Sei sulla pagina 1di 28

Journal of International Business Studies (2019)

ª 2019 Academy of International Business All rights reserved 0047-2506/19


www.jibs.net

Understanding the structural characteristics


of a firm’s whole buyer–supplier network
and its impact on international business
performance

Amalesh Sharma1, Abstract


Building on the network theory and the concept of organizational
V. Kumar2,3,4,5, Jun Yan6, ambidexterity, we investigate the impact of structural characteristics of a
Sourav Bikash Borah7 and firm’s whole buyer–supplier network: network density, betweenness
Anirban Adhikary8 centralization, and average clustering coefficient on its international business
(IB) performance. We also explore the moderating roles of average path length
1
Mays Business School, Texas A&M University, and PageRank centrality. Using a manually-collected dataset and a robust
College Station, TX 77843, USA; 2 Center for empirical methodology, we find that, while network density is negatively
Excellence in Brand and Customer Management, J. related, betweenness centralization and average clustering coefficient have an
Mack Robinson College of Business, Georgia State inverted U-shape and a U-shaped relationship with IB performance,
University, Atlanta, GA, USA; 3 HUST, Wuhan, respectively. We also find significant moderation effects, and, in the process,
Hubei, China; 4 Hagler Institute for Advanced we show the economic importance of firms’ whole buyer–supplier network to
Study, Texas A&M University, College Station, TX,
their IB performance. We contribute to the international business and whole
USA; 5 Indian School of Business, Hyderabad,
India; 6 Management School, Huazhong
buyer–supplier network literature.
University of Science and Technology, Wuhan, Journal of International Business Studies (2019).
China; 7 Indian Institute of Management https://doi.org/10.1057/s41267-019-00215-x
Ahmedabad, Ahmedabad, India; 8 Indian Institute
of Management Udaipur, Udaipur, India
Keywords: whole buyer–supplier network; international business performance; am-
bidexterity; network structure; curvilinear relationship
Correspondence:
J Yan, Management School, Huazhong
University of Science and Technology,
Wuhan, China. INTRODUCTION
Tel: 0086-27-8754-2754; Achieving success in international markets predominantly depends
e-mail: yanjun@mail.hust.edu.cn
on the exploitation of existing firm-specific advantages (FSAs) and
the development of new FSAs that can be exploited in the future
(Vahlne & Jonsson, 2017b). FSAs include assets such as: privileged
access to raw material, technology, and brands; superior gover-
nance structure; a distribution channel; and an organizational
culture. Consequently, scholars argue that firms must be able to
Electronic supplementary mate-
explore and exploit (ambidexterity) FSAs in international markets
rial The online version of this article (Luo & Rui, 2009) to achieve profitability (Vahlne & Jonsson,
(https://doi.org/10.1057/s41267-019-00215- 2017b). Drawing from the literature on organizational learning,
x) contains supplementary material, which is this stream of research shows that tilting towards either exploration
available to authorized users.
or exploitation creates challenges for profitability and growth. For
Received: 15 September 2017
Revised: 24 October 2018 example, by relying on exploration, Volvo in 1999 could create
Accepted: 10 November 2018 new innovations and add new customer segments. However,
Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

profitability declined due to the lack of exploita- multi-tier relationships results in a unique structure
tion. Similarly, Nokia gained high levels of prof- (a whole network2) consisting of a complex inter-
itability due to exploitation, but the lack of play between direct and indirect, voluntary and
exploration created significant challenges for the involuntary, and home country and foreign coun-
firm (Kortmann, Gelhard, Zimmermann, & Piller, try relationships. Concentrating on an ego-centric
2014). On the other hand, IKEA has remained view may be problematic as lower-tier suppliers are
profitable in international markets by embracing critical for the exploitation of existing FSAs and the
ambidexterity (Vahlne & Jonsson, 2017b). development of new FSAs (Borgatti & Li, 2009;
To achieve ambidexterity, MNEs rely on a net- Kano, 2017). Conversely, however, lower-tier sup-
work of relationships. Recent developments in the pliers may also engage in opportunistic behavior,
Uppsala internationalization model suggest that, to hindering a firm’s IBP (Obloj & Zemsky, 2015).
achieve success in international markets, a firm Therefore, considering the whole network perspec-
must be a part of a relevant network, otherwise it tive may challenge the conventional findings based
suffers from liability of outsidership (Johanson & on an ego-centric view. Third, while the Uppsala
Vahlne, 2009). International business performance model has been extended to explain IBP, the model
(IBP)1 of a firm depends not only on managerial focuses only on a firm’s position in the network
intent but also on the actions taken by other (Johanson & Vahlne, 2009; Vahlne & Johanson,
network members (Vahlne & Jonsson, 2017b). 2017a). While the firm position may allow the firm
Networks provide firms with opportunities to to gain access to knowledge and information in IB
exploit FSAs and develop new FSAs (Coviello, operations, exploration and exploitation require
2006). Among multiple relationships that a firm collaboration from all network members (Vahlne &
establishes, those formed with buyers and suppliers Jonsson, 2017b). Therefore, in addition to position,
are of especially high importance due to their long- the structure of the network is critical in facilitating
term nature and the repeated interactions involv- such collaborations. Additionally, the structure of
ing multiple firms, leading to greater commitment, the network is vital because a firm cannot apply
trust building, and knowledge accumulation selection rules in a whole BSR network (Kano,
(Kotabe, Martin, & Domoto, 2003). These benefits 2017). As a firm cannot control who enters the
of a buyers–suppliers (BSR) network may help firms network, the only way to benefit from the network
not only exploit current FSAs but also develop new is to control the structure.
FSAs (Johanson & Vahlne, 2009). While the Upp- Finally, due to the nature of multi-tier relation-
sala model acknowledges the role of BSR relation- ships and in particular involuntary relationships, as
ships in facilitating ambidexterity and subsequent well as the inherent power dynamics of BSR
performance in international markets (Vahlne & networks, firms suffer from information overload
Jonsson, 2017b), we know very little about the and power asymmetries (Ireland & Webb, 2007)
structure of the BSR networks which may facilitate which may hinder a firm’s ability to exploit exist-
IBP, and which is in the firm’s best interest to ing FSAs and explore new FSAs. Firms need strategic
establish. Specifically, research in this domain levers to overcome such overload and asymmetries.
suffers from four major limitations. Given the research linking network position to
First, research in IB has focused on alliances performance (Johanson & Vahlne, 2009) and the
rather than BSR networks. Although important, research linking a structural element such as
alliances in international markets are highly unsta- network reach (Schilling & Phelps, 2007) to the
ble (Bello, Katsikeas, & Robson, 2010), and firm effect of network structure, it is important to
performance decreases with an increase in geo- integrate structural elements with positional ele-
graphical dispersion and the size of the alliance ments in the literature to provide a holistic under-
portfolio (Bos, Faems, & Noseleit, 2017). To under- standing. While doing so, we must also focus on
stand IBP of a firm from the network perspective, one the challenges associated with a comprehensive
must concentrate on unique and long-term inter- BSR network and how firm position and network
organizational relationships, such as BSR networks reach may mitigate such challenges. These ele-
which are more stable and can help a firm achieve ments, among others, serve as strategic levers for
ambidexterity (Aoki & Wilhelm, 2017, Im & Rai, managing a network.
2008). Second, extant IB literature lacks research on Building on the existing research gaps as dis-
multi-tier relationships and considers only a firm’s cussed above, this study attempts to answer two
direct connections (ego network). Consideration of research questions: First, what is the relationship

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

between the structural characteristics of a firm’s These two strategic levers may help a firm mitigate
whole BSR network3 and its IBP? And second, how challenges of information overload and power
does a firm’s position in the network and network asymmetries (see Table 1 for the research gap and
reach moderate these relationships? the unique contributions of our study).
Drawing on the network theory (Borgatti & Halgin, We use whole BSR network data for 303 firms
2011) and the organizational ambidexterity perspec- spanning from 2013 to 2015, from 50 different
tive (March, 1991), we attempt to answer these industries, and expanding across 28 different coun-
questions. Specifically, we explore the impact of tries. We then estimate a random-effects regression
three key structural characteristics critical to under- model accounting for potential endogeneity in the
standing the architecture of a firm’s whole buyer– three focal variables, time, and geography fixed
supplier network: network density (measures the effects. We make multiple contributions to theory4
degree of interconnectedness between network mem- and practice. We contribute to three streams of
bers), betweenness centralization (measures the num- literature. First, we contribute to the domain of the
ber of information gatekeepers in the network), and Uppsala model. By delving deeper into structure,
average clustering coefficient (measures the cliquish- we highlight that merely being part of a network is
ness of the network) on a firm’s IBP (Bellamy & not adequate and only certain types of networks
Basole, 2013). In addition, we focus on two strate- can lead to success in international markets.
gic levers: PageRank centrality that indicates the Second, we contribute to the BSR network in
status or influence of the focal firm in the network international business by demonstrating that the
and average path length that captures the reach (or interplay between structure and position, along
distance) between one member and the others. with different structural elements, is a recipe for

Table 1 Network theory-representative empirical literature

Study Level of Network variable Type of Industry Data Methodological concerns


analysis relationship
Endogeneity Heterogeneity
b
Schilling & Ego Clustering coefficient , average Linear High US No Yes
Phelps path lengthb Technology,
(2007)a Manufacturing
Bellamy et al. Ego Network densityb, average path Linear Electronics US Yes Yes
(2014) lengthb
Fang et al. Ego Closeness, betweenness Linear CPG US Yes No
(2016) centrality, average path lengthb
Thomaz & Ego Average path lengthb Curvilinear Electronics, US No No
Swaminathan Software,
(2015) Telecom &
Power
Swaminathan Ego Average path lengthb, Centrality Curvilinear Computer US No No
& Moorman Software
(2009)
Oehme & Ego Network centrality Linear Biotechnology Germany No No
Bort (2015)
Grewal et al. Ego Degree, eigenvector, and Curvilinear Open source US No Yes
(2006) betweenness centrality projects
Chakravarty Ego Buyer–supplier concentration Linear Electronic US Yes Yes
et al. (2014)
This Study Whole Network density, betweenness Curvilinear 50 industries 28 Yes Yes
centralization, average countries
clustering coefficient, average
path length, PageRank centrality
a
While this paper captures network structure at industry level, there are many disconnected firms with single connection which do not capture the
whole network of those firms.
b
Although some studies have calculated network density and clustering coefficient in the context of a network, the calculations are biased and do not
adequately represent whole networks. Purely from a theoretical standpoint, such conceptualization may not be appropriate as it applies whole network
properties but calculates the same at an ego-centric level.

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

success in international business. Finally, we con- However, it is not clear whether or not such
tribute to network research by highlighting that indirect connections are insiders. To understand
while theorizing about networks, one must focus all of these various facets, we focus on a specific
on the type of networks (alliances, buyer–supplier, type of network – the whole BSR network.5
interpersonal, etc.) and level of relationship (whole Long-term BSR networks play a vital role in
vs. ego), as well as on different elements in the facilitating ambidexterity (Johanson & Vahlne,
network. We offer three practical directions to 2009; Martin, Swaminathan, & Mitchell, 1998).
managers as discussed in a later section. Firms’ supply chains help achieve ‘‘structural sep-
aration’’, as supply chains consist of loosely con-
nected subsystems (Kristal et al., 2010). The
THEORETICAL BACKGROUND inherent tension between exploration and exploita-
AND HYPOTHESIS DEVELOPMENT tion at a subsystem level is mitigated by the
synergies achieved at the system level (Kristal
Uppsala model and Organizational Learning:
et al., 2010). Through an ambidextrous supply
Network Theoretic View
chain, a firm can achieve capabilities vital in
Research on the Uppsala model was first published
environments characterized by demand, competi-
in 1977 (Johanson & Vahlne, 1977). The model,
tion, and technological uncertainties (Patel, Terje-
which was initially conceptualized to understand
sen, & Li, 2012), such as those existing in
the internationalization of firms, has now been
international markets (Werner, Brouthers, &
extended to focus on explaining performance in
Brouthers, 1996). The Uppsala model argues that,
international markets (Vahlne & Johanson, 2017a).
since knowledge exploration and exploitation take
The model highlights that networks provide firms
place under uncertain conditions in international
with knowledge and resources to exploit existing
markets (Forsgren, 2016), whole BSR networks that
FSAs and develop new FSAs in international mar-
determine success in international markets are of
kets. Ambidexterity is achieved through commit-
special importance.
ment and knowledge-development processes which
We employ the lens of network theory. Network
eventually affect performance (Vahlne & Johanson,
theory focuses on suppliers’ actions within an
2017a).
ongoing pattern of exchange relationships and
Through the changes in commitment and knowl-
contends that such actions can be rationalized by
edge development processes, a firm develops a new
economic as well as non-economic motives of
bundle of resources which act as FSAs. Developed
suppliers (e.g., power and position within the
FSAs can be exploited through networks of host–
network) (Granovetter, 2005, Gulati, 1998; Kim,
country and home–country relationships (Rugman
2014). Network theory emphasizes two distinct
& Verbeke, 2001) and the interactions between
dimensions: flow and bond (Borgatti & Halgin,
different home countries and host-country network
2011). In the context of the Uppsala model,
members (Iurkov & Benito, 2017). Although the
scholars have primarily dealt with the dimension
evolution of the Uppsala model brings out novel
of flow (Forsgren, 2016), which can be understood
ideas by integrating networks, ambidexterity, and
in relation to the theory of structural holes (Burt,
performance, subsequent scholars argue that net-
2009). The theory of structural holes suggests that,
work structure plays a vital role in determining a
if a firm is connected to other firms which are not
firm’s ability to explore and exploit (Forsgren,
connected to each other, it can receive non-redun-
2016). As exploration and exploitations are at
dant information which can help in building
loggerheads (March, 1991), certain network struc-
exploration capabilities (Rowley, Behrens, & Krack-
tures may facilitate one over the other. Such
hardt, 2000). Another opposing view suggests that
imbalance creates challenges for ambidexterity
a focal firm must create a dense network that
and subsequent performance (Forsgren, 2016). In
hinders opportunistic behavior and provides a
addition, another challenge that the model faces is
better quality of information (Patel, Fernhaber,
the assumption that all business relationships are
McDougall-Covin, & van der Have, 2014). Such
the same and all network members are insiders,
dense networks may be vital in creating norms,
which is not true in real life. Again, it is important
trust, and behavioral patterns that enhance faster
to understand that the focal firm’s indirect con-
and superior transfers of knowledge and curtail
nections may affect exploration and exploitation
opportunism (Iurkov & Benito, 2017). The bond
(Granovetter, 2005), which in turn affects IBP.
dimension looks at the role that power plays in the

