Sei sulla pagina 1di 18

GOVERNMENT COLLEGE UNIVERSITY, LAHORE

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

M.Phil. Economics
TERM PAPER

An Assessment of Cobb-Dougles, Constant Elasticity of

TITLE OF RESEARCH PROPOSAL Production and Transcendental Logarithmic


Production Function.

NAME OF STUDENT Hadiya Bahadur

ROLL NO. 0116-MPHIL-ECON-2016

SESSION 2016-2018

SUPERVISOR
Dr.Bilal Mehmood (Lecturer)
(NAME/DESIGNATION)
TABLE CONTENT

1. INTRODUCTION…………………………………………………………………….…..1

1.1 OBJECTIVE………………………………………………………………………2

2. LITERATURE REVIEW…………………………………………………………………2

3. COBB-DOUGLES PRODUCTION FUNCTION…………………………………...…..4

3.1 RETURNS TO SCALE…………………………………………………………...5

4. CONSTANT ELASTICITY OF PRODUCTION………………………………………..7

4.1 UNIT ROOT TEST ………………………………………………………….........7

4.2 ESTIMATED MODEL……………………………………………………………8

4.3 RESULTS………………………………………………………………………....9

4.4 PARAMETERS OF KAMENTA APPROXIMATION AND CES......................9

4.5 INTERPRETATION…………………………………………………………….11

5. TRANSEDENTAL LOGRITHMIC FUNCTION………………………………………12

5.1 ESTIMATED MODEL…………………………………………………………..13

5.2 RESULTS………………………………………………………………………..13

5.3 INTERPRETATION……………………………………………………………..13

6. REFRENCES………………………………………………………………………….....14

7. ANNEXURE …………………………………………………………………………….16
1. Introduction:
In modern applied economics and especially in making policies, Computable General Equilibrium
(CGE) models have become one of the leading tools to evaluate policy measures and alternative
scenarios (Goulder, 2002, Böhringen, 2003). CGE, econometric, input-output or linear
programming models use different types of nested production function with Constant Elasticity of
Scale (CES) to describe the production of an economy (Kemfert, 1998). Substitution elasticities
are key parameters in these models since measure the ease or difficulty of substituting between
inputs in production. Therefore elasticities play an important role in any economic assessment of
any policy. In this paper I’ll discuss special production functions. Nature imposes technological
constraints on firms. Only certain combinations of inputs are feasible ways to produce a given
amount of output. And firms must limit itself to technological feasible production plan. So, much
attention is being paid to establishing its production relationship. The possibility of efficient
capital-labor substitution is crucial for the success of most fiscal, financial and technological
policies that are designed to increase employment in developing countries through the adoption of
labor-intensive techniques of production. The easiest way to describe feasible production plan is
to list the set of all combination of inputs and outputs that comprise a technological feasible way
is called a production function. It’s purely a technical relation which connects factor inputs and
outputs. It shows the maximum amount of output that can be produced from any specified set of
inputs given the existing technology. It’s a flow concept so production refers to units of output
over period of time. If the possibilities exist for efficient capital labor substitution then they can be
substituted for capital without necessarily resulting in a decline in output. This issue crucially
depends on whether elasticity of substitution is positive or not. . The variation in the estimates of
the capital labor substitution mainly depends on the type of production function used i.e. Constant
Elasticity of Substitution (CES) and Variable Elasticity of Substitution (VES). In empirical
literature, much attention is being paid to establishing its production relationships which are based
on certain restrictive assumptions. The most famous of these production functions is in CES
production function (CESPF) and is also known as ‘Work Horse’ production function. It comes
with the assumption of EOS = 1. However, EOS ⋛ 1 is a more realistic assumption which is
permitted in constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production function, formulated in CESPF.

