Sei sulla pagina 1di 10

ORGANIZATIONAL BEHAVIOR AND HUMAN DECISION PROCESSES

Vol. 68, No. 1, October, pp. 68–77, 1996


ARTICLE NO. 0090

The Process of Negotiating: Strategy and Timing


as Predictors of Outcomes
MARA OLEKALNS
Department of Management and Industrial Relations, University of Melbourne, Parkville, Victoria, Australia

PHILIP L. SMITH
Department of Psychology, University of Melbourne, Parkville, Victoria, Australia

AND

THERESE WALSH
Department of Psychology, University of Melbourne, Parkville, Victoria, Australia

identifying how the distribution of tactics over time


Using a simulated employment contract negotiation, moves negotiations to resolution (see Holmes (1992)
this research tested for differences in the use of cuing and Putnam (1990) for reviews). It implies that the
and responding strategies across four types of out- frequency with which tactics occur at specific times is
comes (stalemate, win–lose, suboptimum, and opti-
critical to whether negotiations will be resolved. The
mum), over time, and across time and outcomes. The
use of five strategies varied over time, portraying the
second stream has focused on establishing links be-
negotiating process as one of decreasing flexibility. Re- tween the frequency with which strategies are used
sults also showed that distributive outcomes were char- and the quality of negotiated outcomes (e.g., Pruitt &
acterized by high levels of positional information ex- Lewis, 1975; see Putnam & Jones, 1982, for an early
change whereas integrative agreements were charac- review) and implies that outcome quality is primarily
terized by high levels of priority-information exchange. a function of the proportions in which distributive and
It was possible to further differentiate two integrative integrative strategies are used. In this research, we
outcomes (suboptimum and optimum) in terms of how link the two approaches by considering if both fre-
two strategies were used over time: optimum outcomes quency and timing determine whether a settlement is
were associated with a rapid decrease in positional ar-
reached and the quality of that settlement.
guing and a slight increase in restructuring, whereas
suboptimum outcomes showed the reverse pattern. Nei- A substantial proportion of the research examining
ther the frequency with which strategies were used nor links between negotiator strategies and outcomes has
their timing was able to differentiate impasse from focused on establishing relationships between the fre-
win–lose outcomes. q 1996 Academic Press, Inc. quency of strategy use and the quality (integrativeness)
of negotiated outcomes. A fundamental assumption in
this research is that negotiators are strongly influenced
Two streams of negotiation research, both focusing by their general orientation to the negotiation (e.g.,
on the frequency with which particular strategies and Carnevale & Pruitt, 1992; Lewicki & Litterer, 1985;
tactics are used, acknowledge the importance of lan- Pruitt, 1990). Researchers have distinguished between
guage in negotiation. The first stream, represented by distributive (or competitive) and integrative (or collab-
phase models of negotiation, has been concerned with orative) orientations and have argued that these differ-
ences in orientation result in different goals, strategies
and tactics (e.g., Putnam, 1990). There is considerable
This research was supported by funding from a University of Mel-
bourne Special Initiatives Grant, an Economics and Commerce Fac- empirical support for this argument and for the view
ulty Research Grant and Australian Research Council Grant that these differences affect negotiator outcomes.
SG7935603. We thank Sue Olaman and Cindy Shum for their assis- Negotiations that are characterized by a collabora-
tance in transcribing the videotapes of negotiations, and two anony- tive, problem-solving orientation emphasize similari-
mous reviewers for their comments on an earlier version of this pa-
per. Address correspondence and reprint requests to Mara Olekalns,
ties between negotiators and have as their aim the
Dept. of Management & Industrial Relations, University of Mel- identification of common goals (Deutsch, 1973; Lew-
bourne, Parkville, Victoria, Australia 3052. icki & Litterer, 1985). They are employed when individ-

0749-5978/96 $18.00 68
Copyright q 1996 by Academic Press, Inc.
All rights of reproduction in any form reserved.

