Sei sulla pagina 1di 31

Daniel R Amerman Why Early Collection Of Social Security Benefits Can Be

The Best Choice

By, CFA, MBA, BSBA

Overview

The smart financial choice for when to first start collecting Social Security benefits is often
presented as being to wait for as long as we can. The government discourages early collection by
increasing the size of our payments for each year we wait up until age 70 ─ and we are then
scheduled to get that higher payment level for the rest of our lives.

However, when we take into consideration three vitally important factors which are too often
ignored in many retirement decision aids ─ then our results can turn upside down, and the best
choice can be early collection.

For someone on their 62nd birthday who could start collecting $2,102 a month immediately, the
financial case for waiting until age 70 is visually summarized above. Now, there is a cost to
waiting, as it means giving up 8 full years of lower cash payments, represented by the yellow
bars (which slowly rise with an assumed 3% rate of inflation increasing benefit payments).

Yet, the reward for waiting until age 70 is that we are then eligible for a maximum payment of
$3,576 a month (plus the increases for inflation that occurred while we waited). And assuming
that we enjoy an average lifespan for someone who has reached 62 years old, and we live until
age 84, that means that we receive the much higher payments represented by the green bars for a
total of 14 out of our 22 years of retirement.

Over the full 22 years of the example, we get about an additional $158,000 if we wait until age
70 to begin collecting benefits. There is a six figure advantage to waiting! Anyone can see how
an extra six figures of available cash could transform our standard of living in retirement,
something which has been very well publicized in recent years.

Yet, there are three major real world considerations that can entirely change our results and our
decision. Each is quickly introduced below, and then explored in more depth in the rest of this
analysis.

The first issue is properly taking inflation into account. The purpose of indexing Social Security
benefits is not to give retirees an annual raise – but to (hopefully) keep the purchasing power of
their benefits stable, so that their standard of living does not decline with increasing prices.

And clearly, level benefits should look like a flat line – not a rising line.

The hollow bars in the first reality adjustment above represent inflation based increases in
payments that don't involve increases in spending power, but just keeping up with inflation.
When we properly adjust for the falling purchasing power of the dollar over time, we do indeed
get a flat line for reality, which is the inflation-adjusted value of our Social Security benefits.
Taking this simple – and necessary – step also wipes out much of the green bars, and much of the
advantage to waiting. Indeed, the advantage to waiting shrinks to only about $45,000 – which is
a reduction of 71%.

That's right, 70%+ of the widely-publicized "six figure" advantage to waiting to collect Social
Security can vanish in an instant – because the advantage never was real, but is an inflation-
based illusion.

Our second critical reality adjustment is for the dual effects of the "hold harmless" provision for
Social Security benefits, which forms the little-examined financial linkage between Medicare
and Social Security for most retirees. As further explored below, those who are currently
collecting Social Security are generally shielded from excessive Medicare Part B premium
increases – while those who are not collecting Social Security have no protection whatsoever. So
waiting to collect can mean up to five years of vulnerability (ages 65-69) to rapidly increasing
Medicare premium levels - which can then continue for life.

There is also the issue that while "hold harmless" sounds purely beneficial, the financial reality is
that it is the back door for breaking the linkage between stated inflation and Social Security
benefits. When Medicare costs increase, then Social Security benefits net of Medicare Part B
premium deductions no longer keep up with inflation.

Payments which don't quite keep up with inflation should slightly decline in value a little every
year – exactly as visually shown above, with the hollow bars growing just slightly larger, and the
reality of spending power in retirement shrinking just a little bit more each year. And the farther
out in time we go, the bigger the impact, which particularly effects the "back-end loaded" green
bars of the late claiming strategies.

Even if we assume a quite small impact in each year, meaning that Medicare expenses for an
aging population never really explode, then including Medicare along with inflation entirely
changes the outcome, and there is now about a $15,000 dollar advantage to early collection of
Social Security.

Finally, we need to take into account the third and potentially largest issue of all which is the
government's ability to pay, and whether we are in fact likely to be receiving our full scheduled
payments for the rest of our lives. While it may come as a surprise to much of the general public,
the federal government itself could not be more clear that it has not promised to make those
scheduled payments in full, but will only pay beneficiaries to the extent that it has the cash
available.

Under current law, when the Social Security Trust Funds run out, then unless there is a major
(and ultimately unaffordable) increase in tax rates, Social Security benefit payments must be cut.

The "High Cost" scenario contained in the government's 2015 Trustee Report for Social Security
shows the Trust Funds running out by 2028, and payroll taxes only being sufficient to pay 71%
of scheduled benefits from that time forward. That scenario is incorporated into the graphic
above. This would mean someone who is 62 this year and who chooses to give up eight years of
benefits (the yellow bars) in order to wait until age 70 to collect, might in exchange get only
three years of full benefits (the taller green bars), before their benefits are slashed from that point
forward.

