Sei sulla pagina 1di 151

EF3320

Security Analysis and


Portfolio Management
Semester B 2009 - 2010

Dr. Anson C. K. Au Yeung


City University of Hong Kong
Staff Information
Instructor: Dr. Anson C. K. Au Yeung
Office: P7315
Phone: 2194-2163
Email: anson.auyeung@cityu.edu.hk
Office Hours: By Appointment

Class Schedule
CA1: Wednesday 13:30 – 16:20; Venue LT-16
CA2: Friday 13:30 – 16:20; Venue P2633
CA3: Monday 15:30 – 18:20; Venue P4802

Course Objectives
This course is aimed to provide basic investment theories and applications. After the course
is completed, students are expected to apply fundamental principles in portfolio investments.
More precisely, students will get familiar with basic financial instruments for adequate
applications of investment strategies and portfolio management.

References
1. Course Package
2. Bodie, Kane and Marcus, Investments (8th Edition), McGraw Hill 2009. [BKM]

Assessment
Coursework + Midterm (30%)
Examination (70%)

2
Course Outline
Topic 1 – Expected Utility and Risk Aversion
Readings & References:
 BKM Chapter 6 (Appendix A)

Topic 2 – Review of Mathematics and Statistics

Topic 3 – Risk and Return


Readings & References:
 BKM Chapter 5

Topic 4 – Portfolio Theory


Readings & References:
 BKM Chapter 6, 7

Topic 5 – Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)


Readings & References:
 BKM Chapter 9, 13

Topic 6 – Factor Models


Readings & References:
 BKM Chapter 8, 10, 13

Topic 7 – Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT)


Readings & References:
 BKM Chapter 10, 13

Topic 8 – Anomalies and Market Efficiency


Readings & References:
 BKM Chapter 11

Topic 9 – Fixed Income Securities


Readings & References:
 BKM Chapter 14, 16

Topic 10 – Term Structure of Interest Rates


Readings & References:
 BKM Chapter 15

3
Contents

1 Topic 1 – Expected Utility and Risk Aversion ............................................................... 7


1.1 How to Price a Security?......................................................................................................... 7
1.1.1 Expected Payoffs............................................................................................................. 7
1.1.2 St. Petersburg Paradox .................................................................................................... 8
1.2 Expected Utility Theory ........................................................................................................ 10
1.2.1 The Axioms of Preference ............................................................................................ 10
1.2.2 Utility Functions and Indifference Curve ..................................................................... 10
1.3 Risk Aversion........................................................................................................................ 11
1.3.1 Measuring Risk Aversion.............................................................................................. 13
2 Topic 2 – Review of Mathematics and Statistics .......................................................... 15
2.1 Random Variables ................................................................................................................. 15
2.2 Moments ............................................................................................................................... 15
2.3 Comoments ........................................................................................................................... 18
2.4 Properties of Moments and Comoments ............................................................................... 19
2.5 Linear Regression ................................................................................................................. 19
2.6 Calculus and Optimization .................................................................................................... 20
2.6.1 Functions ....................................................................................................................... 20
2.6.2 Limits ............................................................................................................................ 22
2.6.3 Differentiations ............................................................................................................. 23
2.6.4 Optimizations ................................................................................................................ 25
3 Topic 3 – Risk and Return ............................................................................................. 28
3.1 The Definition of Return ....................................................................................................... 28
3.2 The Definition of Risk .......................................................................................................... 29
3.3 The History of U.S. Return ................................................................................................... 30
3.4 International Evidence .......................................................................................................... 31
3.5 Real and Nominal Rates of Interest ...................................................................................... 33
4 Topic 4 – Portfolio Theory ............................................................................................. 35
4.1 Portfolio Risk and Return ..................................................................................................... 36
4.1.1 Portfolio of Two Assets ................................................................................................ 36
4.1.2 Portfolio of Multiple Assets .......................................................................................... 39
4.2 Diversification....................................................................................................................... 40
4.3 Optimal Portfolio Selection .................................................................................................. 43
4.3.1 Case 1: One Risky Asset + Risk Free Asset ................................................................. 44

4
4.3.2 Case 2: Two Risky Assets + Risk Free Asset ............................................................... 50
4.3.3 Case 3: More than Two Risky Assets + Risk Free Asset .............................................. 63
4.4 Appendix – Portfolio Analysis Using Excel ......................................................................... 67
4.4.1 Mean-Variance Efficient Portfolio................................................................................ 67
5 Topic 5 – Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) .......................................................... 73
5.1 The Market Portfolio............................................................................................................. 74
5.2 Derivation of the CAPM ....................................................................................................... 76
5.3 Implications of the CAPM .................................................................................................... 79
5.3.1 Two Important Graphs .................................................................................................. 80
5.3.2 Replicating the Beta ...................................................................................................... 83
5.4 Risk in the CAPM ................................................................................................................. 84
5.4.1 CML and SML: A Synthesis ......................................................................................... 85
5.5 Estimating Beta ..................................................................................................................... 85
5.6 Empirical Tests of the CAPM ............................................................................................... 87
5.6.1 Time-series Tests of the CAPM .................................................................................... 87
5.6.2 Cross-sectional Tests of the CAPM .............................................................................. 89
6 Topic 6 – Factor Models ................................................................................................. 90
6.1 Single Factor Model .............................................................................................................. 90
6.1.1 The Market Model Return Decomposition ................................................................... 91
6.1.2 The Market Model Variance Decomposition................................................................ 91
6.1.3 The Inputs to Portfolio Analysis ................................................................................... 92
6.1.4 The Market Model and Diversification ......................................................................... 92
6.2 Multifactor Models ............................................................................................................... 94
6.2.1 Factor Models for Portfolios ......................................................................................... 95
6.2.2 Tracking Portfolios ....................................................................................................... 96
6.2.3 Pure Factor Portfolio ..................................................................................................... 98
6.2.4 Risk Premiums of Pure Factor Portfolios...................................................................... 99
7 Topic 7 – Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) ................................................................ 101
7.1 Derivation of the APT ......................................................................................................... 101
7.1.1 Single Factor APT....................................................................................................... 101
7.1.2 Two-Factor APT ......................................................................................................... 103
7.1.3 Multifactor APT .......................................................................................................... 105
7.2 Comments on APT .............................................................................................................. 105
7.2.1 Strength and Weaknesses of APT ............................................................................... 105
7.2.2 Differences between APT and CAPM ........................................................................ 105

5
8 Topic 8 – Anomalies and Market Efficiency .............................................................. 106
8.1 CAPM and the Cross-section of Stock Returns .................................................................. 106
8.2 Size Effect ........................................................................................................................... 107
8.3 Value Effect ........................................................................................................................ 110
8.3.1 The Glamour and Value Strategies ............................................................................. 111
8.4 Momentum Investing Strategies ......................................................................................... 115
8.5 Efficient Market Hypothesis ............................................................................................... 117
8.5.1 Empirical Tests of Efficient Market Hypothesis ......................................................... 118
9 Topic 9 – Fixed Income Securities............................................................................... 120
9.1 Fixed Income Securities and Markets ................................................................................. 120
9.1.1 Types of Fixed Income Securities ............................................................................... 120
9.2 Bond Pricing ....................................................................................................................... 121
9.2.1 Coupon Bond .............................................................................................................. 121
9.2.2 Zero-Coupon Bond ..................................................................................................... 124
9.3 Dirty Price, Clean Price and Accrued Interest .................................................................... 124
9.4 Conventional Yield Measures ............................................................................................. 128
9.4.1 Current Yield .............................................................................................................. 128
9.4.2 Yield-to-Maturity ........................................................................................................ 128
9.5 Default Risk ........................................................................................................................ 131
9.5.1 Traditional Credit Analysis ......................................................................................... 131
9.6 Interest Rate Risk ................................................................................................................ 132
9.6.1 Price Volatility and Bond Characteristics ................................................................... 132
9.6.2 Duration ...................................................................................................................... 134
9.6.3 The Determinants of Duration .................................................................................... 138
9.6.4 Convexity .................................................................................................................... 141
9.6.5 Immunization .............................................................................................................. 143
10 Topic 10 – Term Structure of Interest Rates ............................................................. 145
10.1 The Yield Curve .................................................................................................................. 145
10.1.1 Using the Yield Curve to Price a Bond ....................................................................... 146
10.1.2 Constructing the Theoretical Spot-Rate Curve ........................................................... 146
10.2 Spot and Forward Interest Rates ......................................................................................... 148
10.3 Theories of the Term Structure ........................................................................................... 149
10.3.1 The Expectation Hypothesis ....................................................................................... 150
10.3.2 Liquidity Preference.................................................................................................... 151

6
1 Topic 1 – Expected Utility and Risk Aversion

1.1 How to Price a Security?

One of the most important questions in Finance is how to price a security. In Economics, we
know the price of a good can be determined by its demand and supply. Can we follow this
approach to price a security? Unlike a good, however, a security does not provide an
immediate consumption benefit to you. Rather, it is a saving instrument in which the future
payoff is random. In order to study the demand of these uncertain future payoffs, we need a
theory to understand investors’ preferences. Our goal here is to understand how investors
choose between different securities that have different risks and returns.

1.1.1 Expected Payoffs

One possible measure is to assume that investors value risky investment based on expected
payoffs.

Example 1.1

Which investment would you choose?


Investment A Investment B
Payoff Probability Payoff Probability
15 1/3 20 1/3
10 1/3 12 1/3
5 1/3 4 1/3

The expected payoff of:


1 1 1
Investment A = ×15 + ×10 + × 5 = 10
3 3 3
1 1 1
Investment B = × 20 + ×12 + × 4 = 12
3 3 3

However, the expected payoff is unlikely to be the only criterion.

7
1.1.2 St. Petersburg Paradox

You are invited to play a coin-toss game. To enter the game, you have to pay an entry fee.
Thereafter, a coin is tossed until the first head appears. The number of tails that appears until
the first head is tossed is used to compute your payoff.

The probabilities and payoffs for various outcomes:


No of Tails Probability (p) Payoff (x) Probability × Payoff
0 1/2 $1 $1/2
1 1/4 $2 $1/2
2 1/8 $4 $1/2
3 1/16 $8 $1/2


n (1/2)n+1 $2n $1/2

How much would you be willing to pay for this game based on its expected value?
The expected payoff:

= ∑ p ×x
i =1
i i

1 1 1 1
= ×1 + × 2 + × 4 + × 8 + 
2 4 8 16
11 1 1 
=  × 2 + × 4 + × 8 + 
22 4 8 
1
= (1 + 1 + 1 + )
2
= ∞

The St. Petersburg Paradox is that the expected value of this game is infinite, but probably
you will only pay a moderate, not infinite, amount to play this game. To resolve this paradox,
we borrow the concept of expected utility. The insight is that you do not assign the same
value per dollar to all payoffs. Specifically, the extra dollar of wealth should increase utility
by progressively smaller amounts.

8
Graphically, your utility is increasing at a decreasing rate with your wealth. In words, you
exhibit diminishing marginal utility of wealth.

Example 1.2

Suppose your utility function is U ( x ) = ln ( x ) . What is your expected utility of the coin-toss
game?

E U (=
x )  ∑ p × ln ( x )
i =0
i i

∞ i +1
1
= ∑   × ln ( 2 )
i

i =0  2 

ln ( 2 ) ∞  1 
i

= ∑  ×i
2 i =0  2 
ln ( 2 )  12 
=  
2  (1 − 12 )2 
= ln ( 2 )
= 0.69

The expected utility value is indeed finite, 0.69. And the dollar amount to yield this utility
value is $2, which is your maximum amount that you will pay for this game.

9
1.2 Expected Utility Theory

Expected utility theory is used to explain choice under uncertainty. To develop a theory of
rational decision making under uncertainty, we need some precise assumptions about an
individual’s behavior.

1.2.1 The Axioms of Preference

Axiom 1 – Comparability
A person can state a preference among all outcomes. If the person has a choice of outcome A
or B, a preference for A to B or B to A can be stated or indifference between them can be
expressed.

Axiom 2 – Transitivity
If a person prefers A to B and B to C, then A is preferred to C. This is an assumption that
people are consistent in their ranking of outcomes.

Axiom 3 – Independence
If a person were indifferent between having a Canon or a Nikon camera, then that person
would be indifferent to buying a lottery ticket for $10 that gave 1 in 500 chance of winning a
Canon camera or a lottery ticket for $10 that also gave 1 in 500 chance of winning a Nikon
camera.

Axiom 4 – Certainty Equivalent


For every gamble there is a value such that the investor is indifferent between the gamble and
the value.

The axioms of preference allow us to map the preference into measurable utility function.

1.2.2 Utility Functions and Indifference Curve

The utility function is important for us to understand the choice and tradeoff. If we choose
among various goods such as apple and orange, the indifference curve is downward sloping.

Within the same utility, if we consume fewer apples, in order to stay on the same indifference
curve, we have to consume more oranges. Both apple and orange provide positive utility, and
therefore, they can substitute for each other.

However, in investment, expected return provides positive utility, while risk provides
disutility. They cannot substitute for each other. When an investor is asked to take on more
risk, he has to be compensated by a higher expected return. That is why the indifference
curve is upward sloping.

10
Noted that: U3 > U2 > U1

1.3 Risk Aversion

The axioms convert preference into a utility function. We can make use of the utility
functions to establish a definition of risk aversion. Let’s consider a simple game with two
payoffs.
• Option A: $100,000 for certain.
• Option B: $150,000 if “Head” and $50,000 if “Tail” is tossed.

Head = $150,000
p

1–p
Tail = $50,000

The expected payoff:


E (W ) = p ×150, 000 + (1 − p ) × 50, 000
= 0.5 ×150, 000 + 0.5 × 50, 000
= 100, 000

Which options do you prefer? The choice will depend on your risk attitude. If you are:
• Risk averse, you will prefer option A.
• Risk neutral, you will be indifferent between option A & B.
• Risk loving, you will prefer option B.

11
Graphically, we can use three simple utility functions to demonstrate the idea of risk aversion.

Example 1.3

Suppose the utility function is U (W ) = ln (W ) . What is the expected utility from the risky
payoff of the simple game?
E U (=
W )  pU (W1 ) + (1 − p ) U (W2 )
= 0.5 ln ( 50, 000 ) + 0.5 ln (150, 000 )
= 11.37

Graphically, the log function is consistent with the risk aversion. The utility value of option
A is ln(100,000) = 11.51, which is greater than the expected utility. Hence, the risk averse
investor will prefer option A than B.

12
1.3.1 Measuring Risk Aversion

Having established the concept of risk aversion, we can further examine an individual’s
behavior in the face of risk. Intuitively, we may suspect the risk attitude of a person is linked
to his wealth.

Absolute Risk Aversion (ARA)


The definition:
U ′′ (W )
ARA = −
U ′ (W )

Condition Property Implication


d
ARA (W ) > 0
As wealth increases, hold
Increasing ARA
dW fewer dollars in risky assets.
d
ARA (W ) = 0
As wealth increases, hold
Constant ARA
dW equal dollars in risky assets.
d
ARA (W ) < 0
As wealth increases, hold
Decreasing ARA
dW more dollars in risky assets.

Example 1.4

Suppose the utility function of an investor is U (W ) = −e − CW , identify his type of absolute


risk aversion.
U ′ (W ) =
d
dW
( −e−CW ) = Ce−CW
U ′′ (W ) =
d
dW
( Ce − CW ) = −C 2 e − CW

U ′′ (W ) −C 2 e − CW
ARA =
− =
− =
C
U ′ (W ) Ce − CW
ARA′ (W ) = 0

An investor with constant ARA cares about absolute losses. For example, he will always pay
$100 to avoid a $1,000 fair bet, regardless of his level of wealth.

13
Relative Risk Aversion (RRA)
The definition:
U ′′ (W )
RRA = −W
U ′ (W )

Condition Property Implication


d Percentage invested in risky
Increasing RRA RRA (W ) > 0 assets declines as wealth
dW increases.
d Percentage invested in risky
Constant RRA RRA (W ) = 0 assets is unchanged as wealth
dW increases.
d Percentage invested in risky
Decreasing RRA RRA (W ) < 0 assets increases as wealth
dW increases.

Example 1.5

Suppose the utility function of an investor is U (W=


) W − bW 2 , identify his type of relative
risk aversion.
U ′ (W ) =(W − bW 2 ) =
d
1 − 2bW
dW
d
U ′′ (W ) = (1 − 2bW ) =
−2b
dW

U ′′ (W ) −2b 2bW
RRA =
−W =
−W =
U ′ (W ) 1 − 2bW 1 − 2bW
2b
RRA′ (W )
= >0
(1 − 2bW )
2

In general, most investors exhibit decreasing absolute risk aversion. There is less agreement
concerning relative risk aversion.

14
2 Topic 2 – Review of Mathematics and Statistics

2.1 Random Variables

Consider two random variables: x and y

State 1 2 … n
Probability p1 p2 … pn
Value of x x1 x2 … xn
Value of y y1 y2 … yn

n
where∑ pi = 1
i =1

2.2 Moments

Mean: the expected value of a random outcome.


n
E ( x )= x= ∑ p ×x
i =1
i i

Variance: the dispersion of the squared deviation of the realized outcome from its mean.
n
Var ( x ) = σ x2 = ∑ p ×(x − x )
2
i i
i =1

Standard deviation: the volatility of a random outcome.


Std ( x=
) σ=x Var ( x )

Example 2.1

State Bull Bear Crisis


Probability 0.5 0.3 0.2
r1 25% 10% -25%
r2 1% -5% 35%

Mean:
E ( r1=
) 0.5 × 25% + 0.3 ×10% + 0.2 × −25%= 10.5%
E ( r2=
) 0.5 ×1% + 0.3 × −5% + 0.2 × 35%= 6%

15
Variance:
σ 12 = 0.5 [ 25% − 10.5%] + 0.3[10% − 10.5% ] + 0.2 [ −25% − 10.5% ]
2 2 2

= 3.57
σ 22= 0.5 [1% − 6% ] + 0.3 [ −5% − 6% ] + 0.2 [35% − 6% ]
2 2 2

= 2.17

Standard deviation:
σ 1 = 18.9%
σ 2 = 14.7%

In real world data analysis, the mean and variance of a random variable are almost never
known, but rather be estimated from a sample.

Sample Mean:
1 N
x = ∑ xi
N i =1

Sample Variance:
1 N
s2 ( x )
= ∑ ( xi − x )
2

N − 1 i =1

Employing N – 1, instead of N, as the denominator gave an unbiased estimate of the


population variance. To prove that the sample variance estimator is unbiased, we have to
show that E ( s 2 ) = σ 2 .

