Sei sulla pagina 1di 23

Nationalization of Oil in Venezuela: Re-Defined Dependence and Legitimization of

Imperialism
Author(s): Vegard Bye
Source: Journal of Peace Research, Vol. 16, No. 1 (1979), pp. 57-78
Published by: Sage Publications, Ltd.
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/422789
Accessed: 30-07-2016 16:38 UTC

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted
digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about
JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Sage Publications, Ltd. is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of
Peace Research

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
ISSN 0022-3433 Journal of Peace Research, No. 1, Vol. XVI, 1979

Nationalization of Oil in Venezuela

Re-defined Dependence and Legitimization of Imperialism

VEGARD BYE
International Peace Research Institute, Oslo*

Venezuela has been one of the leading proponents of a new international economic order.
As a major oil producer it was instrumental in the creation of OPEC. It has also realized a
basic element of a NIEO - the nationalization of basic economic resources. The oil
industry was nationalized on January 1, 1976, while the second-ranking export industry,
iron and steel, had been expropriated one year earlier.
In this paper the effects of oil nationalization in Venezuela are studied to establish whether
the previous structure of foreign dominance has been fundamentally altered. A set of
dominance indicators is defined and applied to Venezuela before and after nationalization.
The main conclusion is that dominance structures persisted, but with some differences
between indicators. The expected long-term effect of increased oil prices, oil nationalization
and the new development strategy, is that the degree of mono-production will be reduced,
whereas economic and technological penetration as well as dependence on foreign trade will
actually increase. This points to the need for more fundamental changes in power relation-
ships inside the country. Nationalization alone does not guarantee a development in the
interests of the majority.

1. Introduction New International Economic Order


One could expect nationalization to be the (NIEO); the potential content of this ambi-
absolute enemy of any foreign-owned eco- tion has been most clearly manifested
nomic activity in a given country. National- through the OPEC countries' drastic in-
ization, as understood in this article, means crease of oil prices in 1973-74. A major
the transfer of property from a foreign com- issue of the NIEO is the right of less-
pany to the state; and this, taken literally, developed countries to control their natural
should lead to the end of the activity of the resources: i. e. to nationalize formerly for-
company in question. In reality, this is quite eign-owned activity in this field. There have
evidently not the case. been many tough disputes between Third
The power position of multinational cor- World governments and the home govern-
porations (MNCs) in the world economy at ments of most of the MNCs - USA, West
large, and in the economies of Third World Germany, Japan - over this and other
countries in particular, is undisputed. As a issues of the NIEO, at the general as well as
reaction to this control and power position, at a more concrete level. On the other hand,
the world has for years now been observing recently quite a few nationalizations have
a growing ambition on the part of periphery taken place without serious conflicts be-
states to have a more substantial say in tween the nationalizing government and the
their own economic affairs. This has been nationalized MNCs and their governments.
clearly expressed at various international On the contrary, there seems to have been
conferences, in the form of demands for a a most open and cooperative atmosphere
surrounding the whole process. There is
* This article is a shorter version of the post- therefore reason to believe that such na-
graduate thesis written by the same author (in
Norwegian): Bye, Vegard, 1977. Nasfonalisering tionalization need not necessarily be consid-
av oljevirksomheten i Venezuela. En studie av ered as a serious threat to the power posi-
endringer i avhengighetsstruktur. Oslo: University tions of the MNCs, nor of the dominant
of Oslo, Institute of Political Science/International
internal groups and classes in the periphery
Peace Research Institute, Oslo. (265 pages). The
article can be identified as PRIO Publication no countries that have been relying on such
S-27/78. foreign investments for their own prosperity.

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
58 Vegard Bye

The case of Venezuela is most interesting formation? It will also be necessary for us
in this regard. On the one hand, Venezuela to take a brief look into the main develop-
has been one of the most 'verbally militant' ment trends in the structure of dominance
countries in NIEO negotiations. As a major - on both the external and the internal
oil exporter, it was the initiating country level - leading up to the nationalization.
behind the creation of OPEC; it has always In other words: what changes have occurred
taken a leading position within this organi- that has made it possible, advantageous to
zation, aiming at utilizing its potential power external and/or internal power groups, per-
position to increase the exporting countries' haps even necessary, to take this step? We
say and their oil prices substantially. will also make some attempts at forecasting
Even if Venezuela did not directly partici- the possible long-term effects on the domin-
pate in the 1973 Arab boycott, its role in ance structure of Venezuelan society in
creating the necessary conditions for this general, effects that may be created by the
efficient step should not be ignored (see new development strategy founded on the
Acosta Hermoso, 1969-70; Chevalier, 1973; nationalization and the price-hike on oil
Tugwell, 1975). after 1973.
On the other hand, Venezuela has taken When referring to the concept 'structure
the step towards fulfilling perhaps the most of dominance' (or'structure of dependence'),
crucial element of NIEO: nationalization of what is meant is the basic Marxist (or neo-
the country's basic economic activity. The Marxist) understanding of the existence of
Venezuela oil industry was nationalized on a highly specific social formation in periph-
1 January 1976. Mention should also be ery societies, totally unlike earlier 'stages' of
made of the iron and steel, the country's development in centre societies. This specific
second most important export sector, which kind of social formation has developed
was nationalized one year earlier. through a long historical process where the
The nationalization of oil in Venezuela periphery societies have been constantly
was clearly one of the most important and adjusted to the needs of the centre societies
far-reaching nationalizations so far to be and exploited accordingly. This process of
implemented by a Third World government. adjustment, or the systematic incorporation
Ever since oil exploration and production into the world capitalist system,1 has made
started in Venezuela in 1917, oil has totally the structures of production in periphery
dominated the country's economy; and oil societies completely distorted, such that
activity has been totally monopolized by the they even to-day are unable to create a base
world's oil giants. for real development. 'Real development'
Against this background, a detailed study here means organizing production in a social
of the nationalization of oil in Venezuela formation in a such way that it, based on
should be considered a major task. In this present human and natural resources, can
article, our main focus will be on analyzing be directed towards egalitarian satisfaction
the main effects of the nationalization. To of such fundamental needs as food, health,
what degree has it led to change in the house, elementary education, and work.2
power position of the MNCs, and in the
relations between MNCs and the State? In 2. The traditional external structure of
other words, have there been any major dominance
changes in the external structure of domin- From playing an extremely minor role in
ance as a consequence of the nationaliza- world economy before the start of oil pro-
tion? Second, has nationalization led to any duction, Venezuela rapidly developed into
changes in the internal structure of domin- an important actor on the stage of world
ance: i. e. in the character of the state and economy. As early as in 1929, the country
the class structure of the country's social was the world's largest oil producer, with

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Nationalization of Oil in Venezuela 59

10 % of total world production. From the possible because of the established relation-
start, Venezuela's oil sector was completely ship.
monopolized by the major oil corporations. With the coup d'etat that ended the
In 1929, Standard Oil of California Betancourt government and initiated another
(SOCAL) and Gulf together stood for brutal dictatorship in 1948 - most of the
54.8 % of the production, and Shell for the time headed by Perez Jimenez - it was
remaining 45 %. In 1932, Standard Oil of believed that the oil giants would regain
New Jersey (ESSO, laterEXXON) took over their absolute freedom of operation. This
SOCAL's interests; ever since then, these also proved the case as far as expansion of
three companies have been the dominating their activity was concerned. Production
ones in the Venezuela oil business. (NACLA, volume doubled during the following decade,
vol. X (1976), No. 8, pp. 4-5.) and no restrictions were made on foreign
This, of course, meant that abruptly the investments in any sector. But, interestingly
country's economy was completely pen- enough, state income was also doubled
etrated by external interests. The conditions parallelly, which means that the tax level
offered to the oil companies are estimated must have been kept unchanged.
to have been among the most advantageous When the military dictatorship was over-
offered to any foreign enterprises in Latin thrown in 1958, and the AD leadership
America at that time. stepped onto the stage once more, it was a
But even the small share of the oil in- totally open question how the relation to
comes that remained in the country repre- foreign capital would develop. All the polit-
sented a considerable amount of money, and ical forces in the country, from the centre
this created the conditions for the emerg- towards the left, were waiting hopefully for
ence of a growing petty-bourgeoisie. Partic- political solutions totally contradictory with
ularly the state bureaucracy and the intel- each other. In retrospect, it can be con-
lectuals were important in fomenting a na- cluded that the outcome was a policy of cap-
tionalist sentiment and ambitions for a italist consolidation in close alliance with
stronger state apparatus to cope with the oil foreign capital. The major general tendency
giants. The resulting changes in government in the development of external dominance
(see later) produced a certain restriction in during that period was a strong and rapid
the freedom of the foreign companies. process of import substitution. Because of
During the three years of the Venezuelan the excess of oil incomes, Venezuela had
populist government (AD - Accion Demo- never had the structural prerequisites for
crdtica) that came to power in 1945, the creating any substantial domestic industry
possibility of nationalization was first dis- sector, as for instance Mexico, Argentina,
cussed. The answer of President Betan- and Brazil had done in the 1930s. Now,
court, who at that time was considered very however, it became a political objective of
nationalistic, was the following: the leading domestic sectors, including the
Government, to use parts of oil money in an
Practically the whole Venezuelan economy and effort to industrialize. A highly significant
an appreciable portion of government income are
characteristic of this process in Venezuela
based on the petroleum industry. Faced with these
realities, it would have been a suicidal leap into should be emphasized. The process came
space to nationalize the industry by decree. about, from the very beginning, by means
(Quoted by Tugwell, 1975, p. 45). of foreign capital. Thus, the domestic in-
dustry market in Venezuela became inter-
This answer gives a clear picture of the nationalized before any indigenous, national
existing dependency: although the Govern- industry sector was allowed to develop. This
ment could see it as a political objective to had vital repercussions on the development of
nationalize, in practice it was simply im- class alliances. It is important to notice that

