus pricing is practiced in different ways in different
time excessive dependency on oil. Japanese power companies countries. Cost-plus pricing and market based pricing may exist

20  International Gas Union | June 2011


side by side with households and vulnerable industries benefiting the so-called Gas Linkage Committee to ensure that sufficient
from regulations while industries with a bigger choice of fuels gas was allocated to priority consumers – namely the fertiliser
and suppliers are exposed to market based prices. Another industry and the power sector – at subsidised prices.
recurrent feature is that wellhead prices are set on a competitive
basis while transmission and distribution tariffs are regulated. The Gulf war seriously weakened the Indian economy and
forced the government to turn to the IMF, the World Bank and
Cost based pricing shifts the rent in the affected links of the the Asian Development Bank for support. These institutions
value chain to the consumers and may as such boost gas market typically request policy reform in return for loans, and in
growth – at least for a while. But cost based pricing tends to the case of India they made support conditional on the state
discourage efficiency improvements along the supply chain, reducing its involvement in select sectors, among them the
and even households and vulnerable industries may be offered hydrocarbons sector. In response the government introduced the
alternatives to regulated gas. Thus sooner or later the insensitivity ew Exploration and Licensing Policy (NELP) and – eventually
of cost based pricing to changes in the competitive landscape – the multi-tiered pricing system described in chapter 3. In the
may leave the gas priced this way unmarketable. beginning, however, the producer price was fixed on the basis
of a particular committee’s estimate of the long run marginal
On the other hand, since cost based pricing may not provide very costs of gas production. The decision to index the price of gas at
strong incentives to invest in fields and pipelines, growth in gas landfall points to a basket of fuel oil prices was made in 1990.
supply may fall behind growth in gas demand at regulated prices.
In Latin America cost based pricing was the rule until the
Both these developments may pave the way for awarding a early 1990s. Argentina then de-controlled wellhead prices
bigger role to market based pricing, and have indeed triggered with regulator Enargas continuing to regulate transmission
a number of price reform efforts around the world. and distribution tariffs. These were originally set to ensure
a fair return on investments in pipelines and other facilities,
China is not one integrated gas market. China has multiple but emergency legislation passed in the wake of Argentina’s
regional markets that traditionally have received supply from economic crisis in the early 2000s authorised the government
different production areas at different costs, with different prices to re-impose price and exchange controls, with the result that
as a result. These characteristics are gradually giving way to tariffs and prices in dollar terms dropped significantly.
those of a more integrated market. Rapid construction of new
long distance pipelines will give sellers access to a bigger In 2004 Argentinean authorities and the country’s main gas
variety of buyers and buyers access to a bigger variety of sellers. producers agreed on a schedule for partially lifting the price
freeze, but progress has been limited, although more recently
In China as in other centrally planned economies, gas prices producers and large industrial and power sector end users have
were historically used for accounting purposes rather than for been free to negotiate prices.
resource allocation purposes. Gas produced under the national
plan was priced differently from gas produced outside the Brazil in 2002 liberalised gas prices but continues to regulate prices
national plan. End user prices differed not only by region but to qualifying gas power plants. Regulator ANP sets transportation
also by consumption sector; thus the fertiliser industry paid less tariffs on a cost of service basis. Petrobras’ dominating role in
than other industry. Neither the complexity and rigidity of the the upstream and continued hold on the transmission link limits
gas price structure not the fact that many prices did not cover the role of competition in gas price formation, with wholesale
supply costs encouraged gas E&D. On the other hand, gas was gas prices now increasingly following oil prices.
much more expensive in energy equivalence terms than coal.
This prevented gas penetration into the power sector and other Below cost pricing was a hallmark of the 20th century’s centrally
sectors where coal was an option. planned economies. In the FSU, prices served accounting
purposes only. They were not supposed to carry signals between
Cost plus pricing is still the rule but procedures are being market actors and drive resource allocation decisions. Instead
streamlined and standardised. Also an element of competitive hierarchies of plans provided volume targets reflecting the
pricing is introduced. Wholesale buyers are allowed to negotiate prevailing prioritisation between society’s different needs,
directly with suppliers. and the planners’ attempts to optimise under all kinds of
constraints related to the unwieldiness of the productive sectors.
In India decision makers started to take an interest in gas The centrally planned economies’ bias towards heavy, energy
only in the mid 1980s. Consumption was by then around 4,5 intensive industries favoured low accounting prices. Ordinary
bcm a year. In 1984 the Gas Authority of India Ltd. (GAIL) people were offered a meagre selection of consumer goods but
was established to manage the development of a genuine gas in return received free education and health care, and cheap
market. In 1986 GAIL began the construction of the 2688 km housing and other goods including gas.
Hazira-Bijapur-Jagdishpur pipeline to give major fuel users
in the interior of the country access to gas discovered along The former ‘East Bloc’ included a string of countries that
the west coast. Supply via this pipeline fell short of demand received Russian gas in return for pipeline construction or transit
almost from the start. In response the government established services under the division of labour within the Comecon area,

June 2011 | International Gas Union  21 


or cheaply for political reasons. In general terms, constructions legitimacy of rentier state governments dictates generosity in
like the Comecon area need arrangements for their sustainability, the provision of basic goods and services including fuels and
and one arrangement underpinning Russia’s authority within electricity. Positive price and availability incentives to switch
the this area was Moscow’s provision of cheap gas and other to gas appeared much safer.
commodities to its neighbours.
Though Iranian gas use (net of reinjection) increased by 10,5% a
East Europe has moved away from below cost pricing and the year between 1991 and 2006, domestic oil consumption growth
FSU republics are implementing price reform. The countries that continued to outpace oil production growth. The country’s
have opted to retain gas price regulation at below cost levels, position as a major oil exporter came under increasing pressure.
at least for now, are the North African and Middle Eastern oil Iranian rulers have therefore since the 1990s intensified efforts
producers and exporters. to make fuel users switch from oil products to gas by providing
for continuous growth in the gas grid and keeping domestic gas
Oil producers typically have associated gas at their disposal. In prices at very low levels.
the past associated gas was vented, flared or at best reinjected.
Though flaring continues in some countries, globally much of the Saudi Arabia has also maintained the domestic gas price at a
gas that was wasted is now harvested, processed and marketed. very low level for a very long time. Between 2001 and 2008
As a free good at the wellhead, associated gas is low cost gas. It no material adjustments have taken place. Saudi Arabia has
can be supplied economically at prices covering only transmission come under pressure internationally for its highly subsidized
and distribution costs. Alternatively it can be supplied at even prices. Trade partners have protested that the country – now
lower prices or for free with an (at least initially) manageable a full member of the WTO – is unfairly supporting Saudi
subsidisation burden falling on the state. Problems arise only industries and utilities.
when gas demand starts exceeding associated gas supply, i.e.,
when need arises for much more expensive non-associated gas. In an attempt to address the main distortions in the domestic
gas sector, Saudi Arabia recently adopted a new pricing policy
Iran began harnessing associates gas in the 1960s and Saudi that could herald real price reform. In 2006, the local Eastern
Arabia followed suit with the construction of the Master Gas Gas Company was awarded a two-year contract to become
System in the late 1970s. Both countries, and eventually others Aramco’s gas distributor to consumers in the Dhahran industrial
in the region, funded gas infrastructure investments from their area. According to industry reports, its purchase price from
oil export revenues. The rulers’ main motivation was to contain Aramco will be USD 1,12 per MMBtu and its sale price USD
the growth in domestic oil consumption. This could have been 1,34/MMBtu. In Riyadh, the Natural Gas Distribution Company
done in different ways, probably most efficiently by raising was granted a license to supply small-scale manufacturing plants
domestic oil product prices. Oil price reform could however under a similar pricing structure. For the time being, the price
have triggered political and social unrest. The nature of the for foreign investors and other consumers remains unchanged.

22  International Gas Union | June 2011


Chart 7.43: Wholesale prices by price formation 2007 Parts of the world are in transit between gas pricing mechanisms.
Others are trying to fix problems with their existing mechanisms
without plunging into the unknowns of all-out system reform.
Wholesale prices by price formation
Yet others do not envisage significant changes, either because
mechanism 2007
there are no perceptions of tensions calling for release measures,
$8,00
or because there are no perceptions of better models, or because
$7,00
the risks of reform are considered too high.
$6,00

$5,00
Sellers’, buyers’ and regulators’ preferences with respect
$/MMBTU

$4,00
to retaining, adjusting or replacing pricing mechanisms are
$3,00
influenced by a number of factors:
$2,00

$1,00
• Relative efficiency in resource allocation terms of alternative
$0,00 mechanisms
OPE GOG BIM NET RCS RSP RBC TOT
• Price outlook under alternative mechanisms
• Long term gas supply and demand consequences of alternative
There have been some changes in the relative importance of mechanisms
the different price formation mechanisms between 2005 and • Price volatility under alternative mechanisms
2007, but much of it was due to changing consumption patterns • Price risk mitigation opportunities in alternative mechanisms
with the main switching between categories occurring with • Budgetary and macroeconomic consequences of alternative
moves away from OPE to GOG as spot LNG trade increased mechanisms
and trading hubs developed in Europe. • Political risks of moving away from existing mechanisms
• Other transition costs

8. Trends in the extensiveness of individual


pricing mechanisms

Efficiency arguments are typically heard from proponents of The only firm – but also rather trivial – conclusion that can be
gas-on-gas competition based pricing. Only when gas prices made on the relationship between gas pricing model and gas
are allowed to reflect gas supply and demand will the socially price level, is that a shift from subsidised to unsubsidised prices
optimal amount of resources flow to the gas sector relative to will push prices up.
other worthy causes.
The long term impact of alternative pricing mechanisms on
The outlook for gas prices is on everybody’s mind, and different gas supply and demand has been a hot topic in particular in
pricing models may deliver different prices. However, the Europe. Observers, and the gas industry itself, in 2008 noted the
importance of this factor will vary, and while one model may incongruence between the need for gas to remain the preferred
be the most (least) attractive from a seller’s (buyer’s) point of fuel to the power sector if we were to see further growth in
view under one set of circumstances, it may score differently overall demand, and the disincentives that oil linked gas prices
under another set of circumstances. at USD 100-150/b oil represented to the dispatching of existing
and the building of new gas power plants.
In 2008 Continental European and Asian oil linked prices
outpaced North American gas-to-gas competition based prices. On the other hand, demand destruction first became a big issue
Again this may be seen as proof of the gas industry advantages, in the US following the gas price spike in 2005, and the supply
and consumer disadvantages, of oil linked gas pricing. But boosting impact of the post 2000 price gas price environment
there have been periods in this decade when the relationship is nowhere more obvious than in the US. So again it is not so
has been the opposite. that one pricing model necessarily represents a bigger threat to
future gas demand, and a bigger encouragement to future gas
Another observation is that at least over long periods of time supply, than another.
oil linked and gas-on-gas competition based prices tend to
move pretty much in parallel due to links provided by interfuel Gas price volatility is generally seen to be a problem mainly for
competition and international gas trade. actors in liberalised markets with gas-on-gas competition based
pricing. And indeed, Europe’s and Asia’s oil linked prices are

42  International Gas Union | June 2011


less volatile, reflecting the way the indices are defined. With buyers with minimal regulatory interference (apart from tariff
gas prices set to reflect the average of oil prices over a period control of the natural monopoly elements in the supply chain,
of time many months prior to delivery, short term peaks and aka the transmission link) seems to be widely perceived as an
troughs are automatically smoothened out. end state without more efficient alternatives.

However, apart from the fact that price volatility to many actors Continental Europe
represents opportunities rather than problems, it might not be
very difficult to shape the price clause in a contract based on With respect to Continental Europe, the EU commission’s
gas indexation so as to obtain the same smoothening effect. electricity and gas liberalisation agendas reflect the view that
the incumbents dominating electricity and gas supply and
To decision makers in countries with heavily regulated gas cross-border trade in Europe have exploited their monopolist
markets where prices are adjusted as rarely as possible, the or oligopolist positions to secure unreasonable margins for
volatility aspect may nevertheless seem a strong deterrent to themselves instead of delivering maximum benefits to the
convert directly to gas-to-gas competition based pricing. consumers. In any event, it is argued, the incumbents need to
be exposed to competition to stay efficient.
Price risk mitigation opportunities become indispensable as
price volatility increases. When demand for such tools arises, Specifically, the commission’s initiatives have aimed at securing
banks and similar institutions normally rush in to provide them. access at equitable terms to Europe’s electricity and gas grids
However, a limited availability of risk mitigation opportunities for new players, loosening the grip of long term take or pay
in the early phases of market liberalisation may contribute to contracts, and pave the way for gas-to-gas competition based
the resistance that proposals to shift from one pricing model pricing as an alternative to oil indexed pricing.
to another typically encounter.
The Commission’s priorities are being shared to varying
The budgetary and macroeconomic consequences of leaving gas degrees by the EU member states’ governments and commercial
pricing mechanisms as they are, or embarking on reform, and actors. Individual member state positions differ because their
the inevitable political risks of reform, need to be considered incumbent gas companies differ in interests and influence, and
in those countries that practice below cost regulation. Fuel because views on the optimal extent of regulation of economic
subsidies are weighing heavily on many emerging economies’ life, and the proper influence of Brussels on national policy
budgets. The IEA estimated for its World Energy Outlook 2008 making, still vary a lot.
that gas subsidies in 2007 cost the Russian state close to USD
30 billion and the Iranian state more than USD 15 billion. Even Moreover, positions are changing in response to changes in the
the oil exporting countries that recently benefitted from record context and to the surfacing of new issues. During the 1990s
high prices feel the pinch. On the other hand, raising domestic signs of global warming triggered a debate on the sustainability
fuel prices too quickly might boost inflation and trigger political of policies to bring down fuel prices by providing for more
and social unrest. competition in the fuel sectors, given the environmental
downsides of continued fuel consumption growth. In recent
Finally there may be other transition costs related to the years gas supply security concerns have triggered a debate on the
dismantling of old institutions and the establishment of new compatibility of open access to gas infrastructure, a shortening
ones, the teaching of new rules of the game to market actors of contracts and prices set through gas to gas competition with
and regulators and possible dislocations in the transition period the required fast growth in investments in increasingly remote
from the old systems stops functioning properly to the new one upstream options and expensive midstream solutions.
starts working.
As for the commercial actors, with oil prices at record levels and
Clearly the drivers for switching to other pricing models, and with a series of new gas import facilities under construction or
thus the likelihood that changes will take place, differ strongly at the drawing board, as of 2008 Europe’s gas suppliers seemed
from region to region: to believe that oil linked prices will hold up better than gas-on-
gas competition based prices.
North America and the UK
Another factor is the remaining lack of trust in Europe’s gas
In the US, Canada and the UK that have adopted gas-on-gas hubs as sources of reliable price information. Apart from the
competition as the pricing mechanism there are virtually no UK’s National Balancing Point (which though significant is
calls for shifts to other mechanisms. There is concern about the dwarfed by the US’ Henry Hub), European hubs remain small
level of price volatility, and a debate involving market actors, and thinly traded. Illiquidity spells unpredictability and entails
regulators, politicians and observers about how to deal with the a risk of market manipulation. In contrast, the markets for
harmful effects of price spikes and troughs. But there is little the crude oils and refined products are vast, liquid and well
talk about a return to more regulation or for a shift to some understood by everybody involved.
variation on the market value pricing theme. As such, gas price
determination through multiple sellers competing for multiple Thus, while there has been considerable movement on the grid

June 2011 | International Gas Union  43 


access issue, there is for the moment strong interest in retaining cheap LNG, but since Indonesia’s supply challenges became
oil linked pricing. European gas market players have also put manifest their main interest has again been to secure volumes.
up a strong fight on the principle of long term contracts.
The Japanese gas market has traditionally been highly fragmented
Testifying to the continued sympathy for oil linked pricing, with regional monopolies tolerating no competition within their
Gazprom in 2006-07 renewed a string of major gas sales concession areas and refraining from going for customers in
agreements with Western European buyers on oil terms. neighbouring regions. This is changing, with the revised Gas
Utility Law in Japan providing for third party access to LNG
Sellers’ and buyers’ perceptions of the pros and cons of alternative terminals and pipelines. Also, customers using in excess of
contract forms and pricing models are not set in stone. Gas-on- 100,000 cm of gas a year are now allowed to negotiate their
gas competition based pricing will likely gain ground as more own prices with suppliers. But regulatory reform is only the
hubs mature. Additionally coal indexation could come to be first step towards a level playing field and real competition.
seen as an alternative. The fact remains that the gas industry
needs to look to a sector where oil is no longer an interesting The changes that are occurring in Asian LNG import and gas
alternative for further growth opportunities (Chart 8.1). Gas end user pricing are changes within the paradigm of oil linked
prices mirroring record high oil prices could as noted stop that prices. As the Asian LNG market tightened, the gas price–oil
growth in its tracks. price curve steepened towards full parity in energy equivalence
terms between LNG and crude oil import prices. Also the S
Chart 8.1: Electricity generation by source in IEA Europe shape of the curve that Japanese buyers prefer – i.e., the ceiling
offering protection to the buyer if oil prices should increase above
a preset level and the floor offering protection to the seller if
IEA Europe: Electricity generation by source, oil prices should become too low – came under pressure. The
1973-2004
financial crisis and the current outlook for slower growth in LNG
100 %
90 %
demand in a period when much new LNG will come on the
80 % market, have reversed these trends but not affected the oil link.
Others
70 % Hydro
60 % Nuclear However, the globalisation of the LNG business, the growth
50 % 1974: Oil
share 25%
Gas in LNG spot transactions as a share of total LNG sales and
40 % Oil
30 % Coal
purchases (Chart 8.2) and in the future the emergence of LNG
2004: Oil share 4%
20 % transactions across the Pacific will shape Asian buyers’ pricing
10 % habits too. Kogas uses the spot market to manage seasonal
0%
swing in Korea’s gas demand. As a result of several nuclear
1974 1980 1990 2000 2004
incidents, since 2006 also Japanese buyers have been active
Source: IEA in the spot market. Japan in 2007 had to compete on price for
around 20% its total LNG supply. For the moment (1st quarter
This being said, the transformation of the Continental European 2009) Asian buyers are not very active in the LNG spot market
gas market will neither be fast nor proceed at the same pace but demand could bounce back once the financial crisis is over.
across countries. Gas market based pricing, oil linked pricing and Asian buyers will then need to reckon with Henry Hub and the
formulae involving links to inflation, to coal or to electricity (the NBP – i.e., indirectly with supply and demand conditions in
“spark spread”) will likely continue to coexist for many years. North America and Europe – as references that sometimes kick
in as floors, other times as ceilings.
Asia Pacific
Chart 8.2: Asian LNG importers’ spot purchases
The established Asian LNG importers are sticking to crude oil
indexation as the dominant imported gas pricing mechanism.
Gas-on-gas competition based pricing is not a target. Gas mar- Established Asian LNG importers' spot
purchases, 1995-2007
ket based pricing is for the time being not an option other than 25
for spot cargos anyway since the OECD Pacific gas markets Taiwan
are characterised by limited competition and have no gas hubs. 20
Korea
Japan
15
The Japanese gas and power utilities, Kogas and Taiwan’s CPC
Bcm

have traditionally paid more than European and North American 10

buyers for their LNG imports. This is mainly because of their 5


traditional preoccupation with supply security and ability to pass
the costs of added security on to their customers. Japanese end -

user prices, to take them as an example, have been regulated by


96

98

00

01

03

05
95

97

99

02

04

06

07
19

19

20

20

20

20
19

19

19

20

20

20

20

the Ministry of Economy, Trade and Industry on a cost plus basis.


