Sei sulla pagina 1di 16

See

discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/228800608

Tacit Knowledge, Innovation and Economic


Geography

Article in Urban Studies May 2002


DOI: 10.1080/00420980220128354

CITATIONS READS

506 461

1 author:

Jeremy Richard Lockwood Howells


University of Southampton
110 PUBLICATIONS 4,944 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Innovation intermediaries and open innovation View project

Innovation intermediaries View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Jeremy Richard Lockwood Howells on 16 June 2014.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Urban Studies, Vol. 39, Nos 5 6, 871 884, 2002

Tacit Knowledge, Innovation and Economic


Geography

Jeremy R. L. Howells
[Paper received and in nal form, November 2001]

Summary. The aim of this paper is to outline the importance of tacit knowledge in the innovation
process and to highlight the way that geographical location not only in uences the relationship
between knowledge and innovative activity, but also affects the way that such interaction
in uences the geography of innovation and economic activity. After a discussion about the nature
of knowledge, the paper explores the relationship that exists between knowledge and geography.
The paper then reviews, using as an analytical lens, the growing body of literature on knowledge
spillovers which af rm the importance of geography. However, the discussion then seeks to
outline some crucial gaps that remain in our conceptualisation of the knowledge spillover and
transfer process. The paper then highlights the neglected role of knowledge demand and
consumption in a spatial context, before concluding with a review of areas for future research.

1. Introduction
The objective of this paper is to outline the how geography in uences knowledge ac-
importance of tacit knowledge in the inno- tivity and how geography in turn may be
vation process and to highlight the way that shaped by such processes.
geographical location not only in uences the The paper begins by exploring the still-
relationship between knowledge and innova- contested de nition and meaning of knowl-
tive activity, but also affects the way that edge, before highlighting why geography is
such interaction in uences the geography of important when considering knowledge pro-
innovation and economic activity. However, cesses and activity. To provide a lens onto
why is the study of knowledge, in particular some of these issues, the paper then critically
tacit knowledge, important to economic ge- examines the growing body of economic
ography? Knowledge is crucial in helping to literature relating to knowledge spillovers.
create innovation which in turn stimulates The discussion then highlights crucial gaps
economic growth and development. It also in our conceptualisation of the knowledge
plays a more speci c role in establishing and spillover and transfer process. The role of the
sustaining the long-term capabilities and per- demand for, and consumption of, knowledge
formance of rms and organisations and in is then explored before the paper concludes
enhancing the success and well-being of in- with some re ections on the nature of tacit
dividuals and communities. It is understand- knowledge in the context of economic geo-
able, therefore, that interest should focus on graphy and areas for future research.
Jeremy R. L. Howells is in Policy Research in Engineering , Science & Technology (PREST), University of Manchester, Oxford Road,
Manchester , M13 9PL, UK. Fax: 0161 273 1123. E-mail: Jeremy.Howells@man.ac.uk .

0042-098 0 Print/1360-063 X On-line/02/05/60871-14 2002 The Editors of Urban Studies


DOI: 10.1080/0042098022012835 4
872 JEREMY R. L. HOWELLS

2. The Meaning and Importance of two broad types of knowledge is linked to


Knowledge the degree of formalisation and the require-
ment of presence in knowledge formation.
Knowledge can be de ned as a dynamic Explicit or codi ed knowledge involves
framework or structure from which infor- know-how that is transmittable in formal,
mation can be stored, processed and under- systematic language and does not require
stood. Knowledge, therefore, has a relational direct experience of the knowledge that is
characteristic, involving a knowing self and being acquired and it can be transferred in
an event or an entity (Plotkin, 1994, p. 40). such formats as a blueprint or operating man-
Knowledge also requires a memoryan en- ual.1 By contrast, tacit knowledge cannot be
during brain state that must exist to allow the communicated in any direct or codi ed way.
bridging of the time-gap between events that Tacit knowledge concerns direct experience
have occurred and any claim to know about that is not codi able via artefacts. Thus, it
them (although memory about events in the represents disembodied know-how that is ac-
past in turn undergoes change and therefore quired via the informal take-up of learned
forms an unconscious, altering form of behaviour and procedures. Indeed, some tacit
knowing; Plotkin, 1994, p. 8). Above all, knowing is associated with learning without
knowing is an active process that is medi- awarenessa process termed as subception
ated, situated, provisional, pragmatic and by Polyani (1966). Tacit knowledge can also
contested (Blackler, 1995). be associated with scienti c intuition (see,
Knowledge is therefore associated with a for example, Ziman, 1978, p. 103) and the
process that involves cognitive structures development of craft knowledge within sci-
which can assimilate information and put it enti c disciplines (Delamont and Atkinson,
into a wider context, allowing actions to be 2001).
undertaken from it. Thus knowledge in turn Elsewhere, Polyani (1962) sums up tacit
combines the process of learning (Polanyi, knowing as an act of indwelling, the pro-
1958, p. 369). The take-up of learned behav- cess of assimilating to ourselves things from
iour and procedures is a critical element outside. However, it also involves, more in-
within knowledge acquisition, both in terms nate values, such as skills. In addition, it is
of capturing and transferring it from the indi- generally accepted that tacit know-how
vidual to the organisational level (Kim, cannot be directly or easily transmitted,
1993) and also in more widely diffusing such as knowledge and task performance are
competence throughout the whole organis- individual and speci c and involve the ac-
ation (Urlich et al., 1993). To be able to quirer making changes to existing behaviour.
innovate, invent and discover, involves using However, the degree of tacitness does vary
existing knowledge, but often also requires (Howells, 1996). Within the range of tacit
generating and acquiring new knowledge and knowledge itself, the less explicit and
this centrally involves learning. Innovation codi ed is the tacit know-how, the more
also involves sharing learned knowledge. dif cult it is for individuals and rms to
This mutual exchange of knowledge and assimilate it (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990,
shared learning means that knowledge is in- p. 135; see also Nelson and Winter, 1982).
trinsically a socially constructed process Learning by doing (Arrow, 1962), learning
(Berger and Luckmann, 1966). by using (Rosenberg, 1982) and learning to
There have been various attempts to ident- learn (Ellis, 1965; Estes, 1970; Argyris and
ify and classify different types of knowledge, Schon, 1978; Stigilitz, 1987) are seen as
but an early and seminal distinction has been critical elements within tacit knowledge ac-
made by Michael Polanyi (1958, 1961, 1962, quisition.
1966, 1967) who distinguished between ex- It has been argued elsewhere (Howells,
plicit (or codi ed) knowledge and tacit 2000) that much of Michael Polanyis work
knowledge. The difference between these on knowledge has been misinterpreted. One
TACIT KNOWLEDGE, INNOVATION AND GEOGRAPHY 873

