Sei sulla pagina 1di 10

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/222691592

Vocational education in Thailand: A study of choice and returns

Article  in  Economics of Education Review · February 2003


DOI: 10.1016/S0272-7757(01)00059-0 · Source: RePEc

CITATIONS READS

37 1,285

2 authors:

Thammarak Moenjak Christopher Worswick


Bank of Thailand Carleton University
3 PUBLICATIONS   46 CITATIONS    69 PUBLICATIONS   1,305 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

All content following this page was uploaded by Christopher Worswick on 05 March 2015.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Economics of Education Review 22 (2003) 99–107
www.elsevier.com/locate/econedurev

Vocational education in Thailand: a study of choice and


returns
a,* b
Thammarak Moenjak , Christopher Worswick
a
Monetary Policy Group, Bank of Thailand, 273 Samsen Rd., Pranakorn, Bangkok 10300, Thailand
b
Department of Economics, Carleton University, 1125 Colonel by Drive, Ottawa, Ont. K1S 5B6, Canada

Received 18 February 2000; received in revised form 5 June 2001; accepted 30 August 2001

Abstract

This study adds new evidence to the debate on the relative benefits of upper secondary vocational education and of
general education at the same level. Using a probit model, the study finds that an individual from a well-to-do family is
more likely to undertake vocational education. After correcting for possible self-selection, the study also finds vocational
education to give higher earnings returns than general education does. These findings call into question the belief that
vocational education has been overvalued and that providing general education to the workforce followed by on-the-
job training would provide more benefits. Indeed, the study suggests that an investment to improve the access to
vocational education might prove more beneficial.
 2001 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved.

JEL classification: I20; I21; I28

Keywords: Rate of return; School choice

1. Introduction vocational education level gives higher returns than does


upper secondary general education at least for men.
This paper aims to identify the factors that influence (Trost and Lee (1984) did not evaluate the returns to
an individual’s choice between vocational and general technical education for women.)
education in Thailand as well as the relative returns To investigate the factors that influence an individ-
between these two types of education at the upper sec- ual’s choice between the two types of education, the
ondary level. Since the 1970s there have been various paper first estimates a probit model of education choice
studies that examined an individual’s choice and the rela- before proceeding to estimate the relative returns to the
tive returns to each type of program. The findings, two types of education using a self-selection corrected
especially with respect to the relative returns, however, earnings model. The results from the analysis should pro-
have been inconclusive. vide interesting insights with regard to vocational edu-
Hollenbeck (1993) found the returns to post-secondary cation in an industrializing country.
vocational education in 1972 in the United States to be
significant for women but not for men. Trost and Lee 1.1. Overview of Thailand’s secondary education
(1984), on the other hand, found that in the United States
in 1973, technical education at the upper secondary Throughout Thailand, primary education is compul-
sory. Individuals are required to enroll in a primary
school for at least 6 years from age 7 (Office of the
* Corresponding author. National Education Commission, 1997a). Secondary
E-mail address: thammarm@bot.or.th (T. Moenjak). education, on the other hand, is non-compulsory and is

0272-7757/02/$ - see front matter  2001 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/S0272-7757(01)00059-0
100 T. Moenjak, C. Worswick / Economics of Education Review 22 (2003) 99–107