Some of these companies campaigned for lower prices in the early Source: PIRA, defining spot purchases as including contracts up to four years

2000s, in response to India’s and China’s successes in securing

44  International Gas Union | June 2011


Non OECD to the producers if they had exported it instead, and there is
In countries where gas end user prices are set below supply costs every reason to believe that this process will be completed, if
and where the government is able to ensure that gas demand not necessarily on schedule.
growth is accommodated by supply growth, gas subsidisation
may increase to the point of representing a serious drain on Other gas producers are proceeding more carefully. They can
the budget. According to IEA estimates, gas subsidisation is hold back for a while but not necessarily forever.
an issue for Iran, Russia, Ukraine, Kazakhstan, Pakistan and
Argentina in particular (Chart 8.3). China and India face the dilemma that if gas is to become a key
fuel to the power sector, and not just a marginal fuel for peak
Chart 8.3: Energy subsidies by fuel in non-OECD countries, 2007 load generation, and if imported gas is to become an important
part of the supply picture, coal prices need to be raised to make
gas competitive.
Energy subsidies by fuel in non-OECD countries, 2007
While the Middle East’s and North Africa’s needs for gas for
power generation and desalination is booming, the two regions’
associated gas production is typically stagnant or declining,
forcing governments to add non-associated gas to domestic
gas supply to make ends meet. Since non-associated gas
developments require upstream investments and carry much
higher costs than associated gas, this aggravates the budgetary
consequences of continued gas subsidisation.

In the late 1990s when oil prices dipped below USD 10 a


barrel and the oil exporters ran up record trade and fiscal
Source: IEA: World Energy Outlook 2008 deficits, a preparedness to discuss domestic price reform could
be detected across a range of gas producing countries. Saudi
Gas subsidisation takes a particularly heavy toll in periods Arabia, Venezuela and others that took steps to involve IOCs
of extraordinary high international gas prices like 2007 and in non-associated gas E&D needed to make the economics of
2008. Countries that import or need to start importing gas find involvement look viable. However, as oil prices have rebounded
it increasingly hard in such periods to sustain domestic price and the oil exporters are again accumulating trade and fiscal
freezes or very slow price adjustment schedules. surpluses, the “gas openings” of the late 1990s/early 2000s
seem have lost momentum.
While domestic pricing options narrowed for a number of gas
importing countries, they widened in 2007-08 for some oil and Towards a globalisation of gas pricing?
gas producers and exporters. These countries had spending
powers then that they did not have in the late 1990s, and may International gas trade serves to align prices across countries
have felt emboldened to continue ignoring recommendations and – possibly – continents. This is, simply speaking, because
to dismantle subsidy arrangements. trade allows gas to flow from the areas with the lowest prices
to the areas with the highest prices (adjusted for differences
The financial crisis has in a sense reversed the situation. Gas in transportation costs; it is the netback that drives sellers’
has become more affordable and the subsidisation of gas end prioritisation between markets). In the former areas the gas supply
user prices has become less burdensome in absolute terms. curve shifts to the left, up the demand curve. In the latter areas
However, oil and gas exporters need to cope with mounting the supply curve shifts to the right, down the demand curve.
current account and budget deficits and may be less able to
sustain subsidies now than before the crisis broke – and since The most interesting countries in this context are those that
the crisis has weakened not only oil and gas prices but most enter the global marketplace with lower domestic prices than
commodity prices, all countries on the IEA’s list are probably international prices. The importers in this group then come under
now facing bigger subsidy burdens relative to their ability to pay. pressure to raise domestic prices not to be left with unsellable
imported gas or increased subsidisation commitments. The
Governments as a rule respond in two ways: by liberalising exporters come under pressure to raise domestic prices because
prices to select, presumably robust, customers, and by raising of the losses incurred by supplying domestic users at below
remaining regulated prices to the extent politically possible. opportunity costs, and/or because unconstrained growth in
Typically, households and important industries such as the domestic consumption could choke exports off.
fertilizer sector continue to enjoy some protection.
International gas trade is growing. BP estimates that in volume
Russia – the world’s biggest gas producer and exporter – has terms, world gas imports and exports increased from 335 Bcm
embarked on a process of aligning domestic prices with the in 1992 to 776 Bcm in 2007 or by an average of 5,8% a year.
opportunity costs of selling the gas at home, i.e., with the netback As a share of world gas consumption – which only increased by

June 2011 | International Gas Union  45 


2,5% a year in this period – imports and exports nearly doubled Chart 8.4: LNG imports and exports by country
between 1992 and 2008.
LNG imports by country LNG exports by country
Continental Europe’s interfacing with other market structures 1964-2007 1964-2007
has considerably modified its price dynamics. The opening of
Mexico
250 250
China
Norway

the Interconnector gas pipeline in October 1998 created a link


India Eq. Guinea
Dom.Rep. Egypt
200 200

between the oil-indexed North European gas markets and the


Puerto Rico Oman
Portugal Trinidad

liberalised UK market. The UK’s seasonal demand and relatively


Greece Nigeria
150 150
Turkey Qatar

Bcm

Bcm
flat production created arbitrage opportunities for continental
Taiwan Australia
South Korea Malaysia
100 100
buyers who could buy UK spot gas instead of contract gas Germany
Belgium
Indonesia
Abu Dhabi

within their Take or Pay (TOP) – Annual Contract Quantity 50


Italy
USA 50
Brunei
Libya

(ACQ) ranges and use storage to further optimise their positions. Spain
Japan
US
Algeria
0 France 0
UK
6 4 68 72 76 80 84 88 92 9 6 0 0 0 4

04
19 4
19 8
72

19 6
19 0
19 4
19 8
92

20 6
20 0
1 9 1 9 1 9 1 9 1 9 1 9 1 9 1 9 19 20 20
This development looks set to continue. Several new import-export

8
8
8

9
0
6

7
19

19
19
pipelines are under construction or nearing the construction stage. Source: Cedigaz

Unsurprisingly, Europe which its large, dynamic, oil linked and


increasingly integrated gas markets, and its location in between The growth in US LNG imports in the early 2000s and the
half a dozen or so of leading gas producers and exporters, is the reemergence since 2005 of the UK as an LNG importer meant
target of a multitude of pipeline projects. Examples on Europe’s additional opportunities and price influences for Continental
eastern borders include the Russian North and South Stream European gas buyers:
pipelines, and Nabucco, the IGI project and the TAP project
that compete among themselves and with South Stream for • Contract LNG diverted to US/UK markets: At times when
supply from the Caspian and Gulf areas. Further to the south, Henry Hub was higher than European contract prices, France
one new Algerian export pipeline – Medgaz to Spain – is close and Spain were able to sell contracted LNG in the US and
to completion, and another – Galsi to Italy – is going forward, obtain ‘back-fill’ volumes by increasing offtake under their
Libya is planning to extend the capacity of its Green Stream long-term pipeline gas contracts within the TOP – ACQ band.
pipeline, and Egypt’s Arab Gas Pipeline has reached Syria and • Flexible LNG diverted from US/UK markets: When Continental
could, depending on the availability of gas for pipeline exports, European oil indexed prices have exceeded Henry Hub or
be extended to Lebanon and Turkey. In the more distant future the NBP price, LNG intended for delivery to the US or the
a pipeline could link Nigeria and Europe via Algeria. UK may instead be imported to continental Europe, with the
In China the second West-East pipeline is under construction, importers lowering offtake under their long term pipeline
and will be extended to pick up Central Asian gas. China is gas import contracts correspondingly within the TOP – ACQ
also likely sooner or later to gain access to Russian piped gas. band. This has been made easier by the lack of firm long
term contracts with market participants in the UK or US.
However it is the international trade in liquefied gas that is
seeing the fastest growth and makes observers wonder how The UK market is subject to the Interconnector and LNG
soon the characteristics of an integrated global gas market diversion dynamics described above. A conflict of market models
will be in place. arose in November 2005 when, facing a supply shortage, the
UK was expecting Continental European players to send gas
Though LNG makes up only about 30% of world gas trade, bought from the UK the previous summer back to the UK in
and less than 8% of world gas supply, LNG is beginning to response to price signals. This did not occur. The continental
dynamically link more than half of global gas consumption. And players were more concerned with ensuring adequate supplies
the list of countries importing LNG and gaining an exposure for domestic customers during the first quarter of 2006.
to global gas prices is steadily growing. In 2008 Brazil and
Argentina commissioned regasification terminals, and Canada, An interesting development in 2007-08 was the rapid growth
Chile, Croatia, Poland, Singapore, the Netherlands, Germany, in Asian imports of Atlantic – i.e., North and West African,
Indonesia have all taken steps to enter this segment of the Caribbean and even Norwegian – LNG. This trade increased
global gas market. from some 4,8 bcm in 2006 to 9,6 bcm in 2007 and close to 20
bcm in 2008. Offering higher netbacks the Asian importers made
Atlantic suppliers divert as many cargos as they could, given
their contractual commitments, from their regular markets. US
imports in the first 10 months of 2008 plummeted by almost
60% year on year.

The Asian importers’ dips into the pool of LNG supply which
otherwise would be delivered to the Atlantic Basin markets had
consequences for overall LNG availability and required Europe
and North America to rely more on gas in storage. While Asian

46  International Gas Union | June 2011


LNG contract prices are linked to the oil price, spot purchases from the point of view of consumers, arbitrage opportunities
were apparently priced on an Atlantic basin netback basis, from the point of view of suppliers.
though they could also reflect substitute fuel prices (usually in
Japan and usually distillate prices). There is still much enthusiasm, and fairly robust growth
projections, for LNG. The reference scenario in the International
There were particular reasons for the Asian countries’ needs Energy Agency’s 2008 World Energy Outlook had LNG supply
for Atlantic LNG in 2007-08 – in the case of Japan TEPCO’s and demand growing by 6% a year between 2005 and 2015,
temporary loss of big parts of its nuclear capacity, in the case of and 4,7% a year between 2015 and 2020. These rates were
South Korea a fuzzy regulatory situation that prevented Kogas lower than those suggested in previous WEOs but still a lot
from signing new long term contracts, and in both cases poor higher that the Agency’s 2008 projections for total gas supply
utilisation of storage tanks to manage seasonal demand and and demand. The IEA last year believed that in a business as
Indonesia’s problems delivering on its commitments. Some of usual future the LNG share of total gas would increase from
these drivers will weaken, and the global recession has put an 6,7% in 2005 to 16-17% in 2030.
end to the sellers’ market conditions that characterised LNG in
2007-08. In 2009 few Atlantic cargos have ended up with Asian The globalization trend will get a boost from LNG in the years
buyers. On the contrary, Asia Pacific exporters have needed to to 2011-12. During this period some 90 mtpa of new liquefaction
place a few cargos with Atlantic buyers. These developments capacity will be commissioned. Some 15 new LNG trains,
do not constitute evidence that the integration of regional gas including several very big ones, are under construction with
markets has stopped in its tracks, but serve as a reminder that a view to completion before the end of 2011. Nearly all this
the road towards globalised gas pricing may see set-backs and capacity is tied into long term LNG sales and purchase contracts.
could take longer than expected. However, 35% of the capacity is contracted to the marketing
arms of the IOC participants in the projects, and another 24% is
Bumps in the road toward globalised gas pricing contracted to Qatar Petroleum. Thus almost 60% of the capacity
to come onstream between now and the end of 2011 may be
Though the differences between how gas is priced in individual characterized as flexible – and it cannot be ruled our that the
regions may narrow, the driving forces expected to deliver price gas and power companies and end users that have contracted
alignment do not look as powerful as they did some years ago. for the remainder of the new capacity have plans of their own
There may for instance be reasons to revisit the question how to engage in arbitrage plays.
effectively LNG will serve to integrate world markets.
However, the pace of LNG supply growth beyond 2012 is for
It seems a fair assumption that the LNG share of world gas supply the moment highly uncertain. In 2006-08 only five liquefaction
needs to reach a certain threshold – whatever that threshold projects took final investment decisions. The 22-23 mtpa of
may be – if LNG is to play a key role in delivering market capacity that these projects will add to the global total corresponds
integration and price globalisation. By 2008 the LNG share of to only about half of required incremental capacity over the
world gas trade was about 28%, but regasified LNG still made years when the projects may be expected to come onstream –
up only 7,5% of world gas consumption. The conclusion that if, that is, LNG demand grows at around 6% a year. The latter
LNG remains a niche product with limited capacity to drive assumption is of course open to question. The credit crunch
prices, seems to be still valid. Moreover, most LNG chains are may well slow LNG demand growth down for a while. Still,
no less rigid than pipeline gas chains, with volumes, sources the assumption that there will be enough flexible LNG around
and destinations laid down in long term contracts. It is only the to support any conceivable growth in arbitrage operations and
flexible portion of LNG – the volumes purchased by portfolio price alignment across regions and basins also beyond 2012,
players, the volumes available from liquefaction plants after now seems bold.
contractual commitments have been fulfilled, etc. – that can be
routed at short notice to the highest paying markets. The most intriguing aspect of the slowdown in the sanctioning
of new liquefaction projects, is that it took place in a period
Clearly, even small supply increments can make a difference characterized by record high oil and gas prices and extreme
in tight markets. Thus under certain circumstances flexible tightness in the global LNG market. In 2008 LNG buyers
LNG may already have reached ‘critical mass’ in its role as purchased spot cargos and signed short-medium term contracts
globalisation purveyor. Under other market circumstances, at prices representing parity with oil at USD 100-150/b. It
however, the cargos available for rerouting will probably not was widely assumed that parity would become the norm also
matter much to regional price differences. for longer term contracts. This still did not persuade many
LNG project sponsors to proceed from the planning to the
During the first half of this decade forecasters expected rapid implementation phase.
growth in LNG exports and imports. This optimism reflected a
bullish outlook for gas in general, an apparent abundance of gas A string of factors have recently thrown spanners in the wheels
reserves suitable for commercialisation as LNG, favourable gas of LNG supply projects:
price / LNG cost developments and other attractions of LNG
in comparison to pipeline gas – security of supply advantages

