Sei sulla pagina 1di 11

This article has been accepted for publication in a future issue of this journal, but has not been

fully edited. Content may change prior to final publication. Citation information: DOI 10.1109/TSG.2018.2810819, IEEE
Transactions on Smart Grid
1

Prospect Theory based Active Consumer Behavior


Under Variable Electricity Pricing
Kumarsinh Jhala, Student Member, IEEE, Balasubramaniam Natarajan, Senior Member, IEEE
and Anil Pahwa, Fellow, IEEE

Abstract—Active consumers who engage in energy consump- a∗i Optimal action of i th active consumer that maxi-
tion, production and provide ancillary services in a dynamic mizes the perceived payoff
and interactive manner will be an integral part of the future P̂ Perceived price of electricity
grid. This paper models and analyzes interaction between active
consumers and aggregators with a specific focus on consumer A Energy purchased by the aggregator in day-ahead
actions in response to real-time electricity pricing and their market
impacts on grid voltage. Firstly, the paper introduces a unique ρda Price of electricity paid by the aggregator in day-
prospect theory based consumer behavior model that captures ahead market
wide range of consumers each with their individual preferences. ρrt Price of electricity paid by the aggregator in real-
Secondly, the interaction between consumers and aggregators is
modeled as a Stackelberg game. However, unlike existing game time market
theoretic efforts that assume rational behavior of consumers, the v Vector of distribution grid voltage
prospect theory based models systematically incorporate realistic S Voltage sensitivity matrix of the distribution system
consumer behavior including irrationality. Another unique aspect a Vector of best response actions of all active con-
of the formulation is the inclusion of the physical grid constraints sumers
(in terms of voltage violations) within the analysis. In contrast to
prior approaches that limit themselves to economic aspects, the â Vector of previous actions of all active consumers
proposed techno-economic perspective provides an understanding 1 Vector of all 1’s
of the impact of large scale penetration of active consumers on the θ Coefficient of grid awareness for the aggregator
physical grid. The proposed model is analyzed using simulations
on the IEEE 69 bus test system and the impact of irrationality
on both consumer/aggregator payoffs and voltage violations is I. Introduction
quantified.
A smart power grid leverages advances in sensing, commu-
Keywords: Active Consumer, Game Theory, Power Distri- nication, computing, and control to increase grid reliability,
bution, Prospect Theory, Sensitivity, Stackelberg Game resiliency, efficiency, and flexibility [1]. Integration of these
technologies also allows higher deployment of large and small-
Nomenclature scale renewable energy resources. The most significant impact
of these changes is being felt at the consumer level. The
ai Action of active consumer connected to node i new generation of appliances within the home are becoming
i Node and active consumer index smarter with load management and communication capabil-
ρ Price of electricity ities. As a result of these advances, future consumers will
P Probability distribution of electricity price be very different from those today. It is expected that active
ω(·) Probability weighting function consumers who engage in managing energy use, production,
ω(p) Subjective probability storage and providing other ancillary services in a dynamic
p Objective probability and interactive manner will be an integral part of the future
α Coefficient of rationality grid. Therefore, understanding, modeling and quantifying the
Ri Renewable generation of i th active consumer impact of such active consumers under the umbrella of cyber
βi Comfort coefficient of i th active consumer physical social and economic systems is an important and
v(i) Distribution grid voltage at node i much needed research thrust. There will be a continuing need
âi Previous action of i th active consumer to integrate cyber-physical system (CPS) advances into the
S(i, i) ith diagonal element of the voltage sensitivity ma- operation, control, and design of these systems.
trix The biggest change the consumers will see in the future
γi Coefficient of grid awareness for i th active con- is more engagement and ability to actively participate in the
sumer Transactive Energy Market (TEM) [2]. As envisioned, large
ui (ai , ρ) Payoff function of i th active consumer commercial, industrial customers, and individual homeowners
ΠiPT Perceived payoff of i th active consumer will be able to participate directly in markets set up by
the utility or by third party aggregators. For an individual
K. Jhala, B. Natarajan and A. Pahwa are with the Department of Elec- customer, it will be impossible to keep track of various
trical and Computer Engineering, Kansas State University, Manhattan, KS-
66506, USA, (e-mail: kumarsinh@k-state.edu; bala@k-state.edu; pahwa@k- decisions that will be required in real-time as well as in
state.edu) the immediate future in a highly dynamic transactive energy

1949-3053 (c) 2018 IEEE. Personal use is permitted, but republication/redistribution requires IEEE permission. See http://www.ieee.org/publications_standards/publications/rights/index.html for more information.
This article has been accepted for publication in a future issue of this journal, but has not been fully edited. Content may change prior to final publication. Citation information: DOI 10.1109/TSG.2018.2810819, IEEE
Transactions on Smart Grid
2

market. Therefore, each home is expected to be equipped maximize some utility function (e.g., energy costs [9]) under
with a home energy management system [3]–[6] or a complex some constraints (levels of comfort/convenience [10]). One
computer, which will use real-time electricity price, real-time approach is to implement direct load control where a utility or
data on loads/generation, and customer preferences to schedule an aggregator can remotely control certain loads in a house-
different devices in homes. These efforts primarily focus on hold based on an a priori agreement [11]. User privacy is the
cost saving for the consumer as discussed thoroughly in the primary barrier for large scale implementation of such direct
next subsection. However, it is important to note that at the load control methods. Alternately, smart pricing (e.g., critical
utility level, new dynamics may emerge due to participation peak pricing (CPP), TOU pricing and real time pricing (RTP))
of new active customers in the market place that could create can be used to encourage consumers to individually manage
conditions detrimental to reliability and resiliency of the their loads [12]. A plethora of deterministic centralized and
system. Utilities will have to implement appropriate controls distributed optimization [13], model predictive control [14],
to keep the system stable and within bounds. High penetration reinforcement learning [15] as well as game theoretic methods
of solar PV can also cause technical issues as recently reported [16] have been proposed to attack these problems. Recently,
for Hawaii [7], where the utilities are refusing interconnection there have been some efforts to systematically model uncer-
of additional rooftop PV systems due to operating issues. To tainties in this framework and implement stochastic versions
address some of these challenges it is important to integrate of optimization [17], and dynamic programming [18] methods.
physical grid constraints and economic aspects resulting in
techno-economic analysis of the underlying grid. There is a plethora of research in the area of smart buildings
With the anticipated growth in active consumers, modeling energy management systems. Authors in [19] define a building
consumer behavior to changing price of electricity is a crucial management system that controls energy flow inside a smart
aspect of this work. Although the most common reaction for building with renewable energy sources and energy storage
any consumer is to take actions which will save money, there using a heuristic optimization process. [20] reviews some of
are consumers who give more importance to other factors such the technical opportunities provided by internet of things in
as environment and comfort. Frugal consumers are typically smart building management area. Authors in [21] build a build-
more concerned about saving money at the cost of comfort ing energy management system including a grid-connected
and environment. Green consumers give higher importance to PV system and a storage system using the mixed-integer
the environment relative to money and comfort. On the other linear programming framework for the purpose of optimizing
hand, comfort maybe the most important aspect for affluent scheduling of building elements in order to achieve a pre-
consumers. Additionally, there may be consumers who do not specified objective. In [22], an intelligent residential energy
care and thus they will not make any adjustments to their management system to reduce electricity bills for prosumers
power usage pattern based on pricing. Many prior efforts of smart residential buildings is proposed, and its benefits are
attempt to model consumer actions in response to pricing demonstrated through a case study.
within the framework of game theory.
Traditional game theory assumes that players in the game Many of the prior efforts in the area of DR and DG
are rational and uninfluenced by real-life perceptions. Most of management tend to take a user/home centric approach. That
game theoretic work in smart grid are based on assumption that is, the goal is to minimize energy costs for a home owner by
consumers make decisions according to their expected utility. scheduling and reducing load and managing generation and
However, real-life decision making of consumers is influenced storage [23]–[26]. While this is an essential step in under-
by their perceived subjectivity which cannot be explained by standing optimal actions for a consumer, it is important to note
expected utility theory (EUT). A Nobel Prize winning theory, that the consumer is not acting in isolation and the operational
Prospect Theory [8] explains the fact that people usually over- cost and stability of the grid is dependent on the cumulative
weigh low probability bad outcomes and under-weigh high actions of multiple consumers. This aspect was brought out
probability favorite outcomes. This work uses the Prospect in [16], where a demand side management scheme based on
Theory to capture subjective behavior of active consumers for collaborative game theoretic approach is proposed. The efforts
uncertain price of electricity. A unique aspect of this work within the control theory community that focuses on modeling
is the modeling of a wide range of consumers and their consumer behavior also rely on deterministic frameworks [27].
behavior/response to pricing using the Prospect Theory. A data driven approach to model consumers demand response
behavior was presented in [28], where authors hypothesize a
A. Related work long term steady behavior and short term dynamic response
Over the past decade, there have been numerous efforts that behavior. Since, the analysis was data based, the generality of
have attempted to model, manage and optimize participation of this model is unclear. There have been many game theoretic
consumers in the power distribution system. These efforts can efforts to address some of the challenges in smart grid. All
be broadly classified into two classes: (1) demand response these efforts use classical EUT assuming rational behavior
(DR) programs focusing only on load management; (2) de- of players [29], [30], which is not pragmatic. There are few
mand response and distributed generation (DG) management. efforts that use the Prospect Theory to address some of the
The first dimension of the work relates to residential demand challenges in power systems. Most of these efforts are limited
response, which typically leverages price and generation fore- to investigating the energy interactions between micro-grids
casts to either shift or reduce load consumption in order to [31], [32].