divided into two levels. Lower secondary education istical Office of Thailand. The sample for each Labor
covers grades 7 to 9. Lower secondary education aims Force Survey is drawn randomly from different house-
to equip students with literary and numerical skills that holds throughout the country. Records of the question-
would make them competent workers in non-specialized, naires available to the public start from the survey
non-manual jobs, or prepare them for further education year 1989.
levels. Students must complete lower secondary edu- In the analysis, the sample is pooled from the records
cation before continuing on to upper secondary edu- of those individuals who were not attending school and
cation (grade 10 to grade 12). were between 15 and 60 years of age at the time of the
At the upper secondary education level, students can survey. The sample used for the first-step probit analysis
choose between two streams of education; namely, the is restricted to those individuals who reported having
general (or academic) stream and the vocational (or upper secondary vocational or upper secondary general
technical) education stream. Access to both streams of education as the highest level of education, and whose
upper secondary education is rather open, with similar relevant information on parental education and parental
admission criteria.1 The number of places available for occupation is not missing. For the second-step evaluation
general education, however, exceeds that for technical of the individuals’ earnings the sample is further restric-
education (Office of the National Education Com- ted to those who reported their earnings and were
mission, 1997a). Regardless of their choice, once they employed at the time of the survey. Table 1 shows the
finished grade 12, the graduates from both streams are descriptive statistics of our sample.
considered equally qualified to sit for national university Note that for our analysis, the sample is restricted to
examinations (Office of the National Education Com- individuals who are sons or daughters of the household
mission, 1997a). heads. Data from Thailand’s Labor Force Survey do not
Upper secondary general education, other than prepar- explicitly contain information on parents. Information on
ing students for further education, also aims to equip the parents is important in our analysis as it could reflect the
students with basic skills that would make them com- individual’s socioeconomic status, a possible determi-
petent workers in general non-manual jobs such as office nant of his/her education choice. To obtain parental
workers. Upper secondary vocational education, on the information, observations of children are thus matched
other hand, while also preparing students for technical with those of the individuals from the same household
studies in tertiary institutions, aims to equip them with who reported having a parents–children relationship.
specialised technical skills that are deemed essentials for (The only parents–children relationship reported in the
jobs that require relatively highly specialised skills such Labor Force Survey is that of the household heads,
as those for mechanics, electricians, as well as business household head’s spouse and their children.) The
skills such as bookkeeping (Office of the National Edu- resulting sample used in this paper, hence, consists of
cation Commission, 1997a).2 only those who are the sons or daughters of the house-
hold heads. Individuals who did not live with their par-
ents at the time of the surveys are completely excluded
2. The data from our estimation. Such exclusion suggests that our
sample is a selected group, especially if those who live
For the estimation of the probit choice model and the with parents tend to be those who cannot afford to live
earnings equation, the paper uses data from Thailand’s apart on their earnings.
Labor Force Survey for the years 1989 to 1995 inclusive. While the possible sample-selection issue is undeni-
The survey is conducted annually by the National Stat- ably real, it should not, however, seriously affect the
ability of our analysis to address the main questions of
the paper. First, since one of our main concern is to
1
The costs of upper secondary vocational education are on evaluate returns to vocational education as compared to
average higher than those of general education at the same level general education at the upper secondary level, our sam-
are. In this study, however, we do not have information on the ple is large enough to give a good idea of the relative
exact costs of study for each of the individuals. The estimation returns between these two types of education at that
of the returns to education, hence, is performed with the con- level, at least for those in the survey who were living
ventional assumption that, on average, student earnings plus with parents. In any case, there is no reason to expect
scholarships roughly paid for tuition. (See Leibowitz, 1974; that the relative returns to these types of education would
Mincer, 1974, for details.)
2 be different for those who do and those who do not live
Some vocational schools also offer agricultural studies.
The proportions of vocational school students enrolled in agri- with their parents. Even if we assume that an individual
cultural studies, however, have always been very small. In lives with his parents only if he/she can not afford to
1994, for example, less than 5% of vocational school students live on his/her earning, there is no a priori reason to
enrolled in agricultural studies (Office of the National Edu- believe why, ceteris paribus, an individual with a parti-
cation Commission, 1997b). cular type of education is less likely to be able to afford
T. Moenjak, C. Worswick / Economics of Education Review 22 (2003) 99–107 101

