Sei sulla pagina 1di 10

Research Policy 41 (2012) 770–779

Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect

Research Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/respol

Intra-plant diffusion of new technology: Role of productivity in the study of steel


refining furnaces夽
Tsuyoshi Nakamura a , Hiroshi Ohashi b,∗
a
Department of Economics, Tokyo Keizai University, Japan
b
Department of Economics, University of Tokyo, 7-3-1 Hongo, Tokyo, Japan

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: This paper examines intra-plant diffusion of new technology in the Japanese steel industry. The introduc-
Received 20 September 2010 tion of the basic oxygen furnace (BOF) was the greatest breakthrough in steel refining in the last century.
Received in revised form 31 August 2011 Using unique panel data, the paper estimates total factor productivity by technology type, and associates
Accepted 22 November 2011
the estimates with intra-plant diffusion. The paper finds that intra-plant diffusion accounts for about a
Available online 30 December 2011
half of the industry productivity growth. Large plants are likely to adopt the new technology earlier, but
retain the old technology longer, than their smaller counterparts.
JEL classification:
© 2011 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
D24
L61
O14
O33

Keywords:
Intra-plant diffusion
Total factor productivity
Innovation
Technological change

1. Introduction rate of intra-firm diffusion—the rate at which a particular firm sub-


stitutes a new technology for old in its production process—requires
Diffusion of new technology has been viewed as the main driv- firm-level data that identify how capital is utilized by technology
ing force of economic growth. An important set of questions often type.
raised in the literature concerns what factors determine a firm’s Using unique plant-level panel data, this paper analyzes the
decision to adopt a new technology. While this issue of inter-firm role of productivity in intra-plant diffusion, which has received
technology diffusion has been extensively studied, the adoption little attention in previous empirical examinations. In particular,
of new technology is not in and of itself sufficient for economic we focus on the refining furnace technology in the Japanese steel
growth.1 For the social benefits of innovation to be realized, the industry. In the 1950s and 1960s, many integrated steel makers
outcome of an innovation must not only be adopted by a firm, updated their technology, shifting from the conventional open-
but also be extensively utilized in economic activities. Productiv- hearth furnace (OHF) to the imported basic oxygen furnace (BOF).
ity and outputs would not increase in response to the adoption of The introduction of the BOF was praised as “unquestionably one of
new technology, if the utilization of the technology remains low. As the greatest technological breakthroughs in the steel industry dur-
Mansfield (1963: 356) explains, the accurate measurement of the ing the twentieth century” (Hogan, 1971: 1543). Interestingly, the
period of the rapid dissemination of BOF technology coincides with
that of the remarkable growth Japan experienced in the wake of the
夽 We thank Shigeru Asaba, Michele Boldrin, Hiroyuki Chuma, and seminar and devastation wreaked by World War II. The steel industry expanded
conference participants at the BWIE, EARIE, the International Schumpeter Society its production more than fourfold between 1953 and 1964, mak-
Conference, the TEPCO, and the University of Tokyo for their helpful comments. We ing Japan the world’s largest steel exporter by 1969. As we discuss
also thank useful comments from anonymous referees and the Editor. in Section 2, intra-plant diffusion played a major role in BOF dif-
∗ Corresponding Author: Tel.: +81 1 3 5841 5511; fax: +81 1 3 5841 5521.
fusion, resulting in substantial industry growth in the 1950s and
E-mail address: ohashi@e.u-tokyo.ac.jp (H. Ohashi).
1
Although the data used here refer to plants rather than firms, we use the terms
1960s. Restricting our study to examining refining furnace tech-
“plant” and “firm” interchangeably, so as to conform to current usage in the litera- nology allows us to abstract from market structure effects in our
ture. study; virtually all steel plants faced the same market for crude

0048-7333/$ – see front matter © 2011 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.respol.2011.11.002
T. Nakamura, H. Ohashi / Research Policy 41 (2012) 770–779 771