1949-3053 (c) 2018 IEEE. Personal use is permitted, but republication/redistribution requires IEEE permission. See http://www.ieee.org/publications_standards/publications/rights/index.html for more information.
This article has been accepted for publication in a future issue of this journal, but has not been fully edited. Content may change prior to final publication. Citation information: DOI 10.1109/TSG.2018.2810819, IEEE
Transactions on Smart Grid
3

B. Contributions
This work proposes a Prospect Theory based model of active
consumers making subjective actions under uncertain price
of electricity and analyzes the impact of their actions on the
distribution grid voltage. Major contributions of this paper are
listed below.
• This work models interaction between an aggregator and
multiple active consumers connected to a power distribu-
tion system as a Stackelberg leader-follower game, where
the aggregator acts as a leader and the active consumers
are followers.
• A general model that efficiently captures consumers
with varying preferences for electricity consumption is
considered. For the first time, the subjective behavior
of consumers in response to variations in the price of
electricity is modeled using the Prospect Theory.
• Behavior of the aggregator is modeled by considering
both technical and economic aspects of grid operation.
Fig. 1: System Model
The economic goal of maximizing profit is integrated with
the technical goal of maintaining the grid voltage within
permissible limits in the game formulation.
decides the price of electricity that maximizes the profit while
• Actions of active consumers at the Nash equilibrium and
keeping voltages of distribution system within limits.
its impact on the distribution grid voltage is analyzed
In a Transactive Energy Market, each active consumer can
using simulations on the modified IEEE 69 bus test
interact with the grid by changing its energy consumption
system.
or by providing real power support from the local renewable
• The difference between expected utility theory to the
generation. In essence, each consumer chooses an action a i ,
Prospect Theory formulations are highlighted. Specifi-
which is power drawn from the grid or power supplied back
cally the impact of lack of rationality on the physical
to the grid. The consumer’s choice of action a i is based
grid voltage and monetary payoffs for both the consumer
on its perceived payoff that is determined by the price of
and the aggregator is quantified.
electricity. It should be noted that the payoff could depend
The paper is organized as follows. Section II presents a on more than a single metric. For example, the payoff for
system model with an overview of the Prospect Theory and the an active consumer could depend on (1) cost of electricity;
Stackelberg game. A model of active consumers with different (2) comfort achieved by consuming energy, and (3) impact
preferences for electricity consumption is derived in section of their action on the distribution grid voltage. Aggregation
III. Behavior of the aggregator and its best response action is of payoff metrics in the payoff vector to decide the optimal
derived in section IV. Nash equilibrium of the proposed game action would depend on the class to which the consumer
and effect of active consumers on the grid voltage is observed belongs. Goal of a comfort seeking consumer is to maximize
using simulation on the modified IEEE 69 bus test system in the comfort achieved by consuming energy. Some consumers
section V. Conclusions are presented in section VI. may want to minimize the cost of electricity consumption.
Active consumers who consider the physical grid voltage while
II. System Model making their decision want to keep the distribution grid voltage
The future power distribution systems will involve multiple at the node of connection close to the rated value. While
active consumers interacting with a third party aggregator as at this point of time, a grid-conscious consumers may seem
shown in Fig. 1. This paper considers a scenario where mul- utopian, it is interesting to model and consider the impact
tiple active consumers that are part of the power distribution of such customers. One may expect such consumer types
network have a contractual agreement with a third party aggre- in community owned microgrids where the social aspect of
gator. The aggregator buys electricity in a day-ahead wholesale maintaining grid constraints play an important role. In this
market from the independent system operator (ISO) and sells work, it is assumed that a consumer connected to node i
it to consumers. Any additional energy required is purchased of the distribution system knows i th diagonal element of the
in the real-time market. Based on the day-ahead agreement sensitivity matrix, which is used to compute change in voltage
that the aggregator makes with ISO, the aggregator decides at node i due to change in action of i th consumer. Additionally,
the electricity pricing to influence electricity consumption of electricity prices would be communicated to consumers by the
active consumers. In addition to all financial transactions, the aggregator over the cyber infrastructure. Price of electricity,
aggregator is also responsible for maintaining the grid voltage which is decided by the aggregator, can take values from
within allowable limits. In case of a voltage violation, the a set ρ, where ρ = {ρ1 , ρ2 , · · · , ρn }. However exact price of
aggregator pays a penalty to the electric utility company that electricity is unknown to consumers. The aggregator decides
owns the physical grid infrastructure. Therefore, the aggregator the probability distribution of electricity prices. Let P be vector