such example is the crude bi-polar di- Polanyi acknowledges the key negative im-
chotomy that is drawn between tacit and pact that institutional settings and context
codi ed knowledge. This woefully misrepre- could have on knowledge creativity.
sents Polanyis own thinking: Polanyi was at
pains to stress that explicit and tacit knowl- 3. Knowledge and its Geographical Con-
edge were not divided but should be seen text
rather as a continuum between wholly ex- From the de nition and description of
plicit knowledge and a wholly tacit form of knowledge outlined above and its speci c
knowledge. Above all, Polanyi saw that interpretation here, how does geography
explicit knowledge indeed required tacit in uence, and in turn be in uenced by,
knowledge for its interpretation (Polanyi, knowledge and knowledge activity? Basi-
1966, p. 7). This bi-polar distinction has been cally, why is geography important to our
carried through into further analyses which understanding about knowledge? It is argued
suggest that: (a) the codi cation and com- here that there are ve ways in which ge-
modi cation of knowledge are intensifying ography impinges on knowledge and knowl-
and ensuring its more rapid and low-cost edge activity and which has a profound
diffusion; and, (b) you can clearly separate in uence on it. They are
out knowledge transfer into a local-tacit and (1) Knowledge is centred on a knowing self,
global-codi ed matrix. Both Allen (2000) an individual, and this knowing self is
and Roberts (2001) have recently argued in uenced in its human development by
how potentially misleading and spurious its cognitive, social, cultural and econ-
these characterisations are. omic circumstances which in turn are
Michael Polanyi has also been accused of in uenced by its geographical environ-
taking an excessive cognitive approach to his ment; namely, by place.3
de nition of knowledge which tends to bring (2) Associated with this, this development of
the understanding of knowledge down to a an individuals knowledge-set is
personal, atomistic level which makes little in uenced by human interaction, again
allowance for context and institutional set- shaped by place and constrained by dis-
ting. Although Polanyis work does have a tance.
number of dif culties and inconsistencies, (3) The on-going development of an individ-
his cognitive approach is strongly imbued (or uals knowledge-set in turn requires ex-
even dominated) by a wider philosophical ternally acquired information, both in
appreciation of knowledge and, indeed, Gel- codi ed and in more tacit forms (associ-
wick (1977) sees this as his main contribu- ated with human interaction noted
tion to our thinking about knowledge.2 above), which is spatially constrained by
Moreover, Polanyis belief that knowledge distance in terms of scanning costs and
can only be truly personal knowledge, does acquisition barriers.
not diminish the importance of context (4) Although an individuals knowledge-
rather, indeed, it heightens it. Thus, although base depends on externally acquired in-
stressing the individual realm and its cogni- formation, information is also taken up
tive base, Polanyi also acknowledged that through learning, which is by its nature
such cognitive frameworks were strongly situated within a geographical, social and
shaped by external social, organisational and economic context. Much of this learning
economic contexts. Indeed, he was one of the is done jointly with othersnot only in
rst to recognise the communal and institu- educational establishments, but also
tional aspects of knowledge formation (in the through the on-going process of work
context of the role of scienti c communities) which is for the most part site- and
which was subsequently taken up by re- location-speci c (for example, on the
searchers analysing the role of knowledge- factory shop oor or in the research
practitioners and communities. Indeed, laboratory).
874 JEREMY R. L. HOWELLS

(5) Lastly, all the information taken up by an in uences cultural, social and psychological
individual has to be ltered and inter- space through which knowledge is generated
preted. Even highly digestible codi ed and imparted. Hence relational proximity
information requires interpretation using associated with the formation of organisa-
tacit know-how, based on past experi- tional routines and social practices may in-
ence and shaped by geography. deed in many instances be more important
than geographical proximity in a direct sense
Distance, proximity and geography all count (Amin and Cohendat, 1999, 2000), but geo-
here, although the importance of this geogra- graphy has a profound impact on these very
phy will vary depending on what type of routines and practices within organisations
knowledge and the context of its generation (see, for example, Allen, 1977) and therefore
and transfer. For economic geography (and its underlying indirect importance remains.
indeed for corporate management), although Thus, for example, interpersonal distance
individual knowledge generation, transfer which has a strong in uence on task-related
(and consumption; see later) remain import- interaction within organisationsis in turn
ant, the real challenge is how these individ- shaped by physical distance and its con-
ual knowledge-sets interact, con gured and straints.
harnessed within a wider organisational
realm to create a common knowledge context
4. Interpretations of Localised Knowledge:
(Howells, 2000, p. 55).
Knowledge Spillovers
The real confusion and problems set in
when discussing knowledge and geography How has knowledge activity been analysed
when three elements are introduced. The rst and empirically mapped in a geographical
is when rms and organisations are attributed context? Geographers have largely avoided
with having a knowing self and possessing, undertaking large-scale detailed empirical
in a direct sense, knowledge. Trying to analysis of what might be termed the geogra-
attribute a rm as directly possessing knowl- phy of knowledge, although, as will be
edge is misleading. Rather, rmsvia man- shown, this is perhaps not surprising given
agers and employeescan harness the problems of trying to measure knowledge
knowledge through their staff, who organise on the ground and the often heroic assump-
routines which utilise corporate information tions that have been used in undertaking such
and databases and who help to create new analysis. However, economists have had a
knowledge, sharing it with others. The se- growing interest in the geography of knowl-
cond is when knowledge is said to ow edge, in the form of studying spatial dimen-
between individuals (or still less, rms), sions to knowledge spillovers and a
when in fact information is shared and it is burgeoning literature has developed associ-
this sharing which leads to a change in the ated with this eld of research. These studies
knowledge-base of an individual or group of will be reviewed as a way of assessing (how-
individuals. 4 Although extensibly all such in- ever imperfectly): whether geography still
dividuals will obtain the same information, matters in relation to knowledge transfer;
how an individual lters and interprets that and, whether such studies provide insights
information will remain subtly different due that others can usefully take up and develop.
to a persons ability to learn new things Lastly, and not unexpectedly given the com-
based on an individuals former experience. plexity of knowledge processes, such studies
On this basis, the new knowledge based on also help to highlight and yield up major
this information will be different between gaps in our conceptual analysis of knowledge
each person. Thirdly, the impact of geo- and this will form a basis for discussion in
graphical proximity is not always (or indeed the remainder of the paper.
usually) directits in uence is often indi- There has been a growing number of
rect, subtle and varied. Geographical space studies which have sought to analyse the
TACIT KNOWLEDGE, INNOVATION AND GEOGRAPHY 875