steel, a homogeneous product manufactured from the refining fur- 2. Overview of the post-war Japanese steel market
naces. The nature of the market, along with the output data by
technology type, allows our analysis to focus on the influence of In the early 1950s, most Japanese steel was produced by inte-
other determinants of intra-plant technology diffusion. Our unique grated steel manufacturers. Integrated steel works transform raw
furnace/plant-level data set covers the inputs and outputs from materials (iron ore and coking coal) into pig iron in a blast fur-
each furnace type, and the timing and size of new capital instal- nace. Pig iron is subsequently transformed into crude steel in a
lation. The data permit an estimation of the production function second furnace by removing carbon and other elements. The preva-
based on furnace technology and the measurement of the change lent technology used in this second or “refining” stage was the OHF,
in productivity and output growth in the intra-plant diffusion of which blows burning fuel gas over the molten pig iron, which pro-
new technology. vides the heat required to purify the pig iron. In the late 1950s,
Our estimation results indicate that intra-plant diffusion makes the OHF began rapidly losing ground to the BOF. This new technol-
a significant contribution to the industry-level productivity growth, ogy blows oxygen to oxidize the iron, making it possible for steel
and accounts for more than 70% of the diffusion of the new- makers to refine molten iron and scrap charge into steel in approxi-
technology in terms of industry production capacity. Furthermore, mately 45 min—a sharp decrease from the 6 h that the OHF normally
the estimates indicate that differences in the productivities of new required then. Since molten pig iron is a key input for the BOF and
and old technologies owned by a plant is negatively correlated the pig iron is made by blast furnaces, we focus our attention to
with the rate of intra-plant diffusion; if a new technology is more plants owning blast furnaces as well as OHFs. At the time the BOF
productive than an old one within a plant, the plant will shift its was invented, there were thirteen plants owned by nine firms, uti-
production process from the old to the new technology faster than lizing blast furnaces as well as OHFs, all of which have shifted their
it would otherwise, so as to minimize the opportunity cost of retain- entire steel refining technology from OHF to BOF by early 1970s.
ing the old technology. The paper also observes that large plants are Our data set is derived from these thirteen plants.
likely to adopt the new technology earlier than their smaller coun- Invented in Austria, BOF technology was further developed by
terparts. This finding is consistent with those found in the literature Japanese steel makers after being imported to Japan. The Japanese
on inter-firm diffusion such as in Rose and Joskow (1990). have been responsible for the two most important improvements
In his survey of the literature on new technology diffusion, in the BOF hardware: the multi-hole lance and the oxygen con-
Geroski (2000) identifies two leading models: the epidemic and verter gas recovery system (OG system) (Lynn, 1982: 34; Odagiri
probit models. The first model, originally proposed by Mansfield and Goto, 1996: 149). The multi-hole lance reduces splashing in the
(1963), predicts that the extent of use of a new technology within BOF, thus increasing steel-making yield and improving refractory
a plant increases with the number of years since the first adoption. life. Over the course of our study period, the BOF lance continu-
Fig. 1 traces the intra-plant diffusion rate of BOF, i.e., the changes ously improved its capability for softer blowing at lower velocities
in the share of BOF in a plant’s total capacity size, for each of all while achieving higher production rates. The OG system allows the
thirteen plants considered in the paper. Note that they are those recovery of gases from the BOF. It controls pollution and helps
that switched from OHF to BOF. Although the BOF share gener- reduce energy costs, while contributing to steel-making yield.
ally increased over the study period, the epidemic model does not These “user-centered technological improvements” (von Hippel,
fully explain the BOF use observed in Fig. 1; the years elapsed since 2005) associated with the BOF are known to have contributed to
the first BOF adoption, with the use of a third-order polynomial the increase in steel-making productivity in Japan. In Section 3, we
of the variable, explain about ten percent of the total variability observe the effects of these user-side technological innovations on
of the BOF output share, a finding similar to that of Battisti and the process of intra-plant diffusion. 2
Stoneman (2005). In the empirical implementation on intra-plant Fig. 2 illustrates the diffusion of the new technology observed
diffusion, along with explanatory variables that are considered as from the dataset. Three BOF diffusion paths are plotted in the figure:
proxies for the epidemic effect, we incorporate variables that fea- overall diffusion is the BOF share in the industry’s total capacity
ture the alternative model—the probit model, which presumes that size; inter-plant diffusion is defined by the percentage of plants that
differences in the diffusion rates reflect differences in firm and installed at least one BOF out of the population of 13 plants; and
technology characteristics. Estimation of the model indicates a dif- intra-plant diffusion is the annual average across all thirteen intra-
ference in the productivity of new and old technologies across plant diffusion patterns shown in Fig. 1. The inter-plant diffusion
plants, an important determinant of the intra-firm diffusion of new indicates that all plants represented in the data had adopted the
technology. BOF by 1965, at which time within-plant technology penetration
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 pro- had reached approximately 30%, and intra-plant diffusion became
vides an overview of the Japanese steel market after the Second the sole driving force of the overall diffusion. Interestingly, it was
World War. It describes several important features of the market between 1965 and 1970 that the Japanese steel industry doubled
that have a direct bearing on the formulation of empirical strate- its output. The figure thus illustrates the importance of intra-plant
gies and on the interpretation of quantitative results discussed in diffusion in the later stages of the diffusion process. This finding
the subsequent sections. Section 3 describes our data sources and has also been observed with regard to other technologies, including
presents a method for estimating productivity of furnace tech- computer numerically controlled (CNC) machine tools as reported
nologies. The panel feature of our dataset enables us to correct in Battisti and Stoneman (2004).
for endogeneity problems when measuring productivity. Using the Industry circles have recognized that producing steel involves
obtained productivity estimates, the section evaluates the extent to substantial learning from current and previous production. Hogan
which the intra-plant diffusion contributed to productivity growth. (1971) and Lynn (1982) both noted that it was only through
Section 4 quantitatively examines the forces that drive the intra- extensive furnace use that detailed knowledge of furnace oper-
plant diffusion pattern observed in Fig. 1. The analysis reveals ation was gained. Both OHF and BOF refining furnaces cannot
that productivity difference between old and new technologies is be operated without skilled workers. It was the experience and
an important vehicle in intra-plant diffusion of new technology. judgment of skilled workers that made it possible for plants to
Section 5 discusses the relationship between productivity and both
inter- and intra-plant diffusion patterns of new technology. Section
6 presents our conclusions, followed by the appendices on the data 2
This paper does not consider the electric furnace (EF), because its share in pro-
sources and estimation method used in the paper. duction was small during our study period.
772 T. Nakamura, H. Ohashi / Research Policy 41 (2012) 770–779

100%

80%

60%

40%

20%

0%
Years 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971
No. BOF plants 1 2 2 4 7 8 10 11 13 13 13 13 13 13 13
No. OHF plants 13 13 13 13 13 13 13 13 12 10 9 8 6 3 0

Fig. 1. Diffusion of BOF capacity size (13 plants from 1957 to 1971).

adjust the frequency and size of furnace operations, while main- is observed between plant size and the year of new technology
taining the quality and durability of the crude steel produced. While adoption, and that larger plants tended to adopt the BOF earlier.
Ichniowski and Shaw (1999) found that job rotation was a marked This observation, which concerns inter-plant technology diffusion,
feature of Japanese steel-finishing lines in the 1980s and 1990s, by is well documented in the current body of literature. For exam-
the time of our study period, Mori (2006) discovered in the archives ple, Rose and Joskow (1990) reports that larger firms adopt new
that rotation was already rarely observed in the operation of refin- technologies earlier than smaller ones in the electric utility indus-
ing furnaces in Japan. This finding underscores the importance of try. Second, a negative relationship is observed between plant size
experience in the refining stage of Japanese steel production. and the rate of intra-plant diffusion of the BOF. The figure indi-
Theoretical and empirical research informs us that firm size cates that the smallest plant needed four years to fully replace the
plays an important role in the diffusion of new technology, and OHF, whereas the largest plant took twelve years. The correlation
casual observation of our data indeed reveals a clear relationship between replacement speed and plant size is large enough to gener-
between plant size and intra-plant penetration of the BOF. Fig. 3 ate a negative correlation between plant size and the year in which
plots the year in which the first BOF was adopted and the year in the OHF ceased to be used.
which the last OHF was terminated from use for each steel refin- While the first observation regarding inter-plant diffusion has
ing plant. The adoption and termination years are sorted by plant been extensively studied, the second one has not received signifi-
size, as measured by the logarithmic number of workers in 1968. cant attention. To address this imbalance, the econometric analysis
The number of workers evaluated at a different year of the study presented in Section 3 concentrates on analyzing the second
period has little impact to the results discussed here. The figure observation. Note, however, that our empirical analysis uses evi-
contains two important observations. First, a negative correlation dence pertaining to inter-plant diffusion, when controlling for

