Sei sulla pagina 1di 10

ARTICLE IN PRESS

Int. J. Production Economics 93–94 (2005) 253–262


www.elsevier.com/locate/dsw

Inventory management in supply chains:


A bargaining problem
Eric Sucky
Department of Supply Chain Management, School of Business and Economics, Goethe-University Frankfurt, Mertonstrasse 17,
D-60054 Frankfurt, Germany

Abstract

This paper is focused on supply chain management from the perspective of inventory management. The coordination
of order and production policies between buyers and suppliers in supply chains is of particular interest. When a buyer of
an item decides independently, he will place orders based on his economic order quantity (EOQ). However, the buyer’s
EOQ may not lead to a favorable policy for the supplier. A cooperative order and production policy can reduce total
cost significantly. Should the buyer have the dominant position to impose his EOQ on the supplier, then consequently
no incentive exists for him to deviate from his EOQ in order to choose a cooperative policy. To induce the buyer to
order in quantities more favorable to the supplier, the supplier could offer a cooperative policy associated by a side
payment to the buyer. The research presented in this paper provides several bargaining models depending on alternative
production policies of the supplier. With these bargaining models the offered cooperative policy and the offered side
payment can be derived.
r 2004 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Inventory management; Joint economic lot size; Buyer–supplier relationships; Bargaining problem

1. Introduction reach goals that cannot be achieved acting


individually. This paper focuses on the supply
1.1. The problem of coordination: EOQ and ELS chain from the perspective of inventory manage-
solutions ment.
In contrast to multi-echelon inventory manage-
The term supply chain management refers to ment, that coordinates inventories at multiple
cooperative management of materials and infor- locations of one company, a joint inventory
mation flows between supply chain partners, to replenishment policy in supply chains involves
coordination among multiple firms (Johnson and
Tel.: +49-69-79828201; fax: +49-69-79828414. Pyke, 2001, pp. 794–795). Therefore, the coordina-
E-mail address: esucky@wiwi.uni-frankfurt.de (E. Sucky). tion of order policy and production policy between

0925-5273/$ - see front matter r 2004 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.ijpe.2004.06.025
ARTICLE IN PRESS

254 E. Sucky / Int. J. Production Economics 93–94 (2005) 253–262

buyers and suppliers in supply chains is of special batch must be finished before any shipments from
interest (Landeros and Lyth, 1989, pp. 146–147). the batch can take place. Agrawal and Raju (1996)
When the buyer and supplier treat inventory consider that the supplier may wish to ship a
problems singly under deterministic conditions, number of equal sized sub-batches before the
the economic order quantity (EOQ) formula or the whole production batch is finished. Based on a
economic lot size (ELS) formula gives an optimal much earlier idea set out by Goyal (1977), Goyal
solution. However, in general, an order policy (1995) shows the use of unequal sized sub-batches.
based on the EOQ solution is undesirable to the This production and delivery policy involves
supplier and likewise, a production and delivery successive shipments within a production batch
policy based on the ELS solution is unacceptable so that the size of the sub-batches increases
to the buyer (Lu, 1995, p. 312). according to a geometric series. The ith sub-batch
size within a production batch will be: (first
1.2. JELS models with equal and unequal sub- shipment size)  (production rate/demand rate)(i1).
batches Chatterjee and Ravi (1991) present an equivalent
model considering fixed delivery costs associated
The problem of coordination between the order with each shipment. Viswanathan (1998) shows
policy and the production policy of a buyer and a that neither a policy with equal sized sub-batches
supplier has received considerable attention in nor a policy with unequal sized sub-batches
recent years. Goyal (2000), Goyal and Gupta dominates the other. Hill (1997), however, sug-
(1989), Joglekar and Tharthare (1990), Thomas gests a more general class of supplier’s production
and Griffin (1996), and Sharafali and Co (2000) and delivery policies. The ith sub-batch size is
give detailed reviews of integrated buyer–supplier given by: (first shipment size)y(i1), with 1pyp
inventory models. A number of authors, including (production rate/demand rate). He shows that, at a
Goyal (1976, 1988), Banerjee (1986b), Landeros fixed transportation cost per shipment, the total
and Lyth (1989), Chatterjee and Ravi (1991) and costs are smaller then using equal sized sub-
Agrawal and Raju (1996) demonstrate methods to batches. Another kind of delivery policy is shown
gain cost savings. They suggest joint economic lot in Goyal and Szendrovits (1986), Goyal and
size (JELS) models where the objective is to Nebebe (2000) and Goyal (2000). A certain
minimize the joint total relevant costs for both number of unequal-sized sub-batches are com-
the buyer and the supplier. It is shown that an bined with a number of equal sized sub-batches.
integrated inventory replenishment policy is more However, one may identify two deficiencies of
desirable than individual optimal policies of the delivery policies with unequal sized sub-batches.
parties involved. While all models use the accepted First, the capacity of the handling, packing and
EOQ formula to determine buyer’s individual shipping equipment must be at least equal to the
optimal order policy, the distinguishing feature is largest sub-batch size and hence, becomes under-
the assumed production and delivery policy of the utilized for smaller sub-batch sizes, which leads to
supplier. Goyal (1976) assumes an infinite produc- idle-capacity costs (Goyal and Szendrovits, 1986,
tion rate for the supplier. Banerjee (1986a) p. 204). On the other hand, if the size of a sub-
generalizes Goyal’s model by integrating a finite batch exceeds the load-capacity of the transporta-
production rate, assuming that the supplier tion unit more then one shipment per sub-batch
follows a lot-for-lot policy. Goyal (1988) further are necessary. Therefore, using unequal sized sub-
relaxes the lot-for-lot assumption by assuming that batches, it is inappropriate to treat shipment costs
each production batch is dispatched to the buyer as being independent of the sub-batch size
in an integer number of equal sized sub-batches. (Szendrovits, 1978, p. 1018). Second, supply and
Landeros and Lyth (1989) further generalize these receipt of unequal sized sub-batches associated
models by incorporating fixed delivery cost asso- with order intervals of different length cause a
ciated with each shipment to the buyer. However, prohibitive operational planning and control effort
these models assume that the whole production for the supplier and the buyer (Agrawal and Raju,
ARTICLE IN PRESS