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
60 Vegard Bye

the State in this period played an active role issue culminated with the passing of the
in the foreign capital penetration of sectors 'law of reversion' in 1971, which stated
outside oil. Until Venezuela as late as 1972 that all changes in the companies' opera-
became member of the Andean Pact and tional activities needed prior authorization
thus subject to the fairly severe restrictions by the government. The law also made it
on foreign investment effective in that or- clear that all concessions and properties be-
ganization till 1976, the Venezuelan State longing to the companies would revert to
allowed total freedom in transnational cap- the state with the expiration of concession
ital transactions. Import substitution thus agreements in 1983.
led first of all to a diversification of external
The counter-strategy on the part of the
dominance.
oil monopolies - who wished to maintain
The State policy in the oil sector in this their profits, their self-determination of oil
pre-nationalization period was very inter- prices, and not least their general autonomy
esting. From the outset, 'nationalization of against government intervention - consisted
oil' was the slogan of broad popular groups. of three elements: First, de-investment,
This possibility was immediately ruled out which made new investments in the industry
by the AD government, the arguments being drop below the depreciation level for most
the same as during the first AD period. years after 1958. Second, reduction in pro-
Although there were several confrontations, duction volume, although this was used
the government never really challenged the more as threat. (The long-term tendency
oil giants. By means of a careful strategy of during the period was in fact a considerable
experimentation, however, the premises for increase in oil production.) The third ele-
nationalization were gradually created. ment, then, was to build an alliance with the
The strategy, though not consistent,
domestic capitalist sector, and through that
was based on three elements: First, to in- position launch campaigns each time the
crease government income from oil, partly government made new efforts to gain the
through increased production, partly through
upper hand. This strategy, successful only
increased taxation. Of these, the tax in- for a certain time, will be described later on.
creases were by far the most important, un-
Step-by-step, however, the monopolies
like in the 1948-58 decade. The government/ had to yield to the government. The con-
company income split went in favour of the
servative periodical Resumen has claimed
government through various leaps cor- that the 1970 and 1971 oil laws meant a
responding to new tax laws, from 52/48 in de facto nationalization, and that the later
1957 to 87/13 before the dramatic price law of nationalization only formalized this
hike of 1973. But this did not mean that the fact. Resumen also claims that after the
companies' profit rate went down.
passing of these laws, the oil companies were
The second element in the strategy was in fact in favour of nationalization, because
to achieve an increased say in determining any system other than that prevailing be-
oil prices. This was first attempted through tween 1971 and 1975 would be better to
the creation of OPEC, as described earlier. them. (Resumen, 25.4-75, p. 30.) Although
By 1970, after a series of failures, the this seems an exaggeration, there is no
government was at last able to enforce a doubt that the companies gradually changed
law establishing its right to fix unilaterally their strategy from one of opposing na-
the prices of oil produced in the country. tionalization by all means to one of ac-
The third element, then, was an effort at commodating themselves to a situation of
increasing the government's general control formal government control, and reducing
of the activities of the oil companies - their real loss of position within this new
volume of production, investment policy, situation to a minimum (see later).3
exploration, etc. A long struggle over this To sum up the external structure of dom-

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Nationalization of Oil in Venezuela 61

inance/dependence in Venezuela before the tionalization, it is sufficient to refer to some


nationalization of oil on 1 January 1976, of the conclusions in a report published by
we will make use of seven indicators. In our the government's own research-institute for
opinion, each expresses an important aspect oil technology, INVEPET (later INTEVEP)
of the total structure.4 (INVEPET, 1975). The task of this report
was to assess to what extent the oil com-
(1) Economic penetration. The foreign cap- panies operating in Venezuela were depen-
ital penetration of the Venezuela oil sector dent on foreign-based technology, either
can only be characterized as total prior to from the concessionaries' mother companies
nationalization. The world's largest enterprise, or from specialized service companies. That
Exxon Corp., controlled more than 40 % the domestically available technology was
of production. The three largest companies totally monopolized by the giant's operation
- all among the world's Top Ten accord- units in the country was not even ques-
ing to Fortune - were responsible for 80 % tioned.

of production. The 'Seven sisters', of which The conclusions may briefly be summed
all but BP were active in the Venezuela, up as follows: The dependence on mother
controlled 88 %. As to country of origin, conpanies or specialized service companies
US-based companies were responsible for - the latter frequently parts of the same
almost 3/4 of production, Great Britain and enterprises - was almost total in all aspects
Netherlands about 1/4, with only 2-3 % for of the oil industry: exploration, production,
the host country. (Ministerio de Minas e and refining. This was also true for routine
Hidrocarburos - (MMH) 1974, pp. 66-70; operations, but even stronger in innovative
1975, p. 54-70.) operations, and in research and develop-
With regard to refining capacity, the con- ment. This fact notwithstanding, a signi-
centration was even more conspicuous. Here ficant process of 'venezuelization' was going
the 'Seven sisters' controlled more than on in the companies over the 15 years prior
95 %. As a consequence of the foreign-con- to the nationalization: this is shown by the
trolled import substitution that took place fact that the percentage of foreigners on
from 1958 onwards, foreign investments their staff was reduced from 12 to 2.
were gradually diversified to non-oil sectors.
The Venezuelan economist Hector Silva (3) Trade partner concentration. It is not
Michelena estimated that the 'real influence' possible to give the exact percentage of
of foreign capital in the economy of the Venezuelan oil exported to different coun-
country - i. e. the share of the economy in tries, because a substantial share of the
one way or other penetrated through direct crude oil is transported to the Exxon and
investments, imported raw materials or Shell refineries on the Netherland Antilles
semi-produced articles, machines, patents (Aruba and Curagau, respectively) and re-
etc. - was more than 3/4 (H. Silva Michel- exported from there. But if direct export
ena, 1975, p. 109). from Venezuela and re-export from Aruba/
US dominance among the foreign in- Curagau are taken together, about 50 %
vestors was undisputed. It comprised 100 % went to the United States, another 13-14 %
of investments in the second largest export to Canada, about 10 % to the EEC coun-
sector, mining, 68 % in both industry and tries, and 17-18 % to Central America and
commerce, and 73 % in banking. (Blank, the Caribbean (Sources: Creole Petroleum
1973.) Corporation and MMH, various years).5
Out of USA's total oil import, around
(2) Technological penetration. To give a 30 % came from Venezuela (1973) - a
picture of the total technological dependence percentage rapidly falling from 58 % in
in the Venezuelan oil sector before na- 1963.

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
62 Vegard Bye

We can conclude that before nationaliza- ed, their total share of export incomes was
tion Venezuela was basically dependent on 98.4 %.8
the US market, whereas US dependence on
Venezuelan oil was gradually diminishing. (6) External exploitation. By 'external ex-
ploitation' here we mean the total transfer
(4) Foreign trade dependence. Another of value from the country where this value
indicator of dominance/dependence is the is produced to other countries. Such transfer
extent of foreign trade domination in a can take three forms:
country's economy. In the case of Vene-
zuela, this domination was undisputed, be- (i) transfer of surplus value: i. e. taking part
cause the economy had been totally based of the surplus value out of the country where it is
on the exportation of oil. In 1974, the total produced, so that it is accumulated abroad in the
central countries, instead of creating a base for
value of exported goods was exactly 50 %
extended re-production in the periphery. This
of the country's Gross Domestic Product phenomenom can be measured by the relation be-
(MMH, 1975, p. 1). Even if this figure tween invested foreign capital and profit the for-
might have been unnormally high that year, eign investors take out of the country. For the
it would still be around 40 in normal years. period 1964-73, the oil companies had an average
profit rate, in percent of net fixed assets, of about
The value of imported goods per capita 32; this meant that their earnings caught up with
economically active was US $ 1476 in their investments every three years. All this prof-
1975. Sixty percent of it is means of pro- it was not taken out of the country. Some of it
duction (raw materials plus machinery); was re-invested. According to the most conser-
vative estimates, total profits after tax for the
53 % is means of production for the in-
period 1947 to 1975 were 51,345 million bolivares,
dustry. (Rodriguez Trujillo, 1976, table 4). whereas total investments were 30,727 million boli-
vares.9 The difference - 20,518 million bolivares
(5) Mono-production. Venezuela is a coun- (almost $ 4,800 million) - is what here is called
'transfer of surplus value' for that period.'0
try highly dependent on one product. This
(ii) Unequal exchange: i. e. the tendency for
has been the case ever since oil activity was the amount of work necessary in peripheral coun-
started. It is scarcely an exaggeration to say tries to exchange for goods produced by a constant
that the Venezuelan economy is oil. Here amount of work in centre nations to be steadily

