Sei sulla pagina 1di 8

Chapter 2.

3
PRICING AND TRADING IN METALS AND MINERALS
SIMON D . STRAUSS

2.3.1 INTRODUCTION
In any feasibility study for a metals or minerals project, an
assumption must be made as to the prices at which the project’s
products can be sold. This is a difficult assignment. Prices of
many mineral commodities are volatile, reflecting unpredictable
shifts in the balance between supply and demand. Moreover,
with some exceptions, the significant balance is that prevailing
in the world market rather than any national market—for most
mineral commodities are subject to a high degree of international
trade.
Thus the mining engineer involved in the development of a
mineral deposit needs to understand the pricing of the minerals
that deposit will produce. Above all, he/she needs to recognize
the perils involved in forecasting mineral prices. Even the most
experienced and sophisticated observer of mineral markets is
likely to err in predicting the future course of prices. This is true
even though his/her studies have taken into account what appear
to be all relevant factors. Fig. 2.3.1. London Metal Exchange prices for copper, 1970-1985,
Moreover, in projects involving mineral deposits previously expressed in pounds sterling and US dollar equivalents (Strauss,
1986).
unexploited, the forecast of prices must cover an extended pe-
riod. Typically, a “greenfields” project requires several years
for mine development, construction of production facilities, and price of copper in 1938 is measured to have been 23.7¢/1b, not
provision of necessary infrastructure of transport and power l0¢/lb. And the price of copper in 1988 is measured to have
supply. Following project completion, the price forecast will been 33.6¢/1b, not $l.l9/lb. In other words, by restating the
cover the years necessary to recoup the original investment and prices in terms of a constant deflator, the change in the copper
provide an adequate return. For most projects, this means that price over this 50-year period was not a gain of 1l00%, but
the forecast will cover a period of 10 to 20 years. rather 42%.
The yardsticks by which prices are measured are vastly dif- The mining engineer who is making a feasibility study of a
ferent from the yardsticks with which engineers are familiar in mineral project obviously cannot be expected to study the broad
the measurement of production, metallurgical efficiency, or labor economic picture. Therefore, his projection of price will be based
productivity. Engineers are used to working with yardsticks that on what the economists call “money of the day.” If he is prepar-
are constant—measurements of weight in pounds or kilograms; ing his analysis in, say, the year 1992, his forecast of prices can
measurements of distance in feet or meters; measurements of appropriately be stated on the basis of 1992 dollars. If future
time in seconds, minutes, hours, or days. Recovery of mineral economic trends significantly alter the value of the dollar, the
content can be measured in percentages. presumption must be that roughly corresponding changes will
The yardsticks for prices are in terms of monetary currencies. occur in the prices of mineral commodities—although this may
The value of a given currency unit tends to change. Thus if the take time.
current price of a given mineral is the exact monetary equivalent An additional difficulty in forecasting prices is that the cur-
of the price of that mineral 10 years earlier, it nevertheless has rency of any given nation may lose or gain value at a different
almost certainly changed. Due to the shifting tides of economic rate than the currencies of other nations. This has been particu-
fortune, a given amount in dollars and cents today may be worth larly true since the early 1970s, when the system of fixed ex-
more or less than it was 10 years earlier. It will be worth more change rates instituted by the International Monetary Fund at
than 10 years ago if the economy has suffered deflation; it will the end of World War II gave way to a new era of floating
be worth less than 10 years ago if the economy has suffered exchange rates.
inflation. During the 20th century, with the exception of the For most mineral commodities, the currency standard in the
severe depression of the thirties, the general trend worldwide has 20th century became the US dollar, as it was for many years
been inflationary. the accepted denominator of international trading values. Thus
To provide a specific illustration of the shifting value of prices stated in US dollars are the usual measuring stick for
currency units in relation to a mineral commodity, consider the such significant minerals and metals as gold, copper, aluminum,
price of copper in 1988 in the United States—it averaged $1.19/ nickel, zinc, lead, silver, tungsten, iron ore, sulfur, phosphates,
lb ($2.62/kg). Fifty years earlier, in 1938, the average price potash, and talc, to name just a few.
of copper was l0¢/lb (22¢/kg). Thus copper appears to have But due to the change in the value of other leading currencies
increased in price nearly twelvefold in 50 years. However, if in relation to the dollar, it has frequently happened that a rise
these two prices are adjusted to allow for inflation, the compari- in the price of a commodity in terms of dollars may equate to a
son between them yields a very different picture. A common tool loss in the price of that commodity in terms of a different cur-
for making such adjustments is the US consumer price index. rency, say Japanese yen or German marks. See Fig. 2.3.1, espe-
Taking this so-called CPI with the year 1967 equalling 100, the cially after 1980, for an example of this. To further illustrate,

81
82 MINING ENGINEERING HANDBOOK
between February 1985 and March 1987, the price of gold rose The four broad procedures are
from $299/oz ($10.55/g) to $409/oz ($14.43/g), a gain of 37%. 1. Prices established by a producing seller, who periodically
But during those 25 months, the value of the dollar fell in relation announces the terms and conditions, as well as the prices, at
to other major currencies. In terms of Japanese yen, the price of which he/she will make sales. These are called producer prices.
gold declined by 21%, and in terms of German marks, it fell by 2. Prices announced periodically by an independent agency,
24%. often a trade periodical, that makes regular surveys among both
How then can one describe the gold market during those 25 buyers and sellers to ascertain the basis at which actual transac-
months. Was the price rising? Most US citizens would say so. tions have taken place.