(%)
100

80

Inter-plant Diffusion
(Percentage of plants
60
installed BOF)

40
Intra-plant Diffusion
(Average BOF share in the
total capacity across plants
20

Overall Diffusion
(BOF share in the total
capacity at the industry level)
0
1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971

Fig. 2. BOF Diffusions patters, 1957–1971.


T. Nakamura, H. Ohashi / Research Policy 41 (2012) 770–779 773

Fig. 3. Relationship between plant size and the rate of intra-firm diffusion.

selection issues. The econometric analysis described in Section 4 application. Considering that the two furnace technologies, OHF
reports that productivity differences between furnace technologies and BOF, exhibit different operational characteristics, we allow for
account for the intra-plant diffusion of the BOF. The next section ˇz to differ in terms of technology type.
describes the method used to estimate the productivity of furnace Apart from the three factors described in (1), two other impor-
technology. tant influences on steel production are plant-level efficiency of
production management and improved furnace technologies. Such
3. Measuring productivity unmeasured determinants are represented by usi,t . Productivity
unobserved by the econometrician may create endogeneity in input
This section presents the method used to estimate total factor choice. Endogeneity in input choice arises when producers adjust
productivity (TFP) of furnace technology of the steel refining pro- the amount of material (electricity and labor in our application)
cess at the plant level. We use thirteen plants owned by nine firms in according to their efficiency differences in usi,t . For example, plants
the estimation, whose BOF capacity sizes are presented in Fig. 1. Our that are perceived to have higher productivity might use more
data set consists of annual data from 1957 to 1970. The Japan Steel of electricity. Our first response to the endogeneity problem is to
Federation (1955–1970) provides data on the amount of outputs use plant-, year-, and technology-specific components in the esti-
and inputs at the plant level by technology type. Data sources are mation. Further, we allow the fixed technology dummy to differ
detailed in Appendix B. The OHF and BOF both produce crude steel, according to the year, as follows: usi,t = i + ts + εsi,t , where εsi,t is
a homogeneous product. Our econometric model of the produc- a mean-zero error. The fixed plant component,  i , deals with effi-
tion function describes how efficiently the furnaces completed the ciency differences between plants, which do not change over time.
transformation process. We use the following Cobb-Douglas equa- The inclusion of ts serves to control for the differences in furnace
tion estimating the parameters, ˇx , ˇk , and ˇz (all are in logarithmic technologies, which change according to the year. This fixed-effect
form): specification, however, may appear to be restrictive in that a pro-
s
yi,t s
= xi,t s
ˇx + ki,t s
ˇk + zi,t ˇz + usi,t , (1) ductivity difference known to the firm is constant over time. In
an alternative specification, we follow the generalized method of
s is the annual output (in tons and logarithm) for furnace
where yi,t moments (GMM) approach developed by Blundell and Bond (1998).
s (either OHF or BOF) at plant i in year t. In (1), we use plant as the Details of this approach are presented in Appendix A.1.
unit of analysis, and abstract issues of multi-plant operation. Table 1 presents three results based on methods without fixed
The production function comprises of a number of input vari- effects (1-A), those with fixed effects (1-B), and GMM (1-C).
s includes electricity and labor along with a constant
ables. Vector xi,t The upper part of the table presents estimates of the regression
term. All furnaces use electricity as an energy source. The labor vari- coefficients. Our inference is based on heteroskedasticity-robust
able is in units of man-hours, and we multiply the average hours standard errors. Note that estimates of constant parameters are not
worked at the industry level by the number of workers employed reported in (1-C), since the estimated equation is quasi-differenced
at each plant in the data set. as noted in Appendix A.1. The reported statistics indicates that
s . The age of fur-
The capacity size of furnace s is indicated by ki,t our estimation model performs moderately well: the measures of
nace s at plant i (i.e., the number of years for which furnace s was adjusted R2 for specifications (1-A) and (1-B) are above 0.8, and
used at plant i) is denoted by zi,ts . The last variable captures two the Sargan test statistic for (1-C) would not allow us to reject the
aspects of capital utilization: on one hand, this variable reflects the orthogonality condition between some of the instruments and the
experience level, i.e., the extent to which extensive use of a par- error. Note that Blundell and Bond (1998) propose to use the lagged
ticular furnace type leads to more efficient production; and on the explanatory variables for xis , kis and zis as a set of the instruments in
other, it also indicates the degree of capital depreciation, as fur- the estimation of (1). The estimation method creates a concern for
nace productivity deteriorates with age. The estimated coefficient endogeneity in the estimates, if εsi is serially correlated. In order
of the variable implies which of the two effects dominates in our to verify the significance of this concern, we perform the Arellano
774 T. Nakamura, H. Ohashi / Research Policy 41 (2012) 770–779

Table 1
Production function estimates.

(1-A) OLS (1-B) Fixed effects (1-C) GMM

Est. Std. Err. Est. Std. Err. Est. Std. Err.

