Sei sulla pagina 1di 18

Distinguished Lecture in Archeology: Breaking and Entering the Ecosystem - Gender,

Class, and Faction Steal the Show


Author(s): Elizabeth M. Brumfiel
Source: American Anthropologist, New Series, Vol. 94, No. 3 (Sep., 1992), pp. 551-567
Published by: Wiley on behalf of the American Anthropological Association
Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/680562
Accessed: 09-08-2019 21:29 UTC

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

American Anthropological Association, Wiley are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize,


preserve and extend access to American Anthropologist

This content downloaded from 190.96.91.202 on Fri, 09 Aug 2019 21:29:52 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
ELIZABETH M. BRUMFIEL
Albion College

Distinguished Lecture in Archeology: Breaking


and Entering the Ecosystem-Gender, Class, and
Faction Steal the Show

This article was presented as the third annual Distinguished Lecture in Archeology at the 90
annual meeting of the American Anthropological Association, November 22, 1991, in Chic
Illinois.

F OR ALMOST
sumptions of THIRTY YEARS,
the ecosystem American
approach. Thearcheology
longevity ofhas been
this operating
approach unde
is no accid
the ecosystem program has been highly productive. From ecosystem theory, we hav
quired a sensitivity to structural causation and an appreciation for the intercon
ness of social and ecological variables. We have also gathered much relevant informa
about energy exchanges, information flows, scheduling, risk, nutrition, labor inten
cation, and demographic trends in prehistory. But while the ecosystem approa
been very productive in some areas of research, it has retarded progress in others,
ularly in the analysis of social change.
The analysis of social change has been hampered by ecosystem theory's insis
upon whole populations and whole behavioral systems as the units of analysis. In foc
ing on whole populations, and whole systems of adaptive cultural behavior, eco
theorists have neglected the dynamics of social change arising from internal so
gotiation. Social negotiation consists of conflicts and compromises among peopl
different problems and possibilities by virtue of their membership in different all
networks. Most frequently, these alliance networks arise on the basis of gender, cla
factional affiliation.
This paper argues three points. First, the ecosystem theorists' emphasis upon whole
populations and whole adaptive behavioral systems obscures the visibility of gender,
class, and faction in the prehistoric past. Second, an analysis that takes account of gender,
class, and faction can explain many aspects of the prehistoric record that the ecosystem
perspective cannot explain. Third, an appreciation for the importance of gender, class,
and faction in prehistory compels us to reject the ecosystem-theory view that cultures are
adaptive systems. Instead, we must recognize that culturally based behavioral "systems"
are the composite outcomes of negotiation between positioned social agents pursuing
their goals under both ecological and social constraints.

The Ecosystem Approach


The ecosystem approach rests upon two basic tenets. First, ecosystem theorists propose
that human populations adapt to their environments through culture-based behavioral
systems. Our role as archeologists is to record stability and change in these behavioral
systems over time and to explain this record as a product of population-environment in-
teraction (Steward 1955:36-42; White 1959:56; Binford 1962:218; Flannery 1967:121;

ELIZABETH M. BRUMFIEL is Professor, Department ofAnthropology and Sociology, Albion College, Albion, MI 49224.

551

This content downloaded from 190.96.91.202 on Fri, 09 Aug 2019 21:29:52 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
552 AMERICAN ANTHROPOLOGIST [94, 1992

Sanders and Price 1968:71; Hill 1977:88; Redman 1978a:13; Struever and Holton
1979:84-85). Second, ecosystem theorists assert that humans play a very limited role in
determining the course of culture change. Applying the model of natural selection to cul-
tural systems, ecosystem theorists argue that human decisions, intentions, and creativity
are simply sources of behavioral variation. Systemic context determines the differential
survival of these behaviors. Behavioral changes that produce viable cultural systems en-
dure and leave their imprint on prehistory; behavioral changes resulting in nonviable
cultural systems disappear as the cultures, themselves, fail (White 1949:141; Flannery
1967:122, 1972:411; Sanders and Price 1968:73; Hill 1977:66-67; Redman 1978a:10-13;
Dunnell 1980:62; Braun and Plog 1982:506; Price 1982:724).
Together, these two propositions focus attention on the cultural-behavioral system
rather than the social actor. This focus is clearly evident in that diagnostic artifact of
ecosystem archeology, the flowchart of culture change (see Figure 1; other examples in-
clude Wright 1970, 1977; Flannery 1972; Harris 1977; Johnson 1978; King 1978; and
Hassan 1981). For example, the emphasis on systems rather than social actors determines
the perspective of the flowchart, which is "etic" rather than "emic." That is, the chart
provides an overview of the system as a whole, rather than a view of the system as it might
look to a member of the society. As Cowgill (1975:506) notes, ecosystem theorists have
no real interest in "the needs, problems, possibilities, incentives, information, and view-
points of specific individuals or categories of individuals" within the system. The empha-
sis on systems rather than social actors also determines the units that constitute the boxes
or components in this flowchart, which are activities rather than agents, functions rather
than performers. Social actors are reduced to invisible, equivalent, abstract units of labor
power. Finally, the ecosystem theorists' reliance upon natural selection as the mechanism

Expansion into New Regions and Extension of Water Control Systems

Specialized Redistribution Ability to


Food of Foodstuffs Induce Surplus

Production Production Taxation and Corm


Niche I) tiontand Corvee
Need for Manufacturing
Foreign Ra Long Craft Industrie
Materials Distance 4 Specialization

PotentiallColonization of Class Stratified


Potentially
Productive MesopotamiaA o
MesopotamiaNew et
e with Adequate Markets ietad
Administration
Unoccupied Technology Differentiations Elite
Niche (e.g. Irrigation) in Wealth Due to Control
Limited Access
Intensification to Strategic
Population of Agriculture Resources
Increase

Increase in Warfare

SizeNI
Increase in

Information

(after Redman 1978b:3333).