1949-3053 (c) 2018 IEEE. Personal use is permitted, but republication/redistribution requires IEEE permission. See http://www.ieee.org/publications_standards/publications/rights/index.html for more information.
This article has been accepted for publication in a future issue of this journal, but has not been fully edited. Content may change prior to final publication. Citation information: DOI 10.1109/TSG.2018.2810819, IEEE
Transactions on Smart Grid
4

where p is the objective probability and ω(p) is the subjective


w(p) 1

0.9 α = 0.5 probability. Here α is the coefficient of rationality that reveals


0.8
α = 1.0 how a person’s subjective evaluation distorts the objective
0.7
probabilities (P). Active consumers who are more rational
0.6
have higher value for coefficient of rationality (α), whereas
0.5 customers that are more subjective have lower α. Fig. 2 shows
0.4 probability weighting function for α = 0.5 and α = 1.0,
0.3 where α = 1 implies that player is completely rational and
0.2 behaves according to the EUT. Using the Prospect Theory, this
0.1 work develops a model of a general active consumer that may
0
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
not behave rationally and makes subjective decisions. In the
p proposed system model, the home energy management system
Fig. 2: Probability weighting function ω(p) makes real-time decisions on behalf of active consumers. Such
devices must be programmed according to their preferences.
Different consumers can have different preferences for energy
of probabilities given by: consumption and their preference can be possibly irrational,
  especially in the presence of uncertainty. For example, some
P = P(ρ = ρ1 ), P(ρ = ρ2 ), · · · , P(ρ = ρn ) T . (1) consumers may be more risk taking while some may be more
risk averse and this variability is captured in the Prospect
Active consumers decide their energy consumption based on
Theory based model. In either case, consumer preferences
their perceived probability distribution of electricity prices.
and their inherent irrationality can be programmed into such
The Prospect Theory is used to understand decision making
smart home energy management system. Since devices merely
of a subjective consumer under uncertainty.
reflect consumer choices, they will not override any irrational
choice made by a risk aware consumer even if it contradicts an
A. Expected Utility Theory vs Prospect Theory objective option. Interaction between the consumers and the
aggregator is modeled as a Stackelberg leader-follower game
Traditional game theory assumes that players behave ratio- as discussed next.
nally while making decisions under risk. Most game theoretic
studies in the field of power system assume that player
makes decisions according to their expected utility. However, B. Stackelberg Game
it is well known that people do not behave rationally under In game theory, Stackelberg leadership model is a strategic
uncertainty and their decisions are influenced by their real- game in which the leader moves first and then the followers
life perception. Traditional Expected Utility Theory (EUT) move sequentially. In the power distribution system model this
cannot explain deviations in player’s actions due to end user corresponds to the following: the aggregator plays a mixed
subjectivity as illustrated by Allaiss paradox [8]. strategy first. The active consumers observe mixed strategy of
The Prospect Theory (PT) provides a user-centric view to the aggregator and decide energy consumption that maximizes
address this issue by applying probability weighting effect their payoff function. Existence of the Stackelberg equilibrium
to transform objective probabilities of players into subjective is dependent on the following assumptions: (1) the leader
probabilities [8], [33]. The Nobel Prize winning theory ex- chooses the optimal strategy first and it is irreversible, (2) the
plains the fact that people usually over-weigh low probability leader knows ex ante that the followers observe the strategy,
outcomes and under-weigh outcomes with moderate to high and (3) the followers have no means of committing to a
probabilities, which the EUT fails to explain [8]. According non-Stackelberg follower action and the leader knows this. In
to the PT, people use their subjective probabilities (ω(p)) this scenario, it is assumed that the aggregator will play the
rather than objective probabilities (p) to weight the values optimal mixed strategy estimating the best response action of
of possible outcomes. This phenomenon is observed in many the active consumers. The active consumers will observe the
social science studies. Authors in [33] propose an original mixed strategy played by the aggregator and play their best
form of probability weighting function based on experiments. response action under uncertain price of electricity. In this
Although, there have been numerous efforts to mathemat- Stackelberg leader-follower game between the consumers and
ically model the subjectivity in human behavior, most of the aggregator, the aggregator act as a leader that plays mixed
these models are mathematically complex, which makes them strategy by deciding probability distribution for electricity
difficult to use in real-life. Authors in [34] developed a new prices and the consumers are followers that play pure strategy
version of the Prospect Theory using cumulative representation by deciding the power drawn or injected into the grid.
of uncertainty that captures risk aversion for gains and risk The proposed Prospect Theory based framework is general
seeking behavior for losses of high probability with in a low enough to be used for real-time or day-ahead applications.
complexity analytical form. Therefore, in this paper the one The proposed game theoretic framework models behavior of
proposed by Prelec in [34] is used and corresponds to irrational active consumer for only one time instant, which
can be used to model elasticity of loads. However, it does
ω(p) = exp(−(− log p) α ), 0 ≤ α ≤ 1, (2) not capture time dependent model of an active consumer’s

1949-3053 (c) 2018 IEEE. Personal use is permitted, but republication/redistribution requires IEEE permission. See http://www.ieee.org/publications_standards/publications/rights/index.html for more information.
This article has been accepted for publication in a future issue of this journal, but has not been fully edited. Content may change prior to final publication. Citation information: DOI 10.1109/TSG.2018.2810819, IEEE
Transactions on Smart Grid
5

behavior. A time dependent model of active consumer behavior the ith node in the distribution system is also assumed to
along with correlated load scheduling will be pursued as part know ith diagonal element of the sensitivity matrix, which
of the future work which will capture shift in demands due to can be used to compute change in voltage at node i due to
price of electricity. change in power at node i. An analytical method to compute
sensitivity matrix is proposed in [36], [37], using which an
III. Active Consumer Modeling active consumer can compute i th diagonal element of the
sensitivity matrix (S(i, i)). Goal of grid aware active consumers
Modeling different consumer types, capturing their prefer-
is to keep the voltage at point of connection close to the
ences and reactions to changes in electricity price and renew-
rated value by adjusting electricity consumption by minimizing
able generation is challenging. Consumers may belong to dif-
γi (v(i) + S(i, i)(â i − ai ) − 1)2 .
ferent socioeconomic classes with different value or preference
In this work, type of consumers are differentiated based on
for electricity consumption. In the Transactive Energy Market,
their comfort requirement, price responsiveness and awareness
the active consumers decide their energy consumption based
towards grid voltage. The proposed framework is general
on price of electricity that they receive from the aggregator.
enough to accommodate size and elasticity of different types
Actions of consumers are based on their perceived payoff.
of consumers. So, other categories/types of consumers (i.e.
The payoff function could be composed of more than a single
residential, commercial and industrial) can be seamlessly in-
objective. For example, in this work, the payoff function of
tegrated into the model. Since actions of such consumers will
an active consumer incorporates three metrics corresponding
be primarily dictated by their priorities/preferences, we use
to economics, comfort and environmental costs. The payoff
the comfort, price, and grid awareness categories to highlight
function for i th active consumer can be written as:
the efficiency of the proposed approach. For example, among
ui (ai , ρ) = βi log(ai + Ri + 1) − ρai − γi (v(i) + S(i, i)(â i − ai ) − 1)2 residential consumers we may have some who prefer to keep
(3) cost low while some may choose to pay higher cost to maintain
where, ai is action of active consumer that represents energy their comfort levels. Similarly among industrial consumers,
purchased from the grid or sold to the grid. R i is the amount grid stability might be more important.
of renewable generation available to the i th consumer, which
Theorem 1. The payoff function of active consumer u i (ai , ρ)
is known to the aggregator, and β i is the comfort coefficient to
given by equation (3) is a concave function of a i .
represent comfort seeking level of a particular active consumer.
Each active consumer gains some utility for consuming elec- Proof. The payoff function for an active consumer is sum of
tricity as per the energy gain function, which can be written as following three terms: 1) β i log(ai + Ri + 1), 2) −ρai , and 3)
βi log(ai +Ri +1) [35]. The energy gain function of a consumer −γi (v(i) + S(i, i)(â i − ai ) − 1)2 . First term βi log(ai + Ri + 1) is
is an increasing function of a i with diminishing returns. For concave function of a i for βi > 0 and ai > −Ri . Second term
instance, an active consumer consuming less energy benefits is an affine function of a i , and third term −γ i (v(i) + S(i, i)(â i −
much more from receiving additional unit of energy than the ai ) − 1)2 is also concave function of a i . As sum of concave
active consumer consuming higher energy. ρ is the price of functions is concave, payoff function for an active consumer
electricity that a consumer pays to the aggregator. The active shown in equation (3) is concave function of a i . 
consumer have to pay ρa i amount of money to the aggregator.
The electricity price, which is decided by the aggregator
v(i) is the distribution grid voltage at node i, and â i indicates
is unknown to the active consumers. The active consumers
previous action of the i th active consumer when voltage at node
observe the probability distribution of uncertain electricity
i of the distribution grid was v(i). S(i, i) is i th diagonal element
price and decide their action. The active consumers decides
of the voltage sensitivity matrix, and γ i is coefficient of grid
the optimal strategy based on the perceived payoff. Equation
awareness that indicates level of the i th consumer’s concerns
(4) represent expected payoff of an active consumer according
for the grid voltage while taking action. Positive values of a i
to the EUT, whereas equation (5) shows perceived payoff of
indicates that the active consumer is buying energy from the
an active consumer according to the Prospect Theory.
grid and negative values of a i indicate that the active consumer 
is selling energy back to the grid. a i > −Ri , which implies that ΠiEUT = ui (ai , ρ j )P(ρ = ρ j ) (4)
the active consumer cannot sell more energy than produced j
by the renewable generation. Different consumers may give 
different weightage to different metrics. Aggregation of these ΠiPT = ui (ai , ρ j )ω(P(ρ = ρ j )) (5)
metrics into a single payoff function to decide the optimal j