Labor 0.633a 0.077 0.647a 0.120 0.897a 0.085


Electricity 0.169a 0.034 0.132 0.098 0.141b 0.067
Capacity 0.387a 0.040 0.198c 0.100 0.212b 0.094
OHF age 0.158a 0.040 −0.075 0.352 0.060 0.060
BOF age 0.024 0.059 0.060 0.072 −0.074 0.094
Constant 3.598b 1.494
OHF dummy 1.563a 0.605
BOF dummy 2.852a 0.700

Sargan statistic 117.50(109)


R-squared measure 0.9996 0.8631 –
No. observations 229 229 229

Arellano-bond test for zero autocorrelation

Statistics p-value

Order 1 −2.661 0.008


Order 2 1.329 0.184
Order 3 −1.170 0.242

Notes: The data contain thirteen plants considered in the data. Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are used in the table. The variables of labor, electricity, capacity,
OHF age and BOF age are all in logarithm. The estimated coefficients on technology- and year-specific dummies are not reported in the table.
a
Signfincance at the 99% confidence level.
b
Signfincance at the 95% confidence level.
c
Signfincance at the 90% confidence level.

and Bond (1991) test for the existence of serial correlation in the calculated annually as the share-weighted average of furnace and
estimated error. As reported in the lower part of Table 1, the corre- plant productivity, defined as:
lations are estimated to be statistically insignificant up to the third   
s s s  s 
order. This result may be understandable in that we already control i,t wi,t yi,t − xi,t ˇx − ki,t ˇk , (2)
for year-specific component by technology type in the estimation. i s
The table shows that the input coefficients are estimated to be s is the output share of technology s (either OHF or BOF)
in which i,t
positive and many of them are statistically different from zero.
at plant i at year t, and wi,t is plant i’s share in the total industry
While the estimates found in (1-B) are similar to those in (1-A), BOF takes the value of zero
output of crude steel at year t. Note that i,t
we are concerned that endogeneity in input choice may lead to
before year t when plant i adopts BOF. Fig. 4 uses the GMM estimates
a correlation between the inputs (labor and electricity) and the
under (1-C) in Table 1. The productivity increased at an annual rate
unobserved productivity error that varies over time. If input con-
of 14.5% until 1965 when all thirteen plants in the data installed at
sumption was readily adjusted to productivity, the resulting bias
least one BOF. Thereafter, the productivity grew by 11.6%.
in the inputs coefficients could be severe. The GMM estimator
The figure decomposes the productivity growth into two fac-
reported in (1-C) accounts for this bias. While both estimates of the
tors; one is attributed to inter-plant diffusion, and the other to
input coefficients in (1-C) are not statistically different from those
intra-plant diffusion. We calculate the productivity contribution of
found in (1-B), their mean values are estimated to be approximately BOF
inter-plant diffusion by using (2) under the assumption that i,t
40% larger than those in (1-B). Although it is generally impossible
BOF for t ≥ t , where t is the year when plant
takes the value of i,t
in a multivariate context to sign the bias of the fixed-effects esti- i
i
i
mates when simultaneity exists and there are many inputs, the i adopted BOF. The difference between (2) and the productivity
finding from the inputs estimates are consistent with the hypothe- contribution of inter-plant diffusion calculated above is assumed
sis that input’s correlation with productivity shock is much smaller to come from intra-plant diffusion. Note that the assumptions
than either the capacity’s or furnace-age’s correlations with the made here are likely to understate (or overstate) the productiv-
productivity.3 The coefficient of the capacity-size variable is less ity contribution of intra-plant (or inter-plant) diffusion, because
than one, which may indicate the existence of decreasing returns to the intra-plant diffusion is assumed to be absent before the inter-
scale. The furnace-age variable is found to be statistically insignifi- plant diffusion is completed, in contrast to the observations made
cant. in Fig. 2. Fig. 4 shows that the productivity growth after 1964
Based on the estimation results shown in Table 1, we first when the inter-plant diffusion is completed can be solely attributed
aggregate industry productivity for the 1957–1968 period. Our to the intra-plant diffusion. The industry productivity associated
productivity measure comprises the contribution of furnace age with intra-plant diffusion is 13.1%, higher than that of the indus-
(represented by zi,t s ) and of disembodied technical progress
try growth. Moreover, this intra-plant diffusion contributes more
s
(represented by ui,t ). Fig. 4 shows annual changes in the aggre- than half of the industry-level productivity at the end of our study
gated industry productivity. Productivity at the industry level is period.
One of key determinants of intra-plant diffusion pattern is the
productivity difference between OHF and BOF at the time of adop-
tion. Fig. 5 presents estimated productivity by furnace type, tBOF
3
and tOHF , over the period from 1957 to 1968. Note that ts is esti-
This hypothesis is corroborated by the observation that the plant-level labor
and electricity inputs did not vary much over time. The positive correlation between
mated by both technology- and year-dummy variables. The figure
the inputs and capital size (or furnace age) provides an additional support for the uses the GMM estimates under (1-C), but the other estimates shown
downward bias of the FE inputs estimates. in Table 1 have qualitatively the same features. The TFP estimates
T. Nakamura, H. Ohashi / Research Policy 41 (2012) 770–779 775

1.6

1.4

1.2

Aributed to Intra-
plant Diffusion
1.0
T 1957
llog TFPt - log TFP

0.8

0.6

Aributed to Inter-
plant Diffusion
0.4

0.2

0.0
1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968

Fig. 4. Decomposition of TFP growth.

2.0

1.5

BOF
1.0

0.5

OHF
0.0

-0.5
1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968

Fig. 5. Productivity by furnace type, averaged over plants.

