Sei sulla pagina 1di 7

Economic Modelling 35 (2013) 185–191

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Economic Modelling
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/ecmod

Tourism–growth nexus in Pakistan: Evidence from ARDL bounds tests


Abdul Jalil a,⁎, Tahir Mahmood b, Muhammad Idrees a
a
School of Economics, Quaid-i-Azam University, Islamabad 45320, Pakistan
b
Department of Economics, Abdul Wali Khan University Mardan, Pakistan

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: This study is an attempt to test the long run relationship between international tourism and economic growth of
Accepted 24 June 2013 Pakistan by using Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) models over the period of 1972 to 2011. The initial
results show that the causality runs from tourism to economic growth. Furthermore, the estimated growth
JEL classification:
regression clearly indicates that the international tourism has a significantly positive impact on the economic
C32
growth of Pakistan along with other variables like physical capital and international trade. This implies that
L83
O11
the improvement in the tourism sector may enhance the economic growth activities in Pakistan.
© 2013 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Keywords:
Tourism
Economic growth
ARDL bounds tests
Pakistan

1. Introduction different econometric techniques and provide inconclusive results


(see Table 1).
Indeed, the tourism industry is an important business sector of the The findings of the different studies can be summarized into four
world. The importance of this sector can be manifested from the fact main hypotheses. First, Tourism-led growth hypothesis suggests that
that it raises revenues, generates employment opportunities, encourages there is a unidirectional relationship from tourism to economic growth.
the private sector and develops infrastructure (Gee, 1999). Recently, it is According to this hypothesis, the inbound tourism growth is one of the
generating about 9% of the total GDP and 8% of the employment oppor- engines of economic growth. Therefore, the restrictions on the inbound
tunities of the world (World Economic Forum, 2011).1 The researchers tourists may hurt the process of economic growth. However, the
observe that the trickledown effect of tourism development not only en- hypothesis of tourism-led growth is found mostly in small countries
hances the tourism sector but also triggers overall economic growth (Lee such as Mexico (Brida et al., 2010), Taiwan (Chen and Wei, 2009),
and Chang, 2008). Therefore, the tourism sector has gained tremendous Spain, Italy (Jimenez, 2008), South Africa (Akinboade and Braimoh,
academic attention as an important determinant of the economic growth 2010) and Jordan (Kreishan, 2011). Second growth-led tourism hypoth-
of an economy. esis shows that there is a unidirectional causality from economic growth
The economists suggest different channels through which the tour- to improvement in the inbound tourism (Oh, 2005). It implies that the
ism sector may improve the level of economic growth of a country. For restrictions on the international tourists have no or little adverse effects
example, the tourism industry contributes to economic growth by on the economic growth of the country. Third, feedback hypothesis indi-
increasing efficiency via competition between domestic firms and inter- cates that there is bidirectional causality between inbound tourism and
national tourist's destination (Bhagwati and Srinivasan, 1979; Krueger, economic growth. It implies that the inbound tourism and economic
1980) and by creating economies of scale in the local firms (Helpman growth jointly determine each other. This line of research is also not
and Krugman, 1985). Similarly, Lim (1997) and Oh (2005) point out an infant and a number of studies find the bidirectional causality be-
that the improvement in the inbound tourism is an important source tween tourism and economic growth for various countries (Dritsakis,
of rise in the income of household and government revenues. 2004; Durbarry, 2004). Fourth, neutrality hypothesis holds when no cau-
The causal relationship between tourism and economic growth is sality exists between international tourism and economic growth (Kim
well documented in the literature of tourism economics. Different et al., 2006; Ozturk and Ali, 2009). It implies that any restriction on the
studies focused on different countries, sample periods, variables and international tourism policies does not affect the economic growth and
economic growth does not necessarily mean that international tourism
⁎ Corresponding author.
is improving.
E-mail addresses: jalil.hanif@gmail.com (A. Jalil), midrees@qau.edu.pk (M. Idrees). Since the direction of causality has some certain policy implications, it
1
Travel and Tourism Competitiveness Index (TTCI) 2011covers 139 economies. is important to reexamine the tourism–growth relationship in the

0264-9993/$ – see front matter © 2013 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2013.06.034
186 A. Jalil et al. / Economic Modelling 35 (2013) 185–191

Table 1
Tourism growth nexus.

Authors Time coverage Econometric methodology Country coverage Causal relationship

Multi country cases


Lanza et al. (2003) 1977–1992 Almost ideal demand systems 13 OECD countries Tourism → growth
Adamos and Sofranis (2005). 1981–2004 Fixed effect estimation 162 Countries Tourism → growth
Skerrit and Huybers (2005) 1965–1992 Ordinary least square 37 Developing countries Tourism → growth
Neves and Paula (2008) 1982–2002 GMM and LSDV 94 Countries Tourism → growth
Po and Huang (2008) 1995–2005 Threshold autoregressive model 88 Countries Tourism → growth
Lee and Chang (2008) 1992–2002 Panel co-integration OECD and non-OECD countries Tourism → growth
Holzar (2010) 1970–2007 Ordinary least square 134 Countries Tourism → growth
Seetanah (2011) 1990–2007 GMM–Granger causality test 19 Islands Tourism → growth
Tiwari (2011) 1995–2008 Fixed and random effect models China, Pakistan, Russia, and India Tourism → growth