action would depend on the class to which the active consumer Goal of the active consumers is to maximize their perceived
belongs. For example, a highly comfort seeking consumer may payoff based on their subjective probabilities, which is given
have higher values of β i compared to a low comfort seeking by equation (5). Theorem 2 shows the best response action of
consumer. an active consumer.
This work assumes that consumers can measure the dis-
tribution grid voltage at their node of connection. However, Theorem 2. The best response action of an active consumer
information about voltage at nodes other than node i is not that maximizes its perceived payoff is given by equation (6).
available to an active consumer not connected at node i −2z
a∗i = arg max ΠiPT =  , (6)
of the distribution grid. An active consumer connected to ai y − y2 − 4xz

1949-3053 (c) 2018 IEEE. Personal use is permitted, but republication/redistribution requires IEEE permission. See http://www.ieee.org/publications_standards/publications/rights/index.html for more information.
This article has been accepted for publication in a future issue of this journal, but has not been fully edited. Content may change prior to final publication. Citation information: DOI 10.1109/TSG.2018.2810819, IEEE
Transactions on Smart Grid
6

where, where x, y and z are given by equation (7)(8) and (9). 


x = −2γi S(i, i)2 , (7)
Although an individual active residential consumers may
not cause or solve voltage violation in the distribution system
due to relatively low value of energy consumption or gener-
y = 2γi S(i, i)(v(i) + S(i, i)â i − 1) − P̂ − 2γi S(i, i)2 (Ri + 1) (8) ation, commutative actions of multiple active consumers with
distributed energy sources could cause voltage changes in the
power distribution system, which would be detrimental to all
z = βi − P̂(Ri + 1) + 2γi S(i, i)(v(i) + S(i, i)â i − 1)(Ri + 1) (9) consumers. In the envisioned transactive energy system with
Proof. The perceived payoff of an active consumer for taking consumer owned distributed generation, voltage violations can
action ai for given mixed strategy of the aggregator can be be avoided by raising consumer awareness about grid voltage
written by substituting equation (3) in (5): and programming grid awareness into smart home energy
management systems. Additionally, large industrial consumers
 with large load/generation can make a significant impact on
ΠiPT = βi log(ai + Ri + 1) − ρ j ai voltage profile and may have to pay penalties for voltage
j
 (10) violations. In such scenarios, the active consumers may care
−γi (v(i) + S(i, i)(â i − ai ) − 1)2 ω(P(ρ = ρ j )) about the grid voltage profile. This is especially applicable
for microgrid environment, where the distribution system is
The active consumers take an action that maximizes their
more prone to voltage fluctuations. However, in this work,
perceived payoff Π iPT . Let a∗i be an optimal action of the active
violations in the distribution system voltages are not modeled
consumer given by:
as a hard constraint, which may results in infeasible solution.
a∗i = arg max ΠiPT , (11) Although idea of grid aware consumers may be futuristic
ai
at this point, this work demonstrates that one way to solve
where a∗i is the optimal action of an active consumer that voltage violation in the future smart grid is by the active
maximizes the perceived payoff. The optimal action of an consumer participation. Further, this work assumes that the
active consumer can be found by differentiating the perceived aggregator and the active consumers can calculate the line
payoff by action of the active consumer and equating it to voltage at the point of grid connection using smart meter
zero. data. This will allow the active consumer to know the grid
voltage. Based on the voltage information and location of
∂ΠiPT
=0 the household in the grid, an active consumer can compute
∂ai
  value of S(i, i) using an analytical method of voltage sensitivity
βi (12) analysis proposed in [36], [37]. Further, this work assumes that
− ρ j − 2γi S(i, i)(v(i)
j
a i + Ri + 1 the aggregator has some method of estimating coefficient of
rationality of the active consumers. In practice, the aggregator
+S(i, i)(âi − ai ) − 1)] ω(P(ρ = ρ j )) = 0,
can observe past responses of active consumers to change
Dividing with ω(P(ρ = ρ j )) we wet in price of electricity and the distribution system voltages
to estimate coefficient of rationality α i and other behavioral
βi j ρ j ω(P(ρ = ρ j ))
− parameters such as βi and γi . This can be done using regression
a i + Ri + 1 j ω(P(ρ = ρ j )) (13) and curve fitting algorithms. There is a plethora of techniques
− 2γi S(i, i)(v(i) + S(i, i)(â i − ai ) − 1) = 0. available in the area of machine learning to estimates the
Let P̂ be the perceived price of electricity defined as: best response strategy of the active consumers. Exact method
of estimating such parameters is outside the scope of this
j ρ j ω(P(ρ = ρ j )) research. We believe that the advances in data analytic in the
P̂ = . (14)
j ω(P(ρ = ρ j ))
smart grid domain will make this feasible in the near future.
Based on estimated best response actions of all the active
Substituting equation (14) into equation (13): consumers, the aggregator decides the optimal probability
βi distribution of electricity prices that maximizes the payoff.
− P̂ − 2γi S(i, i)(v(i) + S(i, i)(â i − ai ) − 1) = 0. (15)
a i + Ri + 1
Multiplying equation (15) with a i + Ri + 1 and simplifying to IV. Behavior of the Aggregator
standard quartic form, we get Goal of the aggregator is to maximize the monetary profit
 while improving voltage profile of the power distribution
− 2γi S(i, i)2 a2i + 2γi S(i, i)(v(i) + S(i, i)â i − 1) − P̂
  grid. The aggregator purchases A kWh of energy from day-
−2γi S(i, i)2 (Ri + 1) ai + βi − P̂(Ri + 1) (16) ahead market at cost ρ da unit/kWh. Any additional energy
 is purchased in the real-time market at ρ rt unit/kWh. It is
+2γi S(i, i)(v(i) + S(i, i)â i − 1)(Ri + 1) = 0
assumed that the aggregator knows best response action of all
Solution of above quadratic equation corresponds to: active consumers. In other words, the aggregator is assumed
−2z to know βi , γi , Ri , v, S, âi and the coefficient of rationality for
a∗i =  (17)
y − y2 − 4xz all the active consumers. The impact of lack of knowledge or