Table 1 ate the individual’s relative probabilities of attaining one


Descriptive statistics. Sample means and standard deviations type of education over another.
(standard deviations in parentheses) Second, as argued by Bedi and Gaston (1997), given
the prevalence of ‘joint’ families in developing countries,
Variable Males Females
the individuals may simply live with their parents out of
Sample size (N) 2633 2252 convenience in location or because they are participating
Education attainment in family enterprises.3 Unlike western countries where
Vocational education 0.435 0.444 nucleus families are more widespread, ‘joint’ families in
(0.495) (0.497) Thailand remain relatively common. Individuals may
Work characteristics live with parents even after they are married and have
Experience 5.718 5.268 children of their own. Since the Labor Force Survey do
(4.574) (4.454) not indicate who are the ‘breadwinners’ of the families,
Hourly earnings it is premature to assume that all the individuals living
Baht 18.890 17.716 with their parents are still subsidized by their parents
(13.052) (14.379)
incomes (and all those who are not living with their par-
Region of residence
North 0.165 0.150 ents are not). Cultural norm dictates that many of the
(0.372) (0.358) individuals in our sample could actually be providing for
Northeast 0.227 0.235 their parents (who may have long retired, since the
(0.419) (0.424) maximum individual’s own age in our sample reaches
Middle 0.319 0.324 60).
(0.466) (0.498) With the two reasons given above, there is no a priori
Bangkok 0.123 0.130 reason to believe that estimation results of the paper
(0.328) (0.337) would not at least partly reflect the relative probabilities
Area of residence of the individual’s education choice and the relative
Municipal area 0.437 0.460
returns to the different types of education for those of
(0.496) (0.498)
Sanitary district 0.298 0.291 the general population. Admittedly, until large-scale data
(0.457) (0.454) that include parental information become available for
Marital status Thailand, this sample selection issue remains real.
Married 0.222 0.265
(0.415) (0.441)
Divorced, separated, widowed 0.011 0.038 3. Theoretical model
(0.104) (0.192)
Migration status 0.279 0.246 According to Mincer (1974), earnings determinants
Migrant (0.449) (0.430) could be estimated using the following functional form:
No. of family members
More than five 0.366 0.398 ln wi⫽b⬘Xi⫹dVi⫹ei. (1)
(0.481) (0.489)
Survey year after 1991 where lnwi is the log of hourly earnings of individual i;
After 1991 0.688 0.666 Xi is a vector of personal, and background characteristics
(0.463) (0.471) of individual i, Vi is a vector of the individual i’s edu-
Birth cohort cational attainment, and ei is the random disturbance
B1965–69 0.384 0.385 term.
(0.486) (0.486) Griliches (1977), however, pointed out that the coef-
B1970–74 0.332 0.332 ficient estimates of the OLS estimation of the classical
(0.471) (0.471) model could suffer from what is now commonly known
B1975 AND AFTER 0.068 0.088
as ‘self-selection bias’. When the individual’s back-
(0.252) (0.284)
ground and ability ‘dictate’ his/her educational attain-
ment, the individual is said to be ‘self-selected’ into that
particular educational attainment. If educational attain-
ment of an individual is at least partly determined by the
living out on his/her own. Indeed, our descriptive stat- individual’s abilities and family backgrounds, estimating
istics below show that, for both men and women, the classical earnings equation without taking into
vocational school and general school graduates are rep-
resented roughly equally in our sample. This relatively
even distribution reflects the situation in the total survey 3
An example of a ‘joint family’ is a family where the famil-
population. The reason presented here also applies to the ies of the children of the household head reside together in a
fact that the other main concern of the paper is to evalu- household.
102 T. Moenjak, C. Worswick / Economics of Education Review 22 (2003) 99–107