Was the price falling? That would be the verdict of the Japanese 3. Prices negotiated directly between seller and buyer. Fre-
or the Germans. quently, but not always, the result is contracts extending over a
The key point is that on any given day, however, the price of period of several years with provision for price adjustment under
gold in the United States, Japan, or Germany was approximately agreed conditions.
equal—given the high value of the commodity, the ease with 4. Prices established on futures markets or commodity ex-
which it can be transported, and the absence of import duties. changes. These facilities, open to all to trade, provide auctions
For other bulkier commodities, there may at times be significant by open outcry, comparable with securities exchanges.
differences in prices prevailing in particular markets. And where For some commodities, the determination of price in some
there are substantial barriers such as tariffs, quotas, or other markets is by one procedure and in other markets by other
limiting factors, on occasion a wide gap may exist between the procedures. For example, for many years in the United States,
price in one national market as distinct from other countries. the price of lead was based on method 1. The major US and
However, with the increased trend toward freer trade and the Canadian sellers, the chief suppliers of lead in the United States,
continued improvement in transportation facilities, such isolated periodically announced the price at which they would market
instances of large price differentials are becoming increasingly their product. However, in the European market, the price of
rare. One contributing factor to maintenance of fairly uniform lead has long been customarily based on the quotation of the
pricing throughout the trading world at any given time is the London Metal Exchange. In some of the developing countries
information explosion resulting from widespread use of comput- of Asia and Latin America, sales of lead are frequently the
ers, fax machines, international telephone communications, and result of method 3, negotiation between buyer and seller. In
a vigilant trade press. Moreover, a substantial share of the such negotiations, due attention is always given to the prevailing
world’s mineral trade is carried on by international dealers or prices in the United States and Europe.
brokers who have a keen sense of market developments and Some transactions take place in which two or more of the
hence will focus on sales in strong markets in preference to those pricing methods play a role in a single transaction. Typical of
where demand is lagging. these are the sale of copper, lead, zinc, or nickel concentrates by
a producing mine to a so-called custom smelter, a processing
facility which secures part or all of its feed from independent
2.3.2 HOW ARE MINERAL PRICES DETERMINED? mines. Method 3 (direct negotiation between the miner and the
custom smelter) is universally followed to set the treatment
The methods by which mineral prices are established differ charges involved. These are characteristically stated in terms of
widely. Unique patterns have evolved over the years in which an amount per ton of concentrate delivered, modified by credits
minerals have been traded. Since there are literally hundreds for byproduct elements that are recovered and penalties for im-
of distinct mineral commodities being bought and sold, it is purities. However, payment for the recoverable metal contained
impracticable to attempt in this presentation to describe the is based on a price determined either by methods 1, 2, or 4. For
prevailing procedures for each—or even for the 30 or so most example, lead content may be paid on the smelter’s selling price
widely used minerals in terms of volume or value. for lead (method l), a periodical’s published price for lead
Instead, an attempt is made to describe some of the more (method 2), or the London Metal Exchange price for lead
widely used methods of arriving at price. (method 4). Usually, these are the average price for the month
In general, minerals are sold on the basis of weight, varying in which the concentrate has been delivered to the smelter or for
from carats for gem stones, ounces for precious metals, pounds the month following delivery.
or kilograms for the more valuable base metals, and on to tons Perceived advantages and disadvantages of each method of
(be they short, metric, or long) for less valuable metals, ores, and pricing will influence both sellers and buyers as to which they
most of the industrial minerals. In some cases the price is stated select. Method 4 (trading on a commodity exchange) has not
on the basis of the metal content of certain ores rather than gross been found practicable for most mineral commodities even
weight—thus, for example, tungsten is sold on the basis of units though it has become a highly acceptable price determinant for
of tungsten contained in wolframite or scheelite concentrates. several key metals and has long dominated the field of pricing
For any given mineral, market transactions can occur at of leading agricultural commodities.
several stages of production. Thus there is a market for bauxite In the following, we discuss the salient characteristics of
(the usual source of aluminum), for alumina (an intermediate each of the four methods.
product), and for aluminum. Prices are quoted for each of these
three products and the trends are not necessarily the same. At 2.3.2.1 Producer Prices
times, aluminum metal may have been in short supply, but there
may have been an abundance of bauxite. In establishing a producer price, the seller takes into account
One can identify at least four principal methods by which his cost of production, his potential markets, the position of his
the minerals industries arrive at their selling prices. There is competition, and the possibilities of increasing his market share.
considerable difference of opinion among producers, consumers, The competitive factor must always weigh heavily on his deci-
traders, and public officials as to which is the best procedure. sions.