Single country cases


Balaguer and Cantavella-Jorda (2002) 1975–1997 Johansen co-integration Spain Tourism → growth
Dritsakis (2004) 1960–2000 Error correction model Greece Tourism ↔ growth
Durbarry (2004) 1952–1999 Error correction model Mauritius Tourism ↔ growth
Narayan (2004) 1970–2000 Error correction model Fiji Tourism → growth
Oh (2005). 1975–2001 Granger causality test Korea Growth → tourism
Kim et al. (2006) 1956–2002 Granger causality test Taiwan Tourism ≠ growth
Sr and Croes (2003) 1975–2000 Co-integration Aruba Tourism → growth
Jimenez (2008) 1990–2004 Dynamic panel techniques Spain and Italy Tourism → growth
Kaplan and Celik (2008) 1963–2005 VAR model Turkey Tourism → growth
Ozturk and Ali (2009) 1987–2007 ARDL Turkey Tourism ≠ growth
Chen and Wei (2009) 1975–2007 EGARCH-M Taiwan Tourism → growth
South Korea Growth ↔ tourism
Katircioglu (2009) 1960–2005 Granger causality test Cyprus Growth → tourism
Malik et al. (2010) 1972–2007 Johansen co-integration Pakistan Tourism → growth
Akinboade and Braimoh (2010) 1980–2005 VAR model South Africa Tourism → growth
Brida et al. (2008) 1980–2007 Johansen co-integration Mexico Tourism → growth
Noor (2009) 1973–2007 Johansen co-integration Pakistan Tourism → growth
Brida et al. (2010) 1987–2006 Johansen co-integration Mexico Tourism → growth
Chancharat and Chaancharat (2010) 1979–2007 Gregory–Hansen test Thailand Tourism → growth
Khalil et al. (2010) 1960–2005 Johansen co-integration Pakistan Growth ↔ tourism
Tang (2011) 1995–2009 Error correction model Malaysia Growth ↔ tourism
Kreishan (2011) 1970–2009 Johansen co-integration Jordan Tourism → growth

Note: “Tourism → growth” denotes causality running from tourism development to economic growth. “Growth → tourism” denotes causality running from economic growth to
tourism development. “Growth ↔ tourism” denotes bidirectional causality between tourism development and economic growth. Tourism ≠ growth denotes that neither tourism
is effecting growth nor growth is effecting tourism.

presence of contradictory claims of different studies. In particular, it be- the best of our knowledge, available for Pakistan (for example Khalil
comes more important in the absence of a study which is based on the et al., 2010; Malik et al., 2010; Noor, 2009). But these are based either
longer data set. The present study is an attempt in the same direction on the estimation of tourism demand functions or on using the traditional
and the objective of this study is to come out with an evidence that econometric procedures. The present study is an attempt to fill this gap.
shows to what extent Pakistan economic growth reacts to the We try to investigate the long run relationships between tourism and
evolution process of inbound tourism activity during the period of economic growth by using a relatively new co-integration technique
1972 to 2011. popularized with the name of Autoregressive Distributive Lag (ARDL)
There are several reasons for choosing Pakistan as a case study to model over the period of 1972 to 2011.
test the tourism–growth nexus. Pakistan has unprecedented potential The remainder of the study is organized as follows. Section 2 sets the
to become an important tourist destination of the world due to its analytical framework of the study. The econometric methodology is
pure landscapes and diverse culture. For example, different land- presented in Section 3. Section 4 discusses variable construction and
scapes, ranging from the snow-capped mountains in the North to data sources. Empirical results are given and discussed in Section 5.
the sunny beaches in the South, coupled with the lush green valleys Finally, Section 6 concludes and gives some policy implication.
and skyscraper mountains such as the scenic Himalayan hills and K2
are the main sources of attraction for international tourists. Further- 2. Analytical framework
more, ancient civilization such as the Mohenjo-Daro, Harappa and
Taxila has its own worth to prove that Pakistan is a tourist's heaven. The empirical investigation carried out in the present article is based
Importantly, Pakistan received more than 50,000 international tour- on the standard Cobb–Douglas production function, with constant
ists per annum before global economic crisis. According to World returns, within the neoclassical framework having Hicks neutral tech-
Economic Forum (2011), the overall share of travel and tourism is nological process.
6.5% of total gross domestic product (GDP). Furthermore, World
Economic Forum (2011) projected that travel and tourism will generate α
Y t ¼ At K t ð1Þ
about 3.43 million employment opportunities in 2011, which is 5.7% of
total employment level. Furthermore, the share of travel and tourism in
exports is 86 billion rupees, in 2011. It is also important to mention that where Yt is real per capita GDP; At is total factor productivity; Kt is per
it improved its ranking from 125 in 2009 to 113 in 2010 according to worker capital series.
World Economic Forum (2011). This type of production function is expanded in the literature of
All these facts provide a substantial support for conducting a study macroeconomics in several ways. The researchers suggest a number of
to test the impact of tourism in explaining the economic growth of variables that affect economic growth, for example inbound tourism
Pakistan. Unfortunately, despite its importance, little attention has been (Jimenez, 2008; Tang, 2011; Kreishan, 2011), physical capital stock
paid to its quantitative analysis. There are very few studies, according to (Lucas, 1988; Mankiw et al., 1992), trade openness (Grossman and
A. Jalil et al. / Economic Modelling 35 (2013) 185–191 187