account the possibility that family background and impact on the individual’s education decision, as it was
ability might influence educational attainment could give often the mother who provided the learning environment
biased results. The significant magnitudes of coefficient for her child.
estimates of education variables might at least be partly Other than parental education, household head’s occu-
attributable to the individual’s background and ability pation (or ‘father’s’ in our context) can also reflect the
rather than returns to education per se. socioeconomic status of the household. Here we classify
For the investigation on the returns to vocational edu- the different occupations reported in the Labor Force
cation in Thailand, we correct for the possibility that the Survey into three separate groups. White collar includes
estimated relative returns to education might at least be professional and managerial occupations. Blue collar and
partly attributable to the factors that influenced the indi- crafts includes clerical, sales, traders and craftsmen.
vidual’s choice of education by using the standard two- Menial includes farmers, agricultural workers, and ser-
stage procedure with inverse Mills ratio. vice providers. Socioeconomic status is assumed to rank
in descending order from white collar, blue collar and
crafts, and menial, respectively.
4. Econometric specification Since certain individuals might have migrated between
the time of education and the time of the survey, in the
4.1. First stage probit choice model case of these individuals, the reported region/area of resi-
dence might not be the same as the actual region/area of
For the first stage probit choice model, our dependent upbringing. To account for this possibility, if the period
variable takes a value of 1 if the individual’s choice of of residing in the reported residence was less than the
upper secondary education is a vocational one, and takes potential experience, we use the reported prior region
a value of 0 if upper secondary general education is and area of residence as the region and area of upbring-
chosen. The explanatory variables included in the vector ing instead.5
Zi include parental education, parental occupation, region
of residence, area of residence, and the number of house- 4.2. Second stage earnings equation
hold members. All of the explanatory variables, except
number of household members take the form of zero– The dependent variable used is the log hourly earn-
one dummy variables. ings. Hourly earnings are used because other measures
For our estimation, father’s and mother’s educational of earnings (for example, daily or monthly earnings) do
attainment dummy variables are used as proxies for not factor out the ‘labour supply’ effect. An individual
household socioeconomic status.4 In our context, we might report having received higher monthly earnings
would expect higher parental educational attainment to simply because, ceteris paribus, he/she simply supplied
imply higher socioeconomic status. Furthermore, in the more labour. Hourly earnings, hence, are a better meas-
case where ability is partially attributable to genetic mar- ure for our estimation purpose. For our estimation, the
kings, and that education attainment is partly attributable log of hourly earnings is used as the dependent variable
to individual’s ability, parental education variables also instead of hourly earnings because it reduces the effects
proxy for the individual’s ability. of earnings outliers.
In our model, father’s and mother educational attain- To evaluate the returns to vocational education in
ment dummy variables are entered separately. The Thailand, a dummy variable indicating if the individual
father’s education dummy variable takes a value of one has completed vocational education is included in the
if father’s highest level of education attainment is higher model. The dummy variable takes a value of one if the
than primary education, and zero otherwise. The same is individual has completed upper secondary vocational
true for mother’s education dummy variable. In their education and a value of zero if the individual is an upper
work, Behrman and Wolfe (1984), Chiswick (1986) and secondary general graduate.
Heckman and Hotz (1986) all argued that mother’s edu- Experience variables are included in the model since,
cation (rather than father’s) might have more significant ceteris paribus, workers with more years of job experi-
ence are likely to earn more. (Higher experience is often
associated with higher skills and higher productivity.) A
4
Note that the terms ‘father’ and ‘mother’ used in this thesis firm is likely to use higher wages to induce experienced
are actually ‘household head’ and ‘spouse of the household workers to stay on in their jobs, as the cost of training
head’. The terms ‘father’ and ‘mother’ are used here because
new workers could be very expensive. With the higher
they are less cumbersome and more informative in our context.
The sample used in this thesis consists of only the sons and the wages, the firm makes the workers’ costs of leaving the
daughters of the household head. In any case, more than 90
percent of the household heads with spouse present in the data
5
are males (and hence the ‘father’ term is not entirely Regions and areas of residence are classified according to
inappropriate). those done in the Labor Force Survey.
T. Moenjak, C. Worswick / Economics of Education Review 22 (2003) 99–107 103