All express a desire to arrive at prices that are fair and reasonable Historically, there have been two instances of a mineral
and promote stability, yet they differ profoundly in their ap- monopoly, a single significant seller in the world market. One
proaches. was the Chilean nitrate of soda industry prior to World War I,
PRICING AND TRADING IN METALS AND MINERALS 83
and the other was the Greenland cryolite industry prior to World low value and problems of establishing uniform quality stan-
War II. In a sense, these two industries were in a position to dards.
name their own prices without considering competitive factors. Minor metals present a contrast: they have fairly high unit
Eventually, however, the very existence of this seemingly unlim- value but limited volume. Many are byproducts recovered in
ited power sparked successful efforts to develop synthetic prod- processing base-metal ores, for example, bismuth, cadmium, co-
ucts that proved to be acceptable substitutes, and the apparent balt, germanium, indium, tellurium, and selenium. Antimony
monopoly ended. and mercury are two exceptions in that much of their production
Although monopolies are rare, in the mineral field there is derived from deposits in which they constitute the chief ele-
have been numerous instances of what economists call oligopo- ment of value. A problem arises in that output of the byproduct
lies. These are markets dominated by a small number of powerful metals depends on the demand for the major base metals,
sellers. As examples of oligopolies, one might cite the aluminum, whereas demand for byproduct metals does not necessarily coin-
molybdenum, and nickel markets. As late as the middle of the cide with demand for major metals. Hence markets for byprod-
20th century, these markets were examples of producer pricing. uct metals are at times subject to substantial excesses or short-
In the case of aluminum, a handful of companies accounted falls-with drastic effect on price. This price volatility would
for the bulk of world production through the 1960s, notably appear to encourage listing on commodity exchanges, but the
Alcoa, Alcan, Alusuisse, Kaiser, Pechiney, and Reynolds. In prospective trading volume is too small to interest the exchanges.
molybdenum, the dominant seller was Climax, subsequently Producer pricing is not feasible for the two traditional pre-
merged into the company now known as Amax. In nickel, the cious metals, gold and silver. Therefore, they have historically
largest seller by far was Inco (formerly International Nickel Co.). had prices established by other procedures. Huge supplies of
The pricing policies of these companies appeared to be de- gold and silver mined in the past exist as bullion, coins, jewelry,
signed for stability (in contrast with the volatile price behavior and works of art. These holdings dwarf the current newly mined
of such base metals as copper, lead, and zinc) at levels that would product and exercise a dominant role in price determination.
encourage maximum expansion of consumption. Indeed, in the Because supplies of platinum group metals arise chiefly from
third quarter of the century, the consumption of aluminum in- two sources—the Soviet Union and South Africa—in the past,
creased at an average rate of 8% compounded annually, while producer pricing arrangements have existed, yet increasingly the
consumption of nickel and molybdenum both rose by about 6% markets are being influenced by commodity exchange trading.
compounded annually. These figures are for world consumption.
Expanding use of these metals was due to intensive research 2.3.2.2 Independent Pricing Determination
and promotion efforts by the dominant companies, as well as to
the stable price structure. Since success attracts attention and Responding perhaps to consumer concerns over being sub-
imitation, in the long run what happened was that other corpora- ject to prices unilaterally determined by producers, in many
tions were encouraged to enter the aluminum, molybdenum, and minerals pricing is sometimes based on quotations as determined
by a source that is neither seller nor buyer. In many but not all
nickel industries. Intensive exploration discovered previously un-
cases, this may be a trade periodical, such as Metals Week or
known deposits in many areas (including byproduct resources
American Metal Market in the United States or Metal Bulletin
of molybdenum in many copper deposits), financing was ar-
in Great Britain.
ranged, and new producers were launched.
The prices quoted in these periodicals are based on can-
With more sellers competing in the marketplace, gradually
vassing producers, consumers, and merchants dealing in the
the ability of the previous major firms to control price was
specific commodity to determine the prices at which actual trans-
eroded. Stability of price gave way gradually to volatile behavior. actions have taken place at specific dates. The publication then
By the 1980s, the prices of aluminum, nickel, and molybdenum reports these prices as averages for a given day, week, or month.
rose and fell in response to market conditions much as had long Not infrequently, contracts are made between producer-sellers
been the case with other metals. and consumer-buyers providing that the actual price for a given
Producer pricing has coexisted with prices established on tonnage of metal or mineral will be the price as reported in the
commodity exchanges in the case of copper, zinc, and lead. publication. Sometimes a seller will give buyers the option of
Producers of these metals have attempted to lessen the extreme paying either the seller’s price or the periodical’s average price,
swings in price on the exchanges at times in an effort to prevent with the option to be decided in advance.