1949-3053 (c) 2018 IEEE. Personal use is permitted, but republication/redistribution requires IEEE permission. See http://www.ieee.org/publications_standards/publications/rights/index.html for more information.
This article has been accepted for publication in a future issue of this journal, but has not been fully edited. Content may change prior to final publication. Citation information: DOI 10.1109/TSG.2018.2810819, IEEE
Transactions on Smart Grid
7

incorrect information about consumer behavior is analyzed in


the results section. Let a be a vector of the best response action
of all the active consumers, â be a vector of previous action
of all the active consumers, v be a vector of the distribution
grid voltage and S be the sensitivity matrix. Payoff function
of the aggregator can be written as:
ua = PT ρaT 1 − ρda A − θv + S(â − a) − 1 − ρrt (aT 1 − A), (18)
where 1 is vector of all 1’s and θ is the coefficient of grid
awareness for the aggregator that indicates how much the ag-
gregator is committed to maintaining the physical grid voltage.
Here, PT ρaT 1 indicates the total income of the aggregator Fig. 3: Change in consumer action with coefficient of rationality
from money charged to the active consumers. Second term in
equation (18), ρ da A, is the amount that the aggregator pays TABLE I: Consumer Types

to the independent system operator (ISO) for buying bulk Consumer Type β γ
electricity in the day-ahead market. Last term in equation (18), A - Highly comfort-seeking and grid aware 0.85 1
B - Comfort-seeking and grid aware 0.75 1
ρrt (aT 1 − A), indicates the cost of additional energy purchased C - Comfort-seeking and grid unaware 0.75 0
from the real-time market. Finally, v + S( â − a) − 1 is the D - Low comfort-seeking and grid aware 0.40 1
metric that indicates deviation of the distribution grid voltage
from the rated voltage. The aggregator decides the probability
distribution of electricity prices that maximizes (18). observe the aggregator’s mixed strategy and decide their opti-
Theorem 3. For 0.11 ≤ P ≤ 0.91, payoff function of an mal response based on their perceived probability distribution.
aggregator is a concave function of P . This leader follower game results in a Stackelberg equilibrium
where all the active consumers and the aggregator are playing
Proof. Payoff function of the aggregator is given by equation their optimal strategy. Change in the Stackelberg equilibrium
(18). From lemma 1, it can be proven that the optimal action with change in consumer type and rationality and their impact
of an active consumer a i is a convex decreasing function of P. on physical grid voltage is investigated in the next section.
As sum of convex functions is convex, a Ti 1 is also a convex
function of P for 0.11 ≤ P ≤ 0.91. V. Simulation and Results
The first term of equation (18), P T ρaT 1 is a concave
To investigate the Stackelberg equilibrium of the proposed
function of P as it is product of a linearly increasing function
system, we use a modified IEEE 69 bus system as shown in
of P (PT ρ) and a convex decreasing function of P (a T 1). The
Fig. 3. A scenario is considered where four type of active con-
second term of equation (18), −ρ da A is a constant. As convex
sumers exist in the distribution grid. Type-A active consumers
function of a convex function is convex, −θv + S( â − a) − 1
are highly comfort-seeking and consider grid voltage while
is a concave function of P. From lemma 1, it can be shown
making decisions. Type-B active consumers are relatively
that −ρrt (aT 1 − A) is a concave function of P as ρ rt and A are
low comfort-seeking and are also grid aware. Type-C active
constant. Summation of concave functions is concave leading
consumers have the same level of comfort requirement as type-
to Theorem 3.
B active consumers but they do not consider physical grid

voltage while making decisions, and type-D active consumers
The optimal mixed strategy of the aggregator corresponds are the least comfort-seeking with the lowest value of β.
to (19) Table I summarizes the type of active consumers and their
P∗ = arg max ua , (19) value of β and γ. In order to maintain fairness of weights,
P values of β and γ are normalized using weight fairness model
which can be found numerically. Based on estimated best proposed in [38]. Fig. 3 shows location of different kind of
response of the active consumers, the aggregator decides active consumers in the distribution grid. There are no active
the optimal probability distribution of electricity prices that consumers connected to bus 1 to 3. Note that the modeling
maximize the aggregator’s objective function, which is the and analysis approach is general and is applicable to other
Stackelberg equilibrium strategy of the aggregator. In a highly scenarios as well. For simplicity in interpretation, renewable
dynamic transactive energy market, electricity prices changes generation for each active consumer (R i ) is set at 10 kWh.
in real-time. In the proposed system model, the aggregator The price of electricity can take one of the following values:
can determine the distribution for price of electricity (based (1) 0.1 unit/kWh; (2) 0.5 unit/kWh, and (3)1.0 unit/kWh
on estimated response) and announce mixed strategy to the (ρ = {0.1, 0.5, 1.0}). For this case, the optimal mixed strategy
active consumers. This probability distribution for electricity of the aggregator at the Stackelberg equilibrium is shown in
price can be treated as the preliminary handshake process that Table II. Actions of a consumer in response to the optimal
establishes equilibrium electricity prices. The aggregator will mixed strategy of the aggregator are shown in Fig. 4(a) and
decide and announce the actual price of electricity based on corresponding distribution grid voltage levels are shown in Fig.
the equilibrium probability distribution. The active consumers 4(b). From Fig. 4(a) it can be seen that energy consumptions

1949-3053 (c) 2018 IEEE. Personal use is permitted, but republication/redistribution requires IEEE permission. See http://www.ieee.org/publications_standards/publications/rights/index.html for more information.
This article has been accepted for publication in a future issue of this journal, but has not been fully edited. Content may change prior to final publication. Citation information: DOI 10.1109/TSG.2018.2810819, IEEE
Transactions on Smart Grid
8

8 35
Action of Consumer (kWh)
P(ρ = 0.1) = 0.2
6 P(ρ = 0.5) = 0.8

Action of Active Consumer (kWh)


30
P(ρ = 0.1) = 0.8
4 P(ρ = 0.5) = 0.2

25
2

0 20

-2
15
-4
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70
(a) Consumer Index 10
0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
Coefficient of Rationality
1.05
Fig. 5: Change in active consumer action with coefficient of rationality
Node Voltage (p.u.)

the methodology presented in this paper.


