Sei sulla pagina 1di 17

ARTICLE IN PRESS

Energy Policy 34 (2006) 2762–2778


www.elsevier.com/locate/enpol

Examining market power in the European natural gas market


Rudolf G. Egginga, Steven A. Gabrielb,,1
a
Policy Studies Group, Energy Research Centre of the Netherlands, Badhuisweg 3, 1031 CM, Amsterdam, Netherlands
b
Department of Civil & Environmental Engineering, Applied Mathematics and Scientific Computation Program, University of Maryland,
College Park, MD 20742, USA
Available online 14 June 2005

Abstract

In this paper, we develop a mixed complementarity equilibrium model for the European natural gas market. This model has
producers as Cournot players with conjectured supply functions relative to their rivals. As such, these producers can withhold
production to increase downstream prices for greater profits. The other players are taken to be perfectly competitive and are
combined with extensive pipeline, seasonal, and other data reflecting the current state of the market. Four market scenarios are run
to analyze the extent of market power by these producers as well as the importance of pipeline and storage capacity.
r 2005 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Keywords: European gas market equilibrium; Complementary model; Gas market policies

1. Introduction These imports are costly and depend often on countries


in politically unstable regions.
Energy supplies are the major prerequisite for Historically, security of energy supplies (SoS) refers to
economic development and maintaining the current the safeguarding of oil supplies starting from the oil
welfare standard in modern societies. Growing popula- crisis in the early seventies that triggered the formation
tions and increasing economic outputs are drivers of of the 3-months IEA oil reserves. Since then, many
growing energy use (as attempts for a general decou- situations and research reports have broadened the
pling of energy input and economic output have not scope of the concept of SoS. Today SoS covers a wide
been too successful). Although renewable and nuclear range of issues, involving different timeframes, energy
sources add significantly to energy inputs, fossil fuels carriers, infrastructure, geopolitical relations, and mar-
provide the biggest part of the needed energy. To meet ket power in liberalizing markets. In the past few
the growing energy demand, fossil fuels are the most decades the role of natural gas has increased. Natural
cost-efficient in the short term. However their negative gas reserves are spread more widely over the globe than
impact on climate cannot be neglected. The major fossil oil reserves, however the majority of reserves are also
fuel reserves are located in just a handful of countries, so located in just a handful of countries.
most countries, industrialized or developing, will have to In 2001 fossil fuels for the European Union (EU)
continue to import large shares of their fossil fuels. constituted 78 percent of the energy provided with the
remaining share mainly from nuclear and some hydro-
electric power and renewables. Of this 78 percent, oil
Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 301 405 3242;
constituted 40 percent, natural gas 23 percent, and coal
fax: +1 301 405 2585. 15 percent (IEA, 2002a). Recent projections indicate a
E-mail address: sgabriel@umd.edu (S.A. Gabriel).
1
This author was partially supported for this work by the National
stable fossil fuel share in the coming decades but with an
Science Foundation grant 0106880 in the Division of Mathematical ever increasing allotment to natural gas. The share of
Sciences. natural gas will increase to about 30 percent, mainly at

0301-4215/$ - see front matter r 2005 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2005.04.018
ARTICLE IN PRESS
R.G. Egging, S.A. Gabriel / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 2762–2778 2763

the expense of coal which is projected to drop to 10 big energy multinationals. For example, the top four
percent accompanied by a slight decrease in oil use companies account for almost 50 percent of the total
(www.eia.doe.gov). production in the EU, whereas the production of the top
One of the main drivers for the projected increase in ten is 80.7 percent (Cedigaz, 2002b). Both in the external
use of natural gas in Europe is the Kyoto protocol supply situation as well as the internal supply, just a few
(UNFCCC, 1998) and its reduction goals for carbon entities have a big share in supply (either imports or
dioxide emissions. Natural gas has a lower carbon production). Oligopolistic market behavior could give
content than coal and oil, about 50 percent lower than rise to market power by these firms.
coal, and 25 percent lower than oil, which makes gas a Several legislative, informative and infrastructural
favored fuel from an environmental perspective (IPCC, measures have been taken to secure the supply of
1995). natural gas to EU consumers. Legislative measures
Besides environmental reasons another important include the legal splitting of gas sellers and network
factor for natural gas usage is the longer term supply operators and legislation for obligatory Third Party
situation. Currently, the EU imports 45 percent of the Access to transmission, distribution, storage and LNG
natural gas that it uses, whereas the import share of oil is capacity (EC 2003/55/EC, 2003). An informative mea-
as much as 75 percent (IEA, 2002a). Both import shares sure is the setting up of a Monitoring Agency that
will increase in the near future given the limited reserves should develop a database of production volumes,
within the EU (BP, 2003). Indeed, at the current level of demand estimates and stock levels. Regarding infra-
production the reserve/production ratio translates to structure developments the EC has set up lists of priority
around 67 years worldwide for natural gas and 41 years projects (EC, 2000b). This list contains projects for
for crude oil. The main external natural gas suppliers to introduction of natural gas into new regions, connection
the EU are Russia, Norway and Algeria. In 2001 these of isolated gas networks to European interconnected
three countries delivered 80 percent of all gas imports to networks, increasing LNG reception and storage capa-
the EU. In particular, Gazprom (Russia) delivered 30.7 cities, and increasing transmission capacities. Examples
percent, Sonatrach (Algeria) 20.5 percent and GFU of options are: more and extended LNG terminals in
(Norway) 19.4 percent, while Netherlands-based Gasu- countries such as France, Spain, Greece and Italy, as
nie delivered 17.1 percent. Thus, four companies well as better interconnection of United Kingdom and
accounted for 87.7 percent of all imports in 2001 Ireland, and connection of the UK to the mainland.
(Cedigaz, 2002a). As stated above the 87% of all exports to EU
As for internal suppliers, the major EU producers are countries are supplied by only four companies. There
the United Kingdom and the Netherlands. Reserves clearly is a risk that certain players in the European
from the United Kingdom are declining rapidly as natural gas market can be considered as strategic
indicated by the reserve production ratio of only 6.8 relative to their potential exercise of market power. In
years at the end of 2002. The UK will become a net gas the model presented below, producers are modeled as a
importer within a few years leaving the Netherlands as combination of strategic players who can affect end-use
the only country in the EU with significant reserves. At prices by their production levels as well as price-takers
the current level of production, the Dutch reserves will via their conjectures about their rivals’ production. By
last for 25 years (BP, 2003). Clearly the EU dependency contrast, the storage operators and transportation
on external suppliers for gas will grow in the coming operators are taken to be perfectly competitive with no
decades. Nearby suppliers as Russia, Norway and market power. In effect, all the players are depicted as
Algeria hold, respectively, 30.5, 1.4 and 2.9 percent of solving separate optimization problems whose joint
world reserves, and a relatively nearby country as Iran, solution, taken together with market-clearing conditions
14.8 percent, so there are plenty of potential supplies gives rise to a market equilibrium expressed as a
relatively nearby. The large and ever-increasing depen- nonlinear complementarity problem (NCP) (Harker
dency of external supplies has led to a need for measures and Pang, 1990).2
to manage supply risks and secure supplies. Broader Previous efforts for modeling natural gas markets
energy supply security is addressed in the so-called have either concentrated on non-game-theoretic ap-
‘‘Green Paper’’ (EC 2000-769, 2000a) as well as the proaches such as maximizing total surplus (Takayama
European Commission (EC) directive 2004/67/EC con- and Judge, 1971) and/or have not included the level of
cerning measures to safeguard security of natural gas market detail contained in the current work.
supply. Some of the earlier efforts at characterizing various
Besides the issue of external supply security for aspects of the European natural gas market include
natural gas the liberalization process induced by the Tzoannos (1977) who modeled the domestic British
EC as formulated in Directive 2003/55/EC (EC 2003-55, market based on maximizing the social welfare function.
2003) concerning common rules for the internal market
2
in natural gas has resulted in strong positions for some Alternatively, a variational inequality (VI) approach can be used.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
2764 R.G. Egging, S.A. Gabriel / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 2762–2778