a perceived threat of substitution by competing materials. When, In addition to the trade press, other independent arbiters of
as has happened, a material discrepancy has developed between price exist. One of the best known is the Handy & Harman daily
the producer price and the exchange price, difficult market dis- silver quotation. Handy & Harman is a US silver refiner and
tortions have resulted. Increasingly the trend has been away fabricator, based in New York, that buys silver from producers
from the producer price and toward the exchange-denominated and sells fabricated silver products to ultimate consumers. Each
price. day, having determined the quantity of silver it requires to meet
Two important categories of mineral commodities—the in- that day’s sales commitments, Handy & Harman solicits bids
dustrial minerals and the so-called minor metals—tend to be from principal silver sellers to supply a matching amount of
sold either on the basis of producer prices or prices as determined metal. Its price represents the clearing price at which it can
by trade periodicals or other independent sources. Recent price obtain the amount it requires.
histories of representative nonmetallic minerals appear in Table In London, a somewhat similar procedure is undertaken
2.3.1. daily by the leading London bullion dealers to match inquiries
Major industrial minerals tend to be bulk materials of rela- from gold and silver buyers with offers from gold and silver
tively low unit value. They include sulfur, potash, phosphate sellers. Representatives of the firms meet at noon to review offers
rock, barite, gypsum, salt, fluorspar, diatomaceous earth, talc, and bids received from worldwide sources. The consequence is
and asbestos. An appreciable portion of their cost to the user is announced as the official “fixing” for each of the two metals.
absorbed in transportation costs from mine to market. Keen Much of the world’s commerce in the two metals is based on this
competition prevails in these commodities, but they are consid- daily announcement, although since the mid-1970s, attention is
ered unsuitable for listing on commodity exchanges because of also paid to prices as announced in Zurich, Tokyo, Singapore,
84 MINING ENGINEERING HANDBOOK
Table 2.3.1. US Prices for Nonmetallic Minerals, 1973–1985
US Gross National Phosphate
Product Deflator Price Barite, Boron, Diatomite, Gypsum, Rock, Salt, Sulfur,
Year Index = 100 $ $ $ $ $ $ $
1973 49.5 16.66 88.18 65.04 4.60 6.24 6.82 17.56
1974 54.0 16.77 108.03 83.77 4.86 12.10 7.87 28.42
1975 59.3 17.70 115.74 88.18 5.04 25.35 9.85 44.91
1976 63.1 25.63 121.25 95.90 5.51 21.26 8.62 45.72
1977 67.3 22.33 130.07 109.13 6.12 17.39 9.85 44.38
1978 72.2 22.71 141.09 122.36 6.87 18.56 11.13 45.17
1979 78.6 28.08 184.08 138.89 7.53 20.04 11.03 55.75
1980 85.7 32.39 186.28 160.94 9.18 22.78 16.15 89.06
1981 94.0 39.64 205.03 180.78 9.40 26.63 15.17 111.48
1982 100.0 41. 53 221.56 194.00 9.33 25.52 15.31 108.27
1983 103.8 42.69 221.56 203.93 8.68 23.97 14.80 87.24
1984 108.1 36.19 229.28 212.74 8.75 23.99 15.19 94.31
1985 111.7 30.86 229.28 230.38 9.15 23.50 15.43 104.68
Change
1973-85 +125.7% +85.2% +160.0% +254.1% +98.8% +176.6% 126.3% +486.1%
Source: US Bureau of Mines 1986 for prices. GNP Deflator Index as reported by American Bureau of Metal Statistics.
All prices are in $US per ton material, f.o.b. shipping point.

and other bullion-trading centers, as well as to the prices prevail- costs change drastically. The seller has to recognize that if he
ing on the New York Commodity Exchange. makes excessive price demands, the buyer will look for alterna-
In the case of tungsten, two independent sources of price tive sources. Therefore, possible competition influences the sell-
determination have been established. Metal Bulletin in London er’s negotiation stance.
has long been the source of quotations for tungsten content of Concentrates of such base metals as copper, lead, zinc, and
scheelite and wolframite concentrates, the form in which most nickel are normally sold through long-term contracts negotiated
of the world’s tungsten production is traded. In addition, as a between a miner and a smelter—or perhaps by a miner and an
consequence of meetings arranged under United Nations aus- intervening trading firm that then sells to a smelter. In such
pices, a so-called International Tungsten Indicator price is calcu- negotiations, the discussions center about the processing charges
lated, based on details of tonnages sold and prices paid provided for smelting and/or refining of the concentrates. A separate
by both buyers and sellers, stated in price per unit (1%) of matter is the determination of the value of the recoverable metal
tungsten content (in US dollars). content. This is calculated either on the basis of published prices
in trade periodicals or on official quotations from the commodity
2.3.2.3 Negotiated Prices exchanges. The payment for the concentrates is the consequence
of deducting the processing charges from the calculated value of
In many transactions, the applicable price paid for a metal the recoverable metals.
or mineral is the consequence of direct negotiation between buyer Buyer-seller negotiations also frequently determine the price
and seller, rather than the use of a price previously established paid in transactions involving nonmetallic industrial minerals—
by the seller or previously published by an independent agency. for example, chemical companies purchasing sulfur or other
The use of negotiated prices is particularly common in the case materials required in fertilizers and similar products. Major con-
of long-term contracts covering the supply of raw materials to a struction projects are also likely to negotiate on a long-term basis
processing facility. for cement, building stone, and other required minerals.