When we take all three reality adjustments into account – the advantage to claiming Social
Security benefits at age 62 instead of 70 increases to a full $55,000.

We do need to keep in mind that there are multiple levels to the decision about when to start
collecting Social Security, including spousal situation, our employment and current income
status, and the biggest wild card of all which is how long it is that each of us will individually
live.

That said, the simple fact is that retirees have a greater exposure to inflation and medical
expenses than any other age group. And the extreme financial pressures that a steady stream of
about 10,000 more Boomers retiring each day will be placing on an already heavily indebted
federal government over the years to come are well known.

Any retirement decision framework which does properly not take all three of those basic factors
into account is likely to be wrong, and perhaps terribly wrong. Yet, ironically, ignoring all three
factors is commonplace when it comes to the financial analysis of Social Security decisions.

To correct this shortfall, the tutorial below goes into more financial detail on how Social Security
decisions can be changed when we consider four different levels of analysis: 1) simple dollars; 2)
adjusting for inflation; 3) adjusting for the relationship with Medicare; and 4) adjusting for the
depletion of the Trust Funds and potential future payment reductions.

Level One: Simple Dollar Analysis

Beginning at age 62, those eligible for Social Security have a right to collect benefits, but they
are also given a strong financial incentive by the government to not exercise that right. They can
choose to begin collecting benefits immediately, but the benefits are relatively low and will
remain so for the rest of one's life. The incentive for not starting immediately is that the longer
one waits to start collecting benefits, the higher the benefits that will be paid out each month, and
again – this is for life.

The table below shows the financial choices presented to an individual who is just turning 62,
and is eligible for the maximum Social Security benefit for that age. One choice is to claim
Social Security benefits as soon as possible at a level of $2,102 dollars a month, which is
$25,224 per year. This choice is shown in the "Early Strategy" columns on the left.
This monthly cash flow is not fixed, however, but is assumed to increase once each year with an
inflation adjustment of 3%, which is about the long term average rate of inflation for the United
States since 1950. So the cash flow for age 63 is $25,981 which is 3% greater than the cash flow
for age 62, and that climbs in each succeeding year, until it reaches $46,924 for age 83 (the
tables all assume that someone reaches age 84, but not 84 years and 1 month, so the final year of
payments are all for a full 83rd year). Total payments over the 22 years are $770,260.

Now, a person could start claiming Social Security any given month after turning 62, but for
simplicity and to draw the clearest possible distinction between choices, the "Late Strategy"
columns assumes we follow the widely given advice to claim at the latest time for the largest
benefit, which means waiting until age 70. At the time we made our choice, the schedules
showed the benefits for 70 as being $3,576 per month – or a full 70% increase over early
collection.

What is shown in the actual table in the "Late Strategy" columns, however, is $54,360 in benefits
for age 70, which is $4,530 a month in payments. The difference is that with each year that
passes, and each inflation adjustment, our scheduled future payments are rising right along with
the current benefits being paid out. Because eight (assumed) 3% inflation increases have already
occurred, our first payment is much higher that what it looked like eight years earlier.

It is this assumed annual increase in payments with a low and historically average 3% rate of
inflation that produces the graph above, and the yellow and green bars that grow taller in each
year. And while claiming late does mean giving up eight years of payments, when we do start
getting payments – they are much higher.
Even though we only get 14 years of payments with this choice, because they are so much
higher, our total benefit payments received are now up to $928,806, which is getting close to $1
million (and if we just lived one more year, we would reach the million dollar mark in Social
Security payments). This is $158,547 more than we would have received if we had starting
claiming benefits at age 62.

Now, so long as the choice is between some money coming in versus no money coming in – then
as can be clearly seen in the graphic below, there is a quickly building advantage to having some
money coming in, until by the end of one's 69th year there is almost a quarter million dollar
cumulative advantage to early collections. For those who don't make it to their 70th birthday, or
don't live very long beyond that, then this advantage is all that matters.

On the other hand, for the substantial majority of retirees who do live at least that long and much
longer – from that day forward there is a powerful monthly financial advantage to having
waited. The much bigger checks immediately begin to reduce the cumulative advantage to
having collected the smaller checks for a longer period, and the dollar advantage plunges
downward in both chart and table. Until at the age of 78 years and 10 months we reach our
"crossover" date, where the dollar advantage to early Social Security benefit collection
disappears entirely.

