Sei sulla pagina 1di 10

ARTICLE IN PRESS

Energy Policy 38 (2010) 3384–3393

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Energy Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/enpol

Estimates of GHG emission reduction potential by country, sector, and cost


Keigo Akimoto n, Fuminori Sano, Takashi Homma, Junichiro Oda, Miyuki Nagashima, Masanobu Kii
Research Institute of Innovative Technology for the Earth (RITE), Kyoto, Japan

a r t i c l e in f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: In this study, emission reduction potentials in greenhouse gases (GHG) are assessed by country, sector,
Received 1 September 2009 and cost using a GHG emission reduction assessment model with high resolutions with respect to
Accepted 4 February 2010 region and technology and high consistency in terms of assumptions, interrelationships, and solution
Available online 2 March 2010
principles. Model analyses show that large potential reductions can be achieved at low cost in
Keywords: developing countries and power sectors. In addition, cost-efficient emission reductions were evaluated
Climate change for some international emission reduction targets that have been derived on the basis of the principle of
Emission reduction cost common but differentiated responsibilities among developed and developing countries. If (1) emission
Sectoral approach reduction measures at negative costs and below 50 $/tCO2 for developed countries, (2) intensity
improvement measures for selected sectors at negative costs and below 20 $/tCO2 for major developing
countries, and (3) all emission reduction measures with negative costs for other developing countries in
2020 are adopted, then emission reductions of 8.9, 14.8, and 27.7 GtCO2 eq./yr compared to the
technology-frozen case can be expected in developed countries, major developing countries, and
globally, corresponding to a 11% decrease, 40% increase, and 17% increase from 2005 levels,
respectively. Large-scale emission reductions can be achieved even if CO2-intensity targets for major
sectors are assumed for major developing countries.
& 2010 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction approaches in determining reduction targets for national emis-


sions and presents practical, flexible emission reduction targets
Climate change is a very serious global issue that needs to be for developing countries, including intensity improvement targets
addressed, and large emission reductions are required for by sector. Environmental issues such as climate change must be
sustainable development. However, it is difficult to implement considered globally, but these issues must be acted on locally.
measures for effective reductions that involve all the countries. However, on the international level, we must identify the amount
The Kyoto Protocol was internationally adopted in 1997, and and cost of reduction associated with different measures accord-
according to this protocol, national emission reductions are ing to countries and sectors. Moreover, this identification must be
mandatory only for developed countries. Three of the five largest based on the principles of equity and effectiveness. The obtained
greenhouse gas (GHG) emitters in the world, however, do not information will then help in formulating appropriate interna-
participate in or are exempt from binding emission reduction tional policy measures and allow appropriate emission reduction
targets under the protocol, and global emissions have increased measures to be implemented globally.
drastically since 1997. Cost-effective measures for emission The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC))
reduction need to be explored, particularly to achieve large summarized estimates of emission reduction potentials by cost,
emission reductions. In practice, it is important to determine region, and sector. These estimates were obtained by both top-
emission reduction capabilities by country, sector, and cost in down and bottom-up modeling. The summary of bottom-up
order to determine emission reduction targets and policy studies states that the reduction potentials in 2030 are 5–7, 9–17,
measures at the international level and achieve large emission 13–26, and 16–31 GtCO2 eq./yr at costs of below 0, 20, 50, and
reductions. 100 US$/tCO2 eq., respectively (IPCC, 2007). Large emission
The Japanese government proposed that a sectoral approach reduction potentials at low costs are estimated for non-OECD
would be effective for reducing GHG emissions, on both national countries and the building sector. However, uniformity across
and international levels (e.g., see The Japanese government, sectors is not guaranteed because the emission reduction
2008). The proposal incorporates sector-based or bottom-up potentials for different sectors are estimated by different model-
ing teams and are probably based on different assumptions.
Enkvist et al. (2007) estimated the global cost of GHG emission
n
Corresponding author. Tel.: + 81 774 75 2304; fax: +81 774 75 2317. reduction potentials by adopting a bottom-up approach. Hanaoka
E-mail address: aki@rite.or.jp (K. Akimoto). et al. (2008) also assessed emission reduction potentials by cost,

0301-4215/$ - see front matter & 2010 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2010.02.012
ARTICLE IN PRESS
K. Akimoto et al. / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 3384–3393 3385