June 2011 | International Gas Union  47 


• Problems gaining access to gas reserves suitable for LNG open seasons for new regas terminals, that got the globalization
due to host country government decisions to prioritise supply debate started.
for the domestic market and/or for future generations rather
than (additional) LNG exports, The US market had, it was argued, what no other single national
• Shortages of input factors, contractor capacity and skilled market or cluster of national markets had: The size, the hubs
labour driving costs and undermining the pretax economics and the storage capacity to provide swing services to everybody
of LNG; projects that seemed robust some years ago now else without being destabilized itself in the process. As such US
look marginal, gas prices (adjusted for differences in transportation costs) –
• Increasingly tough fiscal terms as host country governments principally the Henry Hub spot price – were uniquely positioned
responded to the shift from buyers’ to sellers’ market conditions to become world benchmarks. Prices elsewhere could not drop
by seeking to increase government take, much below HH; if they did, flexible LNG would flow to the
• Persistently high political risk in key supplier countries, US and stabilize prices elsewhere. Prices elsewhere could on
• Project partner misalignment, the other hand not increase much above HH; if they did, LNG
• Technical challenges related to the increasing size of LNG destined for the US would be rerouted to the higher priced
plants, and to the location of plants to more challenging markets and again align prices across continents.
environments.
One thing necessary to make this vision a reality was robust
It remains to be seen how quickly these hurdles will be cleared growth in US LNG demand, and that seemed an almost done
away or at least made more manageable. Certain cost components, deal. On the one hand, US gas demand looked set to increase on
in particular material costs, are on their way down. Others seem the back of massive investments in gas fired power generation
quite resilient to the financial crisis. capacity. On the other, US gas production, and the availability to
the US of Canadian pipeline gas, appeared to be in irreversible
How quickly the flexible, divertible share of total LNG will decline. Mexico also struggled to increase domestic gas
increase is just as uncertain. There are projections of this share production in line with demand. In short, the North American
doubling from 15% to 30% over the next decade as well as gas supply-demand gap that could only be filled by LNG looked
expectations of a decline. Unsurprisingly, the Atlantic and Mid set to widen rapidly.
East actors that have positioned to become providers of LNG
hub services are the most optimistic. At the other end of the US LNG imports are by nature volatile since they are not normally
scale are certain Asian and European incumbents pointing to underpinned by long term take or pay contracts. Thus the flow
the Japanese nuclear problems and other special circumstances of LNG to North America was below expectations in 2006 with
that drove the growth in flexible LNG in 2007-08, and claiming European buyers stocking up gas in the aftermath of a cold winter
that with these problems out of the way it will be in everybody’s and with the Russian-Ukrainian gas crisis still on people’s mind,
interest to refocus on long term contracts. and above expectations in first half 2007 as a warm winter had
left European storage inventories abnormally high. Until then,
Independently of individual actors’ preferences, a tripling of however, the trend seemed to be pointing squarely upwards.
flexible LNG over a decade (a doubling of the flexible share of
a total increasing by around 50%) could require more projects What many observers missed for a long time was the unconventional
to be sanctioned with smaller shares of output under long term gas revolution underway in the US. Tight gas, shale gas and
contracts, than host governments, company sponsors and the coal bed methane has been supplied in increasing amounts at
financial community seem to be ready for. increasingly competitive costs. US gas productive capacity
which had been on a declining curve since 2001 bottomed out
LNG project sponsors may have hesitated to proceed to FID also in late 2005. LNG largely priced itself out of the US market in
because of doubts about the sustainability of the 2007-08 LNG 2007 and failed to re-enter in 2008 (Chart 8.5).
market boom. In the first place, there were signs that the prices
in 2007 and the first quarters of 2008 would lead to demand Chart 8.5: US dry gas production and LNG imports
destruction. Secondly some players may have suspected that the
price explosion in 2008 was part of a bubble that would burst US monthly dry gas production US monthly LNG imports
(although very few seemed to have anticipated something like 53
Jan 97 - Oct 08
3
Jan 97 - Oct 08

the current price and demand collapse). 51


3
49
Trend line

Sponsors probably also noticed that US LNG demand was not 47 2

45
developing as expected in the early 2000s.
Bcm
Bcm

2
43
Trend line
41 1

North America was – and is – a key piece of the puzzle expected 39


1

to give rise to one integrated world gas market and globalised 37

gas pricing. It was the new outlook for US LNG requirements


35 0
97

00

01

03

04

05

07

08

97

99

00

01

04

05

08
98

99

02

06

98

02

03

06

07

that emerged after the 2000-2001 US gas price spike, and


n.

n.

n.

n.

n.

n.

n.

n.

n.

n.

n.

n.

n.

n.

n.

n.

n.

n.

n.
n.

n.

n.

n.

n.
ja

ja

ja

ja

ja

ja

ja

ja

ja

ja

ja

ja

ja

ja

ja

ja

ja

ja
ja

ja

ja

ja

ja

ja

FERC’s 2002 “Hackberry decision” to stop requiring so-called Source: US DOE EIA

48  International Gas Union | June 2011


Observers/stakeholders like the US DOE have lowered their US Whether the US also will provide a ceiling to world LNG prices
LNG import assumptions year by year in response to the signs as and when markets recover, and as such continue to serve as
of demand destruction and the break-through for unconventional market integrator, is a different issue.
gas. The DOE’s Energy Information Administration almost
comes full circle in its 2009 Annual Energy Outlook. By the If US LNG imports increase in the short term, a recovery in
turn of the decade the EIA believed that US LNG imports world LNG demand in the medium term could to an extent
would stagnate at 0,33 tcf (9,3 bcm) a year. In 2005 the EIA put be supplied from these imports. European and Asian buyers
LNG imports by 2025 at 6,37 tcf (180 bcm) a year. In its most would only need to increase their price offers enough to shift
recent Outlook the EIA sees LNG imports peaking at 1,51 tcf netbacks marginally in their favour. The re-routing potential
(43 bcm) a year by 2018 before dropping to 0,84 tcf (24 bcm) would however eventually become exhausted just as it was in
a year by 2030 (Chart 8.6). 2007-08 when little else than Trinidad cargos under long term
contracts found their way into the US (Chart 8.7).
Chart 8.6: US LNG import forecasts
Chart 8.7: US LNG imports by supplier

US LNG imports
DOE/EIA's forecasts 2000-2009
7 US monthly LNG imports by supplier
6 3000
2000
5 2500 Trinidad
2005
4 Qatar
Tcf

2006 2000
3 Norway
2007
Mcm

2 1500
Nigeria
2008
1 1000 Eq. Guinea
2009
0 Egypt
500
Algeria
15
97

00

03

06

09

12

18

21

24

27

30

0
19

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20
20

20

8
6

7
06

07

7
08

8
6

8
7
r. 0

r.0

r.0
t.0

t.0

t.0
l.0
l.0

l.0
n.

n.

n.
Source: US DOE/EIA: Annual Energy Outlook, various editions

ju
ok

ok

ok
ap

ju

ju
ap

ap
ja

ja

ja
The situation is not that the US may not receive increasing Source: US DOE EIA

amounts of LNG. As a market of last resort the US will likely


receive a significant share of the LNG from the 15 new trains LNG prices could then decouple from the US price level which
set that will start producing in the years to 2012. But there will – if US gas demand and/or indigenous gas supply is flexible
at least initially be no bid wars for this LNG. The sellers will enough to quickly accommodate any loss of flexible LNG to
have to accept or reject the prevailing US prices depending on other market regions – might not change at all.
relative netbacks. In extreme situations they may have no choice
because other destinations are physically unable to receive more If the US instead develops the dependence on LNG that observers
LNG. The US will then provide a floor to world gas prices and in the early 2000s thought they could see around the corner,
as such play its part in the price globalisation process. but now tend to discard, US buyers would need to compete on
price with the rest of the world for LNG supply. Then the LNG
The US gas market is not only large enough and well enough price ceiling provided by US indigenous gas supply costs could
equipped with storage capacity to accommodate such a disintegrate – but we would still in this scenario characterised by
development, it now also has sufficient regas capacity. By the intercontinental competitive bidding see gas market integration
end of 2008 the US had an estimated total of 62,3 mtpa (8,2 bcfd) and price globalisation.
of capacity up and running, and Mexico had an additional 9,5
mtpa (1,2 bcfd). By the end of 2009 the US total will be almost The differences between recent long term US LNG import
100 mtpa (13,1 bcfd) with Mexico and Canada contributing 19 forecasts testify to the complicated nature of this issue. US gas
mtpa (2,5 bcfd). demand growth will play a key role, implying that economic
growth and the current administration’s energy and environmental
Wholesale gas prices in the US will reflect the long term policies will be important drivers. The exact shape of the North
marginal costs of US unconventional gas. These costs are often American unconventional gas supply curve, today and 5, 10
reported to be in the US$ 5-7/MMBtu range, though estimates and 20 years from now considering the resource base and the
tend to come with warnings about their sensitivity to further scope for further technological progress, is another key to the
improvements in E&D technology, positive or negative surprises outlook for LNG. Whether incremental LNG supply costs will
in new basins, general oil and gas industry cost developments stay at today’s level or fall back towards their 2004 level is yet
and a host of other factors. Anyway, if Henry Hub drops below another key.
long term marginal costs – which certainly may happen – drilling
and eventually supply will decline, pushing prices back into
the viability range.

June 2011 | International Gas Union  49 


To state the obvious: If gas supply and/or LNG costs develop differently, then the
anticipated recovery in US LNG imports linked to the need
• US gas demand picks up on the back of an economic recovery for new Qatari, Russian, Indonesian, Yemeni etc. liquefaction
and policies favouring gas over competing fuels for mid- and capacity to be accommodated, could be short lived.
baseload power generation,
• unconventional gas proves to have its limits, and The former scenario would underpin a rapid development of a
• global LNG supply costs decline to the level of ensuring global gas market with unified pricing. The latter would mean
competitiveness in netback terms to the alternatives in the that a vital globalisation and unification driver would disappear
US market, from the scene with the result that the processes might take
much longer.
then LNG may only be temporary down as a component of the
US fuel mix, and the growth in LNG supply to the US that
many observers took for granted a few years ago could still
materialise. If on the other hand US gas demand, unconventional

50  International Gas Union | June 2011


9. Price volatility

General Chart 9.3: Henry Hub standard deviation

In general terms, price volatility refers to the frequency and Henry Hub next month delivery contract price
amplitude of price fluctuations. In financial terms volatility Standard deviation of daily observations
refers to the magnitude of stock variations. The concept of 3,00

volatility is used to quantify yield and price risk. The stronger 2,50
the volatility, the bigger the potential yield but also the bigger
the risk. The concept is typically used to describe short term 2,00

USD/MMBtu
variations rather than long term oscillations, but may in prin- 1,50
ciple be used to discuss all kinds of fluctuations.
1,00

There is a strong popular perception that gas prices fluctuate 0,50


more often and more strongly now than in the past. A glance at
0,00
select wholesale gas prices in the markets relying on gas-to- gas 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008
competition supports this notion (chart 9.1).
Source: US DOE EIA

Chart 9.1: Henry Hub and NBP price fluctuations


The importance of not jumping to conclusions on volatility
developments becomes even clearer when we look at price
Henry Hub next month delivery NBP spot price changes rather than absolute prices. Traders and risk managers
contract price Jan 97 - Dec 08, monthly basis
Jan 94 - Dec 08, daily basis 16 typically measure volatility in terms of the “return” on an
investment in a commodity, with returns calculated on a log-
18
14
16

14
12 normal basis using the form
12 10
USD/MMBtu
USD/MMBtu

Return(t) = ln(Price(t)/Price(t-1)).
10 8
8
6
6
4
4
2
2

0
In this perspective where a USD 2 increase in a USD 10/MMBtu
0
price represents the same level of volatility as a 40 cents increase
. 4
.0 95
.0 6
.0 7
.0 8
.0 9

.0 1
.0 2
.0 3
.0 4
.0 5
. 6

08
. 0 00

. 0 07

Ja 9 7

Ja 0 1

Ja 0 5
13 1. 9
13 1. 9

13 1. 0
13 1. 0
13 1. 0

Ja 98
Ja 99
Ja 00

Ja 02
Ja 03
Ja 04

Ja 06
Ja 07
08
13 1.9

13 1.9
13 1.9

13 1. 0
13 1. 0
13 1. 0
13 01.

13 1.

13 01.
1.

in a USD 2/MMBtu price, it becomes difficult to see any clear


n-
n-
n-
n-
n-
n-
n-
n-
n-
n-
n-
n-
.0

Ja
13

Sources: US DOE EIA, CERA trend in volatility over the 1994-2007 period (Chart 9.4).

It is however not evident that there has been a continued and Chart 9.4: Henry Hub daily returns
consistent increase in volatility through the 2000s. Prices
fluctuated less in 2002-04 and again in 2006-07 than in 2000
and 2001. (Charts 9.2 and 9.3). Henry Hub next month delivery contract price
Daily returns, January 2004 - December 2008
Chart 9.2: Henry Hub means, highs, lows 40 %

30 %

20 %
10 %

Henry Hub next month delivery contract price 0%


Annual means, highs, lows -10 %
18
-20 %
16
-30 %
14 -40 %
12 -50 %
USD/MMBtu

14.01.00

14.01.01

14.01.02

14.01.03

14.01.04

14.01.05

14.01.06

14.01.07

14.01.08
14.01.94

14.01.95

14.01.96

14.01.97

14.01.98

14.01.99

10

6
Source: US DOE EIA
4

2
What effects price volatility has on the affected markets and
0
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 economies is also a controversial issue.

Source: US DOE EIA

June 2011 | International Gas Union  51 


In the 1980s and 1990s oil price volatility was much debated. changes in demand, or demand failing to accommodate price
Many politicians and market actors recommended producer to signals due to changes in supply.
consumer cooperation to dampen price fluctuations. While the
oil price increases in 1973 and 1979-80 triggered consumer How quickly supply is able to respond to a shift in demand
country interest in this concept, the oil price collapse in 1986 depends on the state of the market – i.e., on the shape of the
persuaded many producer countries to support it too. The 1990 supply curve at the point of intersection with the demand curve
‘mini-shock’ related to the Iraqi invasion of Kuwait further – when the shift occurs.
boosted enthusiasm for some kind of dialogue.
Chart 9.5: Price volatility and the flexibility of supply
Economists however cautioned against politicising markets in
this way. One study5 examined the allegations that oil price
Price volatility and the flexibility of supply
volatility had boosted inflation and dampened economic growth by: Price
If the market at the
D 11 D12 D 21 D 22 outset is at A, with
S
• Boosting oil prices plenty of flexibility on
the supply side, an
• Reducing oil industry investments and thereby oil supply, increase in demand
from D11 to D12 will
• Boosting transaction costs – e.g., costs associated with increase prices only
by P1. If the
investments in facilities to increase flexibility – for consumers market at the outset
 P2 is at B, with limited
and producers flexibility on the
B supply side, the
 P1 same increase in
A demand will raise
The study failed to find conclusive proof for any of them. Price prices by P2.

volatility as such did not seem to be the reason for any of these Volume
three situations.

Price volatility may keep investors that pursue low risk The less suppliers are able to accommodate an increase in
activities with correspondingly low returns, and look for a demand by activating spare capacity, the stronger will the
stable environment, from launching new investments. As such, price impact be.
volatility may be an issue from a gas supply security point
of view. However, to other investors price volatility may, by How quickly demand is able to respond to a shift in supply
providing arbitrage opportunities, be seen as preferable to price depends on the shape of the demand curve at the point of
stability in terms of value added. It is important to nuance the intersection with the supply curve when the shift occurs
perception of volatility as a problem for the industry. It needs
to be acknowledged that different types of stakeholders look Chart 9.6: Price volatility and the flexibility of demand
for different price contexts.
Price volatility and the flexibility of demand
This difference is related to the one between long term oil
Price
indexed gas prices and shorter term gas to gas competition If the market is
based prices on gas exchanges. at A when
supply shifts
D1 D2 S2 S1
from S1 to S2,
then if demand

Causes of volatility is flexible (the


D1 curve)
prices only
increase by
Many explanations have been offered for the perceived increase in  P2
P1, whereas
if demand is
 P1
gas price volatility in the 2000s. Those that are most popular with A
inflexible (the
D2 curve)
the media are not necessarily on top in terms of explanatory power. prices increase
by P 2.

Volume
Blaming fingers are pointed at commodity trading techniques
resulting from time to time in waves of speculative gas sales or
purchases. The public is also occasionally fired up by reports The less consumers are able to accommodate a decline in supply
on downright market manipulation. However neither trading by switching to other fuels or just cutting consumption, the
techniques nor criminal activity are credible explanations for stronger will the price impact be.
a general increase in price volatility.
On the margin, if supply has become so stretched that the
Basic gas supply and demand fundamentals go a long way market is on the vertical part of the supply curve, or if demand
towards explaining this increase. has become so rigid that the market is on the vertical part of
the demand curve, disturbances will need to be accommodated
Price volatility is the consequence of supply failing to respond 100% by price adjustments. Since gas markets are ‘disturbed’
immediately, smoothly and precisely to price signals caused by all the time by changes in the weather, maintenance of supply
facilities, etc., under such conditions there will inevitably be
5
Philip K. Verleger, Jr.: Adjusting to Volatile Energy Prices, Washington DC 1993 frequent and sometimes violent price fluctuations.