Thus, for example, a mine supplying iron ore to a steel mill
or one supplying chrome or manganese ores to a ferroalloying
2.3.2.4 Commodity-Exchange Pricing
plant will typically negotiate the price of its product with the
consumer. Because the material involved is bulky and because Prices of a few important nonferrous metals are either deter-
transportation arrangements must be worked out on the basis of mined on or largely influenced by transactions on commodity
a regular schedule, it suits both the buyer and the seller to exchanges, the two most widely known being the London Metal
commit themselves to a long-term arrangement. Exchange and the New York Commodity Exchange. There are
The contract specifies the quality of the product to be deliv- other exchanges in operation that trade in metals, but these two
ered: the seller can only offer material of the particular character- are the ones most frequently referred to in the metals trade. The
istics contained in the deposit it is exploiting. The buyer needs number of metals listed for trading in London and New York
to be certain that his processing facility will receive raw material changes from time to time. When this chapter was written, Lon-
it can handle efficiently. There is thus a community of interest don was trading in aluminum, copper, lead, nickel, tin, and zinc.
between the two. New York was trading in aluminum, copper, gold, and silver.
In the price negotiation, each party is cognizant of the other’s On the New York Mercantile Exchange, platinum and palladium
requirements. The buyer knows that if the price involved is were being traded.
inadequate to insure continued operation by the mine, he may Some description of exchange trading is essential for an
lose a suitable supply of raw material for his plant. To guard understanding of the role played. Essentially, such trading repre-
against adverse consequences of major inflationary trends on his sents an auction at which contracts for a given commodity are
supplier’s operating costs, as a rule he will agree to a provision offered for sale during prescribed hours of each business day.
for price escalation in the event labor, fuel, supply, or transport Trading on an exchange is open to anyone with an appropriate
PRICING AND TRADING IN METALS AND MINERALS 85
credit rating, but the actual transaction must be conducted
through a firm or individual that is a member of the particular
exchange.
Exchange contracts specify a standard quantity of the com-
modity being traded. For example, the London copper contract
is for 25 t (metric tons); the New York copper contract is for
25,000 lb. The quality of the metal that constitutes acceptable
delivery under an exchange contract is carefully specified.
Brands that are produced by known refiners must be approved
for listing by the exchange before they can be traded.
Offerings made on the exchange floor are for delivery at a
specific time. London contracts are traded for the prompt or
“cash” position, requiring immediate delivery or for future deliv-
ery on a specified date. New York contracts specify the month
of delivery.
Under exchange contracts, the seller may deliver any accept-
able brand he chooses at any warehouse site approved by the Fig. 2.3. 2. Average prices for aluminum and copper, 1970- 1985,
exchange. This latter option is of great significance since the stated in pounds sterling per ton (Strauss, 1986).
London exchange has approved warehouses not only in Britain
but also at major ports throughout the European continent and
even in Singapore. The New York exchange has approved ware-
houses scattered throughout the continental United States. of space limitations, however, a brief summary is all that is
If the buyer takes delivery at a warehouse location that is offered here.
inconvenient for him, or if the brand tendered is not one that he The key to the trend of prices on commodity exchanges is
normally consumes in his plant, as a rule he can arrange to the perceived balance between supply and demand. If supply
make an exchange for a more suitable warehouse site or a more exceeds demand, inventories will rise and prices will fall. If
desirable brand through the member firms, but this may involve demand exceeds supply, inventories will fall and prices will rise.
paying a premium identified as “exchange for physical.” The trend of production costs does not immediately affect prices
However, in the vast majority of exchange transactions, on an exchange.
physical delivery is not made. Instead, the buyer of a contract It is different with a producer price. Costs are an important
may sell or the seller of a contract may buy back the quantities price determinant. Thus after making an expensive wage settle-
involved in the original transaction prior to the effective date of ment, a producer will try to increase its price. By contrast,
the contract. What then is the purpose of the transaction? Simply when a wage settlement is reached, no matter how costly, the
to establish a known price to cover the seller’s output or the commodity-exchange price of the product will tend to fall be-
buyer’s raw-material costs. cause the market perceives that the risk of a strike and a reduc-
As an illustration, assume a secondary copper smelter buys tion in supply has been averted.
scrap material to be delivered to its plant in 30 days. After As an example, before aluminum had been listed for trading
delivery, an additional 45 days may be required for processing. on the London Metal Exchange, the producer price of aluminum
The price of copper may rise or fall substantially between the was increased in 1975—even though at the time there was a
date of the original purchase and the date, 75 days forward, serious economic slump under way. The rationale was that an
when metal is available for sale. By selling an equivalent amount expensive wage contract had just been concluded. After trading
of copper on the exchange the day the scrap material is pur- started on the London Metal Exchange during the recession of
chased, for delivery 90 days forward, the secondary smelter has the early 1980s, the price of aluminum fell sharply—despite
fixed the price it will receive based on the position of the market further wage increases (Fig. 2.3.2).