Helpman, 1991; Lucas, 1988; Young, 1991) and inflation (Sidrauski, order of integrations and it is applicable irrespective of whether the
1967; Faria, 2001). regressors are I(0) or I(1) order of cointegration (Pesaran and Pesaran,
Therefore, it is plausible to assume: 1997). Pesaran and Shin (1999) note that ARDL estimators produce the
true parameters as compared to Johansen and Juselius's cointegration
At ¼ f ðT; Z t Þ ð2Þ technique in the case of small sample and coefficients from the ARDL
estimators are super consistent in small sample sizes. Therefore, this is
where Zt is a vector of growth improving variables like the indicators more relevant in our case where we have a data series of 40 annual
of tourism development, capital stocks, trade openness, inflation and observations. Furthermore, the endogeneity is less a problem in ARDL
other macroeconomic policies and T incorporating the time dynamics. framework because it is free of residual correlation. Pesaran and Shin
We have discussed in the last section that tourism is an important (1999) have shown that the ARDL method can distinguish between
determinant of economic growth. However, there are several other dependent and explanatory variables and the estimation is possible
variables, along with tourism, that may affect economic growth. The even when the explanatory variables are endogenous (Pesaran and
relationship between trade openness and economic growth is a long Pesaran, 1997; Pesaran et al., 2001). This is an important issue in the
debated issue in the theoretical and empirical literature of economics. case of tourism–growth nexus, because the published research presents
For example, Grossman and Helpman (1991), Lucas (1988), Young the mixed result on the direction of causality of tourism and economic
(1991) and Rivera–Batiz and Xie (1993) note that trade openness growth. Therefore, the ARDL modeling is adopted in this study.
has negative effect on individual country, while Harrison (1996) doc- ARDL framework of Eq. (3) is as follows:
uments that trade openness has a strong and positive impact on eco-
nomic growth. Similarly, Lee (1993) and Edwards (1998) document the Xp X p X p
negative relationship between average tariff rates and economic growth. Δ lnyt ¼ α 0 þ α 1 Δ lnyt−i þ α 2 Δ ln tourt−i þ α 3 Δtradet−i
The inconclusive results imply that the results of trade openness may not X p i¼1 Xi¼1
p i¼1

be generalized for Pakistan. Therefore, we include it in our growth regres- þ α 4 Δcapitalt−i þ α 5 Δ ln cpit−i þ λ1 ln yt−1
i¼1 i¼1
sion for quantifying its impact in the case of Pakistan.
þλ2 ln tourt−1 þ λ3 tradet−1 þ λ4 capitalt−1 þ λ5 ln cpit−1 þ εt :
Capital stock, according to neoclassical growth theory, is another im-
portant determinant of economic growth. Most of the studies established ð4Þ
a positive and significant relationship between capital stock and eco-
nomic growth (Lucas, 1988; Mankiw et al., 1992). Similarly, the debate On the right-hand side, the expression from λ1 to λ5 depicts the
on inflation and economic growth is somewhat controversial. Consider- long-run relationship between the variables, while the expression
ing the length of time, inflation has contrasting impact on economic from α1 to α5 with the summation signs corresponds to the short-run
growth. In the short-run inflation has negative effect on growth rate of dynamics of the variables. On the other hand, α0 represents drift con-
output, while in the long-run GDP growth rate is not affected by persis- stant and εt is Gaussian white noise.
tent high level (Sidrauski, 1967; Faria, 2001). Importantly, an inflation The complete results for short-run and long-run dynamics through
rate within a moderate range is necessary for the health of the economy ARDL bounds testing are obtained through several steps and procedure.
in the case of Pakistan (Mallik and Chowdhury, 2001; Mubarak, 2005), In the first step, Eq. (4) will be estimated through ordinary least square
while a moderate and low level of inflation is harmful to the growth (OLS) method and F-test will be conducted to test the existence of long
rate of output (Lim, 1997). These contradictory findings motivate us to run relationship among the variables of Eq. (3).
include the inflation indicator in growth regression. The null hypothesis in Eq. (4) is H0 : λ1 = λ2 = λ3 = λ4 = λ5 = 0.
Keeping all above theoretical argument in view, we specify an This means the nonexistence of long run relationship. While the alterna-
econometrically estimable equation, following Katircioglu (2009), as tive is H1:λ1 ≠ 0,λ2 ≠ 0,λ3 ≠ 0,λ4 ≠ 0,λ5 ≠ 0.
follows: The calculated F-statistics value is compared with upper and lower
critical values which are given by Pesaran et al. (2001). If calculated
yt ¼ α þ β1 tourt þ β2 tradet þ β3 capitalt þ β4 cpit þ μ t ð3Þ F-value exceeds the upper critical value, then null hypothesis of no
cointegration will be rejected irrespective of whether the variable are
where yt is the natural log of per capita real GDP, tourt is the natural log I(0) or I(1). In the second step, we will estimate long run relationship
per capita international tourism receipt, capitalt is the natural log of per using the selected ARDL model through R2 criterion, Hannan Quinn
capita physical capital formation, tradet is the natural log of trade to GDP Criterion, Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) and Schwarz Criterion
ratio, cpit is consumer price index which is a proxy for inflation and u is (SBC). The following error correction model is estimated in the third
Gaussian error term. step.