region, and sector by bottom-up modeling. (Amann et al., 2008; 2.2. Key assumptions
IIASA, 2009) used a similar approach to assess reduction
potentials. The population estimates of the United Nations (UN, 2006) are
These approaches essentially evaluate emission reduction used to predict the population scenario. The global population in
potentials separately for each sector. However, the energy 2020 is estimated to be 7.7 billion. The gross domestic product
systems are related across sectors, countries, and points in time. (GDP) growth rates of the world and the GDPs of major countries
The emission reduction activities in different sectors, countries, were estimated by the Japan Economics Research Center for the
and points of time affect each other. Therefore, cost-effective Mid-term Target Exploratory Council of the Japanese Government
emission reduction measures or emission reduction potentials in December 2008. The average annual rates of GDP growth from
across sectors, countries, and time points must be explored 2005 to 2020 are 1.9% for the United States, 1.9% for the EU27,
simultaneously under common assumptions by taking into 1.3% for Japan, 5.0% for Russia, 8.2% for China, 7.2% for India, and
account the interrelationships among them. The results of 3.0% for the whole world.
previous studies cannot be applied for satisfactorily evaluating Population and GDP are not directly used to assume conditions
the sectoral emission reduction potentials for different countries for the energy model but to assume the amount of production or
with consistency. In this study, highly consistent analyses of extent of service activity in individual sectors. The amount of
emission reduction potentials and reduction costs across coun- production or extent of service activity is consistently satisfied by
tries, sectors, and points of time are carried out using a systematic the optimal combination of various bottom-up technologies for
model in which interrelationships are appropriately considered individual sectors that are explicitly modeled. For other sectors,
under common assumptions. baseline amounts of final energy demands are assumed together
with their long-term price elasticities using top-down modeling
without explicitly describing bottom-up technologies.
The historical emissions of total of six kinds of GHGs for Annex
I and non-Annex I countries are based on GHG inventories of
2. Assessment framework
UNFCCC (2009) and IEA Statistics (IEA, 2007), respectively.
Energy-related CO2 emissions are based on IEA Statistics for all
2.1. Overview countries. Whereas the statistical data on energy-related CO2
emissions obtained from the UNFCCC inventory differ from those
To estimate GHG emissions reduction potentials and the obtained from the IEA inventory for some countries. Non-CO2
associated costs, the following assessment framework has GHG emissions for Annex I countries are defined by subtracting
been developed for bottom-up modeling. The model consists the energy-related CO2 emissions given by IEA (2007) and the
of three modules: (1) the key assessment model DNE21+ for energy-unrelated CO2 emissions given by UNFCCC (2009) from
energy-related CO2 emission, (2) an emission scenario for energy- the total GHG emissions given by UNFCCC, in order to meet the
unrelated CO2 in which it is assumed that specific energy- total of six kinds of GHG emissions given by UNFCCC for Annex I
unrelated CO2 emissions are independent of emission reduction countries. Thus, priority is given in ensuring consistency between
levels achieved in energy-related CO2 emissions, and (3) the non- the total GHG emissions and the UNFCCC inventory.
CO2 GHG assessment model for reducing the five types of GHG
emissions outlined in the Kyoto Protocol. However, CO2 emissions
caused by land use, land use change, and forestry (LULUCF) are 2.3. Energy-related CO2 assessment model
not evaluated in this study. Fig. 1 shows an overview of our
assessment framework (see a paper by RITE (2009) for further The DNE21+ model (Akimoto et al., 2008; Oda et al., 2007)
details.). consistently represents energy systems (e.g., energy flows,

DNE21+ Model Energy - unrelated CO 2 Non - CO2 GHG


Emissions Scenario Assessment Model

•Assessment model for •Projection module for •Assessment model for


energy-related CO2 non-energy CO2 the 5 non-CO 2 GHG
emissions emissions emissions (CH 4, N2O,
• 54 regions in the • 54 regions in the HFCs, PFC, SF 6)
world world • 18 regions in the
• Bottom-up modeling • Estimations of world (allocated to the
(200-300 specific sectoral non-energy 54 regions, based on
technologies are CO2 emissions to be the historical data )
modeled) consistent with GDP •The methodology is
and production similar to the USEPA
activities assessment

Estimates of the 6 GHG emissions, emission reduction costs


and potentials, and specific cost-effective measures for
emission reductions

Note: LULUCF is excluded for the estimates.

Fig. 1. Overview of assessment framework. Note: LULUCF is excluded for the estimates.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
3386 K. Akimoto et al. / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 3384–3393

capacities of energy-related facilities, and performances and costs technologies will induce their investment costs; however, this
of various technologies) in which the worldwide costs are to be model assumes their future costs independent of the cumulative
minimized, with the amounts of production activity (e.g., the installation. Although this is also one of the weaknesses of this
production amounts of crude, steel, and cement), the amounts of estimation, the target year of this estimation is the year of 2020
service activity (e.g., the traffic amount in the transportation that remain only about 10 years and the drastic cost changes will
sector), and the final energy demands in other top-down sectors be limited. Implications from the model analysis results should
being met by the best combination of technologies. When any accordingly and prudentially be drawn by recognizing such
emission restriction (e.g., an upper limit of emissions, emission limitations.
reduction targets, targets of energy or emission-specific unit The energy supply sectors are closely related to the energy
improvements, or carbon taxes) is applied, the model specifies the end-use sectors, including energy export/import, and the lifetimes
energy systems whose costs are minimized and still meet all the of facilities are taken into account so that assessments are made
assumed requirements. The salient features of the model include while maintaining complete consistency across the energy
(1) analysis of regional differences with fine regional segregation systems. In this study, intertemporal optimization is carried out
while maintaining common assumptions and interrelationships, for the period between 2000 and 2030. The world is divided into
(2) a detailed evaluation of global warming measures by modeling 54 regions to consider differences such as those in economic
around 300 specific technologies that can be used to counter growth, industrial structure, current energy efficiency by sector,
global warming, and (3) explicit considerations on facility and availability of fossil and renewable energy resources.
transition for the specific technologies over the entire time period.
The model can be used to perform cost minimization assuming
perfect knowledge of the future, without taking into account the
decision making under uncertainties such as factors related to 2.3.1. Technology considerations
energy price volatility. In addition, the lead time is not taken into The technologies considered in this study are listed in Table 1.
account while constructing large-scale facilities such as electric Both widely used technologies and novel technologies, which are
power plants that often requires a long lead time. Furthermore, expected to change within the time period of evaluation, are
the model treats costs by exogenous technology learning or considered. Facility vintages are considered for the technologies
exogenous cost reductions. Cumulative installation of some new in the model.

Table 1
Bottom-up technologies in DNE21 + .