firm high. To capture the relationship between experi- Table 2


ence and earnings, we include two experience variables, Probit maximum likelihood estimation of the decision to under-
namely potential experience and potential experience take vocational educationa
squared. The potential experience squared variable is
Variable Males Females
included in addition to the potential experience variable
to capture the possibility of a non-linear relationship Constant ⫺0.348** ⫺0.192 (p-
between experience and earnings. value=0.11)
Note here that for our estimation, potential experience (0.107) (0.117)
is included instead of actual experience because the Lab- Father’s education
our Force Survey data we use reports neither the work- More than primary 0.253** 0.111
ers’ actual experience on their current job nor in their (0.068) (0.076)
former jobs. To control for the relationship between Mother’s education
experience and earnings, hence, we use potential experi- More than primary 0.046 0.011
ence variable (measured in years) as a proxy for the (0.075) (0.081)
Father’s occupation
actual experience. Note that potential experience is
White collar 0.187** 0.182**
defined here as the age reported at the time of the survey (0.060) (0.068)
minus the age left school. Blue collar 0.272** 0.296**
Other dummy variables included in the model include (0.069) (0.071)
those proxy for regions and areas of residence, marital Region of upbringing
status, migration status, birth cohort, and sample year. North 0.116 ⫺0.269**
(0.107) (0.118)
Northeast ⫺0.052 ⫺0.285**
5. Empirical results (0.099) (0.106)
Middle 0.312** 0.222**
(0.085) (0.092)
5.1. First stage probit equation
Bangkok 0.343** 0.507**
(0.106) (0.116)
Table 2 presents maximum likelihood estimation Area of upbringing
results showing the relationship between background Municipal area 0.180** 0.085
characteristics and the decision, for men and women, to (0.072) (0.078)
undertake upper secondary vocational education versus Sanitary district 0.006 ⫺0.138*
general education at the same level. (0.073) (0.078)
From Table 2, we can see that for both men and No. of family’s members
women, socioeconomic status as measured by father’s More than five ⫺0.071 0.023
occupation, plays a significant role in influencing the (0.053) (0.056)
Survey year
individual’s choice of upper secondary education. Cet-
After 1991 ⫺0.003 ⫺0.025
eris paribus, males and females from a higher economic (0.058) (0.061)
status are more likely to undertake vocational education. Birth cohort
For both men and women, as compared to having father B1965–69 ⫺0.294** ⫺0.218**
in a menial occupation, having father in a white collar (0.074) (0.083)
or a blue collar occupation significantly increases the B1970–74 ⫺0.303** ⫺0.274**
probability of undertaking vocational education. (0.080) (0.088)
With regard to father’s education, for men, father’s B1975 AND AFTER ⫺0.559** ⫺0.193 (p-
educational attainment being higher than primary level value=0.112)
significantly increases the probability of undertaking (0.124) (0.122)
Log likelihood ⫺1726.048 ⫺1452.148
vocational education. Such a result further confirms that,
c2 (d.f.=15) 154.250** 189.829**
at least for men, ceteris paribus, an individual from a
higher socioeconomic status is more likely to undertake a
**Significant at 5% level; *significant at 10% level.
upper secondary vocational education (as opposed to
general education at the same level).
For both men and women, being raised in a more pros-
perous region of the country (the middle region or Looking at the cohort effects, it appears that
Bangkok) significantly increases the probability of vocational education has become less popular for indi-
undertaking vocational education. For women, on the viduals from the more recent cohorts. For both men and
other hand, being raised in a poorer region (eg. the north women, being born after 1969 significantly decreases the
or the north or the northeast) also decreases that prob- probability of undertaking vocational education, ceteris
ability. paribus. The coefficient estimates of the dummy vari-
104 T. Moenjak, C. Worswick / Economics of Education Review 22 (2003) 99–107

