Sei sulla pagina 1di 7

American Economic Association

Property Rights, Protest, and the Siting of Hazardous Waste Facilities


Author(s): Robert Cameron Mitchell and Richard T. Carson
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 76, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Ninety-
Eighth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (May, 1986), pp. 285-290
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1818781 .
Accessed: 13/10/2011 11:36

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
American Economic Review.

http://www.jstor.org
SITING OF HAZARDOUS FACILITIESt

Property Rights, Protest, and the Siting


of Hazardous Waste Facilities

By ROBERT CAMERON MITCHELL AND RICHARD T. CARSON*

In 1980, the U.S. Environmental Protec- ing the siting of HWFs is an important cause
tion Agency estimated that between 50 and of the stalemate. We offer a new approach to
125 new sites for hazardous waste facilities siting which recognizes the de facto property
(HWFs)l would be needed in the near fu- rights assumed by local communities. We
ture. Since that time no major HWF has propose a political market, via a referendum
been sited anywhere in the United States. mechanism, for allocating HWFs. The refer-
The EPA had anticipated that local opposi- endum, supervised by the state, would be
tion would make finding these sites an "ex- held at the request of the firm wishing to site
ceptionally difficult task." Their pessimism the HWF with the developer, in effect, offer-
was well founded and, if anything, under- ing a comprehensive package of incentives
stated. According to the Hazardous Waste for the community in exchange for a yes
Counsultant's latest state-by-state review, the vote.
outlook for siting HWFs in the future is To understand the rationale for our ap-
"even more bleak" than in the past, due in proach, it is first necessary to examine the
large part to what they term a worsening of evolving nature of the property rights for
the "emotional atmosphere" surrounding sit- siting a HWF. The driving forces are chang-
ing efforts. This failure to site any new HWF ing perceptions of the risks associated with
has come about in spite of assurances by toxic waste disposal and a social movement
government and company officials that new of considerable power which has raised the
facilities built according to the present stan- cry of "not in my backyard." We show that
dards would pose negligible risks to the local rational citizens have much to gain by oppos-
residents. Attempts have been made to break ing the siting of new hazardous waste facili-
the deadlock by instituting extensive public ties near them. Their resistance, however,
participation procedures, establishing state imposes large costs on society as a whole,
siting boards with the power to overrule local since as quantities of toxic chemicals are
decision makers, and requiring facility owners being held in temporary and deteriorating
to compensate local governments for safety storage conditions as they await destruction,
services the latter provided. or a permanent home, strong incentives are
In this paper, we argue that the ambiguous created for illegal "midnight" dumping.
nature of the present property rights govern-
I. The Problem

tDiscussants: Allen V. Kneese, Resources for the Hazardous wastes are a by-product of the
Future; William D. Schulze, University of Colorado. chemical revolution that followed World War
*Senior Fellow, Resources for the Future, 1616 P II. Until recently, disposing of wastes was
Street, NW, Washington, D.C. 20036; and Assistant not considered to be a social problem and
Professor, Department of Economics, University of dumps with hazardous materials in them were
California, San Diego, La Jolla, CA 92093, respectively. treated by the public and planners as minor
We thank Peter Navarro, Susan Pharr, Paul Portney,
and Clifford Russell for helpful comments. extensions of their garbage dump and sani-
' These include waste treatment facilities, landfills, tary landfill cousins. Opposition, if any, was
and incinerators. based on their nuisance characteristics, not

285
286 A EA PAPERS A ND PROCEEDINGS MA Y 1986

% Accept
on perceived safety risks. The property rights 100
status quo was one in which the developer's
entitlement to engage in waste handling ac- 90 _- -

tivities was preeminent as long as the facility


80 10 storybuilding//
was located in an industrial area.
The passage of the Resource Conservation 80
-/
and Recovery Act (RCRA) by Congress in 70 - ,

1976 marked official recognition that these 70 / r


HWF ,
/ Coal plant
wastes, many of them disposed of improp- 60 /
60
Largefactory/I
erly in the past, posed a potentially serious
health threat. However, widespread public j ,/ //
awareness of possible danger to local com-
munities from this source did not take shape
until two years later when the problems at
40 /
Love Canal reached the national news media. 30 7 1/Nuclear plant
Congress passed the Superfund legislation in
1979 to clean up existing toxic waste dumps. 20