Sector Technologies

Electricity Coal power {low efficiency (subcriticality), mid-efficiency (supercriticality), high efficiency (extra supercriticality—integrated coal gasification
combined cycle (IGCC)/integrated coal gasification fuel cell combined cycle (IGFC)), IGCC with precombustion CO2 capture}, oil power {low
efficiency (diesel generator, etc.), mid-efficiency (subcriticality), high efficiency (supercriticality), combined heat and power (CHP)}, synthetic
oil power {mid-efficiency, high efficiency}, natural gas power {low efficiency (steam turbine), mid-efficiency (conventional natural gas
combined cycle (NGCC)), high efficiency (high-temperature NGCC), CHP, oxy-fuel combustion}, biomass power {low efficiency, high
efficiency}, nuclear power {conventional, next generation (Generation IV, etc.)}, hydro/geothermal power, wind power, photovoltaics, power
storage system for wind/PV, hydrogen power, electrical cable {conventional, superconducting high efficiency}, carbon dioxide capture and
storage (CCS) {post-combustion capture; applicable for coal, oil, synthetic oil, natural gas, biomass power}
Other energy supply Oil refinery, gas reforming, gas liquefaction, coal liquefaction, coal gasification, biomass fermentation, biomass liquefaction, biomass
gasification, and water electrolysis
Industry
Iron and steel Blast furnace and basic oxygen furnace (BF-BOF) {low efficiency (small scale), mid-efficiency (large scale), high efficiency (large scale,
equipped with coke dry quenching (CDQ), top-pressure recovery turbine (TRT), recovery of by-product gases), next generation (super coke
oven (e.g., SCOPE 21), utilizing plastic wastes and tire wastes, as well as highly efficient equipment), iron production by hydrogen reduction},
coke oven gas (COG) recovery {externally attachable to low/mid-efficient BF-BOF}, Linz–Donawitz converter gas (LDG) recovery, CDQ/TRT
{externally attachable to mid-efficient BF-BOF}, direct reduction {natural gas base (mid/high efficiency), hydrogen gasification base}, scrap-
used electric arc furnace (Scrap-EAF) {low efficiency (small scale), mid-efficiency (tri-phase electric arc furnace), high efficiency (DC water-
cooled walls arc furnace equipped with scrap preheating)}, CCS {applicable to BF-BOF}
Cement Small-scale facilities: vertical kiln, wet rotary kiln, dry rotary kiln, suspension preheater/new supension preheater (SP/NSP) dry rotary kiln,
advanced fluidized bed shaft furnace {equipped with SP/NSP, efficient clinker coolers}
Large-scale facilities (more efficient than small-scale ones): wet rotary kiln, dry rotary kiln, SP/NSP dry rotary kiln, SP/NSP dry rotary kiln (high
efficiency) {equipped with efficient clinker coolers, SP with 5 or 6 levels, efficient waste heat recovery}
Pulp and paper Chemical pulp {low efficiency, mid-efficiency, high efficiency, next generation}, paper recycling {low efficiency, mid-efficiency, high
efficiency}, milling paper {low efficiency, mid-efficiency, high efficiency, next generation}, black liquid recovery and use {low efficiency, high
efficiency}, paper sludge boilers, and steam turbine power systems
Aluminum Söderberg aluminum production, and prebake aluminum production
Chemical Ethylene/propylene: naphtha cracking {low efficiency, mid-efficiency, high efficiency, next generation}, other production {ethane cracker, etc.;
low efficiency, mid-efficiency, high efficiency}
Ammonia: from coal {low efficiency, mid-efficiency, high efficiency}, from oil {low efficiency, mid-efficiency, high efficiency}, and from natural
gas {low efficiency, mid-efficiency, high efficiency}
Transportation Types: small passenger car, large passenger car, bus, small truck, and large truck,
internal combustion engines (gasoline/diesel) {conventional internal combustion cars (low/high efficiency), hybrid cars, plug-in hybrid cars},
electric cars, fuel cell cars, alternative fuels {bioethanol mixed with gasoline, biodiesel mixed with diesel, and compressed natural gas (CNG)}
Residential and Refrigerator {low efficiency, mid-efficiency, high efficiency}, lighting {small bulb, small fluorescent light, small next generation (light-emitting
commercial diode (LED), etc.), medium-size mid-efficiency fluorescent light, medium-size high efficiency fluorescent light, medium-size next generation
(LED, organic light-emitting diode (OLED), etc.), large-size mid-efficiency high intensity discharge (HID), large-size high efficiency HID, large-
size next generation (LED, etc.)}, television {small-size low-efficiency, small-size high efficiency, large-size low-efficiency, large-size high
efficiency, large-size next generation (high efficiency liquid crystal television, plasma, rear projection, OLED)}, air conditioner {low efficiency,
mid-efficiency, high efficiency}, gas cooking stove {low efficiency, mid-efficiency, high efficiency}

Note: Transportation and distribution infrastructures of energy carriers are also explicitly modeled.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
K. Akimoto et al. / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 3384–3393 3387