only three indicators of the situation before growing.11 To measure this, we can look at the
exchange rate between a peripheral country's ex-
nationalization will be mentioned.
port and import goods over a given time-period.
Oil's share of Gross Domestic Product For Venezuela, the development of this ex-
- without taking into account economic change rate was very negative in the period 1958
activities indirectly dependent on oil - to 1970; from 1970 on, rising oil prices more than
caught up with rising prices on imported goods.
was 34 % in 1975 (down from 48 % the
But although oil prices in 1975 were almost six
year before, because of reduced produc- times those in 1970 - which of course, is a unique
tion).6 The share of government income case in the history of raw materials as far as
stable tendencies are concerned - the 'exchange
from oil - in this case also only in a direct
rate' in 1975 compared to 1958 was still clearly
way - was 77 % in 1975 (down from
negative. This can be shown by comparing the
86 % the year before). Oil's share of export price indexes of export and import goods for the
incomes gives, of course, the most con- two years in question. If the relation between
spicuous figure (mono-export). More than these figures is considered equal (1:1) in 1958, it
15 years after the initiation of a policy sup- was 1:0.79 in the favour of import goods by 1975.12
(iii) The third form of external exploitation is
posedly geared towards economic diversi-
the so-called invisible foreign services, which in-
fication, 95.6 % of the export income still cludes interests on foreign credits, payments of
came from oil in 1975. (MMH, various foreign service like transportation, insurance, etc.,
years.)7 If the second most important ex- payments for technology services in the form of
patent and licence royalties, etc.13 We have no
port article, iron - also totally foreign con-
reliable figures on the total amount paid for these
trolled till nationalization in 1975 - is add- services. As to Venezuela's total shipping costs,

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Nationalization of Oil in Venezuela 63

their net negative effect on the balance of pay- 1930s. This also meant that no important
ments in 1975 was $400 million, this figure in- rise of nationalist elements within the bour-
cluding costs of insurance, charters, etc. (LAER,
vol. VI (1978) No. 5).
geoisie could be observed. On the other
hand, despite incredibly advantageous con-
(7) Enclave-structure. By economic enclaves ditions offered to the oil companies, state
we are referring to an economic structure incomes from royalties and taxes grew
dominated by foreign-controlled economic rapidly. This was the material base of the
sectors not integrated into the rest of the emerging state bureaucracy, the main ele-
national economy. An extreme example of ment of the petty bourgeoisie that was to
such an enclave would be a sector where all play such an important role in constructing
an internal structure of dominance in Vene-
inputs except working force and or raw
materials were imported and all products zuela. The other elements of the petty
exported. bourgeoisie were the self-employed crafts-
For Venezuela, I will make brief refer- men that moved from the countryside into
ence to the structure of oil refining. Since the towns, where they easily found prosper-
the very beginning of their activity in the ous conditions in the boom economy; and
country, the oil companies have followed a those employed in private trade, banking
and service activities of all kinds that also
strategy of spreading risks. This was
achieved by, among other things, situating a
flourished - very often on a speculative
basis - as an off-shoot of the oil business.
large part of the refineries outside Vene-
zuelan territory. That is why the huge Shell Taken together, these petty-bourgeois sec-
and Exxon refineries in Curagau and Aruba, tors made up 38 % of the workforce out-
side agriculture as early as in 1935 - a
respectively, were constructed. These two
share that continued to grow to 54 % in
plants refine more Venezuelan oil than do
1950 (Rangel, 1970, p. 269).
those on the Venezuela mainland. Their
existence is also a main reason why as much The important thing about this emergence
as 70 % of Venezuela's oil export consists of a sizable petty bourgeoisie, was that it
of crude oil - which of course reduces the came about before the working class gained
spill-over effect for the rest of the economy any importance, numerically or organiza-
from what it could have been with a higher tionally. Venezuelan oil activity was highly
degree of domestic refining. It also gives the capital intensive, and it ruined much of the
oil companies a greater power position. We agriculture. This started a rapid process of
should note that the percentage of refined urbanization. Without employment possibil-
products out of total export remained more ities in the towns, however, this only led to
or less constant over the last 10 years be- urban marginalization, a problem that has
fore nationalization, even though refinery remained one of the most conspicuous social
capacity was substantially increased. This aspects of Venezuela.
means that the degree of actual use of exist- The combination of the final break-
ing refining capacity dropped dramatically, through of capitalism as the dominant mode
from 95 % in 1970 to 56 % in 1975. (MMH, of production and a gradual political liber-
1975, pp. 66, 68.) alization, initiated after Gomez' death in
1935, led to a comprehensive class organi-
3. The traditional internal structure of zation in the country. The first national
dominance union congress was summoned in 1937,
We have pointed out that the early oil boom and especially the number of industry
in Venezuela hampered the growth of such unions grew rapidly. In the beginning, the
import substitution and national industriali- Communist Party had the initiative in the
zation as those that gained momentum in formation of unions; however, the new
other Latin American economies in the populist party, Accion Democratica (AD),

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
64 Vegard Bye

soon took over the hegemony, partly be- from workers and campesinos. This eco-
cause it was much more critical to the re- nomic programme, combined with intellec-
gime.l4 When Confederacion de Trabaja- tual ideas of democratization, elected gov-
dores de Venezuela (CTV) was created in ernents, etc., made AD a typical Latin
1947, AD was in total control. American populist party, soon to become
The same thing happened in the country- the main social and political force in Vene-
side. After a series of violent but unorgan- zuela.
ized and spontaneous riots, land occupa- When a group of low-ranking officers
tions, etc. carried out by poor farmers and overthrew the military government in 1945,
farm workers (campesinos) in the 1930s, there was no doubt that AD was to take the
AD started a huge mobilization campaign lead in the new government. During the
among these groups, recruiting local cam-
three following years, the first steps towards
pesino-leaders and integrating the local and abolishing the oligarchical state and intro-
spontaneously created sindicatos agricolas
ducing a populist one were taken. But the
into the party structure. When the country- economic basis of the Venezuelan social
wide Federacion Campesina de Venezuela formation was still not prepared to allow a
(FCV) was created in 1947 (the same year final change of this kind: The traditional
as the CTV) the AD leadership was un- sectors of the bourgeoisie, allied with for-
disputed (Huizer, 1973, pp. 67-73, and eign capital, were strong enough to over-
Duncan Powell, 1971, p. 286 ff.). throw the AD government in 1948. The
What kind of party was AD, then? How populist movement, which then consisted of
was it able to gain the control of the popu- a multi-class party and mass movements
lar masses in such a successful way? among workers and campesinos, had not yet
The party was founded in 1941 by a grown into a populist pact, integrated into
group of liberal intellectuals, with the rebel- the state apparatus. The mass movement,
lious students from 1928 prominent. though mobilized from above and under
Although the leadership was petty-bour- control of a bourgeois and petty-bourgeois
geois from the outset, its programme at- party leadership, had during this three-year
tracted much broader sectors of the popu- period still protest and demand as its main
lation. It represented a protest against the characteristics. Not least through quite ex-
old tyranny, the laissez-faire policy of the tensive land reform and government back-
military dictatorship and the traditional ing of the trade unions in their collective
bourgeoisie in general. Its platforms were bargaining with the newly-created em-
those of national capitalist development and ployers' federation - Fedecdmaras - AD
industrialization, protectionism instead of maintained its mass support, obtaining 80 %
free trade, heavier taxation - especially of of the 'popular vote' in the 1946 elections.
the oil companies - and of increased state With this mass basis still more or less intact
regulation of the economy. But these were at the overthrow of the Perez-Jimenez Junta
also the ideas of the new, but still very in 1958, the AD leadership and the social
weak, national urban-based industrial bour- classes it represented were free to continue
geoisie. One necessary condition for a na- their work of constructing a populist state,
tional, inward-oriented (rather than out- with the party and mass movement inte-
ward-oriented) economic development was grated into it. The fact that another party
expansion of the domestic market, and this - the Christian Democratic COPEI - also
necessitated a certain degree of social re- gradually developed into a populist party
form. Two aspects particularly were im- and had gained important mass support,
portant in this respect: legalization of trade thus challenging the monopolist AD hege-
union activity, and land-reform - which, mony, does not falsify such an analysis.
at the same time, secured massive support Starting from this position, AD from 1958