Proof:
Recall that sample variance,
1 N
= ∑ ( xi − x )
2
s2
N − 1 i =1

Take expectation,
 1 N 2
=E ( s2 ) E  ∑ ( xi − x ) 
 N − 1 i =1 
1  N
2
= E  ∑ ( xi − x ) 
N − 1  i =1 

16
Expand the squared terms,
N 
( N − 1) E ( =
s2 ) E  ∑ ( xi2 − 2 xi x + x 2 ) 
 i =1 
=E  ∑ xi  − E  ∑ 2 xi x  + E  ∑ x 2 
2

=E  ∑ xi2  − E  2 x ∑ xi  + E  ∑ x 2 

Given that ∑ x= i N ⋅x ,
( N − 1) E ( s 2 ) = E  ∑ xi2  − E  2 x ∑ xi  + E  ∑ x 2 
= ∑ E  x 2
i
 − 2 N ⋅ E  x 2  + N ⋅ E  x 2 
= N ⋅ E  xi2  − N ⋅ E  x 2 
N −1
N
(
E= s 2 ) E  xi2  − E  x 2 

( y ) E ( y 2 ) −  E ( y )  ,
2
=
Apply the property that Var

 x 2  Var ( x ) +  E ( x ) 
2
E=
1 
= Var  ∑ xi  + x 2
N 
Var ( ∑ xi ) + x 2
1
=
N2
1
2 ∑
= Var ( xi ) + x 2
N
1
2 ∑
= σ 2 + x2
N
1 2
= σ + x2
N

Substitute it into previous equation,


N −1
N
E=( s 2 ) E  xi2  − E  x 2 

1 
= (σ 2 + x 2 ) −  σ 2 + x 2 
N 
N −1 2
= σ
N
E ( s2 ) = σ 2

17
2.3 Comoments

Covariance: a measure of how much the two random outcomes varies together.
N
Cov ( x , y ) = σ xy = ∑ p × ( x − x )( y − y )
i =1
i i i

Correlation: a standardized measure of covariation.


σ xy
Corr ( x , =
y ) ρ=
xy
σ xσ y
• ρ xy must lie between –1 to +1.
• If ρ xy = +1 , the two random outcomes are perfectly positively correlated.
• If ρ xy = −1 , the two random outcomes are perfectly negatively correlated.
• If ρ xy = 0 , the two random outcomes are uncorrelated.
• If one outcome is certain, then ρ xy = 0 .

Example 2.2

State Bull Bear Crisis


Probability 0.5 0.3 0.2
r1 25% 10% -25%
r2 1% -5% 35%

With mean and standard deviation,


= =
r1 10.5%, σ 1 18.9%
= =
r2 6%, σ 2 14.7%

Covariance:
σ r1r2 =0.5 ( 25% − 10.5% )(1% − 6% )
+0.3 (10% − 10.5% )( −5% − 6% )
+0.2 ( −25% − 10.5% )( 35% − 6% )
= −0.02405

Correlation:
−0.02405
ρ r1r2 =
0.189 × 0.147
= −0.8656

18
2.4 Properties of Moments and Comoments

Let a and b be two constants.


E ( ax ) = aE ( x )
E ( ax + by=
) aE ( x ) + bE ( y )
E ( xy
 ) = E ( x ) × E ( y ) + Cov ( x , y )
Var ( ax ) = a 2Var ( x )
Var ( ax +=
by ) a 2Var ( x ) + b 2Var ( y ) + 2 ( ab ) Cov ( x , y )
Cov ( x + y =
, z ) Cov ( x , z ) + Cov ( y , z )
Cov ( ax , by ) = ( ab ) Cov ( x , y )

2.5 Linear Regression

An intuitive example of least square:


yi β xi + ε i so that the population
• Consider a special case of linear regression: =
regression line E ( y | x ) = β x is a ray passing through the origin ( 0, 0 ) .
• We have two pairs of observations, ( x1 , y1 ) = (1,1) and ( x2 , y2 ) = (1, 2 ) .

How do we fit a regression line by suitably choosing β that is meant to represent the data?

2.5

2 1, 2

1.5
y = 1.75x
y = 1.5x
y

1 1, 1

0.5

0
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2
x

19
• The line 1.75x is biased towards the observation (1, 2 ) .
• The line 1.5x is representative because it passes through halfway between the two
observations.

In fact, we can apply the least square principle by choosing β to minimize the residual sum
of squares.
∑ ε i2 min ∑ ( yi − β xi )
2
=
min
β β
i i

β
{
= min (1 − β ⋅1) + ( 2 − β ⋅1)
2 2
}
∂∑ ε 2
−2 (1 − β ) − 2 ( 2 − β ) =
= 0
∂β
⇒β =
1.5

In general, the relation between two random variables y and x : y =α + β x + ε ,


n

Cov ( y , x ) ∑ ( x − x )( y − y )
i i
=βˆ = i =1

Var ( x ) n

∑(x − x )
2
i
i =1

αˆ= y − βˆ x

Note that by assumption:


• ε has zero mean: E ( ε ) = 0 .
• ε is uncorrelated with x: Cov ( x , ε ) = 0 .

2.6 Calculus and Optimization

Calculus and Optimization are basic concepts to finance theory. In this brief review, we shall
summarize the main concepts including: (A) functions, (B) limits, (C) differentiations and (D)
optimizations.

2.6.1 Functions

A fundamental notion used in finance is the concept of a function. There are three ways to
express functions: as (1) mathematical equations, (2) graphs, and (3) tables.

20
Example 2.3

Suppose a variable Y is related to a variable X by the following mathematical equation:


Y = 2 X 2 − 3X + 6

A shorthand way of expressing this relationship is to write Y = f ( X ) , which is read “Y is a


function of the variable X”.

We can also express the function in a tabular and graphical manner. Thus the equation
enables us to construct a range of Y values for a given table of X values. The data in the table
can then be plotted in a graph.

X Y
-2 20
-1 11
0 6
1 5
2 8
3 15
4 26

Example 2.4

From basic capital budgeting concepts, we know that the net present value (NPV) of an
investment project is equal to:
N
CFt
=NPV ∑ − I0
t =1 (1 + r )
t

where :
CFt = cash flow in time period t
I 0 = the project's initial cash outlay
r = the firm's cost of capital
N = the number of years in the project

21
We can express this relationship functionally as:
NPV = f ( CFt , I 0 , r , N )

Given values for the right-hand-side independent variables, we can determine the left-hand-
side dependent variable, NPV. The functional relationship tells us that for every X that is in
the domain of the function a unique of Y can be determined.

2.6.2 Limits

In finance, it is so important to study the effect on changes of the independent variables on


the dependent variable. For example, what happens with the asset return if the market risk
premium increases?

Assume there is a simple function:


Y = f (X )

If X changes from X0 to X1 , then we can say:


∆X = X 1 − X 0

Accordingly, Y will change:


∆Y f ( X 1 ) − f ( X 0 )
=
= f ( X 0 + ∆X ) − f ( X 0 )

The difference quotient measures the change in Y per unit change in X. It is defined as:
∆Y f ( X 0 + ∆X ) − f ( X 0 )
=
∆X ∆X

Example 2.5

Y f (=
Given= X ) 3 X 2 − 4 , the difference quotient is:
∆Y f ( X 0 + ∆X ) − f ( X 0 )
=
∆X ∆X
3 ( X 0 + ∆X )2 − 4  − ( 3 X 02 − 4 )
= 
∆X
6 X 0 ∆X + 3 ( ∆X )
2

=
∆X
= 6 X 0 + 3∆X

22
Let X=
0 3 and ∆=
X 4 , then the average rate of change of Y will be 6(3) + 3(4) = 30. This
means that, on the average, as X changes from 3 to 7, the change in Y is 30 units per unit
change in X.

If we assume an infinitesimally small change in X, what would then happen to the change in
Y?
∆Y f ( X 0 + ∆X ) − f ( X 0 )
lim = lim
∆X → 0 ∆X ∆X → 0 ∆X

This limit is identified as the derivative of the function Y = f ( X ) .

In the above example:


∆Y
= lim ( 6 X 0 +=
lim 3∆X ) 6 X 0
∆X → 0 ∆X ∆X → 0

As ∆X approaches zero (meaning that it gets closer and closer to, but never actually reaches
zero), ( 6 X 0 + 3∆X ) will approach the value 6X 0 .

We may define the derivative of a given function Y = f ( X ) as follows:


dY ∆Y
≡ f ' ( X ) ≡ lim
dX ∆X → 0 ∆X

2.6.3 Differentiations

Rules of Differentiation
1. = f ( X ) c,= f' ( X ) 0 , where c is a constant
f ( X ) X=
2.= n
, f' ( X ) nX n −1
3. f ( X ) = g ( X ) ⋅ h ( X ) , f' ( X ) = g' ( X ) ⋅ h ( X ) + h' ( X ) ⋅ g ( X )
g(X ) g' ( X ) h ( X ) − h' ( X ) g ( X )
=
4. f (X ) = , f' ( X )
h( X )  h ( X ) 
2

5. f (X ) =
c ⋅ g ( X ) , f' ( X ) =c ⋅ g' ( X ) , where c is a constant
6. f (X ) =
g ( X ) + h ( X ) , f' ( X ) =
g' ( X ) + h' ( X )

23
Chain Rule
Suppose Y is a function of a variable Z:
Y = f (Z )

But Z is in turn a function of another variable X:


Z = g(X )

Because Y depends on Z, and in turn depends on X, Y is also a function of X! We can


express this fact by writing Y as a composite function (i.e., a function of a function) of X:
Y = f  g ( X ) 

To determine the change in Y from a change in X, the chain rule says:


dY dY dZ
= ⋅ = f ' ( Z ) ⋅ g' ( X )
dX dZ dX

Example 2.6

Suppose we want to differentiate:


Y= (3 + 6 X )
2 10

= 10 ( 3 + 6 X 2 ) (12 X )
dY 9

dX
= 120 X ( 3 + 6 X 2 )
9

Higher-order Derivatives
The most important of the higher-order derivatives is the second derivative. Understanding
the meaning of the second derivative is crucial. We know that the first derivative of a
function, f’(X), is the slope of a function or the rate of change of Y as a result of a change in X.
The second derivative, f”(X), is the rate of change of the slope of f(X); that is, it is the rate of
change of the rate of change of the original function.

f’(X) f”(X) f(X)


(a) >0 >0 Increasing at an increasing rate
(b) >0 <0 Increasing at a decreasing rate
(c) <0 <0 Decreasing at an increasing rate
(d) <0 >0 Decreasing at a decreasing rate

24
Partial Differentiation
So far we have only considered differentiation of functions of one independent variable. In
practice, functions of two or more independent variables do arise quite frequently.

Since each independent variable influences the function differently, when we consider the
instantaneous rate of change of the function, we have to isolate the effect of each of the
independent variables.

Let W = f ( X ,Y ,Z ) . When we consider how W changes as X changes, we want to hold the


variables Y and Z constant. This gives rise to the concept of partial differentiation. Note that
the rules for partial differentiation and ordinary differentiation are exactly the same except
that when we are taking partial derivative of one independent variable, we regard all other
independent variables as constants.

Example 2.7

W = X 2YZ 3

∂W
= 2 XYZ 3
∂X
∂W
= X 2Z 3
∂Y
∂W
= 3 X 2YZ 2
∂Z

2.6.4 Optimizations

In portfolio theory, investment manager wants to minimize the portfolio risk for a given level
of return. An individual investor seeks to maximize utility when choosing among investment
alternatives. Indeed, we are all engaged in optimization problems every day.

If we have a mathematical objective function, then we can solve our optimization problem
using calculus.

25
Theorem
If f(X) has a relative maximum or minimum at X = a, then f’(a) = 0.

To locate all relative maxima and minima, we differentiate f(X), set the result to zero, and
solve for X. That is, find all the solutions to the equation:
f '(X ) = 0

The above equation is called the first-order condition. To determine which of these solutions
are indeed relative maxima or minima, we need the second-order condition.

=
For maxima, f ' ( X ) 0 and f ′′ ( X ) < 0 .
=
For minima, f ' ( X ) 0 and f ′′ ( X ) > 0 .

Constrained Optimization
Let us consider a consumer who wants to maximize his simple utility function:
U ( x1 ,x=
2) x1 x2 + 2 x1

Without any constraint, the consumer should purchase an infinite amount of both goods.
However, the consumer must also consider his budget constraint into this optimization
problem.

If the consumer intends to spend a given sum, say, $60, on the two goods. If the current
prices are P1 = $4 and P2 = $2, the budget constraint can be expressed by the linear equation:
4 x1 + 2 x2 =
60

Formally, we can express the above optimization problem as:


max U ( x1 , x=
2) x1 x2 + 2 x1
x1 , x2

st : 4 x1 + 2 x2 =
60

An easy way to solve this optimization problem is to remove the constraint by rewriting:
60 − 4 x1
x=
2 = 30 − 2 x1
2

Combining the constraint with the objective function, the result is an objective function in
one variable only:
max U ( x1 ) = x1 ( 30 − 2 x1 ) + 2 x1
x1

26
First-order condition:
U ' ( x1 ) = 0
⇒ −2 x1 + ( 30 − 2 x1 ) + 2 =0
⇒ 32 − 4 x1 =
0
⇒ x1 =
8

The solution is x1 = 8 and x2 =30 − 2 ( 8 ) =


14 .

Lagrange-Multiplier Method
Alternatively, we can set up a Lagrangian function:
L = x1 x2 + 2 x1 + λ ( 60 − 4 x1 − 2 x2 )

The first-order conditions:


∂L
= x2 + 2 − 4λ = 0
∂x1
∂L
=x1 − 2λ =0
∂x2
∂L
=60 − 4 x1 − 2 x2 =0
∂λ

Solving the three system of equations,


x=
2 4λ − 2
x1 = 2λ
4 x1 + 2 x2 =
60

The solution is also x1 = 8 and x2 = 14 .

27
3 Topic 3 – Risk and Return

3.1 The Definition of Return

Holding period return (HPR) is capital gain income plus dividend income.
P − P + Divt
HPRt = t t −1
Pt −1
where:
Pt = stock price at time t
=Pt −1 stock price at time t − 1
Divt dividend during the [t − 1, t ] period

HPRt is a random variable from the point of view at time t – 1. t can be one day, one week,
one month, one year or any time span.

Example 3.1

Suppose you are considering investing some of your money in a stock market index. The
price per share is currently $100, and your time horizon is one year. You expect the dividend
yield is 4% and the price one year from now is $110.

110 − 100 + 4
=HPR = 14%
100
= capital gain yield + dividend yield
=10% + 4% = 14%

HPR is a simple measure of investment return over a single period. For return over multiple
periods, the cumulative return:
1 + RT =(1 + r1 )(1 + r2 ) (1 + rT )

Alternatively, since the log of a product is the sum of the logs, then:
ln (1 + RT )= ln (1 + r1 ) + ln (1 + r2 ) +  + (1 + rT )
T
= ∑ ln (1 + r )
t =1
t

28
3.2 The Definition of Risk

Risk means uncertainty about future rates of return. We can quantify the uncertainty using
probability distributions.

Example 3.2

Consider three assets:


Mean % Std %
r0 10 0
r1 10 10
r2 10 20

Investors care about expected return and risk.

29
Assumptions on investor preferences:
1. Higher mean in return is preferred.
2. Lower standard deviation in return is preferred.
3. Investor only cares about the first and second moment.

3.3 The History of U.S. Return

Some stylized facts about the history of U.S assets returns:


1. Real interest rate has been slightly positive on average.

2. Return on more risky assets has been higher than less risky assets on average.

30
3. Equities were the best performing asset class and bonds proved a disappointing
investment in the 20th century.

3.4 International Evidence

1. Equities outperformed bonds in all countries.

31
2. High and unexpected inflation dampened bond markets return.

3. Interestingly, the four countries – Germany, France, Japan and Italy – which suffered
from high inflation during the first half of 20th century, were amongst the best-
performing bond markets in the recent 50 years.

32
3.5 Real and Nominal Rates of Interest

Q0 = 100 Q1 = 120

P0 = $10 P1 = $11

• At t = 0, you loan 100 apples to your friend, and he promises to return 120 apples to you
after one year.
• The price of an apple at t = 0 is $10 each.
• Due to inflation, the price of an apple at t = 1 is $11 each.

After a year, what is your real return (in terms of goods)?


Q1 − Q0 Q1
=
r = −1
Q0 Q0
120
= −=
1 20%
100

Alternatively, you can offer him an equivalent loan. At t = 0, you lend him $1,000 so he can
convert the loan into 100 apples. Then, at t = 1, he repays you the market price of 120 apples.

Your nominal return (in terms of money) will be:


Q1 P1 − Q0 P0 Q1 P1
=R = −1
Q0 P0 Q0 P0
120 × $11
= = − 1 32%
100 × $10

The nominal return takes into account changes in quantities as well as changes in price.

Inflation is the rate of change in prices:


P1 − P0 P1
=
i = −1
P0 P0
$11
= −=
1 10%
$10

33
In general, we let:
• R = Nominal rate (in terms of money)
• r = Real rate (in terms of real goods)
• i = Inflation rate

We can show explicitly the interrelationships between the nominal interest rate, real interest
rate, and inflation rate.
Q1 P1
=R −1
Q0 P0
Q1 P1
= × −1
Q0 P0
= (1 + r ) × (1 + i ) − 1

By expanding the equation, we obtain the Fisher effect:


(1 + R ) = (1 + r ) × (1 + i )
= 1 + r + i + ri
R = r + i + ri
≈ r +i

The Fisher effect tells us that the real rate of interest is approximately equal to the nominal
rate minus the inflation rate.

Empirically, inflation and interest rates move closely together.

34
4 Topic 4 – Portfolio Theory

Consider three stocks: HSBC, CLP and PCCW


HSBC CLP PCCW
r 19.5% 22.2% 15.5%
σ 26.5% 32.5% 34.3%

25.00%

20.00%

15.00%
r

10.00%

5.00%

0.00%
0.00% 10.00% 20.00% 30.00% 40.00%
sd

HSBC CLP PCCW

Which stock will you prefer to invest?


• CLP has the highest expected return.
• HSBC has lower expected return than CLP but it is less risky.
• PCCW has the lowest expected return but highest risk.

In reality, why investors still hold PCCW?


• Instead of holding single asset, investors hold diversified portfolios.
• Investors care about portfolio risks.

35
4.1 Portfolio Risk and Return

4.1.1 Portfolio of Two Assets

Given two stocks: Stock 1 and Stock 2, we can characterize their behavior by their mean,
variance and covariance.

Mean return:
Stock 1 2
Mean return r1 r2

Variance and covariance matrix:


r1 r2
r1 σ 12 σ 12
r2 σ 21 σ 22

Two notes:
• Covariance of an asset with itself is its variance, i.e., σ 11 = σ 12 and σ 22 = σ 22 .
• The covariance matrix is symmetric, i.e., σ 12 = σ 21 .