2.3.2. Payback time material production and are generally associated with sharp
The assumption for payback time for the investment of increases in energy-unrelated CO2 emissions.
technologies is one of the key factors for estimations of marginal Fugitive emission in most countries, including those in the
abatement costs. The payback period is calculated on the basis of Middle East, is decreasing owing to continuous efforts to
numerous socio-economic factors such as the interest rate, effectively utilize associated gases and to reduce flare. Canada
income and financial leeway, subjective preference for risk- has also made efforts in this direction, but it shows the highest
avoidance, and expected profit rate of stockholders. The return rate of increase among developed countries because of a large
on investment (ROI) is generally 10–20%, corresponding to a increase in the production of oil and natural gas, including
payback period of 5–10 years. Table 2 shows the assumed unconventional oil.
payback periods when considering such situations. In the case of developing countries, there is a lack of reliable,
globally consistent regional data on estimates of future energy-
2.3.3. Nuclear power scenario unrelated CO2 emissions from waste and other sources. Therefore,
Nuclear power is a key technology for CO2 emission reduc- emissions from waste and other sources are assumed to be
tions, but there are key factors other than cost that need to be constant over the evaluated time periods.
considered, including the lead time and the public acceptance of
the use of nuclear power. Therefore, exogenous scenarios are 2.5. Non-CO2 GHG assessment model
assumed for nuclear power generation, as presented in Table 3.
The generation is estimated from national plans of nuclear power The non-CO2 GHG assessment model is derived from the study
plant construction and their current status (IEEJ, 2008). by Hyman et al. (2003). The model converts bottom-up assess-
ments of mitigation technologies performed by the USEPA (2002)
2.4. Energy-unrelated CO2 emission scenario to a proxy model using elasticity (Dowaki et al., 2006). However,
in this study, the historical emission of non-CO2 GHGs was
Exogenous scenarios that are fixed regardless of individual adjusted using the UNFCCC inventory (UNFCCC, 2009) and the IEA
mitigation options are assumed. One specific scenario is applied statistics (IEA, 2007) for Annex I countries and non-Annex I
for each source. The assumed emission sources are industrial countries, respectively. The emission mitigation costs and poten-
processes, including raw material productions, fugitive, waste and tials were modified using new technology assessments performed
other sectors. by the USEPA (2006b). The baseline emissions were estimated
In the scenario of the energy-related CO2 assessment model, using the common assumptions for population and GDP adopted
the increase in the production of raw materials such as cement, in this study. The model considers five types of emissions: CH4 in
steel, and aluminum is assumed to be moderate in Annex I seven sectors, N2O in six sectors, hydrofluorocarbons (HFCs) in
countries. Accordingly, the increase in the energy-unrelated CO2 one sector, perfluorocarbons (PFCs) in one sector, and SF6 in one
emissions is also gradual (reduces or reaches a constant level) in sector for 18 regions. To ensure consistency with 54 regions in the
developed countries. In the scenario, developing countries such as DNE21+ model for analyses of energy-related CO2, the historical
China and India are assumed to demonstrate increased raw data on emissions in the base year are used and distributed
among 54 regions.
Table 2
Assumed payback periods. 2.5.1. Baseline emission
CH4 emissions were considered in seven sectors: agriculture,
Payback periods
(years) oil, coal, natural gas, residential, transportation, and energy-
intensive industries. N2O emissions were considered in six
Upper Lower sectors: agriculture, oil, natural gas, residential, transportation,
limit limit
and energy-intensive industries. HFCs, PFCs, and SF6 emissions
Electricity generation sector 10 6.7
were considered for one macro-sector each. The sectoral baseline
Other energy conversion sector 7 4.7 emissions were estimated as described below.
Industrial sector (energy-intensive industry) 10 6.7 (1) CH4 and N2O
Transportation sector (purchase of environment- 5 3.3
conscious products) (10)
Residential and commercial 3 2.0 2.5.1.1. Agriculture sector. The baseline emission of methane for
the agriculture sector was estimated by region for six groups: rice
Note: Payback periods for different regions are assumed to be within the above cultivation, grassland burning, agricultural residue burning,
limits, depending on the regions’ per-capita GDP. The duration of the payback
period increases with the per-capita GDP. The number of people who purchase
enteric fermentation, livestock manure, and land use change. The
automobiles with long payback periods (i.e., the purchase of environment- emission from rice cultivation was estimated according to the
conscious products) is assumed to increase with the per-capita GDP. population of the relevant regions using the estimation method
proposed by the USEPA (2006a). The emission from grassland
burning was estimated on the basis of the study by Masui et al.
Table 3
(2001), where the emissions are assumed to vary depending on
Scenarios for nuclear power generation (TWh/yr). the meadow areas estimated by cropland growth rates, which are
presented in the IPCC Special Report on Emissions Scenarios
2005 2020 (SRES) B2 scenario (IPCC, 2000). FAOSTAT data (FAO, 2009) were
used to estimate the regional meadow areas for the base year. The
Japan 305 437
United States 811 873 emissions from enteric fermentation and livestock manure were
EU27 987 965 estimated using the method described by the USEPA (2006a) and
Russia 149 346 the relevant number of livestock provided by IFPRI (1999). The
China 53 282 numbers of livestock were estimated using the method of Masui
India 17 124
Worldwide total 2767 3677
et al. (2001), and grazing areas were assumed from the growth
rates of cropland areas estimated in the IPCC SRES B2 scenario.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
3388 K. Akimoto et al. / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 3384–3393