E. Sucky / Int. J. Production Economics 93–94 (2005) 253–262 255

1996, p. 580). Nevertheless, neither the models single buyer (A) of a specific item. The demand
with equal-sized sub-batches nor the models with rate, b [unit/period], for the item is assumed
unequal-sized sub-batches consider the power constant and deterministic. Shortages are not
structure in buyer–supplier relationships. permitted at the buyer’s end, and the time horizon
over which the item is ordered by (A) and supplied
1.3. Models considering the power structure in by (P) is infinite. The lead-time for (A) is zero. If
buyer–supplier relationships (A) operates independently, his total relevant cost
per period is given by
Should either party be in a position to impose b xA
his EOQ or ELS on the other party, consequently K A ðxA Þ ¼ B þ hA ð1Þ
xA 2
no incentive exists for this party to choose a
cooperative policy. Essentially, the dominant party with b being the buyer’s demand rate [unit/period],
will be at a disadvantage if the JELS solution is xA the buyer’s order quantity per order [unit],
adopted. However, by adopting the JELS solution B the buyer’s ordering cost per order [$], and hA
the dominant party’s loss is more than offset by the buyer’s inventory holding cost [$/unit and
the gain of the weaker party (Banerjee, 1986a, p. period].
308). Thus, to provide an incentive to choose a The objective of (A) is to minimize his total
joint policy the weaker party can offer a side relevant cost per period. It is easy to identify that
payment to the dominant party. The order and for an optimal policy every order is received
delivery quantities and the side payment are precisely when the inventory level drops to zero
determined through a bargaining process between (Bramel and Simchi-Levi, 1997, pp. 145–147). The
the parties. The supplier’s problem to influence the EOQ and the minimum total relevant cost per
buyer’s order policy by a price discount was period are given by
analyzed by previous authors, including Monahan sffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
2Bb pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
(1984), Banerjee (1986b), Lee and Rosenblatt xA ¼ ; K A ðxnA Þ ¼ 2BbhA : ð2Þ
(1986), Joglekar (1988) and Hill (1997). However, hA
there are very few contributions dealing with the
bargaining process between the buyer and the 2.2. Individual optimal production and delivery
supplier. Side payment problems can be consid- policy of the supplier
ered as two-person-nonzero-sum games in which
the buyer and the supplier try to maximize their The supplier (P) manufactures the regarded item
individual gains. at a finite production rate of d [unit/period], with
The research presented in this paper offers d4b, in batches of xPP [unit] and a batch set-up
bargaining models, assuming that the buyer has cost R1 [$]. Each batch is dispatched to (A) in an
the bargaining power to enforce his EOQ on the integer number of equal sized sub-batches xPT
supplier in case of a break-down in negotiations. [unit]: xPP ¼ IxPT , with I 2 IN. When a produc-
Therefore, the supplier has to offer a side payment tion batch is split up into an integer number of
that will certainly guarantee that the buyer accepts sub-batches, shipping costs have to be considered
the contract. With these bargaining models opti- (Landeros and Lyth, 1989, p. 151). With each
mal contracts can be derived. shipment a fixed delivery cost, R2 [$], is associated.
The objective for (P) is to determine the optimal
production and delivery policy leading to a
2. Individual optimal order and production policies minimum of total relevant cost per period. The
total costs comprise the production set-up cost, the
2.1. Individual optimal order policy of the buyer cost of handling and processing the shipments to
(A) and the inventory holding cost. When solving
The discussion and analysis in this paper is the problem it has to be considered whether lot
restricted to the case of a single supplier (P) and streaming is allowed or not.
ARTICLE IN PRESS

