Sei sulla pagina 1di 12

Psychological Inquiry Copyright 

C 2007 by
2007, Vol. 18, No. 1, 60–71 Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Inc.

REPLY

Psychology and American Corporate Capitalism:


Further Reflections and Future Directions
Tim Kasser
Knox College, Galesburg, Illinois
Allen D. Kanner
Wright Institute, Berkeley, California
Steve Cohn
Knox College, Galesburg, Illinois
Richard M. Ryan
University of Rochester, Rochester, New York

We want to begin by thanking the nine commenta- cant strides in understanding broad social forces such
tors for taking the time and energy to read our target as individualism/collectivism, religiosity, racism, and
article on American Corporate Capitalism (ACC) and the like. In contrast, significantly less effort has been
for formulating such stimulating responses. We also expended exploring similar dynamics regarding eco-
want to thank them for, on the whole, approaching our nomic systems, despite the fact that economic systems
article in the spirit in which it was intended: an attempt share with other social systems the twin pillars of ide-
to begin to formulate an understanding of how one of ologies (which are internalized by members of culture)
the most dominant features of contemporary American and institutions (i.e., government practices, laws, etc.)
life (and, we believe, global life) may be detrimentally that help to ensure the efficient and continued operation
affecting values, goals, quality of life, social function- of that social system.
ing, and the Earth’s ecology. As we noted in our tar- Several of the commentators present further evi-
get article, it is difficult to write about a politically dence supportive of our claim that ACC is in fact like
and emotionally charged topic such as capitalism in other social systems in that it has an ideology that orga-
a scientific manner—certainly we struggled with this nizes institutions. For example, Dittmar (2007) clearly
challenge as we went through multiple drafts of our shows how certain features of ACC and its cousin con-
target article. We hope that this interchange encour- sumerism work their way into the identities of people
ages more psychologists to begin to explore this topic living under such systems, directing their behavior in
in a rigorous theoretical and scientific manner. important ways and affecting their own subjective ex-
The commentators raise quite a number of interest- periences. Further, if Locke’s commentary is treated as
ing issues, and we hope that readers of Psychological a case study, it is clear that his exposition of Ayn Rand’s
Inquiry will understand that any reply which addressed objectivist philosophy represents the use of a particular
each and every point raised would end up appearing de- set of ideological beliefs concerning human nature and
fensive, ponderous, and disconnected. We have there- social values to support a capitalistic worldview.
fore decided to organize this response around the target Another piece of evidence supporting our claim
article’s major sections and themes, thereby retaining that ACC has an ideology comes from the interesting
some of its structure. Hopefully, such a strategy will history of Adam Smith’s thought alluded to by
make this reply more coherent, integrated and, ulti- several commentators. Recall that Smith’s place as
mately, useful. the grandfather of capitalism rests in part on his
suggestion that the pursuit of self-interest through
General Principles Regarding competition provides the best means of ensuring
American Corporate Capitalism economic growth, happiness, and the good of the
community. As Gowdy, Whybrow, and Myers all
Ideology and Institutions
mention in their commentaries, and as we alluded to
We noted at the outset of our target article that in in footnote 3 of our target article, Smith (1776/1976)
the last two decades psychologists have made signifi- also held that community values, love, empathy,
AUTHORS’ RESPONSE