confirm that BOF was more efficient than OHF. The figure also repairing the OHF prior to adopting the BOF.4 Although the knowl-
indicates that the TFP measures of the two technologies diverged edge spillover also possibly affected OHF operation, the figure
over time: the productivity of BOF more than tripled over the appears to indicate that the depreciation effect dominates. Section
study period, while the productivity of OHF was roughly constant. 5 discusses the role of productivity in diffusion patterns in further
The productivity increase of BOF could be due to user-centered detail.
innovations (von Hippel, 2005), including the multi-hole lance and While identifying the sources of furnace productivity requires
the OG system mentioned in the previous section. It could also be further data collection, the measured productivity presented in this
due to a feature of inter-plant diffusion process: as experience in section implies a negative relationship between plant size and the
the use of the BOF accumulated in adopting firms, some, if not all, of
this experience would spread among non-adopting firms by word-
of-mouth or knowledge spillover. In either case, the late adopters
would benefit from the knowledge transferred from early adopters, 4
Data regarding furnace maintenance time and frequency are available for only
and thus enjoy higher initial productivity when adopting the BOF. one plant in Yawata, then the largest steel maker in Japan. We observed the four OHFs
owned by the plant, and noted that maintenance time and the OHF sizes were clearly
The productivity decline of the old furnace during the later years
negatively correlated. Since smaller plants tend to own OHFs of smaller capacity
in the study period may be primarily attributed to capital depre- size, this observation is in line with our finding regarding changes in measured OHF
ciation: smaller plants spent less time and effort maintaining and productivity.
776 T. Nakamura, H. Ohashi / Research Policy 41 (2012) 770–779

Table 2
Determinants of rate of intra-firm BOF diffusion.

(2-A) (2-B) (2-C) (2-D)

Explanatory variables (Est.) (Std. Err.) (Est.) (Std. Err.) (Est.) (Std. Err.) (Est.) (Std. Err.)

Plant size −0.427a 0.089 −0.354a 0.088 −0.410a 0.085


Plant size when the size is over 10,000 −0.065 0.264
Plant size when the size lies between 5000 and 10,000 −0.028 0.286
Plant size when the size is below 5000 0.004 0.312
ln(TFPBOF) − ln(TFPOHF) 0.593a 0.157 0.580a 0.157 0.758a 0.232
ln(BOF age) −0.073 0.244 −0.165 0.227 −0.344 0.259 −0.174 0.221
ln(BOF age) squared 0.213c 0.109 0.275b 0.106 0.345a 0.112 0.284a 0.105
Inverse mills ratio −0.320 0.317
Constant 2.185a 0.776 0.938 0.854 1.606c 0.871 −2.090 2.728
Pseudo R-squared 0.189 0.255 0.262 0.274

The number of observations is 101.


Notes: The data contain thirteen plants considered in the data. Tobit Model is used in the estimation. The independent variable is the share of BOF in production capacity (in
ton) by plant. Heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are used in the table. The variable of BOF age is in logarithm.
a
Signfincance at the 99% confidence level.
b
Signfincance at the 95% confidence level.
c
Signfincance at the 90% confidence level.

rate of intra-plant diffusion. Because early generation BOFs exhibit plant-size effect, we use the number of workers at the plant level in
lower productivity than later models, it takes more years for early year t. Note that plant size is highly collinear with the number of old
BOF adopters to replace the old technology. In the next section, we furnaces owned by the plant, with a correlation coefficient of 0.8.
statistically analyze the role of the measured productivity differ- We thus do not use, as an explanatory variable, the number of OHF
ences in intra-plant diffusion. owned by plant, and assume that the plant-size variable captures
the feature that a plant that owned more (or fewer) old furnaces
4. Econometric analysis of intra-plant diffusion may be slower (or faster) in installing the same number of new fur-
naces. Finally, we add a plant-level variable in (3) to account for
This section investigates economic determinants of intra-plant the possibility of technology leapfrogging. The BOF-age variable is
diffusion of BOF observed in Fig. 3, considering the relationship included to assess how a plant’s experience with the BOF affects the
between plant size and the number of years a plant took to replace extent of intra-plant diffusion. We include a squared term of this
the old with the new technologies. For this purpose, we use plant- age variable, so as to capture the S-shaped BOF diffusion patterns
level panel data that identify technology type as either OHF or BOF. observed in Fig. 1.
We employ, as the indicator of the extent of intra-plant diffusion, The second term on the right-hand side of (3), ui,t , reflects
the BOF share in the total capacity size for each plant, presented difference in unobserved productivity between old and new tech-
logarithmically. Thus, the rate of intra-plant diffusion is analyzed nologies shown in Fig. 5. In the estimation, we use the productivity
using the following diffusion equation presented in Battisti and estimates obtained from (1-C) in Table 1, but using these other esti-
Stoneman (2005): mates has little qualitative impact to our results. The last term on
 BOF  the right-hand side of (3) is the error term,  i,t , and the parameters
Ki,t
ln = W ln(Wi,t ) + u ui,t + i,t . (3) to be estimated are  W and  u . In the intra-plant diffusion analy-
OHF + K BOF
Ki,t i,t sis, we employ data from plants that operated both OHF and BOF,
s ≡ exp(ks ) (where s is
so that the value of the left-hand side of (3) lies within the range
As defined in the previous section, Ki,t i,t (−∞, 0). We correct for this selectivity of furnace technology by
either OHF or BOF) takes the value of zero when furnace s at plant adopting the Heckit method, the details of which are discussed in
i ceases to be used at year t. Battisti and Stoneman (2005) summa- Appendix A.2.
rize the basis upon which recent theoretical advances in diffusion We pool the data from the thirteen plants. Table 2 presents four
analysis have been built using a neo-classical dynamic optimization estimation results based on the Tobit method. Our inferences are
procedure.5 based on heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors. Specification
We estimate (3) using a Tobit model and deal with possible (2-A) indicates that a one-percent increase in the number of plant
selection bias when Ki,t s is zero. The vector, W , includes two
i,t workers decreases the relative BOF share by less than half a percent.
variables. Plant size is a commonly explored variable in the lit- With the other factors held at the sample averages, the intra-plant
erature of technology diffusion. There are a number of channels BOF diffusion rate is 48% higher for the smallest plant than for the
through which plant size may influence the likelihood of technol- largest. The diffusion rate decreases to 38% in (2-B), in which the
ogy adoption: larger plants are considered to be more capable of variable of productivity difference between the old and new tech-
and less risk-averse to adopting a new technology before substan- nologies, ui,t , is included in (3) as an explanatory variable. The
tial experience has been gained by using it; and the presence of elasticity of the diffusion indicator with respect to the productivity
scale economies may also enable larger plants to reduce costs at a difference between BOF and OHF is found to be 0.59. Since the larger
faster pace through learning by doing in production. To capture the plants were subject to smaller productivity differences, the sign of
the estimate is consistent with findings concerning the plant-size
estimate. BOF-age variable estimates indicate that it takes the aver-
5
In the analysis of the diffusion of CNC, Battisti and Stoneman (2005) explicitly age sample plant about 10 years to achieve the intra-plant diffusion
include relative user costs of capital for new and old technologies as a determinant rate of 50%, and 14 years for the BOF to fully penetrate throughout
of (3). We have no access to the data on user costs on steel refining furnaces; how-
all plants.
ever, notice that steel-making furnaces were installed far less frequently than was
CNC. Thus, annual changes in user costs may have had little impact on the diffusion Specification (2-C) corrects for selectivity in technology choice.
pattern of steel furnaces. In the intra-plant diffusion analysis, we need to consider plants
T. Nakamura, H. Ohashi / Research Policy 41 (2012) 770–779 777