256 E. Sucky / Int. J. Production Economics 93–94 (2005) 253–262

In case of lot streaming, assuming an unin- to the individual optimal shipment quantity
terrupted production run, any shipments can be ðxPP ¼ xPT Þ. (P) follows a lot-for-lot policy, i.e.
made from a production batch before the whole after finishing the production batch he ships the
batch is finished. However, some suppliers cannot whole batch to (A). The individual optimal
accommodate lot streaming because of regula- production and delivery policy and the total
tions, material handling equipment, or production relevant cost per period are given by
restrictions (Silver et al., 1998, p. 657). Without lot sffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
streaming the whole production batch must be 2dðR1 þ R2 Þ
xPT ¼ xPP ¼ ;
finished before any shipments can be made from hP
the batch (Hill, 1997, p. 493). The opportunity of rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
P   2ðR1 þ R2 ÞhP
lot streaming affects supplier’s average inventory. K ðI ¼ 1; xPT Þ ¼ b : (6)
According to Goyal (1988) the average inventory d
without lot streaming will be ðxPT =2ÞðIð1 þ b=dÞ  1Þ
[unit]. With lot streaming, Hill (1997) and Agrawal 2.2.2. Individual optimal production and delivery
and Raju (1996) show the average inventory to be policy with lot streaming
ðxPT =2ÞðI  1  Ib=d þ 2b=dÞ [unit]. The supplier’s If (P) operates independently, using the oppor-
inventory holding cost is given by hP [$/unit and tunity of lot streaming, his total relevant cost per
period]. period is given by
b b
2.2.1. Individual optimal production and delivery K P ðI; xPT Þ ¼ R1 þ R2
IxPT xPT
policy without lot streaming  
xPT Ib 2b
If (P) operates independently, without the þ I 1 þ hP : (7)
2 d d
opportunity of lot streaming, his total relevant
cost per period is given by Using lot streaming the optimum value of xPT
b b for a given value of I is given by
K P ðI; xPT Þ ¼ R1 þ R2 sffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
IxPT xPT
    2bðR1 =I þ R2 Þ
xPT b xPT ðIÞ ¼ : ð8Þ
þ I 1þ  1 hP : (3) hP ðI  1  Ib=d þ 2b=dÞ
2 d
The objective of (P) is to minimize his total Substituting xPT in (7) leads to
relevant cost per period. For a given value of I the pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
K P ðIÞ ¼ 2bhP ðR1 =I þ R2 ÞðI  1  Ib=d þ 2b=dÞ:
optimum value of xPT is given by
sffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi ð9Þ
2bðR1 =I þ R2 Þ
xPT ðIÞ ¼ : ð4Þ The optimal integer number of shipments is
ðIð1 þ ðb=dÞÞ  1ÞhP
given by the I  that satisfies
Substituting xPT in (3), the total relevant cost K P ðI   1ÞXK P ðI  ÞpK P ðI  þ 1Þ: ð10Þ
per period as a function of the integer number I of
shipments per batch production run is given by Substituting (9) into (10) and appropriately
P
K ðIÞ rearranging terms, (10) is equivalent to
sffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
      R1 ð2b=d  1Þ
b b R1 I  ðI  þ 1ÞX XI  ðI   1Þ: ð11Þ
¼ 2bhP R1 1   R2 þ R2 I 1   : R2 ð1  b=dÞ
d d I
(5)
As can be seen from (11), the optimal integer
It is easy to see that the optimal integer number number of shipments can only be determined for
I of shipments is I  ¼ 1. Without lot streaming the 2b4d. In case of 2bpd a lot-for-lot policy will be
individual optimal production lot size is identical assumed.
ARTICLE IN PRESS