1
The CES production function (CESPF) arbitrarily constrains EOS to be a constant and does not
allow it to vary with a change in factor input ratio.
This paper uses the same to find the elasticity of substitution (EOS) between inputs in Itehad
Chemicals industry in Pakistan to evaluate the possibility of substitution between them without
compromising their performance.
1.1 Objectives
Following are the objectives of the paper:
1 To estimate the elasticity of substitution between labor and capital, this is done on the basis of
CES Production Function in Itehad Chemicals ltd of Pakistan.
2 To find the type of returns to scale that is applicable in Itehad Chemicals ltd of Pakistan.
3 To estimate Cobb-Dougles Production Function (CDPF).
4 And to estimate Transcendental Logarithmic Production Function (TPF)
2. Literature Review

Kemfert (1998) estimates the substitution elasticity of a nested CES production function for the
entire German industry and individual industrial sectors. She estimates the elasticity for tree nested
structures1 and concludes that a nested CES function with a nest of capital and energy ((KE)L) is
the most useful for the entire German industry, but for several industrial sectors a nest of capital
and labor ((KL)E) might be closer to the reality.

To avoid issues related to linearization of estimation techniques by Kmenta approximation


(Kmenta, 1967), Van der Werf (2008) and Okagawa and Ban (2008) use a cost function based
approach, where they take advantage of the cost function associated with a specific production
function and derive a linear system of equation from the corresponding optimal input demand. The
disadvantage of this approach is that it requires exhaustive price data, which is in most cases rather
difficult to obtain, especially for sector specific estimates. Van der Werf (2008) estimates a 2-level
nested production function, using the industrial level data from 12 OECD countries in for 1978-
1996. He finds that the nesting structure having capital and labour in the same node fits reality
most closely. Similarly, Okagawa and Ban (2008) estimate a nested CES function using another
OECD dataset. Their data set is more refined compared to that used in Van der Werf (2008), where
the data are disaggregated into 7 sectors; the Okagawa and Ban (2008) data set disaggregated into
19 sectors. Both study use cost function based approach to avoid problems.

2
Koesler & Schymura (2012) confirm that non-linear estimation techniques perform significantly
better than standard linear estimations using Kmenta approximation.

Su, Zhou, Ichi, Ren, & Mu (2012) estimate the China’s elasticity of substitution of two-level CES
KLE production function by three possible combination of nesting: (KL)E, (KE)L and (EL)K.

Mehmood, B., Nisar, A., & Rehman, H. U. (2015) studied the magnitude of elasticity of
substitution (EOS) among factors of production to analyze the impact on the Pakistani banking
sector. They draw upon a comprehensive time series dataset covering the period 1980-2013. To
achieve that purpose the analysis employed Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) production
function in order to follow up a quantitative evaluation of Elasticity of Substitution in the
Pakistan’s banking sector. The paper also investigated returns to scale during the time period under
consideration.

3. Cobb-Douglas production function


Two most important neo-classical production function are Cobb-Douglas production
function and constant elasticity of substitution (CES).
The Cobb-Douglas production function is widely used to represent the relationships between its
inputs in an economy , i.e. physical capital and labor, and the amount of output produced. It's a
means for calculating the impact of changes in the inputs, the relevant efficiencies, and the yields
of a production activity. It was created by Charles Cobb (mathematician) and Paul Dougles
(economist) in 1927, while its functional form was proposed by Knut Wicksell (economist) in 19th
centuary. It lies between linear and fixed proportion production function with elasticity of
substition equals to one. In 1928, Charles Cobb and Paul Douglas presented the view that
production output is the result of the amount of labor and physical capital invested. This analysis
produced a calculation that is still in use today, largely because of its accuracy, fexibility and ease
of use.

3.1. Estimated Model


The basic mathematical form of the Cobb-Douglas production function for two factors is:

𝑌 = 𝑓(𝑌, 𝐿, 𝐾) = 𝐴 ∗ 𝐾𝛽1 ∗ 𝐿𝛽2

In this formula, Y is the quantity produced from the inputs L and K.

3
L = the amount of labor expended, which is typically expressed in hours.
K = the amount of physical capital input, such as the number of hours a particular machine,
operation, or perhaps factory.
A = the total factor productivity (TFP) that measures the change in output that isn't the result of
the inputs. Typically, this change in TFP is the result of an improvement in efficiency or
technology.
The beta 1 and 2 reflect the output elasticity of the inputs where β1 is constant between 0 and 1 (0
< β < 1 ). Output elasticity is the change in the output that results from a change in either labor
or physical capital.
Least squares regression of log output (value added) on a constant and the logarithm of labor and
capital produce parameter estimates of a Cobb-Douglas production function.
Ln Y = B0 + B1 ln K + B2 ln L