presence and signi cance of localised knowl- knowledge ows using patent citations and
edge spillovers. The process whereby knowl- con rm the localisation of knowledge ows.
edge spills over and is appropriated by other These studies have therefore focused on
rms has been largely assumed in traditional the mapping of codi ed knowledge in the
economic literature as an almost costless and form of patents and patent citations, but there
frictionless process. Where knowledge has have been other approaches to analysing
been considered in this tradition, it has been knowledge spillovers. The second approach
treated as a public good that is easily trans- has been to map the movement of people on
ferred between people and organisations. the basis that knowledge moves with them. A
Thus, knowledge was seen as a public good study by Audretsch and Stephan (1996,
because it was seen as being impossible for p. 650) that analysed links between univer-
its creator to prevent it being used by econ- sity scientists and biotechnology rms, found
omic agents who do not pay anything in that spatial proximity matters in shaping
exchange for it (Saviotti, 1998). Knowledge these links, although not on an overwhelming
becomes generally available through various basis. Zucker and Darby (1996) focus on
means including publications, patents and in- star scientists (de ned as highly productive
formal sharing and this non-excludability of individuals who discovered a major scienti c
knowledge is associated with such knowl- breakthrough in biotechnology ) and see their
edge spillover effects. geographical concentrations being linked to
A series of spillover studies have exam- the localisation of new biotech entities
ined the localised relationships in terms of (NBEs; see also Zucker et al., 1997). Alme-
patent activity, industry, labour mobility and dia and Kogut (1997) chart the inter rm
university R&D levels and innovation rates mobility of star patent-holders in the semi-
(see, for example, Jaffe, 1989; Acs et al., conductor industry and similarly conclude
1992; Jaffe et al., 1993; Feldman, 1994, that the transfer of ideas is associated with
1999; Audretsch and Feldman, 1996; Anselin mobility patterns between rms and that this
et al., 1997; Audretsch, 1998). There are a is a further re ection of knowledge spillovers
number of ways in which these knowledge being geographically con ned.
spillover studies can be grouped together. The third stream of analysis has been
Perhaps the most direct are the actual ways based on the assumption that knowledge can
they see knowledge being transferred in the be embodied in goods and that knowledge
spillover process or the relationships in- ows can therefore be mapped, at least at
volved with such a process. the international level, using trade patterns
An early focus of such spillover studies (Feldman, 1999, p. 13).5 Trade is seen as
has been on examining linkages associated being associated with knowledge spillovers;6
with codi ed forms of knowledge. Thus, and both Park (1995) and Coe and Helpman
Jaffes (1989) study analysed corporate (1995) use trade patterns to identify inter-
patent activity at the state level and found national R&D spillovers. Branstetter (1996)
that it was in uenced by university research manages to consider intranational knowledge
spending, after controlling for corporate spillovers on this basis, but there remain
R&D. Similarly, Jaffe et al. (1993) examine severe conceptual and methodological limita-
the localised pattern of patent citations (both tions of mapping knowledge spillovers using
from corporate and university patent cita- this approach. The biggest issue here is the
tions) to suggest that local knowledge notion that knowledge can be embodied in
spillovers exist. Almedia and Kogut (1997) goods.
also used patent citations to study the semi- A further element in these knowledge
conductor industry in the US and found that spillovers has been simply to analyse knowl-
there were clear localisation effects in terms edge-intensive industries and see how con-
of citations. Jaffe and Trajtenberg (1999) centrated they are (and also assess in
take a wider view by studying international performance terms whether they are more
876 JEREMY R. L. HOWELLS

innovative). This is based on the assumption, the assumed spatially unconstrained nature of
and implicit in the knowledge production codi ed knowledge, is that both measures of
function model, that such industries are tacit and codi ed knowledge suggest lo-
concentrated, at least in part, because of calised patterns of interaction. This suggests
knowledge spillovers (but also because that tacit knowledge, situation and locational
knowledge-generating inputs are also context do play a signi cant role in the use
greater). Audretsch and Feldman (1996), fol- and spread of codi ed knowledge. Thus, al-
lowing on from Krugmans (1991) work, though codi ed knowledge may be more
found that industries which were more ubiquitous and accessible, its interpretation
knowledge-intensive (measured by industry and assimilation are still in uenced by ge-
R&D, academic research and skilled labour) ography. Lastly, such studies have shown a
were also more spatially concentrated. This, variety of different attempts at measuring
they observed, reaf rmed the importance and knowledge for locational mapping. Thus,
prevalence of knowledge spillovers particu- they acknowledge that there are a whole
larly in these knowledge-intensive industries, variety of potential parameters involved in
although they acknowledged that this de- measuring knowledge; using one method will
pended on the assumption that knowledge only provide a highly partial view of knowl-
externalities are more prevalent in industries edge activity.
where new economic knowledge plays a However, there are a number of limitations
greater role (Audretsch and Feldman, 1996, associated with these studies. One is the set
p. 639). of assumptions they make about knowledge.
Linked to observing these patterns of con- Much of the analysis concentrates on public
centration has been the attempt to assess their private and private private spillovers, and in
impact on innovative performance and the terms of knowledge as owing in codi ed
output effects of knowledge spillovers. Thus, or embodied formats. Jaffes (1989) original
Feldman (1994) concluded from her study study sees public knowledge, in the form of
that knowledge spillover occurs because geo- university research, being appropriated by
graphical regions with greater amounts of private rms, as underpinning these knowl-
knowledge-generating inputs, measured by edge spillovers. Even where university scien-
using patent counts, produce more inno- tists and their links (such as company
vation. Adams and Jaffe (1996), in their scientists holding university chairs), are stud-
study of the effect of knowledge spillovers ied, their actual contact patterns are not ex-
on the productivity of rm R&D, found that amined. Indeed, most of the metrics imply
spatial proximity did play an important role the imparting of knowledge, but do not actu-
in most instances. In turn, Acs et al. (1999, ally measure it. Above all, real-life investiga-
p. 75) discovered that university R&D cen- tions of micro-level, knowledge transfer and
tres across the US had a statistically sharing are not undertaken. This indeed is
signi cant impact on employment in four acknowledged by Feldman who notes
high-technology sectors.
One limitation is conceptual because
5. Uncovering Localised Knowledge there is no understanding of the way in
Transfer and Sharing which spillovers occur and are realized at
the geographic level (Feldman, 1999,
What can be learned from these knowledge
p. 8).
spillover studies? First, these studies are
valuable in that they do much to suggest the How might these knowledge spillovers ac-
power and in uence of geography in shaping tually occur? The focus of many of the
knowledge interactions. Geography still knowledge spillover studies has been on in-
counts in terms of knowledge activity, a tended and codi ed forms of spillover.7 It is
theme echoed recently by Morgan (2001). important here to recognise that although
Secondly, and perhaps more surprising given many spillover effects may be formally in-
TACIT KNOWLEDGE, INNOVATION AND GEOGRAPHY 877