Now let V1 and V2 be the amount that you invest in Stock 1 and 2 respectively. The total value
of your portfolio is:
V= V1 + V2

The weight on each Stock:


V
• w1 = 1 is the weight on Stock 1.
V
V
• w2 = 2 is the weight on Stock 2.
V
• w1 + w2 = 1

36
Example 4.1

You invest $113,400 in HSBC and $96,600 in Cheung Kong, then:


=
• wHSBC 113,= 400 / 210, 000 54%
= =
• wCK 96, 600 / 210, 000 46% .

Now, you sell $138,600 Cheung Kong (by borrowing $42,000 worth of Cheung Kong from
your friend and short sell them), then:
=
• wHSBC 252, = 000 / 210, 000 120%
• wCK =
−42, 000 / 210, 000 =
−20%

Expected return of a portfolio with two assets:


E ( rp =
) r=p w1r1 + w2 r2
Variance of return of a portfolio with two assets:
Var ( r=
p) E ( rp − rp )
2
σ=
2
p

= w12σ 12 + w22σ 22 + 2 w1w2σ 12


= w12σ 12 + w22σ 22 + 2 w1w2σ 1σ 2 ρ12

Recall that σ 12 = σ 1σ 2 ρ12 .

An easy way to remember the portfolio variance is to sum up all entries in the variance-
covariance matrix.
w1r1 w2 r2
w1r1 w12σ 12 w1w2σ 12
w2 r2 w1w2σ 21 w22σ 22

37
Example 4.2

Consider the monthly returns on HSBC and CLP:


Month HSBC CLP
1 0.1205 0.1409
2 0.1527 0.0296
3 -0.0412 0.0719
4 0.0157 0.2439
5 0.0316 0.0006
6 -0.0279 0.0652
7 -0.0897 -0.0875
8 -0.0118 0.0282
9 0.0107 -0.1397
10 0.1275 -0.0806
11 0.0748 -0.0070
12 -0.0094 0.0880
Investment $150,000 $150,000

From the monthly return table, we can summarize the characteristics of the two stocks.
HSBC CLP
r 0.0295 0.0295
σ 0.0747 0.1051
weight 0.5 0.5
ρ HSBC ,CLP 0.05

The portfolio return:


=rp wHSBC rHSBC + wCLP rCLP
= 0.5 ⋅ 0.0295 + 0.5 ⋅ 0.0295
= 2.95%

The portfolio variance:


σ p2= wHSBC
2
σ HSBC
2
+ wCLP
2
σ CLP
2
+ 2 wHSBC wCLPσ HSBCσ CLP ρ HSBC ,CLP
= ( 0.5 )( 0.0747 ) + ( 0.5 )( 0.1051 )
2 2 2 2

+2 ( 0.5 )( 0.5 )( 0.0747 )( 0.1051)( 0.05 )


= 0.0044
σ p = 6.61%

38
4.1.2 Portfolio of Multiple Assets

We can extend our analysis into n stocks.

Mean return:
Stock 1 2 … n
Mean return r1 r2 … rn

Variance and covariance matrix:


 σ 12 σ 12  σ 1n 
 
 σ 21 σ 2  σ 2n 
2

     
 
 σ n1 σ n 2  σ n2 

Let wi be the weight of the asset i invested in the portfolio, then ∑ w =1.
i
i

The portfolio returns for n stocks:


n
rp = w1r1 + w2 r2 +  + wn rn = ∑wr
i =1
i i

The variance of the portfolio is the sum of all entries in the variance and covariance matrix.
 w12σ 12 w1w2σ 12  w1wnσ 1n 
 
 w2 w1σ 21 w22σ 22  w2 wnσ 2 n 
     
 
 wn w1σ n1 wn w2σ n 2  wn2σ n2 

Var ( r=
p)
n n
σ=
2
p ∑∑ w w σ
=i 1 =j 1
i j ij

In order to compute the variance of a portfolio, with n stocks, we need to estimate:


• Portfolio weights.
• Variance of the individual assets.
• All covariance among assets.

39
4.2 Diversification

Let us select 33 HSI constituents from January 1977 to August 1996. We then perform the
mean-variance analysis and form portfolios with different number of stocks.

No of Stocks r σ
1 33.8 44.2
2 34.3 43.5
3 31.9 42.2
4 31.8 37.3
5 29.1 33.9
10 30.7 35.2
15 29.8 34.8
20 27.9 33.0
25 27.7 33.1
33 28.2 30.7
HSI 21.2 30.3

36%

34% 1

32%

30%
33 5
28%
r

26%

24%

22%
HSI
20%
20% 25% 30% 35% 40% 45% 50%
sd

40
The portfolio risk drops when we add more stocks into the portfolio. Diversification reduces
risk!

50%

45%

40%
sd

35%

30%

25%

20%
1 2 3 4 5 10 15 20 25 33
No of Stocks

However, the extent of diversification is up to a limit. Certain risks cannot be diversified


away. This is because the individual risk of securities can be diversified away, but the
contribution to the total risk caused by the covariance cannot be diversified away.

41
For a well-diversified portfolio:
• Variance of each stock contributes little to portfolio risk.
• Covariance among stocks determines portfolio risk.

To understand this expression, remember the variance of portfolio is the sum of all entries in
the variance and covariance matrix.
 w12σ 12 w1w2σ 12  w1wnσ 1n 
 
 w2 w1σ 21 wσ  w2 wnσ 2 n 
2 2
2 2
     
 
 wn w1σ n1 wn w2σ n 2  wn2σ n2 

n n
σ p2 = ∑∑ wi w jσ ij
=i 1 =j 1
n n n
= ∑ wi2σ i2 + ∑∑ wi w jσ ij
=i 1 =i 1 =j 1
i≠ j

Now, we assume equal amounts are invested in each stock. With n stocks, then the
proportion invested in each stock is 1/n. We can rewrite the portfolio variance as:
n n n
=σ p2 ∑ wi2σ i2 + ∑∑ wi w jσ ij
=i 1 =i 1 =j 1
i≠ j
2
1 n n n
 1  1 
= ∑   σ i2 + ∑∑     σ ij
=i 1  n  =i 1 =j 1  n   n 
i≠ j

 
 1  1 n 2   n − n  1
2 n n
=    ∑σ i  +  2  2 ∑∑ σ ij 
   =i 1  
n n n 
 n − n=i 1 =j 1

 i≠ j 
1 n −n
2
=   σ i2 +  2  σ ij
n  n 
1  n2 − n 
=   ( average variance ) +  2  ( average covariance )
n  n 

From this expression, as n becomes very large:


• Contribution of variance term goes to zero.
• Contribution of covariance term goes to average covariance.

42
4.3 Optimal Portfolio Selection

Now, the question is how do we choose a portfolio? Should we:


• Minimize risk for a given expected return?
• Maximize expected return for a given risk?

Formally, our objective is to maximize utility:


max : U (W ) = U ( r , σ 2 )

And subject to investment constraint.

We want to construct a portfolio that is feasible. In the meantime, the portfolio can maximize
our utility.

Consider three cases:


1. Only one risky asset + risk free asset
(e.g. Invest in one of 43 blue chips + borrow or lend at HIBOR.)

2. Two risky assets + risk free asset


(e.g. Invest in two of the 43 blue chips + borrow or lend at HIBOR.)

3. More than two risky assets + risk free asset


(e.g. Invest in 43 blue chips + borrow or lend at HIBOR. In reality, we can invest in more
than 43 stocks!)

43
4.3.1 Case 1: One Risky Asset + Risk Free Asset

• HSBC + HIBOR
= =
• rHSBC 0.195, σ HSBC 0.265
•= = 0.066
rf rHIBOR
• y = portfolio weight in HSBC

Form a complete portfolio of HSBC and HIBOR:


rc = y × 0.195 + (1 − y ) × 0.066
σ c = 0.265 y

y 1-y rc σc
0.0 1.0 6.6% 0.0%
0.1 0.9 7.9% 2.7%
0.2 0.8 9.2% 5.3%
0.3 0.7 10.5% 8.0%
0.4 0.6 11.8% 10.6%
0.5 0.5 13.1% 13.3%
0.6 0.4 14.3% 15.9%
0.7 0.3 15.6% 18.6%
0.8 0.2 16.9% 21.2%
0.9 0.1 18.2% 23.9%
1.0 0.0 19.5% 26.5%
1.1 -0.1 20.8% 29.2%
1.2 -0.2 22.1% 31.8%
1.3 -0.3 23.4% 34.5%
1.4 -0.4 24.7% 37.1%
1.5 -0.5 26.0% 39.8%

44
Capital allocation line (CAL) is the plot of risk-return combinations available by varying
portfolio allocation between a risk-free asset and a risky portfolio.

CAL - HSBC & HIBOR

30.0%

25.0%

20.0%

15.0%
r

10.0%

5.0%

0.0%
0.0% 10.0% 20.0% 30.0% 40.0% 50.0%
sd

The interpretation of this plot is straight forward. The larger the proportion y we put in
HSBC, the higher the expected return of our portfolio. The standard deviation of our
portfolio is proportional to HSBC’s standard deviation. In other words, each y gives us a pair
of  E ( rc ) , σ c  that is feasible. The collection of these feasible pairs is the CAL.

45
CAL - HSBC & HIBOR

30.0%

25.0% borrow

20.0%
lend
15.0%
r

risk

10.0% premium

5.0%

0.0%
0.0% 10.0% 20.0% 30.0% 40.0% 50.0%
sd

To derive the exact equation for the CAL, we generalize the previous equation and take
expectation:
E ( rc ) = y × E ( rHSBC ) + (1 − y ) × rf
rf + y  E ( rHSBC ) − rf 
=
σ
rf + c  E ( rHSBC ) − rf 
=
σ HSBC

The generalized equation describes the expected return and standard deviation tradeoff.

The slope of the CAL, denoted S, equals the increase in the expected return of the portfolio
per unit of additional standard deviation – incremental return per incremental risk. Therefore,
the slope is called the reward-to-variability ratio.
E ( rHSBC ) − rf
S=
σ HSBC

In our example, the reward-to-variability ratio of holding HSBC is:


E ( rHSBC ) − rf
S=
σ HSBC
0.195 − 0.066
=
0.265
= 0.4868

46
The CAL describes all feasible risk-return combinations available from different asset
allocation choices. The question is: how the investor chooses one optimal portfolio?

The investor makes investment decision based on:


• Utility function (preference)
• CAL (investment opportunity)

In our example, the investor chooses y to maximize his utility:


1
max = U E ( rc ) − Aσ c2
y 2
where :
E ( rc ) =
rf + y  E ( rHSBC ) − rf 
σ c2 = y 2σ HSBC
2

Substitute  E ( rc ) , σ c2  into the utility function:


1
max U =rf + y  E ( rHSBC ) − rf  − Ay 2σ HSBC 2
y 2

First order condition with respect to y:


∂U
= E ( rHSBC ) − rf − Ayσ= 2
0
∂y
HSBC

Therefore, the optimal y is:


E ( rHSBC ) − rf
y* =
Aσ HSBC
2

Note that y* increases when:


• risk premium increases,  E ( rHSBC ) − rf  ↑
• less risk averse, A ↓
• variance of the stock decreases, σ HSBC2

47
Example 4.3

Suppose the investor has a risk aversion parameter, A = 4, and recall that
= =
rHSBC 0.195, σ HSBC 0.265 and
= = 0.066 . What is the proportion of money that
rf rHIBOR
he puts in HSBC?
E ( rHSBC ) − rf 0.195 − 0.066
= y* = = 0.46
Aσ HSBC
2
4 × 0.2652

So 46% of money will be invested in HSBC and 54% will be deposited in the money market.
The expected return and standard deviation of the optimal portfolio are:
rc = 0.46 × 0.195 + 0.54 × 0.066
= 0.125

σ c 0.265 × 0.46
=
= 0.122

Graphically,

CAL - HSBC & HIBOR

30.0%

25.0%

20.0%

15.0%
r

10.0%
[12.5, 12.2]
5.0%
y = 0.46

0.0%
0.0% 10.0% 20.0% 30.0% 40.0% 50.0%
sd

The CAL provided by 1-month T-bills and a board of index of common stocks is called the
CML. In Hong Kong, the CML is a straight line that goes through the HIBOR and the Hang
Seng Index.

48
Example 4.4

The risk aversion parameter A is difficult to measure. But we can have a rough estimate. For
example, in 1987, the total market value of the S&P500 stocks was about 4 times as large as
the market value of all outstanding T-bills of less than 6-month maturity. Therefore,
4
y≈ = 0.8
1+ 4
Suppose:
E ( rm ) − rf =
0.085
σ m = 0.214

Substitute this into y*:


E ( rm ) − rf
y* =
Aσ m2
0.085
0.8 =
A × 0.2142

Solving for A:
A = 2.32

In reality, individual investors cannot borrow at the risk free rate, simply because we do not
have the credit as the government. Therefore individual investors have to borrow at a higher
interest rate than the risk free rate.

Suppose we can borrow at rB = 0.09 , then the CAL becomes kinked.

49
For the borrowing part of the CAL, the slope now becomes:
E ( rHSBC ) − rB
S=
σ HSBC
0.195 − 0.09
=
0.265
= 0.3962

4.3.2 Case 2: Two Risky Assets + Risk Free Asset

Consider two risky assets:


HSBC Cathy
r 0.195 0.127
σ 0.265 0.304
ρ HSBC ,Cathy 0.68

We can form a portfolio with HSBC and Cathy Pacific:


w(HSBC) w(Cathy) rp σp
0.0 1.0 12.7% 30.4%
0.1 0.9 13.4% 29.2%
0.2 0.8 14.1% 28.2%
0.3 0.7 14.7% 27.3%
0.4 0.6 15.4% 26.6%
0.5 0.5 16.1% 26.1%
0.6 0.4 16.8% 25.8%
0.7 0.3 17.5% 25.6%
0.8 0.2 18.1% 25.7%
0.9 0.1 18.8% 26.0%
1.0 0.0 19.5% 26.5%

50
Investment Opportunity from HSBC & Cathy Pacific

20.0%
19.0%
18.0%
17.0%
16.0%
15.0%
r

14.0%
13.0%
12.0%
11.0%
10.0%
20.0% 22.0% 24.0% 26.0% 28.0% 30.0% 32.0%
sd

When forming a portfolio with two risky assets, each pair of portfolio weights [w1 w2] will
give a corresponding pair of portfolio mean and standard deviation  E ( rp ) , σ p  . The
collection of these feasible portfolio mean and standard deviation is the investment
opportunity set of the two risky assets.

Recall that the portfolio standard deviation is:


1
σ p =  w12σ 12 + w22σ 22 + 2w1w2σ 1σ 2 ρ12  2

Since the investor has to fully invest, the fraction that an investor invests in asset 1 plus the
fraction in asset 2 must equal one.
w1 + w2 = 1
⇒ w2 =−
1 w1

51
Some special cases:
1. Perfect Positive Correlation ( ρ = +1)
1

σ
=  w12σ 12 + (1 − w1 )2 σ 22 + 2 w1 (1 − w1 ) σ 1σ 2  2
p  
= w1σ 1 + (1 − w1 ) σ 2

While the expected return on the portfolio is:


rp = w1r1 + (1 − w1 ) r2

Thus, with the correlation coefficient equal to +1, both risk and return of the portfolio are
simply linear combinations of the risk and return of each stock.
rp = w1r1 + (1 − w1 ) r2
 σ −σ2   σ p −σ2 
=  p  r1 + 1 −  r2
 σ1 − σ 2   σ1 − σ 2 

Investment Opportunity from HSBC & Cathy Pacific

20.0%
19.0%
18.0%
17.0%
16.0%
15.0%
r

14.0%
13.0%
12.0%
11.0%
10.0%
20.0% 22.0% 24.0% 26.0% 28.0% 30.0% 32.0%
sd

In the case of perfectly correlated assets, the return and risk on the portfolio of the two assets
is a weighted average of the return and risk on the individual assets.

There is no reduction in risk from purchasing both assets. Nothing has been gained by
diversifying rather than purchasing the individual assets.

52
2. Perfect Negative Correlation ( ρ = −1)
1

σ
=  w12σ 12 + (1 − w1 )2 σ 22 − 2 w1 (1 − w1 ) σ 1σ 2  2
p  
= w1σ 1 − (1 − w1 ) σ 2

If two assets are perfectly negatively correlated, it should always be possible to find some
combination of these two assets that has zero risk. By setting the above equation equal to
zero:
0= w1σ 1 − (1 − w1 ) σ 2
σ2
w1 =
σ1 + σ 2

Employing the formula developed, if we set w1 equal to 0.304 / (0.265 + 0.304) = 0.5343, we
can form a zero-risk portfolio:
w(HSBC) w(Cathy) rp σp
0 1 12.7% 30.4%
0.1 0.9 13.4% 24.7%
0.2 0.8 14.1% 19.0%
0.3 0.7 14.7% 13.3%
0.4 0.6 15.4% 7.6%
0.5 0.5 16.1% 2.0%
0.5343 0.4657 16.3% 0.0%
0.6 0.4 16.8% 3.7%
0.7 0.3 17.5% 9.4%
0.8 0.2 18.1% 15.1%
0.9 0.1 18.8% 20.8%
1 0 19.5% 26.5%

Investment Opportunity from HSBC & Cathy Pacific

20.0%
19.0%
18.0%
17.0%
16.0%
15.0%
r

14.0%
13.0%
12.0%
11.0%
10.0%
0.0% 10.0% 20.0% 30.0% 40.0%
sd

53
3. Zero Correlation ( ρ = 0 )
1

σ
=  w12σ 12 + (1 − w1 )2 σ 22  2
p  

The covariance term drops out when there is no relationship between returns on the assets.