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

network (Borgatti & Halgin, 2011). Contrary to the exploitations and explorations of FSAs may suffer
flow dimension, bond primarily focuses on how a due to less powerful players’ arms length relation-
firm within a given network can coordinate ships with the focal firm (Khoja, Adams, & Kauff-
between others in that same network, increasing man, 2011). Finally, the opportunistic behavior of
benefits for the orchestrating firm (Borgatti & lower-tier suppliers and the non-contractual nature
Halgain, 2011). While the flow dimension will of the relationships beyond Tier1 may cause coordi-
indicate how network structure can facilitate nation challenges and pose a grave threat to a firm’s
ambidexterity in IB contexts, the bond dimension pursuit of ambidexterity, and subsequently IBP
will highlight how a firm can orchestrate that flow. (Kano, 2017; Verbeke, 2003). As firms lack capabil-
To understand how BSR network structure can ities to directly monitor, select, and manage the
facilitate exploration and exploitation of FSAs, one whole BSR network, scholars propose to explore the
would need to integrate flow and bond perspectives, structure of a BSR network that may mitigate some of
as there are challenges specific to each dimension these concerns to help achieve ambidexterity and
which may hinder or facilitate ambidexterity (Jo- subsequently IBP (Chandra & Wilkinson, 2017).
hanson & Vahlne, 2009; Martin, Swaminathan, & Therefore, while theorizing, we take into consider-
Mitchell, 1998). First, multi-tier BSR networks may ation the challenges of the BSR network and inte-
prevent firms from employing selection criteria grate these challenges with the ambidexterity and
beyond their direct suppliers (Tier1) and achieving performance literature.
strategic objectives of exploration and exploitation
(Kano, 2017); hence, opportunistic behavior con- Selection of Network Variables
cerns are more prevalent in such a network (Laz- Our selection of network variables is based on several
zarini, Claro, & Mesquita, 2008). Such opportunistic criteria. As our study is network-based, it is important
behavior may lead to the lack of knowledge sharing to identify constructs which define a network com-
(Ernst & Kim, 2002) and pose challenges for recon- pletely. We explore multiple disciplines including
figuration (Borgatti & Li, 2009). Second, the globally social sciences, biology, and physics which have done
dispersed nature of the BSR networks with dissimilar a great deal of work in this domain. Such research has
technology and cultures creates information over- shown that network density (ND), betweenness cen-
load for the focal firm (Lu & Shang, 2017; Villena, tralization (BC), and average clustering coefficient
Revilla, & Choi, 2011). As a focal firm is bounded (CC) are three fundamental elements which describe
rational, information overload may create a dys- the structure of a network (Dong & Horvath, 2007).
functional supply chain as the organization tends to These elements not only signify the tradeoffs in a
focus on some pieces of information while neglect- network (Provan, Fish, & Sydow, 2007) but also
ing others. This may reduce organizations’ pursuit of highlight how edges have combined to create a
ambidexterity (Simsek, 2009). The lack of focus on network (Kaiser & Hilgetag, 2004). Without under-
the entire spectrum of opportunities will hinder standing this important aspect, one would have to
exploitation. Further, information overload presents alter the analysis as different graphs would make
coordination challenges which may deteriorate different assumptions for the error term (Stadtfeld,
resource commitment and hinder exploitation (Rug- 2012). Thus, theorizing for networks, our measures
man & Verbeke, 2003). In IB, coordination issues indicate both completeness and high predictability.
lead firms to concentrate on less uncertain markets Second, we are interested in how network structure
and create FSAs which are difficult to exploit beyond can provide firms with resources for the development
proximate geographical regions (Guler & Guillen, and exploitation of FSAs. These variables are essential
2010). Third, a skewed focus on a few partners would from an ambidexterity perspective. Extant literature
restrict learning from and about other partners. has shown that ND (by differentially affecting speed
Fourth, the inherent power asymmetry in BSR net- and access to knowledge; Rowley, Behrens, & Krack-
works (Ireland & Webb, 2007) leads bounded hardt, 2000), BC (by facilitating or hindering the focal
rational firms to focus on a narrow set of dominant firm’s access to knowledge; Bellamy & Basole, 2013),
network members, creating redundancy of knowl- and CC (due to homogeneity within clusters and
edge (Jean, Kim, & Sinkovics, 2012; Yli-Renko & heterogeneity across clusters; Schilling & Phelps,
Janakiraman, 2008), challenges for knowledge 2007) will affect exploration and exploitation. There-
reconfiguration, and increased chances of retaliation fore, the selection of our independent variables is
from suppliers due to trust issues (Ireland & Webb, based on network theory and ambidexterity
2007). Mutual commitments required for perspectives.

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

The moderators selected are also based on mul- information. Again, opportunism can only be cur-
tiple criteria. First, both average path length (a tailed if there are shared norms between network
network level property; Lazer & Friedman, 2007) members, and if such norms are enforceable (Cole-
and PageRank centrality (a node level property; man, 2000). However, BSR networks may not offer
Iurkov & Benito, 2017) have been shown to affect these situations. First, as we move from a firm’s
exploitation as well as exploration of FSAs. Second, direct connections (ego) to non-contractual Tier 2
these two moderators are especially significant in suppliers, there is a lack of consensus about goals a
the BSR network context. Prior research has shown focal firm aspires to achieve in the long run (Lee,
that these moderators help in mitigating concerns Klassen, Furlan, & Vinelli, 2014). Therefore, devel-
associated with bounded rationality and oppor- oping common norms for suppliers across tiers may
tunistic behavior (Li, 2014; Gnyawali & Madhavan, be problematic. Similarly, increased ND restricts
2001), which are two important challenges associ- norms enforcement, facilitating unionizations as
ated with a whole BSR network. Third, the Uppsala predicted by bond dimension (Borgatti & Li, 2009).
model focuses on network position as a central Second, power dynamics may lead to non-sharing
driver of performance (Vahlne & Jonsson, 2017a). of information by the lower-tier suppliers. This
Therefore, PageRank centrality, a measure of net- issue is enhanced as suppliers may also be the firm’s
work position, helps us integrate our work with the upstream competitor (Tsai, 2002). Therefore, while
existing scholarship. Again, those who critique the extant literature in IB may provide multiple advan-
Uppsala model argue that a firm’s outsidership is tages of ND, firms may not realize such benefits
related to the distance between the current position within the context of whole BSR networks.
and a relevant network (Forsgren, 2016). Therefore, From an IB perspective, high density creates
average path length would shed light on this multiple challenges. First, increases in ND can lead
aspect. to information overload because there are multiple
paths passing through each partner, as well as
Hypothesis Development through the focal firm. Such information overload
is detrimental to knowledge reconfiguration and
Network density (ND) coordination (Simsek, 2009). An increase in infor-
Network density signifies the depth of connections mation overload would lead a firm to focus on less
between network partners or the degree of inter- uncertain markets and create FSAs which are diffi-
connectedness between network members (Provan cult to exploit beyond a narrow set of markets
et al., 2007; Rowley et al., 2000). While scholars in (Iurkov & Benito, 2017). Increases in ND negatively
IB present a rosy view of ND (Ahuja, 2000; Bellamy, affect exploration, as the problem of information
Ghosh, & Hora, 2014), we argue that, as firms move overload will lead a firm to focus only on certain
from an ego to a whole network and from alliances knowledge and information (Gargiulo, Ertug, &
to BSR networks, such arguments need further Galunic, 2009), which is detrimental for the dis-
reconsideration. Common benefits cited in the covery of new knowledge in international markets
literature are that high density helps a firm exploit (Iurkov & Benito, 2017). Therefore, ND should also
FSAs as it reduces opportunistic behavior and negatively affect knowledge development
minimizes coordination and administration costs processes.
and operating overheads (Kano, 2017). High ND Second, there are inherent power dynamics in
enhances the speed and richness of information BSR networks (Ireland & Webb, 2007), as lower-tier
exchange (Iurkov & Benito, 2017), facilitates trust suppliers (such as those in Tier 2) lack their own
and reputation, builds richer collaboration and FSAs, making them the most vulnerable in the
resource pooling, and introduces mechanisms of network (Ernst & Kim, 2002). These vulnerable
joint problem solving which facilitate the creation partners are particularly resistant to changes, and
of future FSAs (Ahuja, 2000; Bellamy et al., 2014). such vulnerability may hamper trust and commit-
However, these benefits of ND are not guaranteed, ment in a relationship (Vahlne & Jonsson, 2017b).
and extant literature suggests that it can only Higher levels of interactions due to high ND create
facilitate information and knowledge flow in cer- the unionization of lower-tier suppliers (Lee et al.,
tain situations (Coleman, 2000). For example, to 2014) which are detrimental to coordination (as
receive the benefit of the speed of information flow, suppliers may negotiate as a group) and exploita-
members in the network should not only have tion of FSAs. Increases in ND make removal of weak
information but also be willing to share that network links problematic (Lee et al., 2014), raising

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

challenges for the reconfiguration and exploitation power between themselves, and the focal firm will
of FSAs in international markets. Finally, increases become dependent on these gatekeepers for infor-
in ND hinder a firm’s ability to access novel mation (Provan et al., 2007). This would reduce the
information (Rowley et al., 2000), as a result focal firm’s ability to reconfigure and coordinate.
reducing the firm’s exploration capabilities (Rowley Reconfiguration is hindered because powerful
et al., 2000). As an increase in ND undermines a information gatekeepers will resist any attempt to
firm’s ability to exploit existing FSAs and develop- change the value chain that would adversely affect
ment of new FSAs, it should reduce a firm’s IBP. their position. Again, coordination becomes prob-
Hence, we hypothesize that lematic as the focal firm may not have any collab-
orative relationships with lower-tier suppliers.
Hypothesis 1: Network density is negatively
Networks with high BCs would lead to a dysfunc-
related to a firm’s international business
tional supply chain as the vulnerable lower-tier
performance.
suppliers may reduce their commitment to the
relationship (Kano, 2017). Without such commit-
Betweenness centralization (BC) ments, lower-tier suppliers are free to act oppor-
Betweenness centralization refers to the number of tunistically, which may hinder both exploration
firms that have the potential to control the flow of and exploitation of FSAs. Research in internation-
information (i.e., information gatekeepers) between alization shows that the lack of commitment by
network members (Bellamy & Basole, 2013). A firm is network members hinders future FSA development
considered to be more central if it falls between other and the efficient exploitation of existing FSAs
members of the network. In a network with low BC, (Vahlne & Jonsson, 2017b). Finally, as a bounded
many firms have the ability to control the flow of rational focal firm routinizes its filters toward a few
information, whereas, in networks with high BC, powerful members (Simsek, 2009), it may nega-
only a few firms are capable. tively affect ambidexterity due to the focus on only
Prior literature in IB documents the role of a few players. As BC initially increases and then
information gatekeepers (Spencer, 2003). Conse- reduces exploration and exploitation beyond a
quently, scholars have argued that information certain point, we hypothesize:
gatekeepers act as a conduit of knowledge flow Hypothesis 2: There is an inverted U-shaped
(Spencer, 2003). By virtue of occupying gatekeeping relationship between betweenness centralization
positions, these firms may apply, filter, and reframe and a firm’s international business performance.
knowledge as it passes from suppliers to the focal
firm (Kim & Park, 2010). In a whole BSR network,
there can be multiple gatekeepers (Kim, Choi, Yan, Average clustering coefficient (CC)
& Dooley, 2011), and they may also even lie in the Average clustering coefficient highlights the degree
lower tier (supplier’s suppliers) (Yan, Choi, Kim, & to which nodes in a network are clustered together
Yang, 2015). These suppliers bring in diverse infor- (Basole, 2016). With increases in CC, a firm derives
mation which enhances the exploration capability the benefits of quality, speed, the likelihood of
of the focal firm (Yan et al., 2015). Again, with the information access, and the depth of information
increase in BC, firms derive the benefits of integra- through redundancy within clusters, as well as
tion and coordination (Provan & Milward, 1995), novelty of information (through sparse connec-
positively affecting exploitation and exploration of tions) across clusters (Schilling & Phelps, 2007).
FSAs. An increase in BC reduces information over- Extant IB literature emphasizes that clusters help
load concerns as the network gatekeepers act as the exploitation and the exploration of resources in
conduit of knowledge (Spencer, 2003). Decreases in international markets (Rugman & Verbeke, 2003;
information overload will increase capabilities to Iurkov & Benito, 2017). Clusters provide the ben-
exploit current FSAs and the development of new efits of non-location-bound FSAs (technological
FSAs, enhancing IBP (Kano, 2017). advantage) that enhance a firm’s exploitation
However, an increase in BC beyond a point may capabilities (Banalieva & Dhanaraj, 2013). Simi-
be detrimental to both exploration and exploita- larly, with an increase in between-cluster hetero-
tion, as it alters the power dynamics within a geneity, a focal firm gets access to diverse
network. From an exploitation perspective, gate- knowledge which enhances exploration capabilities
keepers will emerge as leaders and try to maintain (Schilling & Phelps, 2007).