tended and codi ed in nature, many are not fessional links associated with speci c com-
and remain unintended, tacit and informal in munities of practice (Lave and Wenger,
nature. Intended and codi ed forms of 1991; Barley, 1996) related to membership
spillover have been already enumerated by of professional associations or informal
the studies. They include research contracts groupings (see, for example, Srensen and
and collaborations with other rms (such as Levold, 1992); and unintended leakage by
suppliers and customers), universities and consultants or design practices of infor-
public research laboratories, as well as for- mation picked up from one client and applied
malised institutional links. On an employee to others.
basis, these include industry-funded univer- However, there are key aspects of knowl-
sity chairs, industrial scientists having sec- edge transfer that have also been largely
ondments or part-time placements in excluded or underplayed from spillover
university laboratories, university students analysis. These can be grouped under two
and staff having placements, directorships or broad areas: inter rm and intra rm issues. In
part-time involvement in private rms.8 terms of inter rm issues, these cover: sec-
On a wider institutional level, universities toral differences in spillover patterns; the
may be involved in rm spin-offs and hold role of knowledge intermediaries; and, insti-
venture capital in such operations. Knowl- tutional frameworks. In relation to intra rm
edge intermediaries in the form of specialist issues, these relate to: intra rm knowledge
service design, research or engineering rms transfers; scanning and the cost of acquiring
and consultancy companies also form information; and, the role of learning in
signi cant mechanisms aiding knowledge knowledge formation and transfer. Obviously
transfer. Intended but largely informal some of the issues, such as learning, cover
knowledge spillovers could be in the form of both levels of analysis, but this framework
local or national membership of learned soci- provides an initial entry-point to the dis-
eties or industry associations or regional cussion.
agencies, as well as attendance at confer- In terms of sectoral issues, this is indeed
ences and workshops. Such mechanisms for one area which knowledge spillover studies
knowledge transfer could be partially have actually highlighted as an area for fur-
re ected in more codi ed forms of infor- ther study. Thus, Adams and Jaffe (1996)
mation, such as patent citation. At best, how- found that spatial proximity did play an im-
ever, they describe conduits of knowledge portant role for chemicals R&D productivity,
transfer rather the process of knowledge but for pharmaceutical R&D locational prox-
transfer itself. imity had very much less of effect on R&D
Unintended, informal knowledge ef ciency. Clearly this depends on the nature
spillovers are much harder to measure and of the industries involved. Thus, if one ac-
therefore have been largely neglected in cepts that codi ed knowledge is less geo-
knowledge spillovers studies, although ac- graphically bounded, then industries which
knowledged as being part of the wider are more scienti c in nature and depend
spillover process. These unintended trans- more on codi cation and the transmission of
fers, where the owners of such knowledge information via codi ed knowledge, such
cannot prevent others from making use of it as scienti c papers and patents, may display
(Grossman and Helpman, 1991, pp. 15 16), knowledge spillovers that are less localised
include: departure of key scientists and engi- in nature. The pharmaceutical industry would
neers (including poaching of key staff); in- be an example of just such an industry. By
formal know-how sharing (von Hippel, 1987, contrast, other sectors, such as certain types
1990); unintended signalling of key infor- of engineering, where learning-by-doing and
mation at conferences and workshops; mem- tacit knowledge are more important, would
bership of invisible colleges and research display more localised spillover effects.
schools (Olesko, 1993, p. 16) and pro- In relation to what might be collectively
878 JEREMY R. L. HOWELLS

termed as knowledge intermediaries, there ferring research and knowledge (Blanc and
has been a growing acknowledgement in the Sierra, 1999). Information and knowledge
geographical literature of the importance of obtained in one location can be transferred to
specialist business service providers, consul- another site within the rm, overcoming the
tants, contract research and testing organisa- often information- and knowledge-poor envi-
tions led by studies by MacPherson (1988, ronments its branch plant, for example, may
1991) and Bryson et al. (1993; see also operate (but equally create a technological
Bryson, 1997). Indeed, Wise (1949, p. 63) isolation effect where such a plant has little
highlights the role of factors and merchants information and knowledge interaction with
in the jewellery and gun quarters of Birming- its local environment; Howells, 1985). How-
ham as providing a similar embryonic sup- ever, even intra rm transfers of knowledge
porting role here. The role of specialist are in uenced by geography and do not re-
business service providers or technology- main unproblematic (Oujian and Carne,
related knowledge-intensive business service 1987).
(t-KIBS) rms has been shown by these stud- Another intra rm element here is the role
ies to be an important catalyst for knowledge of scanning and the cost of acquiring infor-
transfer and local innovative performance. mation and knowledge by rms. Firm-level
The importance of institutions in regional contexts are very important in determining
development and economic performance has the nature and success of rms scanning their
been highlighted in a number of studies and external environment (Taylor, 1975). Thus
they too have a speci c role with knowledge the ability of rms to scan their knowledge
transfer (see, for example, Morgan, 1997; environments is strongly in uenced by the
Cooke and Morgan, 1998). Scotland, for ex- size of the rm, its past experiences, its
ample, in the late 17th century had an institu- research and knowledge capacity and indeed
tional scienti c and innovation infrastructure its location. Some rms are highly limited in
which did much to facilitate the ow of ideas their capacity to scan and acquire knowledge
and led to the prominence of Scotland in (linked to the cost of scanning and resources
terms of its scienti c and medical base available to them to do this). Indeed,
(Howells, 1999, p. 68). Thus institutions are Antonelli (2000, p. 539) has recently high-
important in helping to shape the local con- lighted the role of communication costs in
texts for formal and informal knowledge- acquiring technological knowledge and has
sharing and in providing support outlined the different information character-
infrastructures to utilise knowledge within istics of local environments in facilitating
the innovation process. In this way, they information exchange (see also Warf, 1995).
develop the associational capacity of the sys- Lastly, learning has an important interor-
tem (Cooke and Morgan, 1998) with regard ganisational dimension and this is obviously
to knowledge. important in how knowledge can be shared
Associated with the external patterns of amongst rms (Maskell and Malmberg,
knowledge transfer are the internal knowl- 1999), although much key knowledge is gen-
edge transfers within the rm. The ability of erated, learned and shared in situ within the
rms to transfer information knowledge in- rm. Joint learning and learning contexts
ternally across space is, ceteris paribus, within the rm help to create the formation
much easierand especially if it occurs of shared routines between workers which in
within a research or other group. Research by turn helps the sharing of knowledge and the
Allen (1977, p. 241) has con rmed that, for establishment of an organisational memory
example, R&D information ows show far (Ackerman and Halverson, 2000) which
fewer distance decay effects if they involve guides future interpretation of events. Shared
intragroup communication, associated with a routines and patterns of working, and the
clear organisational bond. Multinational and socialisation of this process, help to create
multisite rms are important agents in trans- important environments for learning to take
TACIT KNOWLEDGE, INNOVATION AND GEOGRAPHY 879