E. Sucky / Int. J. Production Economics 93–94 (2005) 253–262 257

3. Integrated order and production policies quantity xG ¼ xA ¼ xPT [unit] can be derived as
follows (Agrawal and Raju, 1996, p. 582):
(P) delivers equal-sized sub-batches of xPT [unit].  
b R1
(A) orders quantities of xA [unit]. So, in the JELS K G ðI G ; xG Þ ¼ Bþ þ R2
xG IG
solution the sub-batch size corresponds to the   
order quantity, i.e. xA ¼ xPT . The joint total xG I G b 2b
þ IG  1  þ hP þ hA : (15)
relevant cost per period for a joint order and 2 d d
delivery quantity xG ¼ xA ¼ xPT without lot
streaming is given by (Goyal, 1988, p. 237; Equivalent to the case without lot streaming,
Landeros and Lyth, 1989, p. 154) presented above, the joint economic order and
  production policy for both (A) and (P) is given by
b R1
K G ðI G ; xG Þ ¼ Bþ þ R2
xG IG xA ¼ xPT ¼ xG
    sffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
xG b
þ I G hP 1 þ  hP þ hA : 2bðB þ R1 =I G þ R2 Þ
2 d ¼ ;
ðI G  1  I G b=d þ 2b=dÞhP þ hA

(12)
xPP ¼ I G xG ; (16)
The joint economic order and delivery policy is
given by
sffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi where the joint optimal integer number of ship-
2bðB þ ðR1 =I G Þ þ R2 Þ ments is given by the I  that satisfies
xA ¼ xPT ¼ xG ¼ ;
I G hP ð1 þ b=dÞ  hP þ hA R1 ðhA þ hP ð2b=d  1ÞÞ
I G ðI G  1Þp pI G ðI G þ 1Þ:
xPP ¼ I G xG ; (13) hP ðB þ R2 Þð1  b=dÞ
where the joint optimal integer number of ship- ð17Þ
ments is given by the I G that satisfies
Fig. 2 shows the inventory cycles for (A) and (P)
R1 ðhA  hP Þ
I G ðI G þ 1ÞX   XI G ðI G  1Þ: with lot streaming.
ðB þ R2 ÞhP 1 þ b=d However, for xA axPT , obviously the most
ð14Þ common case, the optimal joint order and delivery
Fig. 1 shows the inventory cycles for (A) and (P) quantity xG is situated in the interval between the
without lot streaming. individual optimal solutions, i.e. xG 2 xA ; xPT ½.
If (P) uses lot streaming, the joint total relevant For any joint policy xG 2 xA ; xPT ½ the buyer’s
cost per period for any joint order and delivery
Buyer(A)
Buyer (A)
Inventory

xA
xA
Inventory

Time
Time
Supplier (P)
Supplier (P)
xPP
Inventory

Inventory

xPT

Time Time

Fig. 1. Inventory cycles without lot streaming (I ¼ 2). Fig. 2. Inventory cycles with lot streaming (I ¼ 3).
ARTICLE IN PRESS