This content downloaded from 190.96.91.202 on Fri, 09 Aug 2019 21:29:52 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Brumfiel] DISTINGUISHED LECTURE IN ARCHEOLOGY 553

of systemic change determines the nature of the connection


nents. The connections between boxes are either functional r
(for example, specialized food production requires the red
"necessary" consequences of one variable for another (for ex
agriculture necessarily entails the differentiation in wealth)
ulus-response or input-output relationships. The motivations
actually link variables are not diagramed, so that a small "bla
each pair of linked components (Clarke 1968:58-62; McG
clearly concerned with system-level evolutionary consequ
social change.
The ecosystem focus on the cultural-behavioral system has several drawbacks. First, it
makes invisible the past activities and contributions of particular sets of social actors, for
example, women, peasants, and particular racial or ethnic groups. When archeologists
fail to assign specific activities to these groups, dominant groups in contemporary society
are free to depict them in any way they please. Most often, dominant groups will overstate
the historical importance of their own group and undervalue the contributions of others,
legitimating current inequalities (Williams 1989; Patterson 1991a). In addition, when
women, peasants, and ethnic groups are assigned no specific activities in the past, profes-
sional archeologists make implicit assumptions about their roles and capabilities, result-
ing in the widespread acceptance of untested, and possibly erroneous, interpretations of
archeological data (Conkey and Spector 1984; Nelson 1990). As archeologists, we have a
professional responsibility to present our prehistories in ways that make distorted appro-
priations of the past as difficult as possible, and, as scientists, we need to work with
models that expose our implicit assumptions concerning human roles and capabilities to
critical reflection and hypothesis testing. The systemic models of ecosystem theory hinder
both these efforts.
Second, the ecosystem focus on the cultural-behavioral system leads us to seriously
underestimate the difficulties of systemic change. All institutional innovation has person-
nel and energy requirements (D'Altroy and Earle 1985), and if these requirements cannot
be met, the institution, no matter how beneficial, will not come into being. But, in human
society, access to labor and resources is defined by social categories, and this allocation
is maintained not by cultural norms, which are frequently flouted by actors pursuing their
particular goals, but by alliance networks that organize coercive force. Typically, such
alliance networks materialize on the basis of gender, class, and faction. A major task in
understanding systemic change is to understand how realignments in these alliance net-
works are brought off, permitting a redefinition of social categories and a reallocation of
resources and personnel (see Eisenstadt 1963). But ecosystem theory focuses on abstract
behavior rather than the groups of actors that control resources and power. This focus
obscures both the processes and possibilities of systemic change.
Finally, the ecosystem focus on the cultural-behavioral system leads us to overestimate
the external as opposed to the internal causes of change. As Adams (1978:329-330) ob-
serves, "Much of the flux and dynamism of the historic record derives from the periodic
convergence and divergence of the partly disarticulated geographic, ethnic, class, kin,
and other components of human society." Cause-effect regularities may exist because of
the logic of social negotiation instead of the logic of adaptive response. Rather than re-
garding prehistory as a long-term, systemic-level process of adaptation to environmental
change, it may be better to see prehistory as a string of short-term, composite outcomes
of social conflict and compromise among people with different problems and possibilities
by virtue of their membership in differing alliance networks.
Archeology has much to gain from focusing on the organization of actors rather than
behavioral systems, especially groupings of actors defined on the basis of gender, class,
and factional affiliation.

This content downloaded from 190.96.91.202 on Fri, 09 Aug 2019 21:29:52 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
554 AMERICAN ANTHROPOLOGIST [94, 1992

Gender

In the focus on behavioral systems rather than actors, gender disappears. Despite the
widespread recognition that age and sex provide universal bases of social status and
division of labor in human societies, gender (and age) have received very little attention
from archeologists. Flowcharts of social process, such as that cited above, never ass
gender to the activities they diagram. The lack of attention to gender has contin
through the 1980s, even in archeological studies of the household, where production, di
tribution, transmission, and reproduction are based in very direct and concrete ways o
a gendered division of labor and a gender-based definition of social status (Tringh
1991:101; for examples, see Wilk and Rathje 1982; Wilk and Ashmore 1988; Stani
1989). Even when analysis involves the definition of probable male and female activities
and activity areas (e.g., Clarke 1972; Flannery and Winter 1976), it stops short of recon
structing integrated male and female roles. This failure to define gender roles is an un
derstandable consequence of the emphasis on behavioral systems. The unstated attit
is, I think, that it really doesn't matter who did what in prehistory, as long as the nec
sary subsistence functions were performed. This is thought to be especially true of hou
hold subsistence tasks, since the household is regarded as a cooperative unit based on th
pooling of goods and services. But it matters very much who did what, for at least thr
reasons.

First, when gender roles are not explicitly defined, they are
and Spector 1984; Conkey and Gero 1991). It has been taken
men and women, procure food while women process it. Men co
women engage in household maintenance. Men make states;
it is assumed. And assigning a task to women has virtually assu
archeological data pertaining to that task would go unrecog
Compare, for example, the extensive analysis of food procure
models such as optimal foraging theory and game theory with
given food processing. There is a greater literature on the heat
the heat treatment of food (but see Stahl 1989). Studies of c
number studies of ceramic use. Spatial and temporal variability
ing stones, cooking vessels, fuels, hearths, and ovens has not b
see Jackson 1991; Bartlett 1933; Clark 1988; Braun 1981; Co
Hastorf and Johannessen 1991; Hayden 1981). The same has
cilities associated with hide-working, textile production, and t
cord products such as traps and nets (but see Weiner and Sc
I believe that the explicit effort to assign activities to female
some of these disparities obvious and stimulate ground-breakin
known classes of archeological data, delineating both their r
strategic factors that explain their variation.
Second, assigning activities to male or female actors is a first
tegrated models of the gendered division of labor. Such mo
estimating work loads and pinpointing scheduling conflicts, bo
tant implications for strategic decision making and be
1991:277). Flannery (1968a:75) pointed out some time ago that t
the lines of sex is one common solution to scheduling conflicts
But only recently has it been suggested that scheduling proble
activities might explain observed changes in the exploitation o
shellfish and plants, including plant domestication (Claassen
1991), or that maximizing the efficiency of women's work rou
factor in structuring some settlement patterns (Jackson 1991)
Third, the calculation of gender-specific work loads has im
modeling systemic change. For example, most models of em
tions assume the ability to generate surplus production, a

This content downloaded from 190.96.91.202 on Fri, 09 Aug 2019 21:29:52 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Brumfiel] DISTINGUISHED LECTURE IN ARCHEOLOGY 555