place and then help to form common knowl- outcomes (if the research failed or a solution
edge contexts between workers in the rm was not found). Thirdly, knowledge compo-
(Howells, 2000, p. 55). Learning is inti- nents could be purchased through the direct
mately tied up with the generation, but also recruitment of key scientists, designers and
with the sharing of knowledge between indi- engineers or their temporary hire.
viduals within the workplace (Morgan, It should be recognised, however, that
2001). much of the demand for knowledge is in
non-market terms. Thus, for many other
types of knowledge the exchange is via non-
6. Cities and Regions and the Consump-
market mechanismsthrough, for example,
tion of Knowledge
bartering and informal know-how trading
Most of the above analysis has been about (von Hippel, 1987; Knoedler, 1993) or
the transfer and sharing of knowledge; little through reciprocal knowledge-sharing via
has been discussed in relation to its gener- joint-venture operations. Above all, there are
ation and production or in particular its con- no clear market mechanisms which facilitate
sumption. There have been a whole series of the transfer of tacit knowledge directly
geographical studies on the location of R&D (Malecki, 2000, p. 108). For tacit knowledge,
and other related technical activities associ- however, the real problem goes beyond its
ated with what may be termed the pro- demand, back to the initial identi cation and
duction of knowledge (Gertler, 2001). These articulation of the knowledge to be de-
supply issues are important to understand manded. Since tacit knowledge is essentially
since these will obviously in uence the den- by its de nition dif cult to articulate this
sity and pattern of knowledge interaction. makes its demand and consumption such a
However, there has been little or no ac- dif cult process. Indeed, if we accept
knowledgement of the demand for and con- Polanyis concept of tacit knowledge, there
sumption of knowledge.9 Thus virtually all of will be elements of our knowledge-base that
the knowledge spillover studies fail to ac- not only will we nd dif cult to articulate
knowledge the role of knowledge demand but also that we will not know that we even
and consumption and the ability (and cost) of possess. Uncovering and identifying these
rms to absorb such knowledge (Cohen and often-hidden reserves of tacit knowledge and
Levinthal, 1990), re ecting in part no doubt being able to understand and articulate what
the underlying traditional public good no- is required by individuals and rms is an
tion of knowledge and its costless character- important, but neglected, part of knowledge
istics in a number of these studies. On this activity.
basis, demand in a sense need not be con- What role does geography play in these
sidered, since knowledge would somehow demand-side issues in knowledge activity?
permeate to those who needed it. Allan Pred has indeed highlighted the geo-
In terms of markets for knowledge, where graphical aspect of demand in relation to
knowledge is involved, directly or indirectly, patterns of inventive activity;10 and a key
in some transaction process, there are a num- function for major cities and core regions is
ber of mechanisms. First, for codi ed knowl- that they are places where there is strong,
edge where an outcome is already known, a market- and non-market-related, demand for
posteriori, this could be purchased off the knowledge but perhaps more especially
shelf via publications or through license where tacit knowledge can be more readily
agreements. Secondly, a priori, knowledge articulated by others. Thus the articulation
could be obtained through research agree- and consumption of new knowledge may be
ments, or contract R&D (from design and especially important in such places that are
engineering companies, or universities or also likely to have a concentration of early
public research laboratories) although this adopters of knowledge and innovation
would involve some delay and uncertainty of which rms are keen to tap into and which
880 JEREMY R. L. HOWELLS

makes them important theatres of both market from its geographical shackles (ubiq-
and non-market knowledge. uiti cation; Maskell and Malmberg, 1999;
The spatial pattern of knowledge demand see also Nonaka and Takeuchi, 1995a, 1995b)
can also play a more negative role in the needs reinterpretation.
pattern and scale of knowledge spillovers. In this respect, time can provide a crucial
Thus low demand for knowledge in its local dimension in this discussion and is something
originating area may mean that it has to have that seems to get lost in such a dynamic
a much wider knowledge-spillover s foot- process of knowledge formation and sharing.
print or indeed that it gets lost (or undiscov- Thus a study by Feldman (1999, p. 10) sug-
ered; see below) or ignored and thereby gests that codi ed knowledge (using patent
hardly makes a footprint or impact at all. citations) may be localised, but that this local-
Lastly, there is the question of who bene ts isation effect may fade more rapidly (i.e. after
from consumption in terms of R&D produc- the rst year following the patent). However,
tivity and overall competitive performance. even this relatively short period of localisation
Obviously, the absorptive capacity of rms is may be important as, in a number of key
important here when considering who bene ts sectors (such as electronics and optics) there
from knowledge; however, again there is the is such rapid obsolescence that even after this
issue of the transferability of knowledge. Be- short period of localisation, such knowledge
cause many rms in peripheral regions have would hold little value, once it became more
low absorptive capacities, their ability to widespread. At least in the important (and
bene t from external knowledge remains lim- valuable) early stages of its life, therefore,
ited. However, sometimes the knowledge re- codi ed knowledge does not remain costless
mains too complex and tacit to be in its discovery and use, and the social and
absorbedhowever hard a rm tries. Thus, economic context of its use remains crucial.11
some rms remain supremely con dent that Also, its interpretation still requires a tacit
other companies will have no capacity to component (Polanyi, 1958). All aspects of this
absorb or utilise the particular knowledge-sets process remain in uenced by geography.
they hold. Thus, Leonard and Sensiper (1998, Time, or rather timing, can also play a role
p. 121) highlight the con dence that some in determining when knowledge is shared.
rms have in the inability of their rivals to Thus von Hippel (1987) quotes the example
copy company-held tacit knowledge and of aerospace rms who desist from know-how
quote the examples of Chaparral Steel and trading in anticipation of their direct compe-
Oticon actually inviting competitors to visit tition for a particular defence contract, but
and observe their processes, convinced that no resume knowledge exchange once the award
one could imitate their knowledge-base. is made. Time, decay and loss are therefore
crucial elements in knowledge transfer. The
value and utility of knowledge can decay over
7. Localised Knowledge: Re ections and
time, but it can also be lost or simply forgot-
Conclusions
ten. Thus, in studies of knowledge transfer
Knowledge spillover studies have con rmed and sharing, aspects of the spreading of
that knowledge transfer is spatially con- knowledge through spillover are important,
strained, although they provide little, if any, but the decay or paracme of knowledge can be
analysis of the mechanisms of knowledge equally important in in uencing the geogra-
transfer and sharing. What is interesting here phy of innovation and growth.
is that, although many of the studies only used Knowledge spillover studies have therefore
codi ed knowledge as measures in the proved valuable in highlighting that the
knowledge spillover process, they still found knowledge spillovers process remains
a distinct distance-decay effect in knowl- localised and that this holds true, at least
edge transfer. This indicates that the notion initially, for codi ed knowledge. What such
that codifying knowledge somehow frees it studies do not provide are insights into the
TACIT KNOWLEDGE, INNOVATION AND GEOGRAPHY 881

