Sei sulla pagina 1di 19

CEO Incentives

Jean McGuire
and Corporate Sandra Dow
Social Performance Kamal Argheyd

ABSTRACT. This paper examines the relationship Stakeholder theory, in contrast, emphasizes the
between CEO incentives and strong and weak cor- firm’s relations with a wider range of implicit and
porate social performance. Using the KLD database explicit stakeholders (Donaldson and Preston,
we find that incentives have no significant relation- 1995; Jones, 1995; Jones and Wicks, 1999).
ship with strong social performance. Salary and long- These theoretical perspectives raise the issue of
term incentives have a positive association with weak
whether corporate governance mechanisms
social performance.
developed primarily to protect shareholder inter-
KEY WORDS: corporate governance, executive ests affect the firm’s performance toward a wider
compensation, social performance, social responsibility variety of stakeholders and performance criteria.
This study builds upon prior research in two
ways. There have been few studies of the rela-
Although the relationship between corporate tionship between the various components of
governance and firm financial performance has executive compensation and firm performance.1
received considerable scrutiny, the impact of cor- Executive incentives are a visible and potentially
porate governance on social performance has important mechanism through which owners and
received less attention. This topic, however, is the board of directors can direct managerial
of significant theoretical and practical impor- attention to specific objectives having both finan-
tance. North American corporate governance cial and social implications. Compensation can
mechanisms emphasize shareholder wealth therefore be a potentially important mechanism
maximization (Amihud and Lev, 1981; Fama, for directing managerial attention to social
1980). As a result, corporate governance may objectives. Indeed, the financial rewards given to
focus managerial attention upon shareholder executives may signal the firm’s commitment to
objectives over the interests of other stakeholders. social performance, and may provide “substance”
to corporate social policies. Second, we examine
both weak, or poor, social performance (socially
Jean McGuire earned her Ph.D. from Cornell University. dubious or risky behavior) and strong social per-
She is professor of management at the John Molson formance (exemplary social performance or a
School of Business, Concordia University. Her research firm’s willingness to exceed expectations for
focuses on corporate governance, including international social performance). Most previous research has
corporate governance. implicitly conceptualized social performance
Sandra Dow earned her Ph.D. from Concordia University. along a single continuum. We argue that the vari-
She is associate professor of finance at the École des
ables that encourage “exemplary” corporate per-
Sciences de la Gestion, Université du Québec à
Montréal. Her research focuses on corporate governance formance may differ from those that discourage
and international finance. dubious social performance. Indeed, much
Kamal Argheyd has a DBA from the Harvard Business previous research has, implicitly or explicitly,
School. He teaches strategy at the John Molson School focused on “poor” social performance (Bansal
of Business, Concordia University. His research inter- and Celland, 2000; Makendall, Sanchez, & P.,
ests are cross-cultural management and business ethics. 1999; McKendall et al., 1999). In essence,

Journal of Business Ethics 45: 341–359, 2003.


© 2003 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands.
342 Jean McGuire et al.

existing research tells us little about the factors of this study is whether corporate governance
that encourage exemplary social performance, or mechanisms focus managerial attention on finan-
its implications. There are, however, strong the- cial performance objectives that impact a firm’s
oretical arguments to suggest that the factors social performance.
associated with strong social performance may Existing empirical evidence suggests that cor-
differ from those associated with poor social per- porate governance mechanisms may promote
formance. The following section will outline the shareholder interests over those of other financial
theoretical framework for the study. stakeholders (Caves, 1976; Cruchley et al., 1999;
Gavish and Kalay, 1983; John and John, 1993),
and may direct managerial attention toward
Stakeholder theory, corporate governance, financial objectives. This is not necessarily incon-
and social performance gruent with instrumental or descriptive stake-
holder theory: stakeholders as well as their
Although it is tempting to draw a clear distinc- particular concerns, differ in their salience to
tion between agency theory formulations of cor- management (Jones, 1995).
porate governance and stakeholder theory, Most relevant to our theoretical argument,
particularly instrumental stakeholder theory, both however is that the performance objectives
theoretical perspectives view the firm as a targeted by executive compensation may have
network of contracts with stakeholders (Fama, implications for social performance as well as
1980; Jones, 1995). Although corporate gover- financial performance. It is therefore critical to
nance mechanisms in other contexts incorporate examine the particular performance objectives
a wider range of stakeholders (e.g. employees in implied by various components of executive
Germany), North American corporate gover- compensation. This approach is also congruent
nance mechanisms focus on shareholders as the with the argument that the institutional context
primary stakeholder (Eisenhardt, 1989; Fama and surrounding managerial decision making, specif-
Jensen, 1983). ically here executive compensation, influences
Stakeholder theory examines the firm in the expectations regarding social performance (Jones,
context of a wider range of implicit and explicit 1999).
stakeholders having legitimate expectations, By defining managerial performance standards
urgent claims, and/or power regarding the firm and expectations, executive incentives may direct
(Jones, 1995; Jones et al., 1999; Mitchell et al., managerial attention to specific outcomes or
1997). The broader approach inherent in stake- objectives that have both financial and social
holder theory requires that the interests of implications (Donaldson et al., 1995; Jones
multiple stakeholders be considered in manage- et al., 1999). Simply stated, managerial incentives
rial decision-making. The interests of any one may encourage strategies (or implementation
given stakeholder (e.g. shareholders) should not methods) having positive or negative implications
dominate at the expense of others (Clarkson, for social performance. For example, high levels
1995; Hillman and Keim, 2001; Jones et al., of compensation in the form of short-term bonus
1999). payments may lead executives to focus on the
The concept of corporate social performance more immediate “bottom line”, rather than
evaluates how well firms have met expectations building longer-term stakeholder relations.
of stakeholders and environmental concerns. It Recent cases such as the Enron and WorldCom
therefore focuses on the outcome of firm actions bankruptcies suggest that stock-based incentives
(Griffin, 2000). Clearly, stakeholder management may encourage executives to disregard social per-
and corporate social performance are distinct formance in pursuit of market price increases
constructs (Hillman et al., 2001). Building upon (Despeignes and Hill, 2002; Parker, 2002).
Wood (1991) we view social performance as the Further, Jones and Wicks (1999) argue that firm
extent to which a firm meets the performance social performance is often subject to manage-
expectations of important stakeholders. The focus rial discretion. The nature of executive com-
CEO Incentives and Corporate Social Performance 343