1968:89; D'Altroy and Earle 1985), either to use in adapt


such as "banking" and redistribution (Flannery 1968b;
to incur the social indebtedness of followers (Rowlands 1980
and Earle 1987; Clark and Blake 1993), or to sponsor feast
to claim to be intermediaries between the living and the
1973). Because the vast majority of production in agraria
political change almost always involves the restructuring of
stages of social inequality ought to be marked by high birt
inception of dependent labor within the households of w
Leconte 1986; Coontz and Henderson 1986). As inequality
are extracted from a widening circle of clients and sub
households will experience changes in composition and or
cific changes occur in household labor, they will always be a
energy budgets of household members as established by the
For example, among the historic Blackfoot, women were r
When the markets for tanned robes expanded during the 1
vided an obvious avenue of advance for wealthy, ambiti
(1942:38-40), polygamy did expand, accompanied by incr
men and increased oppression of women who were taken
Had the division of labor made male rather than female
ropean goods, then would-be leaders would have had to reso
mobilization and surplus accumulation. Thus, to explain s
to understand their limits, archeologists must examine the
of household labor.
In studying the organization of household labor, archeologists may note changes that
placed household members in opposition to one another. For example, Hastorf (1991)
presents botanical evidence from the Mantaro Valley, Peru, that suggests that maize beer
production intensified under Inca rule. In the Andes, maize beer production is tradition-
ally a woman's task. At the same time, skeletal evidence indicates that under Inca rul
women consumed less maize beer than did men. One would have to ask, how did it come
to be that women produced more beer and yet consumed a smaller proportion of wha
they produced? Did this arrangement somehow maximize the joint benefits of the collec-
tive household economy? Or does it indicate the flow of benefits from female to mal
household members? If so, how was this flow of benefits achieved? Similarly, we could
look back to the previous example and ask, what alterations of situation or allegiance
permitted the institution of a less egalitarian marriage relationship for third and subse-
quent Blackfoot wives? Rather than attributing change to a heavy-handed selection pro-
cess, we must acknowledge the extent to which a cultural system is an outcome of active
negotiations between individuals with differential power, both within the household
(Hartmann 1981; Moore 1990) and beyond (Wolf 1982:385-391).
To explore this issue more fully, let us consider the way in which ecosystem theorists
have dealt with the relationship between classes in prehistoric societies.

Class

There is an interesting asymmetry in the way that ecosystem theorists have treated
dominant and subordinate classes, as is evident in our flowchart example (see Figur
Elites constitute the only people-filled component of the system, and they are a very ac
component-there are a lot of arrows leaving this box as well as entering it.2 In contra
the activities and interests of subordinate classes are divided among various syst
components and are nowhere regarded as a coherent force in determining ecosys
structure. The existence of this asymmetry is a straightforward consequence of the as
sumptions of ecosystem theory. Elites are viewed as performing managerial funct
and, therefore, as being endowed with the ability to impose their decisions upon the s

This content downloaded from 190.96.91.202 on Fri, 09 Aug 2019 21:29:52 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
556 AMERICAN ANTHROPOLOGIST [94, 1992

system. Managerial theories postulate no simil


fore do not grant them any similar power to
only the emergence of the elites requires expl
been with us.3
But the emergence of elites does not leave non-elites untransformed. The development
of control at the apex of the systemic hierarchy implies the development of subordination
at lower levels, regardless of whether this subordination is considered beneficial "system-
serving" regulation or pathological "self-serving" exploitation (Flannery 1972). And
many systemic relationships within emerging states are revealed only when subordinate
classes enter the model as people coping with the unfamiliar circumstances of subordi-
nation rather than as abstract performers of disaggregated systemic processes. For ex-
ample, if commoners or peasants appeared in the flowchart diagrams, we would be more
likely to ask two key questions about the process of state formation. First, what impact
did emerging hierarchy have on the lives of people in subordinate groups? And second,
to what extend did commoner response to state formation determine the structure of hi-
erarchy? These questions enable us to account for certain aspects of the archeological
record that the ecosystem approach leaves unexplained.
The first of these questions has seemed nonproblematic to most ecosystem theorists,
who assume that, under conditions of emerging hierarchy, commoners simply main-
tained their homeostatic exchanges with the environment under more stable, better-man-
aged conditions (but see Gall and Saxe 1977). But as we have observed, the emergence
of hierarchy always involves the transfer of goods from the hands of direct producers to
political elites with profound implications for other aspects of the cultural system.
For example, during the last four centuries of the pre-Hispanic era, coinciding with the
emergence of a regional state in the Basin of Mexico, the Basin experienced a surge of
demographic growth, which produced an eightfold increase in population (Sanders, Par-
sons, and Santley 1979:184-186). Earlier periods of modest or even negative growth in
the Basin's population suggest that there was nothing "natural" about this dramatic
growth (see Blanton 1975; Cowgill 1975). The absence of evidence for drastic changes in
the Basin of Mexico environment or its food-producing technology leaves this growth
quite unexplained within an ecosystem framework. However, if we consider the impact
of emerging hierarchy on the lives of subordinate groups, we might suggest that it was
the conditions of state formation, itself, that led to population growth (reversing the usual'
ecosystem proposition that population growth causes state formation). Either because the
state's demand for tribute, levied on a household basis, increased the need for household
labor, or because the increasing levels of violence made less certain the survival of chil-
dren to support parents in their old age, households brought into expanding states may
have desired and produced more children. This and other transformations of the house-
hold, especially gender and kinship relations, under conditions of state formation are
problems requiring much further investigation (see Rapp 1978; Gailey 1985a, 1985b,
1987; Silverblatt 1987, 1988).
Turning to the second question, the extent to which commoner response determined
the structure of emerging hierarchy, ecosystem theorists have usually assumed that the
managerial benefits conferred by hierarchy would make subordinate groups willing par-
ticipants in the system. However, this leaves unexplained forms of activity that appear to
be efforts by dominant classes to work around subordinate classes to avoid provoking
their hostility. For example, early stages of state formation are often characterized by the
development of private estates, controlled by elite individuals or corporations, and staffed
by some sort of unfree labor, such as slaves, war captives, or clients. Examples include
the palace and temple estates of Mesopotamia (Fox and Zagarell 1982; Zagarell 1986)
and the slave villages in African kingdoms such as Gyaman and Wolof (Terray 1979;
Tymowski 1991). Zagarell (Fox and Zagarell 1982; Zagarell 1986), Gailey (1985a), and
Tymowski (1991) suggest that these enclave economies, rather than representing the
power of the state, are symptoms of its weakness. Unable to supply sufficient benefits or

This content downloaded from 190.96.91.202 on Fri, 09 Aug 2019 21:29:52 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Brumfiel] DISTINGUISHED LECTURE IN ARCHEOLOGY 557

to muster sufficient coercion to collect taxes from a residen


elites were forced to establish their own income-generating
individuals who were separated from the protection of their
Warfare is another means of financing hierarchy in the fa
The spoils of war may be used to increase the prestige of lea
pacity for generosity (Santley 1980:142; Gilman 198 1). And
anism for capturing resources for enclave economies. Bot
Zagarell 1986; Tymowski 1991) and land (Webster 1975)
control of traditional kin groups. Such assets free leaders fr
status, kinship ties, and, ultimately, the kinship ethic.
In enclave economies and economies based upon plunder,
a bargain: intra-group exploitation is minimized so that l
erate to dominate and exploit outsiders. The formation of su
frequent means of constructing political power (Lenin 19
1987:176-195).
Factions