/ a708$$2642 09-23-96 11:16:14 obhal AP: OBHDP


STRATEGIES, TIMING, AND OUTCOMES 69

uals place a high priority on achieving both their part- Weingart et al., 1993; Zubek, Pruitt, Peirce, McGillic-
ner’s and their own goals (Pruitt, 1983). Such negotia- cuddy & Syna, 1992).
tions seek to maximize the resource pool and use While this research establishes strong support for a
information exchange as a mechanism for establishing relationship between the frequency with which negoti-
trust, understanding opponents’ needs and prefer- ators use distributive and integrative strategies and
ences, and retaining flexibility until the close of negoti- the outcomes that they achieve, it treats the two styles
ations (Wilson & Putnam, 1990). Integrative outcomes of bargaining and their associated outcomes as mutu-
are more likely to occur when individuals adopt a col- ally exclusive. Such analyses ignore the complex,
laborative orientation, which is characterized by more mixed-motive nature of negotiations, which requires
proposals and counterproposals (Pruitt & Lewis, 1975), individuals to both identify the available resources and
problem-solving (Putnam & Wilson, 1989), discussions determine their distribution (e.g., Lax & Sebenius,
about the workability of solutions (Putnam & Wilson, 1986; Putnam, 1990). It further neglects the possibility
1989), a greater level of agreement with opponents’ that outcomes are not determined solely by the fre-
proposals (Donohue, Diez & Hamilton, 1985; Putnam & quency with which strategies are used, but also their
Jones, 1989; Roloff, Tutzauer & Dailey, 1989), more timing. For example Putnam (1990), in reviewing mod-
effort in uncovering underlying needs, less time in gen- els of negotiation, links the temporal location of integ-
erating specific solutions (Sheppard, Blumenfeld- rative and distributive strategies to negotiation out-
Jones & Roth, 1989), and more systematic concessions comes. On this basis, we consider whether the timing
(Pruitt & Lewis, 1975). Generally, such strategies re- of negotiator strategies is a useful predictor of outcome
flect limited positional commitment and greater flexi- quality.
bility (Pruitt & Lewis, 1975; Sheppard et al., 1989; Comparatively little research has examined whether
Weingart et al., 1993). the distribution of strategies over time predicts either
Conversely, negotiations characterized by a competi- the resolution of negotiations or the quality of that reso-
tive orientation emphasize differences and are associ- lution. Indirect support for this argument is found in
ated with more coercive processes aimed at influencing the mediation literature, which provides evidence that
opponents’ resistance points while maximizing own tactic use across phases varies as a function of whether
gain (Deutsch, 1973; Lax & Sebenius, 1986; Lewicki & or not disputes are resolved. This research has shown
Litterer, 1985). As a consequence, information ex- that resolved and unresolved disputes differ in terms
change becomes tactical (Putnam & Jones, 1982; Wil- of strategy distribution across mediation phases. Gen-
son & Putnam, 1990), with negotiators being concerned erally, agreement mediators use all tactics available to
to maximize the information they receive while min- them more evenly across the mediation session (Do-
imizing the information that they give (Walton & nohue, 1989). However, they implement information
McKersie, 1965). In such negotiations, the exchange of search earlier in the negotiation (Donohue, 1989) and
information is used as a means to control the negotia- spend more time in the middle stages discussing facts
tion process and is dominated by information seeking and interests (Donohue, Drake & Roberts, 1994) while
rather than information giving (Wilson & Putnam, also managing process (Jones, 1988). By the end of ne-
1990). Increased argumentation, threats, and the as- gotiations, they are more focused on proposal develop-
sertion of needs all signal an attempt to gain power ment (Jones, 1988). This research identifies the timing
within the negotiation (Wilson & Putnam, 1990). Dis- of mediator interventions as critical in determining
tributive outcomes, which are a likely consequence of whether disputes will be successfully resolved.
such tactics, are characterized by positional and irrele- Further indirect support is provided by Lim and
vant argumentation (Lewis & Fry, 1977; Lewicki & Murnighan (1994), who tested patterns of negotiator
Litterer, 1985; Pruitt & Lewis, 1975; Putnam & Wilson, activity against four models. Although they found some
1989), personal attacks (Lewis & Fry, 1977), and high evidence of increases in concessions as the deadline
demands and concessions (Bateman, 1980; Hamner & approached, they also reported considerable individual
Harnett, 1975; MacMurray & Lawler, 1986; Putnam & differences in the frequency and pattern with which
Wilson, 1989; Smith, Pruitt & Carnevale, 1982). Fur- different tactics were used. A plausible explanation is
thermore, increases in positional argumentation are that there is a direct relationship not only between the
associated with more false information, pressure tac- frequency, but also the pattern of tactics and eventual
tics, and the demand for concessions (Pruitt & Lewis, outcomes. Finally, Putnam, Wilson, and Turner (1990)
1975), as well as an increased possibility of deadlock provide direct support by demonstrating that the tim-
(Roloff et al., 1989). These tactics result in reduced in- ing of strategies predicts outcome quality: integrative
formation exchange, greater positional commitment outcomes are associated with greater flexibility and
and increased hostility (Carnevale & Lawler, 1987; creativity in the final stages of negotiation, whereas