Investment Opportunity from HSBC & Cathy Pacific

20.0%
19.0%
18.0%
17.0%
16.0%
15.0%
r

14.0%
13.0%
12.0%
11.0%
10.0%
0.0% 10.0% 20.0% 30.0% 40.0%

sd

54
4. Various Correlation Coefficients

Portfolio standard deviation for a given correlation:


σp
w(HSBC) w(Cathy) rp ρ = -1 ρ = -0.7 ρ = -0.3 ρ=0 ρ = 0.3 ρ = 0.7 ρ=1
0 1 12.7% 30.4% 30.4% 30.4% 30.4% 30.4% 30.4% 30.4%
0.1 0.9 13.4% 24.7% 25.6% 26.7% 27.5% 28.3% 29.3% 30.0%
0.2 0.8 14.1% 19.0% 21.0% 23.3% 24.9% 26.4% 28.3% 29.6%
0.3 0.7 14.7% 13.3% 16.7% 20.4% 22.7% 24.9% 27.4% 29.2%
0.4 0.6 15.4% 7.6% 13.2% 18.1% 21.1% 23.7% 26.8% 28.8%
0.5 0.5 16.1% 2.0% 11.2% 16.9% 20.2% 23.0% 26.2% 28.5%
0.5343 0.4657 16.3% 0.0% 11.0% 16.8% 20.0% 22.8% 26.1% 28.3%
0.6 0.4 16.8% 3.7% 11.4% 16.9% 20.0% 22.7% 25.9% 28.1%
0.7 0.3 17.5% 9.4% 13.8% 18.0% 20.7% 23.0% 25.8% 27.7%
0.8 0.2 18.1% 15.1% 17.5% 20.2% 22.1% 23.7% 25.8% 27.3%
0.9 0.1 18.8% 20.8% 21.8% 23.1% 24.0% 24.9% 26.1% 26.9%
1 0 19.5% 26.5% 26.5% 26.5% 26.5% 26.5% 26.5% 26.5%

p = -1 p = -0.7 p = -0.3 p=0 p = 0.3 p = 0.7 p=1

20.0%
19.0%
18.0%
17.0%
16.0%
15.0%
r

14.0%
13.0%
12.0%
11.0%
10.0%
0.0% 5.0% 10.0% 15.0% 20.0% 25.0% 30.0% 35.0%
sd

55
There is one point that is worth special attention: the portfolio that has minimum risk. This
portfolio can be found in general by looking at the equation for risk:
1

σ
=  w12σ 12 + (1 − w1 )2 σ 22 + 2 w1 (1 − w1 ) σ 1σ 2 ρ12  2
p  

To find the value of w1 that minimizes the equation, we take the derivative of it with respect
with w1, set the derivative equal to zero, and solve for w1:
∂σ p 1   2 w1σ 1 − 2σ 2 + 2 w1σ 2 + 2σ 1σ 2 ρ12 − 4 w1σ 1σ 2 ρ12 
2 2 2

= 
∂w1  2  1
 w12σ 12 + (1 − w1 )2 σ 22 + 2 w1 (1 − w1 ) σ 1σ 2 ρ12  2
 

Setting this equal to zero and solving for w1 yields:


σ 22 − σ 1σ 2 ρ12
w1 =
σ 12 + σ 22 − 2σ 1σ 2 ρ12

A summary:
1. In general (when ρ ≠ 1 ), the investment opportunity set is a curve that goes through the
two stocks. The portfolio standard deviation is smaller than the standard deviation of
either stock. That is, forming portfolio can always enjoy the benefit of diversification.

2. When two stocks are perfectly positively correlated ( ρ = 1 ), the investment opportunity
set becomes a straight line. There is no benefit of diversification.

3. When two stocks are perfectly negatively correlated ( ρ = −1 ), it is always possible to


reduce the portfolio standard deviation to zero.

4. The closer the correlation is to negative one, the standard deviation for a given expected
return will be lower. That is, the more you can reduce the standard deviation of your
portfolio.

56
Now, we add the risk free asset (two risky assets + risk free asset). Then, how an investor
chooses his portfolio?

In the case of one risky asset plus risk free asset, it is assumed that the investor has decided
the composition of the risky portfolio. His only concern is how to allocate his money
between the risky asset and the risk free asset.

Now, since the investor has two risky assets, he has to decide:
• The weights between the two risky assets within the risky portfolio.
• The weights between the risky portfolio and the risk free asset.

Suppose the investor has constructed the investment opportunity set from two risky assets:
E(r)
CAL(P)

CAL(B)

E(rp) P
CAL(A)

A
rf

σp σ

Two possible CALs are drawn from the risk free asset to two feasible portfolios. Portfolio B
is better than portfolio A because the reward-to-variability ratio is higher for portfolio B:
E ( rB ) − rf E ( rA ) − rf
>
σB σA

57
For any level of risk (standard deviation) that the investor is willing to bear, the expected
return from portfolio B is higher.

But one can keep moving the CAL upward until it reaches the tangency point P. This
portfolio yields the highest reward-to-variability ratio. Therefore, portfolio P is the optimal
risky portfolio combining with the risk free asset.

Formally, the investor has to solve the following problem:


E ( rp ) − rf
max
w1 , w2 σp

Subject to:
E ( rp ) w1 E ( r1 ) + w2 E ( r2 )
=
1
σ p =  w12σ 12 + w22σ 22 + 2w1w2σ 1σ 2 ρ12  2
w1 + w2 =
1

We can substitute the constraints into the objective function:


w1 E ( r1 ) + (1 − w1 ) E ( r2 ) − rf
max 1
w1
 w12σ 12 + (1 − w1 )2 σ 22 + 2 w1 (1 − w1 ) σ 1σ 2 ρ12  2
 

The solution is:


 E ( r1 ) − rf  σ 22 −  E ( r2 ) − rf  σ 1σ 2 ρ12
w =
*

 E ( r1 ) − rf  σ 22 +  E ( r2 ) − rf  σ 12 −  E ( r1 ) − rf + E ( r2 ) − rf  σ 1σ 2 ρ12
1

58
Consider our example:
HSBC Cathy
r 0.195 0.127
σ 0.265 0.304
ρ HSBC ,Cathy 0.68
rf 0.066
A 4

How to select the optimal portfolio?


First, select the optimal risky portfolio of HSBC and Cathy Pacific:
*
wHSBC
 E ( rHSBC ) − rf  σ Cathy
2
−  E ( rCathy ) − rf  σ HSBCσ Cathy ρ HSBC ,Cathy
=
 E ( rHSBC ) − rf  σ Cathy
2
+  E ( rCathy ) − rf  σ HSBC
2
−  E ( rHSBC ) − rf + E ( rCathy ) − rf  σ HSBCσ Cathy ρ HSBC ,Cathy

( 0.195 − 0.066 )( 0.304 ) − ( 0.127 − 0.066 )( 0.265)( 0.304 )( 0.68)


2

=
( 0.195 − 0.066 )( 0.304 ) + ( 0.127 − 0.066 )( 0.265) − ( 0.129 + 0.061)( 0.265)( 0.304 )( 0.68)
2 2

= 1.48

*
wCathy = 1 − wHSBC
*

=
1 − 1.48 =
−0.48

The risky portfolio:


E ( rp*=
) 1.48 × 0.195 + ( −0.48) × 0.127
= 0.228

1
(1.482 )( 0.2652 ) + ( −0.482 )( 0.3042 )  2
σp = 
*

 +2 (1.48 )( −0.48 )( 0.265 )( 0.304 )( 0.68 ) 
= 0.312

Second, select the optimal (complete) allocation between the risky portfolio and the risk free
asset, HIBOR:
E ( rp ) − rf
y* =
Aσ p2
0.228 − 0.066
=
4 × 0.3122
= 0.42

59
The complete portfolio:
E ( rc* ) =
rf + y*  E ( rp* ) − rf 
0.066 + 0.42 ( 0.228 − 0.066 )
=
= 0.133

σ=
*
c y* × σ *p
= 0.42 × 0.312
= 0.130

=U E ( rc* ) − 0.5 Aσ c*2


= 0.133 − 0.5 ( 4 ) ( 0.1302 )
= 0.0996

Interpretations:
Risky Portfolio HIBOR
y* = 42% 1 − y* =
58%
HSBC Cathy
y ⋅ wHSBC
* *
y ⋅ wCathy
* *

= 0.42 ×1.48 = 0.42 × −0.48


= 62% = −20%

Suppose you have $1 million. The optimal decision is to invest $0.42 million in stocks and
deposit $0.58 million at HIBOR. To invest in stocks, you should borrow $0.2 million worth
of Cathy Pacific from your friend, and sell them for $0.2 million (short sell). Together with
your $0.42 million own money, invest $0.62 million in HSBC.

60
Graphically,

E(r)

Optimal risky portfolio


w(HSBC) = 1.48, w(Cathy) = -0.48
CAL
[22.8, 31.2]

HSBC
[19.5, 26.5]

Cathy
[12.7, 30.4]

Optimal complete portfolio


rf y = 0.42
[13.3, 13.0]

Example 4.5

More examples from Hong Kong stocks:


Stocks 1 & 2 r1 σ1 r2 σ2 ρ12
HSBC & Cathy Pacific 0.195 0.265 0.127 0.304 0.68
HSBC & Cheung Kong 0.195 0.265 0.346 0.438 0.70
HSBC & PCCW 0.195 0.265 0.118 0.251 0.54

Optimal risky portfolio:


Stocks 1 & 2 w1 w2 rp σp
HSBC & Cathy Pacific 1.48 -0.48 0.228 0.312
HSBC & Cheung Kong 0.18 0.82 0.319 0.394
HSBC & PCCW 1.19 -0.19 0.209 0.292

Optimal complete portfolio:


Stocks 1 & 2 y* rc σc U
HSBC & Cathy Pacific 0.42 0.133 0.130 0.0966
HSBC & Cheung Kong 0.41 0.169 0.160 0.1175
HSBC & PCCW 0.42 0.126 0.123 0.0962

61
Several observations:
1. If we look at the mean-standard deviation plot, HSBC clearly dominates Cathy Pacific
(higher mean and lower standard deviation). That is why the optimal risky portfolio
involves short selling Cathy Pacific. You want HSBC to have a higher portfolio weight
because it has a higher expected return.

The standard deviation of the optimal risky portfolio is also higher than that of either
HSBC or Cathy Pacific. However, the reward-to-variability ratio is maximized.

The case for HSBC & PCCW is similar.

2. Cheung Kong has a higher expected return than HSBC, but its standard deviation is also
higher. In that case, the optimal risky portfolio invests in both stocks.

3. If we compare the optimal utility levels in the two stocks portfolio with the single stock,
the utility is always higher in the two stocks case. We are better off by diversifying our
portfolio.

Utility Level at Optimal Complete Portfolio


Stocks 1 & 2 Both stocks Stock 1 Stock 2
HSBC & Cathy Pacific 0.0996 0.0956 0.0710
HSBC & Cheung Kong 0.1175 0.0956 0.1171
HSBC & PCCW 0.0962 0.0956 0.0714

62
4.3.3 Case 3: More than Two Risky Assets + Risk Free Asset

In reality, when there are more than two risky assets, the problem becomes more complicated.
Since there is no closed form solution, the problem has to be solved numerically.

The Markowitz Portfolio Selection Model


Specifically, the Markowitz portfolio selection procedure contains the following three steps:

1. Find the minimum-variance frontier from the expected returns and the variance-
covariance matrix of all individual risky assets.

Usually, we use the historical records or time-series averages.

The expected returns for each risky asset i is:


1 T
E ( ri ) ≈ ri = ∑ rit
T t =1

The variances for each asset i:


1 T
σ i2=
≈ σ i2 ∑ ( rit − ri )
2

T − 1 t =1

The covariance for two stocks i and j:

cov ( ri , rj=
) ≈ σ ij T 1− 2 ∑ ( rit − ri ) ( rjt − rj )
T

t =1

Once the mean and variance-covariance matrix of individual risky assets are known, the
mean and variance of the portfolio constructed from these individual risky assets are
given by:

E ( rp ) = ∑ wi E ( ri )
N

i =1

N N N
=σ p2 ∑ wi2σ i2 + ∑∑ wi w jσ ij
=i 1 =i 1 =j 1
i≠ j

For any level of expected return, the investor is interested in the one that yields the lowest
risk (standard deviation).

63
Suppose the expected return is 10%, the investor needs to solve the following problem:
min σ p2
w1 ,, wN

subject to:
N

∑ w E ( r ) = 10%
i =1
i i

w1 + w2 +  + wN =
1

This process tries different values of expected return repeatedly until the minimum
variance frontier has been plotted.

When more assets are included, the portfolio frontier improves. That is, moves toward
upper left – higher mean return and lower risk.

64
2. Find the CAL with the highest reward-to-variability ratio and the optimal risky portfolio.

max
( )
E rp − rf
w1 ,, wN σp

3. Find the optimal complete portfolio.

y* =
( )
E rp − rf
Aσ p2

The most striking feature is that a portfolio manager will offer the same risky portfolio to all
clients regardless of their degree of risk aversion. The more risk averse investor will invest
more in the risk free asset and less in the optimal risky portfolio.

Separation Theorem
The portfolio choice can be separated into two independent tasks:
1. The technical part is to determine the optimal risky portfolio. The best risky portfolio is
the same for all investors.

2. The preference part is to determine the complete portfolio. The allocation between risky
and risk free assets depends on the investor’s preference.

65
Some comments:
1. The separation theory is the theoretical basis for the mutual fund industry. Fund
managers focus on the composition of the funds while investors decide how much money
to put into mutual funds. The composition of the funds is the same for all investors.

2. In reality, not every individual risky asset is included in constructing the minimum
variance frontier. With modern computer technology, the amount of computation is of
less concern. The difficulty is to identify good stocks for the portfolio.

66
4.4 Appendix – Portfolio Analysis Using Excel

This appendix provides us an example on how to model the problem of portfolio optimization
using Excel.

To begin with, recall that the Markowitz portfolio selection contains three steps:
1. Find the mean-variance efficient portfolio.
2. Combine the risk-free asset with the mean-variance efficient portfolio, and find the
optimal risky portfolio.
3. Incorporate the degree of risk aversion of the investors, and solve for the optimal
complete portfolio.

4.4.1 Mean-Variance Efficient Portfolio

The inputs for the efficient portfolio are based on the mean and variance of returns for the
portfolio. In general,

n
The portfolio return: rp = w1r1 + w2 r2 +  + wn rn = ∑wr
i =1
i i

The portfolio variance: Var ( r=


p)
n n
σ=
2
p ∑∑ w w σ
=i 1 =j 1
i j ij

Step 1: Find the time-series mean and variance of returns of all individual stocks.

As an illustration, the sheet “Stock Price” in Markowitz.xls contains the monthly historical
closing price from 2001 to 2005. We first calculate the monthly return based on the closing
price:
Pt
=
rt −1
Pt −1

After getting the monthly returns of each individual stock, we can use the AVERAGE
function to calculate the time-series average:
1 T
ri = ∑ rit
T t =1

We can also use the STDEV function to get the time-series standard deviation:
1 T
=σi ∑ ( rit − ri )
2

T − 1 t =1

67
Step 2: Find the variance-covariance matrix.

The easiest way to get the variance-covariance matrix is to use the COVARIANCE and
CORRELATION function under the Data Analysis ToolPak. But the Data Analysis ToolPak
is not installed with the standard Excel setup. To use it in Excel, we need to enable it first.
To load it:

1. On the Tools menu, click Add-Ins.


2. In the Add-Ins available box, select the check box next to Analysis ToolPak, and then
click OK.
3. Click Tools on the menu bar. When we load the Analysis ToolPak, the Data Analysis
command is added to the Tools menu.

Once the Analysis TookPak is installed, click Data Analysis from the Tools on the menu bar,
and then select COVARIANCE.

68
Highlight the return columns, and then click OK to output the variance-covariance matrix.

The variance-covariance matrix is listed in the sheet “Risk & Return” in Markowitz.xls

Step 3: Finding the portfolio return and variance.

Once the mean, variance of returns and the variance-covariance matrix are known, we can
construct portfolio expected return and variance.

An easy approach is based on Excel’s vector and matrix multiplication. We first denote e and
w as the vector of returns and portfolio weights, and the variance-covariance terms by matrix
V. Then the portfolio return and variance can be written as simple matrix formulas. They
can easily be implemented with Excel array functions.

Matrix Excel Formula


The portfolio return: w′e =SUMPRODUCT(w,e)
The portfolio variance: w′Vw =MMULT(TRANSPOSE(w),MMULT(V,w))

The matrix expression simplifies the calculation of portfolio mean and variance when the
number of stocks is very large.

69
Step 4: Using Solver to find efficient weights.

Given the same data set in Markowitz.xls, suppose we want to construct an efficient portfolio
producing a target return of 1%, the problem is to find the split across the stocks that achieve
the target return whilst minimizing the variance of return.
min σ p2
w1 ,, wN

subject to:
N

∑ w E ( r ) = 1%
i =1
i i

w1 + w2 +  + wN =
1

We can use Excel Solver to solve for this optimization problem. The steps with Solver are:

1. Invoke Solver by choosing Tools then Options then Solver.


2. Specify in the Solver Parameter Dialog Box:
a. The Target Cell (Portfolio SD) to be optimized.
b. The Changing Cell (Portfolio weights).
3. Choose Add to specify the constraints then OK.
4. Click on Options and ensure that Assume Linear Model is not checked.
5. Solve and get the results in the spreadsheet.

70
The Solver Dialog Box to minimize variance:

71
The results:

72
5 Topic 5 – Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)

The portfolio theory has been concerned with how an individual, acting upon a set of
estimates, could select an optimum portfolio. If investors act as we have prescribed, then we
should be able to draw on the analysis to determine how the aggregate of investors will
behave, and how prices and returns at which markets will clear are set.

CAPM gives us an equilibrium model predicting the relationship between the risk of an asset
and its expected return.

The assumptions underlying the CAPM:


1. Many investors who are all price takers.

2. All investors plan to invest over the same horizon.

3. There are no taxes or transaction costs.

4. Investors can borrow and lend at the same risk-free rate over the planned investment
horizon.

5. Investors only care about expected return and variance.

6. All investors have the same information and beliefs about the distribution of returns.

7. The market portfolio consists of all publicly traded assets.

73
The implications from these assumptions:
1. All investors use the Markowitz portfolio selection model to determine the same set of
efficient portfolios. That is, the efficient portfolios are combinations of the risk-free asset
and the tangency portfolio. Therefore, each investor has the same tangency portfolio.

2. Risk averse investors put a majority of wealth in the risk-free asset whereas risk tolerant
investors borrow at the risk-free rate and leverage their holdings. In equilibrium, total
borrowing and lending must equalize so that the risk-free asset is in zero net supply when
we aggregate across all investors.

3. Given each investor holds the same tangency portfolio and the risk-free asset is in zero
net supply, when we aggregate over all investors, the aggregate demand for assets is
simply the tangency portfolio. The supply of all assets is simply the market portfolio, in
which the weight of an asset in the market portfolio is just the market value of the asset
divided by the total market value of all assets. In equilibrium, supply is equal to demand.
Therefore, the tangency portfolio is the market portfolio.

4. Since the market portfolio is the tangency portfolio and the tangency portfolio is mean-
variance efficient, the market portfolio is also mean-variance efficient.

5. The security market line (SML) relationship holds for all assets and portfolios:
E ( ri ) =
rf + βi  E ( rm ) − rf 
Where:
cov ( ri , rm )
βi =
σ 2 ( rm )

5.1 The Market Portfolio

The market portfolio is the portfolio of all risky assets traded in the market.