Later, Haurie et al. (1987) developed a stochastic problems faced by the players in the European natural
Nash–Cournot model and considered long-term pro- gas market are described along with market-clearing
duction contracts. Mathiesen et al. (1987) also consid- conditions. Section 3 outlines the market scenarios that
ered the European natural gas market in their work were considered and presents numerical results of using
which discussed market power on the selling side. De the NCP model described in the Appendix to analyze
Wolf and Smeers (1997) chose a Stackelberg game market power issues. Section 3 concludes with an
perspective for their work on the European natural gas explicit link of our results to recent EC policy
market with one producer as the leader and the others as documents regarding the internal market and security
followers. The stochastic equilibrium approach was also of supply, thus validating the significance of our model.
used by Gürkan et al. (1999) who employed a sample- Lastly, Section 4 provides a summary of the value of this
path perspective. Breton and Zaccour (2001) concen- research and anticipated future work.
trated on analyzing a duopoly of producers but in
abstract form. More recently, Boots et al. (2004)
constructed Gas mArket System for Trade Analysis in 2. The European natural gas market
a Liberalizing Europe (GASTALE), a much more
detailed version of the European natural gas market. 2.1. Overview
That model, based in part on the work by Golombek et
al. (1995, 1998) used a successive oligopoly perspective. Worldwide production of natural gas in 2002 equaled
The current work is an extension of GASTALE in that it 2528 bcm (billion cubic meters, 109 m3). The total
additionally considers storage operations, seasonally production in the 15 EU countries3 was 209 bcm or 8.3
varying demand, explicit incorporation of restricted percent of the global amount. Fig. 1 shows the major
transmission and LNG terminal capacities. Other producing countries in the EU. Production levels for
differences are no successive oligopoly approach, and 2002 were as follows: United Kingdom 103 bcm, the
producers are countries, producers produce in only one Netherlands 60 bcm, Germany 17 bcm, and Italy
country. Due to its level of detail and behavioral 15 bcm. Of the total Russian production of 555 bcm
assumptions, our model will give insights and therefore about 100 is exported to the EU, of the total Algerian
be useful to planners and regulators for the European production of around 80 bcm about 30 is exported
natural gas market. to the EU.
The model we propose is a short-term one simulating EU15 consumption of natural gas was 386 bcm or
the European natural gas market for one year’s time. As 15.2% of world total consumption. Depicted in Fig. 2
such, no build/no build decisions are considered are the major EU consuming countries: the UK with
facilitating the computation of market equilibria. How- 95 bcm, Germany at 83 bcm, Italy 64 at bcm, France at
ever, by comparing the outcomes of the model using 43 bcm, Netherlands 39 bcm, Spain 21 bcm. With the
different assumptions on pipeline transmission capaci- accession of the 10 countries on May 1, 2004, the import
ties (and other parameters), one can simulate the effects dependency has even increased. In 2002 these 10
of capacity expansion. countries consumed about 40 bcm, and produced only
Natural gas market models have also been developed about 8 bcm. Of the new member states, only Poland
for other parts of the world. For example, a wide variety and Hungary have significant own gas production,
of models for the North America market have appeared covering respectively, one third and one quarter of their
in the literature. Notable examples include the early consumption.
work of O’Neill et al. (1979), GRIDNET (Brooks, The current self-sufficiency in terms of natural gas is
2003), the Natural Gas Transmission and Distribution about 50% for EU25. However, the natural gas reserves
Model of the US Department’s National Energy are depleting with only the Netherlands having sig-
Modeling System and its predecessors (Ahn and Hogan, nificant reserves. Also, among the countries that export
1982; Murphy, 1983, 1988; EIA, 1998; Gabriel et al., much natural gas to the EU, there are big differences in
2001), the Gas Systems Analysis Model (Gabriel et al., the reserves base. The Russian reserves are ten times as
2000, 2003), and a Nash–Cournot approach wherein the big as the reserves of EU25 and Norway together, and
marketers exert market power (Gabriel et al., 2004a,b,c). five times the reserves of EU25, Norway, and Algeria all
There are two main research goals that this paper combined. Fig. 3 shows the reserve positions.
attempts to answer. First, analyze possible strategic
3
behavior of producers with respect to rival supplies in a EU15: Austria (AU), Belgium (BE), Denmark (DK), Finland (FI),
liberalized European Natural Gas market to determine France (FR), Germany (GE), Greece (GR), Ireland (IR), Italy (IT),
the extent of this market power. Second, assess the Luxembourg (LU), Netherlands (NL), Portugal (PR), Spain (SP),
Sweden (SE), United Kingdom (UK). May 1, 2004 ten countries joined
impact of transmission and storage capacities on the EU. These new member states (NMS) are: Cyprus, Czech Republic
producer market power. The rest of this paper is (CZ), Estonia, Hungary (HU), Latvia, Lithuania, Malta, Poland (PO),
organized as follows. In Section 2, the optimization Slovakia (SK), Slovenia. EU25 includes these countries plus EU15.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
R.G. Egging, S.A. Gabriel / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 2762–2778 2765

Fig. 1. Production 2002, bcm, (Source: BP stats, 2003).

Fig. 2. Consumption 2002, bcm, (Source: BP stats, 2003).

The European natural gas market that is modeled complement gas from producers delivered over the
consists of producers, pipeline companies, storage pipeline grid.
operators, and end-use consumption sectors. These Conversely, in the non-winter period, gas is injected
sectors are designated as s ¼ 1; 2; 3, respectively, for into storage for later use. Thus, storage can be
industrial (ind), and electric power generation (pg) and considered as the fourth consumption sector but only
residential/commercial (res). Typically the demand can for the non-winter. Fig. 5 shows how the final delivered
vary by season (less so for the industrial sector) with the prices to each sector are determined (in the perfectly
winter having the highest demand. As shown in Fig. 4, competitive case).
to satisfy the higher levels of consumption in the winter An underlying pipeline network is used to model the
timeframe, gas can be extracted from storage (stor) to natural gas market in which the set of nodes N refers to
ARTICLE IN PRESS
2766 R.G. Egging, S.A. Gabriel / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 2762–2778

Fig. 3. Reserve levels 2002, Tcm (Source: BP stats, 2003). Tcm ¼ trillion cubic meters.