When the adaptive value of sociopolitical institutions is assumed, no explicit an


of power building is necessary. Ruling elites derive their power from the regulation
control of a complex subsistence economy, and they fall from power only when their
interested activities impede the efficient operation of the economy (Flannery 1972:4
Johnson 1978:104; Redman 1978b:343-344). Politics becomes a function of subsis
and concern over political process disappears. This is reflected in the flowchart exam
(Figure 1), where the subsistence economy receives much more attention than the po
ical economy, and all administrative elites occupy a single, undifferentiated, box.
However, if ecosystem theorists believe that power building in prehistoric complex
cieties can be ignored, they are in sharp disagreement with the leaders of these grou
In the complex societies known from ethnohistorical records, power building is a cen
concern. Much (if not all) of the administrative bureaucracy is devoted to maint
power. Typically, early states contain military bureaucracies organizing coercive
tax-collecting bureaucracies organizing surplus extraction, and functionaries in
of administered trade, elite craft production, and religious ritual, all of which comm
cate ideologies of elite solidarity and dominance.
Rulers invest heavily in power building because the threats to their survival a
merous (Kaufman 1988). Competing factions form around would-be usurpers within
highest-ranking nobility, would-be independent paramounts within the provincial no
ity, and would-be conquerors among the leaders of neighboring groups. These g
threaten a ruler with coup, separatism, and conquest, respectively. Adding to th
plexity of the situation, these groups frequently form alliances with each other and
outsiders. For example, usurpers and separatists may be aided by neighboring rulers
see ties of patronage as an alternative to conquest for expanding territorial control (
1993). Commoners frequently support usurpers or separatists to put an end to oppre
regimes (Fortes and Evans-Pritchard 1940:11; Fallers 1956:247; Gluckman 1956
Sahlins 1972:145-148; Helms 1979:28).
Political competition is never fully resolved. Rulers always have siblings and offsp
who conceive ambitions to rule (Goody 1966; Burling 1974). Regional hierarchies
always depend upon lower-level local hierarchies, and these local hierarchies will poss
some organizational integrity and some ability to pursue autonomous goals (We
1976:818; Yoffee 1979:14). No matter how great the territory incorporated into the s
it always has borders beyond its control where refugees fleeing state expansion can
with peripheral leaders, usually the political clients and trade partners of the state,
together, refugees and leaders can threaten state control of frontier regions (Lattim
1951; Bronson 1988; Barfield 1989; Patterson 1991b:107-116). Almost always, in t
to satisfy some of these factions, rulers alienate others.

This content downloaded from 190.96.91.202 on Fri, 09 Aug 2019 21:29:52 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
558 AMERICAN ANTHROPOLOGIST [94, 1992

Rulers, then, must concern themselves with


economy, that is, the distribution of wealth to
versa. Some ecosystem theorists (e.g., White
omy with subsistence economy, regarding pow
ample, Gall and Saxe (1977:264-265) state, "
complex sociocultural systems persevere becau
cialist who can harness the greatest number o
cessful power holders must be effective mani
relations. Maintaining a following requires
timing and an ideology that maintains the loy
Several aspects of prehistoric economies are b
of a political economy rather than a subsisten
sification of household production is often the
of surplus to finance factional competitio
Brumfiel and Fox 1993). The elaboration of pr
boyant civic/religious architecture, both of w
record in situations of emerging complexity,
political alliances (Webster 1976; Yoffee 197
1987; Brumfiel 1987a, 1987b).
The prevalence of factional competition in co
implications. It suggests that complex society
implied by the orderly flowcharts of ecosyste
poses, it is "a continually shifting patchwork
bound together by interacting contradictio
comments on the absence of integration in
and peripheries, civil and kin groups, ruler
women, and producers and extractors evok
cesses." The intensity and diversity of these i
riods of time, states are guided by short-term
system-serving goals. This, in turn, calls into
assumption that complex societies are adapt
In biology, evolutionary success is measur
predict evolutionary success. Not the amoun
the efficiency of energy capture, nor the quan
sures continued survival. If we reject all pr
complex societies and apply instead the onl
complex societies, which are often short-l
1989:375; Patterson 1992), may have to be ju
forms. The history of states is the history of
oppositional groups, leading cumulatively t
dissolution. But the membership of these grou
of their strategies cannot be discovered by sy
zation of human actors.

Systems-Centered and Agent-Centered Perspectives


Finding the proper balance between the individual and the system, between agency
and structure, has been a persistent problem for archeology. Under the sway of ecosystem
theory during the 1960s and 1970s, whole populations and whole systems of adaptiv
cultural behavior served as the units of analysis. During the 1980s, a series of actor-based
decision-making models have been introduced to archeology (Keene 1979; Winterhald
and Smith 1981; Boyd and Richerson 1985; Braun 1990; Durham 1990; Earle 1991; Shen
nan 1991). To the extent that these models contextualize decision making in a structure
of ecologically and socially determined payoffs, they show considerable promise. Bu

This content downloaded from 190.96.91.202 on Fri, 09 Aug 2019 21:29:52 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Brumfiel] DISTINGUISHED LECTURE IN ARCHEOLOGY 559