3. Econometric methodology Xp Xp Xp
Δyi ¼ β0 þ δi Δyt−i þ ϕi Δtourt−i þ ϖi Δtradet−i
As we have mentioned in the section of literature review a large vol- X p i¼1 X
i¼1 p i¼1 ð5Þ
ume of tourism–growth literature is based on Engle and Granger (1987), þ λi Δcapitalt−i þ θi Δcpit−i þ αECM t−1 þ U t :
i¼1 i¼1
Johansen (1991) and Johansen and Juselius (1990) cointegration tech-
niques. However, using the same methods with the same variables has
no more potential of any original contribution, because it increases The error correction model result indicates the speed of adjustment
only the number of conflicting results with varying time periods and back to long run equilibrium after a short run shock.
we have serious doubts on the policies of tourism management. We Several diagnostic tests are conducted to ensure the goodness of fit of
use the Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) model to avoid this prob- the model. These tests examine the serial correlation, functional form,
lem. None of the studies, according to best of our knowledge, available normality and heteroscedasticity associated with the selected model.
for Pakistan used the ARDL estimators for testing the tourism–growth Furthermore, Pesaran and Pesaran (1997) suggest using Brown et al.'s
nexus. (1975) stability test to check the stability of the coefficient of the regres-
The ARDL cointegration technique is introduced by Pesaran and Shin sion. This technique is also known as cumulative (CUSUM) and cumula-
(1999) and Pesaran et al. (2001). The researchers are using ARDL esti- tive sum of squares (CUSUMSQ). The CUSUM and CUSUMSQ statistics
mator due to its several advantages. For example, it does not impose are updated recursively and plotted against the break points. If the
the restriction that all under consideration data series have the same plots of CUSUM and CUSUMSQ statistics stay within the critical bounds
188 A. Jalil et al. / Economic Modelling 35 (2013) 185–191

of 5% level of significance, the null hypothesis of all coefficients in the Table 3


given regression which is stable cannot be rejected. Unit root tests.