Suppose there are a total of n risky assets, the market capitalization of asset i is its total
market value:
=MVi price per sharei × # shares outstanding i

Total market capitalization of all risky assets is:


n
MVm = ∑ MVi
i =1

74
The market portfolio is the portfolio with weights in each risky asset i being:
MVi MVi
=wi = n

∑ MVi
MVm
i =1

Why the tangency portfolio is the market portfolio?


Suppose there are only three risky assets, A, B and C, and the tangent portfolio is:
( w , w , w ) = ( 0.25, 0.5, 0.25)
*
a
*
b
*
c

There are only three investors in the economy, 1, 2 and 3, with total wealth of 500, 1000 and
1500 million dollars.

Their asset holdings are:


Investor Riskless A B C
1 100 100 200 100
2 200 200 400 200
3 -300 450 900 450
Total 0 750 1500 750

In equilibrium, the total dollar holding of each asset must equal its market value:
• Market capitalization of A = $750 million
• Market capitalization of B = $1500 million
• Market capitalization of C = $750 million

The total market capitalization is:


750 + 1500 + 750 = 3000 million

The market portfolio:


= = 0.25
wa 750
3000
= = 0.5
wb 1500
3000
= = 0.25
wc 750
3000

Since each investor holds the same risky portfolio or the tangency portfolio, the tangency
portfolio must be the market portfolio.

75
5.2 Derivation of the CAPM

Recall that each investor faces an efficient frontier. When we introduce the risk-free asset,
investor will hold the optimal risky portfolio at the tangency point.

If all investors have homogeneous expectations (A6) and they all face the same lending and
borrowing rate (A4), then they will each face a diagram above, and furthermore, all of the
diagrams will be identical.

Therefore, all investors will end up with portfolios somewhere along the capital market line
(CML) and all efficient portfolios would lie along the CML.

76
We know that if market equilibrium is to exist, the prices of all assets must adjust until all are
held by investors. There can be no excess demand. In other words, prices must be
established so that the supply of all assets equals the demand for holding them.

Suppose a portfolio consisting of a% invested in risky asset i and (1 – a)% in the market
portfolio will have the following mean and standard deviation:
E (=
rp ) aE ( ri ) + (1 − a ) E ( rm )
1

σ=  a 2σ i2 + (1 − a )2 σ m2 + 2a (1 − a ) σ im  2
p  

The change in the mean and standard deviation with respect to a is determined as follows:
∂E ( rp )
= E ( ri ) − E ( rm )
∂a
∂σ p 1 2aσ i2 − 2σ m2 + 2aσ m2 + 2σ im − 4aσ im
= ⋅
∂a 2 1
 a 2σ i2 + (1 − a )2 σ m2 + 2a (1 − a ) σ im  2
 

In equilibrium, the market portfolio already has the value weight wi invested in the risky asset
i. Therefore, the percentage a in the above equation is the excess demand for an individual
risky asset.

But we know the excess demand in equilibrium must be zero. Therefore, we can evaluate the
partial derivatives where a = 0.
∂E ( rp )
= E ( ri ) − E ( rm )
∂a
a =0

∂σ p σ im − σ m2
=
∂a a =0
σm

The slope of the risk-return tradeoff evaluated at point M, the market equilibrium, is:
∂E ( rp ) ∂a E ( ri ) − E ( rm )
=
∂σ p ∂a σ im − σ m2 σ m
a =0

∂E ( rp ) ∂a
Note that is equal to the slope of the CML. Therefore,
∂σ p ∂a
a =0

E ( ri ) − E ( rm ) E ( rm ) − rf


=
σ im − σ m2 σ m σm

77
This relationship can be arranged to solve for E ( ri ) :
σ im
E ( ri ) =
rf +  E ( rm ) − rf 
σ m2
rf + β i  E ( rm ) − rf 
=

This equation is known as capital asset pricing model (CAPM). Graphically, it is also
called the security market line (SML).

78
5.3 Implications of the CAPM

What does beta really mean?


Beta measures the extent to which individual risky asset moves with the market. Suppose:
E ( rm ) 12%,
= = =
rf 6%, β1 0.5

Then:
E ( r1 ) =
rf + β1  E ( rm ) − rf 
6% + 0.5 (12% − 6% )
=
= 9%

If the market goes up to E ( rm ) = 18% , then:


E ( r1 ) =
6% + 0.5 (18% − 6% )
= 12%

In other words, the stock return should go up by:


3% = [ 0.5 × (18% − 12% ) =×β1 change in market return ]

What if another stock has a β 2 = 2 , then the stock should up by 2 × (18% − 12% ) =
12% .

In general,
stock return − rf = beta × ( market return − rf )
∆stock return
= beta × ∆market return

Example 5.1

Suppose that CAPM holds. The expected market return is 14% and T-bill rate is 5%.
1. What should be the expected return on a stock with β = 0?

2. What should be the expected return on a stock with β = 1?

3. What should be the expected return on a portfolio made up of 50% T-bills and 50%
market portfolio?

4. Can beta be negative? What should be the expected return on stock with β = −0.6?

79
5.3.1 Two Important Graphs

Capital Market Line (CML)


Recall that:
 E (r ) − r 
E ( rp =
) rf +  σm f  σ p
 m 

The slope E ( rm ) − rf σ m is the reward-to-variability ratio. CML describes an investment


opportunity, feasible mean and standard deviation pairs from combining the risk-free asset
and the market portfolio.

80
Security Market Line (SML)
Mathematically:
E ( ri ) =
rf + βi  E ( rm ) − rf 

The slope E ( rm ) − rf is the premium on the market portfolio. SML describes an equilibrium
result – a relation between expected return and risk as measured by beta.

81
Notice E ( ri ) =
rf + βi  E ( rm ) − rf  for any stock i, i = 1, ... , N is equivalent to every stock
lies on SML.

What if some stocks are off the SML? For example, stocks XYZ and ABC are off the SML,
what will happen then? Which stock would you like to buy?

For the same beta risk, return on XYZ is higher than the market. Therefore, every investor
wants to buy XYZ. So the price of XYZ will up and the expected return will drop. In
equilibrium, XYZ should lie on the SML.

Likewise, investor will sell ABC, so the price of ABC will go down until the expected return
lie on the SML.

82
5.3.2 Replicating the Beta

We can use market portfolio plus risk-free asset to replicate the beta of any stock.

Let x be the proportion of your money invested in the market portfolio, then 1 – x is the
proportion in the risk-free asset.

The return on this portfolio is:


rp = xrm + (1 − x ) rf

The beta of the portfolio is:


cov ( rp ,rm ) cov ( xrm + (1 − x ) rf ,rm )
=βp =
σm 2 2
σm
cov ( xrm ,rm ) + cov ( (1 − x ) rf ,rm )
=
σ m2
x cov ( rm ,rm ) + 0
=
σ m2
=x

In words, if you want to construct a portfolio that has the same beta as an individual stock,
say β1 , you only need to invest β1 proportion in the market portfolio and 1 − β1 proportion in
the risk-free asset.

Example 5.2

Suppose you want to construct a portfolio with a beta of 0.5, what should you do?
You should invest 0.5 in the market portfolio and 0.5 in the risk-free asset.

83
5.4 Risk in the CAPM

Remember, investors can always diversify away all risk except the covariance of an asset
with the market portfolio. The only risk that investors will pay a premium to avoid is
covariance risk.

This figure shows there are two ways to receive an expected return of E ( rHSBC ) – simply buy
shares in HSBC, or buy portfolio A. For a risk averse investor, portfolio A is preferred to an
investment solely in HSBC since it produces the same return with less risk.

The total risk of HSBC can therefore be decomposed into systematic risk (the minimum risk
required to earn that expected return) and unsystematic risk (portion of the risk that can be
eliminated without sacrificing any expected return by diversifying).

Investors are rewarded for bearing systematic risk, but they are not rewarded for bearing
unsystematic risk, because it can easily be diversified at no cost!

84
5.4.1 CML and SML: A Synthesis

5.5 Estimating Beta

In practice, we estimate the beta of an individual stock from an OLS regression:


rit =α i + βi rmt + ε it

For example, to obtain the beta of China Mobile, we run a regression of the return of China
Mobile on HSI return from January 2003 to December 2008.

The regression results show that:


=
r941 0.02 + 1.19rHSI

85
0.3000

0.2000
Ri = 1.1867Rm + 0.0154
R² = 0.7173
0.1000

0.0000
Ri

-0.3000 -0.2000 -0.1000 0.0000 0.1000 0.2000


-0.1000

-0.2000

-0.3000
Rm

The slope 1.19 is the beta coefficient of China Mobile within the recent 5 years. The beta
1.19 > 1 suggests that the return of China Mobile is more sensitive to the variability from
Hang Seng Index return.

Now, consider we construct a portfolio of three stocks with the following beta and portfolio
weight.
Beta Weight
China Mobile 1.19 40%
HSBC 0.85 30%
PCCW 0.92 30%

What will be the portfolio beta?


cov ( rp ,rm )
βp =
σ m2

=
cov ( ( ∑ w r ) ,r )
i i m

σ 2
m

=
∑ w cov ( r ,r )
i i m

σ m2
= ∑ wi βi

In the example, the portfolio beta is:


β p = 0.4 ×1.19 + 0.3 × 0.85 + 0.3 × 0.92
= 1.007

86
5.6 Empirical Tests of the CAPM

5.6.1 Time-series Tests of the CAPM

If CAPM holds, we should expect that the individual stock return follows this relationship:
E ( ri ) =
rf + βi  E ( rm ) − rf 

Alternatively, we can rewrite:


E ( ri=
) − rf βi  E ( rm ) − rf 

Graphically, if we plot the average risk premiums from portfolios with different betas, we
should expect the portfolios are fitting on the SML.

However, Black (1993) finds that:


• High beta portfolios fall below SML.
• Low beta portfolios land above SML.

87
Separating into different sub periods, CAPM does not seem to work well since the late 1960s.

88
5.6.2 Cross-sectional Tests of the CAPM

Two Step Approach


First, betas were estimated with a set of time-series regressions, one for each security. For
example, the returns on China Mobile and the HSI might be the respective left-hand-side and
right-hand-side values for a single observation.

Each of these regressions, one for each security i can be represented by:
α i + βi rmt + ε it
rit =

The second step obtains estimates of the intercept and slope coefficient of a single cross-
sectional regression.
r =γ + γ βˆ + γ X + δ
i 0 1 i 2 i i

If the CAPM is true, the second step regression should have the following features:
1. The intercept, γ 0 , should be the risk free return.
2. The slope, γ 1 , should be the market portfolio’s risk premium.
3. γ 2 should be zero since variables other than beta should not explain the mean returns
once beta is accounted for.

Both the time-series and cross-sectional tests find evidence that is not supportive of the
CAPM.

89
6 Topic 6 – Factor Models

6.1 Single Factor Model

The simplest factor model is the market model. Casual observation of stock prices reveals
that when the market index goes up, most stocks tend to increase in price; and when the
market index goes down, most stocks tend to decrease in price.

This suggests that stock return may be correlated to market changes. We can relate the return
on a stock to the return on a stock market index as:
ri =α i + βi rm + εi
where :
E ( εi ) = 0
Cov ( εi , rm ) = 0
E ( εiε j ) = 0

To understand the properties of the market model, we can examine the return and risk
decomposition.

90
6.1.1 The Market Model Return Decomposition

The market model suggests we can decompose a stock’s return into three pieces:

αi • The stock’s expected return if the market is neutral, that is, if the market’s
excess return is zero.
βi rm • The component of return due to movements in the overall market.
• βi is the stock’s responsiveness to market movements.
εi • The unexpected component due to an unexpected event that is relevant
only to this stock – firm specific.

By construction, E ( εi ) = 0 , the expected return of a stock only has two components: a unique
part α i and a market related part βi rm . Mathematically,
E ( ri=
) α i + βi E ( rm )

6.1.2 The Market Model Variance Decomposition

Each security has two sources of risk: systematic risk, attributable to its sensitivity to
macroeconomic factors as reflected in R m , and unsystematic risk, as reflected in εi . We can
decompose the risk on each stock by taking variance on both sides:
Var ( ri=
) Var (α i + βi rm + εi )
= βi2Var ( rm ) + Var ( εi )
σ i2 βi2σ m2 + σ ε2
=

Note: α i is a constant term therefore has no variance. The covariance between rm and εi is
zero Cov ( εi , rm ) = 0  because εi is defined as firm specific, that is, independent of
movements in the market.

What about the covariance between the rates of return on two stocks?
Cov ( ri ,rj=
) Cov (αi + βi rm + εi ,α j + β j rm + ε j )
= Cov ( βi rm , β j rm )
= βi β jσ m2

91
6.1.3 The Inputs to Portfolio Analysis

To define the efficient frontier, we have to determine the expected return and standard
deviation on a portfolio.

Recall that the expected return and the standard deviation on any portfolio are:
n
rp = w1r1 + w2 r2 +  + wn rn = ∑wr
i =1
i i

1
 n n n
2
=σ p  ∑ wi2σ i2 + ∑∑ wi w jσ ij 
=i 1 =i 1 =j 1

 j ≠i 

Suppose we are going to analyze 50 stocks. This means that we have to estimate:
• n = 50 estimates of expected returns
• n = 50 estimates of variances
• (n2 – n)/2 = 1,225 estimates of covariances
• A total of 1,325 estimates

What if the number of stocks increases to 3,000, roughly the number of NYSE stocks? We
need more than 4.5 million estimates.

Comparing the set of estimates needed with the Markowitz model, the market model only
needs:
• n estimates of the extra-market expected excess return, α i
• n estimates of the sensitivity coefficients, β i
• n estimates of the firm-specific variances, σ ε2
• 1 estimate for the expected market return, E R m ( )
• 1 estimate for the variance of the common macroeconomic factor, σ m2

Then, the 3n + 2 estimates will enable us to prepare the entire input list for this single-index
universe. For a 50 stocks portfolio, we will need 152 estimates rather than 1,325!

6.1.4 The Market Model and Diversification

Suppose that we choose an equally weighted portfolio of n stocks. The portfolio return can
be written as:
rp =α p + β p rm + ε p

92
Since this is an equally weighted portfolio, each portfolio weight wi = 1 n .
n
1 n
=rp i i
=i 1 =i 1
∑=
iwr
n
∑r
1 n
= ∑ (α i + βi rm + ε i )
n i =1
1 n 1 n  1 n
=
=
∑ i  n ∑
α
n i 1=
+
i 1
β i m
=
r + ∑ εi
ni1

And the portfolio variance is:


σ p2 β p2σ M2 + σ ε2
=

β p2σ M2 is the systematic risk component of the portfolio variance. This part of the risk
depends on portfolio beta and σ M2 , and will persist regardless of the extent of portfolio
diversification.

In contrast, the unsystematic component σ ε2 is attributable to firm-specific components εi .


Because these εi are independent and all have zero expected value, when more stocks are
added to the portfolio, the firm-specific components tend to cancel out.
2
1 2 1 2
n
=σ ∑= 2
ε  σi σε
i =1  n  n

Graphically,

93
6.2 Multifactor Models

The single factor provides a simple description of stock returns, but it is not realistic. For
example, a security can be sensitive to interest rate risk other than market risk alone. In real
life, there exists more than one common factor that generates stock returns.

The multifactor model:


ri = α i + βi1 F1 + βi 2 F2 +  + βiK FK + εi

The F can be thought of as proxies for new information about macroeconomic variables.
Some common factors proposed by Chen, Roll and Ross (1986):
α i + βi ,MP MP + βi ,DEI DEI + βi ,UIUI + βi ,UPRUPR + βi ,UTSUTS + ε i
ri =

1. Changes in the monthly growth rate of the GDP (MP).


• This alters investor expectations about future industrial production and corporate
earnings.

2. Changes in expected inflation (DEI).


• Measured by changes in the short-term T-bill yield.
• Changes in expected inflation affect government policy, consumer confidence, and
interest rate levels.

3. Unexpected changes in the price level (UI).


• Measured by the difference between actual and expected inflation.
• Unexpectedly high or low inflation alters the values of most contracts. These include
contracts with suppliers and distributors, and financial contracts such as a firm’s debt
instruments.

4. Changes in the default risk premium (UPR).


• Measured by the spread between the yields of AAA and Baa bonds of similar maturity.
• As the spread widens, investors become more concerned about default.

5. Changes in the spread between the yields of long-term and short-term government bonds
(UTS).
• The average slope of the term structure of interest rates as measured by the yields on
U.S. Treasury notes and bonds.
• This would affect the discount rates for obtaining present values of future cash flows.

94
The factor betas β describe how sensitive the stock’s return is to changes in the common
factors.

Source: Table 4, Chen, Ross & Ross (1986)

6.2.1 Factor Models for Portfolios

Given the K-factor model for each stock i, a portfolio of N securities with weights wi on stock
i has a factor equation of:
rp = α p + β p1 F1 + β p 2 F2 +  + β pK FK + ε p
Where:
α p= w1α1 + w2α 2 +  + wN α N
β p=
1 w1β11 + w2 β 21 +  + wN β N 1
β p=
2 w1β12 + w2 β 22 +  + wN β N 2

β pK
= w1β1K + w2 β 2 K +  + wN β NK
ε p = w1ε1 + w2ε2 +  + wN εN

95
Example 6.1

Consider the following two-factor model for the returns of three securities: Cheung Kong,
Cathy Pacific and HSBC.
rCK = 0.03 + F1 − 4 F2 + εCK
r = 0.05 + 3F + 2 F + ε
CP 1 2 CP

rHSBC = 0.10 + 1.5 F1 + 0 F2 + εHSBC

Write out the factor equation for a portfolio that equally weights all three securities.
1 1 1
α p = ( 0.03) + ( 0.05 ) + ( 0.10 ) = 0.06
3 3 3
1 1 1
β p1 = (1) + ( 3) + (1.5 ) = 1.83
3 3 3
1 1 1
β p 2 = ( −4 ) + ( 2 ) + ( 0 ) =−0.67
3 3 3

Thus, the equation:


rp =0.06 + 1.83F1 − 0.67 F2 + ε p

6.2.2 Tracking Portfolios

One of the most important applications of the multifactor model is that we can design a
portfolio that targets a specific factor beta in order to track the risk of a security.

Suppose you invest in ICBC. ICBC’s stock price will drop by 10% for every 1% decline in
the growth of China’s GDP and 5% drop when the RMB depreciates 1%. Hence, investing
in ICBC has two sources of risk: currency risk and a slowing of China’s economy.

You can hedge these sources of risk by short selling a portfolio that tracks the sensitivity of
ICBC’s stock to these two sources of risk.

96
Example 6.2

Suppose ICBC has a factor beta of 2 on the first factor and a factor beta of 1 on the second
factor. Design a portfolio of stocks in Example 6.1 that tracks the ICBC return.