many of these models have inherited processual archeol


class, and factional affiliation; thus, they fail to inquire ho
vary by social category. To strike a proper balance between
have to accept the following principles.
First, we must reject the notion that a cultural system is
subject to selection and adaptive change. Instead, we shou
tems are contingent and negotiated, the composite outcome
and the unforeseen consequences of human action.
Second, following suggestions by Cowgill (1975), Orlo
Blanton et al. (1981:23-24), we should recognize that hum
tems, are the agents of culture change. Human actors devis
their problems and meet their goals, and these strategies ar
solely by differential survival either at the population leve
have it, or at the level of the individual as more recent
claim. This is not to say that humans always "get it righ
lead to unforeseen consequences. It is simply to argue th
cultural outcomes.
Third, we should recognize that to argue that human action is goal-directed is not nec-
essarily to open the floodgates to cultural particularism. For, as ecosystem theory h
taught us, human action occurs within a structural context that shapes both its goals and
outcomes. Goals are achieved via the manipulation of two interrelated systems that bind
human choice to a structure of opportunities and constraints. The first of these is the b
now familiar natural ecosystem that determines the costs and benefits of different pro-
duction strategies (Trigger 1991). The second is the system of social alliances that struc-
tures access to resources and power on the basis of gender, class, and factional affiliation
Besides determining people's ability to achieve their goals, the social system also dete
mines, in many ways, what those goals will be: alliance, surplus extraction, usurpation,
resistance, liberation, and so on. Thus, we must analyze social as well as ecological va
ables, what Flannery (1988:58), getting it half right, anyway, has called "man-man" and
"man-land" relationships (also see Adams 1966). In particular, we must insert soci
power as a primary structural variable (Wolf 1990). We must analyze how alliance ne
works controlling labor and resources are constructed on the basis of gender, class, and
factional affiliation, and we must study how individuals and groups contrive to bri
about transformations in the membership and resources controlled by these networks.
Fourth, to analyze specific sequences of change, it will be necessary to alternate b
tween a subject-centered and a system-centered analysis (Giddens 1979). A subject-ce
tered analysis organizes ecological and social variables by weighing them according
their importance in specific behavioral strategies. A system-centered analysis reveals how
the implementation of these strategies alters the quality and distribution of ecological an
social resources among the groups, creating new strategic possibilities for the next roun
of behavior.
Verifying the existence of strategic action in the archeological record will not differ in
principle from the way that subsistence strategies are verified in the ecosystem approach.
In ecosystem theory, many artifact classes, settlement pattern types, and the like, have
been assigned functions within reconstructed subsistence strategies on the basis of their
technical properties, ethnographic analogy, and archeological contexts. These same ap-
proaches may be used to assign functions to classes of data in reconstructed social strat-
egies. These strategies will leave distinctive imprints on such aspects of the archeological
record as house size and plan, and surplus storage facilities (Saitta and Keene 1990). In
addition, many attributes of ceramics, burials, architecture, personal adornment, and the
use of space, which have been considered stylistic from the viewpoint of ecosystem theory,
may be understood as expressions of claims and counterclaims in ongoing social negoti-
ation (Hodder 1986:8; Shanks and Tilley 1987:133; for examples see Hodder 1982; Miller
and Tilley 1984; Fritz 1986; Small 1987; Moore 1986; Brumfiel and Earle 1987b; Brumfiel

This content downloaded from 190.96.91.202 on Fri, 09 Aug 2019 21:29:52 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
560 AMERICAN ANTHROPOLOGIST [94, 1992

1987a, 1987b, 1990; Brumfiel, Salcedo, and


Contrary to Hodder (1986:6) and Shanks an
negotiation can be studied cross-culturally; si
leave broadly similar imprints on material cu
The analytical principles I have suggested
ditional ecosystem theory. This departure
for the full range of archeological data at ou
of household production, variation in househ
in demographic trends, the occurrence of en
the intensity and organization of warfare an
here should also enable us to create a more
acknowledge the creativity and discretion th
exercised in the past to fashion their liveliho

Notes

Acknowledgments. This paper has benefited immensely from the comments and criticisms offe
by Len Berkey, Michael Blake, Mary Collar, John Clark, George Cowgill, Antonio Gilman,
Hodge, Roberto Korzeniewicz, Hattula Moholy-Nagy, Tom Patterson, Glenn Perusek, H
Wright, Rita Wright, and members of the Department of Anthropology, New York Universi
where an earlier version of this paper was presented. I am very grateful for their help.
'This is in keeping with the idea of at least some ecosystem theorists that explanation in arc
ogy would consist of laws of correlation, rather than laws of connection (Wylie 1982:386). Fo
ample, Binford (1962:218) defines scientific explanation as "the demonstration of a constant a
ulation of variables within a system and the measurement of the concomitant variability amon
variables within the system." This definition betrays an interest in systemic function rather
systemic structure, that is, a concern with what the system does as opposed to how it operate
Salmon 1978:175).
2In fact, Redman (1978b:341) regards the self-interested activities of the elite as a major pro
leading to the emergence of social complexity: "the elite . . . were participants in the fifth po
feedback relationship--that is, purposeful strategies of the elite to stimulate further growth o
institutions that gave them their power and wealth."
3Adams's (1974) examination of Mesopotamian ecology from the viewpoint of the indivi
peasant producer offers interesting contrasts to Redman's (1978a:229-236) more system-fo
approach.

References Cited

Adams, Robert McC.


1966 The Evolution of Urban Society: Early Mesopotamia and Prehispanic Mexico. Ch
Aldine.
1974 The Mesopotamian Social Landscape: A View from the Frontier. In Reconstructing Com-
plex Societies. C. B. Moore, ed. Pp. 1-11. Chicago: Supplement to the Bulletin of the Ameri-
can Schools of Oriental Research, No. 20.
1978 Strategies of Maximization, Stability, and Resilience in Mesopotamian Society, Settle-
ment, and Agriculture. Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society 122:329-335.
Barfield, Thomas J.
1989 The Perilous Frontier. London: Basil Blackwell.
Bartlett, K.
1933 Pueblo Milling Stones of the Flagstaff Region and Their Relation to Others in the Southwest:
A Study in Progressive Efficiency. Flagstaff: Museum of Northern Arizona, Bulletin No. 3.
Bender, Barbara
1978 Gatherer-Hunter to Farmer: A Social Perspective. World Archaeology 10:204-222.
Binford, Lewis R.
1962 Archaeology as Anthropology. American Antiquity 28:217-225.
Blanton, Richard E.
1975 The Cybernetic Analysis of Human Population Growth. In Population Studies in Ar-
chaeology and Biological Anthropology: A Symposium. A. C. Swedlund, ed. Pp. 116-126.
Washington, DC: Society for American Archaeology Memoirs, 30.