pensation consequently influences the use of such but may show weak social performance along
discretion in the area of social performance. others, for example labor and employee relations.
In addition to its theoretical interest, the A firm could exhibit both strong and weak social
relationship between executive compensation performance along a single dimension. To illus-
and social performance has important practical trate, the Kinder, Lindenberg, Domini data used
implications. Perhaps more so than other aspects in this study (described in more detail below)
of corporate governance such as ownership noted that IBM exhibited strong environmental
structure and board of director structure or com- performance in its communication efforts, but
position, executive compensation can be manip- performed poorly in its treatment of hazardous
ulated by the board of directors to reward wastes. Further, firm social performance may
managers for pursuing specific objectives. In be “strong” or “dubious” for several reasons,
developing executive compensation plans, and including negative impact on important stake-
awarding executive incentives, the board of direc- holders, raises/addresses more general social
tors can encourage management to pursue social, concerns, and the like.
as well as financial objectives. Thus, compensa- Particularly in the context of corporate gov-
tion can be an important mechanism to promote ernance-social performance relations, however,
the implementation of the firm’s social objectives. the factors contributing to strong social perfor-
Further, institutional investors, particularly mance (a more pro-active position in which the
“activist” investors, have identified corporate firm exceeds usual expectations or performs
governance, and specifically executive compen- particularly well) and weak social performance
sation, as a major area of scrutiny (Prevost and (socially risky strategies or those which do not
Rao, 2000; Wahal, 1996). Much of this attention meet usual norms or expectations) may differ.
has focused on the high levels of compensation Corporate governance, specifically executive
awarded and the limited sensitivity of executive incentives, may have a stronger relationship with
pay to firm performance. The broader social per- “avoidance” of poor social performance than
formance implications of executive compensation with the adoption of exemplary social perfor-
have received less attention. Understanding of the mance. Compensation typically does not reward
social performance implications of executive exemplary social performance (Murphy, 2000).
compensation is relevant to those advocating cor- Rather, incentive payments and salary increases
porate governance reform. tend to focus on the achievement of financial
and strategic objectives, as well as labor market
factors. There is little theoretical reason to believe
Social strengths and social weaknesses: Distinct that such financial and strategic objectives provide
dimensions or a continuum? incentives for exemplary social performance.
Indeed, Donaldson et al. (1995) argue that
Most previous research has viewed high or low managerial discretion and decision making play
social performance along a single continuum. a critical role in determining the firm’s social per-
Although studies have disaggregated social per- formance objectives. Congruent with steward-
formance in terms of stakeholders or substantive ship theory (Davis et al., 1997) managers may
performance dimensions (such as employee/ seek to work in the best interests of a wide range
community issues, environmental performance) of stakeholders. Even beyond this perspective,
(e.g. Johnson et al., 1999; McKendall et al., managerial beliefs and discretion, rather than the
1999), there has been no examination of the constraints and incentives provided by corporate
validity of a continuum of strong to weak social governance, are likely to be the principal drivers
performance. Indeed, it may be quite possible of exemplary social performance. For example,
for firms to exhibit both strong and weak social the strong social orientation of firms such as The
performance. A firm may exhibit strong social Body Shop or Ben and Jerry’s Ice Cream (under
performance along one dimension of social per- founding ownership) were more likely a reflec-
formance, for example environmental concerns, tion of corporate philosophy and managerial
344 Jean McGuire et al.

beliefs than corporate governance (Hartman and Bonus and social performance
Beck-Dudley, 1999; Smith, 2000). Consequently,
our hypotheses will distinguish between weak or We expect a positive association between short-
poor social performance (socially dubious or term incentives (bonus) and weak corporate
risky social performance) and strong social per- social performance. Bonus payments reward
formance (a pro-active social stance or exemplary executives for achievement of short-term per-
social performance). formance targets, rather than for building the
This is not to imply that compensation has no firm’s long term potential (Stata and Maidique,
impact on the adoption of a pro-active position 1980). Further, the performance targets specified
regarding social performance. Rather, it may in bonus plans are almost exclusively financial in
form part of the institutional context which con- nature (Murphy, 2000). A major motivation for
strains management’s attention to social objec- less socially responsible actions may be to
tives, or their ability to implement pro-active improve the short term “bottom line” (Auperle
social performance objectives (Jones, 1999). CEO et al., 1985; McGuire et al., 1988; McKendall
incentives may signal the board’s priorities et al., 1999; McWilliams and Siegel, 2000). This
regarding social and financial objectives. A firm motivation may be particularly relevant when the
whose compensation policies are characterized by executive received significant bonus compensa-
high levels of incentive payments based upon tion. Thus we propose:
achievement of financial performance objectives
may signal the dominance of achieving perfor- H1a: There will be a positive association
mance objectives. Even socially concerned exec- between bonus and weak social perfor-
utives may accommodate such signals. Further mance.
selection bias may also contribute to a negative This logic also suggests a negative association
association between certain forms of managerial between bonus and strong social performance. As
compensation and exemplary social performance. noted earlier, short term incentives are typically
Simply stated, the “socially pro-active” CEOs based upon achievement of financial and strategic
most likely to implement strong social programs objectives, rather than social objectives (Murphy,
may avoid firms in which a “bottom line” 2000). They would therefore provide little
orientation dominates. stimulus for strong social performance. Indeed
bonus compensation may tend to focus manage-
rial attention on financial objectives to the detri-
CEO compensation and social ment of other objectives. Further, a substantial
performance: Research hypotheses bonus component in executive compensation
may signal a “bottom line”, performance-driven
This section more fully discusses the links corporate orientation that may influence man-
between managerial incentives and firm social agerial decision-making. Executive selection
performance. The major elements of executive processes (either by the board or through “self
compensation are fixed compensation (salary), selection”) may further lead management to
short-term incentives, long-term incentives focus on financial objectives.
(which include stock options, other forms of
market based compensation, and non-market H1b: There will be a negative association
based long term incentive plans) (Murphy, 1999). between bonus and strong social per-
Equity ownership provides an additional mech- formance.
anism of managerial incentives. The following
section will outline hypotheses linking each
element of managerial incentives to social per- CEO equity ownership and social performance
formance.
Two arguments concerning the relationship
between CEO ownership and corporate social
CEO Incentives and Corporate Social Performance 345

performance can be made. On the one hand, findings regarding inside ownership-social per-
inside ownership may direct managerial attention formance relations. McKendall et al. (1999)
to performance and shareholder well-being, found a negative relationship between inside
rather than the interests of other stakeholders ownership and illegal corporate activities. These
(McKendall et al., 1999). If, indeed, a trade-off studies, however, focused on the broader
exists between shareholder wealth maximization category of “inside” owners, which encompass
and social performance, this would imply a a broad range of holdings, including ESOPs and
negative association between executive owner- holdings by a wide range of insiders and their
ship and strong social performance. families. However, the limited decision making
A further argument for a positive relationship power of this broader class of owners differs from
between CEO ownership and poor social per- that of the CEO. Reputational effects may also
formance is based upon managerial entrenchment be more limited. In view of this ambiguity, we
and hubris. High levels of CEO ownership may will offer alternative hypotheses.
promote management entrenchment (Shleifer
and Vishny, 1989). Building upon Hayward and H2a: There will be a positive association
Hambrick (1997), significant ownership may between inside ownership and weak
encourage hubris which may lead managers to social performance.
underestimate the risks of poor social perfor- H2b: There will be a negative association
mance. between inside ownership and weak
Although the previous arguments held that social performance.
significant ownership implies performance pres- Entrenchment and hubris arguments also
sures that encourage weak social performance, suggest a positive relationship between CEO
the ownership-social performance relationship ownership and strong social performance. As sug-
may be more complex. As noted earlier, the exis- gested earlier, high levels of CEO ownership may
tence of a social performance-financial perfor- promote management entrenchment (Shleifer et
mance trade-off is far from certain. Moreover, al., 1989). We noted earlier that pro-active social
significant ownership stakes may link executive agendas may reflect managerial or organizational
reputation to the firm. Particularly, given man- beliefs. The protection and power offered by
agement’s numerous links to the firm, manage- large ownership stakes may allow executives the
rial wealth may be more closely tied to the firm freedom to implement pro-active social agendas.
than is the case for outside investors. In essence, Just as hubris arguments suggest that managers
managers may therefore bear more of the may discount the risks of socially risky behavior,
“downside” risk of socially irresponsible actions significant owner managers may discount the
in terms of both financial risk (Fama et al., 1983; risks of pro-active social agendas in terms of crit-
Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Zajac and Westphal, icism of the financial costs of exemplary social
1994), as well as damage to their reputation, than performance or reduced attention to the “bottom
outside owners. Building upon the behavioral line”.
agency model (Wiseman and Gomez-Mejia,
1998; Sanders, 2001) it could be argued that H2c: There will be a positive association
ownership stake may lead to more conservative between CEO ownership and strong
strategies as managers seek to preserve their social performance.
wealth. Such wealth preservation motives may
lead managers to avoid potentially costly socially
dubious behavior. Long-term incentive compensation and social
Again, empirical results have been mixed. performance
Although both studies used the Kinder,
Lindenberg, and Domini, ratings of social per- The relationship between social performance and
formance, Johnson and Greening (1999) and long-term incentives revolves around the issue of
Simerly and Bass (1996) report contradictory whether socially responsible actions build the
346 Jean McGuire et al.