For someone who reaches the age of 62, the average lifespan is about 84 years. And as
indicated, for the entire time between our crossover age of 78 years and 10 months, and an
assumed end to benefit collection on the first day of the 84th year, the cumulative dollar
advantage of about $158,000 goes to those who waited to collect their payments.

This particular kind of Social Security analysis is responsible for the widely reported, headline-
grabbing conclusion that for those retirees who live to an average age, there is a six figure
advantage to waiting until age 70 to collect benefits, with couples having a much bigger
advantage over individuals. As presented, that is quite an advantage, and millions of people are
being urged to use this kind of financial education – which points towards deferring the
collection of their Social Security benefits – in order to make the best possible decisions.

Level Two: Spending Power Analysis

There is unfortunately a fundamental flaw with these calculations, which becomes apparent
when we raise the sophistication of our analysis by just one notch. For, when we look at the
future in terms of spending power (otherwise known as using inflation-adjusted dollars) – as
those with a reasonable amount of financial or economic training usually do – we discover a
surprisingly different outcome.

When we get inflation adjustments to our salary or retirement benefits, while on the surface it
may seem like we're getting a raise, we're actually not – rather we're being compensated for the
loss of the purchasing power of our dollars.

This issue is illustrated in the table below, which shows the effects of a 3% rate of inflation on a
$1,000 benefit payment, that exactly keeps up with the rate of inflation. We do get more dollars
each year, as seen in the red "Level One Simple Dollars" column. However, the dollar buys less
each year, as shown in the green "Value Of Dollar" column.
If in the interests of making the best decision for our retirements we want to get an accurate look
over time at what matters – which is the purchasing power of our benefit payment – then an
evaluation method used by professional analysts is to adjust the amount of each payment for the
value of the dollar at the time, which produces our blue "Level Two Spending Power" column.
And indeed, a benefit payment which exactly keeps up with inflation should maintain an exactly
level purchasing power.

So what happens if we do look at our pivotal decision about when to begin collecting benefits in
spending power terms?
The "Simple Dollar" columns are identical to those of the previous table, but the "Spending
Power" columns have now been filled in in the table above. As one would expect and as
previously illustrated, when we both increase payments by 3% per year, and decrease the value
of the dollar for a 3% rate of inflation, the falling value of the dollar exactly offsets the
increasing number of dollars, and we are left with what inflation-indexing is supposed to produce
– level spending power.

Now, as can be seen with age 62, the level spending power is actually less than the cash coming
in even in the first year, and this is not an error. These tables are the annual summary of monthly
calculations, and inflation means that what we pay for purchases increases a little bit (on
average) each month, but we are given our annual compensating "raise" retroactively, after up to
twelve months of having paid those higher prices. So Social Security, Cost Of Living
Adjustments (COLAs) for salaries, and other inflation-indexed payments don't actually fully
keep with inflation, even if the inflation measure used were to be exactly accurate.

Our total Spending Power for the Early Strategy is reduced by over $220,000 when compared to
Simple dollars, down to $547,480. And unfortunately, this loss of close to a quarter of a million
dollars is reality-based and mandatory – as retirees on fixed incomes know all too well, for even
small ongoing annual increases in prices can steadily reduce standards of living.

As bad as adjusting for Spending Power reality is for the Early Strategy, it is much worse for the
Late Strategy, where our spending power is reduced by over $330,000. This greatly closes the
gap from a $158,547 Simple Dollar advantage to the Late Strategy, to a much smaller $45,225
Spending Power advantage, which is a reduction of over 70%.

For many people, this degree of change may seem counter-intuitive. We have two alternatives
over a 22 year time frame, shouldn't inflation reduce the benefits for both strategies in a more or
less proportionate fashion?
The reason for major change is illustrated in the graphic above, and can be easily seen in the
numerical table of payments as well. Inflation adjustments start small, and get very large with
time. The hollow yellow bars of adjusting for the reality of inflation start very small, and only
slowly grow above the level, solid yellow bars which represent purchasing power. Looking at the
numerical table, our initial adjustments for the Early Strategy are roughly $400 for age 63,
$1,100 for age 64, and so forth.

However, when we reach the green bars of the Late Strategy in the illustration, the hollow bars
of inflation adjustments get much larger in proportion to real spending power, and this becomes
particularly true as we go out to ages in the late 70s and early 80s. Looking at the numerical
table, our annual inflation adjustment for the Late Strategy is over $25,000 by age 78, and over
$37,000 by age 83.

The farther out in time we go, then the greater the possible mistake for people making decisions,
when it comes the difference between Simple Dollars and actual Spending Power. And because
the cash flows are so heavily back-end loaded with the Late Strategy, the impact of accurately
adjusting for Spending Power is far greater.