and neighborliness were necessary to hold unbridled Table 1 of our target article, it is reasonably clear that
self-interest and competition in check. Although we ACC has not yet captured the attention of many psy-
will discuss this issue in more detail below, for now chologists. Understanding the ideology of ACC opens
we want to note that many proponents of ACC happily the door to using extant theorizing and methodologies
cite the portions of Smith’s thought that celebrate on constructs related to other ideologies in order to
self-interest and competition but rarely discuss the study topics related to ACC. It also allows us to look at
other, more pro-social features of his philosophy. Such variations in people’s internalization of ACC’s ideol-
selectivity commonly occurs among the followers ogy as a predictor of behavior and well-being. This is
of ideologies. For example, contemporary Christian particularly important as polls show that an increasing
ideology and practice often de-emphasizes, and indeed proportion of American youth see “getting rich” as a
contradicts, the portions of Jesus’s philosophy that central life value (Pew Research Center, 2007).
insisted upon having few possessions and resolving Third, as described above, ideologies influence in-
conflicts through non-violent means. Our point is that stitutions and the actions of these institutions are par-
when ideologies are internalized, followers typically tially responsible for some of the costs we enumerated
pick and choose which parts they will emphasize and in our target article and upon which some commenta-
which parts they will ignore. The same apparently has tors expanded. Thus, if psychologists are interested in
occurred in the history of capitalist thought. ameliorating the costs of ACC they will need to do so,
Finally, two commentators show that ACC’s ide- in part, through considering the actions of certain in-
ology and institutions are indeed connected. Gowdy stitutions. Recognizing the influence of ideology will
(this issue), for example, describes how the neo-liberal make it easier to think about how to modify institutions
conception of humans as self-interested and rational that support ACC and how to design new institutions
(i.e., an ideology) has led to the development of cer- that facilitate the outcomes ignored or discouraged by
tain types of public policies (i.e., institutions) designed ACC.
to enhance aims consistent with laissez-faire capital-
ism (i.e., ideology). S. H. Schwartz (2007) also empir-
Characterizing ACC and its Effects
ically demonstrates the connections between ideology
and institutions by reporting a consistent pattern of cor- We were gratified to see that the commentators had
relations between the values of nations (i.e., ideology) relatively little quarrel with our attempt to provide an
and the extent to which their economic systems are “objective set of definitions” of ACC—even Locke
organized in a strategic vs. competitive manner (i.e., conceded that we were “almost right.” Three main
institutions). issues were raised, however, to which we would like to
In sum, we believe these types of evidence along respond.
with what we presented in our target article support Advertising. Locke (2007) claims that advertising
the notion that ACC is similar to other social systems does not spread a materialistic mindset, but instead
in that it has a clear ideology that helps to organize “gives people product information, if they want it; if
institutions. This is important to know for at least three they do not want it, they are free to ignore it.” An
reasons. hour or two spent watching advertisements or a second
First, some of ACC’s proponents claim that the sys- read of Dittmar’s commentary should make it clear that
tem actually does not rest on an ideology but rather precious few ads present only “product information”;
reflects natural law or a pure expression of human na- instead, the vast majority attempt to associate a prod-
ture. As Heilbroner (1985) pointed out, this supplies “a uct with a particular lifestyle or potential outcomes
kind of moral pardon” (p. 116) for capitalist, accumu- such as love, status, sex, and the like. Further, unless
lative activities. Such a claim reminds us of monarchs mandated by laws such as those that compel pharma-
who insisted on “the divine right of kings” as a ratio- ceutical companies to mention the negative side effects
nale for quashing challenges to the manner in which of their drugs, it is rare that advertisers publicize the
they ruled, and of whites and males who explained the downside or limits of their products. Thus, the infor-
lower status of non-whites and females by pointing to mation presented in advertisements tends to be highly
the latter’s supposedly innate inferiorities. Thus, the biased towards the positive end.
claim that ACC has no ideology can be understood as We also have difficulty understanding how Locke’s
the portion of its ideology that serves to support the claim about the purity of product information in ad-
social system by claiming that the system is “natural vertising is consistent with the ideology of ACC. As
and good.” Sorting out whether such claims are propa- we understand it, a corporation should use any means
ganda or actuality is, we believe, vitally important for at its disposal to influence the spending of potential
the sole reason of truth-value. consumers, as it is in the corporation’s self-interest to
A second reason it is important to demonstrate that do so. Clearly, limiting advertisements to mere mes-
ACC has an ideology concerns its future as a psy- sages about “product information” would not be as
chological construct. Given the results presented in effective as more sophisticated marketing; indeed, this
61
KASSER, KANNER, COHN, RYAN