Table 3 early adopter takes more years to replace the old technology than
Probit estimation on BOF operation.
a later adopter.
Explanatory variables Est. Std. Err. In theory, diffusion paths are generated under the assumption
Plant size 0.778 0.546 that adoption cost or uncertainty of the innovation declines over
Blast furnace size 0.675 0.506 time. For example, Jovanovic and Lach (1989) show that S-shaped
Plant age 13.651c 7.777 diffusion arises naturally in an environment in which homogeneous
Plant age squared −1.967c 1.101 agents face the prospect of learning by doing, which is an important
OHF age −7.697 5.464
feature of steel-refining technology discussed in Section 2. Owing to
OHF age squared 1.441 0.916
#OHFsothers −0.104b 0.040 learning by doing, costs decrease as time progresses. These reduc-
Year trend 1.132a 0.219 tions in costs are not appropriated by the incumbents but spill over
Year trend squared −0.067a 0.013 to potential adopters of later generation technology. In the model
Constant −27.957a 8.025
described by Jovanovic and Lach (1989), since early adopters have
Pseudo R-squared 0. 576
the advantage of higher revenues per unit of output, delaying the
The number of observations is 169. adoption of new technology entails both benefits and costs.
Notes: The data contain thirteen plants considered in the data. This estimation is
used to control for sample selectivity in the estimation of Eq. (3). The variables of
Large plants were likely to adopt the new technology earlier
plant size, blast furnace size, plant age, and OHF age are in logarithm. than their smaller counterparts, partly because they were more
a
Signfincance at the 99% confidence level. productive plants to begin with. Indeed the largest plant exhibits
b
Signfincance at the 95% confidence level. 28% higher productivity than did the smallest in 1957. This gap in
c
Signfincance at the 90% confidence level. the productivity between the largest and smallest plants increas-
ingly widened up to 43% by the end of the study period. This
observed adoption pattern has been supported by Caselli (1999),
that simultaneously operated both OHFs and BOFs. This sampling
who argued that skilled biased technology tends to be adopted by
method, although necessary in our analysis, could generate biased
plants with high human capital levels, because skill and technology
estimates if there existed a persistent relationship between the dif-
are complementary under strong learning-by-doing conditions.
fusion rate and the choice of plants in the sample. This concern
Since plants with more skilled workers are more productive, the
would make the number of years of technology use correlate with
theory implies that productive plants are more likely to adopt the
the error in the equation. The probit results obtained in Table 3 pro-
BOF technology.
vide an estimate of the expected value of the error in the intra-plant
Indeed, in his study of Japanese steel plants in the 1950s and
diffusion,  i,t . We have applied the Heckit correction procedure in
1960s, Yoneyama (1978) reported that skilled workers tend to be
the sample selection, and included the inverse Mills ratio. Includ-
allocated to the BOF operation, while unskilled workers were like-
ing this variable and assuming normality in the distribution of the
lier to be assigned to the OHF operation. Since a considerable degree
latent variable, the estimates in (2-C) will be consistent even if
of knowledge regarding steel production was embodied in the
the selected sample is endogenous. The results under (2-C) do not
skilled labor force, it is reasonable to consider that skilled workers
indicate the problem in the sample selection. The magnitude of dif-
may have found it easier to accustom themselves to the operation
ferences in the estimates between the results from (2-B) and (2-C)
of new furnace technology. The observation made by Yoneyama
are not significantly different from zero. Thus, we conclude that the
(1978) evidences the importance of human capital levels in the
selection problem is not severe, probably because the termination
adoption and diffusion of BOF in Japan.
of OHF use or adoption of BOF is not related to the intra-plant dif-
While the estimation results reported in Section 4 indicates that
fusion process. This finding that intra-plant diffusion is statistically
the productivity difference between the old and new technolo-
independent from inter-plant diffusion bear a resemblance to those
gies play an important role in intra-plant diffusion, the presence
reported in Battisti and Stoneman (2005) for CNC and Battisti et al.
of human capital provides another interesting viewpoint in deep-
(2009) for e-business.
ening the understanding of intra-plant diffusion pattern. A large
The three specifications discussed above assume that the effect
plant is assumed to have a wider range of workers both skilled and
of the number of plant workers on the diffusion rate is the same
unskilled. Therefore, it must have been easier for a large plant to
for all plant sizes. Specification (2-D) relaxes this assumption, and
promptly adopt BOF to take advantage of its stock of high-level
allows for the plant-size coefficient to differ by size category. We
human capital. Indeed, the productivity of BOF grew at an annual
include three class size-specific variables: plant size of over ten
rate of 7.4% for large plants, and only 4.6% for smaller ones. The
thousand workers, between five and ten thousand workers, and
difference in the growth rates of BOF productivity may have been
the rest of the plants. The three size variables are all estimated
due to large plants having more highly skilled workers than did
to be insignificant, and would not reject the linearity assumption
smaller plants. A limitation of this study is that our data did not
regarding the plant size coefficient that we made in the prior spec-
include indicators of human capital levels, and as such we were
ifications.
not able to test the role of worker knowledge in skilled workers
in the intra-plant diffusion patterns. This is an area that could be
5. Discussion on diffusion pattern examined further by future research.