Now, the use of Simple Dollars is not by itself a mathematical error, nor is it at all uncommon.
Looking at the past and future in terms of simply "dollars", is the unquestioned norm for
newspapers and television and the like.

Indeed, if you read about stock market averages, or real estate prices, or financial records in
almost any category – they are typically not adjusted for inflation. The public is continually
presented with information about record markets and record prices, when in reality what they are
really reading about in most cases is record lows for the purchasing power of the dollar.

So to be fair, the Simple Dollar analysis ─ which is based upon "a dollar being a dollar",
regardless of when we receive it ─ does indeed fall within the normal range of how financial
information is presented to the general public, and the assertion of a six figure Simple Dollar
advantage in situations such as the example above is mathematically accurate.

Unfortunately, however, common usage does not mean making good decisions, and in this
particular case, using the most common approach for the general public can lead to millions of
people making bad decisions that could change their daily lives for the worse over a period of 20
years or more. Because the decisions are being based on an illusion, and the great majority of the
dollar "advantage" to late claiming strategies is indeed an illusion.

When we accurately adjust for spending power, we also get a very different cumulative
advantage graph for visualizing the tradeoffs between strategies. During the early years
something continues to be much better than nothing, and an enormous advantage still builds for
the Early Strategy.
However, once age 70 is reached and the larger Late Strategy payments begin arriving, the slope
downwards is not nearly as steep as with the Simple Dollar graph, because much of the steepness
of the decline was based upon nothing but treating inflation as income. The triangle still goes
negative by the end - because there is still a cumulative disadvantage to early collection - but the
area of the triangle is much smaller. Which can certainly change both the psychological
perception and the decision.

Now, for the half of the population who live at least a little (and hopefully many years) beyond
the average lifespan, the advantage to Late Strategies is still there and growing every month and
every year as we go off the edge of the graph to the right, just not at the same rate as with Simple
Dollars. So the fundamental dilemma remains when it comes to making this decision and the
unknown variable of how long we will live.

The "crossover date" when the financial advantage shifts to delaying our Social Security checks
does now move to 81 years and 4 months – a delay of 2 years and 6 months. Meaning that we
moved much closer to a 50/50 tradeoff, where those who live an average lifespan are
theoretically indifferent between strategies, those who turn out to live shorter lives should have
chosen Early collection, and those who live longer lives should have chosen Late collection.
(Keeping in mind that the timing of the cash flow can be important for different individual
situations in ways that are not captured with this type of analysis.)

Level Three: Adjusting For How Social Security Decisions Can Change
Medicare Premiums

The retirement standard of living delivered by government benefits is not Social Security by
itself, nor Medicare by itself, but Social Security payments net of Medicare premiums and
deductibles.

In other words, what determines our standard of living for food, shelter, utilities, clothing and the
other components of day to day living is the net cash flow we get from the government.

Now, if Social Security were entirely separate from Medicare, we could ignore Medicare and just
make the best decision we can for Social Security, then separately make the best Medicare
decision we can while ignoring Social Security, and that would give us our best result.

However, what many people don't realize is that their Social Security decisions can have a
potentially dramatic impact on the size of the Medicare Part B premiums they pay for the rest of
their lives.

If someone is currently collecting Social Security AND like most people they choose at age 65 to
have their Medicare Part B premiums deducted from their Social Security payments, then under
current law in most cases they will be protected against excessive Medicare premium increases
for the rest of their lives. The "hold harmless" provision of Social Security states that increases in
Medicare Part B premiums cannot result in net Social Security payments being cut.
So if the monthly size of someone's Social Security payment goes up by $30 because of
inflation-indexing, and their Medicare premium which is deducted from that payment is
supposed to increase by $40, then it would appear that their benefit payment would go down by
$10 per month. The "hold harmless" provision which applies to most retirees keeps that from
happening, as their Social Security payments net of Medicare deductions are not allowed to fall.

For most retirees (there are several excluded categories) in that situation, their Medicare
premium could not go up by more than $30 per month. It does not matter whether their monthly
premium would otherwise go up by $30, or $40 or $80, they are protected and capped out at a
$30 increase - which means their net payment is unchanged. (There is an exception, however, if
the government simply doesn't have the money to pay, as covered in the Trust Funds section that
follows.)

There are two important ways in which this little understood or explored linkage with Medicare
premiums can have a powerful impact on the decision about when to start collecting Social
Security benefits.

1) Partially Or Fully Negating Inflation Indexing. Let's say that we are receiving an even
$1,000 per month benefit, and that our Social Security benefit was supposed to go up by $30 per
month to keep up with inflation, but our Medicare Part B premium goes up by $10 per month, so
our net benefit payments increase by only $20. With this round number example, our cost of
living went up by 3%, but our cash coming in goes up by only 2% because the Medicare
premium increase took part of the inflation-indexing increase.