258 E. Sucky / Int. J. Production Economics 93–94 (2005) 253–262

total relevant cost will be 4. The bargaining game


b xG
K A ðxG Þ ¼ B þ hA The bargaining game belongs to the class of
xG 2
  two-person-nonzero-sum games in which (A) and
1 xA xG
¼ þ  K A ðxA Þ (18) (P) try to maximize their individual gains. The
2 xG xA game can be described as follows:
with
  (A) has the power to enforce his EOQ on (P) in
1 xA xG
þ 41: ð19Þ case of a break-down in negotiations. The threat
2 xG xA point, realized in the case of a break-down in
If (A) behaves individually rational, he selects his negotiations (Eichberger, 1993, p. 238), is given
individual optimal policy xA . Should (A) possess by ðK A ðxnA Þ; K P ðI A ; xA ÞÞ.
the dominant position to enforce his EOQ on (P), (P) offers a joint policy x~ G [unit] with an
then no incentive exists for him to choose a joint associated side payment z [$/period]. He makes
policy xG 2 xA ; xPT ½. Essentially, relation (19) a take-it-or-leave-it-offer. In the first stage (P)
shows that (A) will make a loss if the JELS makes an offer, and then, in the second stage,
solution is adopted. Without bargaining, (P) must (A) can either accept or reject. The game is
adapt the buyer’s order policy. For a given immediately terminated after acceptance or
individual order policy xA the optimal integer refusal by (A) (Eichberger, 1993, pp. 55–57).
number of shipments is given by the I A that satisfies (P) has complete information about the cost
P P function of (A).
K ðxA ; I A  1ÞXK ðxA ; I A ÞpK P ðxA ; I A þ 1Þ:
The feasible cost combinations are given by
ð20Þ ðK A ðxG Þ  z; K P ðI; xG Þ þ zÞ.
With (20) follows
2bR1 The objective of (P) is to minimize his total
I A ðI A  1Þp pI A ðI A þ 1Þ
ðxA Þ2 hP ð1
þ b=dÞ relevant cost per period. The following non-linear
minimization problem has to be solved:
ðwithout lot streamingÞ
min K P ðI; xG ; zÞ ¼ K P ðI; xG Þ þ z
and ð22Þ
s:t:
2bR1
I A ðI A  1Þp pI A ðI A þ 1Þ
ðxA Þ2 hP ð1
 b=dÞ
K A ðxG Þ  zpK A ðxnA Þ; ð23Þ
ðwith lot streamingÞ: (21)
Nevertheless, from the supplier’s point of view, in xG ; zX0; I 2 IN: ð24Þ
comparison to the individual optimal order policy
of (A), any joint policy xG 2 xA ; xPT ½ leads to lower Condition (23) ensures individual rationality: it
total relevant cost. Therefore, to provide an must be attractive for (A) to accept the offer. For a
incentive to choose a joint policy (P) can offer a given value of I, the optimization problem with
side payment to (A), which compensates the constraints can be transformed to the following
increase in total relevant cost resulting from this unconstrained minimization problem:
policy. A side payment is defined as an additional
monetary transfer between the parties involved that min LðxG ; zÞ ¼ K P ðI; xG Þ þ z
is used as an incentive for deviating from the  lðK A ðxA Þ  K A ðxG Þ þ zÞ: (25)
individual optimal policy (Rubin and Carter, 1990,
p. 22). (P) must determine the offered delivery As the cost functions K P ðI; xG Þ and K A ðxG Þ are
quantity, the offered side payment and his produc- strictly convex in xG , the Karush–Kuhn–Tucker-
tion policy simultaneously. (KKT-) conditions are sufficient to derive an
ARTICLE IN PRESS

E. Sucky / Int. J. Production Economics 93–94 (2005) 253–262 259

optimal solution: Substituting (32) and (30) into (22), the total
P A relevant cost per period of (P) is given by
qL qK ðI; xG Þ qK ðxG Þ
¼ þl X0; ð26Þ
qxG qxG qxG K P ðIÞ
pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
¼ 2bðB þ R1 =I þ R2 ÞðIhP ð1 þ b=dÞ  hP þ hA Þ
 P  pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
qL qK ðI; xG Þ qK A ðxG Þ  2BbhA : (33)
xG ¼ xG þl ¼ 0;
qxG qxG qxG
Minimizing of (33) is achieved by minimizing
ð27Þ
P R1
K^ ðIÞ ¼ ðB þ R2 ÞIhP ð1 þ b=dÞ þ ðhA  hP Þ:
I
qL qL
¼ 1  lX0 and z ¼ zð1  lÞ ¼ 0; ð28Þ ð34Þ
qz qz
The optimal integer number of shipments is
given by the I~ that satisfies
qL
 ¼ K A ðxA Þ  K A ðxG Þ þ zX0 and P P
ql ~ K^ P ðI~ þ 1Þ:
K^ ðI~  1ÞXK^ ðIÞp ð35Þ
lðK A ðxA Þ  K A ðxG Þ þ zÞ ¼ 0: (29)
Substituting (34) into (35) and appropriately
rearranging terms, (35) is equivalent to (14). (P)
For xG axA follows z40. From z40 and (28) offers exactly the joint economic policy (13),
follows l ¼ 1. For l ¼ 1 and (29) follows presented in the preceding section, associated with
z ¼ K A ðxG Þ  K A ðxA Þ a (theoretical) side payment in accordance with (30).
    pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi In the case of lot streaming, with (31),
1 xA xG
¼ þ  1 2BbhA : (30) xG ¼ xA ¼ xPT , (1) and (7) follows
2 xG xA sffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
2bðB þ R1 =I þ R2 Þ
x~ G ðIÞ ¼ : ð36Þ
(P) will compensate exactly the increase in cost ðI  1  Ib=d þ 2b=dÞhP þ hA
of (A), induced by deviating from the individual
optimal order policy. Condition (23) is fulfilled. Using the opportunity of lot streaming, compar-
The theoretical side payment (30) leads to the able to the case without lot streaming, (P) offers
buyer being just indifferent between accepting and the joint economic policy (16), presented in the
rejecting the supplier’s offer. To create a practical preceding section, associated with a side payment
side payment a small extra incentive of d [$/period] in accordance with (30). In both cases, (P) behaves
should be added. If (A) behaves individually like a master planner and selects the joint
rational, he accepts an offer associated with a side economic order and production policies. A funda-
payment zþd [$/period] and realizes mental principle is illustrated here: if the two
K A ðxG Þ  z  doK A ðxA Þ. It remains to be solved, parties negotiate cooperatively with complete
which joint policy x~ G will be offered by (P). From information, a side payment will lead to a joint
l ¼ 1, (27) and xG 40 follows economic order and production policy (Rubin and
Carter, 1990, p. 25). This result will be illustrated
qK P ðI; xG Þ qK A ðxG Þ by a numerical example.
þ ¼ 0: ð31Þ
qxG qxG