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Nationalization of Oil in Venezuela 65

on could start to transform the main function portant. Large parts of the urban industrial
of the mass organizations from mobilization proletariat are, relatively speaking, quite
to control. This was clearly expressed well off, not least because of the capital-
through the 1959 party programme. The intensive structure of the country's industry
so-called agrarian thesis stated that the main and the high activity in construction. Aver-
objective of the new land reform should not age wages for those employed in the oil
be, as in 1945, to change the structure of industry - of course not only workers -
property in the countryside by distributing were US$ 1590 a month in 1975 (6840
land to landless and small peasants, but to bolivares) (MMH, 1975, p. 122). In con-
increase the efficiency of agricultural pro- trast, 29 % of all employed outside agri-
duction. The land reform of 1960, though culture in 1974 earned less than the official
the most costly ever in Latin America, led minimum wage of 500 bolivares a month
to concentration rather than distribution of (Chossudovsky, 1975, pp. 38-39). In the
land (Duncan Powell, 1971, p. 296). The agricultural sector, about 600,000 persons
campesino organization FCV was bureau- had a monthly income of 250 bolivares or
cracized and made a corporative institution less in 1970 (H. Silva Michelena, 1975, p.
of mediation. The so-called syndical thesis 121). To this it has to be added that many
had the same contents, limiting the function low-income employees in reality are un- or
of unions to negotiating for limited eco- under-employed, such as street vendors, per-
nomic improvements and stripping it of all sons sporadically employed in government
political protest function. service-work or in other kinds of artificial
and totally unproductive occupations. The
From the viewpoint of capitalist repro- real un-/under-employment is by Vene-
duction, the populist pact STATE-
zuelan economists estimated at around
PARTIES-TRADE UNION/CAMPESINO
45 % of the potential labour force (ibid.).
ORGANIZATION is an ideal solution. It is
When we realize that union leaders and
the best imaginable instrument to mediate
popularly recruited leaders in AD come
in what O'Connor (1973) calls the basic
from the relatively privileged groups, which
contradiction in the capitalist state: that be-
to a certain extent have taken advantage of
tween accumulation (reproduction of the
the general economic development, it is no
capitalist mode of production), and legiti- wonder that the populist movement has been
macy. These two needs are fulfilled through
'pacified'. We would in fact say that the
the populist pact's functions of control and popularly recruited union and party workers
mobilization, respectively. responsible for - or at least who have ac-
An important question in this connection cepted - the bureaucratization of the pop-
is the following: How could the party leader- ulist movement and the appearance of the
ship and the union bureaucracy maintain populist pact, can be labelled a labour
control over the organized masses when the aristocracy.'5 The poor masses - be they
populist movement's main function was campesinos, workers in small and medium
changed from one of mobilization to one of industry or unemployed squatters in urban
social control? slum districts - have never taken part in
In the first place, the fact that mobiliza- this process. With almost one half of the
tion always (with the exception of the first country's labour force without stable work
spontaneous riots in the 1930s) had taken and one half of the working class unorgan-
the form of mobilization from above evi- ized, it is no exaggeration to say that the
dently made the populist movement much majority of the people in Venezuela con-
easier to control and manipulate. Second, sists of a poor mass marginalized economi-
the constitution of class structure among the cally, socially, and politically. They fall out-
popular groups in Venezuela has been im- side the populist pact, but the existence of

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
66 Vegard Bye

the pact makes it extremely difficult for any ter of the import substitution (described
alternative and independent mass movement earlier), a close alliance between foreign
to be constructed. and national capital continued during the
Although this populist pact no doubt has first ten years of the post-Perez Jimenez era.
been the main guarantee for the reproduc- This was symbolized through the oil monop-
tion of the capitalist mode of production, olies' strong dominance in the employer
against such revolutionary solutions as e. g. federation Fedecadmaras, where they be-
were intended by the guerilla movement in came members in 1959. Fedecdmaras gave
early 1960s, the capitalist state continued to enthusiastic support to the monopolies in
be under the command of the capitalist all their conflicts with the Government over
class. This was clearly demonstrated by the oil policy, at least up to 1966. (Tugwell,
main political output from the state ap- 1975.) But suddenly, in 1970,when the most
paratus, which Hector Silva Michelena has drastic tax law against the monopolies so
described in this way: For each bolivar the far was submitted, this alliance proved not
capitalists have invested in accumulative so effective any longer. Fedecdmaras, though
production, the state has contributed 2 still supporting the position of the monop-
bolivares in infrastructure, communications, olies, did not take part in any campaign
strongly subsidized raw materials and cred- against the state, as it had before. Obviously,
its. Instead of directing the economy to- an important change had occurred within
wards popular consumption, the state dis- the power bloc.
tribution of the oil surplus (which made the The change no doubt had to do with the
state a vitally important economic agent) led growing importance of the state. Earlier,
to consolidation of the distorted process of the state bourgeoisie, the leading group
accumulation, consequently channelling this within the state bureaucracy, had repeatedly
surplus to the richest 5 % of the population. tried to expand the state's power position
(Silva Michelena, op. cit.) - and thereby indirectly its own. This was
This role of the state as protectionist vis exactly what the struggles with the oil mo-
a vis capital accumulation, and not as a nopolies were about. Gradually, the state
direct participant in accumulation, should and the state bourgeoisie gained so strong a
be stressed. Between 1969 and 1973, only position that the national capitalist sector
4 % of state expenditure went to invest- could no more ignore it. Itself too weak to
ment in direct productive activity (Proceso gain any hegemonic position in the power
Politico 2/1976, p. 26). It is therefore cor- bloc, the national bourgeoisie had to lean
rect to describe the economic system in on either the compradore bourgeoisie or the
Venezuela in this period as one with a very state bourgeoisie. Now the time evidently
comprehensive state intervention; but it was had come to change allies. The hegemony in
not yet any state capitalist system. This the power bloc had been taken over by the
would have required that '... the principal state bourgeoisie. But, as we shall see, that
sources of surplus production are owned and did not mean that the oil monopolies had
directed by the state and that the state be- lost all influence in the power bloc.
comes the principal source of capital ac- What was clear now was that the stage
cumulation within a market economy'. was set for a growing state influence in oil
(Petras, 1976, p. 393). policy, with nationalization the obvious final
A main reason for the lack of state parti- step. The decisive event to warrant such a
cipation in produuctive activity was the rela- step was the so-called oil crisis of 1973-74.
tion of strength within what Poulantzas By Christmas 1973, two weeks after being
(1973) calls the power bloc, i.e. the different elected President, Carlos Andres Perez
fractions of the bourgeoise. Because of the hinted that the moment for nationalization
monopolistic and foreign-dominated charac- was approaching (Latin America, 28/12/73,

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Nationalization of Oil in Venezuela 67

p. 409); and a few weeks after taking office, 4.1. Sales agreements
in March 1974, he issued a decree stating Before nationalization, about 90 % of the
that the decision had in principle been taken oil produced in Venezuela had been ex-
(Decreto No. 10-22, marzo de 1974, arti- ported (MMH, 1975, pp. 54 and 89). The
culo 1).16 sale of this oil abroad was even more monop-
olized by the vertically integrated oil cor-
4. The oil sector nationalized
porations than any other part of their
The Presidential Commission took three
activity.
According to the nationalization law,
quarters of a year to draft a law proposition,
diversification of markets should be a major
presented in December 1974. Another eight
objective. This was intended as an attempt
months elapsed before the Congress of
to reduce Venezuela's dependence on ex-
Venezuela passed the law (August 1975),
port to USA and other large western cap-
and the law was made effective as of 1 Jan-
italist countries. These are countries where
uary 1976.
the possibilities of establishing 'direct mar-
Each of the former concessionaries was kets' (another objective) are relatively il-
simply substitued by a new 'national' oil lusory.
company, which maintained the structures Given the established marketing struc-
and functions of its MNC-predecessor.Y7
ture, however, it seemed almost impossible
All the new companies are owned by a for the state companies to achieve the ex-
holding company - Petroven or PDV - port objectives set out by the new law. The
in its turn owned by the State. As a matter alternative was to enter into agreements with
of principle, all Venezuelans with leading
the newly-nationalized corporations on for-
positions in the MNCs took over the lead-
eign sales. These agreements (Los acuerdos
ing positions of the respective new com-
de Comercializacion Petrolera) have a dura-
panies.
tion of four years, but the exact volumes
Let us mention one example. All the five and prices are fixed every three months. (The
members of the Junta Directiva of the new Economist, 27. 12. 1975, Special Survey,
company Lagoven had from 25 to 30 years p. 14.) The most important agreement is the
of experience from Creole (Exxon), and one with Exxon. It embraces 965 000 b/d,
they had all occupied prominent director of which two thirds is crude oil. In fact,
positions in that company (El Universal, very few details are known about these
19. 12. 1975). In fact, very few foreigners agreement, but there exist agreements with
had occupied such or other positions at the Shell, Gulf, Mobil, Texaco as well as with
time of the nationalization: only 37 out of a some smaller companies (PIW, 12. 1. 1976).
total of 6000 Shell employees, for instance, The agreements give the government a
were foreigners. (El Universal, 30. 12. 1975) right to reduce its sales to them by 10 %
(Compare Vernon, 1971, p. 149). each year after nationalization, starting in
Apart from the fact that the organizational 1977. But even if the efforts of PDV (the
structure, the personnel and thus supposedly state holding company) to find more in-
the ideology of the state-owned companies dependent customers seems successful so
appears identical with that of their respective far, it should be emphasized that the former
MNC predecessors, the oil monopolies have concessionaries are still responsible for
maintained even stronger tools to control marketing of three-quarters of the country's
and profit from oil activity in Venezuela oil export.
after it had officially been nationalized. I am
here referring to the agreements on tech- 4.2. Technological services contracts
nological service and the sales contracts PDV has established contracts for delivery
established. of technological services with the mother

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
68 Vegard Bye

companies of each of the former earlier con- new technology must be agreed upon se-
cessionaries. In reality, these contracts freeze parately. It is explicitly forbidden to make
the old 'feudal' pattern of the country's oil technology available for operators other
industry. Services offered by Exxon are than those who have taken over the conces-
made available for Lagoven only, Shell sions of each MNC. According to the agree-
services for Maraven, Gulf services for ments, the former concessionaries will take
Meneven, etc. The contracts have been kept part in the creation of research institutes,
totally secret, and the political institutions which means they will have free access to
have never had opportunity to discuss them. new technological innovations that might be
The major companies have established their made in the nationalized oil industry. These
own service companies in Venezuela to ful- contracts represent clear proof of the mon-
fil their commitments. As far as Exxon is opolies' successful strategy of guaranteeing
concerned, PIW wrote (12. 1. 76): their role in the nationalized oil sector.