In that case, we are no longer completely protected against inflation, but rather we are only
partially protected. (If we were ever fully protected that is, retiree expenses are not what the
inflation index is based upon, but tend to rise at a faster rate, and the government has enormous
financial incentives to make sure that remains the case.)

If we are spending all the retirement benefit money we have coming in, and those benefits don't
keep up with inflation because of the linkage with Medicare premiums, then either our standard
of living must fall every year, or we must eat into our savings at a faster rate than we otherwise
would, which brings forward in time the depletion of our savings.

A failure to keep up with inflation to even a minor extent is something that grows ever more
powerful with the passage of time. It has a much bigger cumulative effect in year five than in
year one, a much bigger effect in year ten than year five, and still more so in year twenty than
year ten. This slow but steady loss in spending power can be seen in the graphic below, where
the solid bars representing spending power now gradually shrink with time, even as the hollow
bars of that represent inflation and the impact of Medicare premiums now grow slightly larger.
Because the cash flows from late collection occur on average much later than the average cash
flows for early collection, having partial inflation indexing hurts the solid green bars of late
claimer spending power much more than it hurts early claimers, as can be seen above. However,
this is not the only Medicare related disadvantage to delaying collecting Social Security, and it is
not necessarily the worst.

2) Concentrating Medicare Premium Increases. Under current law, when some Medicare
beneficiaries are protected from excessive premium increases, the shortfall does not go back to
the government. Instead, it is paid for by the Medicare beneficiaries who aren't protected.

And for those people aged 65-69 who are paying Medicare premiums but have intentionally
deferred collecting Social Security in order to receive larger payments later – they have no "hold
harmless" protection. What is much worse, however, is that they must "pick up the tab" for
everyone who is protected by "hold harmless", including those in their age group who did choose
to collect Social Security.

As an example, about 30% of current Medicare beneficiaries just barely dodged this bullet in late
2015 when a last minute budget fix averted what would have otherwise been up to a 52%
increase in Medicare Part B premiums that was scheduled to take place on January 1, 2016.

The reason that the scheduled 2016 increase was so large was that the government said that there
wasn't any inflation (on average) in the previous year, so Social Security payments did not
increase for 2016. But yet, despite the purported complete lack of inflation, the cost of the
Medicare Part B program did soar, which meant that under the law the premiums had to soar as
well.

Except premiums couldn't be increased at all for the 70% of Medicare beneficiaries who were
having their Medicare premiums deducted from their Social Security payments, because with no
increase for inflation, any increase in premiums whatsoever would have reduced their net
payments, which is not allowed under the "hold harmless" provisions.

And what that meant was that the 30% of Medicare beneficiaries who were not protected by
"hold harmless" – had to take on the premium increases for everybody.

This real world situation is illustrated above. If it weren't for "hold harmless", then everyone
would have had to pay for 100% of their own Medicare premium increase. But 70% of the
beneficiaries were protected and didn't have to pay anything extra, which is why their orange
bars are hollow.

Those not protected are represented by the solid blue bars, and they had to pay 100% of their
own premium increase. Crucially, they also had to pay the premium increases for everyone who
was held harmless. Since there were 2.33 protected people for every non-protected person (70/30
= 2.33), that meant that each non-protected person had to pick up a total of 333% of the per
person premium increase, with 100% for themselves (the solid blue bar), and 233% for 2.33
other people (the solid orange bars).
That is where the shocking number of up to a 52% increase in Medicare Part B premiums for
2016 came from, it wasn't just the sharp jump in medical expenses, but was even more so the few
paying for the many. This sounds crazy, and it sounds terribly unfair – but it is part of the current
law governing the relationship between Social Security and Medicare.

And while there was a last-minute budget fix for 2016 where the federal government took part of
the financial hit and just added it to the deficit, thereby reducing the size of the premium
increases for those who were vulnerable – that was a one time action. The governing law remains
the same. And those who defer collecting Social Security for as long as possible have no
protection from this danger, while those who are collecting and choose to have their Medicare
premiums deducted are protected.

Accurately estimating the effect is problematic, because it depends on the differential between
what the government states the inflation rate is, and what the actual increase in Medicare Part B
costs are in each future year. There is a further quite "lumpy" and powerful risk, that at least
every now and then the situation of the 2016 premium increase recurs, and all those late claimers
aged 65 to 69 get taken to cleaners, so to speak. But yet, these factors can be life-changing, and
any analysis which does not take this little examined relationship into account is likely to be
skewed towards making bad decisions.