52  International Gas Union | June 2011


Gas exchange prices reflect the supply and demand circumstances Volatility associated with gas price declines
of the day. Both variables are characterised by frequent deviations
from trend, and delayed and imprecise responses are the rule Gas price declines incentive producers to curtail drilling. When
rather than the exceptions. Gas exchange prices are therefore drilling goes down, lost production from wells in decline is not
inevitably characterised by fluctuations. fully replaced and aggregate production starts going down. But
all this takes time, and when production eventually starts to
Volatility associated with gas price increases sag in response to lower prices, the response is initially very
gentle. This is because it pays to shut in wells only at extremely
Gas price increases incentivise producers to increase supply, low price levels.
but liberalised markets as a rule have little spare productive
capacity that can quickly be brought on-stream. In the US the In the UK some fields which are nearing the end of their lives
gas sector restructuring that was triggered by the passing of are typically reducing production in the summer months when
the Natural Gas Policy Act in 1978 led to efficiency impro- prices are soft in the expectation of using the ‘saved’ gas at
vements, cost cuts and a period of low gas prices, but also to the end of their field lives and in addition capturing a winter’s
a decline in underutilised delivery infrastructure available to price premium.
dampen volatility.
How supply responds to price changes depends also on how
Gas price increases incentivise buyers to cut their gas pur- storage inventories are managed. A price increase encourages
chases within the limits set by their flexibility to switch to accelerated withdrawal of gas from storage, and vice versa.
alternative fuels. Typically, power sector gas demand declines
as generators switch from gas to coal or oil-fired capacity, Gas price declines incentivise buyers to increase their gas use,
while industrial gas demand declines as firms relying on gas again within the limits set by their flexibility to switch from
for process heat switch to oil products and firms using gas as alternative fuels to gas. Typically, power generators bring unused
a process feedstock temporarily shut down facilities. gas fired capacity on line at the expense of coal fired capacity.
Industrial gas demand is unlikely to change.
However, only a portion of gas users can easily and quickly
switch to alternative fuels, and this portion is shrinking, be- Prolonged periods of low gas prices would strengthen the case
cause of efficiency considerations and also since environmen- for new investment in gas fired power generation, and slow
tal and land use policies many places have prevented duel the relocation of gas intensive industry to other parts of the
fuel power generating units from being constructed. world, but probably do not affect residential and commercial
sector demand noticeably since past conservation measures
Prolonged periods of high gas prices trigger more drilling reflected in, e.g., building standards for new premises would
for gas. Traditionally in North America the rig count has hardly be reversed.
responded quickly to price signals, and production has in
turn responded quickly to changes in the rig count. The latter On the supply side, the intensity of gas drilling in the US and
relationship seemed not to apply between early 2002 and late Canadian gas drilling would decline from current levels and
2006 when prices more than tripled and the number of gas rapidly depress production, the Alaska and MacKenzie Delta
rigs increased from fewer than 600 to more than 1400, but projects would be further deferred, and UK fields would be
production trended downwards. However, growth in uncon- shut-in and abandoned on earlier timings.
ventional gas production has since early 2006 been strong
enough to deliver a recovery in total gas, and demonstrated In sum, there are rigidities in both gas supply and gas demand
that the old relationship still holds – at least for now. that results in price volatility in competitive markets, and these
rigidities appear to have hardened.
The UK industry would be stimulated by prolonged high
prices to harvest the remaining gas accumulations – probably An increase in gas demand due perhaps to a cold snap does not
through step-outs and extensions of existing fields. Aggregate trigger any appreciable production response. A decline in gas
additional production is not expected to be significant. supply due perhaps to a hurricane damaging critical pieces of
infrastructure does not trigger any appreciable demand response.
As for demand, prolonged periods of high gas prices reduce Prices rise to activate whatever fuel-switching capacity exists
power sector gas needs by encouraging investment in alterna- in the power sector. If this additional cushion is insufficient
tive (typically coal fired) capacity, industrial sector demand to restore balance, prices continue to rise to the point where
by encouraging plant owners to re-locate to countries offering storage withdrawal reach extraordinary levels, or to the point
cheaper gas, and residential and commercial sector demand where demand is ‘rationed’ – i.e. industry shuts down plant and
by triggering conservation measures such as improved build- all alternative power generation options to gas are exhausted.
ing insulation, double glazing and more efficient heating
boilers.

June 2011 | International Gas Union  53 


Volatility of oil indexed prices Volatility and LNG

In Continental Europe and Asia gas prices are as noted LNG under traditional long term take-or-pay contracts is
indexed to oil prices depend on imported gas to satisfy no different from pipeline gas under similar contracts in its
significant portions of their needs. This gas typically travels capacity to aggravate or dampen price volatility. Thus a shift
significant distances from the well-head to the city-gate. in gas supply from long term pipeline gas to long term LNG
will not in itself matter to price volatility. However, a mate-
Importantly, the indices are not crude or product spot prices, rial shift inside the LNG portion of gas supply from long term
which are highly volatile, but rolling price averages typically contracted to flexible LNG would imply further commoditi-
ironing out fluctuations over 6-9 month periods in European zation of gas and different volatility patterns across countries.
pipeline contracts and 3-6 months in LNG contracts. This
averaging (and where applicable, upper and lower limits to the oil Flexible LNG is diverted according to price signals. Thus
price range where indexation applies) significantly dampen the some countries may be deprived of LNG they had counted on,
impact of the underlying oil commodity price volatility on gas with the result that local or even national prices escalate. On
prices. The result is ‘long wavelength’ oil price driven volatility the other hand the recipient countries may receive LNG they
had not counted on with the result that the price increases that
From the perspective of price volatility, the long-term oil indexed triggered the diversions in the first place are arrested.
contract market structure gives rise to the following dynamics:
To an extent this happened in 2008 when Asia – prompted by
Supply and demand in these markets are managed through strong economic and energy demand growth, Japan’s problems
contract volume nominations and storage operations. The gas with its Kashiwazaki-Kariwa nuclear power complex and a
price does not automatically respond to gas demand. The buyer severe drop in Indonesian LNG supply – played the price card
is implicitly paying the seller to maintain a surplus supply to attract numerous flexible cargos from the Atlantic basin. If
capacity in excess of the base capacity the buyer under normal these diversions had not been possible, Asian prices would
circumstances will need. City gate prices reflect contract border have gone even higher while US prices would have been even
prices and in addition in-country transmission and storage lower than they were.
costs. The latter are spread across the year – hence there is no
seasonal shape to city gate gas prices. If Atlantic markets in general, and the US market in particular,
had been tighter than they were in 2008, the only buffering
Chart 9.7 confirms that ‘short wavelength’ price volatility does mechanisms would have been North American producers’
not really feature in ‘pure form’ oil-indexed markets. From the flexibility to boost supply, European buyers’ possibilities to
perspective of, say, a large Continental European gas and power vary their nominations of long term pipeline gas in Europe,
utility company, price uncertainty under the loose heading of and storage inventories above annual norms.
‘volatility’ would largely be confined to the existence of contract
re-openers. Whether triggered by the buyer or the seller, re- By making local supply curves less rigid the advent of flexible
openers can result in significant re-basing of the underlying LNG will likely dampen average price volatility. On the other
contract price. hand, the commoditization of gas that is taking place is also
attracting the interest of financial investors, and does as such
Chart 9.7: Standard deviations of monthly observations of imply a risk of speculative booms and busts.
sample of gas prices

2008 2020
North America, UK
Gas-on-gas competition Gas-on-gas competition
u ro pe
ental E
Con tin
Continental Europe,
Oil price escalation Developed Asia Oil price escalation

Bilateral monopoly Bilateral monopoly

Netback from final product Select market segments Netback from final product
?
ina
Ch
ia,

Regulation – cost of service Regulation – cost of service


ss
Ru

Select Non-OECD
Regulation – social and political Regulation – social and political
D
-O EC
t N on
Selec
Regulation – below cost Select Non-OECD Regulation – below cost

No price No price

Source of price data: PIRA

54  International Gas Union | June 2011


10. Towards further changes in the extensiveness
of individual pricing mechanisms?

Neither the IEA nor the DOE/EIA anticipates much change The possibility of oil linked gas falling out of favour with the
in gas pricing mechanisms – at least not in their respective key power sector is particularly worrisome. Here gas needs to be
reference scenarios. perceived as competitive with coal and in the future increasingly
with biomass, wind, solar, etc. The competition from coal is
The EIA derives its US price assumptions mainly from its blunted by differences in capital costs, lead times, taxation and
supply cost assumptions. The IEA expects that gas prices will regulatory provisions. The competition from renewables other
remain linked to oil prices through contracts or substitution. than hydro is blunted by the still high costs of these options.
Extended oil driven gas price rallies could still erode gas’
The IEA further assumes that gas will continue to be priced position as the preferred fuel.
at a discount to oil. The imported gas/imported crude oil ratio
was by 2008 assumed to stabilise around 75% for the US and Industrial buyers benefit from oil indexation when oil prices
Japan, and around two thirds for Europe (Chart 10.1) are sufficiently low for sufficiently long to make oil linked
gas cheaper than spot gas. Sellers of course benefit from the
Chart 10.1: Oil and gas price assumptions in WEO 2008 opposite situation. Oil market cycles in combination with price
renegotiation clauses in long term contracts may deliver a
balanced distribution of costs and benefits over time. Oil driven
Oil and gas prices assumptions in the IEA's gas price rallies like the one in 2007-08 that led to significant
WEO 2008 industrial demand destruction are nevertheless bad for gas’
25,00 image as a reliable and affordable fuel across cycles.
20,00
More gas-on-gas competition and more use of gas exchange
prices would to an extent decouple gas prices from oil prices. It
USD/MMBtu

15,00
would however increase short term price volatility, and whether
10,00
Crude oil - IEA imports it would eliminate the risk of longer term price rallies is an open
5,00
Gas - US imports question. Basically that would depend on Continental Europe’s
Gas - Japan LNG imports
Gas - European imports and Developed Asia’s future gas supply-demand balances.
0,00
2007 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 For the moment there is ample spare capacity in Europe’s
pipeline gas supply chains as well as in the world’s LNG supply
Source: IEA: World Energy Outlook 2008 system. The financial crisis, the recession and the consequent
drop in gas demand nearly everywhere have forced gas suppliers
The split of gas transactions by price formation mechanism to significantly lower capacity utilisation. Sharp declines
could however change significantly between now and 2020. in sales revenues and doubts about the timing and shape of
the anticipated recovery are however delaying vital up- and
As noted there is little to indicate that the countries that have midstream investments. The IEA and others are concerned that
adopted gas-to-gas competition based pricing – mainly North the current global gas market downturn will only pave the way
America and the UK – will turn away from this mechanism. for another rally.
On the contrary, the still fairly significant share of oil linked
contracts in the UK market will likely diminish with buyers Evidence from North America underlines the question mark at
insisting on competitive pricing as opportunities to do so arise. the long term consequences for gas prices of switching from oil
escalation to gas-on-gas competition. Although gas prices are
In Continental Europe and in big parts of Asia, various pricing not in any way linked to oil prices in US contracts, gas has over
mechanisms co-exist with oil indexation playing a dominant the years – across frequent, sometimes violent short-medium
role. Opinions on the sustainability of this situation differ. term disturbances – tended to track oil in a fairly stable long
term relationship. This is probably because gas and oil prices
The original rationale for oil indexation has weakened. Gas besides being linked by interfuel competition in the industrial
still competes with oil in industry but faces mostly other fuels sector are influenced in the same manner and to the same extent
in the battles for residential, commercial and power sector by the oil and gas industry’s cost cycles, and with deviations also
market share. being arrested, eventually, by changes in oil and gas industry
investment priorities.

June 2011 | International Gas Union  55 


Oil indexation will in any event not disappear any time soon, Gaining acceptance for alternative pricing models will likely
for several reasons. take longer in Asia than in Europe.

Continental European buyers have signed medium-long term Legislation to make these countries’ domestic gas markets
contracts 6 for an estimated 350-350 bcm of gas a year, and a very somewhat more competitive have been passed, and their recurrent
high share of these contracts are of the standard oil linked type. needs to purchase spot LNG will constantly bring them into
Annual commitments start declining only from around 2015. contact with the Henry Hub or NBP price levels. However,
there seemed by mid 2009 to be few champions in the region
By 2008 existing medium-long term contracts corresponded to for dramatic reforms.
more than 80% of Continental European gas consumption (with
the rest being short term purchases). Going forward, this share Moreover, Japan, South Korea and Taiwan have just as Continental
will of course decline (Chart 10.2). If gas demand increases Europe entered into a large number of oil linked medium-long
by 2,4% a year, in line with average annual growth between term gas import contracts that constitute a limit to the possible
1987 and 2007, already contracted supply will meet around pace of introducing alternative pricing principles (Chart 10.3).
two thirds of Continental European gas demand by 2015 and The ratio of contracted supply to total demand was in 2007 –
less than a quarter of demand by 2025. Moreover, the take or when spot purchases reached unprecedented highs – around
pay provisions in most contracts give customers the option to 80%. If gas demand increases by 6% a year the share will fall to
offtake somewhat less than 100% of annual contracted volumes. around 50% by 2015 and less than 10% by 2025. A 6% annual
growth would be in line with the average for 1987-2007 but no
Chart 10.2: Continental Europe’s contracted gas supply, mid 2008 one expects these comparatively mature markets to continue to
expand this fast. A perhaps more realistic 3% a year demand
growth assumption gives ratios of already contracted supply to
Continental Europe's contracted gas
future demand much in line with those of Continental Europe.
supply, mid 2008
400
Chart 10.3: Japan’s, South Korea’s and Taiwan’s contracted
350
gas supply
300
250
bcm

200 Japan's, South Korea's and Taiwan's


150
contracted gas supply, mid 2008
100
140
50
120
0
100
2008

2010
2011

2013

2015
2016

2018

2020
2021

2023

2025
2007

2009

2012

2014

2017

2019

2022

2024

80
bcm

60
Source: Wood Mackenzie
40

Still, the existing body of oil linked contracts considerably 20

reduces the maximum pace at which a shift towards, e.g., gas 0


2007

2010

2012

2014
2015

2017

2019
2020

2022

2024
2008
2009

2011

2013

2016

2018

2021

2023

2025
indexation could proceed.

This is not to say that there is a desire among gas sellers and Source: Wood Mackenzie
buyers to get rid of the oil link overnight even if they could.
As noted, the incumbents on both sides of the table seem for China and India are in the midst of painful adjustments to ‘world
the moment to be broadly in favour of retaining oil indexation. level’ gas prices. These adjustments are driven by a need for
imported gas that is unlikely to peak any time soon, in spite of
The EU Commission will likely continue to push for gas-on-gas gas discoveries that will allow significant growth in indigenous
competition based pricing, but it cannot push very hard in the production in both countries. They proceed, broadly speaking, by
absence of trading places offering reliable price information introducing competitive pricing for the customers able to cope
and the full range of trading facilities and services. Continental with steep gas cost increases while retaining price regulation
Europe’s gas hubs will take on these characteristics and functions for everybody else, but in a differentiated manner, and with the
but that will take time. aim of gradually increasing prices across the board. In other
words, they are on their way from domestic pricing systems
Japanese, South Korean and Taiwanese gas importers have on dominated by below cost regulation, to alternatives characterised
balance been even more hesitant than their Continental European by a mixture of below cost regulation, some sort of cost based
counterparts to switch from oil indexed import prices and cost regulation and gas-to-gas competition based pricing, with the
plus based domestic prices to more competitive arrangements. split of sales gradually shifting from the first to the second and
third pricing principle.
6
Including deals at HoA or MoU level as well as firm sales and purchase contracts

56  International Gas Union | June 2011


More countries than China and India – possibly the majority challenging these perceptions. Now, with oil export revenues
of countries in Asia and Latin America, apart from the richest considerably down on their 2007-08 levels, concerns about the
ones, and the gas importing FSU republics – are struggling to budgetary consequences of subsidisation are likely resurfacing.
accomplish similar transitions. The timelines for getting there
vary across countries and as rulers come and go. As noted, price At the same time, with many North African and Middle Eastern
reform is risky business. Factors such as the pace of economic countries beginning to feel the pinch of stagnant indigenous
growth, inflation and the popularity and leeway of the incumbent gas supply, intraregional gas exports and imports look set to
government need to be constantly considered. increase, and this trade will not be at subsidised prices. Qatar
aims for the same netback from its LNG sales to Kuwait and
Russia appears to be on a broadly parallel course although from Dubai as from its other LNG sales, and if Doha decides to
a different starting point as the world’s biggest gas producer contract additional pipeline gas to the UAE or Oman it will be
and exporter. Russia’s traditionally uneconomic domestic gas at international market prices. This will increase subsidisation
prices that have over-stimulated domestic gas use and limited burdens in the importing countries and could eventually pave
Gazprom’s and other companies’ ability to invest in new fields the way for domestic price adjustments.
and supply infrastructure, are as noted to be partly replaced by
opportunity cost based prices over a period of 4-5 years. Chart 10.4 is an attempt to summarise these hypotheses.