The entire town of Times Beach, Missouri,


was abandoned after finding dioxin con- 10
tamination in 1982, and news reports of con-
taminated drinking water wells have now O . I I I1 1> I
Less 1 5 10 25 50 100 101+ Don't
become commonplace. Proposed HWFs than
one
want
at any
quickly became the subject of widespread mile distance

protest despite the fact that they had to meet FIGURE 1. CUMULATIVE PERCENTAGE OF PEOPLE
the stringent federal design and operation WILLING TO ACCEPT NEW FACILITIES
safety standards imposed by RCRA and fur- AT VARIOUS DISTANCES FROM THEIR HOMiES
ther augmented by additional state regu-
lations. The Sand Canyon facility in Los
Angeles County illustrates this situation.
Four years of work and $1.5 million were
spent on a proposed comprehensive treat- siting in their neighborhood of undesirable
ment and land disposal facility before its facilities. What is new is the scale and in-
corporate owner withdrew the proposal in tensity of protests provoked by facilities per-
the face of seemingly insurmountable public ceived to be risky. The present high level of
opposition. In Texas, a regional authority risk averseness is illustrated in Figure 1 which
proposed a high temperature incinerator for shows the percentage of the public in a na-
toxic wastes from the area (a solution favored tional survey2 willing to accept (without pro-
by environmentalists). Despite a well-demon- testing or moving) each of five hypothetical
strated need for such a facility and initial facilities as a function of the distance of the
support from surrounding local govern- facility from their residence.
ments, citizen opposition caused the de- Three distinct "siting aversion profiles"
veloper to withdraw the proposal after a 3- emerge, with corresponding "backyards" and
year battle when it became apparent that protest constituencies. Reactions to a 10-story
political approval was not going to be office building represent a useful baseline.
forthcoming.

II. AversionProfiles

The NIMBY acronym (not-in-my-back- 2These data are from a survey conducted by Re-
sources for the Future (Mitchell, 1980). The general
yard) aptly captures the views of those who shape of the profiles has been found to be robust against
resist facility siting. The syndrome itself is alternative question wordings and the addition of other
not new-homeowners have long resisted the types of facilities.
VOL. 76 NO. 2 SITING OF HAZARDO US FA CILITIES 287

Over half say they would accept such an scientific uncertainties about the risks they
edifice if it were at least a mile from their pose to the public. At the local level, the
houses. Majority acceptance of either the siting issue appears as an abrupt threat that
industrial plant or the coal-fired electric involves a visible source (the site) for which
power plant, facilities that are likely to be clear responsibility can be ascribed (the de-
perceived as dirty and potentially obnoxious veloper)-characteristics that heighten pub-
neighbors, occurs at approximately 9 miles. lic awareness of the perceived risk. In con-
In contrast, the two facilities posing poten- trast to nuclear power plants or industrial
tially catastropic but extremely low probabil- plants, for which there is usually a local
ity risks, a nuclear power plant and a new, constituency, a HWF provides few benefits
well-regulated disposal site for hazardous such as jobs or tax revenues (A. D. Tarlock,
wastes, reach majority acceptance only at the 1984). Finally, residents may fear the decline
50-mile mark, a distance "premium" of 49 of local property values.
miles from our arbitrarily selected baseline. The degree of concern about the risk ex-
This suggests a crucial difference between the ternality posed by HWFs is strongly in-
siting of an ordinary industrial facility and a fluenced by the nature of the perceived risk.
HWF: the "neighbors" affected by the latter The risks posed by these facilities include
involve entire communities. Another differ- characteristics which have been shown in
ence is the number of people who feel other contexts to be strongly associated with
strongly about the issue. Whereas only 9 risk aversion (Paul Slovic et al., 1980). They
percent expressed the extreme view that they are perceived as: 1) involuntary (imposed on
did not want the two industrial facilities as the community without its consent); 2) lethal;
neighbors "at any distance," 29 percent ex- 3) memorable (due to being subject to arrest-
pressed such a view about the two "risky" ing media coverage); 4) not susceptible to
facilities. personal control; 5) persistent (having the
potential to effect future generations); and 6)
Ill. ProtestMobilization unfair (since most of the benefits accrue to
those living far beyond the geographic area
At the local level, the aversion to HWFs is subject to risk).
translated into active protest whenever new Two characteristics of siting controversies
facilities are proposed. Why do local resi- help lower mobilization costs. First, the local
dents protest? Mobilization is facilitated by: character of the controversy makes it easy to
1) the high cost perceived to be imposed on identify and communicate with potential
the local community by the HWF, 2) the low protesters. Geographic concentration also al-
cost of protesting, and 3) the high probabil- lows use of preexisting social networks and
ity of success. institutions (such as churches and neighbor-
First, HWFs are a prime example of a hood organizations) for leader and member
regulated entity whose costs and benefits are recruitment purposes. This reduces organiza-
so distributed that the former are con- tional costs and makes free riding easier to
centrated, while the latter are distributed, far manage through informal social control in
beyond the local area. The principal costs the form of pressure to participate. Second,
believed to be posed by HWF are the health public participation procedures used in many
risks posed by groundwater and soil con- siting processes, such as hearings, offer a
tamination in the case of landfills, and con- focal point both for organizing and for news
tamination of the air by cancer-causing sub- media coverage, and easy access to decision
stances in the case of incineration facilities. makers.
The high level of perceived risks may be For individual participants, the cost of
attributed both to the institutional context in mobilization involves time and money. This
which these risks occur and to the nature of includes time spent in activities such as re-
the risks themselves. cruitment, fund raising, and organizational
The news media have highlighted past maintenance, as well as time spent in protest
failures to handle toxic wastes properly and activities such as writing letters, working on
288 A EA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 1986