This content downloaded from 190.96.91.202 on Fri, 09 Aug 2019 21:29:52 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Brumfiel] DISTINGUISHED LECTURE IN ARCHEOLOGY 561

Blanton, Richard E., Stephen A. Kowalewski, Gary Feinman, an


1981 Ancient Mesoamerica: A Comparison of Change in Thr
bridge University Press.
Blaut, James M.
1987 The National Question: Decolonising the Theory of Natio
Boyd, Robert, and PeterJ. Richerson
1985 Culture and the Evolutionary Process. Chicago: Universit
Braun, David P.
1981 Pots as Tools. In Archaeological Hammers and Theories
eds. Pp. 108-134. New York: Academic Press.
1990 Selection and Evolution in Nonhierarchical Organization
Systems. S. Upham, ed. Pp. 62-86. Cambridge: Cambridge Un
Braun, David P., and Stephen Plog
1982 Evolution of "Tribal" Social Networks: Theory and Pre
dence. American Antiquity 47:504-525.
Bronson, Bennet
1988 The Role of Barbarians in the Fall of States. In The Colla
ilizations. N. Yoffee and G. L. Cowgill, eds. Pp. 196-218. Tucson
Brumfiel, Elizabeth M.
1987a Elite and Utilization Crafts in the Aztec State. In Speci
plex Societies. E. M. Brumfiel and T. K. Earle, eds. Pp. 102-
University Press.
1987b Consumption and Politics at Aztec Huexotla. American
1990 Figurines, Ideological Domination and the Aztec State. P
nual meeting of the American Anthropological Association, N
1991 Weaving and Cooking: Women's Production in Aztec Me
ology. J. M. Gero and M. W. Conkey, eds. Pp. 224-251. Oxfor
Brumfiel, Elizabeth M., and Timothy K. Earle
1987a Specialization, Exchange, and Complex Societies: An In
Exchange, and Complex Societies. E. M. Brumfiel and T. K. E
Cambridge University Press.
1987b [eds.] Specialization, Exchange, and Complex Societies.
versity Press.
Brumfiel, Elizabeth M., and John W. Fox, eds.
1993 Factional Competition and Political Development in the
bridge University Press. (In press.)
Brumfiel, Elizabeth M., Tamara Salcedo, and David K. Schafer
1993 The Lip Plugs of Xaltocan: Function and Meaning in Azt
and Polities in the Aztec Realm. M. G. Hodge and M. E. Smit
versity of New York Press, Latin American Series. (In press.)
Burling, Robbins
1974 The Passage of Power: Studies in Political Succession. Ne
Chevillard, Nicole, and Sebastien Leconte
1986 The Dawn of Lineage Societies: The Origins of Women's O
Men's Property. S. Coontz and P. Henderson, eds. Pp. 76-107
Claassen, Cheryl P.
1991 Gender, Shellfishing, and the Shell Mound Archaic. In E
Gero and M. W. Conkey, eds. Pp. 276-300. Oxford: Basil Blac
Clark, John E.
1988 The Lithic Artifacts of La Libertad, Chiapas, Mexico. Pr
ological Foundation Papers, 52.
Clark, John E., and Michael Blake
1993 The Power of Prestige: Competitive Generosity and the
Lowland Mesoamerica. In Factional Competition and Politic
World. E. M. Brumfiel and J. W. Fox, eds. Cambridge: Cam
press.)
Clarke, David L.
1968 Analytical Archaeology. London: Methuen.

This content downloaded from 190.96.91.202 on Fri, 09 Aug 2019 21:29:52 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
562 AMERICAN ANTHROPOLOGIST [94, 1992

1972 A Provisional Model of an Iron Age Society


Pp. 801-869. London: Methuen.
Conkey, Margaret W., and Joan M. Gero
1991 Tensions, Pluralities, and Engendering A
Prehistory. In Engendering Archaeology. J. M
ford: Basil Blackwell.
Conkey, Margaret W., and Janet D. Spector
1984 Archaeology and the Study of Gender. Advances in Archaeological Method and Theory
7:1-38.
Coontz, Stephanie, and Peta Henderson
1986 Property Forms, Political Power and Female Labour in the Origins of Class and State
Societies. In Women's Work, Men's Property. S. Coontz and P. Henderson, eds. Pp. 108-15
London: Verso.
Costin, Cathy L.
1986 From Chiefdom to Empire State: Ceramic Economy among the Prehispanic Wanka of
Highland Peru. Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Anthropology, University of Californi
Los Angeles.
Cowgill, George L.
1975 On Causes and Consequences of Ancient and Modern Population Changes. American
Anthropologist 77:505-525.
D'Altroy, Terrance, and Timothy Earle
1985 Staple Finance, Wealth Finance, and Storage in the Inka Political Economy. Current
Anthropology 26:187-206.
Dunnell, Robert C.
1980 Evolutionary Theory and Archaeology. Advances in Archaeological Method and Theory
3:35-99.
Durham, William H.
1990 Advances in Evolutionary Culture Theory. Annual Review of Anthropology 19:187
Earle, Timothy K.
1978 Economic and Social Organization of a Complex Chiefdom: The Halelea Dist
Kaua'i, Hawaii. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Museum of Anthropology, Anthropol
ical Papers, 63.
1987 Specialization and the Production of Wealth: Hawaiian Chiefdoms and the Inka Empire.
In Specialization, Exchange, and Complex Societies. E. M. Brumfiel and T. K. Earle, eds. Pp.
64-75. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
1991 Toward a Behavioral Archaeology. In Processual and Postprocessual Archaeologies. R. W.
Preucel, ed. Pp. 83-95. Carbondale: Southern Illinois University Center for Archaeological In-
vestigations, Occasional Paper No. 10.
Eisenstadt, S. N.
1963 The Political Systems of Empires. New York: Free Press.
Fallers, Lloyd A.
1956 Bantu Bureaucracy: A Century of Political Evolution among the Basoga of Uganda. Chi-
cago: University of Chicago Press.
Flannery, Kent V.
1967 Culture History v. Cultural Process: A Debate in American Archaeology. Scientific
American 217:119-122.
1968a Archeological Systems Theory and Early Mesoamerica. In Anthropological Archeology
in the Americas. B. J. Meggers, ed. Pp. 67-87. Washington, DC: Anthropological Society of
Washington.
1968b The Olmec and the Valley of Oaxaca. In Dumbarton Oaks Conference on the Olmec.
E. P. Benson, ed. Pp. 79-110. Washington, DC: Dumbarton Oaks.
1972 The Cultural Evolution of Civilizations. Annual Review of Ecology and Systematics
3:399-426.
1988 Comment on Sanders and Nichols' "Ecological Theory and Cultural Evolution in the
Valley of Oaxaca." Current Anthropology 29:58.
Flannery, Kent V., and Marcus C. Winter
1976 Analyzing Household Activities. In The Early Mesoamerican Village. K. V. Flannery,
ed. Pp. 34-47. New York: Academic Press.