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

Initially, with the creation of clusters, a focal firm accesses information from distant network mem-
has to deal with a group of unionized suppliers bers and develops FSAs through joint efforts with
which would change the power dynamics within network members, it is important to understand
the network. As previously argued, the unioniza- how reach between these network members may
tion of lower-tier suppliers (which is possible create challenges or facilitate exploration and
within clusters because of high connectivity exploitation. Since, from the knowledge flow per-
between network members) can give rise to oppor- spective, reaching each network member is essen-
tunistic behavior, hindering knowledge develop- tial for the development of FSAs, we consider
ment. This would create challenges for the average path length (AP) as a moderator in our study.
development of new FSAs. Apart from power Further, it is important to understand how a firm
asymmetry, clusters may also be a source of can balance asymmetric power structure in a net-
conflict. Clusters are formed with different strategic work. Consistently, we look at PageRank Centrality
objectives and may even compete with each other (captures the focal firm’s status/position) as
(Lorenzen & Mudambi, 2012). Conflicts due to another moderator in our study. Status may be a
competition between clusters would present chal- source of power for the focal firm (Yang, Lin, & Lin,
lenges for coordination, reconfiguration, and rela- 2010), but it also helps balance power exerted by
tionship development between network members, others (Thye, 2000). Balancing power would essen-
hindering exploration and exploitation and nega- tially help achieve ambidexterity and subsequent
tively affecting IBP. As a result of such conflicts, performance in international markets.
exploration would be hindered as a firm’s access to
heterogeneous knowledge across clusters would Average path length (AP)
diminish (Schilling & Phelps, 2007). Managing Average path length reflects the reach or accessibil-
such conflicts also requires managers to invest vital ity between one firm and others in the BSR
cognitive resources, creating further challenges for network. In the context of IB, reach influences
MNEs operating in markets with high uncertainty propensity to explore new opportunities (Ellis,
(Provan & Skinner, 1989). 2011). Information can travel faster from one node
However, increases in CC beyond a certain point to another if the network has a shorter AP which
will introduce many powerful clusters which will not only impacts likelihood, speed, and integrity of
reduce the power asymmetry within the network. knowledge between firms but also shows how
Once the power in the network is evenly dis- robust and responsive the network is. Prior schol-
tributed, firms can derive the benefit of knowledge ars, however, argue that shorter path length may
development. As there are dense ties within clus- not be effective while exploring opportunities
ters, the repeated interaction will facilitate trust (Lazer & Friedman, 2007). Therefore, from a flow
and build collaboration essential for the develop- perspective, one would need to keep the network
ment of new FSAs (Philips, Lawrence, & Hardy, characteristics in mind while making an assertion
2000), which can be exploited in international about the role of AP.
markets. As CC negatively affects exploration and With increases in AP, nodes become more distant
exploitation initially and then facilitates the same, from one another (Kenis & Knoke, 2002). As a
we hypothesize: result, firms that lie on the periphery remain
isolated, creating challenges of information over-
Hypothesis 3: There is a U-shaped relationship load (Li, 2014). As a result, coordination between
between the average clustering coefficient and a lower-tier members becomes problematic, exploita-
firm’s international business performance. tion becomes hindered, and knowledge reconfigu-
ration becomes limited, meaning that firms need to
invest considerable time and effort to manage such
Moderators
relationships (Iurkov & Benito, 2017). Again, as an
While explaining the relationship between whole
increase in AP makes peripheral members more and
BSR network characteristics and IBP, we argued
more isolated from the focal firm, it will boost
how a firm’s ability to achieve ambidexterity
opportunistic behavior detrimental to the exploita-
through network structure drives its IBP. In doing
tion of existing FSAs and the development of new
so, we focus on concerns associated with informa-
FSAs (Kenis & Knoke, 2002). Finally, exploration
tion overload and power asymmetry which may be
becomes problematic as these isolated suppliers
detrimental to achieving ambidexterity. As a firm
may not form collaborative relationships with

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

other network members. Such concerns are more international markets, which would also help in
prominent in networks with high ND, which the identification and exploitation of existing FSAs.
already suffer from information overload issues As an increase in AP helps exploration and exploita-
with numerous direct and indirect connections tion for networks with high CC, this would posi-
(Uzzi, 1997). Therefore, increases in AP will further tively affect IBP. Hence, we hypothesize:
increase the negative effects of high ND on IBP.
Hypothesis 4c: Average path length positively
Hence, we hypothesize:
moderates the relationship between average
Hypothesis 4a: Average path length negatively clustering coefficient and a firm’s international
moderates the relationship between network business performance.
density and a firm’s international business
performance.
PageRank centrality (PC)
High BC implies that certain firms occupy posi- PageRank centrality refers to the position/status or
tions of power in the network that leads to reputation of the focal firm in the network. The PC
increases in non-reciprocity of lower-tier suppliers of a firm is vital in ripping the benefits from the
(Tsai, 2002). A network with high BC would further network to which it belongs. PC signifies the
suffer from increases in AP. An increase in AP makes influence of the focal firm over other nodes in the
peripheral members more and more isolated from network (Kumar & Jan, 2014). A node is considered
the focal firm, which is detrimental to the exploita- to be of high status if it is connected to others
tion of existing FSAs and the development of new which are also influential (Kukkala, Saini, & Iyen-
FSAs (Kenis & Knoke, 2002). The lack of collabora- gar, 2016). However, PC also takes into considera-
tion with lower-tier suppliers will reduce knowl- tion a firm’s indirect relationships. It penalizes
edge development capabilities, hindering distant connections and assumes that a node is
exploration. Additionally, exploitation is hindered, important if it is connected to other important
as coordination between these distant connections nodes, and also if those important nodes do not
becomes more challenging with an increase in AP. have any significant connections. Hence, PC mea-
Similarly, as isolated lower-tier suppliers may sures the status of actors in terms of popularity,
engage in opportunistic behavior, recombination brokerage power, prestige, and approachability
of knowledge may become considerably hindered. (Kumar & Jan, 2014). Consequently, a focal firm
Hence, we hypothesize: with high network status may enjoy the fruits of
Hypothesis 4b: Average path length negatively both exploration and exploitation (Zaheer, Gözü-
moderates the relationship between betweenness büyük, & Milanov, 2010).
centralization and a firm’s international business High PC can reduce the negative effect of ND on
performance. IBP for multiple reasons. First, network status can
reduce both imbalances of power (Thye, 2000) and
Contrary to ND and BC, an increase in AP is opportunistic behavior (Gnyawali & Madhavan,
beneficial for networks with high CC. Heterogene- 2001). By virtue of occupying a higher status, a
ity between clusters provides firms with the unique focal firm may provoke retaliation if others in the
knowledge and resources essential for exploration. network are not behaving according to the rules of
With shorter AP, there will be intense connectivity the game (Yang et al., 2010). Balancing the power
between network members, which may lead to the within the network would assist in reconfiguration
sharing of common rather than novel information as well as knowledge development, and conse-
across clusters. This common information will be of quently can help a firm successfully exploit current
no help for the focal firm for exploration and FSAs and develop future FSAs. Second, high status
creation of new FSAs (Uzzi & Spiro, 2005). Again, facilitates finding partners for exploring novel
concerns regarding opportunistic behavior would domains (Dimov & Milanov, 2010), positively
rise with shorter AP as there will be intense affecting knowledge development and the creation
connectivity between network members which will of future FSAs. Finally, with increases in PC, a firm
in turn enhance the issues of unionization. There- can balance the power structure (Thye, 2000),
fore, shorter AP may significantly reduce the ben- which would diminish the threat of unionization
efits of clusters. With increases in CC and AP, the (Kano, 2017) and facilitate exploitation. Hence, we
focal firm will have access to novel insights from hypothesize:

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

Hypothesis 5a: PageRank centrality positively Figure 2 in the Web Appendix. Our data represents
moderates the relationship between network firms’ buyer–supplier information across tiers6 for
density and a firm’s international business 2013–2015. The data collection process embeds
performance. significant manual labor and challenges. While
Bloomberg provides information on firms across
In a network with high BC, a few firms may gain
geographies and industries, many have different
status and power as they hold key information
reporting standards. Hence, there is a possibility of
within the network (Bellamy & Basole, 2013). With
mismatches between the data reported in Bloom-
an increase in PC, the status of the focal firm also
berg and what companies have disclosed publicly.
increases, which diminishes the status difference
In case of such a mismatch, which is limited, we
between network members. However, diminishing
have relied upon publicly-disclosed information by
status differences may also lead to an increase in
individual firms.
the power struggle, resulting in conflict between
The construction of whole buyer–supplier net-
network members (Cowen, 2012). Especially, in
works requires significant manual labor. For exam-
networks with high BC where there are a few power
ple, the General Electric Company (GE) has 445
centers, such diminishing status differences can
Tier 1 suppliers, whereas Walmart has 564. Simi-
create more conflicts, leading to challenges of
larly, total buyers of GE are 272. However, these are
coordination and reconfiguration. Exploration
just the direct relationships, which at best represent
may also be negatively affected by high levels of
the egocentric network. To construct the whole BSR
conflict and lack of trust between network mem-
network of GE, for example, we need to find out the
bers. Hence, we hypothesize:
buyers and suppliers of all 445 direct suppliers. One
Hypothesis 5b: PageRank centrality negatively of the prominent suppliers of GE is Microsoft,
moderates the relationship between betweenness which has 437 suppliers and 251 customers. Not all
centralization and a firm’s international business of these suppliers and buyers may be directly
performance. connected to GE, but will be a part of the whole
BSR network. After constructing the whole BSR
A negative effect of power asymmetries arising
network of GE, we have a total of 5856 firms in the
due to the emergence of clusters can be managed if
network. The largest network in our sample is for
the network has a high PC. Contrary to a network
Walmart with 7212 firms, whereas the smallest is
with a high BC, an increase in CC leads to the
for Mitsubishi Tanabe Pharma Corporation with
power difference between different clusters. With
233 firms. On average, we have 2299 firms in every
an increase in network status, therefore, the focal
buyer–supplier network of 303 global firms. Our
firm will balance the power asymmetries between
data consist of firms from 28 countries across 50
clusters within the network (Thye, 2000), which
industries. We used Gephi 0.9.1 and R to construct
will enhance exploration–exploitation of FSAs and
our whole buyer–supplier networks.
subsequently performance in international mar-
It is important to check if our sample represents
kets. Hence, we hypothesize:
the overall population in the database. We check
Hypothesis 5c: PageRank centrality positively this by using the descriptive statistics of the pop-
moderates the relationship between average ulation and the sample. We have randomly selected
clustering coefficient and a firm’s international 2000 firms from the Bloomberg database. Of these
business performance. 2000 firms, we found that only 628 have informa-
tion about their Tier 1 suppliers’ buyers and
Based on the above discussion, we present the
suppliers (which represents the whole network).
conceptual framework (see Figure 1) of our study.
We find that the average values of ND, CC, and BC
of the 628 firms’ whole networks are 0.003, 0.071,
METHODS and 12.9, respectively, which are very close to the
average values of our sample firms (average values
Data of ND = 0.002; CC = 0.06; and BC = 11.29). This
We have compiled a database by collecting data signifies that our sample is representative of the
from multiple sources: Bloomberg database, firms’ available population. Finally, we checked if our
financial reports, and firms’ sustainability reports. sample suffers from selection bias and did not find
The data collection process is shown in WA- any such evidence.7

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

PageRank
Whole Buyer-Supplier Centrality
Network Characteristics
H5a(+)

Network Density H1(-)

H4a(-) H5b(-)

Betweenness International Business


H2(∩)
Performance
Centralization
H4b(-) H5c(+)

Average Control Variables


H3(U)
Clustering
H4c(+)
Coefficient
Average Path
Length

Figure 1 Conceptual framework.

Variable Operationalization Network density ðNDÞ ¼


Actual number of ties among network members
Potential number of ties
Dependent variable ð1Þ
International business performance: To measure a firm’s
IBP, we need a variable8 that distinguishes IBP from a To clarify the conceptualization and the opera-
firm’s overall business performance. Consistent with tionalization, let us consider the example of 3M.
the literature, we operationalize the ‘‘international 3M’s network has 2291 nodes (g) and 4774 edges
business performance’’ of a firm as the total values of (relationships). To compute the potential number
revenue from the international businesses (Hult et al., of ties, we need to know the maximum number of
2008: Shrader, 2001). We operationalize this variable relationships possible, which can be captured with
over a period of time, mitigating the concerns raised the formula g2 C, where C represents the total
by prior researchers regarding the use of cross- combinations possible. Now, for 3M, the potential
g
sectional data to measure IBP (Hult et al., 2008). Note number of ties = 2 C. = 2291 2 C. = 2,623,195. This
that ‘‘international revenue’’ is the only audited provides ND of 3M = 4774/2,623,195 = 0.00182.
measure reported in the balance sheet of firms, and Figure 2a and b provides the visual representation
we use it as a primary indicator of the IBP. However, of networks with high and low ND.
the literature raises concerns regarding international Betweenness centralization. BC is the heterogeneity
revenue as a proper indicator of IBP as it does not or variability in betweenness centrality between
account for the costs, and the importance of costs actors in a network. Consistent with the literature,
may be significant in international markets. To we operationalize BC as follows:
support our primary dependent variable (DV), we ( )
Xg h i
also measure IBP as ‘‘international ROA’’ (operational- 0
 0
BC ¼ 100  C B ð n Þ  C B ð n i Þ =ð g  1 Þ ð2Þ
ized as the ratio of international profits9 to the total i¼1
assets) and use it as a secondary DV. This is to note that
international ROA explicitly captures the profit from where, g is the number of firms in the network,
0
IB. For additional robustness, we use multiple other CB ðn Þ refers to the largest realized normalized
variables that depict the IBP of a firm including betweenness centrality for the firms in the network,
0
ROA,10growth in IB revenue (Hult et al., 2008), Tobin’s and CB ðni Þ refers to normalized betweenness cen-
q11 (Katsikeas, Morgan, Leonidou, & Hult, 2016), and trality for firm i. For 3M, we can compute
0 0
growth in IB profits (Autio, Sapienza, & Almeida, 2000). CB ðn Þ ¼ 0:091. Now, computing CB ðni Þ for each
firm in the network and
  then summing up will give
Pg  
Independent variables 0
 0
CB ðn Þ  CB ðni Þ ¼ 207:51. Hence, using
Network density. Consistent with the literature, we i¼1
operationalize ND as the ratio of the actual number Eq. 2, we can find the BC of 3M at time
of ties between network members to the potential t = 100 9 (207.51/2290) = 9.06. Figure 3a and b
number of ties (Ahuja, 2000, Rowley et al., 2000).

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

Figure 2 a Low ND firm: Mitsubishi (ND = 0.002324). b High ND firm: Cobham Plc. (ND = 0.007066).

provides visual representation of networks with   Xk  


1 PRðpi Þ
high and low BC. PCð pÞ ¼ ð1  dÞ þd ð5Þ
g i¼1
C ðp i Þ
Average clustering coefficient. Consistent with the
literature (Basole, 2016), CC is operationalized as: where PRðpi Þ is PageRank of any node pi ; g is the
g total number of nodes in the network; C(pi) is the
X
CC ¼ 1=g Ci ðwÞ: ð3Þ out-degree of pi . (number of links going out of pi .);
i¼1 pi is the ith link to node p and d is a damping factor,
which lies between 0 and 1. We calculate PageRank
where Ci (w) is the clustering coefficient of firm i.
g centrality using Google’s PageRank algorithm.
P
For 3M, we can find that Ci ðwÞ. = 80.62. If we
i¼1 Control variables
plug this information into Eq. 3, we will get CC of
Control for firm-specific, industry-specific, IB-speci-
3M = 80.62/2291 = 0.035. Figure 4a and b provides
fic, and network-specific variables.
visual representations of two networks with a low
Firm-specific Control: Consistent with prior litera-
and high CC, respectively.
ture, we control for firm size (operationalized as the
number of employees), ROA, and age of the firms
Moderating variables (Autio et al., 2000). We also control for absorptive
Average path length: The AP is operationalized as:
capacity (operationalized as marketing and techno-
P logical intensity). Finally, in a separate sub-analysis,

i6¼j lði; jÞ P
n
AP ¼ : ð4Þ we also use product diversification ½ Pi ln P1i ],
g ðg  1 Þ
where Pi is the share of the ith segmenti¼1 in the total
where i and j are two nodes in the network such sales of the firm (Kim, 2016) as an additional
that i = j; and g is the total number of firms in the control variable. Segments are coded based on the
P four-digit SIC code.
network. For 3M, lði; jÞ. = 21,310,836. Incorpo- Industry-specific control: We control for competi-
i6¼j
rating this into Eq. 4, we get AP = 21,310,836/ tive intensity using the Herfindahl–Hirschman
Index (HHI), computed at the global level. HHI
(2291 9 2290) = 4.062. indicates the market concentration. According to
PageRank centrality: Consistent with the literature the U.S. Department of Justice, a market with an
(Kumar & Jan, 2014), PC is operationalized as: HHI of less than 1500 is considered competitive. It

Figure 3 a Low BC firm: Akzo Noble (BC = 8.17). b High BC firm: Alcoa (BC = 37.77).