basic idea was recognized by the early 20th century nomic growth are a key feature of ACC. Further, we
psychologists who invented the science of advertising agree with the ideas expressed so well by Easterlin and
(Buckley, 1982; Kuna, 1976, 1979). Further, within others that hedonic adaptation and social comparison
ACC’s framework, it would be irrational for corpora- are partially responsible for the well-documented fail-
tions to spend the billions of dollars they do on ad- ure of further economic growth to provide enhanced
vertising if it was not having a financially beneficial happiness in most economically developed nations.
outcome; at the least, corporations that spent their cap- However, it is not obvious to us exactly how and why
ital on such ineffective messages would ultimately, by economic growth, in and of itself, would inevitably
the rules of capitalism, make less profit and eventually cause some of the value conflicts that we described
be replaced by other corporations that pursued more and documented, and that S. Schwartz (2007) empiri-
effective and seductive strategies. cally supported in his commentary. For example, why
Locke also holds that the human potential to be con- would economic growth inherently interfere with good
scious and rational mitigates any untoward effects of relationships and community feeling? Why would it
advertising. Certainly we agree with this suggestion, automatically undermine certain sorts of autonomy?
as substantial research documents that persuasive mes- Further, we can imagine an economy that sets lim-
sages are often most effective when people pay less at- its on growth, yet still encourages materialism, self-
tention to them (Petty and Cacioppo, 1986). However, interest, and competition in regards to the more limited
we disagree with Locke’s insistence that consumers resources now available to people.
who fail to use their rational faculties are responsible In contrast with Easterlin we believe that the ideol-
for the problems associated with advertising; such a ogy of ACC, which fetishizes unbridled, “winner-take
claim, from our viewpoint, “blames the victim.” For all” economic growth, seeps into the culture and creates
example, it is impossible to reconcile Locke’s claim a variety of beliefs, institutions, practices, and behav-
with the recent spate of “stealth marketing” that in- iors that discourage some and encourage other values.
tentionally hides from people the fact that they are Essentially our differences with Easterlin seem to re-
being marketed to; under such circumstances it is ex- volve around whether the costs of ACC are the “nat-
tremely difficult, if not impossible, to use one’s con- ural” result of the “natural” march of technology and
scious awareness and rational choice to ward off undue economic growth or whether they are the “cultured”
influence. Further, we would note that Locke’s asser- result of a particular social system. Because ACC has
tion that “no one but the most mentally retarded and spread so widely, it is tempting to naturalize its out-
mindlessly gullible individuals will have his choices comes, just as in the 19th and 20th centuries it was
‘determined’ by advertising” (p. 39) is actually a pow- tempting to naturalize traditional gender roles because
erful (though rather insensitively worded) argument of their apparent pervasiveness.
against advertising to children, whose cognitive ability But consider, for example, Braverman’s (1974) clas-
to understand the persuasive intent behind most com- sic analysis of how the evolution of workplace tech-
mercial messages is relatively under-developed (APA nology influenced the adversarial character of labor-
Task Force on Advertising and Children, 2004). management relations in ACC. Braverman showed
how the emergence of alienated work environments in
Economic Growth ACC economies, and the psychological implications
Easterlin (2007) is dubious about our claim that of those environments, reflected the social structure
the costs of ACC are due to the ideology and institu- of ACC economies rather than the inevitable unfold-
tions of capitalism, holding instead that they are the ing of technology. For example, Braverman demon-
unintended but inevitable consequences of economic strated how the conflict of interest between employer
growth. Specifically, Easterlin implies that there are and employee in capitalist economies was exacerbated
three main reasons so many nation-states prioritize eco- in ACC economies by ideological beliefs that firms
nomic growth in setting public policy and so many peo- had no moral or social obligations to their employ-
ple have taken on the bundle of values relevant to ACC. ees. This combination promoted the development of
First, modern technology creates new economic oppor- technologies that maximized employer authority in
tunities and requires particular kinds of social institu- the workplace, such as the assembly line, routinized
tions to take advantage of these opportunities. Second, white-collar work, and other Taylorist work practices.
human nature prioritizes the acquisition of economic Later research has similarly demonstrated how parent-
goods and the political power that automatically ac- ing practices (Kohn, 1977) and educational environ-
companies them. And third, people adapt to their eco- ments (Bowles and Gintis’s, 1976) are influenced by
nomic goods and levels of wealth, compare themselves the need to prepare students to fit into the kinds of work
to people who have more wealth and goods, and thus environments characteristic of ACC practices.
become dissatisfied and desire more wealth goods. Another interesting example of how the culture
Certainly we agree with aspects of Easterlin’s view- created by ACC, rather than economic growth per
point. Our target article noted that pressures for eco- se, is partly responsible for the costs we enumerated
62
AUTHORS’ RESPONSE