/ a708$$2642 09-23-96 11:16:14 obhal AP: OBHDP


70 OLEKALNS, SMITH, AND WALSH

distributive outcomes are associated with more posi- sistency (Wilson & Putnam, 1990) require some level
tional argument in these stages. of contentiousness. Therefore, within the class of integ-
In this research, we consider how the frequency and rative outcomes, the use of distributive tactics will dis-
timing of strategies distinguishes resolved from unre- tinguish optimum from suboptimum outcomes: Con-
solved disputes, and how it affects the quality of resolu- tentious tactics aimed at testing the limits of the nego-
tion. We consider two broad classes of outcomes, dis- tiation should be higher for negotiations ending in
tributive and integrative, and further consider the pos- optimum agreements. Further, negotiations ending in
sibility of more fine-grained distinctions between two optimum outcomes will be characterized by a greater
kinds of distributive outcome (impasse and win–lose) use of contentious tactics early in the negotiation pro-
and two kinds of integrative outcome (suboptimum and cess, whereas suboptimum outcomes will be character-
optimum). Win–lose outcomes are characterized by low ized by an increasing use of contentious tactics towards
joint profit; suboptimum and optimum outcomes are the end of negotiations.
characterized by high joint profit and are distinguished
on the basis of their integrativeness quotient (Tripp & METHOD
Sondak, 1992).
Past research has demonstrated that distributive Subjects
and integrative outcomes are distinguished by the One hundred twenty-eight undergraduate psychol-
more frequent use, respectively, of distributive and in- ogy students at the University of Melbourne partici-
tegrative strategies. Given the need for all negotiators pated in the negotiation of an employment contract.
to both create and claim value (Lax & Sebenius, 1986) Participants were run in pairs in separate sessions.
we expect the two classes of outcomes to differ not only Outcomes were classified as falling into one of four out-
in the frequency with which these tactics are used, but comes types (stalemate, distributive, suboptimum, op-
also their distribution over time: Negotiations ending timum) according to the criteria outlined below. Thirty-
in distributive outcomes will be dominated by the use of nine outcomes were classifiable according to these cri-
distributive tactics, with integrative tactics increasing teria.
over time to facilitate settlement; negotiations ending
in integrative outcomes will be dominated by the use Procedure
of integrative tactics, with distributive bargaining in-
creasing over time as individuals claim value. Subjects participated in the negotiation of an em-
When negotiations end in distributive outcomes, the ployment contract. Written instructions assigned the
principal task for negotiators is to avoid a conflict spiral role of either an employer or employee, described the
that results in stalemate (Ben-Yoav & Pruitt, 1984; Pru- task, and gave them their payoff schedule and a con-
itt, 1981, 1983) and this is most likely to be achieved tract for recording their final outcome. They were re-
through the incorporation of some integrative strategies quired to reach agreement on the eight issues shown
(Pruitt, 1981). Therefore, within the class of distributive in Table 1. As can be seen from the table, salary, annual
outcomes, stalemates and win–lose outcomes will be raise, location, and package allowed trade-offs; vaca-
differentiated on the basis of the frequency of conces- tion, start date, and medical benefits were distributive,
sions, which will be higher for win–lose outcomes. It is, whereas contract duration was compatible (i.e., both
however, unlikely that such concessions will be evenly negotiators earned their highest points by agreeing to
spread throughout the negotiation; rather, the use of sign a 6-year contract). Subjects were instructed to
this tactic is more likely to increase during the latter maximize the value of the contract for themselves. A
part of the negotiation, as predicted by deadline models lottery offering a small cash prize was used to provide
(Lim & Murnighan, 1994). Two patterns should, there- an incentive for this; lottery tickets were allocated on
fore, distinguish win–lose outcomes from stalemates: a the basis of contract value. No points were awarded
decline in positional arguing over time and a comple- for stalemates. Negotiation were conducted face-to-face
mentary increase in concessions over time. and were videotaped for subsequent analysis.
For negotiations ending in integrative outcomes the
Classification of Outcomes
principal task for negotiators is to avoid ending negoti-
ations before all solutions have been satisfactorily ex- Outcomes were classified as follows (the number of
plored (Ben-Yoav & Pruitt, 1984; Pruitt, 1981, 1983; outcomes so classified is given in brackets). Stalemates
Thompson, 1990; Weingart et al., 1993) and this is most (9) were negotiations that were unresolved at the end of
likely to be achieved by using a proportion of distribu- the 25-min negotiating period. The remaining outcome
tive strategies. Both the expansion of the resource pool types were defined on the basis of joint outcome.
(Pruitt, 1981) and a test of opponent integrity and con- The integrativeness of outcomes was determined by

/ a708$$2642 09-23-96 11:16:14 obhal AP: OBHDP


STRATEGIES, TIMING, AND OUTCOMES 71

TABLE 1
Payoff Matrices for Employers and Employees

Employer payoffs
Salary (Gains) Vacation (Gains) Start date (Gains) Annual raise (Gains)

$25,000 4000 2 wks 6000 1 Nov 2400 2% 1600


$26,000 3000 2 21 wks 4500 15 Oct 1800 4% 1200
$27,000 2000 3 wks 3000 1 Oct 1200 6% 800
$28,000 1000 3 21 wks 1500 15 Sept 600 8% 400
$29,000 000 4 wks 000 1 Sept 000 10% 000
Location (Gains) Contract (Gains) Package (Gains) Medical benefit

Melbourne 3200 6 years 1200 $2,000 800 25% medical 2400


Sydney 2400 5 years 900 $4,000 600 50% medical 1800
Perth 1600 4 years 600 $6,000 400 75% medical 1200
Adelaide 800 3 years 300 $8,000 300 100% medical 600
Brisbane 000 2 years 000 $10,000 000 . . . & dental 000

Employee payoffs
Salary (Gains) Vacation (Gains) Start due (Gains) Annual raise (Gains)

$25,000 000 2 wks 000 1 Nov 000 2% 000


$26,000 400 2 21 wks 1500 15 Oct 600 4% 1000
$27,000 800 3 wks 3000 1 Oct 1200 6% 2000
$28,000 1200 3 21 wks 4500 15 Sept 1800 8% 3000
$29,000 1600 4 wks 6000 1 Sept 2400 10% 4000

Location (Gains) Contract (Gains) Package (Gains) Medical benefit

Melbourne 000 2 years 000 $2,000 000 25% medical 000


Sydney 200 3 years 300 $4,000 800 50% medical 600
Perth 400 4 years 600 $6,000 1600 75% medical 1200
Adelaide 600 5 years 900 $8,000 2400 100% medical 1800
Brisbane 800 6 years 1200 $10,000 3200 . . . & dental 2400