In return for a fee, Exxon under its separate


Another aspect of the contracts is the
technical assistance agreement will provide a payment the MNC's receive for their serv-
'broad range of technical services' to Lagoven, the ices. As it concerns already-known tech-
state firm now operating in the nationalized assets nology, and as almost all the related costs
of Exxon's Creole. Exxon will 'lend' Lagoven up
- e. g. salaries - are paid additionally,
to 150 employees (who will work for Lagoven).
In addition, Exxon will base 35 employees in such payment can be considered almost a
Caracas in its new Exxon Services Caracas, headed net profit. It has also been considered an
by former Creole directors, to arrange services for extra hidden indemnification, over the four-
Lagoven which will be provided through the new
year period 1976-79 amounting to an ad-
Exxon Sevices Co. in Coral Gables, Florida. Exxon
ditional two thirds to the official indemnifi-
will also help Venezuela set up a 'petroleum
research capability'.
cation of 1 billion US dollars. (This calcula-
tion is based on information in PIW, 12. 1,
With the establishment of the new com- 1.3 and 12. 4. 76). Interestingly, the com-
pany, only three of the foreign-recruited panies themselves also consider this pay as
Creole-employees lost their jobs because of an additional indemnification (PIW, 2. 2.
the nationalization (International Herald 76), contrary to the government's own posi-
Tribune, 15. 11. 76). tion.
Despite the great secrecy surrounding the
contracts, some important details have 4.3. The MNC's influence on the nationaliza-
gradually been unveiled. The Leftist journal tion process
Proceso Politico has claimed to be in pos- Although the concessionaries were not
session of the texts of agreements, and has formally represented in the decision-making
described them in detail (Proceso Politico, process leading up to nationalization, they
no. 4-5, 1977, pp. 55-85). The 'Euro-Com- played a decisive role in formulating the
munist' party MAS claims to have unveiled structure of the nationalized oil sector. In
a contract between PDV and Shell (LAER, the first place, they were - through Fede-
vol. V No. 25, 1977). cdmaras - indirectly represented in the im-
What becomes clear from these agree- portant presidential commision, the legal
ments, which are also valid for 4 years, is proposal of which was accepted with one
that they only grant the national operating important exception (see later). But the
companies the right to use exactly the same most important channel of influence on the
technology as that used before nationaliza- part of the concessionaries was the direct,
tion, for exactly the same type of produc- secret negotiations that took place between
tion, in exactly the same volume as before. them and a high-level governmental com-
In may cases, this also embraces technology mission in parallel with the formal process.
originally created in Venezuela. Transfer of As early as in April 1974 - one month

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Nationalization of Oil in Venezuela 69

after the appointment of the presidential consequently found themselves defending a


commission - these negotiations started, position that three months earlier only had
with the governmental part represented by been held by the monopolies and the em-
the Minister of Mining and Hydrocarbons ployers' federation. All the opposition
and the future President and Vice-President parties, however, defended the original text
of PDV. Two of the participants were also proposed by the presidential commission,
members of the presidential commission.18 and set up a mammoth campaign against the
After the nationalization law was passed in government on this issue. In the end, of
August 1975, the same high-level commis- course, the President's proposal was made
sion and the concessionaries entered into law by the AD majority in Congress.
negotiations on three issues: (1) the amount In retrospect, however, this conflict
of the indemnifications, for which only very seems mostly symbolic. So far, there have
vague criteria were established in the law; been no signs that the opening for mixed
(2) the technological service contracts; and companies will be utilized. The sales and
(3) the sales agreements. There is no doubt services agreements would have been ac-
that these issues, plus the question of article ceptable also according to the original pro-
5 in the law (see below) were considered posal, and private participation in the petro-
together, and that a 'package solution' was chemical industry is not affected by this
agreed upon.19 law. Even so, however, this conflict was a
useful demonstration of important principle
The only issue that provoked discussions
contradictions in the party system, as well
- and indeed fundamental contradictions
within the party system - with relation to as of the functioning of the populist pact
and the MNC's influence on the decision-
the nationalization law, was article 5. In the
making process.
presidential commission's proposal, it was
clearly stated that no private entities were
allowed to take part in oil activity after the 5. The Fifth National Plan
nationalization. The establishment of mixed Venezuela's development strategy, based on
companies was explicitly rule out. The only the new economic and political situation
opposition to this article in the presidential created primarily by the enormous increase
commission came from the representative of in the country's incomes after the 1973-74
Fedecdmaras. It is worth noting that per- oil price hike and the nationalization of oil
sons belonging to AD were in majority in (and iron), is reflected in the Fifth National
the commission. In the period from De- Plan for the period 1976-80 (Gaceta Oficial
cember 1974 through March 1975, the No. 1.860 Extraordinario 1976). Here, we
government and the AD leadership were will only highlight the most outstanding
obviously put under strong pressure from aspects of the plan. For this purpose it may
Fedecdmaras and the concessionaries to be convenient to distinguish between four
change their position; a pressure that proved different development objectives inherent
successful. In March, President Perez sug- in it.
gested a change in the disputed article totally (1) There will be an enormous expansion in
in line with Fedecdmaras' proposition, thus the productive activity on the part of the
allowing private participation on certain state. As pointed out earlier, the state has
conditions. The suggested change was ac- played an important role in the Venezuelan
cepted by the AD party leadership - which economy from the very start of the oil
certainly had taken part in the formulation activity, but this role has by and large been
of it - and by all the representatives of limited to preparing the conditions for
different organizations and interests in the private capital. During the period 1970-74,
commission belonging to AD. Among those the state's share of gross investments was
were the trade union representatives, who 32 % (Banco Central de Venezuela, 1974),

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
70 Vegard Bye

whereas this percentage is meant to reach the same emphasis on social distribution,
an average of 53 % during the plan period because the domestic market will not be
(Gaceta Oficial op., cit., pp. 17-18). This as important as before. It comes as no sur-
means that the state sector now is to be prise that social expenditures now will be
leading in production activity. This impres- reduced, as President Perez himself declared
sion is particularly clear regarding sectors in a statement to the 23rd Annual Congress
like consumer durables, oil, and mining. of Fedecamaras:
(2) The expansion in public activity will be The Government has committed itself (...) to
concentrated to the export-oriented heavy reduce the increase in current expenditures from
industry. This strategy emerges from the 12 % over the last five years to 5.2 % over the
existence of the following three factors: coming five years. This means that 85,288 million
bolivares (almost $20 million - V.B.) will be
availability of cheap energy resources; vast
gained for capitalization, a part of which will be
deposits of natural resources like oil, iron
used to improve the financial activity of the state.
ore, and bauxite in the country itself or in (El Nacional,23.5.76, my translation).
neighbouring countries; and the enormous
financial capacity of the state. The infra- This probably means that social policy
structure built before nationalization is also expenditures will fall in relative terms: a
an important factor. Total public invest- fact which gives a good indication of how
the oil incomes will be used in Venezuela
ments planned for the period amount to
$28 billion, of which 57 % will go to oil, and whom they will serve.
mining, iron, steel and aluminium plus elec- (4) The distribution of labour between state
tricity (ibid, p. 20). The export of metal in- and private capital is fairly well spelled out
dustry products (aluminium and steel) will in the plan, and further specified in the
make up 29 % of the total value of industry President's second message to the Congress
export in 1980, up from 1.3 % in 1975. (Perez, 1976). For the sake of illustration,
Also the export of food and means of the main principles to be followed in the
transportation, especially private cars, will petrochemical industry may be referred to.
rise drastically. On the other hand, oil- and The industry is divided into three groups,
carbon-based products will fall in relative according to degree of processing. In the
share of industrial export from 80 % to category of low-degree processing, the state
40 % (ibid. p. 45-46). will in principle have monopoly, though
Altogether, it seems clear that a new ac- there is an opening for private participation
cumulation model is arising, based on an
of up to 20 % in exceptional cases. In the
export-oriented development of the heavy medium category, the maximum share of
industries under strong public sector domin- private participation is 49 %, whereas in
ance. the high-degree processing petrochemical
industry there are no limits whatsoever for
(3) The prevailing trend of the accumula-
private participation. About the same struc-
tion model of 1958-75 was import substitu-
ture is proposed for the iron and steel in-
tion. This required an extension of the
dustries. The primary function of private
domestic market, and thus a certain distribu-
- not least foreign - capital will be the
tion-oriented policy. In statistics, this was same in these sectors as in the oil sector: to
expressed through the fact that two thirds
guarantee technology and international
of the state expenditures were 'current ex- markets.
penditures' ('gastos corrientes' - as op-
posed to 'capital expenditures'), and that 6. The post-nationalization external struc-
almost the half of this was 'social policy ex- ture of dominance
penditures' (Proceso Politico, 2/76, pp. 25- To sum up the main effects of nationaliza-
26). The new accumulation model of the tion, we shall now return to the seven
Fifth Development Plan no longer requires indicators of external dominance used in