This content downloaded from 190.96.91.202 on Fri, 09 Aug 2019 21:29:52 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Brumfiel] DISTINGUISHED LECTURE IN ARCHEOLOGY 563

Fortes, M., and E. E. Evans-Pritchard


1940 Introduction. In African Political Systems. F. Fortes and
1-23. London: Oxford University Press.
Fox, Richard G., and Allen Zagarell
1982 The Political Economy of Mesopotamian and South India
Reproduction of Urban Society. Comparative Urban Researc
Friedman, Jonathan
1977 Tribes, States, and Transformations. In Marxist Analyse
Bloch, ed. Pp. 201-276. New York: Wiley.
Fritz, John M.
1986 Vijayanagara: Authority and Meaning of a South Indian
Anthropologist 88:44-55.
Gailey, Christine W.
1985a The State of the State in Anthropology. Dialectical Ant
1985b The Kindness of Strangers: Transformations of Kinship
Formation. Culture 5(2):3-16.
1987 Kinship to Kingship: Gender Hierarchy and State Form
Austin: University of Texas Press.
Gall, Patricia L., and Arthur A. Saxe
1977 The Ecological Evolution of Culture: The State as Predato
change Systems in Prehistory. T. K. Earle and J. E. Ericson,
Academic Press.
Giddens, Anthony
1979 Central Problems in Social Theory. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Gilman, Antonio
1981 The Development of Social Stratification in Bronze Age Europe. Current Anthropo
22:1-23.
Gluckman, Max
1956 Custom and Conflict in Africa. New York: Barnes and Noble.
Goody, Jack
1966 Introduction. In Succession to High Office. J. Goody, ed. Pp. 1-56. Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press.
Halstead, Paul, and John O'Shea
1982 A Friend in Need Is a Friend Indeed: Social Storage and the Origins of Social Ranking.
In Ranking, Resource and Exchange. C. Renfrew and S. Shennan, eds. Pp. 92-99. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Harris, David R.
1977 Alternative Pathways toward Agriculture. In Origins of Agriculture. C. A. Reed, ed. Pp.
179-243. The Hague: Mouton.
Hartmann, Heidi
1981 The Family as the Locus of Gender, Class, and Political Struggle: The Example of House-
work. Signs 6:366-394.
Hassan, Fekri A.
1981 Demographic Archaeology. New York: Academic Press.
Hastorf, Christine A.
1991 Gender, Space, and Food in Prehistory. In Engendering Archaeology. J. M. Gero and
M. W. Conkey, eds. Pp. 132-159. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Hastorf, Christine A., and SisselJohannessen
1991 Understanding Changing People/Plant Relationships in the Prehispanic Andes. In Pro-
cessual and Postprocessual Archaeologies. R. W. Preucel, ed. Pp. 140-155. Carbondale:
Southern Illinois University Center for Archaeological Investigations, Occasional Paper No.
10.
Hayden, Brian
1981 Research and Development in the Stone Age: Technological Transitions among Hunter/
Gatherers. Current Anthropology 22:519-548.
1990 Nimrods, Piscators, Pluckers, and Planters: The Emergence of Food Production.Journal
of Anthropological Archaeology 9:31-69.
Helms, Mary W.
1979 Ancient Panama: Chiefs in Search of Power. Austin: University of Texas Press.

This content downloaded from 190.96.91.202 on Fri, 09 Aug 2019 21:29:52 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
564 AMERICAN ANTHROPOLOGIST [94, 1992

Hicks, Frederic
1993 Alliance and Intervention in Aztec Imper
Political Development in the New World. E. M
Cambridge University Press. (In press.)
Hill, James N.
1977 Systems Theory and the Explanation of C
J. N. Hill, ed. Pp. 59-103. Albuquerque: Univers
Hodder, Ian
1982 [ed.] Symbolic and Structural Archaeology
1986 Reading the Past. Cambridge: Cambridge U
Jackson, Thomas L.
1991 Pounding Acorn: Women's Production as
Archaeology. J. M. Gero and M. W. Conkey, e
Johnson, Gregory A.
1978 Information Sources and the Development
Archeology. C. L. Redman et al., eds. Pp. 87-11
Kaufman, Herbert
1988 The Collapse of Ancient States and Civiliz
Collapse of Ancient States and Civilizations. N
Tucson: University of Arizona Press.
Keene, Arthur S.
1979 Economic Optimization Models and the St
ment Systems. In Transformations: Mathematica
and K. Cooke. eds. Pp. 369-404. New York: Aca
Kehoe, Alice B.
1990 Points and Lines. In Powers of Observation
son and A. B. Kehoe, eds. Pp. 23-37. Washingto
tion, Archeological Papers, No. 2.
King, Thomas F.
1978 Don't that Beat the Band? Nonegalitarian
California. In Social Archeology. C. L. Redman
Press.
Kohl, Philip L.
1981 Materialist Approaches in Prehistory. Ann
Kristiansen, Kristian
1981 Economic Models for Bronze Age Scandin
Economic Archaeology: Towards an Integratio
Sheridan and G. Bailey, eds. Pp. 239-303. BAR I
chaeological Reports.
Lattimore, Owen
1951 Inner Asian Frontiers of China. Boston: Beacon Press.
Lenin, V. I.
1939 Imperialism: The Highest Stage of Capitalism. New York: International.
Lewis, Oscar
1942 The Effects of White Contact upon Blackfoot Culture. American Ethnological Society
Monographs, 6. Seattle: University of Washington Press.
McGuire, Randall H.
1983 Breaking Down Cultural Complexity: Inequality and Heterogeneity. Advances in Ar-
chaeological Method and Theory 6:91-142.
McGuire, Randall H., and Robert Paynter, eds.
1991 The Archaeology of Inequality. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Miller, Daniel, and Christopher Tilley, eds.
1984 Ideology, Power and Prehistory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Moore, Henrietta
1986 Space, Text and Gender. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
1990 Gender Relations and the Modelling of the Economy. Paper presented at the 10th annual
meeting of the Society for Economic Anthropology, Tucson, Arizona.