negotiator performance on the four issues that enabled Coding of Negotiations


trade-offs. Win–lose (10) outcomes were negotiations
The coding scheme described by Donohue et al.
in which negotiator joint profit did not exceed the sum
(1981) and subsequently adapted by Alexander, Schul,
of the compromise solutions. Fully integrative agree-
and Babukus (1988) was modified to distinguish be-
ments (i.e., those in which negotiators located all poten-
tween positional and priority information exchange.
tial trade-offs) yielded a joint outcome of 14,400 points
The revised classificatory scheme allows for the coding
across the four issues; if negotiators behaved distribu-
of each utterance as one of 12 responses (to the other’s
tively, the maximum joint outcome was 9,600 points.
preceding utterance) and as one of 13 cues (for the oth-
Agreements were classified as integrative if the joint
er’s next utterance). Two raters coded all transcripts
outcome was between 12,000 and 14,400 points (12,000
and reliability was assessed using Cohen’s k. Bakeman
representing the midpoint between distributive and
and Gottman (1986) classify k in the range 0.70–0.74
fully integrative outcomes). This category was further
as very good and those at or above 0.75 as excellent.
subdivided on the basis of an integrativeness quotient
Cohen’s k was 0.74 for cues and 0.75 for responses. All
(Tripp & Sondak, 1992): A 0 to 1 scale is used to repre-
discrepancies were resolved through discussion.
sent the ratio of better to worse outcomes, with ‘‘1’’
representing settlements for which neither individual
Factor Analysis of Cues and Responses
can obtain a better outcome without worsening an op-
ponent’s outcome. Optimum solutions (12) were defined Utterances were classified as representing one of 13
as those for with in integrativeness quotient of 0.95 or cues and one of 12 responses, yielding a complex data
better. Integrative outcomes with an integrativeness set. Following Weingart, Hyder, Prietula, and Geno-
quotient below 0.95 were classified as suboptimum (8). vese (1995), the initial classification of utterances was

/ a708$$2642 09-23-96 11:16:14 obhal AP: OBHDP


72 OLEKALNS, SMITH, AND WALSH

TABLE 2
Factor Analysis of Cues

Factor

Cuing tactics Description of tactics I II III IV

Positional information Deny relevance Of an opponent’s arguments .88 .31 0.14 .11
Give positional info Arguments in support of own position .87 .06 0.001 0.01
Initial offers Makes or repeats an initial offer .85 .12 .24 .24
Treats/promises Uses threats or promises to change .79 0.06 0.21 0.12
opponent’s position
Find fault Attributes bad faith to opponent .78 .25 0.08 .26
Restructuring Restructuring Proposes a new way for proceeding 0.06 .87 .19 0.05
Openings Makes an open-ended, non-directional .25 .71 0.05 0.02
statement
Seek positional info Requests additional information .45 .65 .17 .11
about opponent’s position
Priority information Seek priority info Requests information about the value 0.15 .15 .85 0.14
of issue(s)
Give priority info Provides information about the value 0.04 .41 .75 .19
of issue(s)
Indicate flexibility Suggests a range of options or trade- .06 0.21 .73 .36
offs across issues
Concessions Request acceptance Proposes modifications to an 0.01 0.08 0.001 .91
opponent’s offer
Offer concession Makes an offer that has a lower .25 .12 .21 .77
value to self than the immediately
preceding offer
Eigen value 4.52 2.54 1.79 1.01
% variance 34.8 19.6 13.7 7.8

factor analyzed to explore the possibility that tactics tion strategy. Finally, the two tactics of proposing mod-
could be grouped together in a meaningful way. Subse- ifications to an opponent’s offer or making concessions
quent analyses are based on the factors that emerge lead us to interpret Factor 4 as representing conces-
from these analyses, which could be considered to rep- sionary behavior.
resent strategies.
Factor analysis of cues. A principal components Factor analysis of responses. A principal compo-
analysis with Varimax rotation yielded four distinct nents analysis with Varimax rotation yielded three dis-
cue factors, shown in Table 2. Factor 1 includes tactics tinct response factors, shown in Table 3. Two of the fac-
that, according to Donohue et al.’s (1981) classificatory tors that emerged in this analysis again fit the descrip-
scheme, represent either attacking or defending moves. tions of distributive and integrative bargaining. Factor
This factor includes tactics aimed at establishing and 1 is represented by attacking and defending tactics that
supporting a negotiator’s position while attempting to focus on opponents’ positional arguments, coupled with
change an opponent’s position. These tactics are typical contentious tactics aimed at changing that position. This
of a distributive bargaining style (e.g., Lewicki & Lit- factor is interpreted as representing a positional infor-
terer, 1985) and are interpreted as providing positional mation strategy. Factor 2, which is interpreted as repre-
information. The second factor better represents tactics senting a priority information strategy, is composed of
that attempt to break negotiating scripts by either en- what Donohue et al. (1981) classify as integrative tac-
gaging in nondirectional discussion or proposing a new tics: giving and seeking priority information, as well as
way of tackling the negotiation. Factor 2 is therefore a willingness to accept offers. Finally, the third factor
interpreted as negotiator attempts to restructure the also represents a contentious style of bargaining in
negotiation. Consistent with descriptions of integrative which negotiators either reject opponents’ offers or re-
bargaining (e.g., Lewicki & Litterer, 1985), Factor 3 is state their demands. This factor is interpreted as rejec-
composed of tactics that either seek or provide priority tion, as these tactics reject opponents’ positions either
information, or suggest tradeoffs; consequently, this explicitly or implicitly. It will be noted that one response
factor is interpreted as representing a priority-informa- tactic, accepts arguments, has a negative loading on the