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Nationalization of Oil in Venezuela 71

section 2. It is of course too early for any quantitative test. We will also attempt to
final assessment of the effects of national- assess the total and long-term effect of oil
ization on the dominance structure. The bonanza, nationalization, and the new
intention of this exercise in comparison is development plan on the external domin-
only to see whether the premises of the ance structure in the Venezuelan social for-
different indicators have changed substanti- mation at large. Our conclusions are set
ally through nationalization. Accordingly, out below, in Tables I and II respectively.
it is a question of a qualitative rather than a

Table I. Effects of the oil nationalization on the structure of dependence in the


Venezuelan oil sector

Almost
Indicator abolished Reduced Constant Increased

Economic penetration x

Technological penetration x

Trade partner concentration x

Dependence on foreign trade x

Mono-production x

External exploitation Xl)


Enclave-structure x

1) This conclusion, meant to be valid for the first 4-5 years after nationalization, is
contrary to what government sources as well as the MNCs state, but they seem to
exclude several important aspects from their calculations. Over some years (5-10
years), it is probable that external exploitation in the nationalized sector will be
reduced.

Table II. Expected long-term effects of increased oil prices, oil nationalization, and
new development strategy on the structure of dependence in the Venezuelan social
formation.

Difficult to Increased
Indicator Reduced Constant determine

Economic penetration x

Technological penetration x

Trade partner concentration x

Dependence on foreign trade x

Mono-production x

External exploitation Xl)


Enclave-structure X2)

1) Contradictory tendencies make it difficult to determine total effect.


2) An economy consisting of various enclaves instead of one.

6.1. Economic penetration investments went to the oil sector. From the
Economic penetration in the country's dominating investor country, USA, only one
dominating sector was almost eliminated third of the investments were in the oil sec-
through nationalization: from 98 % to zero. tor (MMH, 1975, p. 18). Because of the
This is, of course, the most conspicuous diversification of foreign investments, then,
consequence of nationalization. But outside the global effect of nationalization on this
the oil sector, foreign capital will play an indicator is not as strong as it first might
increasing role in the Venezuelan economy; seem to be. During 1976 and 1977, the terms
by 1974, less than a half of total foreign of foreign investments have been substan-

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
72 Vegard Bye

tially liberalized, first through a revision of share of the oil outside the traditional chan-
the so-called Decision 24 in the Andean nels. This share is expected to reach 30 %
Pact (LAER, vol. IV (1976), No. 45), later in 1978, which opens possibilities of diver-
through unilateral liberalizations (LAER, sifying the markets. Several interesting ap-
vol. V (1977), No. 8). Another aspect of proaches have been made, and of special
economic penetration is foreign borrowing, interest is an agreement with Japanese trade
which because of the ambitious investment companies (PIW, 8. 3. 76). It seems prob-
objectives in the Fifth Plan will reach con- able, therefore, that nationalization may
siderable dimensions during the Fifth Plan facilitate diversification of the export mar-
period. The planned amount to be bor- kets for oil, which was clearly established
rowed is more than $ 4.5 billion (LAER, as an objective in the law.
vol. V, (1977), No. 5). This means that a As to the rest of the economy, it is im-
new form of economic penetration is possible to say anything definite about pros-
emerging in Venezuela. pects for trade partner diversification.

6.2. Technological penetration 6.4. Foreign trade dependence


Technological penetration in the oil sector Nationalization as such does not influence
seems more or less constant, despite nation- this indicator. The development model de-
alization. The national operation companies scribed, however, will definitely maintain
are more or less administratively identical and perhaps even increase dependence on
with their MNC predecessors, and the serv- foreign trade, as it is clearly based on out-
ice contracts indicate that the same 'feudal' ward-oriented growth. There are no objec-
dominance structure regarding operational tives like self-reliance to be traced in the
technology will be retained. Even if the Fifth Plan.
national units gradually will be able to run
routine activities without external assistance, 6.5. Mono-production
the centres for development of new tech- This indicator is, like the former, not di-
nology will still be in the MNCs. This is rectly influenced by nationalization. But the
particularly important, as it will be an ob- cut in production volume that occurred
jective to change the patterns of the coun- parallel with nationalization will probably
try's oil industry. reduce the relative importance of oil for
In the rest of the economy, the outward- export as well as for the economy in general.
oriented strategy of development will ab- The general development strategy, however,
sorb as much foreign technology as pos- will no doubt reduce the relative importance
sible, even though the national authorities of oil substantially, although this will con-
will certainly be aware of the new 'codes of tinue to be extremely high for a long period.
conduct' that Third World governments are We must not forget that it is oil which is
pressing for in their relation with MNCs. In to finance the development of the rest of
total, however, there is reason to believe the economy.
that technological penetration will increase.
6.6. External exploitation
6.3. Trade partner concentration The effect of nationalization on this im-
The sales contracts established between the portant indicator has been a disputed ques-
former concessionaries and the national oil tion. The MNCs say they lost on it (El
companies at first seemed to indicate that Nacional, 28. 7. 76, concerning the case of
the trade pattern would continue exactly Exxon), and the government says the coun-
the same as before nationalization. So far, try's income has increased (ibid., 2. 1. 77,
however, the national companies have been referring a speech by the President). These
quite successful in marketing a substantial two sources, thus, are in agreement. On the

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Nationalization of Oil in Venezuela 73

other hand, several economists in Venezuela ploitation is concerned, with the price hike
claim that the country has been getting as a positive factor, and foreign borrowing
lower incomes from the oil activity the first and increased foreign investments in non-
years after the nationalization. This is based oil sectors as negative ones. The total long-
on two kinds of calculations. In the first term effect is therefore difficult to foresee.
place, it seems that the fees the MNCs re-
ceive through the service contracts repre- 6.7. Enclave-structure
sent more money than the surplus value Although changing the pattern of refining is
they were taking out of the country (net desired, technological dependence stands in
profits minus re-investments) before na- the way. It should not be too difficult,
tionalization. Second, from the viewpoint though, to increase the export share of re-
'national oil income',20 the conclusion seems fined products, by full use of actual refinery
to be the same. Although the size of this capacity.
income increased substantially from 1975 The new industrial strategy will lead to
to 1976, the new investments that now have increased manufacture based on the coun-
to be made by the State (according to the try's raw materials, oil and iron. This devel-
Fifth Plan) are higher than this increase. On opment, howevers, will be extremely out-
the minus side, the indemnifications should ward-oriented, regarding both inputs and
also be added, particularly as the invest- outputs (imported technology, machinery
ments had been paid back in the form of and to a large extent capital; export of the
profits several times before the nationaliza- products). The total effect therefore would
tion. The total indemnifications amounted seem to be the creation of several enclaves
to 4,253 bill. bolivares (approximately 1 bil- in the Venezuelan economy instead of one,
lion US $). Most of it was to be paid over each being an extension of the world econ-
a period of five years, with an interest rate omy, without strong linkages within the
of 6 % p. a. (MMH, 1975, pp. 147-148). So country.
altogether, it seems that the state incomes To sum up the picture shown in Tables
will be considerably lower at least the first I and II, then, we can say that nationaliza-
years succeeding the nationalization than tion will reduce external dominance in the
they had been before.2' oil sector somewhat, but in no way elim-
As far as unequal exchange is concerned, inate it. In the Venezuela social formation
the nationalization as such had no effects. as a whole, the total effect of price increase,
The enormous improvement through the nationalization, and new development strat-
price hike, on the other side, is gradually egy can be expected to yield increased rather
being compensated through the price in- than reduced foreign dominance or depen-
crease on imported goods. With regard to dence. The two Tables should help illustrate
invisible foreign services other than service what is meant by the term redefinition of
fees and indemnifications, no immediate ef- the structure of dominance.
fects can be predicted; but in the long run,
there is reason to expect that the country 7. The new internal structure of dominance
gradually will increase its capacity to man- The effects of nationalization and related
age the services it now borrows from for- events on the internal structure of domin-
eign companies, like transport and security. ance were less conspicuous than were the
The quite extensive foreign borrowing, how- effects on the external structure. But even
ever, is a new form of foreign services, so, they were not necessarily less important.
which will lead to substantial foreign ex- Nationalization, at least in the form it took
ploitation in the form of interest payment. in Venezuela, was certainly a brilliant way
The tendencies in the economy at large of mediating the conflict within the cap-
are quite contradictory as far as foreign ex- italist state between accumulation and legit-