1
Fig. 5 shows change in consumer action with rationality
level of the active consumer. An active consumer is considered
with β = 0.65, γ = 1, R i = 10kWh located at node 16 of the
IEEE 69 bus test system. In this scenario price of electricity
0.95 can take only two values 0.1(unit/kWh) and 0.5(unit/kWh)
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70
(b) Node Number (ρ = {0.1, 0.5}). The curve with triangle markers represents
a case where P(ρ = 0.1) = 0.8 and P(ρ = 0.5) = 0.2, and
the expected value of price of electricity is 0.18 unit. It can
Fig. 4: Stackelberg equilibrium and corresponding voltage level
be observed that the active consumers with lower rationality
TABLE II: Stackelberg equilibrium strategy of the aggregator
are more risk averse when expected price of electricity is low.
Curve with diamond marker represent a case where P(ρ =
Price of electricity (ρ) 0.1 0.5 1.0
0.1) = 0.2 and P(ρ = 0.5) = 0.8, with the expected value of
Probability P(ρ) 0.16 0.18 0.66
price of electricity of 0.42 unit. The active consumers with
lower rationality are more risk taking when expected price of
electricity is high for lower values of α.
of type-A active consumers are much higher compare to the Fig. 6 shows change in the aggregator profit and number of
other active consumers because of higher value of β i . On the voltage violations at the Stackelberg equilibrium for different
contrary, type-D active consumers which are low comfort- coefficient of rationality of the active consumers. Here, it is
seeking prefer to sell some of the renewable generation back assumed that all the active consumers have same coefficient
to the grid in order to make more money resulting it negative of rationality and the aggregator is assumed to know it. From
values of ai . Voltages at bus 28 to 35 are higher than 1 p.u. Fig. 6(a) it can be seen that the aggregator’s monetary profit
because of the active consumers injecting power into the grid. decreases as the active consumers become more rational. This
Although all type-B active consumers have same value of β implies that the aggregator can exploit irrational behavior of
and γ, their actions are different because they adjust their the active consumers. Grid aware the active consumers modify
energy consumption in accordance with physical grid voltage their power based on voltage at the point of connection. How-
as shown in Fig. 4(a). On the other side, actions of all type-C ever, the profit of the aggregator depends on how the active
consumers are the same as they do not consider physical grid consumers respond to changes in electricity prices. Therefore,
voltage while making their decisions. The best response action the profit of the aggregator does not change significantly based
of an active consumers can be computed using analytical on grid awareness of consumers. Fig. 6(b) shows number of
expression provided by Theorem 2, which can be computed voltage violations at the Stackelberg equilibrium for different
quickly. For the aggregator, computation of the optimal mixed coefficient of rationality, when the active consumers have high
strategy requires estimation of the best response strategy of coefficient of grid awareness (γ = 1) and when the active
all the active consumers. Although the exact computational consumers are grid unaware (γ = 0). It can be seen from
complexity of such estimation can vary based on the exact Fig. 6(b) that number of voltage violations are less when the
method used, this step has to be performed only once and does active consumers are grid aware. Fig. 6(b) also shows that
not have to be done in real-time. Once the best response action number of voltage violations decrease as consumers behave
of all the active consumers is estimated, the optimal mixed more rationally.
strategy of the aggregator P ∗ can be computed numerically To highlight difference between the EUT and the Prospect
as unconstrained convex optimization problem. Computation Theory models, we consider two different scenarios and ob-
time to calculate the Stackelberg equilibrium for the IEEE 69 serve action of the active consumers for each case. In case one,
bus distribution system is 1.81 second. We have used IEEE the support set for price of electricity is ρ = {0.1, 0.5, 1.0}
69 bus distribution system, which is adequate to demonstrate and for the second case support set for price of electricity

1949-3053 (c) 2018 IEEE. Personal use is permitted, but republication/redistribution requires IEEE permission. See http://www.ieee.org/publications_standards/publications/rights/index.html for more information.
This article has been accepted for publication in a future issue of this journal, but has not been fully edited. Content may change prior to final publication. Citation information: DOI 10.1109/TSG.2018.2810819, IEEE
Transactions on Smart Grid
9

Profit of Aggregator (unit) 350 Coefficent of rationality = 0.5

Action of Consumer (kWh)


Grid unaware consumers 6
300
Grid aware consumers 5
250
200 4
150 3
100
2
50 Price of electricity ∈ {0.1 0.5 1.0}
0
1
Price of electricity ∈ {0.5 0.7 1.0}
0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 0
Coefficient of Rationality 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70
(a) (a) Consumer Index
Number of Voltage Violations

25 Coefficent of rationality = 0.9

Action of Consumer (kWh)


6
Grid unaware consumers
20 Grid aware consumers 5

15 4

10 3

2
5
1
0
0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 0
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70
Coefficient of Rationality
(b) (b) Consumer Index

Fig. 7: Change in consumer behavior with change in reference price level


Fig. 6: (a) Change in the aggregator profit at equilibrium with coefficient of rationality
(b) Corresponding number of voltage violations

is ρ = {0.5, 0.7, 1.0}. In both the scenarios expected price 5


Action of Customer (kWh)

of electricity is kept the same to 0.9 unit/kWh. All other 4


parameters are kept the same in both cases. According to
the EUT, the action of the active consumers should be the 3

same in both cases, which is not the case in reality. When


2
the active consumers are not completely rational, their actions
P(ρ = 0.1) = 0.16 Coefficient of rationality = 0.7
differ in both cases as shown in Fig. 7. Fig. 7(a) and 7(b) 1 P(ρ = 0.5) = 0.18 Coefficient of rationality = 0.8
P(ρ = 1.0) = 0.66
show actions of all the active consumers when coefficient Coefficient of rationality = 0.6
of rationality for all the active consumers are set to 0.5 0
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70
and 0.9 respectively. From Fig. 7(a), it can be observed that Consumer Index

actions of the active consumers are very different for these Fig. 8: Active consumer actions for different coefficient of rationality
scenarios when the active consumers are relatively less rational
(α = 0.5); however, actions of the active consumers are
almost the same for both scenarios as they are highly rational α = 0.7 for all the active consumers. If coefficient of rationality
(α = 0.9) as shown in Fig. 7(b). for all the active consumers is 0.6 or 0.8, actual response of
the active consumers is represented by curve with diamond
The active consumers with different levels of rationality take
and hexagram markers respectively. This shows that incorrect
different actions under the same probability distribution of
estimation of coefficient of rationality can result in actions
electricity price. A scenario is considered when there is an
different from actions expected from the consumers.
error in the aggregator’s estimate of coefficient of rationality
Number of physical voltage violations can be reduced when
(α). The aggregator decides the optimal mixed strategy as-
the active consumers do consider physical voltage while taking
suming αi = 0.7 for all the active consumers. However, actual
actions. To observe change in number of voltage violations
coefficient of rationality for the active consumers is different.
with γ, a scenario is considered where α = 0.8 and β = 0.85 for
In this scenario, values of β = 0.85 and γ = 1 are assumed
all the consumers. Fig. 9 shows change in number of voltage
to be known to the aggregator. Sample space for the price
violation for different values of γ. As value of γ increases
of electricity is {0.1, 0.5, 1.0} and the optimal mixed strategy
number of voltage violations decrease.
of the aggregator is {0.16, 0.18, 0.66} assuming α = 0.7.
Fig. 8 shows response of the active consumers for a given
mixed strategy of the aggregator. Expected response of the VI. Conclusion and Future-work
active consumers by the aggregator is represented by curve This work develops a Prospect Theory based realistic model
with triangle markers, which corresponds to the case where of the active consumers with varied preferences for electricity

1949-3053 (c) 2018 IEEE. Personal use is permitted, but republication/redistribution requires IEEE permission. See http://www.ieee.org/publications_standards/publications/rights/index.html for more information.
This article has been accepted for publication in a future issue of this journal, but has not been fully edited. Content may change prior to final publication. Citation information: DOI 10.1109/TSG.2018.2810819, IEEE
Transactions on Smart Grid
10