process of knowledge transfer and sharing (Kellerman, 1984). There will undoubtedly be
which remains a black box in terms of our differencessome major, some subtlein
conceptual understanding. Above all, tacit how knowledge is transferred in other coun-
knowledge, although acknowledged, remains tries and these need to be explored.
unexplored. The notion that tacit knowledge
is all about individuals and that charting the Notes
movement of individuals within organisations 1. What Polanyi (1958, pp. 69 131) originally
indicates something about tacit knowledge described as articulated knowing; although
transfer, as some knowledge spillover studies articulation and explicitness are not directly
have done, is valid, but still goes little way equivalent.
towards uncovering the speci cswhat, 2. Including his criticism of scienti c objec-
tivism and logical positivism; thus, in
when and howof such transfers. This is not Polanyis (1958, pp. 27 30) view there can be
to suggest that research into studying the no purely factual statements.
spatial transfer of knowledge will be easy. In 3. An alternative word to in uenced is con-
many cases, surrogate indicators will have to ditioned, but this implies a stronger determin-
be used. However, at present, most work istic avour.
4. I indeed own up to this fault of misconceived
depends on oft-repeated assumptions of what thinking in an earlier paper (Howells, 1996).
is supposed to happen under mainly norma- 5. Indeed, knowledge embodied in capital goods
tive conditions. was the main way that economists studied
Two further issues need highlighting in any knowledge (Saviotti, 1998, p. 843).
discussion of knowledge and geography: one 6. Although some of the studies quoted by Feld-
man (1999) relate more speci cally to R&D
that has already been discussed; one that has rather than knowledge spillovers.
not. The rst relates to the demand for, and 7. Although the word spillover suggests a pro-
consumption of, knowledge and how geogra- cess which is not under some formal control.
phy shapes this process. Analysis so far has 8. The placement of university students and staff
concentrated on supply-side issues and the is formalised in the UK via the Teaching
Company Scheme.
transfer process; very little is known about the 9. The word demand is used in a wide sense
way knowledge is demanded and the con- here and not just in terms of payment for
sumption process and the take-up of knowl- knowledge or some kind of formal arrange-
edge. The second issue is the power ment.
dimension, which is strangely ignored in stud- 10. Thus Pred noted
ies of knowledge.12 As with all relationships, Inventive activity is, to a considerable de-
gree, a function of unique supply-and-
the process of transferring and utilising
demand conditions that prevail in the cities
knowledge is shaped by issues of asym- of an industrializing economy such as that
metries in power, both in relation to socially of the United States between 1860 and the
bonded knowledge (Harvey, 1999) and in early twentieth century. More precisely,
terms of inter rm and interorganisational many technological advances in the late
nineteenth century were reliant upon a
knowledge relationships. This omission needs
demand for inventions (Pred, 1966, p. 9).
to be recti ed if we are fully to understand the 11. As Granovetter (1985, p. 486) stresses, actors
process of knowledge formulation and ex- do not behave or decide as atoms outside a
change. social context.
Lastly, we should be careful about the 12. Particularly given the Foucauldian formulae
that knowledge equals power and power
particularities of geography. Virtually all the
equals knowledge (Foucault, 1980, pp 93
empirical studies of knowledge spillovers 94).
have explored the US context which will be,
not unexpectedly, in uenced by the national References
systems of cities (Thompson, 1972; and the
ACKERMAN, M. S. and HALVERSON, C. A. (2000)
resultant information ows: Pred, 1972) and Reexamining organizational memory, Commu-
regions in North America and the nature and nications of the ACM, 43(1), pp. 58 64.
pattern of infrastructure in place there ACS, Z., AUDRETSCH, D. B. and FELDMAN, M. P.
882 JEREMY R. L. HOWELLS