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

Figure 4 a Low CC firm: Jerónimo Martins (AC = 0.016). b High CC firm: Oki Electric (AC = 0.13).

has been found that higher competitiveness within focal variables using the two-step control function
an industry is associated with a firm’s IBP (Kirca, approach (Petrin & Train, 2010). Extant literature
Hult, Deligonul, Perryy, & Cavusgil, 2012). shows that not accounting for endogeneity is a
IB-specific control: We control for a firm’s interna- major issue in prior network-based research (Car-
tional experience (Kirca et al., 2012) and interna- penter, Li, & Jiang, 2012) and in IB (Hult et al.,
tional diversification (operationalized as the ratio 2008). In the first stage, we estimate the correction
of foreign sales to total sales) (Capar & Kotabe, terms by regressing the potentially endogenous
2003). variables, ND, BC, and CC on a set of exogenous
Network-specific control: Finally, we control for variables. Consistent with the literature that sug-
network diameter in our study. Network diameter is gests that firm-specific assets may influence a firm’s
the length of the largest geodesic in the graph. It network design (Jensen & Roy, 2008), we include
signifies how far is the farthest node in the graph. return on assets (ROA), profit, age, and size of the
With increases in network diameter, the focal firm firm. We also include network diameter and inter-
may find it harder to communicate with the firms national experience of the firm in our first-stage
on the periphery, influencing the focal firm’s IBP. regression models.
In addition to the above variables, in line with
Model Specification the exclusion restrictions proposed by Maddala
We test for several functional forms and violations (1983) and Hausman (1978), we include the aver-
of regression assumptions. We test for violations of age of similar firms’ ND (SimNDit Þ, BC (SimBCit Þ,
linearity using the observed versus predicted val- and CC (SimCCit Þ, respectively, and the number of
ues; violations of normality using a Kolmogorov– Tier 1 suppliers (No Tier1it Þ in the first-stage models
Smirnov test; serial correlations using a residual that are excluded from our final model. We find the
autocorrelations plot; multicollinearity using vari- similar firms by comparing the revenues of the
ance inflation factor (VIF),12 tolerance, and condi- focal firm with those of other firms in the industry
tion index; and heteroscedasticity using a Breush– to which the focal firm belongs. These variables
Pagan test. We do not find any significant viola- satisfy both the requirements of relevance and
tions. We use SAS, STATA, R, and Gelphi for exogeneity13 and, thus, serve as valid exclusion
variable operationalization and estimation. We variables. We argue that industry characteristics
use a maximum likelihood estimation approach and market conditions are key determinants of
to estimate our models. firms’ strategic choices, especially for decisions
characterized with ambiguity. Hence, these exclu-
Accounting for endogeneity sion restrictions are relevant. Further, the average
The decision to develop a whole BSR network is a of similar firms’ network characteristics can at best
firm’s strategic choice (Wuyts & Geyskens, 2005), capture the industry performance, not an individ-
and that choice influences the global performance ual firm’s IBP, thus satisfying the exogeneity crite-
of the firm. Specifically, firms may be strategic or ria. Building on the theory of mimetic
managers may choose the level and the type of isomorphism (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983) and the
network based on their evaluations of the potential literature on industry recipe (Spender, 1989), we
of buyers and suppliers with an aim to maximize argue that the SimNDit , SimBCit , and SimCCit should
gains from international markets. Consistently for influence focal firms’ ND, BC, and CC. Further, we
econometricians, the whole BSR network charac- also argue that the number of Tier 1 suppliers will
teristics may be potentially endogenous. We explic- influence the focal variables as the structure
itly account for the potential endogeneity in our depends on the Tier 1 suppliers and how they are

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

Interaction between Betweenness Centralization and PageRank Centrality Interaction between Average Clustering Coefficient and Average Path
Length
800000 60000

IB Performance
IB Performance

600000
40000
400000

200000 20000

0
0
2 7 12 17 22 27 0.01 0.06 0.11 0.16 0.21
-200000
Betweenness Centralization Average Clustering Coefficient
IB_PERF_MEAN(PC) IB_PERF_MIN(PC) IB_PERF_1.5 TIMES IF MEAN(PC)
IB_PERF_MEAN(AP) IB_PERF_MIN(AP) IB_PERF_MAX(AP)

Interaction between Average Clustering Coefficient and PageRank


Centrality
50000
IB Performance

40000
30000
20000
10000
0
0.01 0.06 0.11 0.16 0.21
Average Clustering Coefficient
IB_PERF_MEAN(PC) IB_PERF_MIN(PC) IB_PERF_MAX(PC)

Interaction between Betweenness Centralization and Average Path Interaction between Network Density and PageRank Centrality
Length
600000
IB Performance

40000
IB Performance

400000
0
200000 0.0009 0.0034 0.0059 0.0084 0.0109

-40000
0
2 7 12 17 22 27 Network Density
Betweenness Centralization -80000
-200000
IB_PERF_MEAN(PC) IB_PERF_MIN(PC) IB_PERF_MAX(PC)
IB_PERF_MEAN(AP) IB_PERF_MIN(AP) IB_PERF_MAX(AP)

Figure 5 Moderating Effects.

linked to the other players in the network. How- Unobserved heterogeneity, time fixed-effect,
ever, the number of suppliers will not determine geography fixed effects, and omitted variable bias
the performance as quality and size may also Firms may be inherently different in their network
account for performance.14 Hence, our first stage development strategies, which may not be reflected
regression equations are as follows: in their observed characteristics. Hence, it is critical
to account for the unobserved firm-level hetero-
NDit ¼ cND þ dND SimNDit þ kND No Tier1it þ hND zit geneity. We estimate a random effects model that
þ gND
it captures the unobserved heterogeneity across firms.
ð6aÞ We capture the time fixed effect using a dummy
variable approach. We create three dummy vari-
ables for years 2013, 2014, and 2015, respectively,
BCit ¼ cBC þ dBC SimBCit þ kBC No Tier1it þ hBC zit
and use year 2013 as the baseline. We use the
þ gBC
it dummy variables for year 2014 and year 2015 as the
ð6bÞ additional independent variables in our model. We
capture the fixed effect of geographic regions15
CCit ¼ cCC þ dCC SimCCit þ kCC No Tier1it þ hCC zit operationalized as dummy variables in terms of
þ gCC continents (e.g., Asia, Europe, America Australia,
it
and Africa); we consider Africa as the baseline.
ð6cÞ
Finally, we account for the omitted variable bias by
where zit denotes the exogenous variables. including the estimated value of lagged DV
gND BC CC
it ; git ; and git are the residual terms.
( LagdDV ) obtained by regressing lagged DV on
difference between DV at t - 1 and t - 2. Our final

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

model after accounting for endogeneity, unob- significant evidence of endogeneity in ND (pND ¼
served heterogeneity, time, and geography fixed 25100000:00; p ¼ 0:000Þ, BC (pBC ¼ 11098:54; p ¼
effects is as follows16: 0:009Þ, and CC ðpCC ¼ 461868:30; p ¼ 0:000). Fur-
ther, unobserved heterogeneity matters and with-
Int Perfit ¼ ai þ bND NDit þ bBC BCit þ bSQ BC
BC2it out accounting for it may lead to biased parameter
þ bCC CCit þ bSQ CC
CC2it þ bND BC
BCit  NDit estimates. We find supports for Hypothesis 1 such
þb ND CC
CCit  NDit þ b CC BC
BCit that ND is negatively related to IBP (b ¼
10500000:00; p ¼ 0:000Þ: Our understanding that
 CCit þ bAP APit þ bPC PCit
þ bAP ND
ðAPit  NDit Þ

the BC has an inverted U-shaped relationship
bBC ¼ 76990:51; p ¼ 0:021; bsq BC ¼ 2585:07;

þb AP BC
ðAPit  BCit Þ 0:046Þ and CC has a U-shaped relationship bCC ¼
þb AP CC
ðAPit  CCit Þ 465226:10; p ¼ 0:000; bsq CC ¼ 1761747:00; p¼
PC ND 0:000Þ with IBP is supported by our model and
þb ðPCit  NDit Þ
data (Hypothesis 2 and Hypothesis 3 respectively).
þ bPC BC
ðPCit  BCit Þ These results further indicate that the relationship
þ bPC CC
ðPCit  CCit Þ between characteristics of a firm’s whole BSR
X
J network and its IBP may not be linear but rather
þ oj Controlj þ pND g^ND BC BC
it þ p g^it curvilinear. Drawing our attention to the modera-
j¼1
tion effects (see Figure 5), we find that AP nega-
þ pCC g^CC
it þ eit tively moderates the impact of BC on IBP,
ð7Þ supporting Hypothesis 4b (b ¼ 1699:04; p ¼
0:006Þ. Further, we find that AP positively moder-
where ai represents the unobserved heterogene-
ates the relationship between CC and a firm’s IBP
ity;Int Perf it is international business performance;
(b ¼ 20053:55; p ¼ 0:000), supporting Hypothesis
pND , pBC , and pCC represent the parameters of the
4c.
residual terms from Eqs. 6a–c.
We also find that PC positively moderates the
relationship between ND and IBP (b ¼
714000000:00; p ¼ 0:000Þ, supporting Hypothesis
RESULTS
5a. We get support for Hypothesis 5b, such that
We present the correlation and descriptive statistics
PC negatively moderates the relationship between
in Table 2. Moving our attention to the first-stage
BC and IBP (b ¼ 912903:40; p ¼ 0:000Þ; and for
regression results in Table 3, we see that the
Hypothesis 5c in such a manner that PC positively
SimNDit (b ¼ 0:12; p ¼ 0:000Þ, SimCCit (b ¼ 0:64;
moderates the relationship between CC and a firm’s
p ¼ 0:000Þ, and the SimBCit (b ¼ 0:03; p ¼ 0:000Þ
IBP (b ¼ 12800000:00; p ¼ 0:008Þ. Finally, we do
significantly influence a focal firm’s ND, CC, and
not find any significant impact of AP on
BC. Results further suggest that the number of Tier
the relationship between ND and IBP (b ¼
1 suppliers has a negative influence on ND
446467:30; n:s:Þ.17
(b ¼ 2:16; p ¼ 0:000Þ, and BC (b ¼ 0:77;
Moving our attention to the control variables,18
p ¼ 0:000Þ. However, the number of Tier 1 suppliers
we find that international diversification positively
positively influences CC (b ¼ 0:86; p ¼ 0:000Þ. A
(b ¼ 25872:41; p ¼ 0:000Þ; international experience
firm’s profit (EBITA) has a negative impact on ND
positively (b ¼ 135:65; p ¼ 0:007Þ; network diame-
(b ¼ 1:71; p ¼ 0:000Þ, and a positive impact on BC
ter negatively (b ¼ 1367:70; p ¼ 0:000Þ; marketing
(b ¼ 0:25; p ¼ 0:086Þ, and CC (b ¼ 0:46; p ¼ 0:000Þ.
intensity negatively (b ¼ 16373:24; p ¼ 0:026Þ;
While the network diameter negatively influences
competition negatively (b ¼ 39486:40; p ¼
ND (b ¼ 0:77; p ¼ 0:000Þ and CC (b ¼ 0:25;
0:003Þ, and estimated value of lag of international
p ¼ 0:000Þ, it positively influences BC (b ¼ 0:02;
revenue positively19 (b ¼ 0:56; p ¼ 0:000Þ influence
p ¼ 0:000Þ. Finally, results indicate that as ROA of a
the IBP. Our proposed model has AIC = 19,748.66.
firm increases, BC decreases (b ¼ 0:28; p ¼ 0:080Þ.
Further, the time fixed effect of year 2015 is weaker
Table 4 (Model 1) shows the results of the main
than that of the baseline year ðb ¼ 2468:79; p ¼
model in Eq. 7 where the primary dependent
0:058Þ and the geography fixed effect of America is
variable is international revenue. We present the
weaker than that of Africa ðb ¼ 4440:90;
standard errors and p values in the result tables
p ¼ 0:070Þ. Finally, we find that the two-way inter-
and exact p values in the text. We find
action effects between network characteristics are

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

significant. We estimate several other benchmark


(15)

0.57
0.25
models in order to be sure that the proposed model

1
is significantly better for explaining the relation-
(14)

0.03

0.04
0.04
ship between whole network characteristics and a

1
firm’s IBP. We estimate Eq. 7 without heterogeneity

- 0.08**
0.07**
(AIC = 21,335.16); without endogeneity (AIC =
(13)

8.45
1.80
19,785.41) (see Model 7 in WA-Table 3 in Web

1
Appendix); and without endogeneity and hetero-

0.16***

0.18***
- 0.05

53.95
35.87
(12)

geneity (AIC = 21,344.63). As evident from the


1 results, the performance of our proposed model
- 0.08**
(AIC = 19,748.66) is significantly better than that
0.73***
0.17***

85.61
53.98
(11)

0.04 of other benchmark models. This is to note that we


1

get support for Hypotheses 1, 2, 3, 4a, 4b, 4c, and 5a


152,940.60
88,594.74
in the model with our secondary dependent vari-
0.10***

- 0.01
0.08**

able ‘international ROA’ (Model 2 in Table 4). In a


(10)

0.05

0.04

separate analysis, we also capture the country fixed


1

effects. As displayed in WA-Table 4 (Model 11), we


- 0.08**

- 0.08**
0.13***
- 0.00

get directionally consistent results. However, the


-0.04
0.05

5.08
6.62
(9)

quadratic effect of BC is not significant, and most of


1

the home-country fixed effects are insignificant.


- 0.17***
0.16***
0.14***

0.09***
- 0.02

We also estimate a model with main effects (with-


0.08**
0.07**

0.18
0.14

***Significant at 1%, **significant at 5%, *significant at 10%. Correlations are rounded to the second decimal point.
(8)

out their interaction with each other) and control


1

variables (see WA-Table 2, Model 1). We find


- 0.12***
- 0.21***

- 0.17***
-0.10***

support for our hypotheses.