To the extent European border prices – the starting point for Chart 10.4: Hypotheses on future changes in the extensiveness
netback calculations – remain oil linked, Russian wholesale of individual pricing mechanisms in individual regions
prices will come to reflect oil prices too. This could transfer
the problems of oil linked pricing into a Russian market 2008 2020
poorly prepared to deal with them, possibly leading to delays, Gas-on-gas competition
North America, UK
Gas-on-gas competition
ro pe
exemptions and special arrangements that would reduce the Oil price escalation
Con tin
enta l Eu
Continental Europe,
Oil price escalation
transparency of the process.
Developed Asia

Bilateral monopoly Bilateral monopoly

A fair number of Non-OECD countries – in particular those Netback from final product Select market segments Netback from final product

?
na
in the Middle East and North Africa that benefit from high oil

hi
,C
ia
Regulation – cost of service Regulation – cost of service

ss
prices – will likely seek to continue subsidising domestic gas Ru
Select Non-OECD
Regulation – social and political Regulation – social and political
prices. Cheap electricity, gas and motor fuels are widely seen Select
N on-O
EC D

as obligatory government deliverables in these parts of the Regulation – below cost Select Non-OECD Regulation – below cost

world, and also indispensable to the global competitiveness of No price No price

the regions’ petrochemical industry. In periods with high oil


export revenues there has historically been limited interest in

June 2011 | International Gas Union  57 


Appendix 1
– Price Formation Mechanisms 2005 Survey

Format of Results World Results


In looking at price formation mechanisms, the results have World Consumption and Production
generally been analysed from the perspective of the consuming
country. Within each country gas consumption can come from Before considering the results on price formation mechanisms for
one of three sources, ignoring withdrawals from (and injections 2005, it is useful to consider the regional pattern of consumption
into) storage – domestic production, imported by pipeline and production. In 2005 total world consumption and production
and imported by LNG. In many instances, as will be shown was of the order of 2,800 bcm. Chart A?? below shows the
below, domestic production, which is not exported, is priced distribution of world consumption.
differently from gas available for export and also from imported
gas whether by pipeline or LNG. Information was collected for Chart A1: World gas consumption 2005
these 3 categories separately for each country and, in addition,
pipeline and LNG imports were aggregated to give total imports
and adding total imports to domestic production gives total World gas consumption 2005
consumption. For each country, therefore, price formation could 2,790 bcm

be considered in 5 different categories:


Asia Asia Pacific
5% 10 %
• Domestic Production (consumed within the country, i.e. not Africa North America
3%
exported) Middle East
27 %

• Pipeline Imports 10 %

• LNG Imports
• Total Imports (Pipeline plus LNG) Latin America
5%
• Total Consumption (Domestic Production plus Total Imports) Former Soviet
Union
Europe
19 %
21 %

Each country was then considered to be part of one of the IGU


regions, as described in the Introduction, and the 5 categories
reviewed for each region. Finally the IGU regions were aggregated North America and the Former Soviet Union, followed by
to give the results for the World as a whole for 2005. Europe are the main consuming regions, and it is these regions,
therefore, which will have the greatest influence on the results
In terms of the presentation of results, the World results will be on price formation mechanisms at the World level. The Middle
considered first, followed by the Regional results for the separate East and Asia Pacific will also have an important, but smaller,
regions – North America, Latin America, Europe, Former Soviet influence.
Union, Middle East, Africa, Asia and Asia Pacific.
The Chart on the next page shows World Production by region.
As well as collecting information on price formation mechanisms The largest consuming region – North America – was largely
by country, information was also collected on wholesale price self-sufficient in 2005. The Former Soviet Union was a net
levels in each country in 2005. These results on a country and exporter, principally to Europe, which was a net importer. Asia
regional basis are also presented together with an analysis of Pacific was a net importer, principally from the Middle East,
price trends. while Africa was a net exporter, mainly to Europe. Asia and
Latin America were largely self-sufficient.

58  International Gas Union | June 2011


Chart A2: World gas production 2005 Chart A4: Pipeline exports 2005

World gas production 2005 Pipeline exports 2005


2,785 bcm 663 bcm

Asia Pacific Asia Pacific


8% 1,0 %
Asia North America Middle East Africa Asia
0,9 % 1,8 % North America
Africa 5 % 26 % 6,7 %
18,8 %
6%
Latin America
2,6 %

Middle East
11 % Latin America
5%
Europe Former Soviet Europe
Former Soviet 11 % Union 23,4 %
Union 44,8 %
28 %

With respect to imports by pipeline (both intra- and inter- Chart A5: LNG imports 2005
regional), Europe accounts for more than half of the world total.
Both European intra-regional gas imports (Norway to various
countries) and Europe’s imports of gas from outside Europe LNG imports 2005
190 bcm
(Russia and Algeria) are very significant. In the other regions,
pipeline imports are all intra-regional. North America
9,5 % Latin America
0,5 %
Chart A3: Pipeline imports 2005
Europe
25,2 %

World gas production 2005


2,785 bcm Asia Pacific
61,6 %
Asia
3,2 %
Asia Pacific
8%
Asia North America
Africa 5 % 26 %
6%

Middle East
11 % Latin America
5%
Europe
Former Soviet 11 %
Union
28 %

With respect to gas exports via pipeline, the Former Soviet Union
in 2005 accounted for some 44% of the world total. Africa,
meaning in this case Algeria, is also a significant exporter to
Europe, while any trade in the Asian and American regions is
intra-regional.

June 2011 | International Gas Union  59 


LNG imports are dominated by Asia Pacific – principally Price Formation: Pipeline Imports
Japan, Korea, and Taiwan, with Europe being the second largest
importing region. When compared with the LNG Exports chart, Chart A8: World price formation 2005 – pipeline imports
much of the Asia Pacific trade is intra-regional, but the region
also imports significant quantities from the Middle East, while
Africa and Latin America (Trinidad) are key exporters to Europe World price formation 2005: Pipeline imports
660 bcm
and North America.

Chart A6: LNG exports 2005 Bilateral monopoly


22,7 %

LNG exports 2005


190 bcm
Oil price escalation
54,8 %
Gas-on-gas
competition
North America 22,4 %
1,0 % Latin America
7,4 %
Middle East
Asia Pacific 23,0 %
44,5 %

Pipeline imports at 660 bcm account for some 22% of total world
consumption. Three categories account for internationally–
Africa
24,1 %
traded pipeline gas – OPE almost all in Europe; GOG in North
America with small amount in Europe into UK and BIM almost
all intra-Former Soviet Union trade.

Price Formation: Domestic Production Price Formation: LNG Imports

Chart A7: World price formation 2005 – indigenous production Chart A9: World price formation 2005 – LNG imports

World price formation 2005: World price formation 2005: LNG imports
Indigenous production 190 bcm
1,940 bcm

Not known Gas-on-gas Bilateral monopoly


No price Oil price escalation 3,7 %
0,4 % competition
1,7 % 4,4 %
13,4 %
Regulation below
cost Gas-on-gas
33,6 % competition
36,3 %

Bilateral monopoly Oil price escalation


Regulation Regulation cost of Netback 3,7 % 83,0 %
social/political service 0,7 %
15,6 % 3,6 %

Domestic production, consumed in own country, accounted LNG imports at 190 bcm account for some 6% of total world
for just under 2,000 bcm in 2005, around 70% of total world consumption. Internationally-traded LNG is largely dominated
consumption. The two largest price formation categories were by OPE into Europe and Asia Pacific. GOG is mainly North
GOG – accounting for some 35% mainly in North America, UK America with some spot LNG cargoes into Asia Pacific, while
in Europe and Australia in Asia Pacific – and RBC – accounting BIM is in Asia reflecting the LNG cargoes to India.
for 34%, largely the Former Soviet Union and Middle East with
some in Africa. RSP at 16% is spread through all regions apart
from North America. RCS, at 4%, is principally in Africa and
Asia, while BIM, at 5%, is mainly the Former Soviet Union
and Asia Pacific. There is a small amount of OPE in Europe
and Asia.

60  International Gas Union | June 2011


Price Formation: Total Imports Regional Results
In presenting the World results all 5 identified categories –
Chart A10: World price formation 2005 – total imports Domestic Production, Pipeline Imports, LNG Imports, Total
Imports and Total Consumption – were reviewed and analysed.
At the regional level not all the categories will be relevant, for
World price formation 2005: Total imports example, there may be little or no LNG imports into a region.
850 bcm
The data and charts presented for each region, therefore, will
differ depending on the relevance of each consumption category.
Bilateral monopoly
18,5 %
North America

In terms of an IGU region, North America consists of only 3


Gas-on-gas
competition Oil price escalation countries – Canada, USA and Mexico – but it is the largest
20,4 % 61,1 %
consuming region.

Table A1: North America consumption and production 2005


(BCM)

Total imports at 850 bcm account for some 30% of total world Country Consumption Production
Imports Exports
Pipeline LNG Pipeline LNG
consumption. 60% is OPE with Europe (pipeline mainly) and USA 629.8 511.8 104.2 17.9 20.3 1.8
Asia Pacific (LNG) dominating. GOG is both pipeline and Canada
Mexico
91.4
47.6
185.9
39.2
10.1
10.1
104.2
0.0
LNG imports, with BIM largely intra-Former Soviet Union Total North America 768.8 736.9 124.5 17.9 124.5 1.8

pipeline trade.
Consumption is dominated by the USA, which is also by far
Price Formation: Total Consumption the region’s largest producer. All pipeline trade is intra-regional
with the USA importing from Canada, but also exports to both
Chart A11: World price formation 2005 – total consumption Canada and Mexico. USA LNG exports are from Alaska to
Japan, while LNG imports are principally from Trinidad but
also small amounts from the Middle East and Africa.
World price formation 2005: Total
consumption
Chart A12: North America price formation 2005 – total
2,790 bcm
consumption
No price Not known
Regulation below 1,2 % 0,3 %
cost Oil price escalation
23,3 % 21,7 %
North America price formation 2005: Total
consumption
770 bcm
Regulation
social/political
10,9 % Gas-on-gas No price
competition 1,2 %
Regulation cost of 31,4 %
service Netback Bilateral monopoly
2,5 % 0,5 % 8,2 %

The respective shares of total world consumption for each price


formation mechanism reflect largely the dominance of domestic Gas-on-gas
production consumed in own country. OPE becomes more competition
98,8 %
important because of its dominance in gas traded across borders.

Just over 50% of total consumption is either OPE or GOG, The gas market in the USA is completely deregulated and all
while over 1/3rd is subject to some form of regulatory control prices are effectively set by gas-on-gas competition. Imports,
including RBC, where it could be said gas is effectively whether by pipeline or LNG are effectively price-takers. The
subsidised. Regulation of wholesale prices occurs in all regions market in Canada is linked to the USA markets and the price
apart from North America. formation mechanism is the same. Mexico imports gas from
the US at US prices. For domestically produced gas, a reference
The small amount of NET pricing is in Latin America (Trinidad price is set, which is based on the US price at the US-Mexico
to methanol plants) while NP (gas effectively given away) is border, plus the cost of transportation to the Los Ramones “hub”.
principally in the Former Soviet Union (Turkmenistan) and North From the Los Ramones “hub” further south the reference price
America (in Mexico, where Pemex refineries and petrochemical gets reduced based on transportation costs. However, some 10
plants use gas as a “free” feedstock). bcm of gas is estimated to be used by Pemex for its own internal

June 2011 | International Gas Union  61 


consumption, related to feedstock for petrochemical plants, Europe
fuel for equipment in refineries and plants and for secondary
oil recovery. This gas is not priced and has been allocated to Table A3: Europe consumption and production 2005 (BCM)
the No Price category.
Imports Exports
Latin America Country Consumption Production
Pipeline LNG Pipeline LNG
Austria 10.0 1.6 8.7
Belgium & Luxembourg 16.6 18.0 3.0 4.4

Table A2: Latin America consumption and production 2005 Bosnia-Herzegovina


Bulgaria
0.4
3.0
0.4
2.9
(BCM) Croatia
Czech Republic
2.7
8.5
1.5
0.2
1.2
9.5
Denmark 5.0 10.4 5.3
Estonia 1.5 0.7
Finland 4.0 4.2
Imports Exports
Country Consumption Production France 45.8 1.2 36.2 12.8
Pipeline LNG Pipeline LNG
Germany 86.2 15.8 90.7 9.8
Argentina 40.4 45.6 1.7 6.8 Greece 2.8 2.3 0.5
Bolivia 2.1 12.4 10.4 Hungary 13.2 3.0 10.8
Brazil 19.9 11.4 8.8 Ireland 3.9 0.6 3.1
Chile 8.5 2.0 6.5 Italy 78.7 12.1 71.0 2.5
Colombia 6.8 6.8 Latvia 1.8 1.2
Dominican Republic 0.3 0.3 Lithuania 3.3 2.9
Ecuador 0.3 0.3 Netherlands 39.5 62.9 23.0 46.8
Peru 1.5 1.6 Norway 4.5 85.0 79.5
Puerto Rico 0.7 0.7 Poland 13.6 4.3 10.2
Trinidad 16.3 30.3 14.0 Portugal 4.2 2.6 1.6
Uruguay 0.1 0.1 Romania 17.3 12.1 6.3
Venezuela 28.9 28.9 Serbia & Montenegro 2.2 0.3 1.9
Total Latin America 125.7 139.2 17.2 0.9 17.2 14.0 Slovakia 6.6 0.2 6.4
Slovenia 1.1 1.1
Spain 32.4 0.2 11.6 21.9

Latin American gas is largely produced and consumed within Sweden


Switzerland
0.8
3.1
1.0
2.8
each individual country with Venezuela, Colombia and Peru Turkey
United Kingdom
26.9
95.1
0.9
87.5
22.2
14.7
4.9
0.5 9.7
being completely domestic markets. All pipeline trade is intra- Total Europe 534.6 299.7 367.4 47.6 155.4 0.0

regional with Argentina importing from Bolivia but also exporting


to Chile. Bolivia also exports gas to Brazil. Even then almost Europe is highly dependent on imported gas both by pipeline
all of Argentina’s consumption is domestically produced and and LNG. Of the largest consumers, only the UK produced
over half of Brazil’s. almost all of its gas requirements, and this situation is rapidly
changing. Norway and the Netherlands provided a significant
Chart A13: Latin America price formation 2005 – total proportion of the rest of Europe’s pipeline supplies, but Europe
consumption remained heavily dependent on Russian and Algerian pipeline
supplies. The major importers of LNG were Spain and France with
Algeria being the principal supplier, but significant quantities of
Latin America price formation 2005: Total
consumption
LNG were also sourced from West Africa and the Middle East.
125 bcm
Oil price escalation
Out of the total European consumption in 2005 of 535 bcm,
14,8 % only 124 bcm (23%) was produced and consumed within the
Regulation below
cost
Gas-on-gas
competition country and 2/3rds of this was in the UK market. The chart
2,5 % 1,6 %
below shows the price formation mechanisms for this domestic
Bilateral monopoly
6,7 % production with GOG at 46% and OPE at 36% dominating.
This was largely the UK, where some of the older contracts
Netback
Regulation 9,5 % still retain key elements of competing fuel indexation, but also
social/political
59,5 %
Regulation cost of
service
domestic production in the Netherlands and Italy is largely on an
5,4 % OPE basis. Wholesale prices for domestic production remained
regulated on a RSP basis in Poland and Romania. There were
small elements of NET in Norway and BIM in Denmark.
Latin America consumption at 125 bcm accounts for less than
5% of total world consumption. The traded pipeline gas to Brazil
and Chile mainly account for most of the OPE. Wholesale prices
in the 2 largest consuming countries, Argentina and Venuezela,
are largely determined by regulatory and/or government control
(RSP). Some large customers in Argentina are free to negotiate
directly with suppliers (BIM), as are power generators in Trinidad.
NET is in Trinidad where gas is provided to Methanol plants.
There is a small amount of GOG in Chile.

62  International Gas Union | June 2011


Chart A14: Europe price formation 2005 – indigenous production In total, at 540 bcm, Europe accounts for around 20% of world
consumption. The dependence in imports, most of which are
priced on an OPE basis, is illustrated in the chart above, with
Europe price formation 2005: Indigenous
production
OPE at 79%. GOG is largely the UK market.
124 bcm
Regulation cost of
service
Regulation
Former Soviet Union
1,2 %
social/political No price
11,6 % 2,8 %
Netback
0,6 % Oil price escalation Table A4: FSU consumption and production 2005 (BCM)
34,7 %
Bilateral monopoly
2,0 %
Imports Exports
Country Consumption Production
Pipeline LNG Pipeline LNG
Armenia 1.7 1.7
Gas-on-gas Azerbaijan 8.9 5.3 4.5
Belarus 18.9 0.3 20.1
competition
Georgia 1.5 0.2 1.5
47,0 %
Kazakhstan 19.6 23.3 11.6 7.6
Kyrgyzstan 0.7 0.0 0.7
Moldova 2.5 0.1 2.5
Russian Federation 405.1 598.0 25.6 229.0
Tajikistan 1.4 0.0 1.4
Turkmenistan 16.6 58.8 0.0 45.2
Chart A15: Europe price formation 2005 – total imports Ukraine
Uzbekistan
72.9
44.0
19.4
55.0
55.3
0.0
2.5
12.4
Total FSU 593.8 760.5 124.8 0.0 296.7 0.0

Europe price formation 2005: Total imports


The Former Soviet Union region is dominated by Russia, both
415 bcm
as the largest consumer and producer of gas. All the imported
gas within the region is intra-FSU trade i.e. no imports come
Gas-on-gas
competition Bilateral monopoly
1,5 %
from outside the region. Russia exports gas to almost all its
6,0 %
neighbouring countries but Kazakhstan, Turkmenistan and
Uzbekistan are also exporters, including to Russia. Ukraine is
the major importer of gas.

Chart A17: FSU price formation 2005 – total consumption


Oil price escalation
92,4 %

FSU price formation 2005: Total consumption


595 bcm

The situation for total imports (both pipeline and LNG, comprising
415 bcm or 78% of total consumption) is markedly different, No price
2,8 % Bilateral monopoly
with OPE dominating at 92%. The small amount of GOG (6%) 29,1 %

is predominantly the UK, plus Ireland and a small amount in


the Netherlands. The BIM category (2%) is accounted for by
imports into the Baltic States (Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania) Regulation
social/political
Regulation below
from Russia. cost 3,0 %
65,1 %

Chart A16: Europe price formation 2005 – total consumption

At 595 bcm the Former Soviet Union accounts for just over
Europe price formation 2005: Total
consumption
20% of world consumption. All imported gas is priced on a
540 bcm
BIM basis, together with some Russia domestic production
sold to large users. The dominant price formation mechanism,
Regulation cost Regulation
Netback
0,1 %
of service social/political however, is RBC in Russia, Uzbekistan and Kazakhstan. Since
0,3 % 2,7 %
Bilateral monopoly No price 2005, however, this situation in Russia, at least, is likely to have
0,6 %
1,6 %
Gas-on-gas
changed with increased prices to domestic consumers raising
competition
15,5 %
levels above the average cost of production and transportation.
Domestic production in Ukraine is the RSP category and NP
in Turkmenistan.