Market structure in non-winter periods Market structure in winter periods

Russia ………..Algeria Russia ……….Algeria


.
TSO TSO

Germany ………Czech Rep Germany ………Czech Rep


stor stor

stor stor
pg pg pg pg
ind ind ind ind
res res res res

Fig. 4. Market structure and the role of gas storage in different periods.

individual countries. For a typical node n 2 N, JðnÞ {Netherlands, United Kingdom} and N(Total) e.g.
denotes the set of neighboring nodes, i.e., those {France, Netherlands}.
countries that are directly connected by pipeline to To account for the important differences in demand
node n. Additionally, Nðf Þ is the set of nodes where by season, three time periods P ¼ f1; 2; 3g are used. The
production firm f 2 F can produce gas. Whereas in first time period is the low demand season (April–Sep-
this paper we consider countries as producers, the tember) with periods 2 and 3 referring, respectively, to
model formulation allows for different (commercial) the high demand season (February, March, October,
producers with production in several countries, as is November) and the peak demand season (December and
usual for the big gas companies, like Shell, BP and January). The number of days in each period p is given
Total. As an example N(Shell) would contain at least by d p where d 1 ¼ 183; d 2 ¼ 120; d 3 ¼ 62. Lastly, two
ARTICLE IN PRESS
R.G. Egging, S.A. Gabriel / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 2762–2778 2767

Non-Winter Winter

10 , production unit cost 15 , production unit cost


producer producer

5 , transmission unit cost 5 , transmission unit cost

15 , border cost 50 , 20 , border cost


50 , country country
dist. cost
dist. cost 5 , dist. cost
65 70
Residential Residential 20 , dist. cost
Storage 20 50
/Commercial 30 , dist. cost /Commercial 30 ,
dist. cost 20 dist. cost
, dist. cost
30
Power Power
Industrial dist. cost
Generation 35 Industrial Generation 40

45 50
Sectors: bold is delivered price 20
dist. cost

Fig. 5. Cost components for gas deliveries. Storage delivers gas to the industrial sector at h 50/1000 m3. In non-winter the storage operator buys gas
at h 20. These h 20 are built up from h10 production costs, h 5 transmission costs and h 5 distribution costs.

P
sets, I and X , refer respectively, to the periods when defined as qfsnp ¼ f 0 af qf 0 snp and the extraction of gas
injection and extraction of gas from storage can occur from storage as ensnp .7 The balancing equation is thus8
with I ¼ f1g; X ¼ f2; 3g.
csnp  Exogsnp ¼ qfsnp þ qfsnp þ esnp ,
2.2. Consumption
8s 2 S; n 2 N; p 2 P. ðC 2Þ
Consumption of natural gas may vary both by sector
For this paper, the inverse demand function is taken to
(s ¼ 1; 2; 3) as well as by period p, and is described by
be affine and passing through the reference point
separate inverse demand functions4
fp0snp ; c0snp g with elasticity Zsnp o0. The resulting function
psnp ¼ D1
snp ðcsnp  Exogsnp Þ, (C 1) is given by
where csnp is the (nonnegative) amount of gas consumed
psnp ¼ IIDsnp þ SIDsnp  ðcsnp  Exogsnp Þ, (C 3)
by sector s and node n in period p5 and Exogsnp is the
(nonnegative) amount of exogenous production with
where
csnp XExogsnp and is taken as a fixed parameter.6
For most consuming countries, exogenous produc-
IIDsnp ¼ ð1  1=Zsnp Þ  p0snp , (C 4)
tion is zero or very small. The net consumption
ðcsnp  Exogsnp Þ, must be satisfied by sales and extraction
from storage (in periods 2 and 3). The sales from each
SIDsnp ¼ p0snp =ððc0snp  Exogsnp Þ  Zsnp Þ, (C 5)
production firm f are denoted as qfsnp with rival sales
4
The storage sector demand is determined by the storage system
where IIDsnp ; SIDsnp are the intercept and slope,
operator’s optimization problem. respectively.
5
Consumption and other quantity variables are expressed in millions
of cubic meters (mcm) per day, prices and costs are in h per 1000 m3, 7
The asterisk ‘’ denotes that a variable is an exogenous constant
unless otherwise stated. determined by other players.
6 8
The total exogenous production in each country was (arbitrarily) Note that in the injection season (p ¼ 1) or for the sector for
split based on the consumption sector shares. storage (s ¼ 4), the extraction term is absent.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
2768 R.G. Egging, S.A. Gabriel / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 2762–2778

2.3. Production COfnp ¼ 1, the firm acts strategically since it can


manipulate prices by altering sales accordingly so that
Each producer f is modeled as maximizing revenue in (P1) the exogenous price psnp drops out. The
from sales less (within-country) distribution costs, combined wellhead price for periods 1, 2 and 3 and
production costs and (long-distance) transmission ser- the non-storage sectors is thus given by
vice costs. This net profit is also subject to certain
engineering constraints and economic behavioral as- ð1  COfnp Þpsnp þ COfnp fIIDsnp þ SIDsnp
sumptions. In particular, producer f decides on how ðqfsnp þ qfsnp þ esnp Þg
much gas to produce yfnp , how much to sell qfsnp , and
how much to transport tfnmp from any node n to a noting that for all producers only one of these two
neighboring node m 2 JðnÞ in order to achieve the schemes is in effect for a given scenario for the analysis
highest net profit. The producer will receive revenues in this paper,10 since just perfect competition and
based on the market price of gas in the sector, node, and conjectured supply prices are used in this paper.
time period in question, multiplied by the amount of gas For gas sold in period 1 to storage to be injected, a
sold. To determine the wellhead price of gas, two different price, p4n1 is used. This price is determined by
schemes are used. One involves taking the price market-clearing conditions for the storage market
determined using a perfect competition assumption. described in a later section so that no market price
The second scheme to determine prices posits that each manipulation is possible in this sector.
producer conjectures how rival sales at node n will Besides the revenues, each producer incurs distribu-
change if the computed price changes from its equili- tion costs, DC sn ðÞ, production costs, CY fnp ðÞ and
brium value as a result of firm f shifting its sales (Day et transmission costs11 with exogenously determined unit
al., 2002; Hobbs and Rijkers, 2004; Hobbs et al., 2004; costs wtnmp . Consequently, each producer f has the
Lise et al., 2006). For example, if one assumes that the following objective12
competitors’ sales diverge linearly from their equili- 8 P P 9
> ½ð1  COfnp Þpsnp þ COfnp >
brium value if price psnp ¼ D1 snp ðÞ is changed from its
>
>
> s¼1;2;3 n2N >
>
>
equilibrium psnp , the resulting equation is >
> >
>
>
> fIID þ SID ðq þ q þ e
Þg >
>
>
>
snp
P
snp fsnp
P
fsnp snp >
>
>
> >
>
>
> q  ½DC sn ðq Þ >
>
qfsnp  ½qfsnp þ SF C fnp  ðIIDsnp þ SIDsnp  ðqfsnp >
<
fsnp fsnp
>
=
X P
s¼1;2;3;4 n2N

þ qfsnp þ esnp Þ  psnp Þ ¼ 0, MAX dp  CY fnp ðyfnp Þ


>
> >
>
p¼1;2;3 >
> n2Nðf Þ
P P >
>
>
> >
>
where qfsnp and psnp represent the equilibrium sales and >
>  wt 
 t fnmp >
>
>
>
nmp >
>
prices, respectively. It is important to note that qfsnp >
>
n2N
P
m2JðnÞ >
>
>
>  >
>
and qfsnp are two different items. The first one is an >
: þd 1 p4n1 qf 4n1 : >
;
n2N
endogenous variable as part of the producer problem
measuring what the producer thinks the rival sales are. (P 1)
The second one is exogenous to the particular producer This objective function is optimized subject to a set of
being determined by what the optimal values are for the constraints. First, the production is bounded above by a
other producers. In this conjectured supply function capacity ȳfnp representing limited resources and/or
approach, the larger the coefficient SFCfnp is, the equipment13
greater the supply response that firm f anticipates from
other firms. In this sense, the producers are strategic yfnp pȳfnp ðmfnp Þ 8n 2 Nðf Þ; p 2 P. (P 2)
Nash–Cournot players since by modifying their sales
appropriately, they can potentially manipulate prices A transshipment constraint defines firm f’s gas sales at
(Shy, 1995). This approach also subsumes a pure node n as equal to the production of f at n less the net
Cournot model.9
To combine these two schemes, an exogenous binary 10
A generalization of the binary index COfnp is one taking on values
parameter COfnp is used. Our approach is based to some in [0,1] so that a convex combination of price-taking and conjectured
extent on the methodology described in Hobbs and supply function behavior is assumed in which producers are assumed
Rijkers (2004) and implemented for the European to have market power.
11
electricity markets in Hobbs et al. (2004) but relevant If marketers were in the model, they would pay for the
here. If COfnp ¼ 0, then the firm behaves competitively transmission charges which would then be passed on to the
consumption sectors. Since no marketers are modeled explicitly, these
since it takes the exogenous price as psnp ; see (P1) costs are borne by the producer with an equivalent effect on the
determined by the market-clearing conditions (KM1). If consumption sector delivered prices.
12
The extraction term esnp is not used in period 1.
9 13
Note that if the coefficient SF C fnp ¼ 0, then a pure Cournot Greek symbols in parentheses represent the Lagrange multipliers
approach results with qfsnp ¼ qfsnp . for each constraint.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
R.G. Egging, S.A. Gabriel / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 2762–2778 2769

