Sei sulla pagina 1di 6

Elasticity

Select exercise questions from Chapter 2 & 4

Chapter 2
7. In 2010, Americans smoked 315 billion cigarettes, or 15.75 billion packs of cigarettes. The
average retail price (including taxes) was about $5.00 per pack. Statistical studies have shown
that the price elasticity of demand is −0.4, and the price elasticity of supply is 0.5.
a. Using this information, derive linear demand and supply curves for the cigarette market.
Let the demand curve be of the form Q = a − bP and the supply curve be of the form Q = c + dP,
where a, b, c, and d are positive constants. To begin, recall the formula for the price elasticity of
demand
P Q
EPD = .
Q P
We know the demand elasticity is –0.4, P = 5, and Q = 15.75, which means we can solve for the
slope, −b, which is Q/P in the above formula.
5 Q
−0.4 =
15.75 P
Q  15.75 
= −0.4   = −1.26 = −b.
P  5 
To find the constant a, substitute for Q, P, and b in the demand function to get 15.75 = a −
1.26(5), so a = 22.05. The equation for demand is therefore Q = 22.05 − 1.26P. To find the
supply curve, recall the formula for the elasticity of supply and follow the same method as
above:
P Q
EPS =
Q P
5 Q
0.5 =
15.75 P
Q  15.75 
= 0.5   = 1.575 = d.
P  5 
To find the constant c, substitute for Q, P, and d in the supply function to get 15.75 = c + 1.575(5)
and c = 7.875. The equation for supply is therefore Q = 7.875 + 1.575P.
b. In 1998, Americans smoked 23.5 billion packs cigarettes, and the retail price was about
$2.00 per pack. The decline in cigarette consumption from 1998 to 2010 was due in part to
greater public awareness of the health hazards from smoking, but was also due in part to
the increase in price. Suppose that the entire decline was due to the increase in price. What
could you deduce from that about the price elasticity of demand?
Calculate the arc elasticity of demand since we have a range of prices rather than a single price.
The arc elasticity formula is
Q P
EP =
P Q
where P and Q are average price and quantity, respectively. The change in quantity was
15.75 −23.5 = −7.75, and the change in price was 5 − 2 = 3. The average price was (2 + 5)/2 =
3.50, and the average quantity was (23.5 + 15.75)/2 = 19.625. Therefore, the price elasticity of
demand, assuming that the entire decline in quantity was due solely to the price increase, was
Q P −7.75 3.50
EP = = = −0.46.
P Q 3 19.625