As a solution, this analysis uses a somewhat "gentle" adjustment for the intertwined relationship
between Social Security and Medicare Part B premiums. It is assumed that actual Social Security
payments net of Medicare premiums fall 1% short of the assumed 3% rate of inflation, and this
applies equally to early and late claimers. It also assumes that for those not yet claiming Social
Security, there is an additional shortfall of 1% per year, because they entirely lack the protections
that are offered by the "hold harmless" provision.

The effect of each small adjustment is to create "Partial Inflation Indexing" where net benefits do
steadily increase, but at a slower rate than prices. For the average person this can sound a bit
obscure or subtle – but for retirees, the results are powerful and can help determine standards of
living over a period of many years.
The first thing to notice about the numerical table above is that the Social Security benefits net of
increases in Medicare premiums are still assumed to increase every year, and that this still seems
to occur at a pretty good rate. By age 83, we are up to over $38,000 per year for the Early
Strategy, and almost $61,000 per year for the Late Strategy. And if we stick to Simple Dollars,
there is still about a $61,000 cumulative advantage to the Late Strategy over an expected
lifetime.

So the way most people see the world – they are still getting more money every year. And using
the most common way that information is presented to the general public by those who are not
financial professionals, there is still a substantial advantage to waiting until age 70 to collect
Social Security benefits.

But yet, any increases whatsoever in Medicare Part B premiums mean that we are no longer
keeping up with inflation. Medical expenses don't even have to increase faster than the rate of
inflation to produce this result, because we only (theoretically) keep up with inflation with our
full benefit increase, and any increases in deductions at all means that isn't happening. Social
Security is in truth only partially inflation-indexed when we take Medicare premiums into
account, and this is a matter of design, albeit not a feature that the government talks about.

On a personal level, it doesn't get any more real world than spending what we have left after the
deductions for (government-sponsored) medical insurance, and having to reduce our lifestyle
when the prices we pay for everything else are increasing at a rate that is even slightly faster than
the money that we have coming in.

With even the modest adjustments previously described, in the numerical table we now see
personal reality for each of us, which is our "growing" net Social Security payments actually
buying just a little less each year. And because the value of our Late Strategy cash flows are so
much farther out in time and therefore more vulnerable to adjustments for inflation – and partial
inflation indexing – they are disproportionately reduced, in comparison to the much smaller
impact on the initial years of the Early Strategy.

When we move from Simple Dollars to Spending Power, and we then look at the Spending
Power of Social Security payments net of Medicare Part B premium increases, those two factors
by themselves are enough in combination to produce a complete inversion of the bottom line
results. There is now almost a $15,000 advantage to early claiming at age 62 in our example.

Our "crossover" age where the advantage shifts to Late Strategies has now moved to 85 years
and 2 months, which is beyond the average expected lifespan. So now a majority of people are
better off choosing the Early Strategy. For those living longer lives there is still an advantage to
Late Strategies, but the date this advantage arrives has moved back by 3 years and 10 months,
and the monthly advantage from that date forward is smaller than it previously was.

And there could be a much greater advantage to early collections if the Medicare costs of an
aging population do increase at a rate substantially higher than the government stated rate of
inflation.
Level Four: The Depletion Of The Trust Funds

The preceding sections assume that the government pays every dollar of scheduled future Social
Security payments. The word "scheduled" is critically important because while it may come as a
surprise to much of the general public, the federal government itself could not be more clear that
it has not promised to make those scheduled payments in full, but will only pay beneficiaries to
the extent that it has the cash available.

This uncertainty means that our largest issue of all when it comes to deciding whether to collect
late or early is that of the government's ability to pay, and whether we are in fact likely to be
receiving our full scheduled payments for the rest of our lives.

The above is excerpted from the 2015 Trustee Report for Social Security (only the word
"SHORTFALL" was added). After the Trust Funds run out, there is a top line that says
"Scheduled but not fully payable benefits", and a lower line that says "Payable benefits." And the
government doesn't have any intention of covering the difference. If taxes don't go up in a major
way, then the payments go down so that the deficit doesn't go up.

That is the current law. And the scenario above is the government's own baseline projection for
the future. Which is actual Social Security benefits paid out being cut well below what is
scheduled at some point in the future.

Now some might confuse this little understood feature of Social Security with projections of
bankruptcy for the United States government or the collapse of Social Security ─ but it is instead
arguably the direct opposite of such talk. As explored in more detail here, this provision is the
intended protection against insolvency for both Social Security and the government.
The legal loophole is that Social Security doesn't have to pay us what it doesn't have the cash on
hand to pay, regardless of what we think we are entitled to or what is shown in the Social
Security tables. This keeps the federal government from going bankrupt. This keeps Social
Security alive and solvent.