Recall that from Example 6.1,


rCK = 0.03 + F1 − 4 F2 + εCK
r = 0.05 + 3F + 2 F + ε
CP 1 2 CP

rHSBC = 0.10 + 1.5 F1 + 0 F2 + εHSBC

To design a portfolio with these characteristics, it is necessary to find portfolio weights, wCK,
wCP and wHSBC, that make the portfolio weighted averages of the betas equal to the target
betas.

To make the weights sum to one,


wCK + wCP + wHSBC =1

To have a factor beta of 2 on the first factor,


1wCK + 3wCP + 1.5wHSBC = 2

To have a factor beta of 1 on the second factor,


−4 wCK + 2 wCP + 0 wHSBC =1

With three equations and three unknown, the solution is:


 wCK = −0.1

 wCP = 0.3
w
 HSBC = 0.8

97
6.2.3 Pure Factor Portfolio

Pure factor portfolios are portfolios with a sensitivity of one to one of the factors and zero to
the remaining factors.

Example 6.3

What are the weights of the two pure factor portfolios constructed from the three stocks in
Example 6.1?
rCK = 0.03 + F1 − 4 F2 + εCK
r = 0.05 + 3F + 2 F + ε
CP 1 2 CP

rHSBC = 0.10 + 1.5 F1 + 0 F2 + εHSBC

To construct the pure factor portfolio for the first factor, find portfolio weights that result in a
portfolio with a target factor beta of one on the first beta and zero on the second beta.
 1wCK + 3wCP + 1.5wHSBC = 1

−4 wCK + 2 wCP + 0 wHSBC = 0
 wCK + wCP + wHSBC =
 1

Thus,
 wCK = −0.2

 wCP = −0.4
w
 HSBC = 1.6

To find pure factor portfolio for the second factor, solve the following system of equations:
 1wCK + 3wCP + 1.5wHSBC = 0

−4 wCK + 2 wCP + 0 wHSBC = 1
 wCK + wCP + wHSBC =
 1

The weights become,


 wCK = −0.9

 wCP = −1.3
w
 HSBC = 3.2

98
6.2.4 Risk Premiums of Pure Factor Portfolios

The respective risk premiums of the K-factor model are denoted by λ1 , λ2 , , λK . By


definition,
E ( rFPi =
) rf + λi
where:
E ( rFPi ) = expected return of pure factor portfolio i
λi = risk premium of pure factor portfolio i
rf = risk free rate

Example 6.4

Suppose we have three stocks: A, B and C, and their hypothetical factor equations (with
factor means of zero) are:
rA = 0.08 + 2 F1 + 3F2
r = 0.10 + 3F + 2 F
B 1 2

rC = 0.10 + 3F1 + 5 F2

Write out the pure factor equations for the two factor portfolios and determine their risk
premiums if the risk free rate is 4%.

First, find the weights that satisfy pure factor portfolio 1 and 2.

 wA = 2

 1
For pure factor portfolio 1:  wB =
 3
 4
 wC = − 3

 wA = 3

 2
For pure factor portfolio 2:  wB = −
 3
 4
 wC = − 3

Second, the α for pure factor portfolios 1 and 2:


1 4
α FP1 = 2 ( 0.08 ) + ( 0.1) − ( 0.1) = 0.06
3 3
2 4
α FP 2 = 3 ( 0.08 ) − ( 0.1) − ( 0.1) = 0.04
3 3

99
The pure factor equations:
rFP1 = 0.06 + 1F1 + 0 F2
r = 0.04 + 0 F + 1F
FP 2 1 2

By assumption, the factor means are zero. The risk premiums become:
λ1 = 0.06 − 0.04 = 0.02
λ2 = 0.04 − 0.04 = 0

100
7 Topic 7 – Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT)

Arbitrage pricing theory (APT) is a different approach to determining asset prices. It is based
on the law of one price: two items that are the same cannot sell at different prices. The
advantage of APT is that we do not need strong assumptions made in CAPM.

The APT requires only four assumptions:


1. The returns can be described by a factor model.

2. There are no arbitrage opportunities.

3. There are a large number of securities, so that it is possible to form portfolios that
diversify the firm specific risk of individual stocks.

4. The financial markets are frictionless.

7.1 Derivation of the APT

7.1.1 Single Factor APT

Suppose the return generating process for an individual stock follows a single factor model:
ri =α i + βi F + ε

Now consider an arbitrage portfolio consisting of w in Stock A, and (1 – w) in Stock B. The


two stocks share a common risk factor F . The risk free rate is rf. Here, by arbitrage
portfolio, we mean zero risk portfolio.

The portfolio return is therefore:


rp= wrA + (1 − w)rB

If an investor holds a well-diversified portfolio, residual risk will go to zero and only factor
risk will matter. So that:
i α i + β i Fi
r=

Therefore,
( ) (
rp w α A + β A F + (1 − w ) α B + β B F
= )
=α B + w (α A − α B ) +  β B + w ( β A − β B )  F

101
By definition, this portfolio is to be risk free. Thus we need to choose a w so that:
 β B + w ( β A − β B )  F =
0

This implies this portfolio has a zero factor risk.


 β B + w ( β A − β B )  =
0
βB
⇒w=−
β A − βB

We can replace the w into the portfolio return equation:


rp =α B + w (α A − α B ) +  β B + w ( β A − β B )  F
β
αB −
= B
(α − α B )
β A − βB A

Since this portfolio has zero risk, it must earn a risk free return.
βB
rp =α B − (α − α B ) =rf
β A − βB A

Rearrange the terms,


β
αB −
rf = B
(α − α B )
β A − βB A
β A − βB β − βB βB
rf =α B A − (α − α B )
β A − βB β A − βB β A − βB A
rf β A rβ α B β A − α B βB − α AβB + α B βB
− f B =
β A − βB β A − βB β A − βB
rf β A rβ α β α β
− f B = B A − A B
β A − βB β A − βB β A − βB β A − βB
β B (α A − rf=
) β A (α B − r f )
α A − rf α B − rf
=
βA βB

Since α A = E ( rA ) and α B = E ( rB ) , we can rewrite:


E ( rA ) − rf E ( rB ) − rf
= = λ
βA βB

The equation tells us the excess return over factor loading is constant across stocks. The
constant λ is the risk premium of a stock with unit factor beta.

102
The expected return on any stock can be written as:
) rf + β i λ
E (ri =

This is the single factor APT.

7.1.2 Two-Factor APT

Suppose the return of a security is described by the following two-factor model:


α i + βi1 F1 + βi 2 F2 + εi
ri =

The theory does not say what the factors are but you may think of the individual stock has
two common factors like unexpected growth in GDP and unexpected inflation. If an investor
holds a well-diversified portfolio, residual risk will go to zero and only factor risk will matter.

So the investor will concern about the risk and return of the portfolio by looking at the three
attributes: E ( ri ) , βi1 , βi 2 .

Consider three diversified portfolios:


Portfolio E ( ri ) βi1 βi 2
A 15% 1.0 0.6
B 14% 0.5 1.0
C 10% 0.3 0.2

From the concepts of geometry, the equation of the plane defined by the three portfolios:
E ( ri ) =λ0 + λ1βi1 + λ2 βi 2

By substituting in the values of E ( ri ) , βi1 , βi 2 for portfolios A, B and C, we obtain three
equations with three unknown.
0.15 = λ0 + 1λ1 + 0.6λ2

0.14 = λ0 + 0.5λ1 + 1λ2
0.10 = λ0 + 0.3λ1 + 0.2λ2

Solving the system of equations and we can get the equation of the plane:
E ( ri ) = 7.75 + 5βi1 + 3.75βi 2

Let’s create two additional portfolios here. Portfolio E has the following factor risks and
E ( rE ) 15%,
expected return: = = βi1 0.6,
= βi 2 0.6 . We can compare this portfolio with a
portfolio D constructed by placing one-third of the funds in each portfolio A, B and C.

103
The risk and return for the two portfolios:
Portfolio D Portfolio E
E ( ri ) 3 (15% ) + 3 (14% ) + 3 (10% ) =
1 1 1
13% 15%
βi1 1
3 (1.0 ) + 13 ( 0.5) + 13 ( 0.3) =
0.6 0.6
βi 2 3 ( 0.6 ) + 3 (1.0 ) + 3 ( 0.2 ) =
1 1 1
0.6 0.6

By the law of one price, two portfolios that have the same risk cannot sell at a different
expected return. In this situation, arbitrageurs will step in and buy portfolio E while selling
an equal amount of portfolio D short.

Assume an arbitrageur short sells $100 worth of portfolio D to finance the purchase of
portfolio E, the payoff will be:
Beginning Ending
βi1 βi 2
Cash Flow Cash Flow
Portfolio D +$100 –$113 –0.6 –0.6
Portfolio E –$100 +$115 0.6 0.6
Arbitrage Portfolio $0 +$2 0 0

The arbitrage portfolio involves zero investment, has no systematic factor risk, and earns $2.
Arbitrage will continue until the expected return of portfolio E becomes 13%.

In general, all investments and portfolios must be on a plane in the E ( ri ) , βi1 , βi 2 space. If an
investment were to lie above or below the plane, an opportunity would exist for riskless
arbitrage. The arbitrage would continue until all investment converged to a plane.

Recall that the equation of a plane in our illustration:


E ( ri ) = 7.75 + 5βi1 + 3.75βi 2

We can confirm portfolio D is on the plane and no arbitrage opportunity exists.


E ( rD ) = 13% ≡ 7.75 + 5 ( 0.6 ) + 3.75 ( 0.6 ) = 13%

However, portfolio E is not on the plane.


E ( rE ) = 15% ≠ 7.75 + 5 ( 0.6 ) + 3.75 ( 0.6 ) = 13%

In equilibrium, all portfolios must obey the two-factor APT model.


E ( ri ) =λ0 + βi1λ1 + βi 2 λ2
where:
λ0 = rf
λ=i E ( ri ) − r=
f risk premium of pure factor portfolio i

104
7.1.3 Multifactor APT

The analysis can be generalized into the K-factor case.


ri = α i + βi1 F1 + βi 2 F2 +  + βiK FK + εi

By analogous arguments it can be shown that all securities and portfolios have expected
returns described by the K-dimensional hyper plane:
E ( ri ) = λ0 + βi1λ1 + βi 2 λ2 +  + βiK λK
where:
λ0 = rf
λ=i E ( ri ) − r=
f risk premium of pure factor portfolio i

7.2 Comments on APT

7.2.1 Strength and Weaknesses of APT

Strength
• The model gives a reasonable description of return and risk.
• Factors seem plausible.
• No need to measure market portfolio correctly.

Weaknesses
• Model itself does not say what the right factors are.
• Factors can change over time.
• Estimating multi-factor models requires more data.

7.2.2 Differences between APT and CAPM

• APT is based on the factor model of returns and the no arbitrage argument.
• CAPM is based on investors’ portfolio demand and equilibrium argument.

105
8 Topic 8 – Anomalies and Market Efficiency

8.1 CAPM and the Cross-section of Stock Returns

The CAPM states that:


E ( ri ) =
rf + β  E ( rm ) − rf 

The expected return on a security is positively and linearly related to the security’s beta. In
other words, if one stock has a high beta, then the realized return should also be high.

Example 8.1

Suppose:
• China Mobile has a beta of 1.5.
• CLP has a beta of 0.7.
• The risk free rate is assumed to be 3%, and the market risk premium is assumed to be 8%.

The expected return for China Mobile:


15% = 3% + 1.5 * 8%

The expected return for CLP:


8.6% = 3% + 0.7 * 8%

Here, the beta of China Mobile is higher than the beta of CLP. Therefore, CAPM says that
the return of China Mobile will be higher than CLP (15% > 8.6%) in this example.

In reality, this relationship is NOT true. Fama & French (1992) test the CAPM simply by
looking at the realized return of 10 beta portfolios. In each year, they rank stocks according
to its beta. Their Low-β portfolio, on average, has a beta of 0.87, while the High-β portfolio
has a beta of 1.72.

Source: Table 1, Fama & French (1992).

106
If CAPM holds, then we expect the High-β portfolio should have the highest return. But,
let’s take a look at the evidence:

1.4

Average Monthly Return (%). 1.35

1.3

1.25

1.2

1.15

1.1

1.05

1
Low β β2 β3 β4 β5 β6 β7 β8 β9 High β

Source: Table 1, Fama & French (1992).

There is NO relationship between beta and return. We do not observe any monotonic-
increasing return from the Low-β portfolio to High-β portfolio.

The evidence suggests that high risk (high beta) does not truly mean high return.

The market beta fails to explain the cross-section of expected returns.

We call the empirical contradictions to the benchmark asset pricing models (e.g. CAPM) as
anomalies.

In practice, some important anomalies include:


• Size effect: small stocks earn a higher return than large stocks.
• Value effect: value stocks earn a higher return than growth stocks.
• Momentum effect: winning stocks keep winning over a short-period of time.

8.2 Size Effect

The size effect refers to the negative relationship between returns and the market
capitalization (market value) of a firm. Note that market capitalization is defined as the share
price times share outstanding.

107
A simple way to show the size effect is to form portfolios based on market capitalization.

20.00%
18.00%
16.00%
14.00%
Average Return

12.00%
10.00%
8.00%
6.00%
4.00%
2.00%
0.00%
Small 2 3 4 Large

Source: Table 5, Loughran (1997).

We can see the average return on small stocks is quite a bit higher than the average return on
large stocks.

Can this size effect be explained by risk differences? Is it possible that small stocks are
riskier than large stocks and therefore the return difference is merely compensation for the
extra risk?

The risk story cannot fully explain the size effect.

Source: Table 1, Fama & French (1992).

108
When we control for risk (beta), the stocks that are in the same risk class also have the size
anomaly.

For example, in the High-β portfolio, the size premium (i.e., the difference between Small-
ME and Large-ME) is 0.86%. And this effect applies to other beta portfolios.

One explanation of this size anomaly is related to the January effect. The January effect is a
calendar effect where stocks, especially small-cap stocks, tend to rise markedly in price
during the period starting on the last day of December and ending on the early days of
January.

This effect is owed to year-end selling to create tax losses, recognize capital gains, effect
portfolio window dressing, or raise holiday cash. Because such selling depresses the stocks
but has nothing to do with their fundamental worth, bargain hunters quickly buy in, causing
the January rally.

To test whether January causes this size effect, a simply way is to get rid of the return from
January and then observe the return from the same size portfolios.

Source: Table 5, Loughran (1997).

109
Panel A includes the return from January. We can see the SMALL has an average return of
18.9% while the LARGE is 11.91%. But once we exclude the return from January in Panel C,
the size effect is gone!

How about the evidence from Pacific-Basin markets?

Chiu & Wei (1998) show there is size effect in Hong Kong, Korea, Malaysia and Thailand
except Taiwan.

The size sorted portfolios from 1984 to 1993 show that the size premium in Hong Kong is
ranging from 0.04% to 1.24%.

Source: Table 3, Chiu & Wei (1998).

8.3 Value Effect

The value effect refers to the positive relationship between returns and the ratio of value to
market price of a security. For example, some ratios include:
• B/M (book value of equity/market value of equity)
• E/P or C/P (earnings or cash flow/price).

110
8.3.1 The Glamour and Value Strategies

Value stocks refer to stocks with low prices relative to book equity, earnings or cash flows.
Therefore, they have high B/M, E/P or C/P.

Glamour stocks refer to stocks with high prices relative to book equity, earnings or cash
flows. Therefore, they have low B/M, E/P or C/P.

E/P and C/P are easy to understand:


E P
= 0.05 ⇒ = 20 ⇒ glamour
P E
E P
= 0.15 ⇒ = 6.67 ⇒ value
P E

B/M is a proxy for growth opportunities. The book value of equity refers to shareholders’
equity in the balance sheet and market value of equity is simply the market price * shares
outstanding.

A large extent of book value is based on historical costs. It does not reflect the value of
future prospects.

On the other hand, the market value of the stock does reflect these future prospects.

When the market perceives a firm with good future prospects, the book value will be small
relative to the market value.

Think of a company that has recently introduced a new and exciting product. The historical
cost of its assets-in-place may be small, but sales and earnings are up.

Since the company has great prospects, the market is willing to pay a higher stock price.
Therefore, the B/M will be small for growth firms.

111
And here is the evidence.

B/M

25%

20%
Average Return

15%

10%

5%

0%
Glamour 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Value

C/P

25%

20%
Average Return

15%

10%

5%

0%
Glamour 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Value

Source: Table 1, Lakonishok, Shleifer & Vishny (1994).

Both ratios show that value stocks outperform glamour stocks subsequently. Also, value
stocks outperform the market indices such as S&P500. If you buy value stocks, you can beat
the market!

112
In practice, fund managers apply the size and value to describe their investing style. For
example, Morningstar, one of the largest mutual fund information providers, classifies funds
according to their market capitalization and investment style.

113
The Morningstar style box is a nine-square grid that classifies securities by size along the
vertical axis and by value-and-growth characteristics along the horizontal axis. The size is
divided into large, medium and small, whereas the growth characteristic is specified as value,
balanced and growth. The chart below illustrates a mutual fund which its investment style is
described as "Large-cap Value".

Are the value stocks riskier than the glamour stocks?

Again, this is not the case. The difference in two risk measures – beta and standard
deviations are too small to justify the difference in returns.

Source: Table 8, Lakonishok, Shleifer & Vishny (1994).

114
Lakonishok, Shleifer & Vishny (1994) propose the extrapolation story can explain the value
effect. The idea is that:
1. Value stocks are underpriced because investors have low expectation.
• These stocks performed poorly in the past.
• Investors expect them to continue to perform poorly.
• But once actual performance improved, stock prices rise and returns become high.

2. Glamour stocks are overvalued because investors have high expectation.


• These stocks performed well in the past.
• Investors expect them to perform well in the future.
• When future performance does not meet expectation, investors are disappointed, stock
prices drop and returns become low.

8.4 Momentum Investing Strategies

Stocks with prices on an upward (downward) trajectory over a prior period of 3 to 12 months
have a higher than expected probability of continuing on that upward (downward) trajectory
over the subsequent 3 to 12 months.

This temporal pattern in prices is referred to as momentum.

In layman terms, momentum investing is based on a simple rule: buy stocks that perform the
best (winner) and sell stocks that perform the worst (loser) in recent past.

This strategy focuses on cross-sectional patterns of return continuation instead of the time-
series predictability known as technical analysis.

Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) construct a simple J-K momentum strategy – select stocks on
the basis of returns over the past J months and hold them for K months.
• At the beginning of each month t the stocks are ranked in ascending order on the basis of
their returns in the past J months.
• Based on these rankings, form ten equally-weighted deciles portfolios.
• In each month t, the strategy buys the winner portfolio and sells the loser portfolio and
holds this position for K months.
• The strategy closes out the position initiated in month t – K.