firm’s long-term potential. Since stock options a CEO would take a pro-active stance regarding
and other equity-based compensation are a major social performance in hopes of greater incentive
component of long-term incentive compensation compensation. Rather, a strong social position is
(Murphy, 1999), the social performance impli- more likely an issue of executive beliefs than
cations of long-term compensation may parallel wealth maximization.
those of inside ownership. Long term incentives The performance pressures implied by long
such as stock options, stock appreciation rights, term incentives may encourage CEOs to focus
and long-term performance plans typically imply on achievement of financial objectives to the
no actual “loss” on the part of executives. Should detriment of the interests of other stakeholders.
the firm’s market value fall, the executive incurs In essence, the long term benefits of building
an “opportunity cost” of lost income potential. stakeholder relations may be less visible than the
Using decision theory (Kahnman, 1979; strategies that may boost firm market perfor-
Kahnman, 1992), Sanders (2001) argues that mance, at least in the short term. Indeed, stock
stock options (the major component of long options (a major component of long term incen-
term incentives) encourage riskier strategies by tives) have been increasingly criticized for
focusing attention on potential gains, rather than encouraging earnings manipulation and other
loss. Such “riskier” strategies may include socially strategies aimed at improving market perfor-
dubious behavior. Further, stock options provide mance without significantly building shareholder
no actual ownership stake until exercised and value, as illustrated by the financial manipulations
provide a less visible link the CEO to the firm. preceding the Enron and WorldCom bankrupt-
Thus, reputational arguments for a negative asso- cies (Despeignes and Hill, 2002; Parker, 2002).
ciation between stock options and weak social This suggests the following hypothesis:
performance are less convincing. In essence,
stock options may provide greater incentives for H3b: There will be a negative association
socially weak performance than ownership. We between strong social performance and
therefore propose: long term incentives.
H3a: There will be a positive association
between poor social performance and
Salary and social performance
long-term incentives.
There is less reason to expect a positive asso- Although salary has no direct incentive value,
ciation between long-term incentives and good agency theory holds that fixed compensation
social performance. As noted earlier, long-term (salary) may encourage risk aversion and more
incentive compensation is less likely to bring the conservative strategies (Gray and Canella, 1997;
same reputational ties or feelings of “ownership” Jensen and Murphy, 1990; Murphy, 1985; Zajac
as actual equity ownership. Therefore, reputa- et al., 1994). If, indeed, poor social performance
tional arguments for a positive association is considered “risky”, this argument suggests a
between long-term incentives and strong social negative association between salary and poor
performance would be less relevant. It can social performance. High levels of salary may also
be argued theoretically that exemplary social build executives’ firm specific human capital,
performance may bring financial benefits. thereby tying executives to the firm (Gray et al.,
Indeed, this belief may encourage firms toward 1997). Therefore, executives may be less willing
strong social performance. In the context of to risk their firm’s reputation, and possibly their
executive compensation, which focuses manage- continued employment, by less responsible
rial attention on specific performance targets, the actions.
perceived “instrumentality” of strong social per- This line of reasoning is weakened by the
formance would likely be limited in comparison argument that the widespread attention given
to other strategic actions undertaken to improve executive compensation tends to suggest that
firm performance. In essence, it is less likely that excessive salary may prove at least equally threat-
CEO Incentives and Corporate Social Performance 347

ening to executive reputation as poor social per- possible criticism of “excessive” concern for
formance. Indeed, critics might claim that high social issues to the detriment of financial objec-
salary levels are, themselves, indicative of poor tives and may be more able to implement pro-
social performance. Further, mere avoidance of active social agendas. Although arguing that high
poor social performance does little to enhance salary promotes both strong and weak social
managerial reputation. behavior may appear contradictory, they are
Empirically, Berman (1999) found a negative based upon a single logic that high salary levels
association between salary and social responsive- encourage executives to discount the potential
ness. Berman uses instrumental stakeholder negative implications of either strong or weak
theory to argue that high levels of compensation social performance.
divert managerial attention away from a wider In view of these conflicting arguments, we will
range of stakeholders. This finding is also con- propose alternative hypotheses:
gruent with Haward and Hambrick’s (1997)
argument that high salary may encourage H4b: There will be a negative association
managerial hubris. Highly paid executives may between salary and strong social perfor-
therefore minimize possible negative social reper- mance.
cussions of their decisions. H4c: There will be a positive association
between salary and strong social perfor-
H4a: There will be a positive association
mance.
between salary and weak corporate
social performance.
Similarly, the links between salary and strong The moderating effect of activist institutional
social performance may rest upon reputational investment on the corporate governance-social
and hubris/insulation arguments. It is unlikely performance relationship
that high salary provides direct incentives for
exemplary social performance. As noted earlier, Although the role of activist investors in pro-
it might be symbolic of a lack of concern for moting social performance is an important topic
social issues. of research (Prevost et al., 2000; Waddock and
Two counter arguments, however, can be Graves, 1995; Wahal, 1996), the focus of this
made. If, indeed, salary ties managerial social research suggests the need to control for the
capital to the firm, the perceived benefits of direct effects of activist institutional investment.
exemplary social performance may lead highly Perhaps more critical to the focus of this
paid managers to act in socially responsible ways. study, however, is that in addition to any direct
Simply stated, the potential benefits of good relationships between activist institutional invest-
social performance may be more relevant and ment and social performance discussed above,
visible than simply avoiding any negative repu- activist investment may moderate the relationship
tational effects of poor social performance. To between corporate governance and social per-
illustrate, readers will probably find it easier to formance. Large holdings by activist institutional
identify firms (or executives) well known for investors may encourage attention to the social
their strong social orientations, than to identify and environmental priorities of these institutions.
those with negative social reputations. As noted Such priorities may strengthen the compensa-
earlier, highly paid executives are often subject tion-corporate social performance relationship.
to scrutiny and criticism. To some extent, exem- Further, investor activism has frequently
plary social performance may serve to deflect targeted corporate governance, for example in
stakeholder concerns regarding compensation. promoting policies that facilitate shareholder
Hubris/insulation arguments may also come input and openness in corporate governance
into play. Just as high salary may lead managers and managerial accountability for firm actions
to discount the potential negative implications of (Prevost et al., 2000; Wahal, 1996). Such pres-
poor social behavior, they may also downplay sures toward accountability and openness in
348 Jean McGuire et al.