/ a708$$2642 09-23-96 11:16:14 obhal AP: OBHDP


STRATEGIES, TIMING, AND OUTCOMES 73

TABLE 3
Factor Analysis of Responses

Factor

Responding tactics Description of tactics I II III

Positional information Give positional info Arguments in support of own position .88 0.05 0.05
Seek positional info Requests additional information about opponent’s .85 0.25 0.14
position
Reject argument Opponent’s arguments are treated as irrelevant to .85 0.19 .23
settlement
Continue discussion . . . Of previous topic .82 .28 .03
Personal insult Rejects opponent’s argument with a personal insult .63 0.03 .54
Topic change Introduces a new topic for discussion .66 .23 .13
Priority information Give priority info Provides information about the value of issue(s) .07 .92 0.11
Seek priority info Requests information about the value of issue(s) .06 .88 .04
Accept offer Explicit acceptance of opponent’s proposal 0.09 .55 .28
Rejection Reject offer Explicit rejection of opponent’s offer .48 .08 .71
Assert wants States requirements and expects compliance .55 .22 .56
Accept argument Accepts opponent’s point of view, but not offer .24 0.02 0.72
Eigen value 4.72 2.29 1.43
% variance 39.3 19.1 12.0

third response factor. Consequently, it is retained as a VAs, one for cues and one for responses, were con-
single tactic in further analyses. ducted.2
The preceding discussion of tactics and outcomes
RESULTS suggested (a) that tactical differences would distin-
guish integrative from distributive outcomes; (b) that
Negotiations ranged in length from 10 to 25 min, optimum integrative outcomes would be distinguished
consequently differing in the total number of strategies from suboptimum ones; (c) that win–lose outcomes
used. This raises the possibility that any differences would be distinguished from stalemates. A series of
that emerged if analyses were conducted on raw fre- three planned comparisons on the Outcome factor was
quencies might simply reflect these differences in over- used to test these hypotheses: Contrast 1 compared
all length. Because our hypotheses involve the relative, distributive and integrative outcomes, Contrast 2 com-
rather than the absolute, frequency with which partic- pared optimum and suboptimum outcomes, and Con-
ular strategies are used, the analysis was carried out trast 3 compared stalemates and win–lose outcomes.
on the proportion of times a particular strategy was We argued that the use of strategies and tactics could
used by a dyad during a given phase of the negotiation. differ over time; we further argued that trends over
To avoid problems of linear dependency between values time may serve to differentiate between the four cate-
of the dependent variable (because the sets of propor- gories of outcomes. To test these hypotheses, each tran-
tions always sum to one), one of the strategies was script was divided into six equal segments, determined
arbitrarily dropped from the analysis to create a lin- by the number of utterances. To test for differences
early independent set, in the manner described by Har- in the distribution of tactics over time, the linear and
ris (1985, pp. 109–115). Before carrying out the analy- quadratic trend components were also extracted.
sis, the remaining proportions were subject to a 2arc-
q
sin p transformation to stabilize the variances, as Analysis of Cuing Strategies
described by Winer (1971, pp. 399–400).1 The trans-
The relationship between Time, Outcome and Cuing
formed proportions were then subject to a multivariate
Strategy was examined using MANOVA, with the pro-
analysis of variance (MANOVA). Two separate MANO-
portion of strategies within each time segment provid-
ing the dependent variable. Four significant interac-
1
Because there are only n 0 1 degrees of freedom in a set of n tions were found: Strategy interacted with Outcome
proportions, this procedure does not result in any loss of information.
In the subsequent analysis of the simple effects of tactic type, how-
2
ever, all n tactics were analyzed so that their effects over time could As neither analysis violated sphericity assumptions, univariate
be characterized individually. results are reported (Tabachnik & Fidell, 1983).

/ a708$$2642 09-23-96 11:16:14 obhal AP: OBHDP


74 OLEKALNS, SMITH, AND WALSH

p õ .005, was lowest in the middle stages of the negotia-


tion.
The use of two cuing strategies differentiated distrib-
utive and integrative outcomes. When negotiations
ended in distributive outcomes, dyads used more posi-
tional-information strategies, F(1,35) Å 15.54, p õ
.001, and fewer priority-information strategies, F(1,35)
Å 15.54, p õ .001, than when negotiations ended in
integrative outcomes. The more frequent use of posi-
tional-information strategies, F(1,35) Å 5.23, p õ .05,
also differentiated suboptimum from optimum out-
comes, although this finding was qualified by a three-
way interaction with Time, as described below.
Within the class of integrative outcomes, linear
trends in the use of positional-information strategies,
F(1,175) Å 9.75, p õ .005, and restructuring strategies,
F(1,175) Å 12.72, p õ .001, over time further distin-
FIG. 1. Mean frequency of cuing strategy use over time. guished optimum and suboptimum outcomes. As can
be seen in Fig. 2, the use of positional-information
strategies increased marginally over time when negoti-
(distributive vs integrative), F(2,70) Å 5.97, p õ .005; ations ended in suboptimum outcomes and decreased
with Outcome (suboptimum vs optimum), F(2,70) Å over time when negotiations ended in optimum out-
3.33, p õ .05; and with Time, F(10,350) Å 3.09, p õ comes. Conversely, the use of restructuring strategies
.001. These last two interactions are qualified by a decreased over time when negotiations end in subopti-
three-way interaction between Strategy, Time and mum outcomes, and increased marginally over time
Outcome (suboptimum vs optimum), F(10,350) Å 2.41, when they ended in optimum outcomes. It is also evi-
p õ .01. To further explore these effects, the interac- dent that, over time, the use of these strategies di-
tions were decomposed by strategy into their simple verged when negotiations ended in suboptimum out-
effects. comes, converging when they ended in optimum out-
Analysis of simple effects showed, first, that two cu- comes.
ing strategies varied in their use over time. As can be
Analysis of Responding Strategies
seen in Fig. 1, a significant quadratic trend in the use
of positional-information strategies, F(1,175) Å 4.21, p The relationship among Time, Outcome, and Re-
õ .05, showed this strategy to peak in the middle stages sponding Strategy was examined using MANOVA,
of the negotiation. Conversely, a quadratic trend in the with the proportion of strategies within each time seg-
use of concession-exchange strategies, F(1,175) Å 8.47, ment providing the dependent variable. Two significant