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
74 Vegard Bye

imacy. As far as accumulation is concerned, sensus must replace class struggle and anti-
it was evidently necessary for the state imperialism. The MNCs are now able to
bourgeoisie to come to an understanding execute social control over large parts of
with the MNCs to guarantee efficiency of the the working class formerly in objective and
nationalized industry. That explains the subjective contradiction to them; parts that
secret negotiations and the modification of therefore had had to be controlled by means
article 5. From an accumulation point of of force.
view, nationalization has doubtless been a
great success.22 In regard to legitimacy, per- 8. Conclusion
haps the main motive for nationalization, the If the history of imperialism can be very
effects are obvious. The anti-imperialist po- roughly divided into two phases, the first of
tential among the working class has been no them being the traditional colonial pattern
negligible factor in Venezuela, despite the and the second neo-colonialism character-
absence of strong leftist groups. It is evi- ized by import substitution and distorted
dent that the MNCs' almost total control of industrialization, one may say that the so-
the export sector of the national economy called New International Economic Order
would have been an extremely awkward will be the third phase. This implies that we
fact to live with on a long-term basis. The do not consider the NIEO any real confron-
unions had long demanded nationalization, tation with imperialism, and even less do we
and anti-imperialist demagogy had long been think that it represents any break with it.
a necessary ingredient in most political The question then arises: Why do the
campaigns in Venezuela, although mostly changes - from the first to the second
in the shape of nationalism. By nationaliz- phase and from the second to the third -
ing the oil industry, then, the political and come about? Are they, as some argue, a
economic system regained its national pride strategic goal of imperialism itself? We think
and could claim that the country's economy Samir Amin has given quite a good answer
had been brought under national control. to this question, as far as the first transition
At least for a while, anti-imperialist demands is concerned:
and sentiments seen to have been satisfied.
The system has secured its own legitimacy. The transition from the first to the second phase
The system that has secured its legitimacy of imperialism was not 'planned' by the monop-
olies: it was imposed by the national liberation
does not comprise only the state and the
movement through which the bourgeoisie of the
political apparatus, however. Even more peripheries won, against imperialism, the right to
important was nationalization as a legitimat- an industry (Amin, 1977, p. 12).
ing factor for the MNCs and their future
stake in the national economy, inside as Amin is probably also correct in suggest-
well as outside the oil sector. The MNCs ing that the MNCs did not deliberately
have succeeded in allying themselves directly create the new international division of
with the state bourgeoisie, whose hegemony labour that will be the result of the NIEO.
in the power bloc after the nationalization is It has been an objective outcome of the
beyond doubt. This in fact means that the international and dialectical development
populist pact has been co-opted into the of the forces and relations of production.
transnational economic system. One may This does not mean that the MNCs, the
speak of a populist pact in its second and principal agents of the two latest phases of
extended phase, comprising MNC-STATE- imperialism, have lost on the development
PARTIES-UNIONS. The argument of from one phase to the other. Neither does it
unions, government, and directors of na- mean that they have been unable to take a
tional oil companies is the same. Now that substantial part in the formulation of the
the oil is national property, national con- new 'orders'. In fact, the development of

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Nationalization of Oil in Venezuela 75

the oil sector of Venezuela shows that the limited to a national system of social con-
oil giants - the world's largest MNCs - trol, it has now been extended to an inter-
have had a decisive influence on the design national system of social control. One ef-
of 'economic nationalism'. This was the case fect of this may be a reduction in depen-
when the first change took place (the oil dence on physical violence for holding the
reforms of 1942/43 and 1945, see Tugwell, imperialist system together, although that
1975, p. 43), and not least as regards the eventually may create serious problems for
1976 nationalization discussed in this one of the cornerstones of this very system:
article. arms production. But the case of Venezuela,
Another conspicuous aspect is how suc- one of the most verbally militant defenders
cessful the MNCs have been in preparing of NIEO, clearly shows that social violence
will not be reduced. The victims of that vio-
themselves for the phase to follow, in order
to guarantee their future role. By a com- lence, however - in the case of Venezuela,
bination of leaving the operation of the the large majority of the population - are
subsidiaries to national staffs and increas- left outside all channels of political and
ing the technological dependence of the social mobilization: they are marginalized.
subsidiaries on the mother companies and Therefore, they cannot represent any threat
service companies - often owned by the to the system, at least not till the popular
same corporations - nationalization could groups now part of the pact with the state
be carried out without threatening the control
and the MNCs break out of that pact and
ally themselves with the poor. The national-
position of the MNCs. Their conglomerate
ization of oil was intended to rule out such
structure and vertical integration, which
secures virtual control of all levels from
a development. So far, it seems to have suc-
ceeded in doing so. The decisive question is
production, via refining and manufacturing
whether the immense public investments
to marketing, has been an important factor
will start to pay off early enough to avoid
in enabling the MNCs to maintain their
serious balance-of-payment deficits. Prob-
positions.
lems with the volumes and prices of Vene-
It is clear that the power relation between zuelan oil seemed to be getting worse in
the MNCs and the state has changed over first half of 1978; and if these tendencies
the 60 years of the Venezuelan oil economy. result in a serious accumulation crisis -
Up to 1935, the companies got 92 % of the with insufficient production of surplus
incomes produced in the industry, and the value to reproduce the system - this may
state only 8 %. The two last years prior to ultimately have political repercussions as
nationalization, the relation was a contrary well: a change in forms of control from
one: 94 % went to the state and 6 % to the social to physical, or the introduction of a
companies. This is a development the giants fascist or semi-fascist regime. This pattern
gradually - though not without resistance is too well known in Latin America to be
- have had to accept. But their control excluded as a possibility. However, the
position and future access to the oil re- breakdown of rule through bourgeois-demo-
sources have been secured, through the or- cratic institutions does not seem very likely
ganizational structure of the nationalized in Venezuela at the moment, precisely be-
oil sector. cause of the strength of the populist pact.
The really brilliant aspect of nationaliza-
tion - and maybe of the NIEO in gen- In concluding this article, let us point to
eral - is the way it co-opts economic na- the similarity of the conclusions drawn by
tionalism and even anti-imperialism into Norman Girvan (1976) in his study of eco-
imperialism itself. Whereas the populist pact nomic nationalism in the bauxite sector,
in the second phase of imperialism was especially in the Caribbean:

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
76 Vegard Bye

In effect, we are witnessing the development of Report on Venezuela (January 1978) says it is
rentier states attached to the international alu- 49 % excluding the throughput from Caribbean
minium industry and of 'appendage economies' refineries. The primary source for this information
based on these rentier states... The evidence so is not given.
far is that the governments have been attacking 6. Oil production in Venezuela reached a peak
not so much the system of corporate imperialism in 1970 with an average volume of 3.7 million
in the world aluminium industry as their own barrels a day. The volume produced in 1974 was
place within that system. What may in fact be 3.0 and in 1975, 2.3 million barrels a day.
taking place is ... the formation of a new alliance 7. Only two other oil countries, Libya and
between the corporate managers of the trans- Iraq, were more dependent on one export prod-
national aluminium companies and the buro-polit- uct, with 100 % and 96 % respectively (Hveem,
ical managers of the Caribbean bauxite-producing 1977, appendix B).
states. (pp. 154-155). 8. This figure is based on information about the
iron export in Financial Times Survey, 'Mining
Potential', 17. 11. 75.
Girvan's conclusion may also be made
9. One US dollar is about 4.3 bolivares. These
our own: that the real content of national-
figures also include profits and investments for the
ization is frequently a model of dependent state company (CVP) and a small private Vene-
growth, and its consequence a locking of the zuelan company, but their influence on the total
peripheral social formation into even deeper can for practical reasons be ignored.
10. Such figures are, of course, difficult to
dependence on external markets. In the determine. The figures quoted are based on the
case of Venezuela, there seem no traces price the concessionaries officially claimed for
whatsoever of any effort to avoid such a sales to their mother companies. With respect to
development. the years 1974 and 1975, these prices were conside-
rably lower than those set by the state. Basing it-
self on the state-fixed prices, the Banco Central de
NOTES Venezuela claims that total profits for all com-
1. That peripheral social formations for cen- panies in 1974 was 18,501 million bolfvares, which
turies have been incorporated into the world gives a totally different picture than the figure
capitalist system on the distribution level does not given in Table 1 of my original study for the
mean that capitalist relations of production have same year (2,286 million bolivares). (Banco Cen-
occurred there or even less been dominant all the tral de Venezuela, 1975). According to the BCV
time, as Frank (1966, p. 7) erroneously claims. figure, the transfer of surplus value in 1974 alone
For a good critique of this view, see dos Santos amounted to almost US $ 3,850 million.
(1970, pp. 139-50). 11. For a more accurate definition of this con-
2. Normally, not only fundamental material cept, see Samir Amin, 1974.
needs should be included in a definition of devel- 12. This calculation is based on information
opment, but also a dimension of identity (lack of from the following sources: MMH, 1966, p. 173;
alienation) or self-realization (see Galtung, 1975). 1972, p. 169; 1975, p. 143; Tugwell 1975, app.
3. This change of strategy was confirmed by a table D; Rodriguez Trujillo, 1976, page 15 table 3.
high-level spokesman of Fedecdmaras (the em- 13. Some authors, like Andre Gunder Frank
ployers' association), whom I interviewed in (1965) also include the direct transfer of surplus
Caracas, in May 1976. value in this concept.
4. The list of indicators is not meant to be 14. In this period, the Communist parties played
complete. It can rather be understood as an at- a very anti-militant role all over Latin America,
tempted systematization of available information. in order to fulfil Stalin's order of reduced con-
Cultural, political, and military dominance/depen- frontation with the ruling regimes. The Cuban
dence are excluded, because what is discussed here party took part in the first Batista government,
are principally the economic aspects. The class and in Nicaragua the party supported Somoza.
structure, also a part of the general structure of 15. Of course, it is not unproblematic to link
dominance, will be discussed in next section. It is this concept to Third World workers, as long as
obvious that several of these indicators are inter- Lenin used the concept to describe the fractions
related and that one of them may be an important of the working class and labour movement in
cause of the other, but such factors will not be colonial countries that went into an alliance with
discussed here. capitalists in their own countries in the exploita-
5. According to some sources, the US share of tion of the colonies. The important question of
the export is considerably higher. LAER, vol.V applying this concept to the relatively well-off
(1977), no. 5, suggests that the share is as high fractions of the Third World industrial working
as 70 %, whereas the same journal in its Special class has far too long been neglected. But as