gas exported by f from the same node n14 It is not necessary to explicitly enforce mass balances at
X X the nodes of the transmission network for the znmp as
qfsnp  yfnp þ ðtfnmp  tfmnp Þ ¼ 0; ðyfnp Þ
these will automatically be satisfied because of the firm
s¼1;2;3;4 m2JðnÞ
level mass balancing equation (P 3) and the market-
8n 2 N; p 2 P. ðP 3Þ clearing constraints (MCC 3) described below. Lastly,
A conjectured supply function given as (see footnote 8) one could also add transmission losses to the actual
flows but for clarity we have omitted these losses.
qfsnp  ½qfsnp þ SF C fnp  ðIIDsnp þ SIDsnp  ðqfsnp
þ qfsnp þ esnp Þ  psnp Þ ¼ 0; ðbfsnp Þ
2.5. Storage
8n 2 N; s 2 f1; 2; 3g; p 2 P. ðP 4Þ
In addition, there are nonnegativity constraints for the Similar to the transportation market for natural gas,
production, sales and flows of firm f.15 the storage market is assumed to be perfectly competi-
tive. As such, a price-taking storage system operator
yfnp X0 8n 2 Nðf Þ; p 2 P, (P 5) (SSO) is used to model the storage market. The SSO can
profit from buying gas in the low demand (and thus
qfsnp X0 8n 2 N; s 2 S; p 2 P, (P 6)
low price) periods, storing it, and selling it to end
user sectors in the high demand periods. The SSO’s
tfnmp X0 8n 2 N; m 2 JðnÞ; p 2 P. (P 7)
profit is the difference between the selling prices
and the purchase prices minus storage and distribution
costs.17
2.4. Transportation (
X X X
MAX d p ðpsnp esnp  DC sn ðesnp ÞÞ
In contrast to the production sector, the transporta- n2N p¼2;3 s¼1;2;3
tion of natural gas is taken to be perfectly competitive.16 )
This perspective allows one to use an ‘‘omniscient’’  d 1 ðp4n1 in1 þ CS n ðin1 ÞÞ , ðSTOR 1Þ
transmission system operator (TSO) whose optimization
problem simulates the market-clearing for transmission
capacity by maximizing the value of transmission where CS n ðÞ is the operational costs of storage and in1 is
services. The corresponding objective function for the the injection rate into storage for the injection season
TSO is thus ðp ¼ 1Þ. The SSO maximizes this objective function
X X X given the operational limits of the storage facilities. The
MAX dp ðwtnmp znmp  CZ nm ðznmp ÞÞ, first constraint (STOR 2) is a mass balance restriction
p2P n2N m2JðnÞ that enforces that total extraction from storage equals
(TSO 1) total injection within a year, so no losses. However that
where wtnmp
is an exogenous pipeline tariff determined could easily be incorporated.
by market-clearing conditions, CZ nm ðÞ is the cost of X X
d p esnp ¼ d 1 in1 ; ðsn Þ 8n 2 N. (STOR 2)
operating thePinter-country flow from node n to node m, p¼2;3 s¼1;2;3
and znmp ¼ f 2F tfnmp is the total inter-country flow
across firms from node n to node m during period p. The constraints (STOR 3)–(STOR 6) refer to the
These flows are subject to simple upper bounds, physical operation of the storage facility. The injection
representing the available transmission capacity z̄nmp rate of storage in country n is bounded above by the
limitations of the compressors that are used. Specifi-
znmp pz̄nmp ; ðcnmp Þ 8n 2 N; m 2 JðnÞ; p 2 P
cally,
(TSO 2)
in1 pīn ; ðan Þ 8n 2 N, (STOR 3)
as well as lower bounds of zero
znmp X0 8n 2 N; m 2 JðnÞ; p 2 P. (TSO 3) where īn is an upper bound on the injection rate. The
extraction rate is bounded above by the maximum
14 withdrawal rate ēn
Note that the production term yfnp is only defined for n 2 Nðf Þ.
15
(P 6) and the definition of qfsnp force this variable to be
X
esnp pēn ; ðlnp Þ 8n 2 N; p ¼ 2; 3. (STOR 4)
nonnegative and thus nonnegativity conditions for qfsnp are not
s¼1;2;3
explicitly needed in this optimization problem but could be included in
deriving the optimality conditions shown in the Appendix.
16 17
EU regulations (Global Competition Review, 2003) aim at fair This formulation assigns transportation charges and distribution
competition between market players in both the transportation and costs to get the gas from the production nodes to the gas storage
storage markets. For that reason an assumption of perfect competition facilities to the producers. This is an arbitrary choice but does not
is reasonable. affect the SSO’s profit.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
2770 R.G. Egging, S.A. Gabriel / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 2762–2778

Additionally, more gas cannot be extracted than the variables ðp4n1 Þ are the market-clearing prices for the gas
working gas volume available v̄n storage sectors
X X
d p esnp pv̄n ; ðon Þ 8n 2 N. (STOR 5) X
s¼1;2;3 p¼2;3 in1  qf 4n1 ¼ 0; ðp4n1 Þ 8n 2 N. (MCC 4)
f 2F
Lastly, injection and extraction rates must be nonnega-
tive.
0pin1 ; esnp 8n 2 N; s ¼ 1; 2; 3; p ¼ 2; 3. (STOR 6)
3. Numerical results for the European natural gas market
2.6. Market-clearing conditions 3.1. Description of input data
In addition to the optimization problems presented The data for the scenarios analyzed in this paper are
above, market-clearing conditions are needed to equili- taken from (Van Oostvoorn, 2003). We have trans-
brate supply and demand. The first set of market- formed all volume data (such as production and
clearing conditions is simply the definition of the inverse production capacities and consumption levels) from
demand function. However, in the high demand periods bcm/year to mcm/day by multiplying the values by the
(p ¼ 2; 3) not only direct sales from producers to end- factor 1000/365 and have applied euro-inflation rates
users determine the equilibrium price, but also the gas (IMF-WEO, 2003) to have all prices in 2002 Euros. The
that is extracted from storage. applied inflation rates were: 1.135 for production costs,
psnp ¼ IIDsnp þ SIDsnp  ðcsnp  Exogsnp Þ 1.049 for consumer prices, 1 for transmission costs and
1.075 for distribution costs. The distributional costs of
8n 2 N; s ¼ 1; 2; 3. delivering gas to the storage sector is as expensive as
what is used for the power generation sector. To vary
Also, the equilibrium price psnp must equal the
the demand of user segments by season, we have
anticipated price:
determined relative load factors. The yearly average
psnp ¼ psnp 8n 2 N; s ¼ 1; 2; 3. load factor is 100%. For the residential sector we have
used the so-called Weighted Heating Degree Days
These two equations can be combined and in light of (C method.20 The usual Dutch weight factors are used:
2) the resulting equation is 1.1 for January, February, November, December, 1.0,
! for March and October, and 0.8 for other months.
X For power generation we have used the Dutch