corporate governance may encourage firms to (Graves and Waddock, 1994: Hillman, 2001
look beyond financial performance to address a #460; Johnson et al., 1999). The KLD database
broader range of shareholder concerns. They may used in this study evaluates firm social perfor-
also imply greater management accountability for mance along four dimensions: employee, com-
both financial and social performance. Thus, we munity, product and environmental.3 Reflecting
hypothesize: the reality that firms may exhibit both strengths
and weakness on each dimension of social per-
H5: Holdings by activist institutional formance, social strength and social weakness are
investors will moderate the corporate rated on separate scales ranging from 0 (neutral)
governance-social responsibility rela- to 2 (significant strengths/weakness) for each
tionship. Specifically, dimension. For example, IBM received 1 in
H5a: Relationships between corporate gover- environmental strengths for its communication
nance and strong social performance efforts, but also received a 1 for environmental
will be stronger for firms with higher weakness for its treatment of hazardous waste.
levels of shareholdings by activist insti- Regarding employee issues, it was given a “2”
tutional investors. in strengths, and 0 for weakness. We do not sum
H5b: Relationships between executive incen- the weaknesses and strengths into a single “social
tives and weak social performance will performance” measure for two reasons. Most
be attenuated by high levels of activist obviously, one focus of the study is to examine
institutional investment. the impact of corporate governance on each
dimension of social performance. Empirically,
strengths tend to offset weaknesses, reducing
Methodology variation in the dependent variable.
For each firm, strengths and weaknesses are
Data and sample aggregated along the four dimensions for a
measure of total strengths and total weaknesses.
Data on salary and incentives are taken from We do not analyze differences among the four
Standard and Poor’s Execucomp database. dimensions of social performance or differentiate
Financial and ownership data are taken from the between types of social performance (Hillman et
Disclosure database. Data on corporate social al., 2001; Johnson et al., 1999). The four dimen-
performance are drawn from the Kinder, sions evaluated by KLD each focus on primary
Lindenberg, and Domini Company database as stakeholders. There is no a priori reason to
described below. The final sample consists of 374 expect that corporate governance would favor
firms for which data from the three sources were one dimension over others (Clarkson, 1995;
available.2 Hillman et al., 2001). Empirically, the number of
firms receiving “0” on a dimension would limit
the variance of dimensional measures.4
Social performance measure

Corporate social and environmental performance CEO incentives


is measured by ratings by Kinder, Lindenberg,
and Domini, and Company (KLD), a multidi- Ownership. CEO ownership stake is measured by
mensional Corporate Social Performance the percentage of outstanding shares owned by
database (http://www.socialfunds.com/csb/index. the CEO as reported by Disclosure.
cgi). Data were collected during Winter, 2000.
Examination of the qualitative descriptions of Salary. Salary is measured by CEO salary as
firms showed the date of the ratings as 1999. reported in Execucomp.
KLD data have been used in previous studies
CEO Incentives and Corporate Social Performance 349

Bonus. To reflect the percentage of short-term Results


incentives in the executive’s compensation, we
calculate the percentage of bonus payments in the Executive compensation and firm social performance
CEO’s compensation.
Results of the regression analysis testing
Long-term incentives. We calculate the percentage hypotheses 1 through 4 are presented in Table
of long-term incentive payments (stock options II.7 The model for social strengths has little
and other long-term incentives) in the CEO’s explanatory power with an adjusted R2 of 0.07.
compensation. Neither the control variables tapping industry
and resources nor corporate governance variables
Activist institutional investment. In addition to the appear to influence strong social performance.
need to control for the direct relationship None of our hypotheses regarding the relation-
between activist holdings and CSP, we hypoth- ship between CEO compensation and social per-
esize that activist holdings moderate the incen- formance were supported. It is particularly
tive-CSP relationship. We calculated the interesting that neither bonus nor long term
percentage of shares held by the “activist” incentives discourage strong social performance.
pension funds identified by Wahal (1996) This finding is congruent with our argument that
reported in our sample of firms. Prevost (2000) strong social performance may be primarily
identifies an essentially similar list.5 driven by managerial beliefs.
The model for social weakness has an R2 of
Control variables. We control for firm size, 0.25. The higher explanatory power of this
industry, profitability, and financial slack. Since model supports our argument that corporate
risks and opportunities regarding social perfor- governance has a stronger relationship with weak
mance may vary with the industry, we control social performance. Contrary to Hypothesis 1,
for the firm’s primary SIC code. Profitability and the coefficient for bonus is insignificant. Neither
size have been linked to social performance Hypotheses 2a or 2b were confirmed: the
(McGuire et al., 1988; McKendall et al., 1999; coefficient for CEO ownership is insignificant.
McWilliams et al., 2000; Waddock and Graves, The significant positive coefficient for long-term
1997). They also likely influence salary and incentives confirms Hypothesis 3. Hypothesis 4a
incentive compensation. We therefore use prior is also confirmed. Salary shows a positive rela-
ROA6 and the log transformation of the number tionship with weak social performance.
of employees as control variables. In addition On the whole, these results suggest that cor-
to the performance-CSP relationships, socially porate governance has relatively limited associa-
responsible activities may be affected by the avail- tion with strong social performance. Neither
ability of financial slack and free cash flow control variables nor corporate governance pre-
(McKendall et al., 1999; McWilliams et al., dicted a pro-active social orientation (social
2000). This variable is measured by leverage and strength). This finding is congruent with the
the times interest earned ratio. Descriptive argument that exemplary social performance may
statistics and correlations are presented in Table be a function of more deeply held managerial
I. It is significant to note that the correlation beliefs or corporate culture relatively insulated
between social weaknesses and social strengths is from outside pressures. Both salary and long-term
very low (0.08) (Table I). This low correlation incentives are positively related to poor social
supports the independence of the two dimensions performance. These findings are congruent with
of social performance. arguments of hubris, as well as the performance
pressures imposed by long-term incentive com-
pensation. At the broader level, these findings are
congruent with arguments that high levels of
executive compensation are indicative of a less
TABLE I
350
Descriptive statistics and correlations

Descriptive statistics

Mean Std. deviation

Size 009.91 001.31


Financial slack 035.72 406.80
Leverage 000.81 001.55
ROA 000.04 000.19
Activist institutional investment 002.28 001.36
Salary 874.91 355.32
Long term incentives 060.86 023.64
Bonus 018.40 015.12
CEO ownership 001.24 004.19
Total strengths 000.73 000.92
Total concerns 000.64 000.96

Correlations

Size Financial Leverage ROA Activist Salary Long Bonus CEO Total Total
Jean McGuire et al.