ables for 1970–1974 and 1975 and after are all negative case could be the inclusion of the birth cohort variables
and significant for both men and women. in our estimation. The way we define them, birth cohort
At the first glance, these results for men and women variables are highly correlated with potential experience
seem to suggest that, while vocational education has and hence could take out some of the explanatory vari-
been advocated by the government as a crucial provider ables of the potential experience squared variables. Also,
of skills for the industrialisation of the country, since our sample includes many of the relatively young
vocational education itself has become increasingly less individuals (those still living with parents) the dimin-
popular among the new cohorts of population. On the ishing effects of the returns to experience might still be
other hand, our estimates here might have neglected the relatively weak.
fact that increased access to higher education could have With regard to self-selection effect, for both men and
led more vocational school graduates to undertake ter- women, the parameter estimates of the self-selection cor-
tiary education. Since the information on those rection terms (hi) are negative. For men, the parameter
vocational school graduates who continued on to higher estimate is significant at the 10 percent level. For
education is not available in the Labour Force Surveys women, the p-value of the estimate is at 10.6 percent
(and hence our sample), we cannot further investigate level. The negative signs of the dummy variables suggest
this point. that if the general education graduates had indeed chosen
vocational education, they are not likely to earn less than
5.2. Second stage earnings equation what the vocational education graduates earn, ceteris par-
ibus.
From Table 3, we can see that, for both men and Table 3 also shows the results from the OLS esti-
women, upper secondary vocational education gives sig- mation of Mincer’s classical earnings model. The main
nificantly higher earning returns than does upper second- difference between the results from the OLS estimation
ary general education. Indeed, as compared to general and the self-selection correction model lie in the differ-
education at the same level, upper secondary vocational ences in the estimates of the relative returns to upper
education gives higher earnings returns by 63.9 percent secondary vocational education as compared to general
for men and 49.4 percent for women. education at the same level.
Possible explanations for such results include compen- According to the OLS estimates of the Mincer earn-
sating wage differentials as well as increased demand for ings model, as compared to general education at the
the skills provided by upper secondary vocational edu- same level, upper secondary vocational education gives
cation due to the industrialisation process. According to higher earnings returns by 23.8 percent for men and 20.7
compensating wage differential story, the nature of the percent for women (see Table 3). Both of the OLS esti-
jobs normally taken by upper secondary vocational edu- mates of the vocational education dummy variables are
cation graduates might differ from those normally taken significant at the one percent level. After taking account
by their upper secondary general education counterparts of the possible self-selection, however, the returns to
in such a way that the employers are willing to pay the vocational education are found to be higher than those
vocational school graduates more. (For example, jobs for general education by 63.9 percent for men and 49.4
normally taken by vocational school graduates such as, percent for women respectively. The coefficient esti-
say, mechanics, may be more physically demanding, mates of the vocational education dummy variables in
more hazardous, and more specialised that the employers the self-selection corrected model estimation are signifi-
are willing to pay wage premiums to their employees.) cant at the one percent level for both men and women.
On the other hand, with the rapid industrialisation pro- While the magnitudes of the estimated returns rise dra-
cess going on in the economy, employers in the indus- matically after the self-selection correction procedure, it
tries may be willing to pay wage premiums to retain the must be kept in mind that our rather selected sample
workers with the technical skills provided by could play a role for such a rise. Until a more complete
vocational education. set of data becomes available, the dramatic rise in the
For both men and women, the concavity of the magnitudes of the estimated relative returns to vocational
relationship between potential experience and earnings education remains in question. However, with the high
is not confirmed. For both men and women, while the statistical significance of the vocational education
parameter estimates of the potential experience dummy dummy variables and the self-selection variables, it is
variables are positive and significant at the one percent still very reasonable to conclude that, for our analysis,
level, the potential experience squared variables, though after correcting for self-selection, returns to vocational
negative, are statistically insignificant. Our results here education remain higher than those to general education.
differ from the results found by earlier studies on the Other results from the OLS and the self-selection cor-
returns to education (see, for examples, Bellew and rected estimations appear to agree in general. The signs
Moock, 1990; Tansel, 1994; Gaston and Sturm, 1991). and the magnitudes of all the other variables appear simi-
One possible explanation for the non-concavity in our lar, even though some of significance levels of the para-
T. Moenjak, C. Worswick / Economics of Education Review 22 (2003) 99–107 105

Table 3
Estimated earnings equations (corrected standard errors in parentheses for self-selection corrected results, and normal standard errors
for OLS results)a

Variable Males Males Females Females


(self-selection (OLS) (self-selection (OLS)
corrected) corrected)