The emission from enteric fermentation was estimated by main- marginal abatement costs. The elasticity is determined such that
taining a fixed emission intensity in accordance with the IPCC the marginal abatement cost curves correspond to the USEPA
guidelines (IPCC, 1996). The emission from land use change, estimates obtained separately for each sector and type of gas. The
which may naturally be assumed to arise from burnt or rotten estimates are calculated using a technology database for non-CO2
biomass waste, was estimated to be inversely proportional to the GHG measures. Thus, the model used here is not a direct bottom-
conversion of natural grassland and forest areas in the SRES B2 up model; however, marginal costs and potentials of non-CO2
scenario. GHG mitigation are essentially based on the bottom-up analysis
The N2O baseline emission in the agriculture sector was of the USEPA.
estimated by region for seven groups: emissions from soil and the The elasticity in the model developed by Hyman et al. (2003) is
six groups considered for CH4 emissions from the agriculture essentially applied to the RITE model, but the elasticity is adjusted
sector. N2O emissions from these six groups of the agriculture to be consistent with the result of analysis for a 20%/yr discount
sector were estimated using the same methods as those used for rate, which is close to the rate usually observed in decision
estimating CH4 emission from the agriculture sector. As for N2O makings of socio-economic activities, taking into consideration
emissions from soil, the sum of emissions caused by usage of the results of sensitivity analysis for the discount rate (payback
chemical fertilizers, nitrogen-fixing plants, crop residues, and period) carried out by the USEPA (2002). The elasticity is also
other sources were estimated. The future emissions from partially adjusted on the basis of the mitigation effect report of
chemical fertilizers were estimated using the estimation methods the USEPA (2006b). The elasticity of gases and the mitigation
of Tilman et al. (2001), Masui et al. (2001), and the USDA (2003). potentials in this study are estimated to be less than those
Time-series regression with population and per-capita GDP was reported by Hyman et al. (2003)
also used to obtain this estimate. The emissions from nitrogen-  sðg;h;nÞ
1
fixing plants, crop residues, and other sources were estimated Red_rðg; h; n; tÞ ¼ 1 ð1Þ
Pðg; h; n; tÞ
using the method proposed by the USEPA (2006a). The emissions
from nitrogen-fixing plants were estimated using production data where g represents the gas; h, the sector; n, the region; and t, the
for soybean and edible seeds. The future productions were year. Red_r(g,h,n,t) is the reduction rate for the total emission,
estimated up to 2015 using the future projection data of FAOSTAT P(g,h,n,t) is the marginal abatement cost, and s is the elasticity
(FAO, 2009) and IFPRI (IFPRI, 1999). Thereafter, the baselines were derived on the basis of studies by the USEPA (2002, 2006b) and
estimated using the cultivation areas that were associated with Hyman et al. (2003).
the cropland areas in the SRES B2 scenario. The emissions from
crop residues were estimated using the cultivation areas of rice
and oats along with the abovementioned nitrogen-fixing plants. 3. Emission reduction potentials by country, sector, and cost
Emissions from other sources were estimated by multiplying the
aforementioned numbers of livestock by the N2O-emission- 3.1. National Perspectives
specific units of nitrogen contained in livestock manure.
GHG emission reduction potentials by country, sector, and cost
2.5.1.2. Oil, coal, and natural gas sectors. The baseline emissions for were estimated using the above assessment models with high
oil, coal, and natural gas sectors were estimated using the per- resolution with respect to regions and sectors. Projections of the
capita GDP scenario and the productions for oil, coal, and natural baseline emission are required to determine the emission
gas were estimated by the USDOE EIA (2005). reduction potentials. However, obtaining these projections is very
difficult. In this paper, two types of baseline emissions with
relatively rigid definitions are introduced: (1) the technology-
2.5.1.3. Residential and transport sector. The emissions from
frozen (TF) case and (2) the negative cost measures achieved
transportation, landfills, and sewerage were considered. For
(NCA) case. The baseline emission in the TF case is defined such
transportation, the baseline emissions were estimated using the
that the CO2 intensity is fixed at 2005 levels until 2030 and the
per-capita GDP scenario and the USDOE EIA estimation of energy
contributions of future sectoral activities (e.g., production of crude
demands for the transportation sector. These baseline emissions
steel) are maintained at the assumed baseline. The baseline
were consistent with the results obtained using the methods
emissions in the NCA case are obtained from the energy model
provided by the USEPA (2006a). For landfills and sewerage, the
calculation of cost minimization without any climate-specific
methods used were consistent with the methods explained by
constraints or without any global warming damage being
the USEPA (2006a), and the baselines were estimated using
considered for all the adopted negative cost measures. The
per-capita GDP.
baseline emissions of non-CO2 GHGs are defined on the basis of
the NCA case.
2.5.1.4. HFCs, PFCs, and SF6. The baseline emissions were esti- Table 4 shows the emission reduction potentials compared to
mated using the SRES B2 scenario for each of the four regions the the TF case, presented by country and cost. Around the world,
world was divided into. The emissions for further divided regions there are large emission reduction potentials with negative cost
or countries were estimated according to the GDP shares of each measures, particularly in major developing countries. This means
region or country in the four SRES regions. that a large number of opportunities exist for emission reductions
through technology transfer and technology diffusion, particularly
2.5.2. Methods for estimating emission reduction potentials for non- in developing countries. Emission reduction by negative cost
CO2 GHG measures is not easy to achieve in some developing countries
The assessment model for non-CO2 GHG mitigation potentials because of barriers in their implementation, including technology
is based on the assessments performed by the USEPA (2002, availability and high interest rates.
2006b) and Hyman et al. (2003). Eq. (1) indicates the relationship The emission reduction potentials compare to the TF case and
between the individual non-CO2 GHG mitigation ratio and the NCA case due to measures at negative costs and below
marginal abatement costs evaluated using the elasticity. In this 50 $/tCO2 in Annex I countries are about 8.3 and 3.6 GtCO2 eq./yr,
study, the non-CO2 GHG mitigation in 18 regions is estimated respectively (please note that all the monetary costs in this paper
when the non-CO2 GHG abatement costs are equalized to CO2 are designated by the 2000 year price.). This means that the
ARTICLE IN PRESS
K. Akimoto et al. / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 3384–3393 3389

Table 4
GHG emission reduction potentials compared to the TF case in 2020 by cost (MtCO2 eq./yr).

Emission in 2005 Emission in 2020 in the TF case Emission reduction potentials compared to the TF case in 2020

r 0 $/tCO2 (NCA case) r20 $/tCO2 r 50 $/tCO2 r 100 $/tCO2

US 7107 9226 1686 2391 3121 4331


EU27 5132 6770 1214 1817 2186 2565
Japan 1358 1554 142 180 223 325
Russia 2123 3577 1190 1599 1732 1848
China 7410 20,334 6908 10,578 12,190 12,918
India 2244 6934 3310 4285 4397 4543
Annex I 17,652 23,933 4716 6821 8282 10,320
Other OECD countries 1155 1677 207 503 613 718
Major developing countries 11,832 31,365 11,374 16,573 18,587 19,585
Other non-Annex I 8027 15,754 3939 6244 7006 7491
World 38,666 72,729 20,235 30,142 34,487 38,114

Notes: ‘‘Other OECD countries’’ are the Republic of Korea and Mexico, and ‘‘major developing countries’’ are Brazil, China, India, Indonesia, and South Africa, which
participate in the Major Economies Forum on Energy and Climate (MEF) along with Australia, Canada, the European Union, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Russia, the United
Kingdom, and the United States. The emission reduction potentials at a cost of below 0 $/tCO2 include the emission reductions of non-CO2 GHGs from the TF case to the
baseline emissions, although the reduction costs are not necessarily negative. The emission reduction potentials due to carbon capture and storage are excluded owing to
the uncertainty of its widespread use globally.