Dependent Variable: LN_DY


Method: Least Squares
Date: 12/30/17 Time: 13:53
Sample: 2001 2016
Included observations: 16

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

C 2.594977 0.684580 3.790613 0.0022


LN_DK 0.133141 0.066969 1.988102 0.0683
LN_DL 0.624216 0.154166 4.048989 0.0014

R-squared 0.919340 Mean dependent var 7.866539


Adjusted R-squared 0.906931 S.D. dependent var 0.467710
S.E. of regression 0.142685 Akaike info criterion -0.888992
Sum squared resid 0.264668 Schwarz criterion -0.744132
Log likelihood 10.11194 Hannan-Quinn criter. -0.881574
F-statistic 74.08565 Durbin-Watson stat 1.246655
Prob(F-statistic) 0.000000

Ln Y = 2.59 + 0.13 ln K + 0.62 ln L

4
Ln (natural logarithmic series) generated.
Taking antilog of the production function we get the elasticity of the respective factors in their
powers
Y= 0.41*K0.13L0.62

The model represents the Cobb-Douglas production function under decreasing return to scale as
the inputs will increase, the output will increase but at a lesser rate.

18.6

18.4

.06 18.2

.04
18.0
.02
17.8
.00

-.02

-.04
05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15

Residual Actual Fitted

3.2. Return to scale:


Return to scale is a long run concept when all the factors of production are variable. In long run
output can be increased by increasing factor of production. An increase in scale means that increase
in factors of production in same proportion, output will increase but the increase may be at a
increasing rate, constant rate or decreasing rate. Cobb-Dougles and constant elasticity of
substitution exhibits constant returns to scale i.e. sum of exponents for capital and labor β1 and β2
should equal 1.

B1+B2= 1 under CRS

In the above model, 0.13+0.62= 0.75 that is less than 1 so the model is under DRS (decreasing
return to scale).

5
DY

4,800

4,400

4,000

3,600

3,200

2,800

2,400

2,000

1,600

1,200
01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16

dl

2,400

2,000

1,600

1,200

800

400

0
01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16

dk

4,000

3,500

3,000

2,500

2,000

1,500

1,000

500

0
01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16

6
4. CES production function:

Arrow, Chenery, Minhas and Solow in their new famous paper of 1961 developed the Constant
Elasticity of Substitution (CES) function. This function consists of three variables Y, K and L, and
three parameters.
In this study I have used fixed assets as capital denoted by “K” and employee’s salaries as labor
denoted by “L”, as my independent variable which are regressed against total sales i.e “Y”.

4.1. Unit root model.


𝑌𝑡 = 𝛼𝑌𝑡−1 + µ1𝑡
𝛥𝑌𝑡 = (𝛼 − 1)𝑌𝑡−1 + µ1𝑡
In the same way for capital,

𝐾𝑡 = 𝛽𝐾𝑡−1 + µ2𝑡
𝛥𝐾𝑡 = (𝛽 − 1)𝐾𝑡−1 + µ2𝑡
And labor,

𝐿𝑡 = 𝜏𝐿𝑡−1 + µ3𝑡
𝛥𝐿𝑡 = (𝜏 − 1)𝐿𝑡−1 + µ3𝑡

4.2. Estimated model


𝑌 = 𝐴 [𝛿𝐾− 𝑝+ (𝑙 − 𝛿)𝐿− 𝑝] − 𝑣/ 𝑝
Where; Y = total output,
K = capital,
L = labor,
A = efficiency parameter indicating the state of technology and organizational aspects of
production. It shows that with technological and/or organizational changes, the efficiency
parameter leads to a shift in the production function
p(rho) = the substitution parameter which determines the elasticity of substitution

7
δ = the distribution parameter or capital intensity factor coefficient concerned with the relative
factor shares in the total output.

(1-δ)= the distribution parameter for labor.

Here it is assumed that A=1, therefore:

𝑌 = 𝐴 [𝛿𝐾− 𝑝+ (𝑙 − 𝛿)𝐿− 𝑝] − 𝑣/ 𝑝
CESPF yields any value of EOS (i.e. 0 < EOS < ∞). It posits log-linear relationships among
variables and also requires that the elasticity of substitution be the sables and requires that the
elasticity of substitution be same at all points of the isoquant map. Therefore, applying Kmenta
approximation to the CES.