Firm size (or plant size in the paper’s application) is a commonly 6. Conclusion
explored variable in the empirical literature on technology diffu-
sion. Firm size is relatively easy to observe, and is typically taken In the Japanese steel industry, the share of output produced
as a proxy for factors such as productivity, ability to assimilate and using the new technology was limited even several years after dif-
exploit new process or economies of scale. In the empirical analy- fusion had taken place. While inter-plant diffusion was the main
sis above, we have focused our attention on the role of productivity driver early in the overall diffusion of BOF, intra-plant diffusion
by furnace type at the plant level, and have noted three observa- became the main contributor in later years, accounting for at least
tions regarding the diffusion of new technology: (i) large plants half of industrial productivity growth from 1957 to 1968. This paper
are likely to adopt the new technology earlier than their smaller further analyzes the intra-plant diffusion pattern of the new tech-
counterparts; (ii) the productivity of the old and new technologies nology, a topic that has been relatively neglected in the diffusion
measured at the time of adoption diverged over time; and (iii) an literature.
778 T. Nakamura, H. Ohashi / Research Policy 41 (2012) 770–779

By making use of available panel data that capture the adop- s


instruments xi,t−r s
, ki,t−r s , where r = 2 and 3, and 3 < t, and for
and zi,t
tion and use of old and new technologies used in the Japanese s s s
the level equation xi,t−1 − xi,t−2 , ki,t−1 s
− ki,t−2 s , where 3 < t.
and zi,t
steel refining stage, this paper observed that large plants were We also employ year dummy variables and the dummy variables
likely to adopt new technology earlier, but retain old technology that represents ts as valid instruments. The estimation results are
longer, than their smaller counterparts. This finding, not previously shown under (1-C) in Table 1.
remarked in the literature, implies a negative relationship between
plant size and the rate of intra-plant diffusion of the BOF. The esti-
A.2. Correcting for selectivity in diffusion equation
mation results indicate that productivity difference between new
and old technologies play an important role in the pattern of intra-
Let di,t be a binary response for plant i at year t. It takes the
plant diffusion. If the new technology is more productive than the OHF and 0 < K BOF are both
value of 1 when the conditions of 0 < Ki,t i,t
old one, the plant will shift its production process from the old
satisfied; and takes the value of 0 otherwise. Each plant chooses
technology to the new faster than it would otherwise, to minimize
di,t so as to maximize the discounted stream of profits, the reduced
the opportunity cost of retaining the old technology. The paper also
form of which is parameterized as:
reports that larger plants are estimated to be more productive, as
they might have had higher human capital levels. i,t = i,t ˛ + i,t , (5)
In addition to the above contributions, this paper observed some
other important findings regarding the intra-plant diffusion of the where i,t contains the constant term and a vector of plant- and
BOF. The results of the regression of intra-plant diffusion (3) indi- year-specific observed characteristics that affect the profitability
cate the importance of learning by doing in the operation of furnace of plant i’s technology adoption at time t. We will discuss these
technology. The estimation results are robust to the presence of variables in i,t shortly in this appendix. The unobserved factors
sample selection and endogeneity because of the existence of firm- not captured by i,t are denoted by  i,t , the mean-zero error and ˛
specific uncertainty. represents a vector of the parameters to be estimated. We assume
This study’s findings on intra-plant diffusion have important that the response di,t is binary and that each plant bases its adoption
public policy implications. Analyses of diffusion policy require decision on the latent variable i,t using a probit model.
knowledge of whether a firm’s realized intra-plant diffusion per- The maximum likelihood estimates of (5) are presented in
formance differs from the optimal performance, and of whether Table 3 and are used in the intra-plant diffusion estimation when
policy interventions addressing the diffusion path actually improve controlling for endogeneity in technology adoption. Based on the
social welfare (Stoneman, 2001). The paper’s analysis suggests literature of inter-plant technology adoption (see Geroski, 2000, for
that diffusion policies could be justified on the grounds that firms example), we employ the following four types of plant-specific vari-
have insufficient information regarding the use of new technol- ables for i,t , along with the plant-size variable already introduced
ogy. Our estimation results indicated that experience in furnace in (3).
operation was an important determinant of intra-plant diffusion of We include the variable of blast furnace size (in ton, logarithm)
BOF. Indeed, our analysis showed that approximately 30 percent to test whether the presence of a blast furnace affects the propen-
of the variation in BOF diffusion could be explained by operational sity of the plant to adopt the BOF. We also include the variables
experience. If this operational experience exhibits externalities that of plant age and OHF age (in logarithmic forms). The two age vari-
cannot be fully accounted for by the firms themselves, there must ables may affect the technology choice because older (or younger)
be a need for public policy regarding intra-plant diffusion. Measur- plants have a greater (or lower) likelihood of substituting the BOF
ing the magnitude of the externalities that arise from the adoption for the old facilities. We add the squared terms of the age variables
and use of BOF would be the next step to understanding the need in the estimation. Lastly, we incorporate in i,t the number of old
for public policy addressing technology diffusion. furnaces owned by the other plants in the same company at t − 1. A
company may face difficulty in adopting a new technology, if more
workers are familiar with the OHF. Along with these plant vari-
Appendix A. Estimation methods
ables, a yearly trend variable and its squared term are included in
the estimation to control for the industry-wide aggregate shocks.
This appendix discusses the methods used to estimate the pro-
The binary probit model predicts 148 out of 169, or 88%,
duction function (1) and the diffusion equation (3), which appear
of the observations correctly, suggesting a fair fit to the data.
in Sections 3 and 4, respectively.
Table 3 shows that the estimated coefficients for plant and blast-
furnace sizes are both positive, but not significantly different from
A.1. GMM estimation of production function zero. While the coefficient of the OHF-age variable is statisti-
cally insignificant, the plant-age and yearly trend estimates are
In the estimation of production function, we employed the both statistically and economically significant, indicating that the
method proposed by Blundell and Bond (1998) for specifi- plants that were most likely to install the BOF have a plant age
cation (1-C). Remember that usi,t = i + i,t + ts + msi,t , where of 32 years (because the plant-age variable has a value of 32.13)
i,t =
i,t−1 + ei,t , and that mi,t and ei,t are serially uncorrelated and in the year 1965 (because the year-trend variable has a value of
are the mean zero errors. We quasi-differenced the production 1964.5). Finally, the estimate indicates that a plant with more old
function and estimate the following dynamic representation: furnaces was less likely to adopt the BOF than one with fewer
OHFs.
s s s s s s
yi,t =
yi,t−1 + (xi,t −
xi,t−1 )ˇx + (ki,t −
ki,t−1 )ˇk
Appendix B. Data description
s s
+ (zi,t −
zi,t−1 )ˇz + (1 −
)i + (ts −
t−1
s
) + si,t , (4)
The data used in the paper are plant-level annual data for 13
where s represents either OHF or BOF, and si,t ≡ ei,t + msi,t − steel-making plants from 1957 to 1970. These plants are owned