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Nationalization of Oil in Venezuela 77

Hobsbawm (1973, pp. 125) points out, the source the oil at the same prices as the concessionaries
of the phenomenon is the superprofits of monop- earlier claimed they had received from their
oly which allow the capitalists 'to devote a part mother companies, i. e. abandoning the prices
(and not a small one at that!) to bribe their own fixed by the state. In the same category of pos-
workers, to create something like an alliance be- sible explanations come the charges from the
tween the workers of a given nation and their political party MAS, that Shell according to a
capitalists against other countries'. (Quoted from contract between that company and PDV had
Lenin's article 'Imperialism and the Split in got 49 cents a barrel in discounts on sales (LAER,
Socialism'). Most of this description is valid for vol. V, 1977 No. 25).
the case studied here, except for the constitution 22. All business-oriented analysts seem to agree
of the alliance. That an alliance between monop- on this - see e. g. the earlier referred Special
olies and the 'labour aristocracy' is being cre- Report on Venezuela published by LAER.
ated, is certainly true, and will be discussed later.
It is also important to emphasize that a labour
aristocracy cannot be defined only on the basis REFERENCES
of economic criteria. As Poulantzas (1973) cor- Acosta Hermoso, Eduardo, 1969-70. Andlisis
rectly points out, ideological criteria should also historico de la OPEC. (2 vols.) Caracas: Edito-
be taken into consideration, as has been stated rial Arte.
here. Amir, Samin, 1974. L'accumulation a l'echelle
16. This decree established a presidential com- mondiale. Paris: Editions Anthropes.
mission that should study how nationalization Amir, Samin, 1977. 'Self-reliance and the New
could be carried out. International Economic Order', Monthly Review
17. The intention has been gradually to merge vol. 29, No. 3, July/August 1977, pp. 1-21.
these 14 operation companies into 5 or 6 units. Banco Central de Venezuela, yearly. Informe
So far (March 1978), all the 14 units are still in economico. Caracas. BCV.
operation, but it was recently reported that Blank, David E., 1973. Politics in Venezuela.
Llanoven, CVP, Palmaven, and Roqueven are Boston: Little Brown & Co.
planned to be merged this year (Latin American Chevalier, Jean-Marie, 1973. Le nouvel enjeu
Special Report on Venezuela, supplement to petroiler. Paris: Edition Calman-Levy.
LAER, January 1978). Chossudovsky, Michel, 1975. Pobreza y marginal-
8. The existence of the high-level commission idad en Venezuela. Ottawa: University of
and the negotiations was admitted by the AD rep- Ottawa.
resentative in the presidential commission, Mr. Creole Peroleum Corporation, yearly: Data on
Armas, in the Chamber of Deputies 12. 6. 75, fol- Petroleum and Economy of Venezuela. Caracas:
lowing a series of accusations about this from the Creole Petroleum Corporation.
opposition parties. The constitution of the high- dos Santos, Theotonio, 1970. Dependencia y
level commission was given in Resumen, 21. 9. 75. cambio social. Santiago de Chile: CESO, Uni-
19. This was also confirmed by an advisor to versidad de Chile.
the 'high-level commission' whom I interviewed Duncan Powell, John, 1971. 'Venezuelan Agrarian
in Caracas, Spring 1976. Problems in Comparative Perspective', Com-
20. The national oil incomes before the na- parative Studies in Society and History, vol. 13,
tionalization were made up of taxes and royalties. pp. 282-300.
After the nationalization, it comprises government Frank, Andre Gunder, 1965. 'Invisible Foreign
incomes plus the profits of the operation com- Services or National Economic Development',
panies, of which 10 % is transferred to PDV. - also in A. G. Frank: Latin America: Under-
According to the Latin America Special Report development or Revolution? New York: Monthly
(supplement to LAER, January 1978), the per Review Press 1969.
barrel take for the nation rose from Bs. 33 in Frank, Andre Gunder, 1966. 'The Development of
1975 to Bs. 38.22 in 1976 and Bs. 41.75 in the Underdevelopment', also in A. G. Frank: Latin
first half of 1977. America: Underdevelopment or Revolution?
21. One should have expected the increase in New York: Monthly Review Press, 1969.
'national oil income' to have been much larger Gaceta Of icial de la Republica de Venezuela,
than it actually turned out to be, especially if the 11. 3. 1978, No. 1.860 Extraordinario.
National Bank's calculation of total profits to the Galtung, Johan, el. al., 1975. 'Measuring World
concessionaries the last year before nationalization Development. IL', Alternatives, vol. 1 No. 4.
(18,501 million Bs.) is correct. This calculation Girvan, Norman, 1976. Corporate Imperialism:
was based on the state-fixed prices. The main Conflict and Expropriation. White Plains, N. Y.:
reason for this small increase may have been, as M. E. Shape Inc.
Proceso Politico, op. cit., points out, that the state Hobsbawm, Eric J., 1973. Revolutionaries, Contem-
according to the sales contracts was forced to sell porary Essays, chapter 12, pp. 121-129: 'Lenin

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
78 Vegard Bye

and the Aristocracy of Labour'. New York: Social Classes. London: New Left Books.
Pantheon Books. Rangel, Domingo Alberto, 1970. Capital y desar-
Huizer, Gerrit, 1973. Peasant Rebellion in Latin rollo. II. El rey de petroleo. Caracas: Univer-
America. Penguin Books. sidad Central de Venezuela.
Hveem, Helge, 1977. The Political Economy of Rodriguez Trujillo, Manuel, 1976. 'Tendencia re-
Third World Producer Associations. Oslo: Nor- ciente de las importaciones en Venezuela', Re-
wegian Universities Press. sumen No. 144, 8. 8. 1976, pp. 14-18.
INVEPET, 1975 (Fundacion para la investiga- Silva Michelena, Hector, 1975. 'Proceso y crisis
ci6n en Hidrocarburos y Petroquimica), Dia- de la economia nacional 1960-1973', Nueva
gnostico sobre la transferencia technologica de Ciencia, vol. 1, No. 1, pp. 105-131.
la industria petrolera. Caracas. Tugwell, Franklin, 1975. The Politics of Oil in
Ministerio de Minas e Hidrocarburos (MMH) Venezuela. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
yearly. Petroleos y otros dates estadisticos. Vernon, Raymond, 1971. Sovereignty at Bay. Pen-
Caracas: Oficina de Estudios Economicos Ener- guin Books.
geticos del MMH.
NACLA (monthly). Latin America and Empire
Report. New York: North American Congress Newspapers and periodicals consulted:
on Latin America. El Nacional (Caracas daily)
O'Connor, James, 1973. The Fiscal Crisis of the El Universal (Caracas daily)
State. New York: St. Martin's Press. Latin America Economic Report (LAER)
Perez, Carlos Andres, 1976, Il mensaje al Con- (weekly news-magazine)
greso de la Republica. Caracas: Alocucion Pre- Latin America Political Report (LAPR) -
sidencial. (former Latin American weekly news-
Petras, Jamse & Morris Morley, 1976. 'The Vene- magazine)
zuelan Development "Model" and US Policy', Petroleum Intelligence Weckly (PIW)
Development and Change, No. 7, pp. 391-411. Proceso Politico (political journal edited in
The Hague: Institute of Social Studies. Caracas)
Poulantzas, Nicos, 1973. Political Power and Resumen (weekly magazine edited in Caracas)

INTERNATIONAI PROBLEMS
From the contents of issue No. 1, 1979

Peace Research Reassessed by M. Mushkat; Development Theories Re-


examined by Y. Reuveny; Motivations specifiques de la Politique d'lsrael
par M. Vardi; The US in the ME Talks by Ch. H. Lu; La Participation
d'lsrael Aux Activites Regionales de l'UNESCO par J. Beer-Gabel; On
O. Schachter's 'Sharing the World Resources' by M. Maneli; On Greig's
'The Communist Challenge to Africa' by B. Neuberger; On A. S. Whiting's
and R. F. Dernberger's 'China's Future Policy' by A. Shay.

International Problems is the journal of The Israeli Institute for the Study
of International Affairs (IISIA). It publishes articles in English, French and
Hebrew. Annual subscription is $25; Address: IISIA, P.O.B. 17027, Tel-
Aviv 61170, ISRAEL.

This content downloaded from 204.78.0.252 on Sat, 30 Jul 2016 16:38:22 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

Potrebbero piacerti anche