FIG. 2. Mean frequency of cuing strategy use as a function of outcomes and time.

/ a708$$2642 09-23-96 11:16:14 obhal AP: OBHDP


STRATEGIES, TIMING, AND OUTCOMES 75

FIG. 3. Mean frequency of responding strategy use over time.

interactions emerged. Strategy interacted with both in negotiations suggests that their role varies as a func-
Outcome (distributive vs integrative), F(2,70) Å 3.69, tion of temporal context: They signal flexibility, test
p õ .05, and Time, F(10,350) Å 2.41, p õ .01. To further firmness and define the bargaining zone early in the
explore these effects, the interactions were decomposed negotiations while late in the negotiations they are
by strategy into their simple effects. used to reach settlement. (Note that this is consistent
Analysis of simple effects showed that three response with the arguments made by several authors [Lewis &
strategies varied in their use over time. These trends Fry, 1977; Putnam, 1990; Putnam & Wilson, 1989;
are shown in Fig. 3. A significant quadratic trend in Roloff et al., 1989] that the same strategy may serve
the use of positional-information responses, F(1,175) Å either integrative or distributive functions, depending
14.06, p õ .001, showed this strategy to peak in the on context.) Second, negotiators become progressively
middle stages of the negotiation. Conversely, a qua- less willing to respond by accepting opponent’s argu-
dratic trend in the use of rejection responses, F(1,175) ments as the negotiation progresses. Thus, the limits
Å 8.32, p õ .005, was lowest in the middle stages of of the negotiation are defined early in the negotiation
the negotiation. Finally, a linear trend, F(1,175) Å 6.83, process. The key means for challenging these limits is
p Å .01, showed the acceptance of opponent’s argu- in the high levels of positional-information cuing and
ments to decrease over time. responding cuing and responding during the middle
The use of one response strategy differentiated dis- phases of the negotiation.
tributive and integrative outcomes. In a pattern paral- Consistent with past research, our results showed
leling findings for the use of cue strategies, when nego- that integrative and distributive outcomes were associ-
tiations ended in distributive outcomes, dyads used ated with different levels of positional and priority in-
fewer priority-information strategies, F(1,35) Å 8.62, formation exchange. Whereas distributive outcomes
p õ .01, than when negotiations ended in integrative were characterized by a higher proportion of positional-
outcomes. A second strategy, the use of position infor- information cues and responses, as well as a lower pro-
mation, was a marginally significant differentiator, portion of priority-information cues, the reverse was
F(1,35) Å 3.83, p Å .058, between distributive and in- true for integrative outcomes. These results clearly fit
tegrative outcomes. with Fisher and Ury’s (1981) distinction between posi-
tional and principled bargaining and further demon-
DISCUSSION strate that low levels of positional arguing are associ-
ated with functional outcomes. They are also consistent
Several strategies varied over time independent of with past research showing that integrative outcomes
the way in which negotiations ended. Not only are the are characterized by higher levels of information ex-
temporal patterns broadly consistent with phase mod- change (Thompson, 1990; Thompson & Hastie, 1990).
els of negotiation (as described by Holmes, 1992), they The frequency with which tactics are used did not, how-
also portrayed the negotiating process as one of de- ever, enable more fine-grained distinctions within the
creasing flexibility. First, the more frequent use of con- two outcome types to be made. This suggests that, al-
cessionary cues and rejection responses early and late though the frequency with which strategies are used