msi,t−1 . Estimating (4) takes care of the firm-specific component. by 9 Japanese steel firms. The data are disaggregated by plant and
Blundell and Bond (1998) suggests that the production function be furnace type, and cover approximately 95% of total industry steel
estimated by the GMM as a system combining the first differenced production throughout the study period. Most plants in the data
and level equations. For the differenced equation, we use as a set of operated more than one furnace in a given year; however, the input
T. Nakamura, H. Ohashi / Research Policy 41 (2012) 770–779 779

and output data are aggregated over the multiple furnaces of the variable of the number of years for which furnace s was used at
same technology type within each plant. The output data of crude s .
plant i, namely zi,t
steel and the input data are both obtained from the Japan Steel
Federation (1955–1970). The estimation uses two inputs variables; References
the amount of electricity and labor. The electricity data are obtained
from the same source as the output data. Arellano, M., Bond, S., 1991. Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo
evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic
Data on labor input are constructed from two variables: the
Studies 58 (2), 277–297.
number of workers at the plant level and by furnace type; and the Battisti, G., Stoneman, P., 2004. Inter- and intra-firm effects in the diffusion of new
average work hours at the industry level. The data on the former process technology. Research Policy 32, 1641–1655.
variable are disaggregated by furnace type. The latter variable is Battisti, G., Stoneman, P., 2005. The intra-firm diffusion of new process technologies.
International Journal of Industrial Organization 23, 1–22.
obtained from Tekko Shimbunsha (1955–1970). We multiply the Battisti, G., Canepa, A., Stoneman, P., 2009. E-business usage across and within firms
two variables to obtain the variable of labor input, expressed in in the UK: profitability, externalities and policy. Research Policy 38, 133–143.
terms of total man hours. Blundell, R., Bond, S., 1998. Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic
panel data models. Journal of Econometrics 87, 115–143.
The data pertaining to furnace capacity by plant are obtained Caselli, F., 1999. Technological revolutions. American Economic Review 89, 78–102.
from companies’ semiannual financial reports. They identify the Geroski, P.A., 2000. Models of technology diffusion. Research Policy 29, 603–625.
capacity sizes of each of the furnaces located in each plant. The Hogan, W.T., 1971. Economic history of the iron and steel industry in the United
States. Lexington.
data recorded the capacity size at the end of year t, and investment Ichniowski, C., Shaw, K., 1999. The effects of resource management systems on eco-
was made only when a new furnace was built. The capacity size of nomic performance: an international comparison of U.S. and Japanese plants.
furnace js of technology s located at plant i in year t is thus expressed Management Science 45, 704–721.
js = (1 − ı)K js Japan Steel Federation (1955–1970), Reference Material on Steel Making, Tokyo.
as: Ki,t i,t−1
, where ı is the depreciation rate. The estima-
Jovanovic, B., Lach, S., 1989. Entry, exit, and diffusion with learning by doing. Amer-
tion result reported in Section 3 is based on the assumption that ican Economic Review 79, 690–699.
the value of ı equals zero. To check the robustness to the assump- Lynn, L.H., 1982. How Japan Innovates, A Comparison with the U.S. in the Case of
Oxygen Steelmaking. Westview Press, Boulder, Co.
tion of no capital depreciation, we set the value of ı to be at 0.05 to Mansfield, E., 1963. Intra-firm rates of diffusion of an innovation. Review of Eco-
re-estimate the model. We find that this assumption makes little nomics and Statistics, XLV, 348–359.
change to the original results. While we know the capacity size of MITI, 1958, 1961. Current States of Steel Production Facilities. Japan Steel Federation,
js over s to make the construc- Tokyo (in Japanese).
individual furnace, we aggregated Ki,t Mori, T., 2006. How Important was Skill in Japanese Manufacturing Firms, mimeo,
tion of the variable consistent with those of the others used in the Faculty of Economics. University of Tokyo.
paper. Odagiri, H., Goto, A., 1996. Technology and Industrial Development in Japan: Building
Capabilities by Learning Innovation and Public Policy. Oxford University Press.
Finally, the data on furnace age by plant are from the Ministry Rose, N.L., Joskow, P.L., 1990. The Diffusion of New Technologies: Evidence from the
of International Trade and Industry (MITI, 1958, 1961). The data Electric Utility Industry. Rand Journal of Economics 21 (3), 354–373.
source provides the year that an individual furnace was installed Stoneman, P., 2001. The Economics of Technological Diffusion. Blackwell, Oxford.
Tekko Shimbunsha, 1955–1970. Almanac of Steel. Tekko Shimbunsha, Tokyo (in
at each plant in our data set. We supplement the data with semi- Japanese).
annual financial reports published by each company to obtain the von Hippel, E., 2005. Democratizing Innovation. MIT Press, Cambridge.
year at which each individual furnace was shut down. We take a Yoneyama, K., 1978. Innovation and Workplace Management (in Japanese). Boku-
takusha, Tokyo.
simple average of furnace ages over each plant to construct the

Potrebbero piacerti anche