0.23***
0.17***

0.28***
0.08**

0.04
0.06
(7)

Robustness check
- 0.06*

- 0.06*
0.12***

0.09***

0.14***

In addition to the proposed model in Eq. 7, we


- 0.05
- 0.02
0.09**

0.007
0.007
-0.01
(6)

conduct several additional analyses to ensure the


1

robustness of our results and discuss the same here.


- 0.17***
- 0.16***
- 0.11***

- 0.07**

One variable at a time: We estimate Eq. 7 again in


0.14***

0.11***
0.22***
0.24***
0.71***

0.16***

3.78
0.53

order to check the incremental performance of our


(5)

proposed model. We include one focal variable


- 0.24***

- 0.24***

- 0.28***

- 0.11***
- 0.07**

(e.g., ND) at a time along with the moderation


-0.09***

- 0.06*
0.11***
0.12***

0.002
0.001
0.06*

effects and control variables. Control variable only


0.01
(4)

model in Table 4 (AIC = 19,751.14); Model 2-only


- 0.11***

- 0.13***

- 0.10***
- 0.14***

- 0.12***

ND model (AIC = 19,823.03); Model 3-only BC


- 0.07**
- 0.08**

- 0.06*

11.29

model (AIC = 19,852.20); and Model 4-only CC


0.06*

-0.02
0.02

0.02

4.83
Table 2 Descriptive statistics and correlation matrix

(3)

model (AIC = 19,826.28) (see WA-Table 2 in the


1

Web Appendix) are inferior to our proposed model


- 0.45***
- 0.21***

- 0.17***

- 0.19***
-0.11***
0.09***

0.19***

0.14***
- 0.04

- 0.01

(AIC = 19,748.66) in terms of performance. This


0.08**

0.07**

0.067
0.033
0.05
(2)

analysis specifically shows that it is critical to


1

consider all the key characteristics to understand


22,762.04
35,099.63
- 0.14***

- 0.33***

- 0.08**
- 0.07**

the impact of a specific whole buyer–supplier


0.16***

0.17***

0.46***
0.12***
0.21***
0.17***

0.29***
- 0.03
0.06*

0.04

network on a firm’s IBP. Finally, we estimate an


(1)
1

additional model to rule out the understanding


(3) Betweenness centralization

that the moderating or control variables are driving


(6) PageRank centrality (PC)

the relationships of network characteristics with


(4) Network density (ND)
(5) Avg. path length (AP)
(1) International revenue

(13) Network diameter


(8) Marketing intensity

IBP. As evident from WA-Table 3 (Model 8), we get


(12) Int. experience
(2) Avg. clustering

consistent results, although the performance of the


(15) International
(7) R&D intensity

(14) Competition
coefficient(CC)

model is inferior to that of the proposed model.


(11) Firm Age

diversification

Alternate dependent variable specification: To be


(10) Size
(9) ROA

assured that our results are not driven by the choice


Mean
(BC)

SD

of the DV, we estimate the model in Eq. 7 with

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

Table 3 First-stage regression results

Model 1a- DV: ND Model 1b- DV: BC Model 1c- DV: CC

Est. SE P Est. SE P Est. SE P

SimCC 0.64 0.041 0.000


SimND 0.12 0.035 0.000
SimBC 0.03 0.004 0.000
No. of Tier 1 suppliers -2.16 0.326 0.000 -0.77 0.160 0.000 0.86 0.136 0.000
ROA -0.65a 3.240 0.841 -0.28 0.158 0.080 -0.12 1.358 0.931
EBITA -1.71 0.294 0.000 0.25 0.146 0.086 0.46 0.124 0.000
Size 0.16 0.174 0.346 0.00 0.853 0.997 -0.20 0.737 0.788
Firm age -0.66 0.584 0.258 0.21 0.286 0.466 -0.24 0.248 0.326
Int. experience 0.19 0.870 0.825 -0.53 0.425 0.209 -0.11 0.367 0.773
Network diameter -0.77 0.122 0.000 0.02 0.005 0.000 -0.25 0.052 0.000
Intercept 0.00 0.000 0.000 1.76 0.075 0.000 0.04 0.006 0.000
F statistics 35.80 0.000 16.04 0.000 63.33 0.000
a
Estimates of control variables are scaled for better representation.

alternate DVs. We estimate our model with a firm’s performance of the model with ego characteristics
ROA and Tobin’s q (Hult et al., 2008). For ROA20 as (AIC = 26,169.60) is significantly inferior to our
a DV (see Model 6 in WA-Table 3), we find largely proposed model (AIC = 19,748.66). We also find
consistent results (support for Hypotheses 1, 2, 3, that the model ðR2 ¼ 0:79Þ with whole network
4a, 4b, 5a, 5b, and 5c, with a few estimates characteristics has a significantly higher capability
significant at p = 0.1 level). With Tobin’s q as DV to explain the variance in a firm’s IBP over a model
(AIC = 9184.38), we find support for Hypotheses 1, ðR2 ¼ 0:61Þ with ego characteristics.
2, 3, 4a, 4b, and 5a. Note that we cannot compare
the performance of these models, as the unit of Exploring mechanism
measurement of the DVs is different. Finally, We assume that the mechanism behind the impact
consistent with the literature (Hult et al., 2008), of network characteristics on IBP is ambidexterity.
we estimate the proposed model with ‘‘growth in Thus, it is imperative that we document that
international business revenue’’ (see Model 5 in network characteristics influence organizational
WA-Table 3) and ‘‘growth in profits from interna- ambidexterity22 (Kleinbaum & Stuart, 2014; Regner
tional markets’’ (AIC = - 2140.76) as two addi- & Zander, 2011) and IBP. In the absence of primary
tional DVs.21 We get largely consistent results. data, we cannot directly address how firms gain
Estimating a model with the characteristics of ego ambidexterity through the network and improve
network for the same set of firms: We collect data on IBP. Hence, we create a measure based on secondary
the ND, BC, and CC for the ego network of the data which is a close reflection of ambidexterity
same set of firms for the same time period. and we test the impact of network characteristics
Similarly, we capture the AP and PC for the ego on the measure of ambidexterity. Consistent with
networks of the firms. We re-estimate Eq. 7 with the literature (Mizik & Jacobson, 2003), we opera-
the ego network characteristics and we find support tionalize ambidexterity for firm i at time period t as:
for Hypotheses 1, 3, 4c, 4a and 5b. However, the

ðTotal Marketing Expenditure through Buyer  Supplier NetworkÞit


Ambidextarityit ¼
ðTotal Marketing ExpenditureÞit
ð8Þ
ðTotal R&D Expenditure through Buyer  Supplier NetworkÞit

ðTotal R&D ExpenditureÞit

Journal of International Business Studies


Table 4 Parameter estimates

Model 1 (DV = Int. revenue) Model 2 (DV = Int. ROA) Model 3: Control only model

Hypothesis Est. SE P Est. SE P Est. SE P

Intercept 42,409.57 8933.393 0.000 0.00 0.000 0.000 - 25,946.43 22,569.550 0.250
Independent variables
Network density (ND) (-) - 10,500,000.00 1,380,658.000 0.000 - 0.06 0.029 0.046
Betweenness centralization (BC) inverted U-shaped 76990.51 33,200.004 0.021 0.00 0.000 0.006
Sq_BC - 2585.07 1294.995 0.046 0.00 0.000 0.096
Avg. clustering coefficient (CC) U-Shaped - 465226.10 127,108.700 0.000 - 0.02 0.011 0.021

Journal of International Business Studies


Sq_CC 1,761,747.00 302,605.100 0.000 0.01 0.008 0.084
Interaction between main variables
CC 9 ND - 256,000,000.00 37,700,000.000 0.000 - 1.28 1.126 0.255
CC 9 BC 3,618,531.00 1,244,170.000 0.004 - 0.02 0.046 0.637
ND 9 BC 61,600,000.00 21,100,000.000 0.004 1.52 2.672 0.571
Main effects of moderating variables
Average path length (AP) - 1298.22 1760.791 0.461 0.00 0.000 0.117 309.75 4351.530 0.943
Page rank centrality (PC) - 1,198,485.00 212,053.000 0.000 - 0.006 0.009 0.509 - 279,396.40 237,245.800 0.239
Moderation effects
ND 9 AP (-) - 446,467.30 647,543.500 0.491 - 0.09 0.030 0.003
BC 9 AP (-) - 1699.04 622.372 0.006 - 0.00 0.000 0.057
Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance

CC 9 AP (+) 20,053.55 3912.599 0.000 0.005 0.002 0.047


ND 9 PC (+) 714,000,000.00 178,000,000.000 0.000 25.92 7.272 0.000
BC 9 PC (-) - 912,903.40 230,624.500 0.000 - 0.008 0.005 0.112
CC 9 PC (+) 12,800,000.00 4,803,365.000 0.008 0.01 0.121 0.914
Control variables
ROA 45.65 75.212 0.544 0.00 0.000 0.000 179.94 57.456 0.002
International diversification 25,872.41 5454.969 0.000 0.00 0.000 0.305 27,046.62 5489.478 0.000
Amalesh Sharma et al

Size - 0.004 0.003 0.204 0.00 0.000 0.614 0.09 0.010 0.000
Firm age - 7.57 6.563 0.249 - 0.00 0.000 0.081 -50.01 43.615 0.252
International experience 135.65 50.049 0.007 - 0.00 0.000 0.085 179.64 65.501 0.006
Network diameter - 1367.70 135.250 0.000 0.00 0.000 0.413 1671.60 1254.850 0.183
R&D intensity - 8430.93 19,725.240 0.669 - 0.001 0.001 0.121 - 4072.32 19,820.940 0.837
Marketing intensity - 16373.24 7370.315 0.026 - 0.00 0.000 0.000 - 21,772.09 7370.537 0.003
Competition -39486.40 13,237.810 0.003 0.00 0.001 0.049 58,202.72 31,726.930 0.067
Estimated lag (DV) 0.56 0.015 0.000 0.00 0.000 0.006
Time fixed effect
Year_2014 - 454.04 1300.090 0.727 0.00 0.000 0.062
Year_2015 - 2468.79 1299.286 0.058 0.00 0.000 0.017
Geography fixed effect
Asia - 4230.73 4148.010 0.308 - 0.00 0.000 0.002 3673.15 19613.770 0.851
Europe 3477.65 2575.823 0.177 - 0.00 0.000 0.000 14,576.12 19,701.970 0.459
Australia - 2969.28 6182.249 0.631 0.00 0.000 0.005 1258.79 21,616.920 0.954
America - 4440.90 2446.955 0.070 0.00 0.000 0.004 2280.98 1,9529.700 0.907
Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

The value of the ambidexterity measure lies


between + 1 to - 1. A score of + 1 indicates that a
Model 3: Control only model

firm’s entire marketing spending is through its BSR


network and that the firm invests no resources in
R&D through BSR network (purely exploitative
network). Similarly, a score of - 1 reflects a purely
SE

exploratory network. This proxy has a strong


resemblance with commonly used proxies in the
literature (Mizik & Jacobson, 2003). To simplify the
19,751.14

analysis and interpretation for the effects of struc-


tural characteristics on ambidexterity, we take the
Est.

absolute values of the operationalization. The new


operationalization has values ranging from 0 to 1
0.726
0.064
0.075
Model 2 (DV = Int. ROA)

(both inclusive), where 0 means that a firm is


P

purely ambidextrous (the firm balances exploration


0.102
0.000
0.002

and exploitations) and 1 means that the firm is


SE

non-ambidextrous (either exploitative or explora-


tory). We find that BC has a U-shaped relation-
10,322.91

ship23-
- 0.00
- 0.00
0.035

,
CC has an inverted U-shaped relationship
Est.

b ¼ 2:01; p ¼ 0:002; bsq CC ¼ 2:84; p ¼ 0:096 ;


and ND has an insignificant positive impact
0.000
0.009
0.000

ðb ¼ 10:37; p ¼ 0:328Þ with ambidexterity, confirm-


P

ing our intuition that ambidexterity is indeed the


mechanism behind the proposed effects.
Model 1 (DV = Int. revenue)

1,917,942.000

Further, since the mediation analysis in the


78,698.230

presence of a non-linear term is quite challenging


4241.744

(Hayes & Preacher, 2010), we adopt ‘‘instantaneous


indirect effect’’ which suggests that the rate at
SE

which a change in the independent variable (IV)


changes the dependent variable (DV) through the
changes in mediation variable (MV), is denoted as
25,100,000.00

- 461,868.30

h, which can be estimated as the product of the


11,098.54

19,748.66

partial derivative of the function of MV with


respect to IV and the first derivative of the function
Est.

of DV with respect to MV. The analysis provides


significant direct, indirect, and total effects of
network characteristics on IBP. At the mean value
of BC, we find, h ¼ 0:92. Similarly, for mean plus/
Hypothesis

minus 1 standard deviation, we get h ¼ 1:40 and


h ¼ 0:44 respectively, suggesting that ambidexter-
ity mediates the proposed relationship between BC
and IBP. Further, at the mean value of CC, we get,
h ¼ 0:54.