/ a708$$2642 09-23-96 11:16:14 obhal AP: OBHDP


76 OLEKALNS, SMITH, AND WALSH

channels negotiators to either a distributive or an in- be the ability to define the negotiation in common
tegrative path, it does not determine the quality of out- terms. Pinkley and Northcraft (1994) have shown that
comes within those paths. representations of conflict converge over time and spec-
Extending this point, negotiations that ended in opti- ulate that this may be a necessary condition for resolu-
mum and suboptimum outcomes differed in the use of tion. On this basis, we propose that impasse dyads fail
two cuing strategies (positional information; restructur- to develop a common understanding of the problem,
ing) over time. Two patterns differentiated optimum from and further speculate that this may, in turn, affect
suboptimum outcomes: The relative stability of these information processing. Why such differences occur in
strategies over time and the extent to which their use distributive negotiations is an open question. At a
had converged or diverged by the end of negotiations. macro-level, situational and dispositional factors may
Putnam (1994) argues that the way in which negotiators impact on cognitive representations of conflict. At a
respond to their partners’ cues conveys implicit messages micro-level, it may be the specific sequencing of strate-
about how negotiations should be interpreted and struc- gies (rather than their frequency or temporal distribu-
tured. We propose that how cues are distributed over tion) that facilitates or inhibits the development of
time also conveys an implicit message, signalling a nego- shared meaning.
tiators’ dominant motive. Because its use is more predict- We were able to distinguish distributive and integ-
able, the more stable of the two strategies establishes rative outcomes in terms of the frequency of strategy
the negotiating context; use of the less stable strategy is use, suggesting that information availability or suc-
interpreted within this context. cessful differentiation moves negotiators from distribu-
Earlier, we argued that negotiators must both create tive to integrative outcomes: priority information ex-
and claim value to optimize outcomes. For example, change and negotiator flexibility provide the informa-
Pinkley, Griffith, and Northcraft (1995) demonstrated tion necessary for recognizing differing priorities.
that the self-reported use of mixed-motive strategies However, maximizing benefits also requires effective
is associated with better joint outcomes. The second information processing or integration. This is achieved
pattern described above identifies the management of when negotiators are able to restructure the negotiat-
these strategies as critical to achieving optimum out- ing process, achieving a balance between conten-
comes. Achieving optimum outcomes is a cognitively tiousness and cooperation. Our results suggest that,
complex task that requires dyads to both differentiate, whereas the frequency with which priority and posi-
recognizing multiple perspectives on a problem, and tional-information strategies (as both cues and re-
integrate, building relationships between these per- sponses) are used is sufficient to move negotiators from
spectives (definitions as given by Gruenfeld, 1995). In distributive to integrative outcomes, the temporal dis-
the present case, positional information seems better tribution of two cuing strategies (positional informa-
suited to differentiation and restructuring better suited tion and restructuring) is critical to whether dyads
to integration. Our results then suggest that when fully integrate.
these tasks are accomplished affects outcome opti-
REFERENCES
mality. Suboptimal negotiators focus increasingly on
the task of differentiation over time, whereas optimum Alexander, J. F., Schul, P. L., & Babakus, E. (1991). Analyzing inter-
negotiators focus increasingly on the task of integra- personal communications in industrial marketing negotiations.
tion over time. In doing so, optimum negotiators estab- Journal of the Academy of Marketing Sciences, 19, 129–139.
lish a balance between the two strategies suggesting Bateman, T. S. (1980). Contingent concession strategies in bar-
that this, too, is critical to the quality of integrative gaining. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 26,
212–221.
outcomes.
Bakeman, R., & Gottman, J. M. (1986). Observing interaction: An
The distribution of strategies over time did not, how- introduction to sequential analysis, Cambridge: Cambridge Univ.
ever, differentiate stalemates from win–lose outcomes. Press.
Information processing problems and the cognitive rep- Ben-Yoav, O., & Pruitt, D. G. (1984). Resistance to yielding and the
resentation of negotiations provide alternative expla- expectation of cooperative future interaction. Journal of Experi-
nations for outcome differences in these dyads. Pinkley mental Social Psychology, 20, 323–335.
et al. (1995) found that fixed-pie expectations affect Carnevale, P. J. D., & Lawler, E. J. (1987). Time pressure and the
development of integrative agreements in bilateral negotiations.
both information availability (by affecting search strat- Journal of Conflict Resolution, 30, 636–659.
egies) and information processing, consequently lead- Carnevale, P. J., & Pruitt, D. G. (1992). Negotiation and mediation.
ing to low joint outcomes. Although our results rule out Annual Review of Psychology, 43, 531–582.
the possibility of differences in information availabil- Deutsch, M. (1973). The resolution of conflict. New Haven: Yale Univ.
ity, they do not rule out differences in information pro- Press.
cessing. A second difference between these dyads may Donohue, W. A. (1989). Communicative competence in mediators. In