can be seen in current developments in Thailand, Table 1. Zero-order and Partial Correlations of Schwartz’s
where one of us (Cohn) happens to be on sabbatical. (this issue) Cultural and Individual Values with Hall and
At first glance, Thailand appears to be another Gengrich’s (2004) Strategic vs. Competitive Capitalism
“Orange County” poster child (to borrow Easterlin’s Index and Average Annual GDP Growth in the 1990s
memorable imagery) for the universal logic and GDP
experience of economic growth. The last 40 years Capitalism Growth
have witnessed the prioritizing of economic growth Strategic vs. Average Index controlling
by most sections of Thai society and the emergence Competitive Annual controlling for
Capitalism GDP for GDP Capitalism
of modern consumer lifestyles. But far from being a Value Type Index Growth Growth Index
“natural” or inevitable outcome of growth, it is clear
that historically determined distributions of power Cultural Values
as well as ideological and institutional influences Harmony .83∗∗ −.61∗∗ .77∗∗ −.44+
have played an enormous role in the reconstruction Mastery −.52∗ .43+ −.39+ .25
Egalitarianism .33 −.14 .31 .02
of Thai society. For example, forced privatization Hierarchy −.60∗∗ .11 −.63∗∗ −.25
in the countryside has often crippled the option Intellectual .56∗ −.63∗∗ .38 −.51∗
of community-coordinated rural economic growth. Autonomy
Villagers have been denied access to forests and other Embeddedness −.45∗ .49∗ −.28 .36
previously held common property around their farms Individual Values
Power −.35 .06 −.36 −.12
and homes. Investment has been heavily concentrated Achievement −.73∗∗ .52∗ −.64∗∗ .29
in urban areas. And organizing efforts among laborers Universalism .66∗∗ −.52∗ .55∗ −.31
and independent farmers for alternative economic Benevolence .26 −.02 .29 .13
development paths have been violently repressed Self-direction .64∗∗ −.57∗∗ .51∗ −.40+
(Bello, Cunningham, & Po, 1998; Phatharathana- Conformity −.44+ .40+ −.31 .24
nunth, 2006; Ungpakorn, 2003). Although there seems Note: ∗∗ = p < .01; ∗ = p < .05; + = p < .10. High scores on
to have been a yearning for development options these variables indicate a more strategic and less competitive (i.e.,
that would preserve the reciprocity and community ACC) economic organization, higher economic growth, and stronger
oriented culture of the village, these desires have not concern for each value domain.
been actualized (Nartsupha, 1999). These problems,
while involving economic growth, clearly reflect
institutionalized practices of the Thai government and found that nations with a more American (i.e., com-
a particular ideology about how growth should occur. petitive) form of capitalism had higher GDP growth
Given the competing (but not incommensurate) rates in the 1990s (r = −.47, p < .05; recall that high
hypotheses put forward in our target article and by scores on the capitalism index indicate more strategic
Easterlin, we set out to empirically examine these and less competitive forms of capitalism). Next, we
ideas. S. Schwartz (2007) demonstrated that Hall and compared how the six cultural and six individual
Gingerich’s (2004) index of strategic vs. competitive values that S. Schwartz (2007) examined relate to
capitalism related to specific cultural and individual the capitalism index and to GDP growth rates; these
values in a manner largely consistent with predictions results are reported in the second and third columns
derived from our target article. We reasoned that if of Table 1. As can be seen there, the capitalism index
Easterlin’s hypothesis is correct, then a nation’s eco- was significantly correlated with eight of Schwartz’s
nomic growth rate should be associated with these values and marginally correlated with another one;
values in a similar manner, i.e., nations with high GDP growth was significantly correlated with six of
economic growth rates should place high value on Schwartz’s values and marginally correlated with two
the materialistic ACC goals and less value on the others. Generally speaking, the correlations were of
goals representing community, family, and personal approximately the same magnitude, although they
growth/freedom. Further, we reasoned that Easter- tended to be slightly larger for the capitalism index
lin’s hypothesis suggests that controlling for economic than for the GDP growth measure.
growth rates should substantially diminish the size of Next we examined the relative independence of the
the association between the strategic vs. competitive two variables in the prediction of S. Schwartz’s val-
capitalism measure and these values. ues. That is, were associations still significant after
We therefore obtained the average annual growth controlling for the other measure? Partial correlations
in real GDP for 1990–1999 (The Economist, 2001) between the values and the capitalism index controlling
for each of the 20 countries on which S. Schwartz pro- for economic growth showed that five of the correla-
vided data on the Hall and Gingerich (2004) index and tions remained significant and one became marginal.
on values relevant to his model. Although S. Schwartz In contrast, partial correlations between the values and
reported no association between this capitalism index GDP growth rates, controlling for the capitalism index,
and Gross Domestic Product per capita (r = .04), we showed that only one correlation remained significant
63
KASSER, KANNER, COHN, RYAN

and two became marginal (see columns 4 and 5 of ACC’s values and less frequently to the opposing
Table 1). set of aims. As a consequence, values and goals for
These results provide mixed support for Easterlin’s self-direction/self-acceptance, benevolence/affiliation,
hypothesis but reasonably strong support for the ideas and universalism/community feeling could theoreti-
we presented in our target article. That is, while cul- cally die out.
tures that are more similar in ideology and practice A slightly (but only slightly) more optimistic view
to ACC tended to have higher economic growth dur- about human functioning amidst ACC’s ideology and
ing the period examined, this economic growth did not institutions could be derived from humanistic and some
fully explain the tendency of such cultures to be more dynamically oriented perspectives. These viewpoints
oriented towards materialistic, self-enhancing values, typically hold that the social surround either facili-
and less oriented towards values that are focused on tates or discourages the pursuit of basic psychological
community, close interpersonal relationships, and self- needs and growth strivings. As such, these perspec-
direction/autonomy. Of course, these data are limited in tives would predict that the ultimate, innate source of
multiple ways. First, they explore only a small portion desires for personal growth, affiliation, and connec-
of the possible outcomes of interest; it may be that eco- tion with community would remain present in humans,
nomic growth is particularly important for other more but to the extent ACC makes it difficult for people to
objective indices relevant to our hypotheses. Second, successfully pursue these aims, tension and instability
we only explored relatively recent data, i.e., from the might result, catalyzing possible change. As seen in
1990s; it may be that examination of longer time spans B. Schwartz’s commentary, the social-constructionist
would reveal different results. Further, the hypotheses viewpoint seems to make somewhat different predic-
were tested in small number of highly economically de- tions about the costs of living under ACC. We hope
veloped nations; it may be that different results obtain that researchers from both theoretical traditions will
in nations less far along the road of capitalistic devel- take up the challenge of examining how the ideology
opment. Thus, we acknowledge that more research is and institutions of ACC play into these age-old ques-
needed to adjudicate between Easterlin’s claims and tions about the relative influence of nature and nurture
those made in our target article. Hopefully this discus- in explaining different aspects of human behavior.
sion and our initial empirical tests will stimulate work
in this area.
Some Costs of ACC, Revisited