𝑙𝑛|Yt | = ln|A| + β1 ln|K t | + β2 ln|Lt | + β3 (ln|K t /Lt |)2

𝛽1 −2 𝛽3 (𝛽1 +𝛽2 ) 1
Where, δ = 𝛽 ; 𝑣 = 𝛽1 +𝛽2 , ; 𝑝 = ;𝜎=
1 +𝛽2 𝛽1 𝛽2 1+𝜌

The elasticity of substitution EOS is denoted by “𝜎” and is a function of “p”.

4.3. Results of the unit root test

Variables ADF
At level 1st Difference
𝑙𝑛|𝑌| -1.283792 2.724457
𝑙𝑛|𝐾| 2.915914 0.113380
𝑙𝑛|𝐿| -2.157979 0.633874
𝐾
(𝑙𝑛 | | )2 -0.349154 -0.089182
𝐿

8
4.4. Parameters of Kamenta Approximation and CES

Parameter estimation of CES Production Function


Parameter Estimates
Kamenta Approximation (FMOLS) CES
𝛽0 2.724457 Δ 0.15
𝛽1 0.113380 𝑣 0.74
𝛽2 0.633874 P -1.85
𝛽3 -0.089182 𝜎𝐶𝐸𝑆 0.35
Adj R2 0.906696 (1-δ) 0.84

𝐾
𝑙𝑛|𝑌𝑡 | = +(𝑙𝑛|𝐾𝑡 |) + (𝑙𝑛|𝐿𝑡 |) + (𝑙𝑛 | |)2
𝐿

Dependent Variable: LN_DY


Method: Least Squares
Date: 12/29/17 Time: 03:12
Sample: 2001 2016
Included observations: 16

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

C 2.724457 0.697974 3.903378 0.0021


LN_DK 0.113380 0.069999 1.619740 0.1313
LN_DL 0.633874 0.154673 4.098158 0.0015

9
LN(DK_DL) -0.089182 0.090681 -0.983468 0.3448

R-squared 0.925357 Mean dependent var 7.866539


Adjusted R-squared 0.906696 S.D. dependent var 0.467710
S.E. of regression 0.142865 Akaike info criterion -0.841509
Sum squared resid 0.244926 Schwarz criterion -0.648362
Log likelihood 10.73207 Hannan-Quinn criter. -0.831618
F-statistic 49.58826 Durbin-Watson stat 1.085224
Prob(F-statistic) 0.000000

The substitution parameter between K and L is -1.852

With the respective isoquant

isoquant at D(-1.85)
12
C 10
a
8
p
i 6
t 4
a
2
l
0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7
labor

Applying the values in the CES production function

Y = A [0.15K-1.85+ 0.84L-1.85] -1/-.1.85


To check convexity

= (1-a/a))-1.85+1(K/L)-1.85K/L2

= (0.15/0.84)-0.85(K/L)-1.85K/L2

10
As the values are positive we will be get the answer positive so Quasi-convexity is evident.

4.5. Interpretation
For CD production function, the EOS is equivalent to 1. σces = 0.35 implies that production function
for Itehad chemicals is quite close to case of Cobb Dougles but CES is more suitable functional
form. Value of δ shows the share of capital in total sales i.e. 15.1% and (1- δ) depicts the labor-
share in total sales i.e. 84.9%. ⱱ shows the elasticity of scale, which allows for increasing and
decreasing return to scale degree of homogeneity of function can be observed from ⱱ(= 0.7463<1).
It implies DRS prevail in Itehad Chemicals industry. p = -0.114, represents the substitution
parameter that determine EOS (σces). σces is 0.35 < 1 implying low substitution-ability between
inputs i.e. employee wages (proxy for labor) labor and total assets (proxy for capital). This shows
that labor and capital are relatively not easily substitutable in long run. It implies changes in
capital. The R2 shows that 92% of the variations in the dependent variable are explained by the
independent variables. The low elasticity of substitution between factors of production implies that
there exists low flexibility to adjust the factors of production in response to changes in factor prices
and/or growth in demand for products of the Itehad chemicals industry emanating from any
external or internal reasons.