(1992) Real effects of academic research: com- BARLEY, S. R. (1996) Technicians in the work-
ment, American Economic Review, 82, place: ethnographic evidence for bringing work
pp. 363 367. into organization studies, Administrative
ACS, Z. J., FITZROY , F. R. and SMITH , I. (1998) Science Quarterly, 41, pp. 404 441.
Contrasting U.S. metropolitan systems of inno- BERGER, P. L. and L UCKMANN, T. (1966) The
vation, in: J. DE LA MOTHE and G. PAQUET Social Construction of Reality. Garden City,
(Eds) Regional Systems of Innovation, pp. 111 NY: Doubleday.
124. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers. BLACKLER , F. (1995) Knowledge, knowledge
ACS, Z. J., FITZROY , F. R. and SMITH , I. (1999) work and organisations: an overview and in-
High technology employment, wages and uni- terpretation, Organization Studies, 16,
versity R&D spillovers: evidence from US cit- pp. 1021 1046.
ies, Economics of Innovation and New BLANC, H. and SIERRA, C. (1999) The internation-
Technology, 8, pp. 57 78. alisation of R&D by multinationals: a trade-off
ADAMS, J. D. and JAFFE, A. B. (1996) Bounding between external and internal proximity,
the effects of R&D: an investigation using Cambridge Journal of Economics, 23, pp. 187
matched establishment- rm data, The Rand 206.
Journal of Economics, 94, pp. 700 721. BRANSTETTER , L. (1996) Are knowledge spillovers
ALLEN, J. (2000) Power/economic knowledge: international or intranationa l in scope?
symbolic and spatial formations, in: J. R. Microeconomic evidence from the U.S. and
BRYSON, P. W. DANIELS , N. HENRY and J. Japan. Working Paper W-5800, National
POLLARD (Eds) Knowledge, Space, Economy, Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge,
pp. 15 33. London: Routledge. MA.
ALLEN, T. J. (1977) Managing the Flow of Tech- BRYSON, J. R. (1997) Business service rms, ser-
nology. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. vice space and the management of change,
ALMEDIA, P. and KOGUT, B. (1997) The explo- Entrepreneurship and Regional Development,
ration of technological diversity and the geo- 9, pp. 93 111.
graphic localization of innovation, Small BRYSON, J. R., W OOD , P. and KEEBLE, D. (1993)
Business Economics, 9, pp. 21 31. Business networks, small rm exibility and
AMIN, A. and COHENDAT, P. (1999) Learning and regional development in UK Business services,
adaptation in decentralised business networks, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development,
Environment and Planning D, 17, pp. 87 104. 5, pp. 265 277.
AMIN, A. and COHENDAT, P. (2000) Organisa- COE, D. T. and HELPMAN , E. (1995) International
tional learning and governance through embed- R&D spillovers European Economic Review
ded practices, Journal of Management and 39, pp. 859 887.
Governance, 4, pp. 93 116. COHEN, W. M. and LEVINTHAL , D. A. (1990)
ANSELIN , L. A., VARGA, A. and ACS, Z. J. (1997) Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on
Local geographical spillovers between univer- learning and innovation, Administrative Science
sity research and high technology innovations, Quarterly, 35, pp. 128 152
Journal of Urban Economics, 42, pp. 422 448. COLLINS , H. M. (1985) Changing Order: Replica-
ANTONELLI , C. (2000) Collective knowledge com- tion and Induction in Scienti c Practice. Lon-
munication and innovation: the evidence of don: Sage Publications.
technological districts, Regional Studies, 34, COOKE, P. and MORGAN, K. (1998) The Associa-
pp. 535 547. tional Economy: Firms, Regions and Inno-
ARGYRIS, C. and SCHON, D. A. (1978) Organisa- vation. Oxford: Blackwell.
tional Learning: A Theory of Action Perspec- DELAMONT , S. and ATKINSON, P. (2001) Doctoring
tive. New York: Addison-Wesley. uncertainty: mastering craft knowledge, Social
ARROW, K. (1962) The economic implications of Studies of Science, 31(1), pp. 87 107.
learning by doing, Review of Economic Studies, ELLIS, H. C. (1965) Transfer of Learning. New
29, pp. 155 173. York: Macmillan
AUDRETSCH, D. B. (1998) Agglomeration and the ESTES , W. K. (1970) Learning Theory and Mental
location of innovative activity, Oxford Review Development. New York: Academic Press.
of Economic Policy, 14(2), pp. 18 29. FELDMAN, M. P. (1994) The Geography of Inno-
AUDRETSCH, D. B. and FELDMAN , M. (1996) vation. Dordrecht: Kluwer.
Spillovers and the geography of innovation and FELDMAN, M. P. (1999) The new economics of
production, American Economic Review, 86, innovation spillovers and agglomeration: a
pp. 630 640. review of empirical studies, Economics of
AUDRETSCH, D. B. and STEPHAN, P. E. (1996) Innovation and New Technology, 8, pp. 5 26.
Company scientist locational links: the case of FELLER, I. (1971) The urban location of United
biotechnology, American Economic Review, States inventions, 1860 1910, Explorations in
86, pp. 641 652. Economic History, 43, pp. 232 244.
TACIT KNOWLEDGE, INNOVATION AND GEOGRAPHY 883

FELLER , I. (1973) Determinants of the compo- vation?, in: D. ARCHIBUGI, J. HOWELLS and J.
sition of urban inventions, Economic Geogra- MICHIE (Eds) Innovation Systems in a Global
phy, 49, pp. 47 57. Economy, pp. 67 93. Cambridge: Cambridge
FOUCAULT, M. (1980) Power/Knowledge. Selected University Press.
Interviews and Other Writings. Hemel Hemp- HOWELLS , J. (2000) Knowledge, innovation and
stead: Harvester Wheatsheaf. location, in: J. R. BRYSON, P. W. DANIELS , N.
GELWICK, R. (1977) The Way of Discovery: An HENRY and J. POLLARD (Eds) Knowledge,
Introduction to the Thought of Michael Space, Economy, pp. 50 62. London: Rout-
Polanyi. Oxford: Oxford University Press. ledge.
GERTLER , M. S. (2001) Tacit knowledge and the JAFFE, A. B. (1989) The real effects of academic
economic geography of context or the research, American Economic Review, 79,
unde nable tacitness of being (there). Paper pp. 957 970.
presented to the DRUID Summer Conference, JAFFE, A. B. and T RAJTENBERG, M. (1999) Inter-
Aalborg, September. national knowledge ows; evidence from
GRANOVETTER , M. (1985) Economic action and patent citations, Economics of Innovation and
social structure: the problem of embeddedness, New Technology, 8, pp. 105 136.
American Journal of Sociology, 91 (3), JAFFE, A. B., TRAJTENBERG, M. and HENDERSON,
pp. 481 510. R. (1993) Geographic localization and knowl-
GRANT, E. B. and GREGORY, M. J. (1997) Tacit edge spillovers as evidenced by patent cita-
knowledge, the life cycle and international tions, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108,
manufacturing transfer, Technology Analysis & pp. 577 598.
Strategic Management, 9, pp. 149 61. KELLERMAN , A.. (1984) Telecommunications and
GRILICHES, Z. (1992) The search for R&D the geography of metropolitan areas, Progress
spillovers, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, in Human Geography, 8, pp. 222 246.
94(Supplement), pp. 29 47. KIM , D. H. (1993) The link between individual
GROSSMAN, G. M. and HELPMAN, E. (1991) Inno- and organisational learning, Sloan Management
vation and Growth in the Global Economy. Review, Fall, pp. 37 50.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. KNOEDLER , J. T. (1993) Market structure, indus-
HALL , E. T. (1959) The Silent Language. New trial research, and consumers of innovation:
York: Fawcett. forging backward linkages to research in the
HARRYSON, S. J. (1997) How Canon and Sony turn-of-the-century U.S. steel industry, Busi-
drive product innovation through networking ness History Review, 67, pp. 98 139.
and application-focused R&D, Journal of KRUGMAN, P. (1991) Geography and Trade. Cam-
Product Innovation Management, 14, pp. 288 bridge, MA: MIT Press.
295. LAVE, J. and WENGER , E. (1991) Situated
HARVEY, M. (1999) How the object of knowledge Learning: Legitimate Peripheral Participation.
constrains knowledge of the object: an episte- Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
mological analysis of a social research investi- LAWSON, C. and L ORENZ, E. (1999) Collective
gation, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 23, learning, tacit knowledge and regional innova-
pp. 485 501. tive capacity, Regional Studies, 33, pp. 305
HILLIS, K. (1998) On the margins: the invisibility 317.
of communications in geography, Progress in LEONARD, D. and SENSIPER , S. (1998) The role of
Human Geography, 22, pp. 543 566. tacit knowledge in group innovation, California
HIPPEL, E. VON (1987) Cooperation between ri- Management Review, 40(3), pp. 112 132.
vals: informal know-how trading, Research MACPHERSON, A. D. (1988) New product devel-
Policy, 16, pp. 291 302. opment among small Toronto manufacturers:
HIPPEL, E. VON (1990) The Sources of Innovation. empirical evidence on the role of technical
New York: Oxford University Press. service linkages, Economic Geography, 64,
HIPPEL, E. VON (1994) Sticky information and the pp. 62 75.
locus of problem solving: implications for MACPHERSON, A. (1991) Inter rm information
innovation, Management Science, 40, pp. 429 linkages in an economically disadvantaged
439. region: an empirical perspective from metro-
HOWELLS, J. (1985) Product sophistication, indus- politan Buffalo, Environment and Planning A,
trial organisation and location: the UK pharma- 23, pp. 591 606.
ceutical industry, Environment and Planning A, MALECKI, J. (2000) Creating and sustaining com-
17, pp. 1045 1062. petitiveness: local knowledge and economic ge-
HOWELLS, J. (1996) Tacit knowledge, innovation ography, in: J. R. BRYSON, P. W. DANIELS, N.
and technology transfer, Technology Analysis HENRY and J. POLLARD (Eds) Knowledge,
& Strategic Management, 8, pp. 91 106. Space, Economy, pp. 103 119. London: Rout-
HOWELLS, J. (1999) Regional Systems of Inno- ledge.
884 JEREMY R. L. HOWELLS