psnp ¼ IIDsnp þ SIDsnp  qfsnp þ esnp
f 2F
monthly electricity consumption levels (http://statli-
ne.cbs.nl) to deduce relative load factors and applied
8n 2 N; s ¼ 1; 2; 3. ðMCC 1Þ them to North Western European Countries and
Central and East European countries. In these regions
A consistency condition determining that in equilibrium
the number of day light hours is an important factor in
the by firm f conjectured sales equal the actual sales of
electricity consumption. Mediterranean countries also
firm f’s rivals is given as follows.18
have cooling and air-conditioning as major drivers for
qfsnp ¼ qfsnp 8s 2 S; 8f 2 F ; 8n 2 Nðf Þ; 8p 2 P. energy consumption. UCTE (www.ucte.org) data sug-
gest that the upward effect of these drivers in summer
(MCC 2)
more or less outweighs the upward effects of day light
Also, the transmission services need to match the flows hours in winter. (So France, Spain, Italy and Turkey
resulting from producers’ actions.19 have an all year load factor of 100% for power
X generation). For the industrial sector, the gas input
znmp  tfnmp ¼ 0; ðwtnmp Þ 8n 2 N; m 2 JðnÞ; p 2 P. levels barely vary by season and so we take 1.0 as the
f 2F relative load factor in all seasons (Table 1).
(MCC 3) We have set the maximum injection rates equal to the
peak output rates. Injection costs of storage (besides
Lastly, the injections in gas storage equal the total sales distribution costs towards storage and distribution costs
to the storage system operator (in period 1). The dual from storage to end user segments) are set to
18
h5=1000 m3 (Table 2).
(MCC 2) is actually redundant, as the equality is already enforced
by (P 4) and (KM 1).
19
It is just the producers’ actions, as bringing the gas from gas
20
storage facilities to market sectors involves distribution networks only, See for an explanation: www.eia.doe.gov/neic/infosheets/degree-
and we consider (long-distance) transmission services here. days.htm
ARTICLE IN PRESS
R.G. Egging, S.A. Gabriel / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 2762–2778 2771

Table 1
Relative season load factors per consuming country

Season Sector

Residential Industries Power generation

Low High Peak Low High Peak Low High Peak

Country
Austria 0.22 1.52 2.31 1 1 1 0.93 1.04 1.14
Belgium 0.36 1.45 2.04 1 1 1 0.93 1.04 1.14
France 0.28 1.52 2.12 1 1 1 1.00 1.00 1.00
Germany 0.31 1.47 2.13 1 1 1 0.93 1.04 1.14
Italy 0.16 1.46 2.59 1 1 1 1.00 1.00 1.00
Netherlands 0.39 1.41 2.02 1 1 1 0.93 1.04 1.14
Spain 0.19 1.55 2.33 1 1 1 1.00 1.00 1.00
United Kingdom 0.34 1.42 2.13 1 1 1 0.93 1.04 1.14
Czech Republic 0.12 1.55 2.56 1 1 1 0.93 1.04 1.14
Hungary 0.03 1.42 3.08 1 1 1 0.93 1.04 1.14
Poland 0.09 1.58 2.59 1 1 1 0.93 1.04 1.14
Romania 0.03 1.45 3.02 1 1 1 0.93 1.04 1.14
Slovakia 0.06 1.46 2.91 1 1 1 0.93 1.04 1.14
Turkey 0.09 1.46 2.80 1 1 1 1.00 1.00 1.00

Table 2 3.2. Analysis of market scenarios


Storage costs and capacitiesa,b

Country Year Working gas Peak output To analyze the European natural gas market, we
(bcm) rate (mcm/day) constructed four market scenarios. The first one
assumed that the producers were in perfect competition
Austria 2000 2.82 28
(PC) with each other relating to COfnp ¼ 0. For the
Belgium 2000 0.71 20
Bulgaria 2000 0.20 2 remaining scenarios, COfnp ¼ 1, indicating that the
Czech Republic 2000 2.06 40 producers were strategic Cournot players with the
Denmark 2000 0.81 24 ability to influence prices. The second market scenario,
France 2000 10.49 182 denoted as Strategic Base Case (SBC), assumed that the
Germany 2000 19.10 438
data values specified in the previous section were in
Hungary 2000 3.29 44
Italy 2000 12.75 236 force. The third scenario, designated as Strategic Extra
Netherlands 2000 2.48 175 Pipelines (SEP), allowed for three extra pipelines serving
Poland 2000 1.26 23 the UK market as shown in Fig. 6 and described in
Romania 2000 1.57 11 Table 3. The fourth scenario, labelled Strategic No
Slovakia 2000 2.74 33
Storage (SNS), considered the effect of the storage
Spain 2000 1.41 11
Turkey 2000 0 0 sector on the whole market.
United 2000 3.63 138 These four scenarios led to three comparisons as
Kingdom shown below (the reference cases are underlined).
a
Source is (IEA, 2002b).
b
The peak output rate of the Czech Republic is adjusted upwards I. Effects of Market Power: Perfect Competition vs.
based on recent information
Strategic Base Case.
II. Effects of Transmission Capacity: Strategic Base
Case vs. Strategic Extra Pipelines.
We have transformed the yearly exogenous produc-
III. Effects of Storage: Strategic Base Case vs. Strategic
tion levels into daily numbers, according to their relative
No Storage.
load factors.21

The first comparison analyzed the market inefficiencies


due to producers having market power and driving up
21 prices by withholding production. The second compar-
It turned out that the Romanian daily exogenous production level
is about 1% higher than its low demand period reference consumption
ison measured the gain to the UK system if extra
level. We shifted 1% of the Exogenous Production from the low pipeline capacity were added in strategic markets. The
demand to the high and peak demand periods to solve this issue. last comparison measured the importance of the storage
ARTICLE IN PRESS
2772 R.G. Egging, S.A. Gabriel / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 2762–2778

Fig. 6. Extra pipelines in Scenario 3.

Table 3
Transmission capacity extensions scenario 3 (bcm/year)

From To Current capacity Extension Reason Due:

Norway United Kingdom 12 +12 Ormen Lange field 2007


Netherlands United Kingdom 0 +12 Balgzand Bacton line 2006
Denmark Netherlands 0 +5 Tyra field July 2004

sector to the whole EU market by contrasting it with no prices will lead to higher revenues. Of course, one needs
storage. to also consider the cost side but this is strong
motivation for producers exercising market power.
3.2.1. Comparison I: Perfect Competition vs. Strategic Libya and LNG World, included in ‘‘Other’’ producers
Base Case in Fig. 7 start producing in SBC. In the perfect
When producers are able to exercise market power competition case, they were not able to compete, but
from a Cournot perspective, they dramatically change with the higher price levels they can.
the market. In particular, production drops by 20%,
and average price levels increase by 86%, resulting in a 3.2.2. Comparison II: Strategic Base Case vs. Strategic
drop in consumer surplus of 28%; the production by Extra Pipelines
country is shown in Fig. 7. The magnitude of the change In contrast to the previous analysis, this comparison
in production levels was not the same by country. In concerned two cases in which the producers were
particular, the lower the marginal production cost, the strategic. The market inefficiencies brought about by
greater the withholding of production. producers exerting market power, were, to some extent,
The increase in prices is felt in all market sectors and mitigated by this extra pipeline capacity. The result was
countries as shown for the major countries in Fig. 8. The that more gas was available in the system that led to
producers, SSO, and TSO reap enormous profits as dramatically lower prices for the UK (see Table 4) and
compared to the perfect competition case, with respec- generally lower prices overall.
tively, increases of 345%, 4483%, and 45%.22 Part of These new pipelines as well as the existing ones were
the rationale for the extreme price increases is due to the at or near capacity in most seasons. In particular, 41.8
fact that as modeled, all three of the market sectors out of a total of 44.8 bcm of pipeline capacity into the
exhibit low elastic demand, so that producers raising UK was used on an annual basis. This extra capacity
was also beneficial to the EU’s consumer surplus causing
22
See the Appendix for a clarification of the profit increases of the it to rise 3% over the Strategic Base Case. Of course,
SSO and the TSO. with this extra capacity, a greater level of production (a
ARTICLE IN PRESS
R.G. Egging, S.A. Gabriel / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 2762–2778 2773

Production levels
300

PC SBC
250

200
bcm
150

100

50

0
EU15 Norway Russia Algeria Other

Fig. 7. Production levels from comparison I.