at the time it bought its raw material. When the recovered metal Producer prices are still quoted for some metals traded on
is available, it is sold to a consumer based on the then prevailing commodity exchanges, but their significance has diminished.
price and the outstanding exchange contract is bought back. Many producers of the metals traded in London and New York
These two latter transactions offset each other, so the net out- believe that the volatility of prices is increased by the exchange
come is based on the original exchange sale even though no mechanism. Yet they are reconciled to living with the prices
delivery is made on the exchange. quoted on the exchanges and have modified their former market-
In addition to the large volume of exchange transactions ing strategies to take the exchange prices into account.
based on this type of hedging, there are also trades made by
speculators who believe they can realize capital gains through
2.3.3 EFFORTS TO STABILIZE PRICES
purchasing when a rise in price is probable or through selling
when a fall in price seems imminent. Speculators are not actually Volatile mineral prices create problems for producers, con-
involved in the metals business. They are as apt to trade in sumers, and governments. Ore has been defined as mineralized
orange juice or hog bellies as they are in aluminum or gold. rock that can be profitably extracted. At a given price a deposit
They too have no interest in holding supplies of metal per se. may be profitable; at a lower price it will not be. Therefore a
Therefore, in the great majority of instances, they either liquidate mine operator’s estimate of ore reserves is dependent on price
their positions prior to maturity or, alternatively, liquidate and the very existence of his enterprise can be threatened by a
nearby positions and roll the contracts forward to more distant sharp fall in price.
dates. Consumers who produce products containing minerals need
Obviously, much more could be spelled out in regard to to establish their own selling prices. Frequent changes in those
exchange transactions—volumes have been written in regard to prices are resented by the buying public. Hence consumers de-
their operations (see the bibliography for some sources). Because plore constant fluctuation in the cost of essential raw materials-
86 MINING ENGINEERING HANDBOOK
particularly those raw materials that constitute a large part of to levels far below the floor price, and the Council’s inability to
their total costs. meet its obligations resulted in staggering losses of hundreds
Governments—particularly governments of developing of millions of pounds to lenders and London Metal Exchange
countries that depend on mineral exports for a large share of member firms. The banks had loaned funds and the traders had
their foreign-currency revenues and of their tax incomes—find assumed that the member governments would stand behind the
it hard to plan their budgets in the face of widely fluctuating Council’s obligations. They did not. Litigation resulted that con-
mineral prices. tinued until 1990, when settlements were made that mitigated a
Not surprisingly, therefore, repeated efforts have been made fraction of the losses.
to stabilize mineral prices. Sometimes these efforts are made by The tin agreement was undertaken in good faith by member
private-sector producers of minerals; sometimes they are made governments that operated with the best of intentions. It worked
by governments through commodity agreements. With few ex- for a while, but eventually ran afoul of the market because good
ceptions, these efforts have ultimately been unsuccessful because intentions are not enough. Consuming countries, wanting to help
market forces have proved more powerful than the most ingen- the producing nations that were for the most part poor countries
iously contrived stabilization schemes. with limited resources, had been persuaded to agree to unrealistic
Perhaps the most extensive and longest lasting of the formal floor prices based on the costs of production at the most marginal
inter-government stabilization arrangements was that under- mines. Once the target was set too high, trouble was inevitable
taken, beginning in 1956, by the International Tin Council. Al- in the long run.
though the number of member governments varied from time to There have been discussions of intergovernmental price sta-
time, during most of the three decades of ITC operation, there bilization arrangements for several other minerals—copper,
were over 20 tin-consuming and 6 or 7 tin-producing countries bauxite, manganese, tungsten, and iron ore to name a few—but
formally allied with this undertaking. none have gone beyond the talking phase. The collapse of the
The stated objectives of the ITC were to avoid persistent tin agreement has reduced the interest in similar schemes.
disequilibrium between production and consumption of tin and Of course, history has been replete with efforts to stabilize
the accumulation of burdensome stocks, to stabilize employment prices through private arrangements. Under existing anti-
in the tin producing and consuming countries, to maintain steady monopoly legislation in many industrialized countries, such ef-
export revenues for the producing countries, and to minimize forts would today be illegal.
price fluctuations. One exception that perhaps proves the rule is in the field of
Producing and consuming country members shared equally gemstones. A high proportion of the world’s supply of diamonds
in decisions, but on major issues a two-thirds majority was re- is marketed by a group called the Central Selling Organization
quired, ensuring that approved measures were acceptable to (CSO), controlled by De Beers, a prominent South African
some members from both groups. Individual members had vo- diamond-mining firm. With its affiliates, De Beers today ac-
ting rights proportional to their production or consumption. counts for perhaps somewhat less than one-half of world produc-
The Council set both floor and ceiling prices for tin, with tion of gem and industrial diamonds. A large part of the balance
the objective of keeping the actual price in the trading zone of the production is bought by the CSO for classification and
between floor and ceiling. These prices were subject to periodic subsequent resale.