Oil price escalation


79,1 %

June 2011 | International Gas Union  63 


Middle East Chart A19: Africa price formation 2005 – total consumption

Table A5: Middle East consumption and production 2005 (BCM)


Africa price formation 2005: Total
Imports Exports
consumption
Country Consumption Production
Pipeline LNG Pipeline LNG 75 bcm
Bahrain 10.7 10.7
Iran 102.4 100.9 5.8 4.3
Iraq 2.5 2.5 Oil price escalation
Israel 0.7 0.7 No price 5,7 % Netback
Jordan 1.6 0.3 1.3 1,1 % 1,2 %
Kuwait 12.3 12.3
Oman 9.2 19.8 1.4 9.2
Regulation cost of
Qatar 18.7 45.8 27.1
service
Saudi Arabia 71.2 71.2
32,6 %
Syria 6.1 5.4 Regulation below
United Arab Emirates 41.3 47.0 1.4 7.1 cost
Total Middle East 276.6 316.6 8.5 0.0 5.7 43.5 48,2 %

Regulation
social/political
The Middle East region is largely an insulated market in terms 11,2 %

of gas consumption with very little gas being traded (excluding


exports) across borders. Small quantities of gas are imported
by Iran from Turkmenistan and Jordan from Egypt. In terms of consumption, Africa is the smallest region at 75
bcm, or 2.5% of total world consumption. Wholesale prices
Chart A18: Middle East price formation 2005 – total consumption are highly regulated, with RBC accounting for just under half,
in Egypt and Nigeria. RCS is predominantly Algeria and RSP
in Libya and South Africa. The OPE category reflects the only
Middle East price formation 2005: Total
consumption
traded gas with Tunisia importing from Algeria.
275 bcm
Asia
Not known Bilateral monopoly
0,9 % 2,6 %
No price Regulation
1,3 % social/political Table A7: Asia consumption and production 2005 (BCM)
14,8 %

Imports Exports
Country Consumption Production
Pipeline LNG Pipeline LNG
Afghanistan 0.2 0.2
Bangladesh 14.2 14.2
China 45.7 50.0 3.1
China Hong Kong 3.1 3.1
Regulation below India 38.1 32.1 6.0
cost Myanmar 4.1 13.0 8.9
80,4 % Pakistan 29.3 29.3
Total Asia 134.7 138.8 3.1 6.0 12.0 0.0

Middle East consumption at 275 bcm accounts for almost 10% Again there is not a large amount of traded gas within this
of total world consumption. The dominant price formation region – China Hong Kong imports from China, while India
mechanism in the region is RBC in largely Iran, Saudi Arabia, imports LNG, principally from Qatar. China, India and Pakistan
Kuwait and Qatar. The RSP category is accounted for by the are the largest consumers. China and India are expected to
UAE, where price is regulated by each emirate. The BIM increase gas consumption significantly from both indigenous
category relates to Iranian imports from Turkmenistan and the resources and imports.
trade from Oman to the UAE.
Chart A20: Asia price formation 2005 – total consumption

Africa
Asia price formation 2005: Total consumption
135 bcm
Table A6: Africa consumption and production 2005 (BCM)
Regulation below
Imports Exports Oil price escalation
Country Consumption Production cost
Pipeline LNG Pipeline LNG 10,5 %
3,0 %
Algeria 23.2 88.2 39.1 25.7
Bilateral monopoly
Angola 0.8 0.8
6,8 %
Egypt 25.8 34.6 1.1 6.9
Equatorial Guinea 1.3 1.3
Ivory Coast 1.3 1.3
Libya 5.8 11.3 4.5 0.9
Nigeria 10.4 22.4 12.0 Regulation cost of
South Africa 2.2 2.2 Regulation service
Tunisia 4.3 2.5 1.8 social/political 21,8 %
Total Africa 75.1 164.6 1.8 0.0 44.7 45.5 57,9 %

Excluding its export trade, Africa has virtually not traded gas,
with only Tunisia importing some gas from Algeria via the
pipeline to Italy.

64  International Gas Union | June 2011


Asia accounts for less than 5% of world consumption at 135 Wholesale Prices
bcm. Regulation of wholesale prices is widespread. RSP at 57% As well as collecting data on price formation mechanisms the
is predominantly China and India, RCS in Pakistan and RBC in IGU study also collected information on wholesale price levels
Myanmar. OPE at 11% is all in Bangladesh. The BIM category in 2005. As noted elsewhere, the results here should be treated
is Indian LNG imports and Hong Kong imports from China. as broad orders of magnitude, since the definition of wholesale
prices is quite wide. It is typically a hub price or a border price
in the case of internationally traded gas, but could also easily
Asia Pacific be a wellhead or city-gate price.

Table A8: Asia Pacific consumption and production 2005 (BCM) Chart A22: Wholesale prices by region 2005

Imports Exports
Country Consumption Production
Pipeline LNG Pipeline LNG World: Average wholesale prices 2005
Australia 26.8 40.3 14.9
Brunei 2.4 11.5 9.2 North America
Indonesia 37.5 73.8 4.8 31.5
Japan 79.0 5.1 76.3 Europe
Malaysia 39.3 59.9 1.8 28.5
New Zealand 3.5 3.8 Asia Pacific
Philippines 3.0 2.9
Total World
Singapore 6.6 6.6
South Korea 33.7 0.5 30.5 Asia
Taiwan 10.7 0.8 9.6
Thailand 29.9 23.7 8.9 Africa
Vietnam 6.9 6.9
Total Asia Pacific 279.3 229.2 15.5 116.4 6.6 84.0 Latin America

Former Soviet Union

Middle East
After Europe, Asia Pacific is the region most heavily dependent
on internationally traded gas, principally LNG into Japan, $0,00 $1,00 $2,00 $3,00 $4,00
$/MMBTU
$5,00 $6,00 $7,00 $8,00 $9,00

Korea and Taiwan, although much of the LNG comes from


within the region together with imports from the Middle East.
A distinguishing feature of Japan, Korea and Taiwan is that The chart above shows a snapshot of price levels for 2005.
they are virtually totally dependent on LNG imports for all Wholesale prices have changed since 2005, as discussed elsewhere.
their gas consumption, leading to what some might argue are Generally the highest wholesale prices are in regions where, it
the premium prices paid for the gas. The pipeline imports are could be said that, there is more “economic” pricing – GOG and
into Singapore from Indonesia and Malaysia and Thailand OPE – in North America, Europe and Asia Pacific. The lowest
from Myanmar. wholesale prices are generally where regulation dominates in
the Middle East and Former Soviet Union, particularly RBC.
Chart A21: Asia Pacific price formation 2005 – total consumption
These conclusions are illustrated more clearly in the chart
below which considers wholesale prices at the individual
Asia Pacific price formation 2005: Total
consumption
country level, at least for those countries with more than 10 bcm
280 bcm
annual consumption. Only Bahrain, UAE and Turkmenistan are
missing with over 10 bcm consumption. The highest wholesale
Regulation
Not known prices in 2005 were found in North America (USA, Canada
2,0 %
social/political
24,8 %
and Mexico). The LNG dependent countries of Japan, Korea
and Taiwan also had relatively high wholesale prices. These
were followed by a whole host of European countries headed
Oil price
Regulation cost of escalation by UK and France. At the bottom of the chart were generally
service
2,9 %
50,4 %
countries where wholesale prices were subject to some form
Bilateral monopoly
8,1 %
Gas-on-gas of regulation, typically RBC – Iran, Nigeria, Saudi Arabia,
competition
11,8 % Russia and Egypt.

At 280 bcm, Asia Pacific accounts for 10% of total world


consumption. Some 50% of gas is imported by countries. OPE
at 50% is the largest category and comprises LNG imports
into Japan, Korea and Taiwan, pipeline into Singapore and
domestically produced gas in Thailand. GOG is Australia and
spot LNG trade. BIM is mainly imports into Thailand and some
domestic production in Indonesia and New Zealand. RSP is the
majority of wholesale gas in Indonesia and Malaysia. RCS is
Vietnam.

June 2011 | International Gas Union  65 


Chart A23: Wholesale prices by country 2005 Chart A25: World price formation 2005 – total consumption

Average wholesale prices 2005 World price formation 2005: Total


USA
Taiwan
Mexico
consumption
Canada
South Korea
France
United Kingdom
Japan
2,790 bcm
Netherlands
Belgium & Luxembourg
Hungary
Austria
Poland
No price Not known
Turkey
Germany Regulation below 1,2 % 0,3 %
Italy
Spain
Thailand cost Oil price escalation
Indonesia
Romania World Average 23,3 % 21,7 %
Brazil
Bangladesh
Australia
Pakistan
China
Algeria
India
Malaysia
Trinidad
Ukraine
Belarus
Russian Federation
Egypt
Regulation
Kuwait
Kazakhstan social/political
Venezuela
Argentina 10,9 % Gas-on-gas
Qatar
Saudi Arabia Countries over 10 bcm
Uzbekistan competition
Nigeria Annual Consumption
Iran
Regulation cost of 31,4 %
$0,00 $1,00 $2,00 $3,00 $4,00 $5,00 $6,00 $7,00 $8,00 $9,00 $10,00 service Netback Bilateral monopoly
$/MMBTU 2,5 % 0,5 % 8,2 %

Chart A24: Wholesale prices by price formation mechanism 2005 Table A9: World price formation 2005 – total consumption (BCM)

Total Consumption
Wholesale prices by price formation Region
OPE GOG BIM NET RCS RSP RBC NP NK TOT
mechanism 2005 North America 0.0 759.4 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 9.4 0.0 768.8
Latin America 18.7 2.0 8.4 11.9 6.8 74.8 3.1 0.0 0.0 125.7
$9,00
Europe 426.6 83.4 8.7 0.7 1.7 14.4 0.0 3.5 0.0 539.1
$8,00
$7,00
Former Soviet Union 0.0 0.0 172.9 0.0 0.0 17.6 386.6 16.6 0.0 593.7
$6,00 Middle East 0.0 0.0 7.2 0.0 0.0 40.6 221.5 3.6 2.5 275.3
$/MMBTU

$5,00 Africa 4.3 0.0 0.0 0.9 24.5 8.4 36.2 0.8 0.0 75.1
$4,00 Asia 14.2 0.0 9.1 0.0 29.3 78.0 4.1 0.0 0.0 134.7
$3,00 Asia Pacific 140.8 33.0 22.6 0.0 8.0 69.3 0.0 0.0 5.6 279.3
$2,00 Total World 604.6 877.9 228.9 13.5 70.3 303.2 651.4 33.8 8.1 2,791.7
$1,00 22% 31% 8% 0% 3% 11% 23% 1% 0% 100%
$0,00
y

T
n

ck

al
n

ce

s
ol
tio

io

TO
co

The chart above illustrates the overall results at the world level,
ic
ba

vi
op
tit

lit
la

er

w
et
pe

o
on
ca

fs

l/p

lo
N
m
es

be
to

ia

while the table looks at the breakdown by region.


co

c
e

ra

n
so
ic

co
s

io
te
ga
pr

at
n
la

io
n-

ul
il

io
Bi
O

at
-o

eg
at

ul
as

ul

R
eg
eg
G

• The largest price formation category is GOG at 31%, but


R
R

this is due to the impact of the North American market,


An alternative way of analysing the data is to categorise by price which is predominantly domestic gas production, plus
formation mechanism. The highest wholesale prices are GOG smaller quantities in the UK and, in Asia Pacific, Australia
followed by OPE. At the bottom end, as might be expected, and spot LNG cargoes;
wholesale prices determined by RBC are less then RSP which, • The OPE category at 22%, is generally only found in
in turn, are less then RCS. The low level of wholesale prices internationally traded gas, which is mainly pipeline and
for NET are presumably affected by low commodity prices for LNG in Europe and LNG in Asia Pacific;
the final products – almost all Trinidad and some in Norway. • Together the GOG and OPE categories, which could be said
The result for BIM is largely impacted by the low levels of to reflect an “economic” or “market” value of gas, account
wholesale prices in intra-Former Soviet Union trade. for just over 50% of total world consumption;
• Wholesale price “regulation”, which covers 3 categories
– RCS, RSP and RBC, accounts for 37% of total world
Conclusions consumption, but is only found in domestic gas production
and not internationally traded gas. The RBC category in
In 2005 just over 70% of the world’s consumption of gas 2005 was the largest, as a consequence of the low levels
comprised of domestic production consumed within that country, of prices in the Former Soviet Union, mainly Russia, and
with no trade across international borders. Some 22% was the Middle East. While wholesale prices in Russia have
traded through pipelines and some 6% LNG. The wholesale remained regulated there have been price increases, which
price formation mechanisms are largely very different for would mean that, by 2007, most of the market would not be
internationally traded gas compared to gas which is produced in the RBC category, probably moving to the RSP category;
purely for domestic consumption. • The RSP category, at 11%, is found across all regions, apart
from North America;
• The BIM category, at 8%, is mainly traded gas between
the Former Soviet Union countries, principally Russian
exports, plus, in Asia Pacific, imported gas in India and
Thailand and partly domestically produced gas in Indonesia.

66  International Gas Union | June 2011


In respect of wholesale price levels in 2005, the chart below
shows that price levels were generally higher in the GOG
markets of the US and the UK, as prices peaked at high levels
during the year, followed by OPE. At the bottom end, as might
be expected, wholesale prices determined by RBC are less then
RSP which, in turn, are less then RCS. The result for BIM is
largely impacted by the low levels of wholesale prices in intra-
Former Soviet Union trade. In 2006/7, however, GOG prices
have declined to below comparable OPE prices.

Chart A26: Wholesale prices by price formation 2005

Wholesale prices by price formation


mechanism 2005
$9,00
$8,00
$7,00
$6,00
$/MMBTU

$5,00
$4,00
$3,00
$2,00
$1,00
$0,00
y

T
n

ck

al
n

ce

s
ol
tio

io

TO
co
ic
ba

vi
op
tit

lit
la

er

w
et
pe

o
on
ca

fs

l/p

lo
N
m
es

be
to

ia
co

c
e

ra

n
so
ic

co
s

io
te
ga
pr

at
n
la

io
n-

ul
il

io
Bi
O

at
-o

eg
at

ul
as

ul

R
eg
eg
G

R
R

June 2011 | International Gas Union  67 


IGU
The International Gas Union is a worldwide non-profit
organisation aimed at promoting the technical and
economic progress of the gas industry. The Union has
more than 100 members worldwide on all continents.
The members of IGU are national associations and
corporations of the gas industry. IGU’s working organi-
sation covers all aspects of the gas industry, including
exploration and production, storage, LNG, distribu-
tion and natural gas utilisation in all market segments.
IGU promotes technical and economic progress of
the gas industry emphasising environmental perform-
ance worldwide. For more information, please visit IGU members
www.igu.org

International Gas Union

Office of the Secretary General


c/o Statoil ASA
0246 Oslo
Norway

Telephone: + 47 51 99 00 00
Fax: + 47 22 53 43 40
Email: secrigu@statoil.com
Website: www.igu.org

110352 IGU 2011, Photo: Eiliv Leren, Harald Pettersen, Helge Hansen, Øyvind Hagen

Sponsored by:

68  International Gas Union | June 2011


 

  PROGRAM ON ENERGY AND   
SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT 
 

  Working Paper
 
#94 
 
August 2010 
 

 
T HE 
 
W ORLD ’ S  G REATEST  C OAL  A RBITRAGE :   C HINA ’ S  C OAL 
I MPORT 
  B EHAVIOR AND  I MPLICATIONS FOR THE  G LOBAL  C OAL 
M ARKET
   
 
RICHARD K. MORSE AND GANG HE 
 

FREEMAN SPOGLI INSTITUTE FOR INTERNATIONAL STUDIES 

 
 

Photo credit: Reuters  Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1654676


 

About the Program on Energy and Sustainable Development

The Program on Energy and Sustainable Development (PESD) is an international, interdisciplinary


program that studies how institutions shape patterns of energy production and use, in turn affecting
human welfare and environmental quality. Economic and political incentives and pre-existing legal
frameworks and regulatory processes all play crucial roles in determining what technologies and policies
are chosen to address current and future energy and environmental challenges. PESD research examines
issues including: 1) effective policies for addressing climate change, 2) the role of national oil companies
in the world oil market, 3) the emerging global coal market, 4) the world natural gas market with a focus
on the impact of unconventional sources, 5) business models for carbon capture and storage, 6) adaptation
of wholesale electricity markets to support a low-carbon future, 7) global power sector reform, and 8)
how modern energy services can be supplied sustainably to the world’s poorest regions.

The Program is part of the Freeman Spogli Institute for International Studies at Stanford University.
PESD gratefully acknowledges substantial core funding from BP.

Program on Energy and Sustainable Development


Encina Hall East, Room E415
Stanford University
Stanford, CA 94305-6055
http://pesd.stanford.edu

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1654676


About the Authors

Richard K. Morse leads global coal market research at the Stanford Program on Energy and
Sustainable Development (PESD). PESD's coal research examines the political economy of coal,
the international trade and pricing of coal, and coal's long term role in the world's energy mix.
Other research interests include carbon policy and carbon markets, carbon capture and storage,
renewable energy markets, and financial markets for energy commodities.

Richard received a B.A. in philosophy from Rice University, where he was awarded the James
Street Fulton Prize for the top graduate in the field. He has worked in commodities markets for
oil, natural gas, renewable energy, and emissions as an energy analyst and trader.

Gang He is a research associate at the Program on Energy and Sustainable Development


(PESD). Gang leads PESD’s research on China, focusing on China’s energy and climate change
policies, carbon capture and storage, the domestic coal sector, and its key role in both the global
coal market and in international climate policy frameworks. He also studies other issues related
to global climate change and the development of lower-carbon energy sources.