In this section, we revisit each of the three sets of


Does ACC Discourage, Conflict
aims our target article proposed were undermined and
with, or Destroy Values?
discouraged by the goals and values of ACC, replying
One of the central points of our target article was that to and expanding upon points made by the commenta-
“when the values and goals necessary for the smooth tors.
functioning of ACC become increasingly central to
individuals and to institutions, the result is a corre-
Universalism/Community Feeling
sponding conflict with three other aims: concern for the
broader community and the world; close, intimate re- Supportive Behavioral Data. Henrich (2007) noted
lationships; and feeling worthy and autonomous” (this that his cross-cultural work, which uses laboratory-
issue, p. 6, emphasis added). B. Schwartz (2007) seems based, behavioral measures of generosity, found that
to agree with this basic point but suggests an even Americans are among the most generous individuals
stronger position: The values and goals of ACC may he has sampled. He thus suggests that although ACC’s
actually destroy these three types of values. With his rhetoric may be opposed to such pro-social concerns,
characteristic flair, B. Schwartz provided a number of in actual fact it may not impact behavior. Said differ-
examples, both empirical and anecdotal, for this dire ently, Henrich points to the well-known gap between
prediction. attitudes and behavior, and proposes that while our hy-
Extrapolating from this claim and his other writ- potheses may hold for beliefs such as values and goals,
ings, it seems to us that B. Schwartz has a rather they may not hold for specific, objective outcomes.
post-modern, social-constructionist, and tabula rasa While we agree that it is necessary to conduct further
view of humans. Such a viewpoint logically leads research to help discern when the ideology of ACC
to the conclusion that the values and goals that con- undermines community-oriented behavior and when it
flict with ACC’s ideology and institutions would be does not, we feel data exist that do indeed support our
at greater risk for extinction to the extent that ACC claim that ACC’s ideology influences actual behavior.
gains control of more aspects of social and economic For example, some of the studies we cited in our
life, as succeeding generations would be exposed more target article assessed self-reports of actual social and
frequently to socializing influences that emphasize environmental behavior (Brown and Kasser, 2005;
64
AUTHORS’ RESPONSE