DISCUSSION
Table 4 (Continued)

We have investigated the impact of structural


characteristics of a firm’s whole BSR network on
its IBP. Our study reveals the importance of
Endogeneity
Endo_ND

Endo_CC

considering the whole BSR network for designing


Endo_BC

international business strategies. The study pro-


AIC

vides compelling theoretical arguments for how the

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

whole network characteristics impact firms’ IBP. Kamal, 2011), and some scholars have focused on
We find that, while ND negatively influences a network position and its impact on performance
firm’s IBP, BC has an inverted U-shaped relation- (Turkina & Van Assche, 2018). Our study extends
ship. Similarly, there is a U-shaped relationship the literature on buyer–supplier networks and
between CC and a firm’s IBP. These are very international business performance. We show that
interesting and novel, as most studies demonstrate performance in international markets is not only
either positive or negative effects of ego network driven by a firm’s position but also by the network
characteristics on firm performance (Rowley et al., structure and by the interaction between position
2000). We also show that both network-level (e.g., and structure. We show that there is a differential
AP) and node-level (e.g., PC) characteristics mod- effect of structure–position interaction on firm
erate the proposed relationships. By doing so, we performance for different network characteristics.
are able to resolve the existing theoretical para- While past scholars have focused on position as a
doxes and propose a generalized framework to predictor of success in international markets (Turk-
highlight the role of a whole network on a firm’s ina & Van Assche, 2018), our work argues that such
IBP. The lack of empirical work, which remains a relationships must be viewed from the perspective
major concern for establishing a generalized phe- of specific structural characteristics and their inter-
nomenon, has been overcome in this study. In action with firm position. We show that, while
doing so, we contribute to three separate streams of network status negatively moderates the relation-
literature. ship between BC and IBP, it positively moderates
Our first contribution is in the space of the the relationship between CC and IBP. We highlight
Uppsala model. We contribute to the Uppsala the asymmetric effect of structure–position inter-
model by challenging the fundamental assumption action on IBP and thus extend the knowledge in
that being a part of a relevant network will lead to the literature. Apart from this extension, we have
high performance in international markets. Extant also shown that AP can mitigate concerns associ-
literature has pointed out that a focal firm must be ated with bounded rationality and thus enhance
embedded in the relevant network to explore and IBP. Structure–position interaction as well as inter-
exploit FSAs, leading to performance (Vahlne & action between different structural elements may
Johanson, 2017a). Thus, scholars argue that ‘‘the enhance or hinder performance in international
model should be seen as providing necessary but markets. Therefore, we bring in different structural
not sufficient conditions for success’’ (Vahlne & elements, interaction between the structural ele-
Johanson, 2017a: 1088). Providing theoritical cri- ments, and the interaction between structual ele-
tique to the Uppsala model, Forsgren (2016) sug- ments and positions as new antecdents for success
gests that more work is required to understand how in international business. In doing so, we have also
network structure may facilitate or hinder firm extended the Uppsala model by highlighting the
performance in international markets. We add to differential effect of network position on IBP.
this stream of literature by theorizing and empiri- Finally, our study makes a broader theoretical
cally validating the kind of network structure a firm point with regard to theorizing for network
may construct to explore and exploit FSAs, which research in general. Relying on alliance and inter-
will ensure high IBP. Thus, we argue that network personal networks, extant literature has shown how
embeddedness may not be adequate for perfor- an MNE can access knowledge from diverse inter-
mance; a firm must consider all three central national markets and how it can influence perfor-
network characterstics: ND, BC and CC. In doing mance in international markets (Iurkov & Benito,
so, we also enhance the explanatory potential of 2017; Yu, Gilbert, & Oviatt, 2011). Our work
the Uppsala model. We add network structure as a establishes the idea of a whole buyer–supplier
new dimension to the model and, therefore, answer network in this discussion. We present evidence
the call for research made by scholars in the past that a MNE must understand nuances associated
(Forsgren, 2016). with different types of networks and their effect on
Second, as we explore the whole BSR network, we performance. Again, the level at which theorization
contribute to research on buyer–supplier networks takes place also matters. For example, prior research
and international business performance. Research has almost always argued that ND has a positive
in this space has looked at the BSR network from effect on performance of a MNE (Spencer, 2003; Yu
the point of view of suppliers (Nobeoka, Dyer, & et al., 2011). Two rationales for such an explanation
Madhok, 2002) as a dyad of relationship (Zaheer & are that highly dense networks provide

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

opportunities for co-learning (Collinson & Rug- delete connections. First, firms that are a part of a
man, 2008) and reduce opportunistic behavior highly-interconnected network may need to add
(McEvily, Perrone, & Zaheer, 2003), thereby other players on the periphery to gain access to
increasing performance in international markets novel information. Firms may have limited busi-
(Obloj & Zemsky, 2015). However, our results ness relationships (in terms of value) with these
suggest that, as we focus on whole buyer–supplier firms, but their strategic positions will be highly
networks, such findings may not hold true. This beneficial. In this case, adding firms that may be
pertains both to the nature of the buyer–supplier connected to diverse industries may provide firms
network and multi-tier structure, and to the com- with significant new information and facilitate
plex interplay between these two elements. Because exploration capabilities. Second, firms with high
a focal firm cannot apply selection rules going concentrations of information gatekeepers in the
beyond Tier 1 and because lower-tier suppliers lack network may wish to develop ties with lower-tier
FSAs, density actually becomes detrimental to IBP. suppliers to create a more balanced power structure
Again, all network elements have differential rela- in the network. Third, a firm may connect with
tionship with performance (density has a linear many suppliers with similar strategic objectives to
relationship whereas BC and CC have a curvilinear create high cliquishness. Fourth, if managers wit-
relationship). These findings indicate that theoriz- ness a change in the network characteristics, they
ing in the case of network research should consider should consider whether it is due to their own
not only the type of network, but also different actions (e.g., changing the criteria for supplier
elements in the network and the level of network relationship building) or to external factors (e.g.,
(whole vs. ego) while making predictions about the suppliers removing themselves from the business).
relationship between structure and performance. A careful understanding of such interactions may
help design effective network strategies for
Managerial Implications enhanced IBP. Again, in case a firm cannot change
Our findings have important implications for MNEs its structure, the firm may certainly alter its posi-
operating in international markets. Most MNEs face tion by forming new relationships and by manag-
significant challenges when it comes to the con- ing AP and network status.
struction of their supply networks. The rapid It is also important for MNE managers to under-
change in customer expectations,24 coupled with stand the different types of network relationships.
suppliers’ opportunistic behavior,25 have presented While, in the case of alliances or interpersonal
major challenges for MNEs. To add to the agony, networks, a firm may establish dense networks, our
there is an increase in global competition further findings indicate that this is not the case with a
deteriorating MNEs’ performance in international whole buyer–supplier network. Therefore, to create
markets. Our findings therefore provide strategies a holistic strategy, a firm must integrate findings
to MNEs to mitigate such concerns. We show that from alliances and interpersonal as well as the
designing a network in a specified manner can buyer–supplier network to achieve high perfor-
overcome these challenges. Developing a BSR net- mance in international markets. For example, while
work with low density, the optimal level of average a dense network with a high CC may be effective
clustering coefficient, and BC can help a MNE not for an alliance network, a BSR network with low ND
only exploit existing FSAs but also develop new and moderate levels of both CC and BC will achieve
FSAs. Thus, our research provides focal firms with better results.
multiple strategies to mitigate such challenges.
MNE managers must look beyond their direct Economic Impact
suppliers and also construct a network considering As the prior discussion suggests, a firm can gain
the indirect connection. However, changing the (lose) in its international businesses if it does not
supply network may not be easy for a firm and, in emphasize the whole network characteristics.
many cases, it may be difficult to change the Hence, the insights from our research are of
existing structure. In such cases, a firm may use economic importance to a firm. We discuss the
our strategic levers to mitigate the challenges economic relevance of our study to the broader
associated with the existing structure. audience of international businesses. We rely on
Based on our findings, we argue that a firm must the estimates of our model and uncover the
first focus on three structural elements. Consider- economic relevance of increasing/decreasing the
ing multi-tier structure, a firm may decide to add or values of the network characteristics. For example,

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

we find that a firm, on average, can gain an 18% possibility of intermingling as suppliers and cus-
increase in international revenue by increasing BC tomers may be common to multiple firms. It would
by 20% from its respective mean. However, the be interesting to see how this intermingling may
same 20% increase in BC, along with a 10% affect IBP.
reduction in the AP, can yield a 18.71% increase In summary, with an increased number of firms
in international revenue, on average, thus exposing going global, understanding and managing a whole
the impact of the moderating variable. At the buyer–supplier network is critical for IB success.
tipping point of the CC, a firm can gain a 55% This study is a novel attempt to create large-scale
increment in IB revenue over operating at the mean whole networks and build a generalized framework.
value of CC. We present managers with a concrete framework to
rely upon and create a holistic understanding of
relationships between a whole buyer–supplier net-
LIMITATIONS AND FUTURE RESEARCH work and a firm’s IBP. Our study unravels many
DIRECTIONS hidden facts about a firm’s whole buyer–supplier
Although our research generates unique findings, network and its effect on the firm’s IBP. Finally, we
there are certain limitations. First, we provide a believe that the study will significantly enhance
generalized understanding across industries; how- research in the domain of international business as
ever, we may have missed some industry-specific well as multi-tier buyer–supplier networks.
factors. For example, while some industries may
require more exploration, others may rely more on
exploitation (Rowley et al., 2000). In those cases,
certain network structures may become more
NOTES
important within a particular industry. Future
1
researchers may consider this aspect in greater International business performance refers to the
detail. Second, future research may even consider performance of a firm from its international busi-
incorporating lower-tiered relationships, such as nesses. A measure that isolates a firm’s performance
Tier 3, Tier 4, etc., and check whether our findings from its international business from that of its
still hold true. What may change if we incorporate domestic performance or overall performance will
such relationships? One may argue that the curvi- distinctly capture the IB performance. One can
linear relationship between BC and CC with IBP measure the performance using various matrices
may change. Specifically, the inflection point may including a firm’s revenue from IB operations and
shift as constraints of bounded rationality and the return on assets from the IB operations.
2
threat of opportunistic behavior may rise. Third, Empirically, the characteristics of a whole net-
although our measures adequately capture whole work are different not only in magnitude but also
BSR networks, other network measures may gener- structurally from that of ego networks (see WA-
ate additional insights. As the purpose of this Table 1 in the Web Appendix for the differences in
research is to offer a generalized framework, we magnitude for a representative set of firms and WA-
consciously refrained from delving into other net- Figure 1 in the Web Appendix for differences in
work measures. Future research may consider addi- structure for a firm).
3
tional whole network characteristics. Fourth, future Note that we study the whole buyer–supplier
researchers may explore additional mechanisms network, not the whole network. A whole network
through which network structure impacts IBP, may contain a firm’s buyers–suppliers, alliances,
and may investigate how BSR networks evolve over intermediaries, and strategic partners. However, the
time. Fifth, while we do consider information flow relationships a firm develops with various players
and bond, our work does not consider the different are different. Taking all players together and form-
functions that value-chain members perform. ing a whole network faces structural issues, and,
Future research may consider different functions hence, we limit to a particular type of network:
that network members may perform and their buyer–supplier, and concentrate on a pure multi-
impact on profitability. Again, foreign market tier perspective (whole) for the first time in the
expansion strategy and centralization/decentraliza- literature. Further, our selection of a whole BSR
tion of the governance system may impact a firm’s network is dependent on three reasons: (1) multi-
IBP. Therefore, we urge future scholars to pay close tier structure amplifies both adverse selection and
attention in this regard. Finally, there is also a opportunistic behavior (Kano, 2017); (2) BSR

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

networks are a combination of multiple relation- Bloomberg SPLC data and it took ‘‘15 weeks and
ships (e.g., transactional, adversarial) (Choi, Doo- over 300 person-hours’’ (p. 115). Thus, in our work,
ley, & Rungtusanatham, 2001), and therefore, we we are able to open a new frontier of data collection
are able to theorize at a much broader level than for researchers and practicing managers.
7
any other relationship; and (3) BSR networks may We used the Heckman two-step approach to
help an organization achieve knowledge, informa- assess if there is any potential bias and estimates
tion, and strategic competitiveness (Kristal, change due to such a bias. To assess the bias caused
Huang,& Roth, 2010). by the sample selection, we compared the results of
4
Two key elements of theoretical contributions the proposed model with the results obtained from
include the addition of new knowledge and a the two-step approach. We found strong consis-
deepening understanding of existing knowledge tency between the estimates (we thank an anony-
(Brown & Dant, 2008). Our theoretical contribu- mous reviewer for suggesting this). We used age as
tions are driven by these two principles. the exclusion restriction in the selection model (see
5
Wellman (1997) argued that while creating a Lu & Shang, 2017). See WA-Table 4 for results
whole network, one needs to define the boundaries (Model 9 and Model 10).
8
of a population and who the external observer is. The research in ambidexterity has looked into a
Extant literature has argued that a whole network is variety of performance outcomes including objec-
one where researchers study relationships between tive as well as subjective measures (Junni, Sarala,
all members in a predefined population (Wellman, Taras, & Tarba, 2013). Ambidexterity positively
1997). We draw our boundaries of a whole BSR influences growth in sales (He & Wong, 2004),
network by capturing data up to Tier 2. This is stock market performance (Uotila, Maula, Keil, &
because, in most cases, a firm can only acquire Zahra, 2009), firm survival (Junni et al., 2013), and
information up to Tier 2 level (Hartmann & subjective ratings of performance (Gibson & Birkin-
Moeller, 2014) and thus the firm’s supply base shaw, 2004). In the context of IB, return on capital
policy is at best extended to Tier 2 suppliers (Choi growth is considered as a primary performance
& Krause, 2006). In fact, scholars have pointed out indicator of ambidexterity (Hsu, Lien, & Chen,
that ‘‘Coordination with Tier 2 suppliers is more 2013). As we focus on exploiting current FSAs and
complex and difficult, because they have no direct developing new FSAs in international markets, our
contractual relationship. The focal firm might performance measures must not only reflect abso-
request information about its Tier 2 suppliers from lute levels of performance but also relative levels of
its Tier 1 suppliers, which maintains contractual performance (relative to inputs). Similarly, as firms
relationships with both sides. Information about start developing new FSAs and exploit them, our
Tier 3 suppliers is nearly impossible to obtain’’ research must also focus on temporal measures of
(Hartmann & Moeller, 2014, pg. 283). Given the performance. Finally, as a firm starts achieving
procedure of creation of the networks as outlined ambidexterity, it should reflect in stock market
by Wellman (1997) and Hartmann & Moeller performance which takes into consideration both
(2014), we can define our networks as whole BSR short-term and long-term aspects of performance.
networks. In this work, we include multiple performance
6
Our data consists of 303 individual networks of measures to reflect these elements. Consistent with
buyers and suppliers up to Tier 2. For example, the prior literature, international revenue is used as
General Motors (GM) has 293 unique firms in Tier 1 an absolute measure of performance; international
and 6878 unique firms in Tier 2 in its whole ROA and ROA are used as relative measures of
network; and General Electric (GE) has 717 unique performance; growth in international revenue and
firms (445 suppliers + 272 buyers) in Tier 1 and growth in international profits have been used as
5139 unique firms in Tier 2 in its whole network. temporal measures of performance; whereas
The whole network of GM contains 7171 buyers- Tobin’s Q is used as a measure of stock market
suppliers and the whole network of GE contains performance (Katsikeas et al., 2016). However, as
5856 buyers-suppliers. Recent research has outlined exploration and exploitation take place simultane-
that, in general, such data collection is a huge ously in international markets, we use absolute
challenge not only for researchers but also for firms performance (international revenue) as the primary
operating in the real world (Shao, Shi, Choi, & dependent variable in our study (Vahlne & Johan-
Chae, 2018). For example, Shao et al. (2018) have son, 2017b). The correlation between dependent
constructed single buyer–supplier network using variables in the study ranges between - 0.0483 and