8. In Example 2.8 we examined the effect of a 20% decline in copper demand on the price of
copper, using the linear supply and demand curves developed in Section 2.6. Suppose the long-
run price elasticity of copper demand were −0.75 instead of −0.5.
a. Assuming, as before, that the equilibrium price and quantity are P* = $3 per pound and
Q* = 18 million metric tons per year, derive the linear demand curve consistent with the
smaller elasticity.
Following the method outlined in Section 2.6, solve for a and b in the demand equation
QD = a − bP. Because −b is the slope, we can use −b rather than Q/P in the elasticity
 P*
formula. Therefore, ED = −b   . Here ED = −0.75 (the long-run price elasticity), P* = 3
Q*
and Q* = 18. Solving for b,
3
−0.75 = −b   , or b = 0.75(6) = 4.5.
 18 
To find the intercept, we substitute for b, QD (= Q*), and P (= P*) in the demand equation:
18 = a − 4.5(3), or a = 31.5.
The linear demand equation is therefore
QD = 31.5 − 4.5P.
b. Using this demand curve, recalculate the effect of a 20% decline in copper demand on the
price of copper.
The new demand is 20% below the original (using our convention that quantity demanded is
reduced by 20% at every price); therefore, multiply demand by 0.8 because the new demand is
80% of the original demand:
QD = (0.8)(31.5 − 4.5P) = 25.2 − 3.6P.
Equating this to supply,
25.2 − 3.6P = −9 + 9P, so
P = $2.71.
With the 20% decline in demand, the price of copper falls from $3.00 to $2.71 per pound. The
decrease in demand therefore leads to a drop in price of 29 cents per pound, a 9.7% decline.
9. In Example 2.8 (page 52), we discussed the recent increase in world demand for copper, due in
part to China’s rising consumption.
a. Using the original elasticities of demand and supply (i.e., ES = 1.5 and ED = −0.5), calculate
the effect of a 20% increase in copper demand on the price of copper.
The original demand is Q = 27 − 3P and supply is Q = −9 + 9P as shown on page 51. The
20% increase in demand means that the new demand is 120% of the original demand, so the
new demand is QD = 1.2Q. QD = (1.2)(27 − 3P) = 32.4 − 3.6P. The new equilibrium is where
QD equals the original supply:
32.4 − 3.6P = −9 + 9P.
The new equilibrium price is P* = $3.29 per pound. An increase in demand of 20%, therefore,
entails an increase in price of 29 cents per pound, or 9.7%.
b. Now calculate the effect of this increase in demand on the equilibrium quantity, Q*.
Using the new price of $3.29 in the supply curve, the new equilibrium quantity is Q* = −9 +
9(3.29) = 20.61 million metric tons per year, an increase of 2.61 million metric tons (mmt)
per year. Except for rounding, you get the same result by plugging the new price of $3.29 into
the new demand curve. So an increase in demand of 20% entails an increase in quantity
of 2.61 mmt per year, or 14.5%.
c. As we discussed in Example 2.8, the U.S. production of copper declined between 2000 and
2003. Calculate the effect on the equilibrium price and quantity of both a 20% increase in
copper demand (as you just did in part a) and of a 20% decline in copper supply.
The new supply of copper falls (shifts to the left) to 80% of the original, so QS = 0.8Q =
(0.8)(−9 + 9P) = −7.2 + 7.2P. The new equilibrium is where QD = QS.
32.4 − 3.6P = −7.2 + 7.2P
The new equilibrium price is P* = $3.67 per pound. Plugging this price into the new supply
equation, the new equilibrium quantity is Q* = −7.2 + 7.2(3.67) = 19.22 million metric tons
per year. Except for rounding, you get the same result if you substitute the new price into the
new demand equation. The combined effect of a 20% increase in demand and a 20% decrease
in supply is that price increases by 67 cents per pound, or 22%, and quantity increases by 1.22
mmt per year, or 6.8%, compared to the original equilibrium.
Chapter -4

7. The director of a theater company in a small college town is considering changing the way he
prices tickets. He has hired an economic consulting firm to estimate the demand for tickets.
The firm has classified people who go to the theater into two groups, and has come up with two
demand functions. The demand curves for the general public (Qgp) and students (Q s) are given
below:
Qgp = 500 − 5 P
Qs = 200 − 4 P
a. Graph the two demand curves on one graph, with P on the vertical axis and Q on the
horizontal axis. If the current price of tickets is $35, identify the quantity demanded by
each group.
Both demand curves are downward sloping and linear. For the general public, Dgp, the vertical
intercept is 100 and the horizontal intercept is 500. For the students, Ds, the vertical intercept
is 50 and the horizontal intercept is 200. When the price is $35, the general public demands
Qgp = 500 − 5(35) = 325 tickets and students demand Qs = 200 − 4(35) = 60 tickets.

b. Find the price elasticity of demand for each group at the current price and quantity.
P Q 35
The elasticity for the general public is  gp = = (−5) = −0.54, and the elasticity for
Q P 325
P Q 35
students is  S = = (−4) = −2.33. If the price of tickets increases by 10% then the general
Q P 60
public will demand 5.4% fewer tickets and students will demand 23.3% fewer tickets.
c. Is the director maximizing the revenue he collects from ticket sales by charging $35 for
each ticket? Explain.
No, he is not maximizing revenue because neither of the calculated elasticities is equal to −1.
The general public’s demand is inelastic at the current price. Thus the director could increase the
price for the general public, and the quantity demanded would fall by a smaller percentage,
causing revenue to increase. Since the students’ demand is elastic at the current price, the
director could decrease the price students pay, and their quantity demanded would increase by a
larger amount in percentage terms, causing revenue to increase.
d. What price should he charge each group if he wants to maximize revenue collected from
ticket sales?
To figure this out, use the formula for elasticity, set it equal to −1, and solve for price and
quantity. For the general public:
−5P
 gp = = −1
Q
5P = Q = 500 − 5P
P = 50
Q = 250.
For the students:
−4 P
s = = −1
Q
4 P = Q = 200 − 4 P
P = 25
Q = 100.
These prices generate a larger total revenue than the $35 price. When price is $35, revenue is
(35)(Qgp + Qs) = (35)(325 + 60) = $13,475. With the separate prices, revenue is PgpQgp + PsQs =
(50)(250) + (25)(100) = $15,000, which is an increase of $1525, or 11.3%.