Kasser and Ryan, 1993; McHoskey, 1999). Further, has long pointed towards the difficulties of simulta-
two of the studies we cited in our target article directly neously pursuing self-interest and universalism val-
examined behavioral outcomes associated with the val- ues, and recent cross-cultural evidence presented by
ues of ACC: Sheldon and McGregor’s (2000) study of Grouzet et al. (2005) has demonstrated via circular
resource use and Sheldon, Sheldon, and Osbaldiston’s stochastic modeling analyses that the values of finan-
(2000) work on the Prisoner’s Dilemma Game. Finally, cial success and community feeling are almost di-
in the interim between submitting our target article to ametrically opposed, laying 192 degrees from each
the commentators and writing this reply, Vohs, Mead, other (perfect opposition being of course 180 degrees).
and Goode (2006) presented four studies demonstrat- The fascinating studies conducted by Frey and Stutzer
ing that when the idea of money and wealth (a promi- (2002) referred to by B. Schwartz in his commentary
nent value of ACC) is highly accessible, people are less and the studies of Vohs et al. (2006) described above
likely to engage in pro-social behavior. Specifically, in provide further evidence for how the activation of fi-
comparison to subjects primed with neutral concepts, nancially relevant cognitions “crowds out” community
subjects primed with ideas of wealth and money vol- and universalism aims. Such work suggests that so-
unteered less of their time to help an experimenter cial cognitive methods could be applied to understand
code data (Experiment 3), spent less time helping a the associative networks that lead these two values to
confused confederate (Experiment 4), helped pick up be in conflict. Further, it would be extremely informa-
fewer pencils dropped by a confederate (Experiment tive to study the kinds of businesspeople described by
5), and donated less money to a University Student Myers (2007) in order to understand how they man-
Fund (Experiment 6). age the frequent conflict between these aims. Are such
Such behavioral evidence suggests Henrich’s data businesspeople actually motivated primarily by tran-
yielded a different pattern of findings than what we scendent aims, as Myers suggests, thus alleviating the
proposed in our target article because of the predictor conflict? Do particular personality or situational factors
variable, not the dependent variable (i.e., behavioral help them cope, resolve, or live with this conflict? And
vs. attitudinal). That is, whereas Henrich examined when their transcendent aims come in serious conflict
how citizenship in one or another nation related to with profit making, is Bakan (2004) correct in his as-
generosity, the studies just described either measured sertion that even the most well-intentioned individuals
how much the materialistic values of ACC were in- will bow to the bottom line?
ternalized or manipulated how much such values were The second explanation for ACC’s relative rejection
cognitively accessible. These latter operationalizations of Smith’s neighborly values concerns the fact that na-
are, we think, more valid ways of assessing the influ- tional and inter-national institutions support the values
ence of ACC than is “being an American,” as many of financial progress and discourage economic deci-
other factors compose this particular identity status, sions based on universalism/community feeling values.
some of which may promote generosity. What seems As we noted in our target article, and as B. Schwartz
clear from the studies just reviewed is that the val- (2007) also emphasized, US laws designed to promote
ues of ACC were likely working against any generous economic growth and to protect the “rights” of share-
behavior emitted by Henrich’s American subjects. Fu- holders compel the Boards and the CEOs of publicly-
ture studies would do well to examine a variety of held corporations to pursue profit at all costs and to
cultural beliefs, including the internalization of ACC’s ignore concerns for the greater good of the community
values, in attempting to understand cultural differences in their decision-making process; similar laws increas-
in community-oriented behaviors, or any other type of ingly govern international economic treaties (such as
behavior, for that matter. NAFTA, etc.). Not all nations have such laws, and fam-
Where did Smith’s Moral Virtues Go? The commen- ily businesses of the type described by Myers (2007)
taries of Gowdy, Whybrow, B. Schwartz, and Myers all do have the opportunity to insert their own (sometimes
raise the question of how Adam Smith’s philosophy of transcendent) values into their business decisions in a
capitalism evolved in the case of ACC to become a way that is just not as much of an option, legally, for
one-sided ideology emphasizing competition and self- limited liability corporations owned by share-holders.
interest at the expense of compassion, empathy, and Again, it would be fascinating to better understand how
neighborliness. In particular, these commentators won- such situational constraints faced by politicians and
der about the processes that removed the moral checks businesspeople in the real world affect their behavior
that Smith held to be an important and essential part in interpersonal interactions; social-dilemma games in
of a free market capitalistic system. We see three com- the laboratory may also give insight into this dynamic.
plementary approaches to this issue. The third approach to understanding how Smith’s
The first, most obvious explanation for why ACC neighborly values have been de-emphasized relates to
undermines community and universalism values con- what political economist Princen (2002) calls “dis-
cerns the inherent incommensurability of the two aims. tancing.” When consumers are unable to see the up-
As we noted in our target article, S. Schwartz (1992) stream production costs (e.g., sweatshop labor) and
65
KASSER, KANNER, COHN, RYAN