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

16
0.7446. While growth in international revenue and Although we do not hypothesize, we account
growth in international profits are highly corre- for the two-way interactions between ND, BC, and
lated (q = 0.7446, p \ 0.000), international ROA CC.
17
and Tobin’s Q has a correlation of 0.587. Tobin’s Q Haans, Peiters, & He (2015) provide guidance
has the lowest correlation with growth in interna- regarding testing the moderation effects in
tional profit (- 0.0483). U-shaped or inverted U-shaped relationships. Fol-
9
Note that ‘‘international profit’’ is not an audited lowing Haans et al., (2015), we now include the
measure and firms do not directly report them in interactions of the quadratic terms with moderat-
the balance sheet. We collect firms’ international ing variables in a separate analysis. We find that the
profit from various sources including news articles estimate of the interaction between quadratic term
in Lexis Nexis, firms’ profit statement in media, of BC and PC to be positive (b = 99,934.01,
analysts’ reports, etc. For example: https://www. p = .036), predicting a flattened curve when we
forbes.com/sites/samanthasharf/2015/04/28/ups- increase PC. This prediction is even reflected in the
delivers-stronger-than-expected-14-earnings- graphical representation when we consider the
growth/#606b82fe32ca captures UPS profit from interaction between linear effect of BC and PC.
international business. Similarly, http:// We also find that the coefficient of the interaction
calgaryherald.com/business/energy/schlumberger- between quadratic term of average clustering coef-
ceo-expects-further-pain-in-oilpatch captures the ficient and average path length to be positive
profit margin of Schlumberger. (b = 114,389.5, p \ 0.085). We did not find the
10
Note that ROA captures a firm’s overall perfor- significant effects of other terms that include the
mance which includes the firm’s IB performance. interaction of PC and AP with quadratic function of
11
We thank an anonymous reviewer for suggest- average clustering coefficient and BC respectively.
18
ing this. This is to note that we estimate a separate
12
With highest VIF = 2.38 and average VIF = model with ‘‘product diversification’’ as an addi-
1.55, multi-collinearity is not a concern in our tional control. Since we could not calculate the
model. measure due to the lack of data for firms outside the
13
We test the validity of instruments using mul- United States, we estimated the model for a sub-
tiple tests. First, F test results for Eq. 6a–6c are sample. We find that product diversification has a
significant (see Table 3). Second, a modified Sargan positive and a significant impact on IBP.
19
test to test the over-identification restrictions show We also estimate our proposed model with
that there is no over identification issue. Third, generalized least square (GLS) approach in order to
Angrist and Pischke F test to perform independent confirm that serial correlation does not influence
tests for the strength of instruments (Angrist & our results. Results are consistent..
20
Pischke, 2008) illustrate that the instruments are When we estimate our model with ROA as the
strong. DV, we remove ROA from the first stage models and
14
Correlation analysis further suggest that the from the list of control variables.
21
correlation between Tier 1 suppliers and dependent While estimating these models, we drop the
variable is less than 0.19, and between Tier1 estimated value of lag (DV) as the DVs are opera-
suppliers and endogenous variables is greater than tionalized as growth variables.
22
0.56 and significant. correlations of The prior work by Kleinbaum & Stuart (2014)
SimNDit ,SimBCit , and SimCCit with IBP are and Regner & Zander (2011) shows that network
0.11,0.21, and 0.12, respectively. Correlations of structure influences ambidexterity. Further, we
SimNDit , SimBCit , SimCCit with ND, BC, and CC are adopt the approach of testing from Sharma et al.
0.74, 0.68, and 0.59, respectively. Similar instru- (2018) where they study the impact of process
ments are used by recent studies (see Saboo, Kumar, characteristics on firm value relying on the mech-
& Anand, 2017). anism of organizational learning/knowledge gain.
15
Capturing country fixed effect is feasible. How- To explore that the mechanism is truly in place,
ever, given the 28 countries in our data and with they have operationalized learning/knowledge as
some countries having only a few observations, we the quality and quantity of patents that a firm
test the country fixed effects in a separate robust- generates and test the impact of process character-
ness analysis. istics on quality and quantity of knowledge gained.

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

Similarly, our proposed mechanism is ambidexter- opposite to that of the directions of the relation-
ity (exploration/exploitation) and we test the ships of the structural characteristics with IBP. We
impact of network characteristics on ambidexterity. find exactly the consistent results.
23 24
We argue and show that structural characteris- https://www.salesforce.com/research/
tics of a firm’s BSR network assist a firm to achieve customer-expectations/.
25
ambidexterity, which in turn impacts IBP. As such, https://www.forbes.com/sites/jwebb/2018/03/
given our new operationalization of ambidexterity, 30/how-to-manage-strategic-suppliers/
the directions of the relationships of the structural #524c73787994.
characteristics with ambidexterity should be

REFERENCES
Ahuja, G. 2000. Collaboration networks, structural holes, and emergence. Journal of Operations Management, 19(3):
innovation: A longitudinal study. Administrative Science Quar- 351–366.
terly, 45(3): 425–455. Choi, T. Y., & Krause D. R. 2006. The supply base and its
Angrist, J. & Pischke, J. 2008. Mostly harmless econometrics. complexity: Implications for transaction costs, risks, respon-
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University. siveness, and innovation. Journal of Operations Management,
Aoki, K. & Wilhelm, M. 2017. The role of ambidexterity in 24(5): 637–652.
managing buyer–supplier relationships: The toyota case. Coleman, J. S. 2000. Social capital in the creation of human
Organization Science, 28(6): 1080–1097. capital, Knowledge and Social Capital. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Autio, E., Sapienza, H. J., & Almeida, J. G. 2000. Effects of age at Collinson, S. & Rugman, A. M. 2008. The regional nature of
entry, knowledge intensity, and imitability on international Japanese multinational business. Journal of International Busi-
growth. Academy of Management Journal, 43(5): 909–924. ness Studies, 39(2): 215–230
Banalieva, E. R. & Dhanaraj, C. 2013. Home-region orientation Coviello, N. E. 2006. The network dynamics of international new
in international expansion strategies. Journal of International ventures. Journal of International Business Studies, 37(5):
Business Studies, 44(2): 89–116. 713–731.
Basole, R. C. 2016. Topological analysis and visualization of Cowen, A.P. 2012. An expanded model of status dynamics: The
interfirm collaboration networks in the electronics industry. effects of status transfer and interfirm coordination. Academy
Decision Support Systems, 83: 22–31. of Management Journal, 55(5): 1169–1186
Bellamy, M. A. & Basole, R. C. 2013. Network analysis of supply DiMaggio, P. J. & Powell, W. W. 1983. The iron cage revisited:
chain systems: A systematic review and future research. Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organi-
Systems Engineering, 16(2): 235–249. zational fields. American Sociological Review, 48(2): 147–160.
Bellamy, M. A., Ghosh, S., & Hora, M. 2014. The influence of Dimov, D. & Milanov, H. 2010. The interplay of need and
supply network structure on firm innovation. Journal of opportunity in venture capital investment syndication. Journal
Operations Management, 32(6): 357–373. of Business Venturing, 25(4): 331–348.
Bello, D. C., Katsikeas, C. S., & Robson, M. J. 2010. Does Dong, J. & Horvath, S. 2007. Understanding network concepts
accommodating a self-serving partner in an international in modules. BMC Systems Biology, 1(1): 24.
marketing alliance pay off? Journal of Marketing, 74(6): 77–93. Ellis, P.D. 2011. Social ties and international entrepreneurship:
Borgatti, S. P. & Halgin, D. S. 2011. On network theory. Opportunities and constraints affecting firm internationaliza-
Organization Science, 22(5): 1168–1181. tion. Journal of International Business Studies, 42(1): 99–127.
Borgatti, S. P. & Li, X. 2009. On social network analysis in a Ernst, D. & Kim, L. 2002. Global production networks, knowl-
supply chain context. Journal of Supply Chain Management, edge diffusion, and local capability formation. Research Policy,
45(2): 5–22. 31(8–9): 1417–1429.
Bos, B., Faems, D., & Noseleit, F. 2017. Alliance Concentration Fang, E., Lee, J., Palmatier, R., & Han, S. 2016. If it takes a village
in Multinational Companies: Examining Alliance Portfolios, to foster innovation, success depends on the neighbors: The
Firm Structure, and Firm Performance. Strategic Management effects of global and ego networks on new product launches.
Journal, 38(11): 2298–2309 Journal of Marketing Research, 53(3): 319–337.
Brown, J. R., & Dant, R. P. 2008. On what makes a significant Farjoun, M. 2010. Beyond dualism: Stability and change as a
contribution to the retailing literature. Journal of Retailing, duality. Academy of Management Review, 35(2): 202–225.
84(2): 131–135. Forsgren, M. 2016. A note on the revisited Uppsala internation-
Burt, R. S. 2009. Structural holes: The social structure of alization process model–the implications of business networks
competition. Harvard: Harvard University Press. and entrepreneurship. Journal of International Business Studies,
Capar, N. & Kotabe, M. 2003. The relationship between 47(9): 1135–1144.
international diversification and performance in service firms. Gargiulo, M., Ertug, G., & Galunic, C. 2009. The two faces of
Journal of International Business Studies, 34(4): 345–355. control: Network closure and individual performance among
Carpenter, M. A., Li, M., & Jiang, H. 2012. Social network knowledge workers. Administrative Science Quarterly, 54(2):
research in organizational contexts: A systematic review of 299–333.
methodological issues and choices. Journal of Management, Gibson, C.B., & Birkinshaw, J. 2004. The antecedents, conse-
38(4): 1328–1361. quences, and mediating role of organizational ambidexterity.
Chakravarty, A., Kumar, A., & Grewal, R. 2014. Customer Academy of Management Journal, 47.2: 209–226.
orientation structure for internet-based business-to-business Gnyawali, D.R., & Madhavan, R. 2001. Cooperative networks
platform firms. Journal of Marketing, 78(5): 1–23. and competitive dynamics: A structural embeddedness per-
Chandra, Y. & Wilkinson, I. F. 2017. Firm internationalization spective. Academy of Management Review, 26(3): 431–445.
from a network-centric complex-systems perspective. Journal Granovetter, M. 2005. The impact of social structure on
of World Business, 52(5): 691–701. economic outcomes. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(1):
Choi, T.Y., Dooley, K.J., & Rungtusanatham, M. 2001. Supply 33–50.
networks and complex adaptive systems: control versus

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

Grewal, R., Lilien, G. L., & Mallapragada, G. 2006. Location, Katsikeas, C. S., Morgan, N. A., Leonidou, L. C., & Hult, G. T. M.
location, location: How network embeddedness affects project 2016. Assessing performance outcomes in marketing. Journal
success in open source systems. Management Science, 52(7): of Marketing, 80(2): 1–20.
1043–1056. Kenis, P. & Knoke, D. 2002. How organizational field networks
Gulati, R. 1998. Alliances and networks. Strategic Management shape interorganizational tie-formation rates. Academy of
Journal, 19(4): 293–317. Management Review, 27(2): 275–293.
Guler, I. & Guillen, M. F. 2010. Home country networks and Khoja, F., Adams, J., & Kauffman, R. 2011. The inside story of
foreign expansion: Evidence from the venture capital industry. relationship development: power asymmetry in a buyer?
Academy of Management Journal, 53(2): 390–410. supplier relationship. International Journal of Integrated Supply
Haans, R. F., Pieters, C., & He, Z. L. 2016. Thinking about U: Management, 6(1): 73–91.
Theorizing and testing U-and inverted U-shaped relationships Kim, C. & Park, J.-H. 2010. The global research-and-develop-
in strategy research. Strategic Management Journal, 37(7): ment network and its effect on innovation. Journal of Interna-
1177–1195. tional Marketing, 18(4): 43–57.
Hartmann, J., and Moeller, S. 2014. Chain liability in multitier Kim, D.-Y. 2014. Understanding supplier structural embedded-
supply chains? Responsibility attributions for unsustainable ness: A social network perspective. Journal of Operations
supplier behavior. Journal of Operations Management, 32(5): Management, 32(5): 219–231.
281–294. Kim, M. 2016. Geographic scope, isolating mechanisms, and
Hausman, J. A. 1978. Specification tests in econometrics. value appropriation. Strategic Management Journal, 37(4):
Econometrica, 46(6): 1251–1271. 695–713.
Hayes, A. F., & Preacher, K. J. (2010). Quantifying and testing Kim, Y., Choi, T. Y., Yan, T., & Dooley, K. 2011. Structural
indirect effects in simple mediation models when the con- investigation of supply networks: A social network analysis
stituent paths are nonlinear. Multivariate Behavioral Research, approach. Journal of Operations Management, 29(3): 194–211.
45(4), 627–660. Kirca, A. H., Hult, G. T. M., Deligonul, S., Perryy, M. Z., &
He, Z. L., & Wong, P. K. 2004. Exploration vs. exploitation: An Cavusgil, S. T. 2012. A multilevel examination of the drivers of
empirical test of the ambidexterity hypothesis. Organization firm multinationality: A meta-analysis. Journal of Management,
science, 15(4): 481–494. 38(2): 502–530.
Heckmann, J. J. 1979. Sample selection bias as a specification Kleinbaum, A. M., & Stuart, T. E. (2014). Network responsive-
error. Econometrica, 47 (1): 153–161. ness: The social structural microfoundations of dynamic
Hsu, C.W., Lien, Y.C., & Chen, H. 2013. International ambidex- capabilities. Academy of Management Perspectives, 28(4),
terity and firm performance in small emerging economies. 353–367.
Journal of World Business, 48(1): 58–67. Kortmann, S., Gelhard, C., Zimmermann, C., & Piller, F. T.
Hult, G. T. M., Ketchen Jr, D. J., Griffith, D. A., Chabowski, B. R., 2014. Linking strategic flexibility and operational efficiency:
Hamman, M. K., Dykes, B. J., Pollitte, W. A., & Cavusgil, S. T. The mediating role of ambidextrous operational capabilities.
2008. An assessment of the measurement of performance in Journal of Operations Management, 32(7–-8): 475–490.
international business research. Journal of International Business Kotabe, M., Martin, X., & Domoto, H. 2003. Gaining from
Studies, 39(6): 1064–1080. vertical partnerships: knowledge transfer, relationship dura-
Im, G. & Rai, A. 2008. Knowledge sharing ambidexterity in long- tion, and supplier performance improvement in the US and
term interorganizational relationships. Management Science, Japanese automotive industries. Strategic Management Journal,
54(7): 1281–1296. 24(4): 293–316.
Ireland, R. D. & Webb, J. W. 2007. A multi-theoretic perspective Kristal, M. M., Huang, X., & Roth, A. V. 2010. The effect of an
on trust and power in strategic supply chains. Journal of ambidextrous supply chain strategy on combinative compet-
Operations Management, 25(2): 482–497. itive capabilities and business performance. Journal of Opera-
Iurkov, V. & Benito, G. R. 2017. Domestic alliance networks and tions Management, 28(5): 415–429.
regional strategies of MNEs: A structural embeddedness Kukkala, V. B., Saini, J. S., & Iyengar, S. 2016. Privacy preserving
perspective. Journal of International Business Studies: 1–27. network analysis of distributed social networks. Berlin: Springer.
Jean, R. J., Kim, D., & Sinkovics, R. R. 2012. Drivers and Kumar, S. & Jan, J. M. 2014. Research collaboration networks of
performance outcomes of supplier innovation generation in two OIC nations: Comparative study between Turkey and
customer–supplier relationships: The role of power-depen- Malaysia in the field of ‘Energy Fuels’, 2009–2011. Sciento-
dence. Decision Sciences, 43(6): 1003–1038. metrics, 98(1): 387–414.
Jensen, M. & Roy, A. 2008. Staging exchange partner choices: Lazer, D. & Friedman, A. 2007. The network structure of
When do status and reputation matter? Academy of Manage- exploration and exploitation. Administrative Science Quarterly,
ment Journal, 51(3): 495–516. 52(4): 667–694.
Johanson, J. & Vahlne, J.-E. 1977. The internationalization Lazzarini, S. G., Claro, D. P., & Mesquita, L. F. 2008. Buyer–
process of the firm—a model of knowledge development supplier and supplier–supplier alliances: do they reinforce or
and increasing foreign market commitments. Journal of Inter- undermine one another? Journal of Management Studies,
national Business Studies, 8(1): 23–32. 45(3): 561–584.
Johanson, J. & Vahlne, J.-E. 2009. The Uppsala internationaliza- Lee, S.-Y., Klassen, R. D., Furlan, A., & Vinelli, A. 2014. The green
tion process model revisited: From liability of foreignness to bullwhip effect: Transferring environmental requirements
liability of outsidership. Journal of International Business Studies, along a supply chain. International Journal of Production
40(9): 1411–1431. Economics, 156: 39–51.
Junni, P., Sarala, R. M., Taras, V., & Tarba, S. Y. 2013. Li, X. 2014. Can Yin-Yang guide Chinese indigenous manage-
Organizational ambidexterity and performance: A meta-anal- ment research? Management and Organization Review, 10(1):
ysis. Academy of Management Perspectives, 27(4): 299–312. 7–28.
Kaiser, M. & Hilgetag, C. C. 2004. Edge vulnerability in neural Lorenzen, M. & Mudambi, R. 2012. Clusters, connectivity and
and metabolic networks. Biological Cybernetics, 90(5): catch-up: Bollywood and Bangalore in the global economy.
311–317. Journal of Economic Geography, 13(3): 501–534.
Kano, L. 2017. Global value chain governance: A relational Lu, G. & Shang, G. 2017. Impact of supply base structural
perspective. Journal of International Business Studies (2017) complexity on financial performance: Roles of visible and not-
1–22. so-visible characteristics. Journal of Operations Management,
53: 23–44.