reviews and the underlying agreement was itself renewed every De Beers is well financed, able to hold substantial invento-
five years. ries, and prepared to adjust its own production as demand fluctu-
The mechanism by which the Council undertook to keep the ates. Competitive producers have come to recognize that to mar-
price within its desired trading range involved buffer stocks, ket diamonds in competition with De Beers could lead to sharp
financed by contributions from the producing-country members, price declines that, in turn, would destroy the attraction that
and export quotas to be invoked if demand and prices were weak. diamonds possess as long-term investments. They have therefore
Some consumer countries eventually made voluntary contribu- been willing to dispose of their output through the Central Sell-
tions to the buffer-stock fund, thus increasing available re- ing Organization. A case in point is provided by the major
sources. Australian diamond deposits developed by firms independent of
The buffer stock was operated by a manager who was in- De Beers in the early 1980s. Originally, the operators planned
structed to buy tin in the open market if prices dropped toward to do their own selling but before actual production began, they
the stipulated floor and to sell tin if prices rose toward the ceiling. agreed to sell all gemstones and 75% of industrial stones through
The initial funds raised when the Council began operations were the De Beers mechanism.
equivalent to about 25,000 tons (22,700 t) of tin, about one-sixth At the time this is written, the diamond market is firmly
of the then current rate of world production. under CSO control with prices stable—although not inflexible.
During the 29 years of its existence, the floor and ceiling Public confidence in diamonds as investment has been main-
prices inexorably moved higher, reflecting worldwide inflation tained. Revenues realized by developing countries from their
trends. In this period of time, the floor price was never lowered; diamond exports have been stabilized. Nevertheless, in the
the tin-agreement mechanism worked like a jack that steadily United States, the cartel is considered illegal, but efforts to insti-
ratcheted the price upward. There were two consequences— tute legal proceedings have been unavailing since neither De
one was that production of tin by nonmember countries was Beers nor CSO maintains offices within the United States.
encouraged; the other was that consumption of tin was discour- The nonmetallic minerals have been less subject to severe
aged. World tin consumption in the 1980s was roughly at the price volatility than the metals. As previously commented, they
same level as in the 1950s, whereas consumption of all other are not traded on commodity exchanges and hence are rarely the
base metals had increased sharply. target of speculators. Furthermore, the nature of consumption of
By 1985, the buffer stock manager had not only exhausted all nonmetallics is different from that of the metals: demand tends
the funds available from member contributions, he had borrowed to be steadier and less subject to short-term cyclical economic
heavily using the buffer stock as a collateral to buy still more trends. Because most of them sell at low prices in relation to
metal. In the lackluster economic situation then prevailing, sup- bulk, the threat of substitution by competitive materials is much
ply exceeded demand, and stocks continued to build. In October, less pronounced. Indeed, for most of the industrial minerals, the
operations of the stock were suspended, the price of tin collapsed level of world consumption has shown steady but not spectacular
PRICING AND TRADING IN METALS AND MINERALS 87
gains in line with population trends and overall industrial activ- their domestic iron-ore resources, but the best of these deposits
ity. Hence forecasts of nonmetallic mineral prices can be made have been long since depleted. Today these countries are huge
with greater confidence than is the case with the metals. importers of ore. The United States was at one time a net exporter
of iron ore, thanks to the resources of its Mesabi Range, but
since World War II has become a major importer.
2.3.4 SOURCES OF PRICING INFORMATION Among the market economy countries, the largest iron-ore
Mining engineers need reliable information about prices. For producers in the last three decades have been Brazil and Austra-
current prices, the best sources are the three publications already lia. Although they have substantial domestic iron and steel indus-
mentioned, Metals Week and American Metal Market in the tries, the bulk of their output is exported. Since they are located
United States and Metal Bulletin in Great Britain. Commodity at considerable distances from their potential customers, they
exchange quotations are available on a daily basis in the Wall have developed superb port loading facilities served by huge
Street Journal in the United States and the Financial Times in bulk-carrying freighters to transport their ores to the major con-
Britain and also in some metropolitan dailies, but these publica- suming centers.
tions carry only limited information about prices of minerals not For many of the mineral-exporting countries, a major thrust
traded on commodity exchanges. has been to encourage the development of domestic processing
Other professional and trade publications carry price infor- facilities. Thus, rather than export copper concentrates, the pref-
mation (e.g., Engineering and Mining Journal, Skillings Mining erence has been to develop domestic smelting and refining facili-
Review), but it tends to be less current than the data appearing ties so that exports will be in the form of refined copper or
in the five periodicals mentioned. even, perhaps, fabricated copper products. The economics of
When long-term historical pricing data are needed for feasi- downstream processing are complex; considerations such as
bility studies or basic understanding of macro-economic trends, availability of fuel, skilled labor, and transport facilities between
useful tabulations can be found in the yearbooks published by mines and processing plants may result in costs that exceed the
the US Bureau of Mines, the American Bureau of Metal Statis- charges offered by foreign processors—particularly if the initial
tics, and a private German organization, Metallgesellschaft of capital cost of building a new facility is high.