115
The result:

Source: Table 1, Jegadeesh and Titman (1993)

Buy-sell means a zero dollar investment strategy. The investors short the loser portfolio and
use the proceeds to long the winner portfolio. Without putting money, the momentum
strategy generates positive return!

116
Two explanations:
• Risk-based explanations for momentum.
• Behavioral explanations for momentum.

The risk story is not consistent because they find that the beta of the winning portfolio (P10)
is not significantly higher than the losing portfolio (P1).

Source: Table 2, Jegadeesh and Titman (1993)

The behavioral explanations challenge the often-assumed fully rational behavior of investors.

Some psychological factors may explain:


• Investors are over confident in their private signals related to the value of a firm. (Daniel
et al., 1998)
• Investors are conservative (Barberis et al., 1998). Conservatism relates to slow updating
of beliefs when new evidence is presented.

8.5 Efficient Market Hypothesis

In an efficient market, an asset’s price should be the best possible estimate of its economic
values.

A financial market is informational efficient when market prices reflect all available
information about value.

117
What does it mean to “reflect all available information”? There are three types of market
efficiency.

Weak Form Efficiency


• Stock prices reflect all historical information.
• No investor can earn abnormal returns by developing trading rules based on historical
price or return information.

Semi-strong Form Efficiency


• Stock prices reflect all public information.
• Publicly available information includes published accounting statements and information
found in annual reports.

Strong Form Efficiency


• Stock prices reflect all public and private information.
• No investor can earn abnormal returns by developing trading rules based on private
information.

8.5.1 Empirical Tests of Efficient Market Hypothesis

In general, the tests of efficient market hypothesis often start with:


= ri E ( ri ) + ei
where :
E ( ri ) = risk adjusted expected return from a
pricing model (e.g. CAPM)
ei = residual term

The efficient market hypothesis says that the residual term ei must be (1) zero on average; (2)
unpredictable based on current information.

118
Example 8.2

The annual return and beta of the three assets are as follows:
Average
Annual Beta
Return
The Franklin Income Fund 12.9% 1.000
Dow Jones Industrial Average 11.1% 0.683
Salomon’s High Grade Bond Index 9.2% 0.367

Suppose the market return is 13% and the risk free rate is 7%. Using CAPM, the expected
returns are:
Expected Return
The Franklin Income Fund 13.0%
Dow Jones Industrial Average 11.1%
Salomon’s High Grade Bond Index 9.2%

Consider this example, the expected return on the Franklin Income Fund was higher than the
realized return. The market expected 13% performance the Fund delivered 12.9%. The
difference is the abnormal return.

Is the existence of this abnormal return evidence market inefficiency? However, we cannot
conclusively state that the market is inefficient because:
1. The model that we used to risk adjusted the returns (CAPM) could be incorrect.
2. Our estimates of beta may be incorrect.
3. Our estimate of the expected return of the market may be incorrect.

As a result, all statements about market efficiency should be conditioned in terms of the
model used to test efficiency. That is, any test of efficiency is a joint test of efficiency and the
asset pricing model.

Given a particular pricing model, you might find evidence against market efficiency.
Another explanation, however, is that the market is efficient and you are using the wrong
pricing model. This is a common dilemma in testing joint hypotheses.

119
9 Topic 9 – Fixed Income Securities

9.1 Fixed Income Securities and Markets

Fixed income securities are financial claims with promised cash flows of fixed amount paid
at fixed dates. A bond is a basic fixed income security. The issuer sells a bond to the
bondholder for some amount of cash. This arrangement obligates the issuer to make
specified interest payments to the bondholder on specified dates.

A typical coupon bond obligates the issuer to make semiannual interest payments to the
bondholder. These payments are called coupon payments. When the bond matures, the
issuer repays the debt by paying the bondholder the bond’s par value.

Some bonds do not make any periodic coupon payments. Zero-coupon bond is issued that
makes no coupon payments. Instead, the bondholder realizes interest by the difference
between the maturity value and the purchase price.

9.1.1 Types of Fixed Income Securities

Treasury securities
• Treasury bills
Treasury bills (T-bills) mature in one-year or less. Like zero-coupon bonds, they do not
pay interest prior to maturity.

• Treasury notes
Treasury notes have maturities between 1 to 10 years. Like straight bonds, they make
semiannual coupon payments.

• Treasury bonds
Treasury bonds have maturities usually ranging from 10 to 30 years. They also make
semiannual coupon payments.

120
Corporate bonds
• Mortgage bonds
The issuer has granted the bondholders a first-mortgage lien on substantially all of its
properties. A lien is a legal right to sell mortgaged property to satisfy unpaid obligations
to bondholders.

• Debentures
Debentures are not secured by a specific pledge of designated property. They are
unsecured debt backed only by the goodwill of the corporation. In the event of
liquidation, debenture holders are paid after mortgage bondholders.

• Convertible bonds
Convertible bonds give bondholders an option to exchange each bond for a specified
number of shares of common stock of the corporation.

• Callable / Puttable bonds


The call provisions on corporate bonds allow the issuer to repurchase the bond at a
specified call price before the maturity date. The puttable bond grants the bondholder the
right to sell the issue back to the issuer at par value on designated dates.

9.2 Bond Pricing

The price of a bond is equal to the present value of the expected cash flow.

9.2.1 Coupon Bond

The cash flow for a coupon bond consists of an annuity of fixed coupon interest and the par
value at maturity.
$C $C $C $C+$F

1 2 3 T

121
In general, the price of a bond is given by:
C C C C+F
P= + + + +
1 + y (1 + y ) 2
(1 + y )
T −1
(1 + y )
T

 1 1 1   1 
= C + + + T 
+F T 
1 + y (1 + y ) (1 + y )   (1 + y ) 
2

1  1   1 
= C ×  1 −   + F ×  T 
 y  (1 + y )    (1 + y ) 
T

= Coupon × Annunity Factor ( y, T ) + Par × PV Factor ( y, T )

Example 9.1

A 30-year bond with an 8% (4% per 6 months) coupon rate and a par value of $1,000 has the
following cash flows:
Semiannual coupon = $1,000×4% = $40
Par value at maturity = $1,000

Therefore, there are 60 semiannual cash flows of $40 and a $1,000 cash flow 60 six-month
periods from now.
$40 $40 $40 $40+$1,000

1 2 3 60

The price of this 30-year bond:

40 40 40 1040
=
P + + + +
( ) ( ) ( )
2 59 60
1+ y 1+ y 1+ y 1+ y
2 2 2 2
where :
y = annual discount rate

Suppose the discount rate is 8% annually or 4% per 6-month, the price of the bond is:
1  1   1 
P = C ×  1 −   + F ×  T 
 y  (1 + y )    (1 + y ) 
T

 1  1   1 
= 40 ×  1 −   + 1000 ×  60 
 0.04  (1.04 )    (1.04 ) 
60

= 904.94 + 95.06
= 1000

122
What if the discount rate rises to 10% annually, then the bond price will fall by $189.29 to
$810.71.
1  1   1 
P=40 × 1 −  + 1000 ×  60 
0.05  (1.05 )60   (1.05 ) 
= 757.17 + 53.54
= 810.71

The central feature of fixed income securities is that there is an inverse relation between bond
price and discount rate.

In this example, the price/yield relationship for a 30-year, 8% coupon bond:

Yield 4% 6% 8% 10% 12%


Price 1,695.22 1,276.76 1,000.00 810.71 676.77

Note:
• When the coupon rate equals the discount rate, the price equals the par value.
• When the coupon rate is less than the discount rate, the price is less than the par value.
• When the coupon rate is greater than the discount rate, the price is greater than the par
value.

123
9.2.2 Zero-Coupon Bond

In the case of a zero-coupon bond, the only cash flow is the par value. Therefore, the price of
a zero-coupon bond is simply the present value of the par value.

Example 9.2

A zero-coupon bond that matures in 20 years has a par value of $1,000. If the required yield
is 4.3%, then the value is:
1000
= P = 430.83
1.04320

9.3 Dirty Price, Clean Price and Accrued Interest

Typically, an investor will purchase a bond between coupon dates. So how to determine the
price when the settlement date falls between coupon periods?

Suppose we have a coupon bond that matures in 4 years has a par value of $1,000. Assume
the bond pays 10% coupon annually and the market yield is also 10%.

The price of the bond at t = 0 is:


100 100 100 1100
Pt =0 = + + +
1.1 1.12 1.13 1.14
= 1000

After half year, if the bondholder wishes to sell the bond, the price of the bond at t = 0.5
becomes:
100 100 100 1100

.5 1 2 3 4

100 100 100 1100


Pt =0.5 = + + +
1.10.5 1.11.5 1.12.5 1.13.5
= 1048.81

124
In general, the present value formula should be modified because the cash flows will not be
received one full period from now. For a bond with T coupon payments remaining to
maturity, the price becomes:
C C C C+F
= P + + + +
(1 + y ) (1 + y ) (1 + y ) (1 + y )
w 1+ w 2+ w T −1+ w

where :
No. of days between settlement and next coupon payment
w=
No. of days in the coupon period

The price calculated in this way is called the dirty price because it reflects the total cash flow
the buyer will receive.

In this illustration, the dirty price has been moved without any economic reasons, such as
changes in interest rate. When we look at the dynamics of the dirty price, the price gradually
rises and then suddenly drops every period. The rises reflect the accrued interest to the seller
and the drop is the result of ex-coupon.

Therefore, the dirty price can be disaggregated into clean price and accrued interest. In short,
Dirty Price = Clean Price + Accrued Interest.

125
To compute the accrued interest,
 No. of days from last coupon payment to settlement date 
AI = C  
 No. of days in coupon period 
where :
AI = accrued interest
C = coupon

The accrued interest calculation for a bond is dependent on the day-count basis. Below are
different versions of day-count conventions:

Convention Definition Securities


Actual / Actual  The actual number of  US Treasury bonds and
days between two dates notes
is used.
 Leap years are 366 days,
non-leap years are 365
days.
Actual / 365  The actual number of  Eurobonds, and Euro-
days between two dates floating rate notes
is used in numerator. (FRNs)
 All years are assumed to  Foreign government
have 365 days. bonds
Actual / 360  The actual number of  Eurodollar deposits,
days between two dates commercial paper,
is used in numerator. banker’s acceptance
 A year is assumed to  Repo, FRNs and
have 12 months of 30 LIBOR-based
days each. transactions
30 / 360  All months are assumed  Corporate bonds, US
to have 30 days, agency securities,
resulting in a 360 day municipal bonds,
year. mortgages
 If the first date falls on
the 31st, it is changed to
the 30th.
 If the second date falls
on the 31st, it is changed
to the 30th, but only if
the first date falls on the
30th or the 31st.

126
Example 9.3

Suppose that a corporate bond with a coupon rate of 10% maturing March 1, 2006 is
purchased with a settlement date of July 17, 2000. What would the price of this bond be if it
is priced to yield 6.5%?

For corporate bond, the day count convention is 30 / 360. That is, each month is assumed to
have 30 days and each year 360 days. The number of days between July 17 and September 1
is:
July 13 days
August 30 days
September 1 days
44 days

There are 44 days between the settlement date and the next coupon date. The number of days
in the coupon period is 180. Therefore:
44
=w = 0.2444
180

The number of coupon payments remaining is 12. The semiannual interest rate is 3.25%.
Suppose the par value is $1,000, the dirty price is:
C C C C+F
=P + + + +
(1 + y ) (1 + y ) (1 + y ) (1 + y )
w 1+ w 2+ w T −1+ w

50 50 50 1050
= 0.2444
+ 1.2444
+ 2.2444
+ +
1.0325 1.0325 1.0325 1.032511.2444
= 1200.28

The number of days from the last coupon payment date (March 1, 2000) to the settlement
date is 180 – 44 = 136. The accrued interest per $1,000 of par value is:
 No. of days from last coupon payment to settlement date 
AI = C  
 No. of days in coupon period 
136 
= 50 
180 
= 37.78

The clean price is the dirty price minus accrued interest, 1200.28 – 37.78 = 1162.5.

127
9.4 Conventional Yield Measures

An investor who purchases a bond can expect to receive a dollar return from one or more of
the following sources:
• The coupon interest payments made by the issuer.
• Any capital gain or loss when the bond matures, is called or is sold.
• Income from reinvestment of the coupon interest payments (interest-on-interest).

Three yield measures are commonly used by market participants to measure the three
potential sources of return.

9.4.1 Current Yield

The current yield relates the annual coupon interest to the market price.

Annual dollar coupon interest


Current yield =
Price

Example 9.4

The current yield for an 18-year, 6% coupon bond selling for $700.89 per $1,000 par value is:
60
Current yield =
700.89
= 0.0856

The current yield does not account for the return from interest-on-interest.

9.4.2 Yield-to-Maturity

Yield-to-maturity (YTM) is the average rate of return that will be earned on a bond if it is
bought now and held until maturity.

Given its maturity, the principal and the coupon rate, there is a one to one mapping between
the price of a bond and its YTM.
T
Ct F
= P ∑ +
t =1 (1 + YTM ) (1 + YTM )
t T

128
Example 9.5

Consider a 30-year bond with $1,000 face value has an 8% coupon. Suppose the bond sells
for $1,276.76, the YTM:
60
40 1000
1276.76 ∑
= +
( ) ( )
t 60
t =1 1 + YTM 1 + YTM
2 2

Solve for the discount rate, YTM = 6%.

The yield-to-maturity considers the return from interest-on-interest. It assumes that the
coupon interest can be reinvested at YTM.

Suppose we deposit $1,000 for 4 years which earns 10% p.a. After 4 years, we receive:
1000 × (1.1) =
4
1464.1

What if we invest in a coupon bond that matures in 4 years has a par value of $1,000? The
bond pays 10% coupon annually and the market yield is also 10%.

After 4 years, the total cash flow we receive is $1,400. The difference 1464.1 – 1400 = 64.1
is the interest earned from the reinvestment at the rate equal to the YTM.

129
Example 9.6

Consider the T-bills maturing on April 5, 2007, the asked quote is 4.9%. That is, the T-bills
is selling at a discount d = 4.9%. There are n = 90 days to maturity.

The price you actually pay:


=P 10, 000 1 − d × ( n 360 ) 
= 10, 000 1 − 0.049 × ( 90 360 ) 
= 9,877.5

Rate of return for 90 days:


10, 000 − 9,877.5
r=
9,877.5
= 0.0124
= 1.24%

The ask yield:


1.24% × 365 90 =
5.03%

130
9.5 Default Risk

Fixed income securities have promised payoffs of fixed amount at fixed times. Excluding
government bonds, other fixed income securities carry the risk of failing to pay off as
promised.

Default risk refers to the risk that a debt issuer fails to make the promised payments – interest
or principal.

To gauge the default risk, rating agencies, like Moody’s and S&P provide indications of the
likelihood of default by each issuer.

Moody’s S&P
Investment Grade
Gilt-edge Aaa AAA
Very high grade Aa AA
Upper medium grade A A
Lower medium grade Baa BBB
Below Investment Grade
Low grade Ba BB

Investment grade bonds are generally more appropriate for conservative clients. These bonds
typically provide the highest degree of principal and interest payment protection, and they are
generally the least likely to default:
• Moody’s – Aaa to Baa
• S&P – AAA to BBB

Speculative (junk) bonds may be suitable for more aggressive clients willing to accept greater
degrees of credit risk in exchange for significantly higher yields:
• Moody’s – Ba or below
• S&P – BB or below

9.5.1 Traditional Credit Analysis

Traditional credit analysis for corporate bond default or potential downgrade has focused on
the calculation of a series of ratios historically associated with fixed income investments.

131
The Altman Z-score is a metric that gives insights into the likelihood of a firm going
bankrupt in the next 2 years:
EBIT Net sales Market value of equity
Z= 3.3 × + 1× + 0.6 ×
Total assets Total assets Total liabilities
Retained earnings Working capital
+1.4 × + 1.2 ×
Total assets Total assets

The interpretation of Altman Z-score:


• Z > 3.00 – not likely to go bankrupt
• 2.70 < Z < 2.99 – on alert
• 1.80 < Z < 2.70 – likely to go bankrupt within 2 years
• Z < 1.80 – financial catastrophe

9.6 Interest Rate Risk

The fundamental principle of bonds is that the price changes in the opposite direction of the
change in the yield for the bond. An increase (decrease) in the yield decreases (increases) the
present value of its future cash flow, and therefore, the bond’s price.

9.6.1 Price Volatility and Bond Characteristics

The characteristics of a bond that affect its price volatility are:


• Maturity
• Coupon rate

As an illustration, consider the four hypothetical bonds with par value of $1,000 but different
maturity and coupon rate.

Price
Yield 6% / 5 Year 6% / 20 Year 9% / 5 Year 9% / 20 Year
4.00% 1,089.83 1,273.55 1,224.56 1,683.89
5.00% 1,043.76 1,125.51 1,175.04 1,502.06
5.50% 1,021.60 1,060.20 1,151.20 1,421.37
5.90% 1,004.28 1,011.65 1,132.56 1,361.19
6.00% 1,000.00 1,000.00 1,127.95 1,346.72
6.01% 999.57 998.85 1,127.49 1,345.29
6.10% 995.75 988.54 1,123.37 1,332.47
6.50% 978.94 944.48 1,105.28 1,277.61
7.00% 958.42 893.22 1,083.17 1,213.55
8.00% 918.89 802.07 1,040.55 1,098.96

132
An examination of this exhibit reveals that:
• Although the price moves in the opposite direction from the change in required yield, the
percentage price change is not the same for all bonds.
• For small changes in the required yield, the percentage price change for a given bond is
roughly the same, whether the required yield increases or decreases.
• For large changes in required yield, the percentage price change is not the same for an
increase in required yield as it is for a decrease in required yield.
• For a given large change in basis points in the required yield, the percentage price
increase is greater than the percentage price decrease.

Percentage Price Change (Initial Yield = 6.00%)


Yield 6% / 5 Year 6% / 20 Year 9% / 5 Year 9% / 20 Year
4.00% 8.98% 27.36% 8.57% 25.04%
5.00% 4.38% 12.55% 4.17% 11.53%
5.50% 2.16% 6.02% 2.06% 5.54%
5.90% 0.43% 1.17% 0.41% 1.07%
5.99% 0.43% 1.17% 0.41% 1.07%
6.01% -0.04% -0.12% -0.04% -0.11%
6.10% -0.43% -1.15% -0.41% -1.06%
6.50% -2.11% -5.55% -2.01% -5.13%
7.00% -4.16% -10.68% -3.97% -9.89%
8.00% -8.11% -19.79% -7.75% -18.40%

In short,
The impact of maturity:
• The longer the bond’s maturity, the greater the bond’s price sensitivity to changes in
interest rates, holding all other factors constant.