expected emission in Annex I countries is 11% less than the 2005 future economic growth, and other factors. Fig. 2 shows the
level (15% less than the 1990 level). If all the measures are distribution of emission reduction potentials by sector, country,
implemented at negative costs and below 50 $/tCO2, the emis- and cost. There is great potential for emission reductions at
sions are 14%, 11%, 2%, and 13% less than the 2005 levels in the negative costs in the form of energy efficiency improvements in
United States, EU27, Japan, and Russia, respectively. The reduction the power sector, along with improved vehicles and various
potentials from the 2005 level are relatively small in Japan control measures for improving traffic flow in the transportation
because high energy efficiencies have already been achieved. The sector. In addition, large emission reduction potentials in the
energy efficiency in Russia is relatively low, but high economic range from 0 to 20 $/tCO2 are expected in the power sector,
growth is expected in the future, and therefore, the emission mainly due to energy efficiency improvement in coal power,
reduction potentials are almost at the same levels as those of the particularly in developing countries. Large emission reduction
United States and EU27. potentials in this cost range are also evident in the agriculture and
On the other hand, there is a large potential for emission waste sectors for non-CO2 GHGs. Furthermore, the emission
reductions from the TF case at negative costs and below 50 $/tCO2 reduction potentials in (1) the wind power sector, (2) the energy-
in major developing countries, up to approximately 19 GtCO2 intensive sector (where energy reductions are mainly achieved via
eq./yr. The potential for global emission reductions from the TF halocarbon emission reduction measures), and (3) the energy
case at a cost of below 20–50 $/tCO2 including negative cost are conversion sector (where energy reductions are mainly achieved
approximately 30 and 34 GtCO2 eq./yr, corresponding to a 10% via methane emission reduction measures in natural gas
increase and 1% decrease relative to the emission level in 2005, production) are large in the United States, Japan, and Russia,
respectively. respectively. Large emission reduction potentials in the range
The IPCC reported that the global potentials of emission from 20 to 100 $/tCO2 are expected after switching from coal
reductions in 2030 are 5–7, 9–17, 13–26, and 16–31 GtCO2 eq./yr power to gas power plants.
at costs of below 0, 20, 50, and 100 US$/tCO2 eq., respectively Carbon capture and storage technology have the potential to
(IPCC, 2007). Two large differences should be noted between result in large emission reduction at a relatively low cost;
the estimates by IPCC and this study: the target year and the however, they are not included in the figures because they were
definition of baseline emissions. This study estimates the poten- excluded from the evaluations across countries and sectors owing
tial in 2020, while the IPCC reported the potential in 2030. The to large uncertainties in implementation. In addition, the emis-
baselines are defined by TF and NCA cases without ambiguity sion reduction potentials of nuclear power are presented only in
and with consistency in this study, while the baseline reported the figure for the negative cost range because nuclear power is
by the IPCC is not. Thus, the potentials only above 0 US$/tCO2 assumed to be part of a fixed exogenous scenario.
eq. between two studies should be compared recognizing the
differences in the target year. The emission reduction potentials of
0–20, 20–50, and 50–100 US$/tCO2 eq. estimated by this study 4. Expected emission reductions under common but
are 10, 4, and 4 GtCO2 eq./yr, respectively, while the emission differentiated scenarios
reduction potentials of 0–20, 20–50, and 50–100 US$/tCO2 eq. in
the IPCC report are 4–10, 4–9, and 3–5 GtCO2 eq./yr, respectively. Equalizing marginal reduction costs across countries can help
The reduction potentials should not be directly compared due to globally to achieve a certain reduction at the least cost. However,
the differences in the target year; however, the global reduction developed countries should make greater efforts to reduce their
potentials are nearly consistent with two studies. emissions, given that they are responsible for past emissions
accumulated in the atmosphere and given their current capabil-
ities. The expected emission reductions under different targets for
3.2. Sector perspectives developed and developing countries are presented in Table 5.
In the NCA case, it is assumed that all countries undertake all
Cost-effective emission mitigation measures differ across the emission reduction measures that have negative costs. In
countries owing to differences in industrial structures, current Case 20-0, it is assumed that all measures that have negative
energy efficiency levels, renewable energy potentials, expected costs and below 20 $/tCO2 are adopted by developed countries
ARTICLE IN PRESS
3390 K. Akimoto et al. / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 3384–3393

(Annex I and OECD countries) and those that have negative costs measures at negative costs and below 20 $/tCO2 as a macro-CO2-
are adopted by developing countries. In Case 50-0, it is assumed intensity target (per-GDP greenhouse gas emissions by country
that developed countries and developing countries reduce their are assumed to be reduced by the carbon price corresponding to
emissions by adopting all measures that have negative costs and 20 $/tCO2.). In Case 50-20b, it is assumed that all measures at
below 50 $/tCO2 and those that have negative costs, respectively. negative costs and below 50 $/tCO2 are adopted by developed
From the viewpoint of avoiding dangerous climate change, it countries and that those at negative costs and below 20 $/tCO2
might be insufficient to carry out emission reductions only in are adopted by major developing countries; however, for major
developed countries, and there are large reduction potentials at developing countries, measures only apply to energy-intensive
low costs available to developing countries, as discussed in the sectors (i.e., iron and steel, cement, and aluminum sectors) as an
previous section. On the other hand, many developing countries energy-intensity target and high-emission sectors (i.e., power and
whose rates of economic growth are high and whose emissions transportation sectors) as a CO2-intensity target.
are expected to grow rapidly would find it difficult to accept Fig. 3 shows the emission reduction potentials compared to
national emission caps. Considering these circumstances, two the TF case. The emission reduction potentials achieved by
additional cases are considered to examine the reduction efforts measures at cost of below 50–100 $/tCO2 including negative
among countries in accordance with the principle of common but cost measures in Annex I countries are 8.3 and 10.3 GtCO2 eq./yr,
differentiated responsibilities. In Case 50-20a, it is assumed that respectively, as presented in the previous section. The potential
developed countries adopt all measures at negative costs and corresponds to reductions of 11% and 23% compared to the 2005
below 50 $/tCO2, and that major developing countries adopt all level and 15% and 26% compared to the 1990 level. Large emission

Power sector: Fuel switching


United States among fossil fuels
Power sector: Efficiency
EU-27 improvement
Power sector: Wind power
Japan
Power sector: Other renewables
Russia Power sector: Nuclear power

China Other energy conversion sectors

India Energy intensive industries


Other industries
Annex I & OECD
Transportation sector
Major developing
countries Residential&Commercial sector
Other developing
countries Agriculture
0 20 40 60 80 100 Waste
GHG emission reduction potentials [%]

Power sector: Fuel switching


United States among fossil fuels
Power sector: Efficiency
EU-27 improvement
Power sector: Wind power
Japan
Power sector: Other renewables
Russia Power sector: Nuclear power