Constant 1.830** 2.003** 1.578** 1.707**


(0.098) (0.102) (0.124) (0.108)
Work characteristics
Experience 0.062** 0.609** 0.070** 0.068**
(0.009) (0.013) (0.012) (0.014)
Experience squared ⫺0.0003 ⫺0.0003 ⫺0.0004 ⫺0.0003
(0.0003) (0.0004) (0.0005) (0.0005)
Education attainment
Vocational education 0.639** 0.238** 0.494** 0.207**
(0.146) (0.028) (0.180) (0.031)
Region of residence
North ⫺0.017 ⫺0.005 0.155** 0.131**
(0.038) (0.051) (0.053) (0.057)
Northeast ⫺0.089** ⫺0.090* 0.283** ⫺0.262**
(0.039) (0.053) (0.052) (0.057)
Middle 0.157** 0.192** 0.384** 0.403**
(0.036) (0.045) (0.045) (0.049)
Bangkok 0.366** 0.404** 0.460** 0.508**
(0.043) (0.054) (0.059) (0.058)
Area of residence
Municipal area ⫺0.092** ⫺0.055 ⫺0.094** ⫺0.074*
(0.032) (0.040) (0.039) (0.042)
Sanitary district 0.031 0.038 ⫺0.007 0.011
(0.031) (0.041) (0.038) (0.043)
Marital status
Married 0.043* 0.036 ⫺0.003 ⫺0.003
(0.026) (0.035) (0.035) (0.040)
Divorced, separated, widowed ⫺0.244** ⫺0.249* ⫺0.251** ⫺0.250**
(0.098) (0.137) (0.074) (0.086)
Migration status
Migrant ⫺0.111** ⫺0.087** ⫺0.057 ⫺0.029
(0.032) (0.042) (0.046) (0.049)
Survey year
After 1991 0.228** 0.229** 0.212** 0.208**
(0.032) (0.043) (0.041) (0.046)
Birth cohort
B1965–69 0.069 0.031 0.105* 0.090
(0.045) (0.057) (0.061) (0.068)
B1970–74 0.153** 0.115 0.260** 0.237**
(0.065) (0.087) (0.087) (0.098)
B1975 AND AFTER 0.221** 0.140 0.485** 0.468**
(0.096) (0.126) (0.116) (0.132)
Self-selection term
hI ⫺0.251** ⫺0.178
(0.091) (0.110)
Adjusted R-squared 0.307 0.305 0.294 0.292

a
**Significant at 5% level; *significant at 10% level.
106 T. Moenjak, C. Worswick / Economics of Education Review 22 (2003) 99–107

meter estimates of the marital status, and the birth cohort presented in Section 3). The unrestricted model (see Eq.
dummy variables change after we correct for the possible (A2)), on the other hand, has an intercept dummy vari-
self-selection (see Table 3). able for the sons or daughters of household heads as well
as its interactive terms with the other explanatory vari-
ables included in addition.
6. Conclusion
ln wi⫽bXi⫹ei. (A1)
The estimation results from the analysis above ques-
tion the belief that vocational education has been overva-
ln wi⫽bXi⫹ddi⫹g(di∗Xi)⫹ei (A2)
lued and that providing general education to the work-
force followed by on-the-job training would be more where ln wi is log hourly earnings, Xi is a vector of per-
beneficial. After correcting for the possibility of self- sonal characteristics of the individual i, di is a dummy
selection and other factors such as experience, marital variable indicating whether the individual reported being
and migration status, the paper finds that, in Thailand, a son, or a daughter of the household head (di=1) or not
upper secondary vocational education gives statistically (di=0), b, d, and g are the vector of parameters pertaining
higher returns than general education at the same level. to the vectors of explanatory variables to be estimated.
Such results imply vocational education underinvestment To check whether the sons and daughters of household
in Thailand. Furthermore, the findings from the probit heads have different earnings structures from those of
estimation that an individual from a well-to-do family is the general population, we check if the dummy variable
more likely to undertake vocational education suggest di and its interactive terms are statistically significant as
inadequate access. More investment to improve the a group. If they are, the sample of the sons and daughters
access to vocational education could thus prove ben- of the household heads used in the analytical chapters
eficial. Further research into the issue, once a more com- above has earnings structures that are statistically differ-
plete set of data become available, should also provide ent from those of the general population. To check the
more insights. significance of the dummy variable di and its interactive
terms, an F-test could be performed to test the follow-
ing restriction:
Acknowledgements
d⫽g⫽0. (A3)
The paper was written while the authors were at the The sensitivity analysis results suggest that our sample of
University of Melbourne, Australia. The authors wish to the sons and daughters of household heads have earnings
thank Dr Robert Dixon, Dr Lisa Cameron, Dr Lata structures that are statistically different from those of the
Ganghadaran, and Quy Tran for their helpful comments, general population. For both men and women, the F-
suggestions, and assistance. Any error in this paper, how- statistics are larger than the critical value Fcrit.6 Any
ever, is not theirs. inference of the results from the earnings models above
to the general population thus needs to be done cau-
tiously.
Appendix A. Sensitivity analysis determining In any case, although the sensitivity analysis results
whether we can make inferences about the general are not ‘satisfactory’, the paper’s conclusions with
population respect to the relative returns between upper secondary
vocational and upper secondary general education cannot
As mentioned in the analysis above, our sample be completely disregarded. The results of our analysis
exclusion means caution is required when making infer- indeed may remain applicable to the general population
ences to the general population. Although, as mentioned for two reasons.
in Section 2, there are theoretical reasons to believe that First, for both men and women, the parameter esti-
our results with respect to the relative returns to mates of the vocational education dummy variables are
vocational education are at least partly applicable to the found to be positive and significant in both restricted and
general population, for completeness a sensitivity analy- unrestricted models.7 For men, the estimate of the returns
sis needs done to ascertain such applicability. to education in the restricted model in our sensitivity
For our sensitivity analysis, the restricted and unre- analysis is extremely close to that found in the ‘naı̈ve’
stricted earnings models are estimated on the general OLS estimation of the earnings model of Section 3
population sample. The explanatory powers of the corre- above. (See Table 3 for the ‘naı̈ve’ OLS estimate.)
sponding restricted and unrestricted models are then
compared. In our case, a restricted model (see Eq. (A1))
has an identical econometric specification to that of the 6
Fcrit=苲1.976, Male’s F-stat=2.65, Females; F-stat=3.046.
simple Mincer’s earnings model (the ‘naı̈ve OLS’ model 7
Please contact the authors for the complete results.
T. Moenjak, C. Worswick / Economics of Education Review 22 (2003) 99–107 107