ADF k ADF K
4. Variable construction and data y −1.173 0 Δy −4.446⁎⁎⁎ 0
Tour −1.273 1 ΔTour −6.853⁎⁎⁎ 1
To accomplish our task, we take several variables like per capita GDP Trade −2.997 1 ΔTrade −6.296⁎⁎⁎ 2
(denoted by y), international tourism receipts (denoted by tour), capital Capital −0.937 1 ΔCapital −8.144⁎⁎⁎ 2
Cpi −3.766⁎ 2 ΔCpi −6.7734⁎⁎⁎ 1
stock (denoted by cap), inflation (denoted by cpi) and trade openness
(trade) directly from the Economic Survey of Pakistan and Handbook Notes: ADF augmented Dickey–Fuller test. k is the degree of augmentation that is auto-
of Statistics 2010. Trade openness ratio is the total value of exports matically determined by following the procedure of Campbell and Perron (1991).
⁎ Represents 10% level of significance.
and imports as share of GDP. ⁎⁎⁎ Represents 1% level of significance.
The data of the capital stocks is not available directly. Therefore, the
capital series is constructed from the perpetual inventory method. If we
assume that the capital depreciates at a rate of δ then Kt + 1 =
It + (1 − δ)Kt where, δ is the rate of depreciation and K(0) is the initial we estimate Eq. (4) by OLS estimation procedure and joint F-statistics is
stock in period zero. Initial capital stock can be estimated in a number of computed. The results of computed F-statistics and the critical values
ways; here we follow Nehru and Dhareshwar (1993). The value of in- suggested by Pesaran et al. (2001) at different levels of significance are
vestment in the first period is estimated through a linear regression of given in Table 4. The F-statistics is well beyond the critical value at 5%
the log of investment against time. The fitted value of initial investment level of significance. Therefore, this is an evidence of strong long run
is used to calculate initial capital stock using the following equation: relationship among the variables.
Kt = It/(g + δ). Here, g is the rate of growth of GDP and δ is deprecia- The growth led tourism hypothesis is also well observed in the
tion rate of capital. We choose 4% rate of depreciation following Khan empirical literature of economics (Oh, 2005). Therefore, there is prob-
(2006) and Jalil and Feridun (2011). The summary of the main macro- ability of endogeneity between tourism and economic growth. Ang
economic indicators and their descriptive statistics are presented in (2010) suggests that Eq. (4) should be re-estimated by keeping tourism
Table 2. as dependent variable to address the problem of endogeneity. If the cal-
culated values of F-statistics remain below the lower bound of the crit-
5. Empirical results ical value then it implies that there is no long run relationship, when
tourism is a dependent variable and growth does not lead to improve
One of the major advantages of using the ARDL estimators is that it can the tourism. We also follow the same methodology and the results are
be used without taking the consideration of data series which is either presented in the lower panel of Table 3. It is evident that the
I(0), I(1) or frictionally co-integrated. However, Ouattara (2004) docu- F. calculated values are significantly lower than the lower bound of
ments that ARDL estimators may not be valid for any data series which the critical value of Pesaran et al. (2001). Therefore, we conclude
is generated by I(2) process or beyond because Pesaran et al. (2001) ex- that there is only one co-integration vector from tourism to growth.
plicitly mentioned that the ARDL bounds tests is subject to the assump- We have established that there exists a long run relationship between
tion that the variables are integrated of order (0) or (1). Therefore, tourism development and economic growth of Pakistan. However, the
testing the level of stationarity is still necessary. For this purpose we use direction of causality is not clear from the ARDL cointegration test. There-
the Augmented Dickey–Fuller (ADF) estimators to check the stationary fore, we shall conduct the Granger causality test for establishing the
process of the data series. The results of the ADF tests are presented in direction of causality. It is clear from Table 5 that the null hypothesis of
Table 3. It is evident from the ADF results that some of the data set are tourism does not Granger cause GDP is clearly rejected at 1% but the
integrated of I(0) or I(1). Importantly, none of the data series are I(2) or null hypothesis of GDP does not Granger cause tourism is accepted.
above. Therefore, we are justified for using the ARDL estimators. This result concludes that causality runs through tourism to economic
Unit root test confirms that none of the series is integrated of I(2); growth and not vice versa in the case of Pakistan.
therefore, we may apply ARDL bounds testing procedures for establishing Next, we estimate Eq. (4) following the ARDL co-integration tech-
the long-run relationship between tourism and economic growth. For this nique for the long run estimates. We estimated the model keeping the
different criteria, like R2 criterion, Hannan Quinn Criterion, AIC Criterion
and SBC Criterion, in mind to find the coefficient of the level of variables.
Table 2 The long run and short run results of all models were almost near to
Main macroindicators and descriptive statistics.
identical. Therefore, we present only the results of the model that
Years y Tour Trade Capital Cpi were selected on the basis of AIC criterion as Monte Carlo experiment
1972–75 18.955 13.816 4.976 13.548 3.450 of Liew (2004) documented that AIC is superior to other criteria, partic-
1976–80 8.727 14.038 6.458 12.519 3.436 ularly when time span is less than 60 observations.
1981–85 7.169 14.362 7.612 12.769 3.519 The results of long run estimates are presented in Table 6.
1986–90 6.784 14.664 8.062 13.034 3.575 The coefficient of tour, which is 0.1987, implies that 1% increase in inter-
1991–95 11.197 14.915 8.184 13.252 3.603
1996–00 7.297 15.090 8.350 13.331 3.518
national tourism receipts leads to 0.20% increase in real per capita
2000–05 5.172 15.274 8.848 13.382 3.460 GDP in the long run. The finding confirms the tourism-led growth
2006 7.921 15.461 9.477 13.642 3.650 hypothesis, that is, the improvements in the inbound tourism activities
2007 7.599 15.516 9.744 13.770 3.570
2008 12.000 15.532 9.712 13.840 3.604
2009 20.000 15.568 10.112 13.720 3.503 Table 4
2010 10.700 15.610 10.084 13.699 3.462 Bounds tests for the existence of a long relationship.
2011 12.933 15.648 10.342 13.612 3.381
5% Critical 10% Critical
Descriptive statistics bounds bounds
Mean 14.736 7.862 3.516 13.187 9.378
F-statistics I(0) I(1) I(0) I(1)
Median 14.820 8.110 3.533 13.269 8.270
Maximum 15.610 10.110 3.661 14.580 26.660 Tourism led growth 4.9217 3.12 4.25 2.75 3.79
Minimum 13.730 3.920 3.322 12.194 2.910 Growth led tourism 1.0382 3.12 4.25 2.75 3.79
Std. dev. 0.567 1.389 0.093 0.513 5.409
Source of critical values: Pesaran et al. (2001).
A. Jalil et al. / Economic Modelling 35 (2013) 185–191 189

Table 5 Table 7
Granger causality test. Short run ARDL estimate.

Null hypothesis F-statistics p-Values Dependent variable is the natural log of per capita GDP