downstream environmental costs (e.g., pollution when people who have highly internalized the aims of ACC
an item is discarded) of goods they purchase, they do not have friends and fall in love. Surely they do,
are necessarily “distanced” from these “externali- as the motive for love and connection to other people
ties”; certainly such downstream and upstream costs is a basic human need shared by all people, regardless
are very rarely included in the product information of the economic system under which they live. What
of which Locke (2007) suggests advertisements are we did claim is that when the aims of ACC become
comprised. When consumers are not confronted with increasingly salient to people, tendencies towards self-
awareness of such factors, they are less likely to interest, competition, and objectification are likely to
enter these community-oriented variables into their generalize to their relationships in non-business con-
decision-making processes than when they live in the texts. We supported this claim by reporting data that
same neighborhood as the low-paid workers and the materialistic individuals have lower quality relation-
garbage dumps full of pollution from discarded goods ships (Kasser and Ryan, 2001; Solberg, Diener, and
(see also Clapp, 2002). Robinson, 2004) and compete rather than cooperate
Similar distancing processes can be identified on the with their friends (Sheldon et al., 2000), and that in the
production end of the equation as well. Many features last few decades under ACC, Americans are spend-
of ACC seem to ensure that decision makers of large ing more time working to the detriment of their rela-
corporations are distanced from those who are affected tionships with families and friends (Hochschild, 1997;
by their decisions. CEOs and board members rarely see Lane, 2000; Schor, 1991). We hope this clarifies our
the workers laboring in factories far from the home of- position that rather than eliminating such desires for
fice, vice presidents are transferred from town to town affiliation and intimacy, the values of ACC instead in-
every few years before they can put down roots and feel filtrate and damage such relationships.
part of a community, and faceless shareholders spread Second, S. Schwartz (2007) found a positive but
across the globe ultimately have the say in the decisions non-significant correlation between benevolence val-
a corporation makes. As Whybrow (2007) notes, these ues and Hall and Gingerich’s (2004) strategic vs. com-
features of the modern global economy are in striking petitive capitalism index, leading him to conclude that
contrast to the setting in which Smith’s philosophy de- ACC “affects pro-social motivation toward members
veloped: capitalists living in small villages, employing of the in-group (Benevolence values) only weakly,
and selling to their neighbors. Myers (2007) provides if at all” (p. 56). To be clear, the direction of the
a glimpse into this “earlier time” by sharing exam- correlation S. Schwartz reported is consistent with
ples of business owners in Hope, Michigan: men who the predictions derived from our target article—what
grew up with and continue to “rub elbows” with their needs to be explained is the relative weakness of the
employees, and who contribute to their community be- correlation.
cause they feel they have a stake in it. As we know A starting point can be derived from close exami-
from years of social psychological research, proximity nation of the circumplex models of values and goals
breeds liking and people tend to treat members of their presented in Figures 1 and 2 of our target article. Es-
in-groups in more beneficent ways than members of pecially in Figure 2, it can be seen that financial suc-
out-groups. It may be that globalization, in addition cess goals more directly oppose community feeling
to connecting people in the world through the inter- goals than affiliation goals. Indeed, Grouzet et al.’s
change of products, services, and money, is breeding (2005) circular stochastic modeling analyses showed
conditions that also create distance, to the detriment of that financial success and community feeling aspira-
worker equality and environmental sustainability. tions were 192 degrees apart, whereas financial success
As we hope is obvious from this discussion, research and affiliation goals had a less direct conflict, being
on pro-social behavior, sharing, proximity, in-groups 105 degrees apart. Thus, it appears somewhat easier,
and out-groups, and decision-making processes might although still basically difficult, for people to balance
fruitfully test these propositions in future research. the aims of ACC with benevolence/affiliation goals
than with universalism/community feeling goals. As
such, potential correlations between ACC and benevo-
Benevolence/Affiliation
lence values should be weaker than with universalism
Two commentators raised questions about how the values, which is of course what S. Schwartz (2007)
aims of ACC interfere with goals concerning love and found.
close interpersonal relationships. We respond to each But why is the opposition between the aims of ACC
in turn. and benevolence/affiliation goals somewhat less se-
First, Locke (2007) wonders, “So does this mean vere than the opposition between the aims of ACC and
that capitalists cannot distinguish between business universalism/community feeling goals? It seems to us
and the rest of their lives? Does it mean that they do that the answer lies in how transcendent the two types
not have friends and do not fall in love?” (p. 39). In of values and goals are. In both circumplex models,
answer, nowhere in our target article did we claim that universalism values, and community feeling goals are
66
AUTHORS’ RESPONSE

labeled transcendent and concern something “higher” you can keep at least most of the money you earn.
and “outside the self” as well as “society as a whole.” You can choose what to buy and what to sell. You can
In contrast, affiliation and benevolence goals, at least in choose whom to do business with (italics in original;
the Grouzet et al. (2005) model presented in Figure 2 of p. 39).
our target article, are only slightly more transcendent
than financial success goals, with both lying at about Locke makes important points here, and we agree
the mid-point of the vertical dimension labeled self- that it is worth reiterating that capitalism, including
transcendent vs. physical. As such, affiliation goals the form of capitalism we have called ACC, has in-
have less of a transcendent quality than do commu- deed opened up some choices and options that are less
nity goals, making them somewhat more like financial available under other systems. ACC does not directly
success goals in that they are more self-interested. S. restrict people’s movement, identity adoptions, or in
Schwartz’s comments reinforce this interpretation, as most cases, their consumer behaviors. And sometimes
he notes that benevolence goals concern the “in-group” the dynamics of ACC have increased choices, as ex-
which people often experience as “extensions of the emplified by the increasing number of corporations
self.” that are adopting “flex time” because it is profitable.
This common bond of “self-interest” may help peo- Indeed, part of the core dynamic of ACC is to have a
ple who have strongly internalized ACC’s aims to enact large menu of certain types of options before everyone.
benevolence values and affiliation goals. A good exam- But as we noted in our target article, work by Lane
ple of this can be seen in Locke’s contention that when (2000), B. Schwartz (2004) and others suggests that
the wealthy donate, “it should be to causes in which having too many choices can be daunting and even
they have a selfish interest, e.g., if a capitalist’s father burdensome. And, more importantly for our argument,
dies of cancer, he might want to donate money for can- as Ryan and Deci (2006) recently expressed, “one can
cer research” (p. 40). Not only is this a clear example of have many options, and not feel autonomy” (p. 1577).
Miller’s (1999) concept of the norm of self-interest, but That is, while we agree that it is rare under ACC that
it demonstrates that individuals who strongly identify people are compelled to work at McDonald’s or in a
with the values of ACC may be more likely to act in sweatshop, practically speaking a significant portion
benevolent ways so long as they also see such behavior of people living under ACC do not have the freedom
as being in their own self-interest. In contrast, it may to pursue any aim they desire, and certainly not any
be more difficult for a person oriented towards ACC to career or occupation they desire. Consider that many
come to terms with the more “self-less,” transcendent people in developing nations are leaving rural areas
aims typical of universalism and community feeling. and moving to urban megalopolises to take jobs in fac-
Such considerations lead us to wonder whether the tories. Do some of them choose (i.e., make a decision)
primary way in which ACC damages affiliation and to do so? Absolutely. But do some of them do so be-
benevolence goals is by working against the more “self- cause the global forces of agribusiness, controlled by
less” behaviors that are necessary to maintain and en- a few massively powerful corporations and supported
hance good intimate relationships. We had noted in our by international laws, have diminished the viability of
target article several examples relevant to this, as peo- their small farms and the chances they have to feed
ple who have highly internalized ACC’s aims are less their families? Absolutely. Do some single mothers
empathic, less cooperative, and more likely to manip- choose to work two minimum-wage jobs? Absolutely.
ulate others. Thus, while it seems as though ACC does Do some do so because they live in a system that, as
not eliminate the very human desire for intimate re- of this writing, does not insist that full-time workers
lationships, the self-interested, competitive values of receive a living wage and that does not provide a strong
the economic system creep into them, diminishing social safety net for the significant percentage of the
the kinds of transcendent, self-less, empathic behav- population that does not have the discretionary income
iors that help create optimal experiences of love and to choose in what company to invest their retirement
friendship. fund? Absolutely.
These problems with limited freedom and options
Self-direction/Self-acceptance are surely most salient to the individuals at the bottom
Locke’s commentary provides an excellent example of ACC’s social hierarchy who often lack opportunity
of how freedom is viewed by many proponents of ACC: to gain access to or partake in such options. But,
as we discussed in our target article, there are other
Capitalism is the system of freedom. You can choose
limits to ACC as well. That is, like any social system,
your career. You can choose what jobs to apply for. ACC provides certain choices and benefits (wealth,
You can choose what business(es) to enter. You can a panoply of consumer goods, etc.), but the options
choose to leave a job situation you dislike. You can it offers are generally those that fit the system’s
choose to start your own business. You can choose goals; as can be seen from Locke’s prose, these are
how to invest your money. Even in a mixed economy, primarily economic freedoms involving the pursuit
67
KASSER, KANNER, COHN, RYAN