slack investment term ownership strengths concerns


incents

Size –1.00** –0.09** –0.07 –0.35** –0.13** –0.38** –0.16** –0.07** –0.07** –0.23** –0.20**
Financial slack –0.09** –1.00** –0.07 –0.16** –0.01** –0.04** –0.05** –0.01** –0.00** –0.04** –0.05**
Leverage –0.07** –0.07** –1.00 –0.00** –0.06** –0.02** –0.01** –0.01** –0.03** –0.04** –0.00**
ROA –0.35** –0.16** –0.00 –1.00** –0.11** –0.08** –0.05** –0.10** –0.01** –0.04** –0.10**
Activist institutional investment –0.13** –0.01** –0.06 –0.11** –1.00** –0.02** –0.05** –0.01** –0.11** –0.06** –0.13**
Salary –0.38** –0.04** –0.02 –0.08** –0.02** –1.00** –0.03** –0.01** –0.11** –0.20** –0.30**
Long term incentives –0.16** –0.05** –0.01 –0.05** –0.05** –0.03** –1.00** –0.66** –0.02** –0.13** –0.14**
Bonus –0.07** –0.01** –0.01 –0.10** –0.01** –0.01** –0.66** –1.00** –0.00** –0.03** –0.06**
CEO ownership –0.07** –0.00** –0.03 –0.01** –0.11** –0.11** –0.02** –0.00** –1.00** –0.13** –0.15**
Total strengths –0.23** –0.04** –0.04 –0.04** –0.06** –0.20** –0.13** –0.03** –0.13** –1.00** –0.08**
Total concerns –0.20** –0.05** –0.00 –0.10** –0.13** –0.30** –0.14** –0.06** –0.15** –0.08** –1.00**

** Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed).


* Correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed).
CEO Incentives and Corporate Social Performance 351

TABLE II
Full sample

Dependent variable: Poor social performance

Model Beta T statistic Significance

1 (Constant) –3.08 0.00


Size –0.30 –5.05 0.00
ROA –0.24 –3.79 0.00
Activist institutional investment –0.08 –1.33 0.18
Financial slack –0.00 –0.03 0.97
Leverage –0.04 –0.70 0.49
2 (Constant) –2.63 0.01
Size –0.13 –1.97 0.05
ROA –0.25 –4.07 0.00
Activist institutional investment –0.07 –1.22 0.22
Financial slack –0.00 –0.03 0.98
Leverage –0.04 –0.73 0.47
Salary –0.27 –4.43 0.00
Long term incentives –0.16 –2.09 0.04
Bonus –0.11 –1.46 0.14
CEO ownership –0.06 –1.14 0.26

Model 1 (controls) F Ratio: 7.1; Significance: 0.000 Adjusted R2 = 0.19.


Model 2 (full model) F Ratio: 7.19; Significance: 0.000 Adjusted R 2 = 0.25.

Dependent variable: Strong social performance

Model Beta T statistic Significance

1 (Constant) –2.29 0.02


Size –0.24 –3.66 0.00
ROA –0.07 –0.99 0.32
Activist institutional investment –0.04 –0.69 0.49
Financial slack –0.07 –1.07 0.29
Leverage –0.06 –0.89 0.38
2 (Constant) –1.91 0.06
Size –0.17 –2.26 0.02
ROA –0.08 –1.21 0.23
Activist institutional investment –0.03 –0.52 0.60
Financial slack –0.08 –1.19 0.23
Leverage –0.06 –1.00 0.32
Salary –0.06 –0.90 0.37
Long term incentives –0.11 –1.30 0.19
Bonus –0.01 –0.16 0.87
CEO ownership –0.08 –1.30 0.19

Model 1 (controls) F Ratio: 2.62; Significance: 0.00 Adjusted R2 = 0.06.


Model 2 (full Model) F Ratio: 2.32; Significance: 0.01 Adjusted R 2 = 0.07.
352 Jean McGuire et al.

socially responsible orientation. The significance coefficient for salary is significant and positive.
of long-term compensation, rather than owner- The coefficient for long term incentives, while
ship, is congruent with Sander’s (2001) argument positive, is no longer significant. Activist holdings
that ownership stake is associated with greater remain insignificant. Among firms with high
attention to the potential downside risks of levels of activist investment, the R2 of the
actions than stock options whose downside risk equation increases from 0.15 to 0.21 with the
is limited. Further, the performance pressures inclusion of CEO incentive variables. Both
implied by ownership may be balanced by salary and long-term incentives are significant.
reputational effects. From perhaps a more prag- Interestingly, the coefficient for bonus becomes
matic perspective, levels of stock options and significant and positive. These results suggest
long term incentives typically exceed ownership a counter-intuitive finding that the positive
levels (Conyon and Murphy, 2000). The lack of association between salary and long term incen-
significance for ownership may reflect the lower tives and poor social performance is stronger
levels of ownership stake as compared to the among firms with high levels of activist institu-
value of long-term incentives. tional investment. Further, bonus compensation
The lack of significance for bonus did not becomes significantly related to poor social per-
support our hypotheses. However, there has been formance among firms with high levels of activist
considerable debate as to the incentive power of investment. In neither sub-sample is the coeffi-
bonus payments. Simply stated, critics have cient for activist institutional investment signifi-
argued that given the potential for CEO’s to cant.
manipulate accounting performance numbers, Turning to the equations for strong social per-
and their control over the board of directors, formance, in neither sub-sample is the coefficient
“bonus” payments provide very little incentive for activist institutional investment significant.
value. This criticism argues that CEO’s often Among firms with low levels of activist holdings,
receive their bonus regardless of firm perfor- there is a slight increase (0.02) in the R2 with the
mance (Anderson, 1995; Boyd, 1994; Conyon addition of CEO incentive variables. None of the
and Peck, 1998; Crystal, 1991; Healy, 1985). If individual coefficients, however, are significant.
this were the case, executives would have little The equation for the high activist institutional
reason to engage in poor social performance to investment sub-sample has little predictive
achieve bonus targets.8 validity. Neither category of institutional invest-
ment predicts social strengths.
Although it might have been expected that
The moderating effect of activist institutional high levels of activist institutional investment
investment might lead to stronger CEO incentive-social per-
formance relationships, this is not the case. The
Although we found no direct effects of activist findings of stronger relations between executive
holdings on social responsibility, Hypothesis 5 compensation and poor social performance
postulates that higher levels of activist holdings among firms with high levels of activist invest-
might moderate the relationship between cor- ment are puzzling. However, Wahal (1996)
porate governance and social performance. We suggests that a major concern of activist funds is
therefore split the sample at the median level of the establishment of effective corporate gover-
activist holdings and repeated the preceding nance to assure that management focuses on
analyses. These results are presented in Table III. shareholder value. In essence, the pension funds
The top portion of Table III reports the results examined in this study may have focused their
for the equation for poor social performance. attention on shareholder accountability. Further,
Among firms with lower levels of activist insti- a major area of concern for activist investors is
tutional holdings, we found a small (0.03) corporate governance, and most specifically exec-
increase in the R2 with the addition of CEO utive compensation (Prevost et al., 2000). By
incentive variables. As with the full sample, the encouraging increased performance sensitivity in
CEO Incentives and Corporate Social Performance 353