8 [11] C. Chen, J. Wang, and S. Kishore, “A distributed direct load control ap-
proach for large-scale residential demand response,” IEEE Transactions
7 on Power Systems, vol. 29, no. 5, pp. 2219–2228, Sept 2014.
Number of Voltage Violations

6
[12] A. Faruqui and S. George, “Quantifying customer re-
sponse to dynamic pricing,” The Electricity Journal,
5 vol. 18, no. 4, pp. 53–63, 2005. [Online]. Available:
http://EconPapers.repec.org/RePEc:eee:jelect:v:18:y:2005:i:4:p:53-63
4
[13] A. H. Mohsenian-Rad and A. Leon-Garcia, “Optimal residential load
3 control with price prediction in real-time electricity pricing environ-
ments,” IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid, vol. 1, no. 2, pp. 120–133,
2 Sept 2010.
1 [14] E. Vrettos, K. Lai, F. Oldewurtel, and G. Andersson, “Predictive control
of buildings for demand response with dynamic day-ahead and real-
0 time prices,” in 2013 European Control Conference (ECC), July 2013,
0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0
γ→
pp. 2527–2534.
[15] Z. Wen, D. ONeill, and H. Maei, “Optimal demand response using
Fig. 9: Change in number of voltage violation at equilibrium with γ device-based reinforcement learning,” IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid,
vol. 6, no. 5, pp. 2312–2324, Sept 2015.
[16] A. H. Mohsenian-Rad, V. W. S. Wong, J. Jatskevich, R. Schober,
and A. Leon-Garcia, “Autonomous demand-side management based on
consumption and different levels of rationality. The interaction game-theoretic energy consumption scheduling for the future smart
between the active consumers and the aggregator is modeled grid,” IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid, vol. 1, no. 3, pp. 320–331,
Dec 2010.
as a Stackelberg leader-follower game from a techno-economic [17] Z. Chen, L. Wu, and Y. Fu, “Real-time price-based demand response
perspective by including physical grid constraints in terms of management for residential appliances via stochastic optimization and
voltage violation within the analysis. The interaction between robust optimization,” IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid, vol. 3, no. 4,
pp. 1822–1831, Dec 2012.
the active consumers and the aggregator is analyzed using [18] D. Eryilmaz, T. Smith, S. Dhople, E. Wilson, and J. Schmitt, “Demand
simulations on the IEEE 69 bus test system. Impact of con- response for industrial-scale energy users in midwest iso: A dynamic
sumer actions and irrationality on physical grid voltage and the programming approach for curtailing energy use,” in 2014 IEEE PES T
D Conference and Exposition, April 2014, pp. 1–4.
aggregator payoff is quantified using simulation. Developing a [19] D. Arnone, V. Croce, G. Patern, A. Rossi, S. Emma, R. Miceli,
time dependent model of the active consumer behavior along and A. O. D. Tommaso, “Energy management of multi-carrier smart
with correlated load scheduling will be pursued in the future buildings for integrating local renewable energy systems,” in 2016
IEEE International Conference on Renewable Energy Research and
work. Applications (ICRERA), Nov 2016, pp. 845–850.
[20] D. Minoli, K. Sohraby, and B. Occhiogrosso, “Iot considerations,
requirements, and architectures for smart buildings x2014;energy op-
VII. Acknowledgment timization and next-generation building management systems,” IEEE
Internet of Things Journal, vol. 4, no. 1, pp. 269–283, Feb 2017.
The authors would like to thank the NSF for providing [21] Y. Wang, Y. Xu, Z. Dong, and W. Zhang, “Multi-stage planning and
support for this research through award No. CNS-1544705. economic analysis of intelligent energy management system in a smart
building,” in 10th International Conference on Advances in Power
The views expressed in this paper are of the authors. System Control, Operation Management (APSCOM 2015), Nov 2015,
pp. 1–6.
[22] S. L. Arun and M. P. Selvan, “Intelligent residential energy management
References system for dynamic demand response in smart buildings,” IEEE Systems
Journal, vol. PP, no. 99, pp. 1–12, 2017.
[1] “The smart grid: An introduction,” US DOE Publication, 2008. [23] K. Jhala, B. Natarajan, A. Pahwa, and L. Erickson, “Coordinated electric
[2] “Gridwise transactive energy framework version 1.0,” The GridWise vehicle charging solutions using renewable energy sources,” in 2014
Architecture Council, January 2015. IEEE Symposium on Computational Intelligence Applications in Smart
[3] R. B. Jr, J. Romanowiz, and C. Staples, “Energy management and home Grid (CIASG), Dec 2014, pp. 1–6.
automation system,” US Patent 5,544,036, 1996. [24] ——, “Coordinated electric vehicle charging for commercial parking
[4] M. Kuzlu, M. Pipattanasomporn, and S. Rahman, “Hardware demon- lot with renewable energy sources,” Electric Power Components and
stration of a home energy management system for demand response Systems, vol. 45, no. 03, pp. 344–353, 2017. [Online]. Available:
applications,” IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid, vol. 3, no. 4, pp. 1704– http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/15325008.2016.1248253
1711, Dec 2012. [25] ——, “Real-time differential pricing scheme for active consumers
[5] M. Pipattanasomporn, M. Kuzlu, and S. Rahman, “An algorithm for with electric vehicles,” Electric Power Components and Systems,
intelligent home energy management and demand response analysis,” vol. 45, no. 14, pp. 1487–1497, 2017. [Online]. Available:
IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid, vol. 3, no. 4, pp. 2166–2173, Dec https://doi.org/10.1080/15325008.2017.1362074
2012. [26] K. Jhala, “Coordinated electric vehicle charging with renewable energy
[6] M. A. A. Pedrasa, T. D. Spooner, and I. F. MacGill, “Coordinated sources,” Master’s Thesis, Department of Electrical and Computer
scheduling of residential distributed energy resources to optimize smart Engineering, Kansas State University, Aug 2015. [Online]. Available:
home energy services,” IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid, vol. 1, no. 2, http://krex.k-state.edu/dspace/handle/2097/19767
pp. 134–143, Sept 2010. [27] I. O. Volkova, M. V. Gubko, and E. A. Salnikova, “Active consumer:
[7] D. Cardwell, “Solar power battle puts hawaii at forefront of worldwide Optimization problems of power consumption and self-generation,”
changes,” New York Times, April 2015. Automation and Remote Control, vol. 75, no. 3, pp. 551–562, 2014.
[8] D. Kahneman and A. Tversky, “Prospect theory: An analysis of [Online]. Available: http://dx.doi.org/10.1134/S0005117914030114
decision under risk,” Econometrica, vol. 47, no. 2, pp. 263–291, 1979. [28] S. Ghosh, X. A. Sun, and X. Zhang, “Consumer profiling for demand
[Online]. Available: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1914185 response programs in smart grids,” in IEEE PES Innovative Smart Grid
[9] S. Salinas, M. Li, and P. Li, “Multi-objective optimal energy consump- Technologies, May 2012, pp. 1–6.
tion scheduling in smart grids,” IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid, vol. 4, [29] N. Zhang, Y. Yan, S. Xu, and W. Su, “Game-theory-based electricity
no. 1, pp. 341–348, March 2013. market clearing mechanisms for an open and transactive distribution
[10] S. Althaher, P. Mancarella, and J. Mutale, “Automated demand response grid,” in 2015 IEEE Power Energy Society General Meeting, July 2015,
from home energy management system under dynamic pricing and pp. 1–5.
power and comfort constraints,” IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid, [30] N. Zhang, Y. Yan, and W. Su, “A game-theoretic
vol. 6, no. 4, pp. 1874–1883, July 2015. economic operation of residential distribution system with