Gang received a B.S. in Geography from Peking University and a M.A. in Climate and Society
from Columbia University.

 
 

 
The World’s Greatest Coal Arbitrage:
China’s Coal Import Behavior and
Implications for the Global Coal Market

Richard K. Morse and Gang He

Introduction

In 2009 the global coal market witnessed one of the most dramatic realignments it has ever seen
– China, long a net exporter of coal, suddenly imported a record-smashing 126 Mt tons (see
Figure 1). 1 This inversion of China’s role in global coal markets meant that Chinese imports
accounted for nearly 15% of all globally traded coal, and China became the focal point of global
demand as traditional import markets like Europe and Japan stagnated in the wake of the
financial crisis. By the first quarter of 2010, even Colombia was defying established trade
patterns by sending cargoes to China despite its massive geographic disadvantage to export coal
into Asian markets. The middle kingdom’s appetite for imported coal seems insatiable, and the
“China Factor” appears to have ushered in a new paradigm for the global coal market.

But China doesn’t “need” the coal. The world’s largest coal producer cranked out 2.96 Bt of
production in 2009, backed up by 114.5 Bt of reserves. 2 While the world’s other fastest growing
importer, India, is plagued by a growing gap between coal supply and power demand that it is
unable to fill domestically, this is not the case in China. The spike in Chinese demand for
imported coal is therefore a more complex (and less easily predictable) phenomenon that
requires careful examination if the world is to understand what impact China might have on
global energy markets in the coming decade.

                                                            
1
103 Mt net imports. Source: National Energy Administration of China.
2
This reserve number is widely used by IEA, BP Energy Statistics Review, etc. China’s Ministry of Land and
Resources shows 183 Bt in its updated “Mineral Resources Reserves Classification”. See more details in Wang
Qingyi, China Energy Statistics.

5 August 2010 1 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


In this paper we outline a model that explains Chinese coal import patterns and that can allow the
coal market to understand, and to some degree predict, China’s coal import behavior. We argue
that the unique structure of the Chinese coal market creates a series of key arbitrage relationships
between Chinese domestic coal markets and international coal markets that determine Chinese
import patterns. Based on this theory of China’s import behavior, we construct an arbitrage-
based import model that explains the dramatic shift in Chinese net imports over the last several
years.

The implications of this model are significant for the development of the global coal trade in the
coming decade. First, we find that China’s import behavior does not represent a “structural
shift” in global markets. China, as a participant in the global coal market, is a cost-minimizer
that will be both a buyer and seller in the global market as key price relationships fluctuate.
Second, and perhaps most importantly, the arbitrage relationships that we describe directly link
the domestic price of coal in China to the global price of coal. This linkage has significant
implications for the use of coal and the cost of generating power globally in the coming decades.
Developments in China’s domestic coal market will be a dominant factor determining global
coal prices and trade flows (and by implication power prices in many regions). This makes
understanding the domestic Chinese coal market, which operates according to a unique economic
and political logic, crucial for any participant in the global markets.3

                                                            
3
A series of forthcoming studies on the structure and long term future of the Chinese coal market will be release by
PESD Stanford in 2010, and can be found at http://pesd.stanford.edu

5 August 2010 2 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


18
Monthly Million Metric Tons
16
14
12
10 Imports
8
6
Total 
4
Exports
2
0

Jul‐09

Jan‐10
Jul‐08

Jan‐09
Jul‐07

Jan‐08
Jul‐06

Jan‐07
Jul‐05

Jan‐06
Jul‐04

Jan‐05
Jul‐03

Jan‐04
Jul‐02

Jan‐03
Jan‐02

Figure 1 – Chinese net imports were negative until 2008, when historical trade balances inverted
dramatically. Source: McCloskey.

1 Geographic Fundamentals of the Chinese Coal Market

China’s coal reserves and production are concentrated in the North and West of China. Three
provinces in these regions – Shanxi, Shaanxi, and Inner Mongolia – have 69% of the country’s
proven reserves and were home to half of national production in 2009. That same year Inner
Mongolia surpassed Shanxi to become the largest producer at 637 Mt; Shanxi produced 615 Mt,
and Shaanxi produced 296 Mt. 4 70% of the production in these three provinces is exported
outside of its home province to supply coal demand most heavily concentrated along the eastern
and southern coasts. Figure 2 illustrates the basic geography of Chinese coal regions.

Northern coastal Chinese coal demand is served by a network of truck routes and railways that
move coal east and south from western and northern production centers. But rail and truck
capacity to supply coal to Southeast China is both insufficient and prohibitively expensive.
Therefore coal supply for Southeast China is first transported east on rail lines like the Da-Qin
and Shuo-Huang to eastern ports like Qinhuangdao, Huanghua, Rizao, next loaded onto boats,
and finally shipped south via sea routes. Figure 3 illustrates China’s major coal transport
infrastructure segments. This rail-to-sea link is still much cheaper than moving coal overland
                                                            
4
National Bureau of Statistics China.

5 August 2010 3 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


from North to South. Though the costs associated with this transport route are still high; the
transportation cost of moving coal from Shanxi to Guangzhou can be as high as 50-60% of the
price of coal delivered to Guangzhou. 5 The high cost of moving coal to the heavily industrialized
coastal area that includes the Pearl River Delta and the Yangtze River Delta opens windows for
import coals to compete with domestic coals.

Southeast China is also the closest region in China to two major global coal exporting nations,
Indonesia and Australia. Coal buyers in Southeast China therefore are often confronted with two
options: buy domestic coal delivered by sea from Northern Chinese ports, or buy international
coal. This arbitrage opportunity allows Chinese coal buyers to take advantage of price
differentials between domestic Chinese coal and international coal prices. Until 2009, those
differentials had not favored imports.

Figure 2 – Map of Chinese “coal planning regions”, as described by NDRC’s Coal Industry Policy of
2007. Source: Kevin Tu.

                                                            
5
This is an estimate. Costs fluctuate according to the price of coal and the price of shipping coal.

5 August 2010 4 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


Figure 3 – Schematic of China’s major coal transportation infrastructure. Source: Kevin Tu.

2 The Arbitrage Model of Chinese Coal Imports

We argue that modeling arbitrage spreads between domestic and international coals for coal
buyers in Southern China explains China’s 2009 import spike and can also be used to reliably
analyze China’s national import behavior under future market conditions. In this section we
describe the parameters of our model, called the China Coal Import Arbitrage Model
(ChinaCoalArb for short), and demonstrate how its results can be used to interpret China’s
import trends.

Chinese coal buyers in Southeastern China can buy coal from multiple markets, and price
discrepancies between different markets create profit opportunities. For a portion of spot market
demand, buyers will compare the CIF 6 cost of coal landed in Guangzhou from multiple
F

destinations and, all other things equal, will take the cheapest coal. 7 The differentials between
CIF Guangzhou coal prices from multiple origins therefore create arbitrage opportunities for

                                                            
6
CIF is a coal market term indicating that a price is for the delivered location, and thus includes all freight costs.
7
For purposes of modeling we have slightly simplified the dynamics of Chinese coal buying behavior to focus on
the domestic vs. import tradeoff. For instance, we have not included term contracts or prices at port stockpile in our
model.

5 August 2010 5 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


Chinese buyers who can shift their purchasing patterns to capture the differential between
domestic and international markets under different conditions. The model calculates these
arbitrage relationships of domestic to key international coals. We then compare these arbitrage
relationships to historical imports, demonstrating that import levels have broadly tracked these
arbitrage trends, increasing where price spreads favored international coals over domestic coals.

3.1 Supply Points and FOB Prices

Chinese domestic prices in ChinaCoalArb are represented by FOB 8 prices at the Qinhuangdao
port. Qinhuangdao port is mainly supplied with coal from Shanxi, Shaanxi and Inner Mongolia
and is China’s largest coal port. Qinhuangdao throughput in 2009 was 206.33 Mt, and the total
throughput of the seven major coal ports serving Northern China was 433Mt. 9,10 Coal loaded in
Qinhuangdao and delivered to Guangzhou is transported south down the Chinese coast via
maritime shipping. Figure 4 below shows the historical development of prices at Qinhuangdao.

We select three key international coal supply countries as the model’s suppliers. Australia,
Indonesia, and Russia were the largest exporters of coal to China in 2009. 11,12 All three
countries are major exporters to the international market and benefit from reasonably proximity
to Chinese import markets. Table 1 shows 2009 total Chinese imports from these origins. FOB
coal prices in each of these markets are derived from bids and offers at those locations. 13 Figure
4 shows the historical development of Russian, Indonesian, and Australian export coal prices
from 2005.

                                                            
8
 FOB is a shipping term meaning “Free On Board”, and in the coal market it indicates the price quoted for coal
loaded on the vessel at the port of origin. 
9
Qinhuangdao Port, China Coal Transportation and Distribution Association.
10
These ports include: Qinhuangdao, Tangshan, Huanghua, Tianjin, Rizhao, Lianyungang, and Qingdao.
11
China has historically imported coal from Vietnam, but due to increased Vietnamese domestic consumption and
price increases imports from Vietnam are expected to decline.
12
Russian imports are not necessarily delivered into Southern China as the port of Vostochny is north of the Chinese
border. But even though Russian ports are north rather than south, the general arbitrage principal applies and thus
we have included Russia in our model even if Russian material is not always imported to Guangzhou. Russian
exports to China are still comparatively small, but increased from 0.76Mt in 2008 to 11.8 Mt in 2009.
13
There are multiple price indices used in the coal market. We have used here indices provided by McCloskey and
Reuters.

5 August 2010 6 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


180
Qinhuangdao (6,000 kcal/kg NAR)

160 Newcastle (6,700 kcal/kg GAD)

140 Vostochnny Russia (6,700 kcal/kg GAD)
USD / metric ton

Kalimantan Indonesia (4,900 kcal/kg 
120 NAR)

100

80

60

40

20

Apr‐10
Apr‐09

Oct‐09
Jan‐10
Apr‐08

Oct‐08
Jan‐09
Apr‐07

Oct‐07
Jan‐08
Apr‐06

Oct‐06
Jan‐07
Apr‐05

Oct‐05
Jan‐06
Jan‐05

Jul‐09
Jul‐08
Jul‐07
Jul‐06
Jul‐05

Figure 4 – Major coal price indices in Asia. Source: McCloskey, Reuters.

Table 1 – 2009 China Coal Imports by Source

Total Australia Indonesia Vietnam Russia Mongolia

126.491 Mt 44.602 Mt 30.461 Mt 23.932 Mt 11.787 Mt 6.002 Mt

Canada North Korea USA South Africa New Zealand Other

4.093 Mt 3.599 Mt .805 Mt .732 Mt .303 Mt .145 Mt


Source: McCloskey. Units: Million metric tons.

5 August 2010 7 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


3.2 Import Demand Centers

The port of Guangzhou in Guangdong province functions as the demand center of our arbitrage
model. Guangdong is a heavily industrialized zone that has historically been the largest coal
importing province. Coal imports by province for 2009 are shown in Table 2. Guangzhou
port’s coal handling capacity reached 56.5Mt/year in 2008. Nearby import centers witness
similar price relationships between domestic and international markets and exhibit import
patterns. Arbitrage relationships for Guangzhou can therefore be used as a proxy for arbitrage
relationships for all of Southeastern China. 14 Other major coal ports of Southeastern China
include Shanghai, Ningbo, Fuzhou, Xiamen, Quanzhou, Shantou, and Beihai ports.

Table 2 – China coal import by provinces, 2009

All Total
Province Guangxi Guangdong Fujian Zhejiang Shanghai
other

Import 14.14 33.72 12.00 10.26 3.13 52.75 126

Source: Calculated from China Customs Statistics. Units: Mt.

3.3 Freight Prices

The delivered cost of coal in Guangzhou (CIF) is calculated by adding freight costs between
loading and discharge ports to the FOB coal cost. 15 Dry bulk freight rates from Indonesia,
Russia, or Australia into China largely track international dry bulk freight markets which are
volatile, internationally traded commodity markets (see historical freight rates in Figure 5). 16
The model uses specific freight prices quoted from each FOB loading port and delivered into
Guangzhou port provided by AXS Marine.
                                                            
14
The basis difference between Guangzhou and other cities in Southeast China will be roughly the freight costs
differential between those two locations. Thus while Guangzhou is the center of coal imports in China and is
indicative of market conditions for imports in general, some minor basis differentials will exist for other locations.
15
There are a few other adjustments which we describe later.
16
The Baltic Dry Index, which is widely used to indicate the cost of chartering dry bulk freight vessels, reached
highs of 11,459 in 2008 before crashing to lows near 670 in late that year. The Index is comprised of charter rates
for four types of ships: capsize, panamax, supramax, and handysize. For further details see the Baltic
Exchange: http://www.balticexchange.com/default.asp?action=article&ID=1
A price history is available from Bloomberg:
http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/quote?ticker=BDIY&exch=IND&x=15&y=11

5 August 2010 8 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


Freight prices for the Chinese maritime coastal shipping market are not fully connected to
international freight prices, however. Smaller boats are typically dedicated to the domestic
market, though larger boats can switch into the international shipping markets when prices are
attractive. 17 The Shanghai Shipping Index measures the cost of sending coal from Qinhuangdao
to Guangzhou (see Figure 3). 18 Model freight price assumptions assume capesize vessels for all
international shipping routes, and 40-50,000 dead weight ton (DWT) vessels for Chinese coastal
shipping prices. Representative port handling charges for loading and discharge are added for all
ports. 19

50 Newcastle to GZO

Qinhuangdao to GZO
40
Kalimantan to GZO
USD / metric ton

Vostochny to GZO
30

20

10

0
Jun‐07

Aug‐07

Oct‐07

Dec‐07

Feb‐08

Apr‐08

Jun‐08

Aug‐08

Oct‐08

Dec‐08

Feb‐09
Apr‐09

Jun‐09

Aug‐09

Oct‐09

Dec‐09

Feb‐10
Apr‐10

Figure 5 – Dry bulk freight rates from FOB ports to Guangzhou (GZO) port in ChinaCoalArb. Source:
AXS Marine, Reuters, authors’ analysis. Rates are based on historical quotes for specific shipping routes.
All international quotes are based on capesize vessels, China domestic quotes are based on 40-50,000 dwt
vessels.

                                                            
17
We benefited from discussion with Jon Windham of Macquarie Securities who offered his views of the Chinese
domestic shipping market and generously shared his research and data.
18
More information on the Shanghai Shipping Index is available at http://en.chineseshipping.com.cn/html/index.asp.
19
We assign port fees based on rates provided by AXS Marine.

5 August 2010 9 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


3.4 Adjustments: Energy Content, Taxes, Exchange Rates, Transaction Costs

We make the following adjustments in order to more accurately reflect real market conditions:

First, coal buyers are buying energy. We therefore adjust all FOB prices to an energy equivalent
USD/metric ton basis of 6,700 kcal/kg gross air dried (GAD). 20 The original energy content of
FOB indices are shown in Figure 4 (above). Energy equivalent prices are shown in Figure 6
(below).

Second, relevant taxes are added to all coal prices. Chinese VAT of 17% is added to the CIF
price of all coals. We do not adjust for China’s import tax because it has been phased out by
2007, before China’s import surge. 21

Third, all coal and freight prices are adjusted for historical exchange rates between RMB and
USD.

Fourth, Chinese buyers face increased transaction costs when purchasing coal from the
international market as compared to the domestic market. 22 Transaction costs for Chinese
buyers associated with import vs. domestic coal include raising letters of credit (LCs), dealing
with foreign sellers and more onerous contracts. Though it is impossible to know precisely the
increased transaction costs for individual buyers, we add a $3/ton advantage to Qinhuangdao
coal over all international coals. 23

                                                            
20
We assume a linear relationship between price and energy content, though in some cases pricing may not exactly
follow this method, especially pricing for price lower CV coal. For instance, historically, lower CV Indonesian
coals have traded at a deeper discount to higher CV material. For more information see PESD Stanford’s
forthcoming study of the Indonesian coal market by Bart Lucarelli at
http://pesd.stanford.edu/publications/the_history_and_future_of_indonesias_coal_industry_impact_of_politics_and_
regulatory_framework_on_industry_structure_and_performance/
21
China’s coal import tax for all coals with the exception of coking coal was 6% prior to April 1, 2005, 3% till Nov.
1, 2006, and 1% until May 31, 2007. The import tax was abolished after June 1, 2007. Coking coal import taxes
were 3% until January 1, 2005, at which point they were abolished.
22
Stuart Murray of London Commodity Brokers shared his insights with us on what transaction costs Chinese
buyers of international coal face.
23
Results are not highly sensitive to this assumption because shifts in arbitrage relationships that we describe here
are much larger than $3/ton. The overall impact is to make domestic coal slightly more favorable in all
circumstances. For instance, the highest import disadvantage prior to 2009, which was for Newcastle against
Qinhuangdao, would only drop from highs of $70/ton to $67. Conversely the highest import advantage after 2008,
which was for both Indonesian and Russian material, would only increase from highs of about $43/ton to about
$46/ton. Though domestic coals at the margin that are less than $3/ton more profitable than import coal may
become unprofitable against imports if this assumption is eliminated.