5. Transcendental Logarithmic Function:


Translog production function is a more flexible production function, which was suggested by
Christensen et al. (1973). The benefit of using transcendental logarithmic function is the elasticity
as it can estimate almost any functional formula (Intriligator, 1978). The Translog function is
distinct flexible function due to presence of both linear and quadratic terms with the ability of
using more than two factor inputs. It can be approximated by second order Taylor series
(Christensen et al., 1973).in this production function level of production is measured through
production function which is the technical relationship between inputs and output. Applying the
transcendental logarithmic model in the above equation we use the values of natural logarithmic
series and using square and cross-term values in the new model.
In this study I’m using two input case and can be written as.

Y= f (K.L)
Ln (Y) = Bo + B1ln (K) + B2ln (L) + B3ln (K) 2 + B4ln (L) 2 + B5ln (K)* ln (L) + µ

11
Where,
ln = Natural Logarithm
Y = total sales
K = Fixed Assets
L = Employee’s wages
Where β0, β1, β2, β3, β4, β5, are associated output elasticities that are to be estimated and µ is the
regression disturbance.
Conventionally, symmetry conditions are imposed on Translog function i.e.
βLK = βKL
Moreover, constant returns to scale (CRS) requires following conditions
to hold:
βL + βK = 1
βKK + βLK = 0
5.1. Results

Dependent Variable: LN_Y


Method: Least Squares
Date: 12/30/17 Time: 14:48
Sample: 2001 2016
Included observations: 16

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

C -0.786854 4.781261 -0.164570 0.8726


LN_K -3.217502 1.586560 -2.027973 0.0700
LN_L 5.320827 4.676227 1.137846 0.2817
LN_K_2 -0.349375 0.220710 -1.582958 0.1445
LN_L_2 -1.740425 1.208721 -1.439890 0.1805
LN_K_LN_L 1.852177 0.886197 2.090028 0.0631

R-squared 0.963993 Mean dependent var 3.416394


Adjusted R-squared 0.945990 S.D. dependent var 0.203124

12
S.E. of regression 0.047206 Akaike info criterion -2.988583
Sum squared resid 0.022284 Schwarz criterion -2.698863
Log likelihood 29.90867 Hannan-Quinn criter. -2.973747
F-statistic 53.54492 Durbin-Watson stat 1.389615
Prob(F-statistic) 0.000001
Substituting the values in the model
Log(Y) = -0.78 – 3.21 log(K) + 5.32 log(L) – 0.34 log(K) 2 – 1.74 log(L) 2 + 1.85 log(K)*log (L)
We get the translog model with the respective coefficients

5.2. Interpretation:
The model represents that the production of Itehad Chemicals in Pakistan is having a positive
relationship with labor while negative relation with fixed assts. So we can state that the company
is labor-intensive. Itehad Chemicals is growing manufacturing set of industries and the rate of the
capital and labor significance points out the rate of technology the industry uses.

6. References
1. Arrow, K. J., Chenery, H. B., Minhas, B. S., & Solow, R. M. (1961). Capital-labor
substitution and economic efficiency. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 225-
250.
2. Goulder, L. H. (2002). Environmental policy making in economies with prior tax
distortions. Edward Elgar Publishing.
3. Henningsen, A., & Henningsen, G. (2011). Econometric Estimation of the" Constant
Elasticity of Substitution" Function in R: Package micEconCES. Institute of Food and
Resource Economics, University of Copenhagen.
4. Kemfert, C. (1998). Estimated substitution elasticities of a nested CES production
function approach for Germany. Energy Economics, 20(3), 249–264.
doi:10.1016/S0140-9883(97)00014-5
5. Khan, A., Mehmood, B., & Sair, S. A. THE VARIABLE ELASTICITY OF
SUBSTITUTION PRODUCTION FUNCTION: A CASE STUDY FOR PAKISTANI
BANKING SECTOR.
6. Kmenta, J. (1967). On estimation of the CES production function. International
Economic Review, 8(2), 180-189.