At first, the case where (P) cannot use lot 5. A numerical example
streaming will be analyzed. From (31),
xG ¼ xA ¼ xPT , (1) and (3), follows 5.1. The bargaining situation
sffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
2bðB þ R1 =I þ R2 Þ
x~ G ðIÞ ¼ : ð32Þ Consider the following information for both (A)
IhP ð1 þ b=dÞ  hP þ hA and (P) displayed in Table 1.
ARTICLE IN PRESS

260 E. Sucky / Int. J. Production Economics 93–94 (2005) 253–262

Table 1 units is the order and delivery quantity, the


Numerical example
supplier’s total relevant cost, according to Eq. (3)
Buyer (A) Supplier (P) and condition (20), is K P ðI A ; xA Þ ¼ 6883:33. The
absolute cost penalty of (P) is 2883.33 [$/period],
b=10 000 [unit/period] d=15 000 [unit/period] i.e. an increase of 72.08 percent. Adopting the
B=45 [$] R1 ¼ 360 [$], R2 ¼ 40 [$]
JELS solution, 558.36 units, would result in a cost
hA ¼ 10 [$/unit and period] hP ¼ 3 [$/unit and period]
penalty of 597.73 [$/period] on the part of the
buyer, i.e. an increase of 19.92 percent. Therefore,
(A) has no incentive to choose the JELS solution.
But, adopting the JELS solution, (P) saves 988.96
[$/period]. Thus the buyer’s loss is more than
offset by the supplier’s gain. If (P) offers a side
payment of 597.73 [$/period] and persuades (A) to
change his order policy from 300 to 558.36 units,
the increase in total relevant cost of (A) will be
compensated exactly by (P). If (A) accepts the
offer (P) gains 391.23 [$/period].