GDP does not granger cause tourism 0.3765 0.4131 Regressor Coefficient T-states
Tourism does not Granger cause GDP 3.1925 0.0116
ΔTour 0.1391 2.0495
ΔTrade 0.206 2.0987
ΔCapital 0.253 3.2292
ΔCpi −0.4283 −1.8331
may lead to higher level of economic growth. The results of our study ΔIntercept 0.2858 2.8291
Ecm(−1) −0.2848 3.5167
are in line with the recent empirical studies, for example, Balaguer
and Cantavella-Jorda (2002), Vanegas and Croes (2003), Dritsakis Diagnostic test statistics
(2004), Durbarry (2004), Skerrit and Huybers (2005), Neves and Paula R-squared 0.8280
F 7.4331
(2008), Lee and Chang (2008), Kaplan and Celik (2008), Jimenez
DW 1.8671
(2008), Brida et al. (2010), Tang (2011) and Kreishan (2011) and in CUSUM Stable
sharp contrast with Oh (2005) and Katircioglu (2009) which have a CUSUMSQ Stable
stance of growth led tourism hypothesis. The results are statistically sig- Ecm = y − 0.1987 ∗ tour − 0.3233 ∗ trade − 0.7181 ∗ capital + 0.7459 ∗ cpi − 0.2615.
nificant at 1% level of significance.
Then we use some important control variables, like interna-
finding indicates that our selected variables have the stronger impact
tional trade, capital stock and inflation. The coefficient of trade, a
on the economic growth in the long run.
measure of international trade, implies that a 1% increase in the
The important outcome of the short run dynamics is the calculation
volume of international trade will lead to 0.32% rise in real per
of the coefficient of ECM. The lagged error correction coefficient
capita GDP. The results of the present study are consistent with
ECMt − 1 is presented in the last row of the upper panel of Table 6. The
Beck (2002), and Katircioglu (2009), which have a stance that
lagged error correction coefficients, ECMt − 1 are correct in sign, and sig-
the improvement in the international trade will lead to higher level
nificant in both cases verifying the established co-integrating relation-
of output. Importantly, our findings are also consistent with Jalil and
ships among the variables. The coefficient of ECMt − 1 shows the speed
Feridun (2011) and Shahbaz (2012) who document that trade has a sta-
of the adjustment back to the long-run equilibrium after a short run
tistically significant positive impact on the economic growth in the case
shock. For example, the coefficient of ECMt − 1 is 0.2825. This implies,
of Pakistan.
nearly 28% of the disequilibria of the previous year's shock adjusting
The empirical economic literature provides an inconclusive de-
back to the long run equilibrium in the current year.
bate on the long run relationship of inflation and economic growth.
Our model passes through the diagnostic tests. The results are
For example, Ghosh and Phillips (1998), Khan and Senhadji (2001)
reported in the lower panel of Table 5. The p-values of the χ2 state
and Sarel (1996) show a negative relationship between inflation
that there is no evidence of serial correlation and heteroscedasticity.
and economic growth, while Akerlof et al. (1996) favor low but pos-
Furthermore, the p-value 0.16 of functional form is an evidence of
itive inflation which may keep the economy to grow. However, our
well specification of the model and p-value 0.42 is an indication of
results favor the stance of Ghosh and Phillips (1998), Khan and
the acceptance of the null hypothesis of normality assumption of
Senhadji (2001) and Sarel (1996) in the case of Pakistan. Specifical-
the residuals. Furthermore, the plots of CUSUM and CUSUMSQ sta-
ly, we find a statistically significant negative sign with a magnitude
tistics are well within the critical bounds, implying that all coeffi-
of 0.7459.
cients in the error-correction model are stable.2 Therefore, the
The coefficient of capital implies that 1% increase in physical capital
preferred growth equation can be used for policy decision-making
contributes to real per capita GDP of almost 0.7181%. The magnitude is
purposes, such that the impact of policy changes considering the ex-
showing diminishing marginal returns to capital which is consistent
planatory variables of growth equation will not cause major distor-
with the neo classical school of thought. However, the magnitude is
tion in the level of per capita GDP, since the parameters in this
relatively higher as compared to Jalil and Feridun (2011) in the case of
equation seem to follow a stable pattern during the estimation
Pakistan.
period.
Next the results of the short run analysis and the coefficient of the
error correction terms are presented in Table 7. The short run results
are almost same in the signs as compared to the long run and are in 6. Conclusion
line with a priori expectations. However, the magnitudes of the short
run estimates are smaller as compared to the long run estimates. This Indeed, explaining the economic growth dynamics is an arduous
task and a number of important factors have been discussed in the vari-
ety of growth models. A plethora of studies consider that the inbound
tourism is one of them. However, this line of research is completely
Table 6 missing in the case of Pakistan which is generating 6.5% of the GDP
Long run ARDL estimates. from travel and tourism World Economic Forum (2011). The present
Dependent variable is the natural log of per capita GDP
study is an attempt to test the tourism led growth hypothesis in the
case of Pakistan over the period of 1972 to 2011. The findings of the
Regressor Coefficient T-states
present study confirm the tourism led growth hypothesis in the case
Tour 0.1987 4.5711 of Pakistan. Therefore, in general, we support the evidence for many
Trade 0.3233 3.9073
countries that the improvement in the international tourism is one of
Capital 0.7181 2.4285
Cpi −0.7459 −4.4453
the important sources of economic growth in the case of Pakistan. We
Intercept 0.2615 1.8648 settle this conclusion by estimating the growth regression through the
ARDL estimators due to its several advantages over the other estima-
Diagnostic test statistics (p-values)
χ2 (serial correlation) 0.7386
tors. It is also important to mention here that we explicitly reject the
χ2 (functional form) 0.1644
χ2 (normality) 0.4282
χ2 (heteroscedasticity) 0.5848 2
The graphs are not presented to save space; however, these are available upon request.
190 A. Jalil et al. / Economic Modelling 35 (2013) 185–191