5 August 2010 10 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


200

180 Qinhuangdao

160 Newcastle
140
Vostochny Russia
USD / metric ton

120
Kalimantan Indonesia
100

80

60

40

20

Oct‐09
Oct‐08
Oct‐07

Apr‐10
Jan‐10
Oct‐06

Apr‐09
Jan‐09
Oct‐05

Apr‐08
Jan‐08
Apr‐07
Jan‐07
Apr‐06

Jul‐09
Jan‐06
Apr‐05

Jul‐08
Jan‐05

Jul‐07
Jul‐06
Jul‐05

Figure 6 – Energy equivalent coal price indices (6,700 kc/kg GAD). Source: McCloskey, Reuters,
authors’ analysis.

3.5 Implications of Key ChinaCoalArb Assumptions

Several necessary assumptions in ChinaCoalArb may impact the performance of the model and
should be noted when comparing model results to real market outcomes.

First, the model does not explicitly separate thermal from coking coal. 24 Though some coals can
switch between these markets making the distinction blurry at times, buying behavior in these
markets will differ under certain conditions. Most worth noting is that some demand for high-
quality material is likely less responsive to price movements than demand for thermal coal
because high-quality coking coal supplies are much tighter in China and internationally. We
suspect this accounts for a large share of Australian imports into China pre-2009 when CIF
prices for most Australian coals compared to Qinhuangdao coals were significantly higher.

                                                            
24
In 2009 total coking coal imports were 34.5 Mt out of 126 Mt total imports.

5 August 2010 11 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


Second, by using the Qinhuangdao spot price to represent the Chinese domestic price, the model
does not take into account discrepancies between spot prices and “term prices” for power
generators in the Chinese market. Although in theory the two should be tightly correlated since
the deregulation of all coal prices in 2006 (spot was deregulated in 2002 but the NDRC still
directly capped term prices for power generators until 2006), this is not always the case in
practice. As evidenced by the June 2010 NDRC price cap on term prices, 25 China can in reality
have a “two-tiered” coal market under certain conditions. Thus if demand for import coal in the
power sector could replace either spot domestic coal or term domestic coal, it may be useful to
consider any price discrepancies between these two domestic markets as they will affect
arbitrage relationships. Though we argue that the current model capably represents Chinese
buying behavior in the aggregate, under certain circumstances modeling of power generators
buying behavior may be improved by using the NDRC capped term price as the domestic price
instead of spot. 26

Third, China announced that it would relax foreign exchange controls in June 2010, which has
led to minor RMB appreciation. Possible RMB appreciation going forward could increase
China’s buying power for foreign coal and thus make imports more attractive. 27

Fourth, while the indicative energy-equivalent coal ton that we have created reflects differences
in energy content, the relationship of coal price to energy content may not always be linear (as
we have already discussed). Thus lower CV coals that are priced at a deeper discount coals may
present a greater arbitrage opportunity than our model indicates.

Fifth, while energy content is arguably the most significant variable impacting coal pricing, the
model does not reflect several key variables that can also impact price. Ash, moisture, volatiles,
sulfur, and other coal properties will also influence price. It is therefore important to note our
energy-equivalent coal ton should be broadly indicative of buying behavior but cannot capture
all variables that impact coal purchasing and pricing.

                                                            
25
See NDRC: http://jgs.ndrc.gov.cn/gzdt/t20100625_356688.htm
26
This is complicated because even coal buyers that can acquire coal at below-market, government-capped prices
may still have to buy a fair amount of their supplies from the spot market. We estimate that 40-50% of coal supply
for key SOEs is under term contract (and thus impacted by the recent cap) and the remainder is purchased on the
spot market.
27
Albert Saputro and Adam Worthington of Macquarie Securities helpfully highlighted the importance of this issue
to us, which they have analyzed in their own research.

5 August 2010 12 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


Sixth, while we argue that Guangzhou is the best proxy to represent China’s national import
behavior, other importing locations will witness slightly different arbitrage relationships that
might impact purchasing decisions. For instance, Shanghai is slightly farther from Indonesia and
Australia than Guangzhou while slightly closer to Qinhuangdao and Russia. This will increase
freight costs from the former two and favor coal shipped from the latter two.

3.6 Relevant External Factors Not Captured by ChinaCoalArb

Several macro-level factors that could impact coal imports should be noted.

First, there are technical limitations to imports that prevent a full switch to imports even if it was
clearly the most profitable option. Power plant boilers are designed to burn specific
specifications of coal, which is almost always domestic coal for energy security considerations.
However, power generators can blend imports and domestic coal supplies. For each boiler there
will be a technical limitation on the amount of blending that can occur. 28 Other industrial
applications, like cement or steel making, are likely also designed to burn domestic
specifications of coal and may not be able to fully switch to imports.

Second, import port capacity is also a theoretical limit on possible Chinese coal imports (one that
has not yet been tested).

3.7 Model Results

Figure 7 displays the results of the arbitrage model. We compare arbitrage relationships to total
monthly imports in order to demonstrate the relationship. The left axis indicates the price
advantage on a $/ton basis of import coals landed in Guangzhou compared to domestic coals
landed in Guangzhou. Negative values indicate a profit advantage for domestic coals and
positive values indicate a profit advantage for imports. The right axis indicates million tons of

                                                            
28
From interviews with coal and power experts at Yudean Group in Guangdong. This is a complex engineering
issue which we will not address in detail here as there are multiple variables that impact blending ratios at coal
plants, though we do want to note that some blending limitations may exist.

5 August 2010 13 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


national coal imports by month. Figure 8 displays the only arbitrage relationships in greater
detail (weekly basis).

50 18

Million Tons Imports
16
30
Import Price Advantage ‐ USD / metric ton

14

10 12

Russia
10
Indonesia
‐10
Australia
8
QHD‐NEWC
QHD‐INDO
‐30 6
QHD‐RUS

4
‐50
2

‐70 0
Aug‐09
Aug‐08

Feb‐10
Mar‐10
Apr‐10
May‐10
Dec‐09
Sep‐09
Oct‐09
Jun‐09
Aug‐07

Feb‐09
Mar‐09
Apr‐09
May‐09
Dec‐08
Sep‐08
Oct‐08
Jun‐08

Nov‐09
Jan‐10
Feb‐08
Mar‐08
Apr‐08
May‐08

Jul‐09
Dec‐07
Sep‐07
Oct‐07
Jun‐07

Nov‐08
Jan‐09
Jul‐08
Nov‐07
Jan‐08
Jul‐07

Figure 7 – Arbitrage relationships drive Chinese coal import patterns. Note: All arbitrage values are the
CIF Guangzhou from Qinhuangdao minus CIF value of imported coals. Source: McCloskey, Reuters,
AXS Marine, Shanghai Shipping Index, authors’ analysis.

5 August 2010 14 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


45.00

35.00

25.00
Import Price Advantage ‐ USD / metric ton

15.00

5.00

‐5.00

‐15.00

‐25.00
QHD‐NEWC
‐35.00
QHD‐INDO
‐45.00
QHD‐RUS
‐55.00

‐65.00

‐75.00

Aug‐09
Aug‐08
Aug‐07

Oct‐09

Dec‐09

Feb‐10

Apr‐10
Dec‐08

Feb‐09

Apr‐09

Jun‐09
Jun‐07

Oct‐07

Dec‐07

Feb‐08

Apr‐08

Jun‐08

Oct‐08

Figure 8 – Weekly arbitrage values from 2007 show the dramatic shift in the relationship of domestic to
international coals. Note: All arbitrage values are the CIF Guangzhou from Qinhuangdao (QHD) minus
CIF value of imported coals. Source: McCloskey, Reuters, AXS Marine, Shanghai Shipping Index,
authors’ analysis.

The results explain the dramatic shift from China importing 40.4 Mt in 2008 to importing 126 Mt
in 2009. Prior to the fourth quarter of 2008, international coal prices were disadvantaged
compared to domestic coal prices. In summer 2008 Australian and Russian imports were out of
the money against Qinhuangdao by as much as $65/t and $30/t respectively. While minor
amounts of Australian material was still imported – likely specific qualities of coking coal not
readily available in the Chinese domestic market – China’s imports were negligible because
importing wasn’t profitable. The partial exception to this description is Indonesian coal, which
came in and out of the money against Qinhuangdao in Southern China. This can be attributed to
two primary factors, both of which give Indonesia competitive advantage exporting into China.
First, Indonesia’s geographic proximity to Chinese markets means that it pays a smaller freight
penalty than Australia and Russia (assuming Russian material is delivered into South China,

5 August 2010 15 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


which in reality it may not always be). Second, Indonesian FOB prices were historically slightly
lower than Australian and Russian on an energy adjusted basis. Thus as freight and domestic
and international coal prices fluctuated, import windows opened for Indonesian coal in Southern
China.

At the end of 2008 this historical relationship of domestic to international coal changed
dramatically. In the wake of global recession, the historical relationship of domestic to
international coals in Southern China inverted and a massive arbitrage opportunity arose. By late
2009, Indonesian coal was as much as $40/ton more profitable than domestic coal, Australian
coal was as much as $29/ton more profitable, and even Russian coal – which suffers from a huge
rail transport penalty to move coal from central Russia to eastern ports – was pricing into
Southern China against domestic coal at $40/ton better than Qinhuangdao. Imports skyrocketed,
cresting in winter 2009-2010. International prices have since recovered and the arbitrage
window began to close by summer 2010.

This model therefore provides credible explanation of China’s coal import behavior and explains
China’s record imports in 2009. We conclude China’s coal buying behavior follows the logic of
a “cost minimizer” and China’s coal imports will fluctuate according to the arbitrage differentials
between domestic and international coal prices.

3.8 Drivers of Arbitrage Inversion in 2009

Analyzing causes of the dramatic inversion of the historical relationship between China’s
domestic coal market and the international coal market provides a more detailed understanding
of the market conditions that caused this shift, and thus enables coal market observers to examine
how likely these conditions are to carry forward. We argue that in the wake of the global
financial crisis of 2008 seven principal drivers caused the inversion of historical price
relationships of international to Chinese coal prices.

First, the macroeconomic impact of the global financial crisis was comparatively smaller on
China than many other coal consuming nations. China’s GDP growth rate was 9.6% in 2008 and

5 August 2010 16 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


9.1% in 2009, declining by only 0.5%. 29 By contrast, real global GDP growth was estimated to
be a negative 2.1% in 2009. 30 This meant that Chinese macroeconomic activity sustained a
comparatively high level of energy demand relative to other coal importing economies. And in
China energy means coal.

Second, after the global financial crisis Chinese domestic freight prices remained higher than
international freight prices, giving imports an advantage over domestic coal. Figure 9 shows
Chinese domestic freight compared to international freight rates as a percentage of their pre-
financial crisis levels. 31 This meant that the freight component of the delivered price of imports
decreased relative to its domestic counterpart.

Third, international FOB prices declined more than Chinese domestic FOB prices when
measured as a percentage of their pre-financial crisis levels. Figure 10 illustrates this trend. This
shift, combined with the relative freight advantage, in put imports at a significant advantage to
domestic coal.

                                                            
29
Both are numbers after adjustment announced by China National Bureau of Statistics.
http://www.stats.gov.cn/tjdt/zygg/sjxdtzgg/t20100702_402654527.htm
30
World Bank global outlook:
http://web.worldbank.org/external/default/main?theSitePK=659149&pagePK=2470434&contentMDK=20370107&
menuPK=659160&piPK=2470429
31
We chose September 2008 as the pre-financial crisis point, as equities markets began their precipitous drop in that
month and Lehman Bros filed for bankruptcy. For a history of the performance of the S&P 500 see Bloomberg:
http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/quote?ticker=SPX:IND

5 August 2010 17 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


Newcastle to Shanghai
140%
Qinhangdao to Shanghai
120% Kalimantan to Shanghai
100% Vostochny (RUS) to Shanghai

80%

60%

40%

20%

0%

May‐10
Jun‐10
Mar‐10
Jan‐10
Feb‐10
Oct‐09

Dec‐09
May‐09
Jun‐09

Aug‐09
Sep‐09
Mar‐09
Jan‐09
Feb‐09
Oct‐08

Dec‐08

Apr‐10
Sep‐08

Nov‐09
Jul‐09
Apr‐09
Nov‐08

Figure 9 – Cost of freight indexed to pre-financial crisis levels in September 2008. Source: Shanghai
Shipping Index, AXS Marine.

120%
110% Qinhuangdao
Newcastle
100%
Vostochny
90% Kalimantan
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
May‐10
May‐09

Feb‐10
Mar‐10

Apr‐10
Jul‐09

Aug‐09

Sep‐09

Oct‐09

Nov‐09

Dec‐09

Jan‐10
Jun‐09
Feb‐09
Mar‐09

Apr‐09
Sep‐08

Oct‐08

Nov‐08

Dec‐08

Jan‐09

Figure 10 – FOB coal prices indexed to pre-financial crisis levels in September 2008. Source:
McCloskey, Reuters.

5 August 2010 18 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


Fourth, the relative strength of China’s domestic coal prices was largely due to a series of
regulatory events in key production regions that curtailed supply and supported prices.
Consistent with national coal mining policies, Shanxi province embarked on a major campaign
of mine consolidation. The government began a program of closing small mines or
consolidating them into larger mines and implementing more rigorous safety standards. The
targets of that program are shown in Table 3. The result was a shut-in of traditional supply that
supported prices. There is evidence in summer 2010 that the program was not completely
successful and that government officials may re-implement similar measures. 32

Table 3 – Mining consolidation targets in Shanxi.

2008 Target 2009 Target 2010 Target

Mine number 2600 1053 1000

Average mine size 300,000 ton/yr 900,000 ton/yr 900,000 ton/yr

130
Number of firms 2200 4 at 100 million scale 100
3 at 50 million scale

Source: Government of Shanxi.

Fifth, the traditional negotiations for term coal contracts between coal producers and power
generators, which in 2008 allocated 1.1 Bt of coal (40% of China’s total coal consumption that
year), broke down in 2009 when an agreement on price could not be reached. This led some coal
buyers that would otherwise have purchased domestic coal to look overseas.

Sixth, Chinese national policy on resource use facilitated increased imports. The so called “Two
Markets, Two Resources” 33 policy encourages coal buyers to import coal when the economics
justify it.

Finally, temporary factors in China like weather interruptions of transport and weak hydro
generation due to droughts contributed to higher domestic coal prices.

                                                            
32
Research by Macquarie Securities in June 2010.
33
Two Markets, Two Resources is a Chinese term reflecting a strategy to encourage Chinese company and Chinese
industry “Walking Out” of the country to explore both domestic markets and international markets.

5 August 2010 19 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


There are a number of long term factors that will determine price relationship of Chinese coal to
international coal. Several forthcoming studies from Stanford address a set of key issues and
reforms that will impact China’s domestic market such as the coal power conflict and resulting
policy and market reforms, the possible vertical integration of China’s coal and power industries,
the consolidation of coal producing into larger mines, the adoption of more efficient power
generation technologies, and the construction of major coal-power bases that will produce over
100 Mt/year each. 34

4 Conclusions and Implications for the Global Market

Once a largely isolated coal market, China now plays a central role in determining global trade
flows and prices. Understanding Chinese import behavior under current and future market
conditions is therefore imperative for any analysis of the global coal trade. We have put forward
a theory of Chinese import behavior based on arbitrage relationships between China and the
global market and proved that theory in the ChinaCoalArb model.

Our findings indicate that China is a “cost minimizer” in the international market that will import
heavily when the price is right – as it was in 2009 due to a confluence of circumstances we have
described here – and largely rely on domestic coal when imports are unattractive.

The nature of Chinese demand for international coal is therefore fundamentally different from
India, the other source of dramatic demand growth in international coal markets. India is
structurally short coal because demand growth (mainly for power) has outstripped domestic coal
supplies. China, on the other hand, is now the world’s largest coal arbitrage trader. This means
that the relationship between China’s domestic coal price and the international coal price will be
one of the key factors in determining global trade flows in the coming decade as China could just
as easily buy 15-20% of internationally traded coal as it could buy very little.

China’s role as world’s largest coal arbitrageur has a hugely significant implication for the global
coal market: it links the international price of coal to China’s domestic price. China’s buying
and selling activity on the margins of its massive domestic coal market bring domestic and
global prices closer to parity (though at present not to complete parity). In other words, what
                                                            
34
Forthcoming studies from PESD Stanford by Huaichuan Rui, Kevin Tu, and Yu Yuefeng address these issues.
See http://pesd.stanford.edu.

5 August 2010 20 He and Morse, PESD WP #94


happens in the mines of Shanxi will impact the price of power in Munich. The unique politics
and economics of the Chinese coal market are now therefore by necessity the politics and
economics of the global market, and whether or not China imports coal in a given year, “the
China factor” will increasingly define how the world sells, buys, and uses coal.

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank a number of people who made this analysis possible. Our
colleagues at PESD, including Frank Wolak and Mark Thurber, as usual provided invaluable
insights. We also greatly benefitted from discussion with many people in the coal and financial
industries. The Macquarie Securities team, including Adam Worthington, Yeeman Chin, Jon
Windham, Albert Saputro, shared their own insightful analyses of these issues for which we are
quite grateful. Bart Lucarelli also helped sharpen many of the ideas here. Stu Murray of London
Commodity Brokers, who is unmatched in his insight into Chinese buying behavior, shared his
experiences with us. Thanks also to many Chinese scholars and analysts, includingYang
Xianfeng, Li Hongjun, Hu Pingfan, Cai Guotian, Wu Lixin, Zhang Guoqiang, Wu Wenhua, Li
Hong, Gao Shixian. Finally, thanks to Kathy Lung and Sunny Wang for their support.

5 August 2010 21 He and Morse, PESD WP #94

Potrebbero piacerti anche