CEO compensation, activist investors may have decision to adopt a pro-active stance along the
encouraged executives to focus on financial per- four dimensions of social performance examined,
formance to the detriment of social performance. is not related to the financial or corporate gov-
To shed some light on this counter-intuitive ernance variables used in this study. This suggests
finding, we went to the web sites for CALPERS that the firm’s decision to become an “exemplary
and TIAA/CREFF, the activist institutions with corporate citizen” is less subject to financial pres-
the most significant holdings in our sample. Both sures and corporate governance pressures than are
web sites give considerable attention to corpo- social weaknesses. This finding is also congruent
rate governance issues, listing areas of particular with the argument that corporate governance
concern and specific corporate governance ini- effects regarding social performance may tend to
tiatives. The CALPERS web site notes that, be more reactive in nature by deterring socially
“The California Public Employees’ Retirement risky behavior. In other words, they might serve
System (known as “CalPERS”) has long been a as a deterrent to potentially damaging actions,
leader in the corporate governance movement. rather than as an incentive to adopt more pro-
As the largest public retirement system in the active stakeholder orientations.
U.S., CalPERS’ Board of Administration has However, we find that high levels of salary and
concluded that “good” corporate governance long-term incentives are related to poor social
leads to improved long-term performance” performance. At the most general level, high
(www.calpers.org). Proxy voting guidelines compensation levels may be indicative of a less
provide extensive discussion of corporate gover- socially responsible orientation. Further, the per-
nance policies, and specifically address CEO per- formance pressures implied by these incentives
formance evaluation and compensation. The may have encouraged managers to engage in
dimensions of social performance tapped by the more socially “risky” behavior. Dividing the
KLD measures, in contrast, are given consider- sample by levels of activist investment supports
ably less attention. The discussion of social the conclusion that corporate governance has
responsibility specifically highlights that social limited effect on strong social behavior. However,
objectives should not take precedence over the we find that the positive association between
organization’s primary objective of financial per- salary and incentives and poor social performance
formance for its members. The TIAA/CREF is stronger among firms with high levels of
annual report states: “In the area of executive activist holdings. Although initially surprising,
compensation, the oversight role of shareholders anecdotal evidence suggests that pay-performance
is taking on increasing importance. TIAA- sensitivity is a major concern of activist investors.
CREF’s Policy Statement addresses several exec- Our findings may reflect a “trade-off ” between
utive compensation issues, including the role of corporate governance objectives and other
stock and stock options” (www.tiaa-cref.org). elements of social performance.
Little mention is given of social objectives. This Several areas of future research can be sug-
superficial exploration supports the argument that gested. The relatively modest significance of both
activist investors may focus on issues of share- control variables and corporate governance vari-
holder return and shareholder responsibility ables may suggest that management may have sig-
rather than other dimensions of social perfor- nificant discretion in establishing the firm’s social
mance. orientation, particularly in the establishment of
a more “pro-active” social agenda. The charac-
teristics of management, as well as that of the
Conclusions board of directors, may help shape the firm’s
social agenda. Thus, examination of the man-
The results of this study suggest that firm agement characteristics, as well as the role of the
strengths and weaknesses in the area of social per- board of directors in shaping corporate social
formance are subject to different dynamics. Firm policy and monitoring managerial actions, may
strength in social performance, in other words its provide further insights.
354 Jean McGuire et al.

TABLE III
Split sample results (median level of activist institutional investment)

Dependent variable: Poor social performance


Low activist investment sub-sample

Model Beta T statistic Significance

1 (Constant) –2.28 0.02


Size –0.29 –3.57 0.00
ROA –0.23 –2.70 0.01
Activist institutional investment –0.12 –1.60 0.11
Financial slack –0.00 –0.04 0.97
Leverage –0.03 –0.36 0.72
2 (Constant) –1.65 0.10
Size –0.15 –1.60 0.11
ROA –0.24 –2.85 0.01
Activist institutional investment –0.10 –1.36 0.18
Financial slack –0.01 –0.15 0.88
Leverage –0.04 –0.51 0.61
Salary –0.19 –2.22 0.03
Long term incentives –0.14 –1.40 0.16
Bonus –0.01 –0.13 0.90
CEO ownership –0.10 –1.28 0.20

Model 1 (controls) F Ratio: 6.97; Significance: 0.000 Adjusted R2 = 0.32.


Model 2 (full model) F Ratio: 6.01; Significance: 0.000 Adjusted R 2 = 0.36.

High activist investment sub-sample


Dependent variable: Poor social performance

Model Beta T statistic Significance

1 (Constant) –2.83 0.01


Size –0.39 –4.32 0.00
ROA –0.28 –3.10 0.00
Activist institutional investment –0.05 –0.62 0.54
Financial slack –0.02 –0.22 0.82
Leverage –0.13 –1.51 0.13
2 (Constant) –2.99 0.00
Size –0.22 –2.15 0.03
ROA –0.31 –3.50 0.00
Activist institutional investment –0.07 –0.93 0.35
Financial slack –0.03 –0.40 0.69
Leverage –0.12 –1.41 0.16
Salary –0.28 –3.20 0.00
Long term incentives –0.19 –1.65 0.10
Bonus –0.24 –2.13 0.04
CEO ownership –0.02 –0.24 0.81

Model 1 (controls) F Ratio: 3.51; Significance: 0.00; Adjusted R2 = 0.16.


Model 2 (full model) F Ratio: 3.60; Significance: 0.00; Adjusted R 2 = 0.21.
CEO Incentives and Corporate Social Performance 355

TABLE III
Continued

Social strengths
Low activist investment sub-sample

Model Beta T statistic Significance

1 (Constant) –2.23 0.03


Size –0.29 –3.19 0.00
ROA –0.15 –1.52 0.13
Activist institutional investment –0.02 –0.25 0.80
Financial slack –0.03 –0.32 0.75
Leverage –0.01 –0.12 0.91
2 (Constant) –1.86 0.07
Size –0.17 –1.53 0.13
ROA –0.15 –1.51 0.13
Activist institutional investment –0.05 –0.52 0.61
Financial slack –0.04 –0.45 0.66
Leverage –0.00 –0.04 0.97
Salary –0.13 –1.34 0.18
Long term incentives –0.21 –1.71 0.09
Bonus –0.07 –0.54 0.59
CEO ownership –0.10 –1.14 0.26

Model 1 (controls) F Ratio: 2.41; Significance: 0.01; Adjusted R2 = 0.10.


Model 2 (full model) F Ratio: 2.25; Significance: 0.01; Adjusted R 2 = 0.12.

High activist investment sub-sample


Dependent variable: Strong social performance

Model Beta T statistic Significance

1 (Constant) –0.98 0.33


Size –0.22 –2.26 0.03
ROA –0.02 –0.22 0.83
Activist institutional investment –0.01 –0.11 0.91
Financial slack –0.14 –1.50 0.13
Leverage –0.12 –1.28 0.20
2 (Constant) –0.87 0.38
SIZE –0.20 –1.69 0.09
ROA –0.04 –0.41 0.68
Activist institutional investment –0.02 –0.25 0.80
Financial slack –0.15 –1.53 0.13
Leverage –0.11 –1.21 0.23
Salary –0.01 –0.06 0.95
Long term incentives –0.05 –0.34 0.73
Bonus –0.04 –0.28 0.78
CEO ownership –0.06 –0.60 0.55

Model 1 (controls) F Ratio: 1.16; Significance: 0.32; Adjusted R2 = 0.01.


Model 2 (full model) F Ratio: 0.88; Significance: 0.58; Adjusted R 2 = 0.01.
356 Jean McGuire et al.