lawsuits, and organizing and attending ral- to "accommodate externalities associated


lies. The time commitments necessary for a with important changes in technology or
successful protest movement are lumpy: only market values" (1967, p. 350). Firms wishing
a relatively small number of activists need to to site a HWF lost their unfettered right to
commit substantial amounts of time to the locate where they wished as the public and
effort. For most participants, only occasional government officials became alarmed over
participation is necessary, because much is the possible risks posed by the technology.
demanded of only a few. Local residents have obtained increasing
The third factor affecting mobilization is ability to delay (and thus effectively block)
the perceived likelihood that the protest ac- siting efforts in adminstrative and judicial
tivity will benefit the participant. Some peo- hearings. Local communities have taken a
ple, usually highly committed activists, de- leading role in stopping the construction of
rive utility from the act of protest itself, new HWF through the use of their extensive
which confirms their values and sense of police powers to regulate zoning and safety
self-worth. The efficacy calculus for ordinary matters. With a few exceptions, however,
participants normally involves a belief that communities do not have the legal right to
their cause has some chance of achieving its ask for sizeable payments in exchange for
goals. Factors that contribute to a sense of issuing the necessary licenses and permits.
efficacy in siting protests include the wide- The recent establishment of state siting
spread support for the protest in the affected boards with the power to preempt local
community, the frequent sympathy or even governments represents an attempt to reas-
support for the protest on the part of local sert the former property right regime. The
elected officials, the availability of proven concurrent establishment of schemes for
tactics (ranging from sit-ins and demonstra- compensating communities for the presence
tions to lobbying and legal interventions), of a HWF represents a movement in the
expertise (from national organizations), and opposite direction-toward giving the prop-
arenas in which to contest and delay the erty right to the community. The innovative
siting (such as local hearings, the courts, and, Massachusetts' siting law (M. O'Hare et al.,
of particular importance, local zoning and 1983) has both features, going further in the
permiting processes). direction of bargaining for compensation and
less in the direction of preemption (calling
IV. EvolvingPropertyRights for binding arbitration only in the case of
irreconcilable differences) than any law in
Property rights specify how persons may the country. No facilities yet have been sited
benefit or be harmed and, therefore, who under this law, suggesting that compensation
must pay whom to modify the actions taken without ultimate local veto power over a
by affected parties. In a now famous article facility may not be a successful strategy. But
(1960), Ronald Coase argued that the assign- if local residents were individually to hold
ment of property rights to one party or the property right, developers could not
another did not, in the absence of transac- bargain efficiently with the large number of
tions cost, affect economic efficiency, al- potentially affected residents and one holdout
though it did affect the distribution of wealth. could block a well-conceived project.
Coase's insight was a deep one: resources
would be put to their most efficient use re- V. CommunityPropertyRights:A Proposal
gardless of how the political system initially
chose to allocate property rights. The prob- One possible solution is to recognize a
lem with the hazardous waste situation is collective property right by having states pass
that currently no one really has clear title to a law specifying the use of referenda to de-
site a HWF-not the firm, not the commun- termine local approval or rejection of a pro-
ity, and not the residents as individuals. posed HWF facility. Such a law would re-
Harold Demsetz correctly saw that prop- quire the relevant political authorities to hold
erty rights were subject to change over time a referendum when requested by a qualified
VOL. 76 NO. 2 SITING OF HAZARDOUS FACILITIES 289