/ 1000 m^3 Gas prices PC SBC


250

200

150

100

50

-
FR GE IT NL UK FR GE IT NL UK FR GE IT NL UK
Low Low Low Low Low High High High High High Peak Peak Peak Peak Peak

Fig. 8. Price levels from comparison I.

Table 4 protect some of their own profits, the UK producers


Price changes for the United Kingdom under pipeline capacity hold back production by 10 bcm.
extension

Sector Low High Peak 3.2.3. Comparison III: Strategic Base Case vs. Strategic
No Storage
Industry 18% 21% 15% In this comparison, the value of the storage market,
Power generation 22% 10% 4%
Residential 13% 15% 15%
under Cournot producers is examined. When no storage
Storage 5% market is allowed, both production and TSO profits rise
dramatically, 43% and 41%, respectively. These in-
creased profits are the result of an average price increase
of 15% occurring at lower production and consumption
3% increase) resulted, manifested mainly in Norway, the levels. Also, the disadvantage to the market of not
Netherlands and Russia. This translated to increased having storage decreases the consumer surplus by 13%.
sales to the UK whose market shares, as evidenced in The importance of storage and its effect on consump-
Fig. 9, indicate stronger positions by Norway and the tion is shown in Fig. 10. In particular, we see that by
Netherlands. Higher production but lower prices led to country, storage has different impacts on changes in
lower producer profits by 3.7% as well as decreased SSO consumption. The greater the difference between the
and TSO profits of 4.5% and 5.9%, respectively. To height of the bar (change in storage) and the height of
ARTICLE IN PRESS
2774 R.G. Egging, S.A. Gabriel / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 2762–2778

1% 2%SBC 3%
4% SEP
9%

16%

16%
UK
NO
51% NL
AL
Other

26%
72%

Fig. 9. Market shares of sales to the United Kingdom (left: Strategic Base Case, right: Strategic Extra Pipelines Case).

bcm Change in consumption related to change in storage capacity


20

18
Change in Storage
16
Change in Consumption
14

12

10

0
AU BE FR GE IT NL SP UK CZ HU PO RO SK

Fig. 10. Relation between change in consumption and storage capacity. RO: Romania.

the point (change in consumption), the less the impact. in place are national legislation and are formulated by
E.g., Germany suffers relatively little, whereas Italy is national governments. Whereas some governments (like
more affected. the Dutch) are very willing to have an open competitive
market and have ambitious market opening schemes,
3.2.4. Link of results with recent EC policy documents others are only putting the least effort in reaching the
As addressed before in the introduction the large and minimum EC requirements.
ever-increasing dependency of external supplies has led Our results show that when adequate policies are not
to a need for measures to manage supply risks and in place, market power abuse may lead to significant
secure supplies. Besides the issue of external supply social welfare losses because of lower consumption
security for natural gas the liberalization process in levels and higher prices. But the EC market liberal-
recent years has resulted in strong positions for some big ization efforts have been triggered in the first place by
energy multinationals. Both in the external supply the wish to have lower energy prices as one of the means
situation as well as the internal supply oligopolistic to become the most competitive economic world region
market behavior could give rise to market power. in 2010 (‘Lisbon 2010 Agenda’). The different ambition
Directives EC (2000a, 2003, 2004) provide regulations levels regarding market opening, (or equivalently, the
to be put in place by EU members states in years to different attitudes of governments in protecting national
come, whereas EC (2000b) provides a list with priority interests) may lead to slower market opening eventually,
infrastructure projects. However the influence of the as countries will adapt their market opening pace to the
many countries having to find a compromise text to slower movers to not sell out their national interests.
meet all interests can be seen in the global and abstract Ownership of infrastructure in the gas market
level of the formulated policies. Most policies to be put (transmission pipelines, distribution networks) easily
ARTICLE IN PRESS
R.G. Egging, S.A. Gabriel / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 2762–2778 2775

leads to natural monopolies, therefore Third Party Appendix


Access (TPA) is a necessity to allow for competition in
the first place.23 Many of the policies regarding the A.1. The nonlinear complementarity problem
internal market rules and security of supply situation
deal with TPA. (e.g. articles 8, 12, 15, 18–22, EC, 2003) The nonlinear complementarity problem (NCP) and
Besides access, the availability of sufficient capacity the variational inequality problem (VI) are two very
is of major importance. EC 2000b provides priority general problem formats which include the Karush–-
infrastructure projects regarding the trans-European Kuhn–Tucker (KKT) optimality conditions, Nash–-
Energy Networks (TEN) The selection of the infra- Cournot games, Wardrop traffic equilibria, as well as
structure extensions in the SEP case was triggered by many other examples in economics and engineering
project f02 of EC 2000b and the new Denmark–Nether- (Ferris and Pang, 1997; Facchinei and Pang, 2003).
lands line already being in place. Adding only three Given a function F : Rn ! Rn , the (mixed) nonlinear
pipelines and the relatively isolated position of the complementarity problem NCP(F), is to find a vector
United Kingdom enables a straightforward interpreta- x 2 Rn such that:
tion of the results.
xi ¼ ui ) F i ðx Þp0,
Our case SNS shows the impact of available gas
storage facilities in the market. One can imagine that gas l i oxi oui ) F i ðx Þ ¼ 0,
storage facilities owned by producing parties will not xi ¼ l i ) F i ðx ÞX0, ðA1Þ
enhance a competitive market situation but would allow where l, u are lower and upper bound vectors,
for strategic behavior as well. TPA to storage is a respectively, and
prerequisite for competition.
l i ; ui 2 R [ f1; þ1g; l i oui ; 8i ¼ 1; 2; . . . ; n.
Our results for the UK show the importance of
sufficient transmission infrastructure and TPA, which
A.2. Formulating the complementarity model
only increases when the UK becomes a significant net
importer in the coming years. The TEN projects in EC
The mixed complementarity model for calculating the
2000b are meant for the coming decades, however the
market equilibrium is constructed by combining the
document does not prioritize which projects to be following set of conditions:
developed first. Quantitative analysis can support
prioritizing of projects, and help monitoring whether
 the first-order KKT conditions for the profit-max-
the market invests in the projects thought of most
imization model for each producer f;24
relevant by the EC.
 the first-order conditions for the TSO model,
 the first-order conditions for the storage model; and
 the market-clearing conditions.
4. Summary and future work
The mixed complementarity problem below is a linear
In this paper we have developed an equilibrium model one if the indicated derivatives are affine. The problem is
for the European natural gas market. This model allows square (as many conditions as variables).
for both perfect competition as well as Cournot strategic
producers. The other players in storage and transmis- A.2.1. Producer KKT conditions
sion are taken to be in perfect competition. This model
was then applied to four market scenarios to gauge the
For each yfnp:
effects of market power, increased pipeline capacity to
0pyfnp ? ½CY 0 fnp ðyÞ  mfnp þ yfnp p0 (KP 1)
the United Kingdom, as well as the importance of
For each qfsnp, s ¼ 1; 2; 3; p ¼ 1; 2; 3: (KP 2)
storage. The results indicate that extreme market power
0pqfsnp ?
by the producers would result in huge market ineffi- 2 3
ciencies necessitating strong (possibly EU) regulations ð1  COfnp Þpsnp þ COfnp  ðIIDsnp þ SIDsnp
6 7
to protect consumers. Additionally, both ample pipeline 6 ðqfsnp þ 2qfsnp þ esnp ÞÞ 7p0
4 5
capacity and storage are key to favorable market 0
DC sn ðÞ  yfnp þ bfsnp  SF C fnp  SIDsnp
conditions for consumers. Future anticipated work will
concentrate on allowing stochasticity in the players For each qf4n1:
problem to better reflect uncertainty in actual markets. 0pqf 4n1 ? ½p4n1  DC 4n ðÞ  yfn1 p0 (KP 3)
In addition consideration of modeling of forward
markets and capacity investments.
24
A reasonable assumption of concavity of the nonlinear terms in
23
Note that we have assumed unlimited infrastructure access. each objective functions is made so that the KKT conditions are
Limitations in access would allow for more market power. sufficient for optimality (Bazaraa et al., 1993).
ARTICLE IN PRESS
2776 R.G. Egging, S.A. Gabriel / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 2762–2778