Although we made use of a well-accepted strong network of ties that contribute to firm
measure of social performance, other measures success. Building upon this logic, the perfor-
may provide additional insights. Specifically, firms mance benefits of exemplary social performance
are increasingly adopting “triple bottom line” may be stronger than those of simply avoiding
reporting, which include non-financial measures poor social performance. Simply stated, “doing
of social performance. Although Murphy (2000) nothing wrong” may do little to build good rela-
provides evidence for the dominance of finan- tions with stakeholders, whereas exemplary
cial performance criteria in executive compen- actions may bring greater long-term benefits.
sation plans, future research can examine the The challenge to examining this link, however,
extent to which consideration of broader per- is to identify performance measures that tap the
formance indexes influences firm social perfor- long-term benefits of stakeholder relations.
mance. Further, research should examine the
extent to which “triple bottom line” criteria are
reflected in executive compensation. Acknowledgements
The recent cases of Enron and WorldCom and
other instances of improper accounting practices The authors wish to thank Basma Ali, Zied
suggest that the relation between CEO com- Guedri, and Elie Matta for their assistance in data
pensation and poor social performance may be collection. We also thank Goeff Bell and Percy
most relevant when poor social performance Heugens for their useful comments. This research
(in these cases manipulation of accounting was funded by the Social Science and Humanities
results) directly impacts the executive’s personal Research Council of Canada.
wealth. The incentives to manipulate accounting
numbers to meet performance targets or for
maximum gain from stock options are more Notes
direct and obvious than the stakeholder manage-
1
ment issues examined in this article. Research Studies examining ownership-social performance
examining such issues as earnings restatements, relations are discussed in more detail later in this
regulatory actions, or similar evidence of finan- paper. Studies examining the association between
cial improprieties may reveal stronger compen- Board of Director characteristics and social perfor-
sation-social performance links. Further, it is mance include Coffey and Wang (1998); Harrison and
Freeman (1999); McKendallSanchez and Sicilian
interesting that the KLD social ratings do not
(1999). Although we acknowledge the importance of
explicitly consider corporate governance in their the board of directors as a corporate governance
evaluation of social performance. Recent corpo- mechanism, we do not examine board effects in this
rate governance failures may suggest the need to study. Therefore, this literature will not be discussed
incorporate corporate governance into evalua- in detail.
tions of social performance. 2
There is no reason to suspect systematic bias from
Finally, this research does not examine the link incomplete data. The overlap between financial and
between social strengths and weaknesses and firm social performance data was good. Social performance
performance. Previous research considering social data were available on 374 of the 430 firms with
performance as a continuum has ignored the pos- complete financial data.
3
sibility that the performance benefits of strong The community dimension includes charitable
and weak social performance may differ. From giving, concern for the international community, and
the economic impact of firm operations. The envi-
the perspective of stakeholder theory, appropriate
ronmental dimension includes pollution, hazardous
corporate governance mechanisms that direct waste, climate change, and environmental communi-
managerial attention to stakeholder interests cation. The product dimension of the KLD ratings
should contribute to the firm’s long-term devel- includes quality and safety, impact on the disadvan-
opment and performance. Stakeholder theory taged, and marketing/contracting controversies.
suggests that building good relations with Employee dimensions include promotion of women
primary stakeholders may build goodwill and a and minorities, family benefits, safety issues, employee
CEO Incentives and Corporate Social Performance 357

relations, and international labor issues. Thus, this show a positive relationship between compensation
version of the KLD database does not consider “diver- and environmental and product weaknesses. Although
sity” as a unique dimension of social performance, but in the predicted direction, long term incentives were
rather as a dimension of the firm’s performance vis- insignificant. Although these findings reflect the
à-vis employees. greater variance along these dimensions of social per-
4
Heteroscidastitity among the four dimensions formance, they are also congruent with an argument
further complicates inter-dimensional comparisons that poor performance along these dimensions may
Hillman, A. and Keim, G. 2001. Shareholder value, be more subject to our hubris and cost-cutting argu-
stakeholder management, and social issues: What’s the ments.
bottom line? Strategic Management Journal 22(2):
125–139.
5
These funds were the California Public Employee References
Retirement System (CalPers), The California State
Teacher’s Retirement System, The Pennsylvania Amihud, Y. and B. Lev: 1981, ‘Risk Reduction as a
Public School Employee Retirement System, The Managerial Motive for Conglomerate Mergers’,
State of Wisconsin Investment Board, TIAA/CREF, Bell Journal of Economics 12, 605–617.
the Florida State Board of Administration, and The Anderson, D.: 1995, ‘The European Union and the
New York State Common Retirement System, the Outlook for Trade’, Business Economics 30, 17–26.
Colorado Employee Retirement System, and the Auperle, K. E., A. Carroll and J. Hatfield: 1985,
NYC pension fund system. The Colorado and NYC ‘An Empirical Examination of the Relationship
funds are among the smallest of those identified, and between Corporate Social Responsibility and
had negligible holdings in sample firms. Although Profitability’, Academy of Management Journal 28(2),
other “activist” institutional investors exist, those 446–463.
included in our study are the most significant in terms Bansal, P. and I. Celland: 2000, The Market Risk of
of both size of shareholdings and visibility. In addi- Corporate Environmental Illegitimacy. Paper presented
tional analyses we subtracted “activist” institutional at the Academy of Management Meetings,
holdings from total institutional investment to calcu- Toronto.
late a “non activist” institutional investment variable. Berman, S.: 1999, Managerial Opportunism and Firm
Inclusion of non-activist holdings was insignificant Performance: An Empirical Test of Instrumental
and was therefore eliminated from further analysis. Stakeholder Theory. Paper presented at the Academy
6
Since ROA can vary to a greater extent than size of Management Meetings, Chicago, IL.
or capital structure, we used a two-year average of Boyd, B.: 1994, ‘Board Control and CEO
ROA. Results were similar when single year lagged Compensation’, Strategic Management Journal 15(5),
or concurrent ROA were used. 335–334.
7
Coefficients for industry control variables are not Caves, R. and M. Uekasa: 1976. Industrial
presented. Only two of the industry dummy variables Organization in Japan (The Brookings Institute,
were significant. Examination of the qualitative Washington, DC).
description of social performance on the KLD web Clarkson, M.: 1995, ‘A Stakeholder Framework for
site suggests that social performance may have been Analyzing and Evaluating Corporation’, Academy
evaluated in the context of the social challenges facing of Management Review 20(1), 92–117.
the firm and industry. For example, discussion of a Coffey, B. and J. Wang: 1998, ‘Board Diversity and
mining or forestry firm tended to focus on the firm’s Managerial Control as Predictors of Corporate
response the environmental challenges they faced, Social Performance’, Journal of Business Ethics 17(4),
rather than the environmental threats posed by the 1595–1603.
industry itself. Conyon, M. and S. Peck: 1998, ‘Board Control,
8
We conducted additional analysis using the four Remuneration Committees, and Top Management
individual dimensions of social performance. These Compensation’, Academy of Management Journal
results must be interpreted with caution given the 41(2), 146–157.
more limited variance in the dependent variable. Conyon, M. J. and K. J. Murphy: 2000, ‘The Prince
Nevertheless, results are suggestive. Congruent with and the Pauper: CEO Pay in the US and UK’,
the aggregate analysis, models predicting strength Economic Journal, forthcoming.
along each dimension were insignificant. Results on Cruchley, C., M. Jensen, J. Jahera and J. Raymond:
the four social performance weakness dimensions 1999, ‘Agency Problems and the Simultaneity
358 Jean McGuire et al.