China Other energy conversion sectors

India Energy intensive industries


Other industries
Annex I & OECD
Transportation sector
Major developing
countries Residential&Commercial sector
Other developing
countries Agriculture
0 20 40 60 80 100 Waste
GHG emission reduction potentials [%]

Fig. 2. Sectoral emission reduction potentials from TF case by region in 2020. (a) r 0 $/tCO2 (from TF to NCA cases), (b) 0–20 $/tCO2, (c) 20–50 $/tCO2, and (d) 50–100 $/t
CO2. Notes: the figures show the sectoral contributions to the emission reduction potentials shown in Table 4. Emission reductions achieved by switching from coal power
to gas combined power are divided and distributed among power sector: efficiency improvement (as gas combined power is generally more efficient than coal power) and
power sector: fuel switching among fossil fuels. The emission reduction potentials at a cost below 0 $/tCO2 include the emission reductions of non-CO2 GHGs from the TF case
to the baseline emissions, although the reduction costs are not necessarily negative.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
K. Akimoto et al. / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 3384–3393 3391

Power sector: Fuel switching


United States among fossil fuels
Power sector: Efficiency
EU-27 improvement
Power sector: Wind power
Japan
Power sector: Other renewables
Russia Power sector: Nuclear power

China Other energy conversion sectors

India Energy intensive industries


Other industries
Annex I & OECD
Transportation sector
Major developing
countries Residential&Commercial sector
Other developing
countries Agriculture
0 20 40 60 80 100 Waste
GHG emission reduction potentials [%]

Power sector: Fuel switching


United States among fossil fuels
Power sector: Efficiency
EU-27 improvement
Power sector: Wind power
Japan
Power sector: Other renewables
Russia Power sector: Nuclear power

China Other energy conversion sectors

India Energy intensive industries


Other industries
Annex I & OECD
Transportation sector
Major developing
countries Residential&Commercial sector
Other developing
countries Agriculture
0 20 40 60 80 100 Waste
GHG emission reduction potentials [%]

Fig. 2. (Continued)

Table 5
Assumed cases.

Case Developed countries Major developing countries Other developing


(Annex I and OECD) ($/tCO2) countries

NCA case 0 0 $/tCO2 0 $/tCO2


Case 20-0 20 0 $/tCO2
Case 50-0 50 0 $/tCO2
Case 100-0 100 0 $/tCO2
Case 50-20a 50 Macro-CO2-intensity target corresponding to 20 $/tCO2
Case 50-20b 50 CO2/energy-intensity target for selected sectors corresponding to 20 $/tCO2

Note 1: ‘‘Major developing countries’’ are Brazil, China, India, Indonesia, and South Africa. The selected sectors for intensity targets in major developing countries are power,
iron and steel, cement, aluminum, and transportation sectors.
Note 2: All measures at a cost of below the indicated cost are assumed to be adopted.

reduction is expected in Case 50-20a, and the emission reduction 20 $/tCO2 only in energy-intensive sectors and high-emission
potential compared to the TF case in major developing countries sectors.
is 16.6 GtCO2 eq./yr. The reduction potential in major developing International discussions have led to calls for Annex I countries
countries is 14.8 GtCO2 eq./yr even in Case 50-20b, in which it is to achieve GHG emission reductions of 25–40% from 1990
assumed that measures are adopted at negative costs and below levels by the year 2020. The required reductions from the emis-
ARTICLE IN PRESS
3392 K. Akimoto et al. / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 3384–3393

from the TF case to the baseline emissions, although the reduction


costs are not necessarily negative.

GHG emission reduction compared to the TF case [MtCO2eq./yr]


30000 Corresponding to the required emission
reduction of 40% from 1990 level in Annex I

Emission reduction of 25% in Annex I Major developing countries


($0-$20/tCO2)
25000
Developed countries
($50-$100/tCO2)
NCA case
20000 Developed countries
($20-$50/tCO2)

Developed countries
15000 ($0-$20/tCO2)

Other developing countries


( $0/tCO2)
10000
Major developing countries
( $0/tCO2)
5000 Developed countries (
$0/tCO2)

0
se

-0

-0

0a

0b
0-
20

50
ca

-2

-2
10

50

50
e

e
A

as

as

e
C

as

e
N

as

as
C

Fig. 3. Expected reductions in GHG emission in 2020.

sion level of Annex I countries in 2005 are 3.8 and 6.6 GtCO2 several cooperative measures adopted by seven member countries
eq./yr in 2020 for 25% and 40% reductions, which correspond to (the member countries include both developed and developing
5.4 and 8.2 GtCO2 eq./yr compared to the NCA case, respec- countries). There is a need for strong action at the international level,
tively. The required emission reductions are also shown in Fig. 3. and estimates of emission reduction potentials by country, sector,
In Case 50-20b, it is expected that emission reductions will be and cost would be greatly helpful in this regard.
achieved through global cooperation among developed and Model analyses show that there are large emission reduction
developing countries. potentials available to developing countries at low costs. Such
The additional costs to developed countries in shifting from emission reduction opportunities should be utilized. However,
the NCA case to Cases 50-0 and 100-0 are 77 and 231 billion US$/ emission reduction targets that take into account the principle of
yr, respectively. On the other hand, the cost to major developing common but differentiated responsibilities among developed and
countries is 101 billion US$/yr in Case 50-20b. The cost in Case 50- developing countries should also be considered. Large-scale
20 b corresponds to 55 and 30 US$/yr in terms of the per-capita emission reductions would be achieved if, for example, only
cost in developed and major developing countries, corresponding CO2-intensity measures at negative costs and below 20 $/tCO2
to per-GDP costs of 0.2% and 0.8%, respectively. In this paper, the are adopted for major sectors in major developing countries.
cost burden is not discussed; however, if half the cost for reducing For achieving low-cost opportunities of emission reductions and
emissions in major developing countries is simply assumed to be successfully avoiding dangerous climate change, one of the
covered by developed countries, the total costs of reductions are proposed schemes will consist of (1) flexible targets (including
128 and 50 billion US$/yr in developed and major developing intensity targets) for selected sectors, (2) financial support by
countries, respectively. developed countries to developing countries for their emission
reductions, and (3) developments of technology transfer schemes.