developer meeting state requirements. The minister and enforce and contract estab-
terms of the arrangement would be proposed lished by the referendum? This would un-
by the developer and incorporated into the doubtedly fall to the local political authori-
ballot proposal. Both the developer and the ties first, and ultimately to the state. Doubts
state, to the extent that it desired the siting, about enforcement would only increase the
would have strong incentives to develop win- payments required to pass the referendum.
ning proposals. Developers obviously would There must be sufficient administrative flexi-
aim at selecting potential sites where voters bility to respond to new EPA regulations and
would be more likely to agree to the least to technological change. How should the
expensive package of measures designed to boundaries defining who should be allowed
compensate a community for accepting the to vote on the proposal be defined? This is
HWF. Designing the package and promoting an admittedly difficult political question
it would necessarily involve the equivalent of which the state legislature would have to
a public participation program. Naturally the decide.
costs of the package would be passed on to Assigning the right to refuse a risk exter-
enterprises that wished to use the facility. In nality to those who claim it, and exercising
order for such a proposal to be viable, there coercion only to the extent of requiring them
would have to be enough technically accept- to vote on legitimate offers to compensate
able sites available so that the political market them for accepting the risk, has several de-
could be sustained, and no single community sirable properties in this case. The developer
would have a siting monopoly. and the state have strong incentives to ad-
A large number of possible compensatory dress the issues of most concern to the com-
measures have been suggested in recent years. munity, and the state's role is more con-
The contents of a developer's particular sistent with its interest in the outcome. The
package could vary according to the nature community's incentive to be intransigent is
of the facility, the characteristics of the site, minimized because it has the power to say
and the community's concerns. The types of no. The community is presumably protected
measures which might be included are: from unwittingly accepting too great a risk
guarantees against property value declines, because the facility would have to meet strict
incentive payments to the community (which federal and state safety regulations. More-
could be earmarked to reduce property taxes over, the debate occasioned by the refer-
or for other purposes), outside monitoring,3 endum should ensure close scrutiny of the
accident insurance, credible guarantees of developer's proposal. Paying for the com-
nonabandonment, donation of land for use pensation package transforms the hitherto
as parks, and in-kind services such as free concentrated costs on the local community
waste disposal for community residents and into more equitably shared burdens that are
businesses. borne by the ultimate beneficiaries of the
Should the decision rule be a simple facility. Finally, to the extent that this in-
majority, or something larger, such as the creases the costs of handling hazardous
often used two-thirds majority? Although a wastes, those who produce the wastes will
two-thirds majority requires a more expen- have an incentive to engage in in-plant
sive package, we argue that it is more likely waste-stream modifications and resource re-
to result in a Pareto-improving outcome and covery.
greater community harmony. Who would ad-
REFERENCES

31f the developer or government is not trusted by the Coase, R. H., "The Problem of Social Cost,"
community to monitor the facility, the cost of a winning Journal of Law and Economics, October
compensation package may be drastically increased.
Monitoring by an outside agent, such as an environmen-
1960, 3, 1-44.
tal organization, might reduce the cost of the package's Demsetz, H., "Toward a Theory of Property
other elements. Rights," American Economic Review Pro-
290 A EA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MA Y 1986

ceedings, May 1967, 57, 347-59. Plenum, 1980.


Mitchell, R. C., Public Opinionon Environmen- Tarlock, A. D., "Siting New or Expanded
tal Issues: Results of a National Public Treatment, Storage, or Disposal Facilities:
Opinion Survey, Washington: Council on The Pigs in the Parlors of the 1980s,"
Environmental Quality, 1980. Natural Resources Lawyer, September
O'Hare,M., Bacow,L. and Sanderson,D., Facil- 1984, 17, 429-61.
ity Siting and Public Opposition,New York: HazardousWaste Consultant,"The Outlook for
Van Nostrand Reinhold, 1983. Commercial Hazardous Waste Manage-
Slovic, P., Fischhoff, B. and Lichtenstein,S., ment Facilities: A Nationwide Perspec-
"Facts versus Fears: Understanding Per- tive," March/April 1985, 4, 1-49.
ceived Risk," in R. C. Schwing and W. A. U.S. EnvironmentalProtection Agency, "Haz-
Albers, Jr., eds., Societal Risk Assessment: ardous Waste Facility Siting: A Criticial
How Safe is Safe Enough, New York: Problem," Washington: USEPA, 1980.

Potrebbero piacerti anche