Frankfurt A.M. The latter is particularly helpful if data are A further complication has been the fact that the raw-
desired for prices within some of the principal consuming coun- material importing country may be encouraging its domestic
tries stated in terms of local currencies. processors through high duties on refined product and no duties
The World Bureau of Metal Statistics publishes excellent on raw material imports. Thus a considerable share of the world
information on production, consumption, and trade in metals, trade in minerals remains in the form of raw materials rather
but its yearbook does not contain tabulation of prices. However, than semi-finished or refined products.
it has perhaps more data on production and trade in minerals Nevertheless, the long-term trend has been toward an in-
between the market-economy countries and the nations of the crease in processing in the country where the minerals originate.
Communist bloc than any other source. Much of the production This has been particularly true for ferroalloying materials. Prior
information is perforce based on informed estimates since official to World War II, most of the trade in manganese and chrome was
statistics have not been provided by many of the governments of represented by ores. By the 1970s, a major share of international
the Communist bloc. commerce in these two elements was in ferromanganese and
Further discussion of the marketing and sale of minerals is ferrochrome. Indeed, one of the principal manganese export-
contained in Chapter 25.5. ers—India—prohibited the export of ore at one time and permit-
ted only export of ferromanganese.
Although much of the international minerals trade is carried
2.3.5 TRADING IN MINERALS on through direct contracts between the minerals producer and
the minerals consumer, a very large share—perhaps an increas-
As commented in the opening paragraph of this chapter,
most minerals are subject to a high degree of international trade. ing share—is carried on through the intermediation of trading
This is the consequence of the erratic distribution of viable min- firms. These enterprises, headquartered in Tokyo, London, New
eral deposits around the globe. For example, among the com- York, Frankfurt, Brussels, Zug (Switzerland), Helsinki, Paris,
modities that have highly concentrated production, one might or other metropolitan centers, maintain offices or agencies in all
cite platinum-group metals (primarily produced in the Soviet of the principal producing and consuming centers. They deal
Union and South Africa), cobalt (Zaire, Zambia, and Canada), in a whole range of minerals and are familiar with customer
columbium (Brazil), phosphate rock (United States, Soviet requirements of quality and physical characteristics. They under-
Union, and Morocco), and asbestos (Soviet Union, Canada, and stand the mechanics of dealing in foreign exchange and of com-
Zimbabwe). modity exchange trading. The key to their success lies in their
Even in the case of minerals that are somewhat more widely access to information about both production and consumption
distributed—such as tin, nickel, bauxite, and copper—the extent developments.
of international trade is huge because much of the production is Following the break-up of the colonial empires and the
concentrated in countries that are not large consumers while granting of independence to most of the developing nations,
much of the consumption takes place in countries that have public-sector companies have taken over the operation of many
limited production potential. Western Europe and Japan are mineral properties previously owned by private foreign investors.
examples of the latter. Highly industrialized, they have only The governments involved have taken an active interest in the
meager viable mineral resources and must depend on import marketing of the mineral products. This has introduced a new
sources to provide the mineral raw materials they require. element into minerals trading because on occasion foreign-policy
Particularly illustrative of the extent of international trade or social considerations have replaced strictly commercial fac-
in minerals is the position in iron ore. Deposits of iron ore are tors in determining where and how minerals are to be sold.
to be found in every country, but the quality and quantity of In the long run, however, market forces will predominate in
these resources vary enormously. Great Britain, Germany, and determining what will happen to mineral prices and where the
Japan in their early stages of industrial development exploited bulk of mineral trading will occur.
88 MINING ENGINEERING HANDBOOK
Manners, G., 1971, The Changing World Market for Iron Ore, 1950-
BIBLIOGRAPHY 1980: An Economic Geography, Johns Hopkins University Press,
Baltimore.
Anon., 1985, “The London Metal Exchange,” The Economist, Econo- Slade, M.E., 1988, Pricing of Metals, Queen’s University Centre for
mist Intelligence Unit, London. Resource Studies, Kingston, ON, Canada.
Adams, F.G., and Klein, S.A., 1978, Stabilizing World Commodity Mar- Strauss, S.D., 1986, Trouble in the Third Kingdom: The Minerals Indus-
kets: Analysis, Practice and Policy, Heath, Lexington, MA. try in Transition, Mining Journal Books, London.
Fox, W., 1974, Tin: The Working of a Commodity Agreement, Mining Tarring, L.H., and Cordero, H.G., eds., 1958, In a Metal Merchant’s
Journal Books, London. Office, 2nd ed., Quin, London.
Gibson-Jarvie, R., 1976, The London Metal Exchange: A Commodity Thewles, R.J., Harlow, C.V., and Stone, H.L., 1977, Commodity Future’s
Market, Woodhead-Faulkner, Cambridge, UK. Game: Who Wins? Who Loses? Why?, McGraw-Hill, New York.
Knoerr, A., ed., 1985, MineraI Facts and Problems, US Bureau of Mines, Vogely, W.A., and Risser, E.H., eds., 1976, Economics of the Mineral
Washington, DC. Industries, 3rd ed., AIME, New York.

Potrebbero piacerti anche