13
7. Koesler, S., & Schymura, M. (2012). Substitution Elasticities in a CES Production
Framework-An Empirical Analysis on the Basis of Non-Linear Least Squares
Estimations.
8. Mehmood, B., Nisar, A., & Rehman, H. U. (2015). TECHNOLOGY MATTERS:
EVIDENCE FROM PAKISTANI BANKING SECTOR USING FLEXIBLE
TRANSCENDENTAL LOGARITHMIC PRODUCTION FUNCTION. Pakistan
Economic and Social Review, 53(2), 203.
9. Rečka, L. (2013). Estimation of the elasticity of substitution of production factors in
CEE economies (No. 5420). EcoMod.
10. Revankar, N. S. (1971). A class of variable elasticity of substitution production
functions. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 61-71.
11. Su, X., Zhou, W., Nakagami, K. I., Ren, H., & Mu, H. (2012). Capital stock-labor-
energy substitution and production efficiency study for China. Energy
Economics, 34(4), 1208-1213.
12. Van der Werf, E. (2008). Production functions for climate policy modeling: An
empirical analysis. Energy economics, 30(6), 2964-2979.

14
7. Annexure:

years Y k l ln Y ln_k ln_k^2 ln_l ln_l^2 ln_k*ln_l


2,001 1,239 155 380 3.093071 2.190332 4.797553 2.579784 6.655283 5.650582
2,002 1,307 150 408 3.116276 2.176091 4.735373 2.61066 6.815546 5.681035
2,003 1,321 189 734 3.120903 2.276462 5.182278 2.865696 8.212214 6.523648
2,004 1,514 739 536 3.180126 2.868644 8.229121 2.729165 7.44834 7.829003
2,005 1,903 687 848 3.279439 2.836957 8.048324 2.928396 8.575502 8.307732
2,006 2,158 2,510 1,008 3.334051 3.399674 11.55778 3.003461 9.020775 10.21079
2,007 2,534 2,360 962 3.403807 3.372912 11.37654 2.983175 8.899334 10.06199
2,008 2,685 2,316 918 3.428944 3.364739 11.32147 2.962843 8.778437 9.969191
2,009 3,633 2,598 1,212 3.560265 3.414639 11.65976 3.083503 9.507988 10.52905
2,010 3,258 2,471 1,261 3.512951 3.392873 11.51159 3.100715 9.614434 10.52033
2,011 3,310 2,499 1,347 3.519828 3.397766 11.54482 3.129368 9.792942 10.63286
2,012 4,004 2,515 1,346 3.602494 3.400538 11.56366 3.129045 9.790923 10.64044
2,013 4,278 2,496 1,619 3.631241 3.397245 11.54127 3.209247 10.29927 10.9026

15
2,014 4,104 2,485 1,704 3.613207 3.395326 11.52824 3.23147 10.4424 10.97189
2,015 4,046 3,756 1,437 3.607026 3.574726 12.77866 3.157457 9.969533 11.28704
2,016 4,557 3,638 2,040 3.658679 3.560863 12.67974 3.30963 10.95365 11.78514

years dY dk dl log(dk/dl) (logdl)^2 (logdk)^2 log(dk/dl)^2


2,001 6 5.043425 5.940171 -0.89675 35.28563 25.43614 0.804154
2,002 6 5.010635 6.011267 -1.00063 36.13533 25.10647 1.001264
2,003 7 5.241747 6.598509 -1.35676 43.54032 27.47591 1.840803
2,004 6 6.605298 6.284134 0.321164 39.49034 43.62996 0.103146
2,005 7 6.532334 6.742881 -0.21055 45.46644 42.67139 0.04433
2,006 7 7.828038 7 0.912315 47.82723 61.27818 0.832318
2,007 7 7.766417 6.869014 0.897402 47.18336 60.31723 0.805331
2,008 7 7.747597 6.822197 0.925399 46.54238 60.02526 0.856364
2,009 7 7.862497 7 0.76247 50.41039 61.81886 0.581361
2,010 7 7.812378 7 0.672718 50.97475 61.03325 0.452549
2,011 7 7.823646 7 0.618011 51.92118 61.20944 0.381937
2,012 7 7.830028 7 0.625136 51.91048 61.30934 0.390794
2,013 7 7.822445 7 0.432881 54.60566 61.19064 0.187386
2,014 7 7.818028 7 0.377294 55.36452 61.12156 0.142351
2,015 7 8.23111 7 0.960797 52.85745 67.75117 0.923131
2,016 8 8.199189 8 0.578484 58.07515 67.22671 0.334644

16

Potrebbero piacerti anche