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

Luo, Y. & Rui, H. 2009. An ambidexterity perspective toward Shrader, R. C. 2001. Collaboration and performance in foreign
multinational enterprises from emerging economies. Academy markets: The case of young high-technology manufacturing
of Management Perspectives, 23(4): 49–70. firms. Academy of Management Journal, 44(1): 45–60.
Maddala, G. S. 1983. Limited-dependent and qualitative variables Shao, B. B., Shi, Z. M., Choi, T. Y., & Chae, S. 2018. A data-
in econometrics. Boston, MA: Cambridge University Press. analytics approach to identifying hidden critical suppliers in
March, J. G. 1991. Exploration and exploitation in organiza- supply networks: Development of nexus supplier index.
tional learning. Organization Science, 2(1): 71–87. Decision Support Systems, 114, 37–48.
Martin, X., Swaminathan, A., & Mitchell, W. 1998. Organiza- Saboo, A. R., Kumar, V., & Anand, A. 2017. Assessing the Impact
tional evolution in the interorganizational environment: of Customer Concentration on Initial Public Offering and
Incentives and constraints on international expansion strategy. Balance Sheet–Based Outcomes. Journal of Marketing, 81(6):
Administrative Science Quarterly: 566–601. 42–61.
McEvily, B., Perrone, V., & Zaheer, A. 2003. Trust as an Simsek, Z. 2009. Organizational ambidexterity: Towards a
organizing principle. Organization Science, 14(1), 91–103. multilevel understanding. Journal of Management Studies,
Mizik, N. & Jacobson, R. 2003. Trading off between value 46(4): 597–624.
creation and value appropriation: The financial implications of Spencer, J. W. 2003. Global gatekeeping, representation, and
shifts in strategic emphasis. Journal of Marketing, 67(1): 63–76. network structure: a longitudinal analysis of regional and
Nobeoka, K., Dyer, J. H., & Madhok, A. 2002. The influence of global knowledge-diffusion networks. Journal of International
customer scope on supplier learning and performance in the Business Studies, 34(5): 428–442.
Japanese automobile industry. Journal of International Business Spender, J. C. 1989. Industry recipes: An enquiry into the nature
Studies, 33(4): 717–736. and sources of managerial judgement. Cambridge, MA: Basil
Obloj, T. & Zemsky, P. 2015. Value creation and value capture Blackwell.
under moral hazard: Exploring the micro-foundations of Stadtfeld, C. 2012. Events in social networks: A stochastic actor-
buyer–supplier relationships. Strategic Management Journal, oriented framework for dynamic event processes in social
36(8): 1146–1163. networks. Karlsruhe: KITg.
Oehme, M. & Bort, S. 2015. SME internationalization modes in Swaminathan, V., & Moorman, C. 2009. Marketing alliances,
the German biotechnology industry: The influence of imita- firm networks, and firm value creation. Journal of Market-
tion, network position, and international experience. Journal of ing, 73(5) 52–69.
International Business Studies, 46(6): 629–655. Thomaz, F. & Swaminathan, V. 2015. What goes around comes
Patel, P. C., Fernhaber, S. A., McDougall-Covin, P. P., & van der around: The impact of marketing alliances on firm risk and the
Have, R. P. 2014. Beating competitors to international moderating role of network density. Journal of Marketing,
markets: The value of geographically balanced networks for 79(5): 63–79.
innovation. Strategic Management Journal, 35(5): 691–711. Thye, S. R. 2000. A status value theory of power in exchange
Patel, P. C., Terjesen, S., & Li, D. 2012. Enhancing effects of relations. American Sociological Review: 407–432.
manufacturing flexibility through operational absorptive Tsai, W. 2002. Social structure of ‘‘coopetition’’ within a
capacity and operational ambidexterity. Journal of Operations multiunit organization: Coordination, competition, and
Management, 30(3): 201–220. intraorganizational knowledge sharing. Organization Science,
Petrin, A. & Train, K. 2010. A control function approach to 13(2): 179–190.
endogeneity in consumer choice models. Journal of Marketing Turkina, E. & Van Assche, A. 2018. Global connectedness and
Research, 47(1): 3–13. local innovation in industrial clusters. Journal of International
Phillips, N., Lawrence, T. B., & Hardy, C. 2000. Inter-organiza- Business Studies,49(6): 1–23.
tional collaboration and the dynamics of institutional fields. Uotila, J.,Maula, M., Keil,T., & Zahra, S.A. 2009. Exploration,
Journal of Management Studies, 37(1). exploitation, and financial performance: analysis of S&P 500
Provan, K. G., Fish, A., & Sydow, J. 2007. Interorganizational corporations. Strategic Management Journal, 30(2): 221–231.
networks at the network level: A review of the empirical Uzzi, B. 1997. Social structure and competition in interfirm
literature on whole networks. Journal of Management, 33(3): networks: The paradox of embeddedness. Administrative
479–516. Science Quarterly, 42(1): 35–67.
Provan, K. G. & Milward, H. B. 1995. A preliminary theory of Uzzi, B. & Spiro, J. 2005. Collaboration and creativity: The small
interorganizational network effectiveness: A comparative world problem 1. American Journal of Sociology, 111(2):
study of four community mental health systems. Administra- 447–504.
tive Science Quarterly: 1–33. Vahlne, J.-E. & Johanson, J. 2017a. From internationalization to
Provan, K. G. & Skinner, S. J. 1989. Interorganizational depen- evolution: The Uppsala model at 40 years. Journal of Interna-
dence and control as predictors of opportunism in dealer- tional Business Studies, 48(9): 1087–1102.
supplier relations. Academy of Management Journal, 32(1): Vahlne, J.-E. & Jonsson, A. 2017b. Ambidexterity as a dynamic
202–212. capability in the globalization of the multinational business
Regner, P., & Zander, U. 2011. Knowledge and strategy creation enterprise (MBE): Case studies of AB Volvo and IKEA. Interna-
in multinational companies. Management International tional Business Review, 26(1): 57–70.
Review, 51(6):821–850. Verbeke, A. 2003. The evolutionary view of the MNE and the
Rowley, T., Behrens, D., & Krackhardt, D. 2000. Redundant future of internalization theory. Journal of International Business
governance structures: An analysis of structural and relational Studies, 34(6): 498–504.
embeddedness in the steel and semiconductor industries. Villena, V. H., Revilla, E., & Choi, T. Y. 2011. The dark side of
Strategic Management Journal, 21(3): 369–386. buyer–supplier relationships: A social capital perspective.
Rugman, A. M. & Verbeke, A. 2003. Extending the theory of the Journal of Operations Management, 29(6): 561–576.
multinational enterprise: Internalization and strategic man- Wellman, B. (1997). Structural analysis: From method and
agement perspectives. Journal of International Business Studies, metaphor to theory and substance. Contemporary Studies in
34(2): 125–137. Sociology, 15, 19–61.
Rugman, A. M. & Verbeke, A. 2001. Subsidiary-specific advan- Werner, S., Brouthers, L. E., & Brouthers, K. D. 1996. Interna-
tages in multinational enterprises. Strategic Management tional risk and perceived environmental uncertainty: the
Journal, 22(3): 237–250. dimensionality and internal consistency of Miller’s measure.
Schilling, M. A. & Phelps, C. C. 2007. Interfirm collaboration Journal of International Business Studies, 27(3): 571–587.
networks: The impact of large-scale network structure on firm
innovation. Management Science, 53(7): 1113–1126.

Journal of International Business Studies


Buyer–supplier networks and IB performance Amalesh Sharma et al

Wuyts, S. & Geyskens, I. 2005. The formation of buyer—supplier in multiple countries with prestigious awards and
relationships: detailed contract drafting and close partner fellowships including the Chang Jiang Scholar,
selection. Journal of Marketing, 69(4): 103–117.
Yan, T., Choi, T. Y., Kim, Y., & Yang, Y. 2015. A theory of the HUST, China; Lee Kong Chian Fellow, Singapore
nexus supplier: A critical supplier from a network perspective. Management University, Singapore; Senior Fellow,
Journal of Supply Chain Management, 51(1): 52–66. Indian School of Business, India; and Hagler Fellow,
Yang, H., Lin, Z. J., & Lin, Y. L. 2010. A multilevel framework of
firm boundaries: firm characteristics, dyadic differences, and Hagler Institute for Advanced Study, TAMU, Col-
network attributes. Strategic Management Journal, 31(3): lege Station, Texas. VK has also been recognized as
237–261. a Legend in Marketing where his works were
Yamane, Taro. 1967. Statistics, An Introductory Analysis, 2nd Ed.,
New York: Harper and Row. released as a 10-Volume encyclopedia with com-
Yli-Renko, H. & Janakiraman, R. 2008. How customer portfolio mentaries from scholars worldwide.
affects new product development in technology-based entre-
preneurial firms. Journal of Marketing, 72(5): 131–148.
Yu, J., Gilbert, B. A., & Oviatt, B. M. 2011. Effects of alliances, Jun Yan is Associate Professor of Marketing and a
time, and network cohesion on the initiation of foreign sales member of V. Kumar International Marketing Sci-
by new ventures. Strategic Management Journal, 32(4): ence Institute at the School of Management,
424–446.
Zaheer, A., Gözübüyük, R., & Milanov, H. 2010. It’s the Huazhong University of Science and Technology.
connections: The network perspective in interorganizational She obtained her Ph.D. in Marketing from Wuhan
research. Academy of Management Perspectives, 24(1): 62–77. University, China. Her research interests cover
Zaheer, A. & Kamal, D. F. 2011. Creating trust in piranha-
infested waters: The confluence of buyer, supplier and host multi-channel marketing, integrated marketing
country contexts. Journal of International Business Studies, communication, and customer relationship man-
42(1): 48–55. agement. Her research has been published in multi-
disciplinary academic journals including Interna-
tional Journal of Market Research, Journal of
ABOUT THE AUTHORS Interactive Advertising, Journal of Euromarketing,
Amalesh Sharma is an Assistant Professor of Mar- Internet Research, Computers in Human behavior
keting at the Mays Business School at Texas A&M and some of the leading Chinese business journals.
University. He earned his Ph.D. in Marketing from She is a Chinese citizen.
the Georgia State University, Atlanta. Amalesh is
interested in studying the impact of firm and cus- Sourav Bikash Borah is an Assistant Professor of
tomer level strategies on firms’ performance. His Marketing at Indian Institute of Management (IIM)
substantive areas of interest include Supply Net- Ahmedabad, India. Sourav completed his Fellow
work, Innovation, Marketing-Mix Decisions, Cus- Management Program in Marketing from IIM Ban-
tomer Management, and International Business. galore. Sourav is interested in firm level strategy
research where he is interested in investigating
V. Kumar is the Regents’ Professor, Richard and service management strategy, supplier-relation-
Susan Lenny Distinguished Chair, and Professor of ships, and business strategies in emerging markets.
Marketing, and Executive Director, Center for
Excellence in Brand and Customer Management, J. Anirban Adhikary is an Assistant Professor of
Mack Robinson College of Business, Georgia State Operations Management, Quantitative Methods
University, Atlanta. VK has been recognized with and Information Systems Area at Indian Institute of
15 lifetime achievement awards in several areas in Management Udaipur, India. He has completed his
Marketing from the American Marketing Associa- Fellow Management Program in operations man-
tion (AMA) and other professional organizations. agement from IIM Bangalore. His research interest
VK has published over 250 articles, 25 books, and includes operational issues in firms’ supply chain
has received over 25 Best Paper, Research and management and firm performance.
Teaching Excellence Awards. VK has been honored

Publisher’s Note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional
affiliations.

Supplementary information accompanies this article on the Journal of International Business Studies website (www.palgrave.com/ journals).

Accepted by Constantine Katsikeas, Area Editor, 10 November 2018. This article has been with the authors for four revisions.

Journal of International Business Studies

Potrebbero piacerti anche