1949-3053 (c) 2018 IEEE. Personal use is permitted, but republication/redistribution requires IEEE permission. See http://www.ieee.org/publications_standards/publications/rights/index.html for more information.
This article has been accepted for publication in a future issue of this journal, but has not been fully edited. Content may change prior to final publication. Citation information: DOI 10.1109/TSG.2018.2810819, IEEE
Transactions on Smart Grid
11

high participation of distributed electricity prosumers,” Applied 2


Energy, vol. 154, pp. 471 – 479, 2015. [Online]. Available: ∂2 √ 1 −1 ∂2 b 1 −3 ∂b
http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0306261915006212 b= b 2 − b 2 (23)
[31] L. Xiao, N. B. Mandayam, and H. V. Poor, “Prospect theoretic analysis ∂ P̂2 2 ∂ P̂2 4 ∂ P̂
of energy exchange among microgrids,” IEEE Transactions on Smart ∂b
Grid, vol. 6, no. 1, pp. 63–72, Jan 2015. = P̂[2−4γi S(i, i)(v(i)+S(i, i)â i−1+S(i, i)(Ri +1))] ≥ 0 (24)
[32] Y. Wang, W. Saad, N. B. Mandayam, and H. V. Poor, “Integrating energy ∂ P̂
storage into the smart grid: A prospect theoretic approach,” in 2014 IEEE
International Conference on Acoustics, Speech and Signal Processing ∂2 b
= [2−4γi S(i, i)(v(i)+S(i, i)â i −1+S(i, i)(Ri +1))] ≥ 0 (25)
(ICASSP), May 2014, pp. 7779–7783. ∂ P̂2
2 √
[33] A. Tversky and D. Kahneman, “Advances in prospect theory:
Cumulative representation of uncertainty,” Journal of Risk and Therefore, ∂∂P̂2 b ≥ 0. From this it can be proved that
Uncertainty, vol. 5, no. 4, pp. 297–323, 1992. [Online]. Available: 
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF00122574 y2 − 4xz is convex non-decreasing function function. 
[34] D. Prelec, “The probability weighting function,” Econometrica,
vol. 66, no. 3, pp. 497–528, 1998. [Online]. Available:
http://EconPapers.repec.org/RePEc:ecm:emetrp:v:66:y:1998:i:3:p:497-
528
[35] M. N. Faqiry and S. Das, “A budget balanced energy distribution
mechanism among consumers and prosumers in microgrid,” in 2016 Kumarsinh Jhala (S’14) received the B.E. degree
IEEE International Conference on Internet of Things (iThings), Dec in electronics and communication engineering from
2016, pp. 516–520. Gujarat Technological University, Ahmedabad, In-
[36] K. Jhala, B. Natarajan, and A. Pahwa, “Probabilistic voltage sensitivity dia, and the M.S. degree in electrical engineering
analysis (pvsa) - a novel approach to quantify impact of active con- from Kansas State University, Manhattan, KS, USA
sumers,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. PP, no. 99, pp. 1–1, in 2013 and 2015, respectively. Currently, he is
2017. a Ph.D. candidate in department of electrical and
[37] ——, “Probabilistic voltage sensitivity analysis (pvsa) for random spatial computer engineering at Kansas State University,
distribution of active consumers,” in 2018 IEEE Power Energy Society Manhattan, KS, USA. His research interests include
Innovative Smart Grid Technologies Conference (ISGT), Feb 2018, pp. power systems and smart grid technologies, cyber
1–5. physical security, stochastic signal processing, game
[38] L. Akter and B. Natarajan, “Modeling fairness in resource allocation theory, mathematical modeling, networked control theory, and wireless com-
for secondary users in a competitive cognitive radio network,” in 2010 munication. Mr. Jhala is a member of honor society of Eta Kappa Nu and Phi
Wireless Telecommunications Symposium (WTS), April 2010, pp. 1–6. Kappa Phi.

Appendix A
Concavity Analysis
Balasubramaniam Natarajan (SM’08) received
Lemma 1. Optimal action of an active consumer a ∗i , given by the B.E. degree (Hons.) in electrical and electronics
equation (6), is convex decreasing function of P. engineering from Birla Institute of Technology and
Science, Pilani, India, and the Ph.D. degree in elec-
Proof. Numerator of equation (6) is linear and decreasing trical engineering from Colorado State University,
Fort Collins, CO, USA, in 1997 and 2002, respec-
function of P̂. Denominator of (6) is y − y2 − 4xz, where tively. Since Fall 2002, he has been a Faculty Mem-
x, y, and z are given by equation (7), (8),and (9). Here y is ber of the Department of Electrical and Computer
linear and decreasing function of P̂; and y2 − 4xz is convex Engineering, Kansas State University, Manhattan,
KS, USA, where he is currently a Clair N. Palmer
and decreasing function of P̂, which is proved in lemma 2. As and Sara M. Palmer Endowed Professor and the
reciprocal of a positive convex function is convex, it can be Director of the Wireless Communication and Information Processing Research
shown that √−12 is convex and increasing function of P̂ Group. His research interests include statistical signal processing, stochastic
y− y −4xz modeling, optimization, and control theories. He has worked on applications
and product of such two functions is concave. spanning wireless communications, sensor networks, biomedical, and cyber
 physical systems. He has published nearly 180 refereed journal and conference
articles along with a book titled Multicarrier Technologies for Wireless
Lemma 2. Action of an active consumer that maximizes its Communications.
perceived payoff given by equation (6).

y2 − 4xz, (20)
Anil Pahwa (F’03) received the B.E. (honors)
where, x, y, and z is given by equation (7), (8), and (9) is degree in electrical engineering from BITS-Pilani,
convex and increasing function of P. India, in 1975, the M.S. degree in electrical engineer-
ing from University of Maine, Orono, in 1979, and
Proof. Let b = y2 − 4xz. Therefore, the Ph.D. degree in electrical engineering from Texas
√   A&M University, College Station, in 1983. Since
b = 2γi S(i, i)(v(i) + S(i, i)â i − 1 − S(i, i)(Ri + 1)) 2 + P̂2 1983, he has been with Kansas State University,
Manhattan, where presently he is University Distin-
− 4P̂γi S(i, i)(v(i) + S(i, i)â i − 1 − S(i, i)(Ri + 1)) + 8γi S(i, i)2 guished Professor and holds the Logan-Fetterhoof
0.5 Chair in the Electrical and Computer Engineering
[βi − P̂(Ri + 1) + 2γi S(i, i)(v(i) + S(i, i)â i − 1)(Ri + 1)] . Department. The National Academy selected him as
(21) a Jefferson Science Fellow in 2014 to serve as a Senior Science Advisor
in the U.S. State Department for one year. He worked in the East Asian and
Taking first and second order derivative: Pacific Affairs Bureau on international policies to facilitate higher deployment
∂ √ 1 −1 ∂b of renewable energy. His research interests include distribution automation,
b= b2 (22) distribution planning, renewable energy integration into power systems, and
∂ P̂ 2 ∂ P̂ intelligent computational methods for distribution system applications.

1949-3053 (c) 2018 IEEE. Personal use is permitted, but republication/redistribution requires IEEE permission. See http://www.ieee.org/publications_standards/publications/rights/index.html for more information.

Potrebbero piacerti anche