But the price of that solvency is that we don't get what the schedules say we will. And that hits
Late Strategies much worse than it does Early Strategies.

How bad will the hit be?

To answer that question requires more information than anybody has at this point, so all we have
to work with are projections. The number one question is what the size of the economy will be in
each future year. The number two question is what percentage of that economy will be taken by
the government in the form of the payroll taxes that are used to pay for Social Security and
Medicare.

The basic relationship is that the greater the economic growth, the greater the future payroll
taxes. This means that the Trust Funds deplete at a slower rate, which pushes back in time any
shortfalls, and because the economy is assumed to be still larger at that point and generating
more payroll taxes, this reduces the size of the future reductions in benefit payments.

So any projection of what each of our individual Social Security benefits will be is only as good
as the accuracy of the economic and tax rate projections. This is what is left out of most Social
Security calculators, yet it is arguably the most important factor.

There is no certainty. Particularly once we get ten, fifteen or twenty years out, it is the size of the
economy and the economic health of the nation that will determine the actual resources available
to support retirees. If sufficient economic growth has not occurred, then all the tables of precise
numbers for different Social Security claiming strategies become meaningless.

What matters most is whether the government's projections turn out to be accurate, and it should
be noted that the government's baseline projection is based on a series of remarkably optimistic
assumptions which over time create a much larger and more prosperous economy than what we
currently have.

In the Trustee Report, the slow to no growth economy in the United States over the last decade is
assumed to be a temporary anomaly that disappears, and is replaced by the higher rates of
economic growth of 20 or 50 years ago.

Steadily rising wages in inflation-adjusted terms are assumed to replace the falling real median
wages and shrinking middle class that the US has been experiencing for these last 40 years. And
the payroll taxes that support Social Security and Medicare are assumed to rise with those real
wages.
Not only is there assumed to full or close to full employment, but the 15 year trend of falling
workforce participation rates (as explored here) is assumed to reverse, with an ever growing
percentage of the workforce age population getting jobs – and paying payroll taxes.

An endless and large stream of highly productive, young, and fertile immigrants (both legal and
"other") are assumed to come to the United States, and they and their children are assumed to
support us with their large and ever growing payroll taxes.

And even if every one of those remarkably optimistic assumptions contained in the
"Intermediate" scenario turns out to be true, the US government itself still projects that the ability
to make full Social Security payments runs out by 2034 (absent major tax increases).

For our numerical table, we will use the only slightly less optimistic "High Cost" scenario from
the 2015 Trustee Report. All of the key assumptions are still remarkably optimistic, in terms of a
economically healthy and growing nation that reverses all of the currently negative 10, 15 and 40
year economic trends that were previously mentioned. But, the assumptions are not quite as
robustly optimistic as the "Intermediate" scenario.
With the government's "High Cost" scenario, the Trust Funds are assumed to run out by 2028,
and payroll taxes are assumed to be able to pay close to 71% of scheduled benefits thereafter. For
someone making a decision that is effective at the end of 2016, and assuming the Trust Funds
run out at the beginning of 2028, this would mean they would get three full years of scheduled
Social Security payments with a Late Strategy, before their payments would be cut by 29%.

(There are lots of ways between assumed birthdays for someone turning 62 in 2016 and the
assumed actual date of Trust Fund depletion within 2028 to get 3.5 to 4 years of full benefits, but
that is still based on quite optimistic economic assumptions, and doesn't materially change the
conclusion.)

With this scenario, annual benefits for the Late Strategy in Simple Dollar terms fall from
$48,823 at age 72, down to $35,358 at age 73. When we look at Spending Power net of Medicare
premiums, then it falls from $35,842 at age 72 down to $25,201 at age 73 – and then slightly
declines each year thereafter, as slowly increasing Medicare premiums prevent net Social
Security payments from fully keeping up with inflation.

Now, something interesting about that Late Strategy spending power at age 74 of $25,201, is that
it is roughly equal to the Early Strategy spending power at age 62 of $24,885 – which can also be
seen in the graphic below.

What is illustrated above is the central problem with people choosing Late Strategies when the
government itself projects that it is likely to run out of the money needed to make future
scheduled payments in full.
The core tradeoff is that someone gives up the certainty of the solid yellow bars in the here and
now, in exchange for the alluring income that is the top of the hollow red bars many years down
the road. But, as previously analyzed, most of the hollow red bars turn out to be illusions when
we properly adjust for Spending Power and the linkage between Social Security and Medicare.