of Financial Decision Making: The Role of the Bottom Line?’, Strategic Management Journal
Institutional Ownership’, International Review of 22(2), 125–139.
Financial Analysis 8(2), 177–197. Jensen, M. and W. Meckling: 1976, ‘Theory of the
Crystal, G.: 1991, In Search of Excess (W. W. Norton, Firm: Managerial Behaviour, Agency Costs, and
New York). Ownership Structure’, Journal of Financial Economics
Davis, J. H., F. D. Schoorman and L. Donaldson: 3, 305–360.
1997, ‘Toward a Stewardship Theory of Jensen, M. and K. Murphy: 1990, ‘Performance and
Management’, The Academy of Management Review Top Management Incentives’, Journal of Political
22(1), 20–47. Economy 98(2), 225–264.
Despeignes, P. and A. Hill: 2002, ‘Calls for Review John, T. A. and K. John: 1993, ‘Top Management
of Stock Ooption Accounting’, Financial Times Compensation and Capital Structure’, Journal of
(London). Finance XLVIII(3), 949–974.
Donaldson, T. and L. Preston: 1995, ‘The Stakeholder Johnson, R. and D. Greening: 1999, ‘The Effects
Theory of the Corporation: Concepts, Evidence, of Corporate Governance and Institutional
and Implications’, Academy of Management Review Ownership Types on Corporate Social Perform-
20(1), 65–91. ance’, Academy of Management Journal 42(5),
Eisenhardt, K.: 1989, ‘Agency Theory: An Assessment 564–578.
and Review’, Academy of Management Review 14, Jones, M.: 1999, ‘The Institutional Determinants of
57–74. Social Responsibility’, Journal of Busines Ethics
Fama, E.: 1980, ‘Agency Problems and the Theory 20,163–179.
of the Firm’, Journal of Political Economy, 288–307. Jones, T.: 1995, ‘Instrumental Stakeholder Theory:
Fama, E. and M. Jensen: 1983, ‘The Separation of A Synthesis of Ethics and Economics’, Academy of
Ownership and Control’, Journal of Law and Management Review 20(2), 404–437.
Economics 26, 301–325. Jones, T. and A. Wicks: 1999, ‘Convergent
Gavish, B. and A. Kalay: 1983, ‘On the Asset Stakeholder Theory’, Academy of Management
Substitution Problem’, Journal of Financial and Review 24(2), 208–221.
Quantitative Analysis 18, 21–29. McGuire, J., T. Schneeweis and A. Sundgren: 1988,
Graves, S. and S. A. Waddock: 1994, ‘Institutional ‘Corporate Social Responsibility and Firm
Owners and Corporate Social Responsibility’, Financial Performance’, Academy of Management
Academy of Management Journal 31(1), 195–200. Journal 31(4), 854–872.
Gray, S. and A. Canella: 1997, ‘The Role of Risk in McKendall, M., C. Sanchez and P. Sicilian: 1999,
Executive Compensation’, Journal of Management ‘Corporate Governance and Corporate Illegality:
23(4), 517–540. The Effects of Board Structure on Environmental
Griffin, J.: 2000, ‘Corporate Social Performance: Violations’, International Journal of Organizational
Research Directions for the 21st Century’, Business Analysis 7(3), 201–223.
and Society 39(4), 479–491. McWilliams, A. and D. Siegel: 2000, ‘Corporate
Harrison, J. and R. Freeman: 1999, ‘Stakeholders, Social Responsibility and Financial Performance:
Social Responsibility and Performance: Empirical Correlation or Misspecification?’, Strategic
Evidence and Theoretical Perspectives’, Academy of Management Journal 21(5), 603–610.
Management Journal 42(5), 479–489. Mitchell, R., B. Agle and R. Wood: 1997, ‘Toward
Hartman, C. and C. Beck-Dudley: 1999, ‘Marketing a Theory of Stakeholder Identification and
Strategies and the Search for Virtue: A Case Salience: Defining the Principle of Who and What
Analysis of the Body Shop, International’, Journal Really Counts’, Academy of Management Review
of Business Ethics 20(3), 249–263. 22(4), 853–886.
Hayward, M. and D. Hambrick: 1997, ‘Explaining the Murphy, K.: 1985, ‘Corporate Performance and
Premiums Paid for Large Acquisitions: Evidence of Managerial Remuneration’, Journal of Accounting
CEO Huberis’, Administrative Science Quarterly and Economics 7, 11–42.
42(1), 103–127. Murphy, K.: 1999, ‘Executive Compensation’, in O.
Healy, P.: 1985, ‘The Effect of Bonus Schemes on Ashenfelter and D. Card (eds.), Handbook of Labor
Accounting Decisions’, Journal of Accounting & Economics (New Holland, Amsterdam).
Economics 7(1), 85–107. Murphy, K.: 2000, ‘Performance Standards in
Hillman, A. and G. Keim: 2001, ‘Shareholder Value, Incentive Contracts’, Journal of Accounting &
Stakeholder Management, and Social Issues: What’s Economics 30(3), 245–278.
CEO Incentives and Corporate Social Performance 359

Parker, A.: 2002, ‘Conviction Gives Ammunition to Taking’, Academy of Management Review 23(1),
Case for Reform’, Financial Times, 19 (London). 133–153.
Prevost, A. and R. Rao: 2000, ‘Of What Value Zajac, E. J. and J. D. Westphal: 1994, ‘The Costs and
are Shareholder Proposals Sponsored by Public Benefits of Managerial Incentives: When is More
Pension Funds?’, Journal of Business 73(2), 177– Not Better?’, Strategic Management Journal (Winter
204. 1994 (Special Issue), 121–142.
Sanders, W. G.: 2001, ‘Behavioral Responses of
CEO’s to Stock Ownership and Stock Option Jean McGuire
Pay’, Academy of Management Journal 44(3), Department of Management,
477–492. Concordia University,
Shleifer, A. and R. Vishny: 1989, ‘Management
1550 De Maisonneuve W,
Entrenchment: The Case of the Manager Specific
Investments’, Journal of Financial Economics 25, Montreal QC,
123–139. Canada
Smith, G.: 2000, ‘A Famous Brand on a Rocky E-mail: jeanm@jmsb.concordia.ca
Road’, Business Week, 54.
Stata, R. and M. Maidique: 1980. ‘Bonus System for Sandra Dow
a Balanced Strategy’, Harvard Business Review, École des Sciences de la Gestion,
158–183. Université du Québec à Montréal,
Waddock, S. and S. Graves: 1995, ‘Attraction or 315 Rue Sainte-Catherine Est,
Repulsion: How Institutional Owners React Montréal, QC,
to Corporate Social Performance’, Management Canada
Research News 18(2), 20–25. E-mail: dow-anvari.sandra@uqam.ca
Waddock, S. A. and S. Graves: 1997, ‘The Corporate
Social Performance-financial Performance Link’,
Strategic Management Journal 18(4), 303–370. Kamal Argheyd
Wahal, S.: 1996, ‘Pension Fund Activism and Firm Department of Management,
Performance’, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Concordia University,
Analysis 30(1), 1–23. 1550 De Maisonneuve W,
Wiseman, R. and L. Gomez-Mejia: 1998, ‘A Montreal QC,
Behavioral Agency Model of Managerial Risk Canada

Potrebbero piacerti anche