growth led tourism hypothesis in the case of Pakistan. Specifically, 1% Jalil, A., Feridun, M., 2011. Impact of financial development on economic growth:
empirical evidence from Pakistan. Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy 16, 71–80.
increase in international tourism receipts leads to 0.1987% increase in Jimenez, I.C., 2008. Which type of tourism matters to the regional economic growth? The
real per capita GDP in the long run. Therefore, international tourism re- cases of Spain and Italy. International Journal of Tourism Research 10, 127–139.
ceipts can be regarded as pivotal channels to boost economic growth. Johansen, S., 1991. Estimation and hypothesis testing of co-integration vectors in
Gaussian vector autoregressive models. Econometrica 59, 1551–1580.
The result of robustness check is also in line with the previous infer- Johansen, S., Juselius, K., 1990. Maximum likelihood estimation and inference on
ences. Trade and capital are other important determinants of the eco- cointegration—with applications to the demand for money. Oxford Bulletin of
nomic growth of Pakistan. Economics and Statistics 52, 169–210.
Kaplan, M., Celik, T., 2008. The impact of tourism on economic performance: the case of
The empirical evidences of the present study provide two poten-
Turkey. International Journal of Applied Economics and Finance 2, 13–18.
tially fruitful research possibilities. First, consider and explore the Katircioglu, S., 2009. Tourism, trade, and growth: the case of Cyprus. Applied Economics
internal tourism which is one of the vital sources of economic 41, 2741–2751.
Khalil, S., Kakar, M.K., Waliullah, 2010. Role of tourism in economic growth: empirical
growth along with the traditional channels, for example, physical
evidence from Pakistan economy. The Pakistan Development Review 46, 985–995.
capital, human capital, international trade and financial develop- Khan, M.S., Senhadji, A.S., 2001. Threshold effects in the relationship between inflation
ment in the case of Pakistan. Second, explore the possibilities of and growth. IMF Staff Paper 48, 1–21.
protecting and enhance the possibilities of tourism especially in Khan, S.U., 2006. Macro determinants of total factor productivity in Pakistan. SBP Re-
search Bulletin 2 (2), 819–837.
the scenario of lacking the directing resources, for example, security, Kim, H.J., Chen, M.H., Jang, S., 2006. Tourism expansion and economic development:
energy, infrastructure and marketing skills. Therefore, the govern- the case of Taiwan. Tourism Management 27, 925–933.
ment should help travel and tourism industry for expanding as Kreishan, F.M., 2011. Time series evidence for tourism led-growth hypothesis: a case
study of Jordan. International Management Review 7, 89–93.
much as possible by focusing attention on long-run policies (Lee Krueger, A.O., 1980. Trade policy as an input to development. American Economic
and Chang, 2008). Furthermore, the strong evidence of long run re- Review 70, 288–292.
lationship between tourism and economic growth may also moti- Lanza, A., Templec, P., Urgad, G., 2003. The implications of tourism specialisation in the
long-run: an econometric analysis for 13 OECD economies. Tourism Management
vate the researcher for constructing the theoretical models of 24, 315–321.
economic growth by incorporating the impact of tourism in the Lee, J.W., 1993. International trade, distortions and long run economic growth. IMF
case of Pakistan. Staff Paper 40, 299–328.
Lee, C.C., Chang, C., 2008. Tourism development and economic growth: a closer look at
panels. Tourism Management 29, 180–192.
Liew, V.K.-S., 2004. Nonlinear adjustment of ASEAN-5 real exchange rates: symmetrical
References or Asymmetrical? Economics Bulletin 6, 1–19.
Lim, C., 1997. Review of international tourism demand models. Annals of Tourism
Adamos, A., Sofranis, C., 2005. Prospects of limits of tourism-led growth: the international Research 24, 835–849.
evidence. Review of Economic Analysis 3, 287–303. Lucas, R., 1988. On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary
Akerlof, G.A., Dicken, W., Perry, G., 1996. The macroeconomics of low inflation. Economics 22, 3–42.
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, 1–59. Malik, S., Chaudhry, I.S., Sheikh, M.R., Sharif, F., 2010. Tourism, economic growth and
Akinboade, A.O., Braimoh, L.A., 2010. International tourism and economic development current account deficit in Pakistan: evidence from co-integration and causal analysis.
in South Africa: a Granger causality test. International Journal of Tourism Research European Journal of Economic, Finance and Administrative Sciences 22, 21–31.
12, 149–163. Mallik, G., Chowdhury, A., 2001. Inflation and economic growth: evidence from four
Ang, J.B., 2010. Does foreign aid promote growth? Exploring the role of financial South Asian countries. Asia-Pacific Development Journal 8, 123–135.
liberalization. Review of Development Economic 14, 197–212. Mankiw, N.G., Romer, D., Weil, N.A., 1992. Contribution to the empirics of economic
Balaguer, J., Cantavella-Jorda, M., 2002. Tourism as a long-run economic growth factor: growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107, 407–437.
the Spanish case. Applied Economics 34, 877–884. Mubarak, Y.A., 2005. Inflation and growth: an estimate of the threshold level of inflation
Beck, T., 2002. Financial development and international trade: is there a link? Journal of in Pakistan. SBP-Research Bulletin 1, 35–44.
International Economics 57, 107–131. Narayan, P., 2004. Economic impact of tourism on Fiji's economy: empirical evidence
Bhagwati, J., Srinivasan, T., 1979. Trade policy and development. In: Dornbunsch, R., from the computable general equilibrium model. Tourism Economics 10, 419–433.