5.3. Bargaining solution with lot streaming

These results change in case of using lot


streaming on supplier’s side (see Table 3).
The individual optimal policy of (P) leads to
Fig. 3. Individual optimal solutions. K P ðI  ; xPT Þ ¼ 3577:71. If (A) enforces his EOQ on
(P); his absolute cost penalty is 588.95 [$/period],
i.e. 16.46 percent. Adopting the JELS solution,
The individual optimal policy of (A), i.e. five
398.34 units, would result in a cost penalty of
orders per period of xA ¼ 300, leads to total
102.5 [$/period] on the part of the buyer and at the
relevant cost of K A ðxA Þ ¼ 3000. The individual
same time, the supplier saves 261 [$/period]. If (P)
optimal policy of (P) is given by I  ¼ 1,
persuades (A) to change his order policy from 300
xPT ¼ xPP ¼ 2000, with K P ðI  ; xPT Þ ¼ 4000 (with-
to 398.34 units, offering a side payment of 102.5
out lot streaming) or xPT ¼ 894:43, I  ¼ 3,
[$/period], (P) gains 158.5 [$/period]. With lot
xPP ¼ 2683:29, with K P ðI  ; xPT Þ ¼ 3577:71 (with
streaming, (P) can react more flexible on a given
lot streaming), i.e. xA axPT applies. Fig. 3 shows
order policy of the buyer. The cost penalty of
these individual optimal solutions.
adopting the buyer’s individual optimal order
policy, and likewise, the gain induced by the
5.2. Bargaining solution without lot streaming bargaining solution are smaller than without lot
streaming.
Without lot streaming, Table 2 shows the results
for (A) and (P) in case of
(A) and (P) choosing the JELS solution, 6. Conclusion
(P) adapting his delivery policy to the individual
optimal order policy of (A) and In this paper a joint order and production policy
(P) offering a joint policy associated by a side is developed as a bargaining solution assuming
payment. that the buyer has the dominant position. The
paper presents an analytical approach to deter-
The individual optimal policy of (P) leads to mining the terms of a supplier-oriented optimal
K P ðI  ; xPT Þ ¼ 4000. As the buyer’s EOQ of 300 side payment scheme. It is shown that the joint
ARTICLE IN PRESS

E. Sucky / Int. J. Production Economics 93–94 (2005) 253–262 261

Table 2
Illustration of the solution without lot streaming

Joint policy Buyer’s cost Supplier’s cost

Buyer’s solution xG ¼ xA ¼ xPT ¼ 300 K A ðxA Þ ¼ 3000 K P ðI A ; xA Þ ¼ 6883:33


I A ¼ 4; xPP ¼ 1200
JELS solution xG ¼ xA ¼ xPT ¼ 558:36 K A ðxG Þ ¼ 3597:73 K P ðI G ; xG Þ ¼ 5894:37
I G ¼ 2; xPP ¼ 1116:72
Bargaining solution x~ G ¼ xA ¼ xPT ¼ 558:36; I~ ¼ 2 K A ðx~ G Þ  z ¼ 3000 ~ x~ G Þ þ z ¼ 6492:1
K P ðI;
xPP ¼ 1116:72; z ¼ 597:73

Table 3
Illustration of the solution with lot streaming

Joint policy Buyer’s cost Supplier’s cost

Buyer’s solution xG ¼ xA ¼ xPT ¼ 300 K A ðxA Þ ¼ 3000 K P ðI A ; xA Þ ¼ 4166:66


I A ¼ 9; xPP ¼ 2700
JELS solution xG ¼ xA ¼ xPT ¼ 398:34 K A ðxG Þ ¼ 3102:5 K P ðI G ; xG Þ ¼ 3905:66
I G ¼ 7; xPP ¼ 2725:38
Bargaining solution x~ G ¼ xA ¼ xPT ¼ 398:34; I~ ¼ 7 K A ðx~ G Þ  z ¼ 3000 ~ x~ G Þ þ z ¼ 4008:16
K P ðI;
x~ PP ¼ 2725:38; z ¼ 102:5

optimal policy with an according side payment EOQ and, likewise, the buyer’s ordering cost can
results from negotiations. Adopting the bargaining be specified as an implicit function of his holding
solution, the gain of the supplier depends on his cost and his EOQ. The relative insensitivity of z ¼
production policy, i.e. if the supplier has the K A ðxG Þ  K A ðxA Þ to measurement errors permits
opportunity to use lot streaming or not. With lot the establishment of a ‘‘good’’ side payment.
streaming the supplier is provided with more Therefore, a bargaining solution succeeds if (P)
flexibility to react on buyer’s individual optimal estimates the cost structure of (A) with sufficient
order policy. The supplier realizes a lower cost accuracy.
penalty with lot streaming than without lot
streaming. Nevertheless, in both cases, with or
References
without lot streaming, the supplier benefits from
the presented bargaining solutions. This raises a Agrawal, A.K., Raju, D.A., 1996. Improved joint economic lot
crucial practical issue. In order to determine the size model for a purchaser and a vendor. In: Khan, M.K.,
side payment the supplier must obtain the Wright, C.S., Whalley, R. (Eds.), Advanced Manufacturing
numerical estimates of buyer’s ordering cost per Processes, Systems, and Technologies (AMPST 96),
order and buyer’s inventory holding cost. While pp. 579–587.
Banerjee, A., 1986a. A joint economic-lot-size model for
the buyer’s periodical demand can be anticipated purchaser and vendor. Decision Sciences 17, 292–311.
from the past ordering behavior of the buyer, it is Banerjee, A., 1986b. Notes on ‘‘A quantity discount pricing
very difficult to estimate buyer’s holding and model to increase vendor profits’’. Management Science 32,
ordering costs. This is true unless the buyer is 1513–1517.
willing to disclose the true values of his cost Bramel, J., Simchi-Levi, D., 1997. The Logic of Logistics—
Theory, Algorithm, and Applications for Logistics Manage-
parameters (Landeros and Lyth, 1989, p. 313). ment. New York.
However, the buyer’s holding cost can be specified Chatterjee, A.K., Ravi, R., 1991. Joint economic lot-size model
as an implicit function of his ordering cost and his with delivery in sub-batches. Opsearch 28, 118–124.
ARTICLE IN PRESS