This content downloaded from 190.96.91.202 on Fri, 09 Aug 2019 21:29:52 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Brumfiel] DISTINGUISHED LECTURE IN ARCHEOLOGY 565

Nelson, Sarah M.
1990 Diversity of the Upper Paleolithic "Venus" Figurines and
Powers of Observation: Alternative Views in Archeology. S. M
Pp. 11-22. Washington, DC: American Anthropological Assoc
No. 2.
Orlove, Benjamin S.
1980 Ecological Anthropology. Annual Review of Anthropolog
Patterson, Thomas C.
1991a Race and Archaeology: A Comparative and Historical Vie
annual meeting of the American Anthropological Association.
1991b The Inca Empire: The Formation and Disintegration o
York: Berg.
1992 Archaeology: The Historical Development of Civilizations. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Pren-
tice-Hall. (In press.)
Paynter, Robert
1989 The Archaeology of Equality and Inequality. Annual Review of Anthropology 18:369-
399.
Price, Barbara J.
1982 Cultural Materialism: A Theoretical Review. American Antiquity 47:709-741.
Rapp, Rayna
1978 The Search for Origins: Unraveling the Threads of Gender Hierarchy. Critique of An-
thropology 3:5-24.
Redman, Charles L.
1978a The Rise of Civilization. San Francisco, CA: W. H. Freeman.
1978b Mesopotamian Urban Ecology: The Systemic Context of the Emergence of Urbanism.
In Social Archeology. C. L. Redman et al., eds. Pp. 329-347. New York: Academic Press.
Rowlands, Michael
1980 Kinship, Alliance and Exchange in the European Bronze Age. In Settlement and Society
in the British Later Bronze Age.J. Barrett and R. Bradley, eds. Pp. 15-55. BAR British Series,
83. Oxford: British Archaeological Reports.
Sahlins, Marshall
1968 Tribesmen. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
1972 Stone Age Economics. Chicago: Aldine.
Saitta, DeanJ., and Arthur S. Keene
1990 Primitive Communism and the Origin of Social Inequality. In The Evolution of Political
Systems. S. Upham, ed. Pp. 203-224. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Salmon, Merrilee H.
1978 What Can Systems Theory Do for Archaeology? American Antiquity 43:174-183.
Sanders, William T., Jeffrey R. Parsons, and Robert S. Santley
1979 The Basin of Mexico. New York: Academic Press.
Sanders, William T., and BarbaraJ. Price
1968 Mesoamerica: The Evolution of a Civilization. New York: Random House.
Santley, Robert S.
1980 Disembedded Capitals Reconsidered. American Antiquity 45:132-145.
Shanks, Michael, and Christopher Tilley
1987 Re-Constructing Archaeology. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Shennan, Stephen J.
1991 Tradition, Rationality, and Cultural Transmission. In Processual and Postprocessu
chaeologies. R. W. Preucel, ed. Pp. 197-208. Carbondale: Southern Illinois University C
for Archaeological Investigations, Occasional Paper No. 10.
Silverblatt, Irene
1987 Moon, Sun, and Witches: Gender Ideologies and Class in Inca and Colonial Peru. P
ton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
1988 Women in States. Annual Review of Anthropology 17:427-460.
Small, David B.
1987 Toward a Competent Structuralist Archaeology: Contribution from Historical St
Journal of Anthropological Archaeology 6:105-121.

This content downloaded from 190.96.91.202 on Fri, 09 Aug 2019 21:29:52 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
566 AMERICAN ANTHROPOLOGIST [94, 1992

Stahl, Ann B.
1989 Plant-Food Processing: Implications for D
Evolution of Plant Exploitation. D. R. Harris a
Unwin Hyman.
Stanish, Charles
1989 Household Archeology: Testing Models of
Andes. American Anthropologist 91:7-24.
Steward, Julian H.
1955 The Concept and Method of Cultural Ecol
Urbana: University of Illinois Press.
Struever, Stuart, and Felicia Antonelli Holton
1979 Koster: Americans in Search of Their Preh
Terray, Emmanuel
1979 Long-Distance Trade and the Formation o
of Gyaman. In Toward a Marxist Anthropolog
Mouton.
Trigger, Bruce G.
1991 Distinguished Lecture in Archeology: Constraint and Freedom-A New Synthesis for A
cheological Explanation. American Anthropologist 93:551-569.
Tringham, Ruth E.
1991 Households with Faces: The Challenge of Gender in Prehistoric Architectural Remai
In Engendering Archaeology. J. M. Gero and M. W. Conkey, eds. Pp. 93-131. Oxford: Bas
Blackwell.
Tymowski, Michal
1991 Wolof Economy and Political Organization: The West African Coast in the Mid-Fif-
teenth Century. In Early State Economics. H. J. M. Claessen and P. van de Velde, eds. Pp.
131-142. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction.
Watson, PattyJo, and Mary Kennedy
1991 The Development of Horticulture in the Eastern Woodlands of North America: Women'
Role. In Engendering Archaeology. J. M. Gero and M. W. Conkey, eds. Pp. 255-275. Oxford
Basil Blackwell.
Webster, David
1975 Warfare and the Evolution of the State: A Reconsideration. American Antiquity 40:4
470.
1976 On Theocracies. American Anthropologist 78:812-828.
Weiner, Annette B., andJane Schneider, eds.
1989 Cloth and Human Experience. Washington, DC: Smithsonian Institution Press.
White, Leslie A.
1949 The Science of Culture. New York: Grove.
1959 The Evolution of Culture. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Wilk, Richard R., and Wendy Ashmore, eds.
1988 House and Household in the Mesoamerican Past. Albuquerque: University of N
ico Press.
Wilk, Richard R., and WilliamJ. Rathje, eds.
1982 Archaeology of the Household: Building a Prehistory of Domestic Life. American Behav-
ioral Scientist 25(6).
Williams, Brackette F.
1989 A Class Act: Anthropology and the Race to Nation across Ethnic Terrain. Annual Review
of Anthropology 18:401-444.
Winterhalder, Bruce, and Eric Alden Smith, eds.
1981 Hunter-Gatherer Foraging Strategies. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Wolf, Eric R.
1982 Europe and the People without History. Berkeley: University of California Press.
1990 Distinguished Lecture: Facing Power-Old Insights, New Questions. American Anthro-
pologist 92:586-596.
Wright, Henry T.
1970 Toward an Explanation of the Origin of the State. Paper presented at the School of Amer-
ican Research symposium, "Explanation of Prehistoric Organizational Change," Santa Fe,
New Mexico.

This content downloaded from 190.96.91.202 on Fri, 09 Aug 2019 21:29:52 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Brumfiel] DISTINGUISHED LECTURE IN ARCHEOLOGY 567

1977 Recent Research on the Origin of the State. Annual Revie


Wylie, Alison
1982 An Analogy by Any Other Name Is Just as Analogical. Journal of Anthropological Ar-
chaeology 1:382-401.
Yoffee, Norman
1979 The Decline and Rise of Mesopotamian Civilization: An Ethnoarchaeological Perspective
on the Evolution of Social Complexity. American Antiquity 44:5-35.
Yoffee, Norman, and George L. Cowgill, eds.
1988 The Collapse of Ancient States and Civilizations. Tucson: University of Arizona Press.
Zagarell, Allen
1986 Trade, Women, Class, and Society in Ancient Western Asia. Current Anthropology
27:415-430.

This content downloaded from 190.96.91.202 on Fri, 09 Aug 2019 21:29:52 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

Potrebbero piacerti anche