8. Judy has decided to allocate exactly $500 to college textbooks every year, even though she knows
that the prices are likely to increase by 5 to 10% per year and that she will be getting a
substantial monetary gift from her grandparents next year. What is Judy’s price elasticity of
demand for textbooks? Income elasticity?
Judy will spend the same amount ($500) on textbooks even when prices increase. We know that total
revenue (i.e., total spending on a good) remains constant when price changes only if demand is unit
elastic. Therefore Judy’s price elasticity of demand for textbooks is −1. Her income elasticity must
be zero because she does not plan to purchase more books even though she expects a large monetary
gift (i.e., an increase in income).

9. The ACME Corporation determines that at current prices the demand for its computer chips
has a price elasticity of −2 in the short run, while the price elasticity for its disk drives is −1.
a. If the corporation decides to raise the price of both products by 10%, what will happen to
its sales? To its sales revenue?
We know the formula for the elasticity of demand is:
%Q
EP = .
%P
For computer chips, EP = −2, so −2 = %Q/10, and therefore %Q = −2(10) = −20. Thus a
10% increase in price will reduce the quantity sold by 20%. For disk drives, EP = −1, so a 10%
increase in price will reduce sales by 10%.
Sales revenue will decrease for computer chips because demand is elastic and price has increased.
We can estimate the change in revenue as follows. Revenue is equal to price times quantity sold.
Let TR1 = P1Q1 be revenue before the price change and TR2 = P2Q2 be revenue after the price
change. Therefore
TR = P2Q2 − P1Q1
TR = (1.1P1 )(0.8Q1) − P1Q1 = −0.12P1Q1, or a 12% decline.
Sales revenue for disk drives will remain unchanged because demand elasticity is −1.
b. Can you tell from the available information which product will generate the most revenue?
If yes, why? If not, what additional information do you need?
No. Although we know the elasticities of demand, we do not know the prices or quantities sold, so we
cannot calculate the revenue for either product. We need to know the prices of chips and disk drives and
how many of each ACME sells

12. You run a small business and would like to predict what will happen to the quantity demanded
for your product if you raise your price. While you do not know the exact demand curve for
your product, you do know that in the first year you charged $45 and sold 1200 units and that
in the second year you charged $30 and sold 1800 units.
a. If you plan to raise your price by 10%, what would be a reasonable estimate of what will
happen to quantity demanded in percentage terms?
We must first find the price elasticity of demand. Because the price and quantity changes are
large in percentage terms, it is best to use the arc elasticity measure. EP = (Q/P) 
(average P/average Q) = (600/−15)  (37.50/1500) = −1. With an elasticity of −1, a 10%
increase in price will lead to a 10% decrease in quantity.
b. If you raise your price by 10%, will revenue increase or decrease?
When elasticity is −1, revenue will remain constant if price is increased.

15. Suppose that you are the consultant to an agricultural cooperative that is deciding whether
members should cut their production of cotton in half next year. The cooperative wants your
advice as to whether this action will increase members’ revenues. Knowing that cotton (C) and
soybeans (S) both compete for agricultural land in the South, you estimate the demand for cotton
to be C = 3.5 − 1.0PC + 0.25PS + 0.50I, where PC is the price of cotton, PS the price of soybeans,
and I income. Should you support or oppose the plan? Is there any additional information that
would help you to provide a definitive answer?
If production of cotton is cut in half, then the price of cotton will increase, given that the equation above
shows that demand is downward sloping (since the sign on PC is negative). With price increasing and
quantity demanded decreasing, revenue could go either way. It depends on whether demand is elastic
or inelastic. If demand is elastic, a decrease in production and an increase in price would decrease
revenue. If demand is inelastic, a decrease in production and an increase in price would increase revenue.
You need a lot of information before you can give a definitive answer. First, you must know the current
prices for cotton and soybeans plus the level of income; then you can calculate the quantity of cotton
demanded, C. Next, you have to cut C in half and determine the effect that will have on the price of
cotton, assuming that income and the price of soybeans are not affected (which is a big assumption).
Then you can calculate the original revenue and the new revenue to see whether this action increases
members’ revenues or not.

Potrebbero piacerti anche