Second, for the unrestricted model, for men, the coef- impact of schooling in a developing country. Review of Eco-
ficient estimate of the interactive dummy variable indi- nomics and Statistics, 66, 296–303.
cating if an observation is that of a household head’s Bellew, R., & Moock, P. (1990). Vocational and technical edu-
child with upper secondary vocational education is stat- cation in Peru. Economics of Education Review, 9 (4),
365–375.
istically insignificant. This statistical insignificance
Chiswick, B. R. (1986). Comment on Hauser and Sewell. Jour-
means that the relative returns between upper secondary nal of Labor Economics, 4 (3 (Part 2)), S116–S120.
vocational and upper secondary general education for a Gaston, N., & Sturm, R. (1991). Educational attainment and the
child of the household head are not statistically different returns to education for Australian youth: evidence of self-
from those for the general population. In the case of selection? Economic Analysis and Policy, 21 (1), 29–45.
women, the coefficient estimate of the aforementioned Griliches, Z. (1977). Estimating the returns to schooling: some
interactive dummy variable is statistically significant, but econometric problems. Econometrica, 45, 1–22.
with a negative sign. This means the returns to Heckman, J. J., & Hotz, V. J. (1986). An investigation of the
vocational education for the household head’s daughters labor market earnings of Panamanian males: evaluating the
understate the returns to vocational education for the sources of inequality. Journal of Human Resources, 21,
507–542.
general women population.
Hollenbeck, K. (1993). Postsecondary education as triage:
With the two reasons cited above, it is arguable that returns to academic and technical programs. Economics of
the paper’s conclusion with respect to the relative returns Education Review, 213–232.
to vocational education remains applicable to the general Leibowitz, A. (1974). Home investments in children. Journal
population. Until a more complete set of data becomes of Political Economy, 82 (2), S111–S131.
available for further research, however, the inference of Mincer, J. (1974). Schooling, experience and earnings. New
the coefficient estimates of the from the self-selection York: National Bureau of Economic Research.
corrected earnings models of this paper needs to be Office of the National Education Commission (1997a). Edu-
done cautiously. cation in Thailand 1997. Bangkok, Thailand. Bureau of
Educational System Development and Macro Planning.
Office of the National Education Commission (1997b). The
Eighth National Education Development Plan: 1997–2002.
Bangkok, Thailand: Office of the Prime Minister.
References
Tansel, A. (1994). Wage employment, earnings and returns to
schooling for men and women in Turkey. Economics of
Bedi, A., & Gaston, N. (1997). Returns to endogeneous edu- Education Review, 13, 305–320.
cation: the case of Honduras. Applied Economics, 29, Trost, R. P., & Lee, L. F. (1984). Technical training and earn-
519–528. ings: a polychotomous choice model with selectivity. The
Behrman, J. R., & Wolfe, B. L. (1984). The socioeconomic Review of Economics and Statistics, 66, 151–156.

View publication stats

Potrebbero piacerti anche