262 E. Sucky / Int. J. Production Economics 93–94 (2005) 253–262

Eichberger, J., 1993. Game Theory for Economists. Academic one vendor and many purchasers. Decision Sciences 21,
Press, San Diego. 492–506.
Goyal, S.K., 1976. An integrated inventory model for a single Johnson, M.E., Pyke, D.F., 2001. Supply chain management.
supplier–single customer problem. International Journal of In: Gass, S.I., Harris, C.M. (Eds.), Encyclopaedia of
Production Research 15, 107–111. Operations Research and Management Science. Centennial
Goyal, S.K., 1977. Determination of optimum production Edition, Kluwer, Boston, pp. 794–806.
quantity for a two-stage production system. Operational Landeros, R., Lyth, D.M., 1989. Economic-lot-size models for
Research Quarterly 28, 865–870. cooperative interorganizational relationships. Journal of
Goyal, S.K., 1988. ‘‘A joint economic-lot-size model for Business Logistics 10, 146–158.
purchaser and vendor’’: A comment. Decision Sciences 19, Lee, H.L., Rosenblatt, M.J., 1986. A generalized quantity
236–241. discount pricing model to increase supplier’s profits.
Goyal, S.K., 1995. A one-vendor multi-buyer integrated Management Science 32, 1177–1185.
inventory model: A comment. European Journal of Opera- Lu, L., 1995. A one-vendor multi-buyer integrated inventory
tional Research 82, 209–210. model. European Journal of Operational Research 81,
Goyal, S.K., 2000. On improving the single-vendor single-buyer 312–323.
integrated production inventory model with a generalized Monahan, J.P., 1984. A quantity discount pricing model to
policy. European Journal of Operational Research 125, increase vendor profits. Management Science 30, 720–726.
429–430. Rubin, P.A., Carter, J.R., 1990. Joint optimality in buyer–sup-
Goyal, S.K., Gupta, Y.P., 1989. Integrated inventory models: plier negotiations. Journal of Purchasing and Materials
the buyer–vendor coordination. European Journal of Management (Spring), 20–26.
Operational Research 41, 261–269. Sharafali, M., Co, H.C., 2000. Some models for understanding
Goyal, S.K., Nebebe, F., 2000. Determination of economic the cooperation between the supplier and the buyer.
production—shipment policy for a single-vendor–single- International Journal of Production Research 38,
buyer system. European Journal of Operational Research 3425–3449.
121, 175–178. Silver, E.A., Pyke, D.F., Peterson, R., 1998. Inventory
Goyal, S.K., Szendrovits, A.Z., 1986. A constant lot size model Management and Production Planning and Scheduling,
with equal and unequal sized batch shipments between 3rd Edition. Wiley, New York.
production stages. Engineering Costs and Production Szendrovits, A.Z., 1978. A comment on determination of
Economics 10, 203–210. optimum production quantity for a two-stage production
Hill, R.M., 1997. The single-vendor single-buyer integrated system. Journal of the Operational Research Society 29,
production-inventory model with a generalised policy. 1017–1020.
European Journal of Operational Research 97, 493–499. Thomas, D.J., Griffin, P.M., 1996. Coordinated supply chain
Joglekar, P.N., 1988. Comments on: A quantity discount management. European Journal of Operational Research
pricing model to increase vendor profits. Management 94, 1–15.
Science 34, 1391–1398. Viswanathan, S., 1998. Optimal strategy for the integrated
Joglekar, P.N., Tharthare, S., 1990. The individually respon- vendor–buyer inventory model. European Journal of
sible and rational decision approach to economic lot size for Operational Research 105, 38–42.

Potrebbero piacerti anche