Worse, they may only receive their full benefits for a few years, as represented by the taller
green bars, before their benefits are slashed – as required under current law – when the Trust
Funds deplete, tens of millions more Boomers have retired, and payroll taxes are (as expected)
insufficient to make scheduled Social Security benefit payments in full. So in exchange for
waiting, based on the best information we currently have, they get a brief spike in benefits, then
their benefits drop with everyone else – and they never do get most of the reward that they
thought waiting until age 70 would lock in for them.

Even with a complete reversal of the economic trends of the last decade and the return of
strongly positive economic growth for the United States – there is still a $54,460 Spending
Power advantage to the Early Strategy over the Late Strategy when we take into account the
depletion of the Trust Funds. And for the first time in our series of analyses, there is now a
Simple Dollar advantage to the Early Strategy as well, albeit a very small advantage of about
$4,000.

On a Spending Power basis, our "crossover" date where the advantage shifts to the Late Strategy
is now age 90 years and 8 months. Which means that for the great majority of the population,
there is no longer a tradeoff, but a double advantage to the Early Strategy. For eight straight
years in their 60s they do get some money instead of no money. And on a cumulative basis they
never lose that initial financial advantage even if they do live a normal lifespan – or up to 6+
years beyond that normal lifespan.

It should also be noted that while the Trust Funds sound comforting, they are much stranger than
most people realize because they are entirely invested in financing the national debt. This raises
the question: if the national debt isn't repaid – then how is it that Social Security benefits get
paid?

There is a way, but for those with the curiosity and courage to seek that answer, be prepared "to
go down the rabbit hole". Because as explored here, the real source of your security and where
the Trust Funds money will come from to pay for your Social Security benefits is likely not at all
what you think it is, and there is a downright toxic relationship with the national debt.

Now, it is possible that the United States could exceed the strongly positive economic growth
rate that is projected in the government's "High Cost" scenario, and instead meet the even more
robustly positive economic and demographic projections contained in the "Intermediate"
scenario from the Trustee report. If so, then someone following a Late Strategy might get 9 years
of full benefits starting at age 70, and 79% of their benefits thereafter.

Nonetheless, the advantage for someone living an average lifespan would still remain with the
Early Strategy, because our adjustments for inflation and Medicare were enough by themselves
to remove the advantage to the Late Strategy, and any benefit decreases whatsoever in the later
years would just increase the advantage to the Early Strategy.

That said, there is little or no protection for those who choose the Late Strategy when it comes to
the possibility of disappointing future economic growth.

If the economic growth rate for an aging and heavily indebted nation remains what we have
actually experienced since the financial crisis of 2008 – then the results are much worse than
what is shown above. Payroll taxes are lower in each year, the Trust Funds deplete sooner, and
the hit to future benefits is greater.

If real (inflation-adjusted) median wages don't reverse their 40 year trend and start to grow along
with a resurgent middle class – then payroll taxes will be lower, and we may see only one or two
years (or no years) of higher payments being received by late claimers

If we don't see a reversal in the 15 year trend we have seen for declining workforce participation
rates, then benefit payments could fall each year after the Trust Funds run out, instead of
remaining level.

In closing summary:

1) Inflation is fundamental for retirement decisions.

2) Medical expenses are fundamental for retirement decisions.

3) The ability of society to actually pay for future retirement benefits is fundamental for
retirement decisions.

4) To make retirement decisions that are based only on scheduled payments while ignoring those
fundamentals – is to risk making an absolutely fundamental and potentially life-changing
mistake.

What you have just read is an "eye-opener" about critically important retirement
decisions, and how they can change when we take a holistic look at the future.
Most of the financial planning used for IRAs, 401(k)s and Roth IRAs does not take into account
the financial condition of Social Security. However, when we take a holistic look at people
drawing down retirement accounts at the same time that Social Security is in deep financial
trouble, then our retirement account decisions can indeed change our Social Security benefit
payments in a way that could transform our standard of living in retirement, as explored here.
Retirement lifestyle is determined by both benefits and savings. Linked here is a related "eye-
opener" that shows how the government's suppressing interest rates can reduce retirement
investment wealth accumulation by 95% over thirty years, and how low interest rate policies are
profoundly reducing standards of living for those already retired.
National debts have been reduced many times in many nations ─ and each time the lives of the
citizens have changed. The "eye-opener" linked here reviews four traditional methods that can
each change your daily life, and explores how governments use your personal savings to pay
down their debts in a manner which is invisible to almost all voters.

If you find these "eye-openers" to be interesting and useful, there is an entire free book of them
available here, including many that are only in the book. The advantage to the book is that the
tutorials can build on each other, so that in combination we can find ways of defending
ourselves, and even learn how to position ourselves to benefit from the hidden redistributions of
wealth.

Potrebbero piacerti anche