/ a708$$2642 09-23-96 11:16:14 obhal AP: OBHDP


STRATEGIES, TIMING, AND OUTCOMES 77

K. Kressel, D. G. Pruitt and Associates (Eds.), Mediation Research: coordination. The International Journal of Conflict Resolution, 5,
The Process and Effectiveness of Third-Party Intervention. San 284–298.
Francisco: Jossey-Bass Publishers. Putnam, L. L. (1990). Reframing integrative and distributive bar-
Donohue, W. A., Drake, L., & Roberts, A. J. (1994). Mediator issue gaining: A process perspective. Research on Negotiation in Organi-
intervention strategies: A replication and some conclusions. Medi- zations, 2, 3–30.
ation Quarterly, 11, 261–274. Putnam, L. L., Wilson, S. R., & Turner, D. B. (1990). The evolution
Donohue, W. A., Diez, M. E., & Hamilton, M. (1984). Coding natural- of policy arguments in teachers’ negotiations. Argumentation, 4,
istic negotiation interaction. Human Communication Research, 10, 129–152.
403–425. Putnam, L. L., & Jones, T. S. (1982) Reciprocity in negotiations: An
Fisher, R., & Ury, W. (1981). Getting to Yes: Negotiating Agreement analysis of bargaining interaction, Communication Monographs,
Without Giving In. Great Britain: Arrow Press. 49, 171–191.
Gruenfeld, D. H. (1995). Status, ideology and integrative complexity Putnam, L. L., & Wilson, S. R. (1989). Argumentation and bargaining
on the U.S. Supreme Court: Rethinking the politics of political strategies as discriminators of integrative outcomes. In M. A.
decision making. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 68, Rahim (Ed.), Managing Conflict: An Interdisciplinary Approach,
5–20. New York: Praeger.
Hamner, W. C., & Harnett, D. L. (1975). The effects of information Putnam, L. L., & Jones, T. S. (1982). Reciprocity in negotiations: An
analysis of bargaining interaction. Communication Monographs,
and aspiration level on bargaining behavior. Journal of Experimen-
tal Social Psychology, 11, 329–342. 49, 171–191.
Roloff, M. E., Tutzauer, F. E., & Dailey, W. O. (1989). The role of
Harris, R. J. (1985). A Primer of Multivariate Statistics (2nd ed.).
argumentation in distributive and integrative bargaining contexts:
Orlando, FL: Academic Press.
seeking relative advantage but at what cost? In M. A. Rahim (Ed.),
Holmes, M. E. (1992). Phase structures in negotiation. In L. L. Put- Managing Conflict: An Interdisciplinary Approach, New York:
nam, & M. E. Roloff (Eds.), Communication and Negotiation, New- Praeger.
bury Park: Sage Publications.
Sheppard, B. H., Blumenfeld-Jones, K., & Roth, J. (1989). Informal
Jones, T. S. (1988). Phase structures in agreement and no-agreement thirdpartyship: Studies of everyday conflict intervention. In K.
mediation. Communication Research, 15, 470–495. Kressel, D. G. Pruitt and Associates (Eds.), Mediation Research:
Lax, D., & Sebenius, J. (1986). The Manager as Negotiator. New The Process and Effectiveness of Third-Party Intervention. San
York: Free Press. Francisco: Jossey-Bass Publishers.
Lewicki, R. J., & Litterer, J. A. (1985). Negotiation. Homewood, IL: Smith, D. L., Pruitt, D. G., & Carnevale, P. J. D. (1982). Matching
Irwin. and mismatching: The effect of own limit, others toughness and
Lewis, S. A., & Fry, W. R. (1977). Effects of visual access and orienta- time pressure on concession rate in negotiation. Journal of Person-
tion on the discovery of integrative bargaining alternatives. Orga- ality and Social Psychology, 42, 876–883.
nizational Behavior and Human Performance, 20, 75–92. Tabachnik, B. G., & Fidell, L. S. (1983). Using Multivariate Statistics.
New York: Harper & Row, Publishers.
Lim, S. G-S., & Murnighan, J. K. (1994). Phases, deadlines and the
bargaining process. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Thompson, L. (1990). An examination of experienced and naive nego-
Processes, 58, 153–171. tiators. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 59, 82–90.
MacMurray, B. K., & Lawler, E. J. (1986). Level-of-aspiration theory Thompson, L., & Hastie, R. (1990). Social perception in negotiation.
and initial stance in bargaining. Representative Research in Social Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 47, 98–123.
Psychology, 16, 35–44. Tripp, T. M., & Sondak, H. (1992). An evaluation of dependent vari-
ables in experimental negotiation studies: Impasse rates and par-
Pinkley, R. L., & Northcraft, G. B. (1994). Conflict frames of refer-
eto efficiency. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Pro-
ence: Implications for dispute resolution and outcomes. Academy
cesses, 51, 273–295.
of Management Journal, 37, 193–205.
Walton, R. E., & McKersie, R. B. (1965). A Behavioral Theory of
Pinkley, R. L., Griffith, R. L., & Northcraft, G. B. (1995). ‘‘Fixed Pie’’
Labor Negotiations: An Analysis of a Social Interaction System,
a la mode: Information availability, information processing and
Ithaca: NY: ILR Press.
the negotiation of suboptimal agreements. Organizational Behav-
Weingart, L. R., Prietula, M. J., Hyder, E. B., & Genovese, C. R. (1995).
ior and Human Decision Processes, 62, 101–112.
Tactical knowledge and the process of negotiation. Paper presented
Pruitt, D. G. (1990). Problem solving and cognitive bias in negotia- at the Academy of Management Meeting, Vancouver, BC.
tion: A commentary. In B. H. Sheppard, M. H. Bazerman, & R. J.
Weingart, L. R., Bennett, R. J., & Brett, J. M. (1993). The impact
Lewicki (Eds.), Research on Negotiation in Organizations (Vol. 2).
of consideration of issues and motivational orientation in group
Greenwich, CT: JAI Press Inc.
negotiation process and outcome. Journal of Applied Psychology,
Pruitt, D. G. (1983). Strategic choice in negotiation. American Behav- 78, 504–517.
ioral Scientist, 27, 167–194.
Wilson, S. R., & Putnam, L. L. (1990). Interaction goals in negotia-
Pruitt, D. G. (1981). Negotiation Behavior. New York: Academic tion. Communication Yearbook, 13, 374–406.
Press, Ltd. Winer, B. J. (1971). Statistical Principles in Experimental Design
Pruitt, D. G., & Lewis, S. A. (1975). Development of integrative solu- (2nd ed.). Tokyo, Japan: McGraw-Hill Kogakusha.
tions in bilateral negotiations. Journal of Personality and Social Zubek, J. M., Pruitt, D. G., Peirce, R. S., McGillicuddy, N. B., & Syna,
Psychology, 31, 621–630. H. (1992). Disputant and mediator behaviors affecting short-term
Putnam, L. L. (1994). Productive conflict: Negotiation as implicit success in mediation. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 36, 546–572.

Received: June 26, 1996

/ a708$$2642 09-23-96 11:16:14 obhal AP: OBHDP

Potrebbero piacerti anche