For each qfsnp: For each psnp ; s ¼ 1; 2; 3; p ¼ 2; 3 :


P 9
COfnp  SIDsnp  qfsnp  bfsnp psn1  II Dsn1  SIDsn1  qfsn1 ¼ 0 > (KM 1)
>
>
ð1  SF C fnp  SIDsnp Þ ¼ 0 (KP 4) f 2F >
>
 >
=
For each tfmnp: psnp  IIDsnp  SIDsnp
( )
0ptfnmp ? ½wtnmp  yfnp þ yfmp p0 (KP 5) P >
>
>
>
For each mfnp : 0pmfnp ? ðyfnp  ȳfnp Þp0 (KP 6)  qfsnp þ ensnp ¼ 0 >
>
f 2F ;
For Peach yfn1 : P P
qfsn1  yfn1 þ ðtfnm1  tfmn1 Þ ¼ 0 (KP 7) For each wtnm : znmp  tfnmp ¼ 0 (KM 2)
f 2F
s21;2;3;4 m2JðnÞ P
For each yfnp ; p ¼ 2; 3: For each p4n1 : in1  qf 4n1 ¼ 0 (KM 3)
P P f 2F
qfsnp  yfnp þ ðtfnmp  tfmnp Þ ¼ 0
s21;2;3 m2JðnÞ
For each bfsnp; p ¼ 1: (KP 8)
qfsnp  ½qfsnp þ SF C fnp A.3. Clarification of SSO and TSO profits in the
ðIIDsnp þ SIDsnp Strategic Base Case
ðqfsnp þ qfsnp Þ  psnp Þ ¼ 0
For each bfsnp; p ¼ 2; 3: A.3.1. SSO
qfsnp  ½qfsnp þ SF C fnp The SSO makes money by buying gas in the low
ðIIDsnp þ SIDsnp demand period and selling it in the high demand period
ðqfsnp þ qfsnp þ esnp Þ  psnp Þ ¼ 0 for a higher price. As the per m3 costs are constant for
the SSO in our model, the SSO profits depend on the
buying price, selling price and volume. The price that the
SSO pays for the gas is based on the marginal
A.2.2. TSO KKT conditions
production costs of the producers. That is in both the
perfect competition as well as the strategic base cases
For each znmp: (KT 1) (Table 5).
0pznmp ? wtnmp  CZ 0 nm ðznmp Þ  cnmp p0 In the strategic base case the production levels are
For each cnmp : 0pcnmp ? ðznmp  z̄nmp Þp0 (KT 2) lower than in the PC case, and the average price that the
SSO pays for the gas is lower. In the SBC case the winter
prices are higher than in the PC case, so the SSO gets on
A.2.3. Storage KKT conditions average a higher price for its gas that is sold. Also
contrary to what happens in the PC case, in the SBC
For each esnp, p ¼ 2; 3, s ¼ 1; 2; 3: (KS 1) case all storage capacity is used, so the traded volume of
0pesnp ? psnp  DC 0sn ðesnp Þ  sn  on  lnp p0 gas by the SSO is higher. So the buying price, selling
price and volume are all three better in the SBC case
For each in1 : (KS 2)
than in the PC case. So the SSO makes more profit in the
0pin1 ? pP 
CS 0 ðin1 Þ þ sn  an p0
4n1  P SBC case relative to the PC case.
For each sn : d p esnp  d 1 in1 ¼ 0 (KS 3)
p¼2;3 s¼1;2;3

Pīn p0
For each an : 0pan ? in1  (KS 4) A.3.2. TSO
For each lnp : 0plnp ? ensnp  ēn p0 (KS 5) The TSO profits depend on the difference between
s¼1;2;3
P P transport tariff and transport costs (the ‘congestion
For each on : 0pon ? d p esnp  v̄n p0 (KS 6) tariffs’) and transported volumes. The aggregated
s¼1;2;3 p¼2;3
transported volume in SBC is lower than in PC. The
total period-weighted flows are 644 billion m3 in SBC
A.2.4. Definitional constraints (not part of the
complementarity system) Table 5
SSO summary of profits
P
For each qfsnp : qfsnp ¼ qf 0 snp (DC 1) Strategic Base Perfect
f 0 af
Case (SBC) Competition Case
For each ensnp : ensnp ¼ esnp (DC 2) (PC)

Production Lower
Average SSO buying costs Lower
A.2.5. Market-clearing conditions Winter SSO selling prices Higher
Storage capacity All used Not all used
Traded SSO volume Higher
For each psn1 ; s ¼ 1; 2; 3 :
ARTICLE IN PRESS
R.G. Egging, S.A. Gabriel / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 2762–2778 2777