5. Conclusion References

In this paper, GHG emission reduction potentials are assessed Akimoto, K., Sano, F., Oda, J., Homma, T., Rout, U.K., Tomoda, T., 2008. Global
by country, sector, and cost using a GHG emission reduction emission reductions through a sectoral intensity target scheme. Climate Policy
assessment model with high resolutions with respect to region 8, S46–S59.
Amann, M. et al., 2008. Comparing GHG Mitigation Potentials and Costs for Annex I
and technology and high consistency in terms of assumptions, Countries, IIASA Poznan Side Event: Scientific Tools to Help Negotiators Set
interrelationships, and solution principles across regions, sectors, Emission Reduction Targets to 2020. /http://www.iiasa.ac.at/Admin/INF/
and points of time. Determining emission reduction potentials is research_updates/2008/poznan08.htmlS.
Dowaki, K., K. Akimoto, F. Sano, T. Tomoda, S. Mori, 2006. An Impact Analysis on
believed to be indispensable for achieving large emission
Greenhouse Gases Including an Effect of Non-CO2 Emissions, Operations
reductions. Research, Germany.
For example, the Asian–Pacific Partnership on Clean Develop- Enkvist, P.A., Nauclér, T., Rosander, J., 2007. A Cost Curve for Greenhouse Gas
ment and Climate (APP) adopts an action-oriented, sector-based Reduction. McKinsey & Company.
FAO, 2009. FAOSTAT; FAO Statistical Database, /http://faostat.fao.org/S.
approach. The partnership assesses potential improvements in Hanaoka, T., et al., 2008. Greenhouse gas emissions reductions potentials and
energy efficiency to achieve effective emission reductions, with mitigation costs in world regions. Journal of Japan Society of Energy and
ARTICLE IN PRESS
K. Akimoto et al. / Energy Policy 38 (2010) 3384–3393 3393

Resources 29 (4) (in Japanese). /http://www.jser.gr.jp/journal/journal_pdf/ RITE, 2009. RITE GHG Mitigation Assessment Model. /http://www.rite.or.jp/
2008/journal200807_6.pdfS. English/lab/syslab/about-global-warming/download-data/E-RITE_GHGMitiga
Hyman, R.C., Reilly, J.M., Babiker, M.H., Valpergue De Masin, A., Jacoby, H.D., 2003. tionAssessmentModel_20090529.pdfS.
Modeling non-CO2 greenhouse gas abatement. Environmental Modeling and The Japanese government, 2008. Japan’s Proposal for AWG-LCA: for Preparation of
Assessment 8, 175–186. Chair’s Document for COP14. /http://www.mofa.go.jp/policy/environment/
IEA, 2007. CO2 Emissions from Fuel Combustion. OECD/IEA. warm/cop/cop14-p.htmlS (accessed in July 2009).
IEEJ, 2008. Report on Actual Conditions of Nuclear Power Plant Construction in Tilman, D., Fargione, J., Wolff, B., D’Antonio, C., Dobson, A., Howarth, R., Schindler, D.,
Various Countries. Institute of Energy Economics, Japan in Japanese. Schlesinger, W.H., Simberloff, D., Swackhamer, D., 2001. Forecasting agriculturally
IFPRI, 1999. Livestock to 2020, International Food Policy Research Institute. driven global environmental change. SCIENCE 292, 281–284.
/http://www.ifpri.org/2020/dp/dp28.pdfS (accessed in July 2009). UN, 2006. World Population Prospects: The 2006 Revision. /http://esa.un.org/
IIASA, 2009. On-Line Access to GAINS, International Institute for Applied Systems unpp/S (accessed in February 2009).
Analysis. /http://gains.iiasa.ac.at/index.php/home-page/241-on-line-access- UNFCCC, 2009. GHG Data from UNFCCC. /http://unfccc.int/ghg_data/ghg_data_
to-gainsS (accessed in July 2009). unfccc/items/4146.phpS (accessed in February 2009).
IPCC, 1996. Revised 1996 IPCC Guidelines for National Greenhouse Gas Inventories. USDA, 2003. Food Security Assessment, GFA-14, /http://www.ers.usda.gov/
IPCC/OECD/IEA. /http://www.ipcc-nggip.iges.or.jp/public/gl/invs1.htmlS. publications/GFA14/S (accessed in July 2009).
IPCC, 2000. Special Report on Emissions Scenarios. Cambridge University Press. USDOE EIA, 2005. International Energy Outlook 2005 Data, /http://www.eia.doe.
IPCC, 2007. Climate Change 2007—Mitigation of Climate Change: Working Group gov/oiaf/forecasting.HtmlS.
III Contribution to the Fourth Assessment Report of the IPCC. Cambridge USEPA, 2002. International Methane and Nitrous Oxide Emissions and Mitigation
University Press. Data, /http://www.epa.gov/methane/appendices.htmlS (accessed in February
Masui, T., Matsuoka, Y., Morita, T., Kainuma, M., Takahashi, K., 2001. Development 2009).
of land use model for IPCC new emission scenarios (SRES). In: Matsuo, T., USEPA, 2006a. Global Anthropogenic Non-CO2 Greenhouse Gas Emissions:
Kida, H. (Eds.), Present and Future Modeling Global Environmental 1990–2020.
Change. Toward Integrated Modeling, Terra Scientific Publishing Company, USEPA, 2006b. Global Mitigation of Non-CO2 Greenhouse Gases, /http://www.epa.
pp. 441–448. gov/climatechange/economics/downloads/GlobalMitigationFullReport.pdfS.
Oda, J., Akimoto, K., Sano, F., Tomoda, T., 2007. Diffusion of energy efficient (accessed in February 2009).
technologies and CO2 emission reductions in iron and steel sector. Energy
Economics 29, 868–888.

Potrebbero piacerti anche