Frenkel, J. (Eds.), International Economic Policy: Theory and Evidence. Johns Hopkins Nehru, V., Dhareshwar, A., 1993. A new database on physical capital stock: sources,
University Press, Baltimore, pp. 1–35. methodology and results. Revista de Analisis Economica 8, 37–59.
Brida, J.G., Carrera, E.S., Risso, W.A., 2008. Tourism's impact on long-run Mexican economic Neves, S.T., Paula, M.N., 2008. Does tourism influence economic growth? A dynamic
growth. Economics Bulletin 3, 1–10. panel data approach. Applied Economics 40, 2431–2441.
Brida, J.G., Lanzilotta, B., Lionetti, S., Risso, W.A., 2010. Tourism led-growth hypothesis Noor, A., 2009. Economic Analysis of Tourism Sector in Pakistan. (MPhil Dissertation)
for Uruguay. Tourism Economics 16, 765–771. School of Economics, Quaid-i-Azam University, Islamabad, Pakistan.
Brown, R.L., Durbin, J., Evans, J.M., 1975. Techniques for testing the constancy of regression Oh, C., 2005. The contribution of tourism development to economic growth in the
relations over time. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society 37, 149–163. Korean economy. Tourism Management 26, 39–44.
Campbell, J.Y., Perron, P., 1991. Pitfalls and opportunities: what macroeconomists Ouattara, B., 2004. Foreign aid and fiscal policy in Senegal. Mimeo University of Manchester.
should know about unit roots. NBER Chapters. In: NBER Macroeconomics Annual Ozturk, I., Ali, A., 2009. On the causality between tourism growth and economic
National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. 6, 141–220. growth: empirical evidence from Turkey. Transylvanian Review of Administrative
Chancharat, S., Chaancharat, N., 2010. Tourism development and economic growth: Sciences 25, 73–81.
evidence from Thailand. International Journal of Applied Business and Economic Pesaran, M.H., Pesaran, B., 1997. Working with Microfit 4.0. Interactive Econometric
Research 8, 65–77. Analysis. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Chen, C.F., Wei, S.Z.C., 2009. Tourism expansion, tourism uncertainty and economic Pesaran, M.H., Shin, Y., 1999. An autoregressive distributed lag modelling approach to
growth: new evidence from Taiwan and Korea. Tourism Management 30, 812–818. cointegration analysis. In: Strom, S. (Ed.), Econometrics and Economic Theory in
Dritsakis, N., 2004. Tourism as a long-run economic growth factor: an empirical investigation 20th Century: The Ragnar Frisch Centennial Symposium, Chapter 11. Cambridge
for Greece using causality analysis. Tourism Economics 10, 305–316. University Press, Cambridge.
Durbarry, R., 2004. Tourism and economic growth: the case of Mauritius. Tourism Pesaran, M.H., Shin, Y., Smith, R.J., 2001. Bounds testing approaches to the analysis of
Economics 10, 389–401. level relationships. Journal of Applied Econometrics 16, 289–326.
Edwards, S., 1998. Openness, productivity and growth: what do we really know? Po, W.C., Huang, B.N., 2008. Tourism development and economic growth—a non-linear
Economic Journal 108, 383–398. approach. Physica A, Statistical Mechanics and its Applications 287, 5535–5542.
Engle, R., Granger, C., 1987. Co-integration and error correction representation: estima- Rivera–Batiz, L.A., Xie, D., 1993. Integration among unequals. Regional Science and
tion and testing. Econometrica 55, 251–276. Urban Economics 23, 337–354.
Faria, J.R., 2001. Does high inflation affect growth in the long run. Journal of Applied Sarel, M., 1996. Non linear effects of inflation on economic growth. IMF Staff Papers 41,
Economics 4, 89–105. 199–215.
Gee, C.Y., 1999. International Tourism: a Global Perspective. World Tourism Organization, Seetanah, B., 2011. Assessing the dynamic economic impact of tourism for Island economies.
Madrid, Spain. Annuals of Tourism Research 38, 291–308.
Ghosh, A., Phillips, S., 1998. Warning: inflation may be harmful to your economic Shahbaz, M., 2012. Does trade openness affect long run growth? Cointegration, causality
growth. Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, 45, pp. 672–710. and forecast error variance decomposition tests for Pakistan. Economic Modelling 29,
Grossman, G.E., Helpman, E., 1991. Endogenous product cycle. Economic Journal 101, 2325–2339.
1214–1229. Sidrauski, M., 1967. Rational choice and pattern of growth in a monetary economy.
Harrison, A., 1996. Openness and growth: a time series, cross-country analysis for American Economic Review 57, 534–544.
developing countries. Journal of Development Economics 48, 419–447. Skerrit, D., Huybers, T., 2005. The effect of international tourism on economic development:
Helpman, E., Krugman, P., 1985. Market Structure and International Trade. MIT Press. an empirical analysis. Asia Pacific Journal of Tourism Research 10, 23–43.
Holzar, M., 2010. Tourism and development: the beach disease. Tourism Management Sr, M.V., Croes, R.R., 2003. Growth, development and tourism in a small economy:
32, 922–933. evidence from Aruba. International Journal of Tourism Research 5, 315–330.
A. Jalil et al. / Economic Modelling 35 (2013) 185–191 191

Tang, C.F., 2011. Is the tourism-led growth hypothesis valid for Malaysia? A view from Vanegas Sr., M., Croes, R.R., 2003. Growth, development and tourism in a small
disaggregated tourism markets. International Journal of Tourism Research 13, economy: evidence from Aruba. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/jtr.441.
97–101. World Economic Forum, 2011. The Travel and Tourism Competitiveness Report
Tiwari, A.K., 2011. Tourism, exports and FDI as a measure of economic growth: 2011: beyond the Downturn. World Economic Forum, Geneva.
evidence from four Asian countries. The Romanian Economic Journal 40, Young, A., 1991. Learning by doing and the dynamic effects of international trade.
131–151. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 369–405.

Potrebbero piacerti anche