Table 6 References
TSO summary of profits
Ahn, B.H., Hogan, W.W., 1982. On convergence of the PIES algorithm
TSO Profit PC SBC Absolute Relative
for computing equilibria. Operations Research 30, 281–300.
difference difference
Bazaraa, M.S., Sherali, H.D., Shetty, C.M., 1993. Nonlinear
LNG 28,918 547,975 519,057 1795% Programming Theory and Algorithms. Wiley, New York.
Pipe 5,113,202 6,898,328 1,785,126 35% Boots, M.G., Rijkers, F.A.M., Hobbs, B.F., 2004. Modelling the role
Total 5,142,119 7,446,303 2,304,183 45% of trading companies in the downstream European gas market: a
successive oligopoly approach. The Energy Journal 25 (3), 73–102.
BP, 2003. BP Statistics 2003, www.bp.com.
Breton, N., Zaccour, Z., 2001. Equilibria in an asymmetric duopoly
and 670 billion m3 in PC. So the congestion tariffs must
facing a security constraint. Energy Economics 23, 457–475.
be the explanation for the higher TSO profit in SBC Brooks, R.E., 2003. Optimizing complex natural gas models, http://
relative to PC. The TSO can only impose congestion rbac.com/articles/informs.htm.
tariffs on congested pipelines and LNG supply chains Cedigaz, 2002a. From Energiebulletin 2002, no. 4145, p. 5.
(Table 6). Cedigaz, 2002b. From European Gas Markets, 29 November 2002.
Over 20% of extra TSO profits results from more Day, C.J., Hobbs, B.F., Pang, J.S., 2002. Oligopolistic competition in
power networks: a conjectured supply function approach. IEEE
LNG supply chains becoming restrictive. Because of the Transactions on Power Systems 17 (3), 597–607.
higher price levels in SBC more LNG producers enter De Wolf, D., Smeers, Y., 1997. A stochastic version of a Stack-
the market. Therefore the demand for LNG transport elberg–Nash–Cournot equilibrium model. Management Science 43
services is significantly higher than in PC, leading to (2), 190–197.
capacity of more LNG supply chains to be restrictive in EC, 2000a. COM(2000) 769 final, Towards a European strategy for the
security of energy supply, 29 November 2000.
SBC relative to PC. In SBC the Belgian, Turkish and
EC, 2000b. The present list of projects of common interest is available
Italian LNG regasification terminals and the Libyan in the annex of Commission Decision no 761/2000/EC of 16
liquefaction terminal are congested in all seasons, November 2000, setting out the specifications for projects of
whereas in PC only the Italian LNG regasification common interest (Decision C(2000) 2683).
terminal is congested (in all three periods). EC, 2003. Directive 2003/55/EC concerning common rules for the
The main part of over 75% of the higher TSO profits internal market in natural gas, June 26.
EC, 2004. Directive 2004/67/EC concerning measures to safeguard
results from more pipelines being restrictive in SBC security of natural gas supply.
relative to PC in combination with a much higher EIA, 1998. The National Energy Modeling System: an overview. Office
average congestion tariff. The following numbers of Integrated Analysis and Forecasting. US Department of Energy,
illustrate that the pipelines are restrictive. Of all Washington, DC.
pipelines in the model and in the three seasons in PC Gabriel, S.A., Vikas, S., Ribar, D.M., 2000. Measuring the influence of
Canadian carbon stabilization programs on natural gas exports to
108 pipeline/season combinations are used. Of these 108
the United States via a ‘bottom-up’ intertemporal spatial price
used pipelines 53 are congested. In SBC 263 pipeline/ equilibrium model. Energy Economics 22, 497–525.
season combinations are used of which 133 are Gabriel, S.A., Kydes, A.S., Whitman, P., 2001. The national energy
congested. Regarding the congestion tariffs there is an modeling system: a large-scale energy-economic equilibrium model.
unweighted average congestion tariff of congested pipes Operations Research 49, 14–25.
Gabriel, S.A., Manik, J., Vikas, S., 2003. Computational experience
in PC of 19.23 whereas in SBC it’s 67.09 [EUR/1000 m3].
with a large-scale, multi period, spatial equilibrium model of the
That in SBC more pipelines are restrictive can be North American natural gas system. Networks and Spatial
understood by the following line of reasoning. When we Economics 3, 97–122.
compare SBC with PC we can understand that Gabriel, S.A., Kiet, S., Zhuang, J., 2004a. A competitive equilibrium
producers have an incentive to deliver in more different model for the natural gas market based on a mixed complemen-
markets in SBC than in PC. Take as starting point the tarity formulation, Operations Research, forthcoming.
Gabriel, S.A., Zhuang, J.-F., Kiet, S., 2004b. A Nash-Cournot model
PC outcome. A producer lowering sales levels in the for the North American natural gas market. IAEE Conference
currently penetrated markets results (as we have seen in Proceedings, Zurich, Switzerland.
3.2.1) in higher price levels and higher revenues. Gabriel, S.A., Zhuang, J.-F., Kiet, S., 2004c. A large-scale comple-
However delivering in a ‘new’ market (a market not mentarity model of the North American natural gas market,
penetrated by the producer in PC but to be penetrated in Energy Economics, in press.
Golombek, R., Gjelsvik, E., Rosendahl, K.E., 1995. Effects of
SBC) will result in lower prices in that market, but these
liberalising the natural gas markets in Western Europe. The
lower price levels do not affect the newly entering Energy Journal 16 (1), 85–111.
producer’s own revenues, only that of the competitors Golombek, R., Gjelsvik, E., Rosendahl, K.E., 1998. Increased
that were already supplying in that market. So competition on the supply side of the Western European natural
producers deliver in more markets, and as in the PC gas market. The Energy Journal 19 (3), 1–18.
situation they supplied to the nearest markets, the newly Global Competition Review. 2003. Gas regulation in 26 jurisdictions
worldwide, www.globalcompetitionreview.com.
penetrated markets need longer transport routes and Gürkan, G., Özge, A.Y., Robinson, S.M., 1999. Sample-path solution
(what we do not know a priori, but see as a model of stochastic variational inequalities. Mathematical Programming
outcome) more transport capacity system-wide. 84, 313–333.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
2778 R.G. Egging, S.A. Gabriel / Energy Policy 34 (2006) 2762–2778

Harker, P.T., Pang, J.-S., 1990. Finite-dimensional variational inequal- Mathiesen, L., Roland, K., Thonstad, K., 1987. The European natural
ity and nonlinear complementarity problems: a survey of theory, gas market: degrees of market power on the selling side. In:
algorithms and applications. Mathematical Programming 48, Golombek, R., Hoel, M., Vislie, J. (Eds.), Natural Gas Markets
161–220. and Contracts. North-Holland, Amsterdam.
Haurie, A., Zaccour, G., Legrand, J., Smeers, Y., 1987. A stochastic Murphy, F.H., 1983. An overview of the intermediate future
dynamic Nash-Cournot model for the European gas market. forecasting system. In: Kydes, A.S., et al. (Eds.), Energy Modeling
Technical Report G-86-24, GERAD, Ecole des Hautes Etudes and Simulation. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 66–73.
Commerciales, Montréal, Québec, Canada. Murphy, F.H., Conti, J.J., Shaw, S.H., Sanders, R., 1988. Modeling
Hobbs, B.F., Rijkers, F.A.M., 2004. Strategic generation with and forecasting energy markets with the intermediate future
conjectured transmission price responses in a mixed transmission forecasting system. Operations Research 36, 406–420.
pricing system—Part I: Formulation. IEEE Transactions on Power O’Neill, R.P., Williard, M., Wilkins, B., Pike, R., 1979. A mathema-
Systems 19 (2), 707–717. tical programming model for allocation of natural gas. Operations
Hobbs, B.F., Rijkers, F.A.M., Wals, A.F., 2004. Strategic generation Research 27, 857–873.
with conjectured transmission price responses in a mixed transmis- Shy, O., 1995. Industrial Organization Theory and Applications. The
sion pricing system—Part II: Application. IEEE Transactions on MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
Power Systems 19 (2), 872–879. Takayama, T., Judge, G., 1971. Spatial and Temporal Price and
IEA, 2002a. IEA Energy Statistics 2001, www.iea.org/Textbase/stats/ Allocation Models. North-Holland, London.
index.asp. Tzoannos, J., 1977. An empirical study of peak-load pricing and
IEA, 2002b. IEA Natural Gas Information, 2002 (with 2001 data). investment policies for the domestic market of gas in Great Britain.
IMF-WEO, 2003. IMF-WEO September 2003. Applied Economics 9, 133–153.
IPCC, 1995. IPCC Guidelines for national Green House Gas UNFCCC, 1998. Kyoto Protocol to the United Nations Framework
inventories, 1995, vol. 3, Ref Manual. Convention on Climate Change (COP 3 report, document FCCC/
Lise, W., Linderhof, V., Kuik, O., Kemfert, C, Östling, R., Heinzow, CP/1997/7/Add.1 (18 Mar 1998)).
T. 2006. A game theoretic model of the Northwestern European Van Oostvoorn, F., 2003. Long-term gas supply security in an enlarged
electricity market—market power and the environment, Energy Europe: final report ENGAGED project, www.ecn.nl/library/
Policy, forthcoming. reports/2003/c03122.html.

Potrebbero piacerti anche