MASKELL, P. and MALMBERG, A. (1999) Localised U.S. Systems of Cities, 1790 1840. Cambridge,
learning and industrial competitiveness, Cam- MA: Harvard University Press.
bridge Journal of Economics, 23, pp. 167 185. ROBERTS, J. (2001) The drive to codify: implica-
MORGAN, K. (1997) The learning region, institu- tions for the knowledge-based economy,
tions, innovation and regional renewal, Prometheus, 19, pp. 99 116.
Regional Studies, 31, pp. 491 503. ROSENBERG, N. (1982) Inside the Black Box:
MORGAN, K. (2001) The exaggerated death of Technology and Economics. Cambridge: Cam-
geography: localised learning, innovation and bridge University Press.
uneven development. Paper presented to The SAVIOTTI , P. P. (1998) On the dynamics of appro-
Future of Innovation Studies Conference, priability, of tacit and of codi ed knowledge,
Eindhoven Centre for Innovation Studies, Eind- Research Policy, 26, pp. 843 856.
hoven University of Technology, September. SRENSEN, K. H. and LEVOLD, N. (1992) Tacit
NEFF, P. J. (1995) Cross-cultural research teams networks, heterogeneous engineers and embod-
in a global enterprise, Research Technology ied technology, Science, Technology and Hu-
Management, 38(3), pp. 15 19. man Values, 17, pp. 13 35.
NELSON , R. R. and WINTER, S. G. (1982) An STIGILITZ , J. E. (1987) Learning to learn, localised
Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. learning and technological progress, in: P. DA-
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. SUPTA and P. STONEMAN (Eds) Economic Policy
NONAKA, I and TAKEUCHI, H. (1995a) Theory of and Technological Performance, pp. 125 153.
Organizational Knowledge Creation. Oxford: Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Oxford University Press. STORPER, M. (1995) The resurgence of regional
NONAKA, I and TAKEUCHI, H. (1995b) The Knowl- economies ten years later: the regions as a
edge Creating Company: How Japanese Com- nexus of untraded interdependencies, European
panies Create the Dynamics of Innovation. Urban and Regional Studies, 2, pp. 191 221.
Oxford: Oxford University Press. TAYLOR, M. J. (1975) Organisational growth, spa-
OLESKO , K. M. (1993) Tacit knowledge and tial interaction and location decision-making,
school formation, OSIRIS, 8, pp. 16 29. Regional Studies, 9, pp. 213 223.
OUJIAN, M. I. and CARNE, B. (1987) A study of THOMPSON, W. R. (1972) The national system of
the factors which affect technology transfer in a cities as an object of public policy, Urban
multilocational multibusiness unit corporation, Studies, 9, pp. 99 116.
IEEE Transactions on Engineering Manage- URLICH, D., JICK, T. and GLINOW , M. A. VON
ment, 34, pp. 194 201. (1993) High-impact learning: building and
PARK, W. G. (1995) International R&D spillovers diffusing learning capability, Organisational
and OECD economic growth, Economic Dynamics, 22(2), pp. 52 66.
Inquiry, 33, pp. 571 591. WARF, B. (1995) Telecommunications and the
PLOTKIN, H. (1994) The Nature of Knowledge: changing geographies of knowledge trans-
Concerning Adaptations, Instinct and the mission in the late 20th century, Urban Studies,
Evolution of Intelligence. London: Allen Lane. 32, pp. 361 378.
POLANYI, M. (1958) Personal Knowledge: To- WISE, M. J. (1949) On the jewellery and gun
wards a Post-critical Philosophy. London: quarters of Birmingham, Transactions of the
Routledge & Kegan Paul. Institute of British Geographers, 15, pp. 59 72.
POLANYI, M. (1961) Knowing and being, Mind N. ZIMAN, J. (1978) Reliable Knowledge: An
S., 70, pp. 458 470. Exploration of the Grounds for Belief in
POLANYI, M. (1962) Tacit knowing, Review of Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Modern Physics, 34, pp. 601 616. Press.
POLANYI, M. (1966) The logic of tacit inference, ZUCKER, L. G. and DARBY, M. R. (1996) Star
Philosophy, 41, pp. 1 18. scientists and institutional transformation: pat-
POLANYI, M. (1967) The Tacit Dimension. Lon- terns of invention and innovation in the forma-
don: Routledge and Kegan Paul. tion of the biotechnology industry, Proceedings
PRED, A. R. (1966) The Spatial Dynamics of U.S. of the National Academy of Science,
Urban-industrial Growth, 1800 1914: Inter- 93(November), pp. 12709 12716.
pretive and Theoretical Essays. Cambridge, ZUCKER, L. G., DARBY, M. R. and BREWER, M. B.
MA: MIT Press. (1997) Intellectual human capital and the birth
PRED, A. R. (1972) Information Circulation and of U.S. biotechnology enterprises, American
the Process of Urban-industrial Growth: The Economic Review, 87, pp. 290 306.
View publication stats

Potrebbero piacerti anche