The impact of coupon rate:


• The lower the coupon rate, the greater the bond’s price sensitivity to changes in interest
rates.
• An implication is that zero-coupon bonds have greater price sensitivity to interest rate
changes than same maturity bonds bearing a coupon rate and trading at the same yield.

With the background about the price volatility characteristics of a bond, we can now turn to
an alternate approach to full valuation: the duration/convexity approach.

133
9.6.2 Duration

Recall that:
• When interest rate goes up, bond price drops.
• Long-term bond is more sensitive to interest rate movement.

For zero coupon bond, the maturity is well defined. For coupon bond, however, there are
many payments and each has its own “maturity date”. Therefore, we need a measure for the
average maturity of the bond’s cash flows, or effective maturity.

Macaulay’s Duration
Macaulay’s duration is the average maturity of the portfolio of mini-zeros. Let wt denotes the
weight associated with cash flow made at time t (CFt), then:
CF (1 + y )
t

wt = t
P
where :
y = YTM
P = Bond Price

The weights sums to one because the sum of cash flows discounted at yield to maturity is
equal to the bond price.

The Macaulay’s duration formula is given by:


T
=
D ∑t × w
t =1
t

134
Example 9.7

Suppose we have 8% coupon and zero coupon bond, each with 2 years to maturity. Assume
the YTM is 10% on each bond or 5% semiannually.

CFt (1 + y ) t × wt
t
t CFt wt
0.5 40 38.095 0.0395 0.0197
8% 1.0 40 36.281 0.0376 0.0376
Coupon Bond 1.5 40 34.554 0.0358 0.0537
2.0 1,040 855.611 0.8871 1.7741
∑ 964.540 1.0000 1.8852

0.5 0 0.000 0.0000 0.0000


Zero 1.0 0 0.000 0.0000 0.0000
Coupon Bond 1.5 0 0.000 0.0000 0.0000
2.0 1,000 822.702 1.0000 2.0000
∑ 822.702 1.0000 2.0000

The duration of the zero coupon bond is 2 years.

The duration of the 2-year coupon bond is 1.8852 years < 2 years.

In general, duration is a measure of the approximate sensitivity of a bond’s value to interest


rate changes.

Remember that the price of a bond is the present value of all of its future cash flows.
CF1 CF2 CFT
P= + + +
1 + y (1 + y ) 2
(1 + y )
T

T
CFt
=∑
(1 + y )
t
t =1

Mathematically, to represent the sensitivity of a bond’s value to changes in the yield:


∂P ∂  T CFt 
= ∑ 
∂y ∂y  t =1 (1 + y )t 

1 T  CFt 
= − ∑  t × 
1 + y t =1  (1 + y )t 

135
Dividing by P gives:
T 
∂P − 1 CFt 
∑ t × 
1 + y t =1  (1 + y )t 
∂y
=
P P
1
= − ×D
1+ y

We can switch to discrete changes:


∂P
∂y 1
= − ×D
P 1+ y
∆P
∆y 1
≈− ×D
P 1+ y
∆P ∆y
⇒ = − ×D
P 1+ y

Modified Duration
The modified duration is defined as:
D
D* =
1+ y

With slightly modification,


∆P
= − D* × ∆y
P

The percentage change in bond price is just the product of modified duration and the change
in the bond’s yield to maturity. Modified duration is a natural measure of the bond’s
exposure to changes in interest rates.

136
Example 9.8

The 2-year 8% coupon bond sells at $964.54 at half-year discount rate of 5%. If the discount
rate rises to 5.01% (1 basis point), then the bond price will drop by:
∆P
= − D* × ∆y
P
2 ×1.8852
= − × 0.01%
1 + 0.05
= −0.0359%

The bond price becomes:


$964.54 × (1 − 0.0359% ) =
$964.19

Notice here the discount rate 5% is a semiannual rate. Therefore the corresponding duration
is 2(1.8852) = 3.7704 half year periods.

Effective Duration
The Macaulay’s / modified duration assumed that yield changes do not change the expected
cash flows. For bonds that have embedded options, such as puttable and callable bonds, the
Macaulay’s / modified duration will not correctly approximate the price move for a change in
yield.

The effective duration is a measure in which recognition is given to the fact that yield
changes may change the expected cash flows.

The effective duration of a bond is estimated as follows:


V− − V+
D effective =
2 (V0 )( ∆y )
where :
∆y =change in yield in decimal
V0 = initial price
V− price if yields decline by ∆y
V+ price if yields increase by ∆y

137
Example 9.9

Consider a 9% coupon 20-year option-free bond selling at 1,346.72 to yield 6%. Suppose the
yield changed by 20 basis points, what is the effective duration?

With 20 basis points up and down,


∆y =0.002
V0 = 1,346.72
V− = 1,375.89
V+ = 1,318.44

V− − V+
D effective =
2 (V0 )( ∆y )
1,375.89 − 1,318.44
=
2 (1,346.72 )( 0.002 )
= 10.66

The duration of 10.66 means that the approximate change in price for this bond is 10.66% for
a 100 basis point change in rates.

9.6.3 The Determinants of Duration

1. The duration of a zero coupon bond equals its time to maturity.

2. Holding maturity constant, a bond’s duration is lower when the coupon rate is higher.

138
3. Holding the coupon rate constant, a bond’s duration generally increases with its time to
maturity.
• For bonds selling at par or at a premium, duration always increases with maturity.
• For deep discount bonds, duration can decrease with maturity.

4. Holding other factors constant, the duration of a coupon bond is higher when the bond’s
yield to maturity is lower.

139
5. The duration of a level perpetuity is:
1+ y
y
• This rule makes it clear that maturity and duration can differ substantially.
• For y = 10%, a level perpetuity paying $100 forever will have a duration of 1.1/0.1 =
11 years. But the time to maturity is infinite.

6. The duration of a level annuity is:


1+ y T

(1 + y ) − 1
T
y
where :
T = the no of payments
y = the annuity's yield per payment period
• The duration of a 10-year annual annuity with a yield of 8% is:
1.08 10
− = 4.87 years
0.08 1.0810 − 1

7. The duration of a coupon bond equals:


1 + y (1 + y ) + T ( c − y )

c (1 + y ) − 1 + y
T
y
 
where :
c = coupon rate per payment period
T = the no of payments
y = the annuity's yield per payment period

For coupon bond selling at par (i.e., c = y), the duration simplifies to:
1+ y  1 
1 − 
y  (1 + y )T 

Example 9.10

A 10% coupon bond with 20 years to maturity pays semiannual coupons. The annualized
yield to maturity is 8%. What is its duration?

Note here c = 5%, T = 40 and y = 4%, the outcome will be the half-year period!
1.04 1.04 + 40 ( 0.05 − 0.04 )
− =
19.74
0.04 0.05 1.0440 − 1 + 0.04

19.74 half-year = 9.87 years.

140
9.6.4 Convexity

Consider a 4-year T-note with face value $100 and 7% coupon, selling at $103.5, yielding 6%.
For T-notes, coupons are paid semiannually. Using 6-month intervals, the coupon rate is 3.5%
and the yield is 3%.

t CF PV(CF) t*PV(CF)
1 3.5 3.40 3.40
2 3.5 3.30 6.60
3 3.5 3.20 9.60
4 3.5 3.11 12.44
5 3.5 3.02 15.10
6 3.5 2.93 17.59
7 3.5 2.85 19.92
8 103.5 81.70 653.63
103.50 738.28

Duration in half year periods is:


= =
D 738.28 103.50 7.13

Modified duration is:


D 7.13
=
D* = = 6.92
1 + y 1.03

As the yield changes, the bond price also changes:


Yield Price Using D* Difference
0.040 96.63 96.30 0.33
0.035 100.00 99.90 0.10
0.031 102.79 102.78 0.01
0.030 103.50 - -
0.029 104.23 104.22 0.01
0.025 107.17 107.08 0.08
0.020 110.98 110.70 0.28

For small yield changes, pricing by modified duration is accurate. However, for large yield
changes, pricing by modified duration is in accurate.

141
The reason is that bond price is not a linear function of the yield. For large yield changes, the
effect of curvature (nonlinearity) becomes important.

The mathematical definition of convexity can be derived by applying Taylor series expansion
of a function.

The Taylor series expansion of a function f ( y + h ) in the region of y as h approaches zero is:
f ′ ( y ) h f ′′ ( y ) h 2 f (n) ( y ) hn
f ( y + h=
) f ( y) + + + +
1! 2! n!

Define P ( y ) as the price of a bond at a yield y. Then, writing the price of the bond at a new
yield ( y + ∆y ) using the Taylor series expansion results:
P′ ( y ) ∆y P′′ ( y ) ∆y 2
P ( y +=
∆y ) P ( y ) + +
1! 2!

The price of the bond is:


T
CFt
P ( y) = ∑
t =1 (1 + y )
t

The first derivative with respect to y:


1 T  CFt 
P′ ( y ) =
− ∑ t × 
1 + y t =1  (1 + y )t 

The second derivative is:


1 T  CFt 
P′′ ( y )
= ∑ t ( t + 1) × t 
(1 + y ) (1 + y ) 
2
t =1 

Then the return due to the change in yield is:


142
P ( y + ∆y ) − P ( y ) P′ ( y ) ∆y 1 P′′ ( y ) ∆y 2
= + ×
P ( y) P ( y) 2 P ( y)

1 T  CFt  1 T 
CFt 
∑  t × −
 2 ∑ (
t t + 1) × t 
 (1 + y ) 
1 + y t 1= 1 (1 + y ) t 1  (1 + y ) 
t
=∆P
= × ∆y + × × ∆y 2
P P ( y) 2 P ( y)
1
= − D* × ∆y + × Convexity × ∆y 2
2

Where convexity is the curvature of the bond price as a function of the yield:
 CF 
∑  1 + y (t + t )
T
1 t 2
Convexity
P × (1 + y )  ( )
2 t
t =1 

9.6.5 Immunization

Bank’s assets and liabilities are subject to interest rate risk. Their assets are loans and their
liabilities are the deposits. Both will fluctuate when interest rate moves.

By properly adjusting the maturity of their portfolios, banks can shed their interest rate risk.

Immunization refers to strategies to shield their overall financial status from exposure to
interest rate fluctuations.

For assets with equal yields, the duration of a portfolio is the weighted average of the
durations of the assets comprising the portfolio.

Suppose you have an obligation of $19,487 due in 7 years. At 10% rate, the PV of the
amount is $10,000.

You want to immunize the obligation by holding a portfolio of the 3-year zero coupon bond
and a perpetuity with y = 10% (i.e., paying $100 forever, with a face value of F = $1,000).

Let w be the weight for the zero’s weight and (1 – w) be the perpetuity’s weight. The
duration of the zero is 3 years and the duration of the perpetuity is 1.1/0.1 = 11 years.

The desired duration is 7 years, what is the weight?


w × 3 + (1 − w ) ×11 =7
1
⇒w=
2

143
You therefore invest $5,000 in the zero coupon bond and $5,000 in the perpetuity.

Next year, even if the interest rate does not change, rebalance is necessary!

Because now the zero coupon bond has a duration of 2 years, while the perpetuity’s duration
is still 11 years. The obligation’s duration is 6 years.

Therefore, the new weight is given by:


w × 2 + (1 − w ) ×11 =6
5
⇒w=
9

Since now you have $11,000 after 1 year of investment at 10%, you will invest 5/9*$11,000
= $6,111 in the 2-year zero bond and $11,000 – $6,111 = $4,889 in the perpetuity. You need
to put the entire $500 perpetuity payment in the zero and sell an additional $111 of the
perpetuity.

144
10 Topic 10 – Term Structure of Interest Rates

Recall that from bond pricing, we have assumed that the interest rate is constant over all
future periods. In reality, interest rates vary through time.

The term structure of interest rates refers to the relation between the interest rate and the
maturity or horizon of the investment.

The term structure can be described using the yield curve.

10.1 The Yield Curve

The yield curve is a plot of yield to maturity as a function of time to maturity.

The slope of the yield curve depends on the difference between yields on longer and shorter
maturity bonds.

Upward sloping yield curve:


• Short term interest rates are below long term interest rates.
• Reflect the higher inflation risk premium that investors demand for longer term bonds.

Downward sloping yield curve:


• Long term interest rates are below short term interest rates.
• The market expects interest rate to fall.
• An inverted curve may indicate a worsening economic situation in future.

145
10.1.1 Using the Yield Curve to Price a Bond

Consider a five-year Treasury bonds, the coupon rate is 12%. The cash flow for the bond per
$100 par value for the 10 six-month periods to maturity would be:
Period Cash Flow
1–9 $6
10 $106

$6 $6 $6 $106

1 2 3 10

Because of different cash flow patterns, it is not appropriate to use the same interest rate to
discount all cash flows.

Instead, each cash flow should be discounted at a unique interest rate that is appropriate for
the time period in which the cash flow will be received.
6 6 6 106
=
P + + + +
1 + z1 (1 + z2 ) 2
(1 + z9 ) (1 + z10 )
9 10

But what should be the interest rate for each period?

We can view the bond as 10 zero-coupon instruments: One with a maturity value of $6
maturing six months from now, a second with a maturity value of $6 maturing one year from
now, and so on. The final zero-coupon instrument matures 10 six-month periods from now
has a maturity value of $106.

To determine the value of each zero-coupon instrument, it is necessary to know the yield on a
zero-coupon Treasury with that same maturity. This yield is called the spot rate.

10.1.2 Constructing the Theoretical Spot-Rate Curve

Consider the six-month Treasury in the following:


Maturity Coupon Rate Annualized Yield Price
0.5 0.0000 0.0800 96.15
1.0 0.0000 0.0830 92.19
1.5 0.0850 0.0890 99.45
2.0 0.0900 0.0920 99.64

146
What is the spot rate for a (theoretical) 1.5-year zero coupon Treasury?

The price of a theoretical 1.5-year Treasury should equal the present value of three cash flows
from an actual 1.5-year coupon Treasury.

Using $100 as par, the cash flow is:


t CF
0.5 0.085*$100*0.5 = $4.25
1.0 0.085*$100*0.5 = $4.25
1.5 0.085*$100*0.5 + $100 = $104.25

The present value:


4.25 4.25 104.25
P= + +
(1 + z1 ) (1 + z2 ) (1 + z3 )
1 2 3

Because the 6-month & 1-year spot rate are 8% and 8.3%, and the price of the 1.5-year
coupon Treasury is $99.45, the following relationship must hold:
4.25 4.25 104.25
99.45 = + +
(1.04 ) (1.0415) (1 + z3 )
1 2 3

We can solve for the theoretical 1.5-year spot rate:


4.25 4.25 104.25
99.45 = + +
(1.04 ) (1.0415) (1 + z3 )
1 2 3

104.25
= 4.08654 + 3.91805 +
(1 + z3 )
3

⇒ z3 =
0.04465

Doubling this yield, the theoretical 1.5-year spot rate is 8.93%.

147
10.2 Spot and Forward Interest Rates

The spot rate yt is the annualized interest rate for maturity date t.

Example 10.1

On 1/8/2001, the spot interest rates for different maturities are:

The set of spot interest rates for different dates gives the term structure of spot interest rates,
which refers to the relation between spot rates and their maturities.

The forward rate ft,T is the rate of return for investing that is set today. It is the rate for a
transaction between two future dates, for instance, t and T.

Consider a 2-year investment horizon and the following instruments: a 2-year spot rate y2
(from time 0 to 2), a 1-year spot rate y1 (from time 0 to 1) and a forward rate from year 1 to
year 2, which we denote f1,2.

148
An investor with a 2-year investment horizon has two choices:
1. Invest at the 2-year spot rate y2.
2. Invest at the 1-year spot rate y1 and roll over the deposit with the forward rate f1,2.

Since all rates y1, y2, and f1,2 are known today, the two investments can be compared:
(1 + y2 ) (1 y1 ) (1 + f1,2 )
=+
2

In general, the forward interest rate between time t – 1 and t is:


(1 + yt ) =(1 + yt −1 ) (1 + ft −1,t )
t t −1

or
(1 + y )
t

(1 + ft −1,t ) = t t −1
(1 + yt −1 )

Example 10.2

Suppose the discount bond prices are as follows:


t 1 2 3 4
Price 0.9524 0.8900 0.8278 0.7629
YTM 0.050 0.060 0.065 0.070

A customer would like to have a forward contract to borrow $20 million three years from
now for one year. What is the quote rate for this forward loan?
(1 + y4 ) − 1
4

=f3,4
(1 + y3 )
3

1.0704
= −1
1.0653
= 8.51%

10.3 Theories of the Term Structure

What determines the shape of the term structure?


• The expectation hypothesis
• Liquidity preference

149
10.3.1 The Expectation Hypothesis

The expectation hypothesis states that the forward rate is a prediction of the future spot rate.
Recall that:
(1 + y2 ) (1 y1 ) (1 + f1,2 )
=+
2

We can restate this as:


(1 + y2 )
2
=+ (
(1 y1 ) 1 + E ( r 1,2 ) )
Suppose that y1 is 8%, y2 is 9% and E(r1,2) is 6%, investors with two-year horizons can either:
1. Buy a two-year bond or invest one-year spot and one-year forward. The expected two-
year return is:
(1.09 )
= (1.08
= )(1.1001)
2
1.188

2. Invest for one year and take whatever r1,2 happens to be at time 1. The expected two-year
return is:
(1.08)(1.06 ) = 1.1448

Given the investors’ belief, (1) is more attractive, thus, they will buy the two-year bond.

Therefore, the price of two-year bond will go up, and y2 will drop, therefore, f1,2 decreases.
The adjustment stops when f1,2 and E(r1,2) are approximately equal.

The pure expectation theory tells us:


• An upward sloping yield curve (the forward rates are higher than the current spot rates
and therefore) implies that the market is expecting higher spot rates in the future.
• A downward sloping (inverted) yield curve implies that the market is expecting lower
spot rates in the future.

When f1,2 = E(r1,2), the theory tells us that there would be no buying or selling pressure, and
hence prices and yields would be in equilibrium. When expectations are revised, the yield
curve changes its shape accordingly.

150
10.3.2 Liquidity Preference

In the market, there are short-term and long-term investors.

Short-term investors will be unwilling to hold long-term bonds unless the forward rate
exceeds the expected short interest rate, i.e., f1,2 > E(r1,2).

Long-term investors will be unwilling to hold short bonds unless f1,2 < E(r1,2).

The liquidity preference of the term structure believes that short-term investors dominate the
market so that the forward rate will generally exceed the expected short rate. That is:
f1,2 = E(r1,2) + L
where:
L is the liquidity premium at 2 years horizon

151

Potrebbero piacerti anche