of making and spending money. Acknowledging that In this last section, we hope to go beyond these issues
ACC provides these freedoms does not imply that it and sketch out what we believe a fuller psychological
provides all freedoms that people might value. To say analysis of economic systems would entail.
it once again, ACC is most likely to offer options that As we have noted, all social systems, including
are consistent with its own ideology and institutions systems designed to address economic issues, are
and is least likely to offer options that are inconsistent themselves built around key assumptions about hu-
with its ideology and institutions. Further, it is most man nature, about social interactions, and about what
likely to provide the freedoms it offers to those who optimally motivates individuals. ACC is a particu-
are willing and able to follow the dictates of the lar economic system with particular assumptions, i.e.,
system; those who, for whatever reason, do not fit into that people are primarily self-interested, are most
the system well are more or less out of luck. productive in competitive situations, and are most
An excellent example of how these macro-options effectively motivated by material rewards. Identify-
are limited under ACC concerns advertising. Certainly ing these assumptions, we believe, is a central task
there are millions of options for watching television of any full psychological analysis of economic sys-
ads that support the ACC mindset that consumption tems, as it lays the groundwork for identifying the
is fun and good. But consider the plight of an or- ways in which the system’s ideology and institutions
ganization known as Adbusters, which pokes fun at relate to psychological, behavioral, and social out-
commercialism and over-spending through the use of comes. That is, the psychological assumptions be-
sophisticated marketing images. Adbusters has repeat- hind ACC deeply influence the institutions—such as
edly attempted to purchase, at the going-rate, air-time corporations, the WTO, and the like—that emerge
for its “anti-ads,” only to meet with frequent refusal from these assumptions. These institutions, in turn,
from the corporations who own television networks work alongside the ideology to contribute to peo-
(Bordwell, 2002). Why? Because the ads run counter ple becoming more self-interested, competitive, and
to the ideology of these corporations, which demand materialistic, with concomitant costs for universal-
profit and which obtain that profit largely by spreading ism/community feeling, benevolence/affiliation, and
the consumerist mindset through advertising. self-direction/self-acceptance aims in life.
In sum, if ACC claims that it “is the system of free- When the psychological assumptions embedded in
dom” when in fact freedom is only limited to certain an economic system are not clearly identified and ex-
individuals and to certain options, we insist that ideol- amined, proponents of the system can point to the re-
ogy rather than fact drives such a claim. Psychologists sulting emotional and behavioral outcomes as evidence
interested in these dynamics have many theories and that the economic system simply reflects human nature,
tools at their disposal to study this issue. Two com- rather than molds it. Stated somewhat differently, the
mentators suggest what seem to us particularly fruitful assumptions behind economic systems lead certain as-
avenues for future work. Specifically, B. Schwartz and pects of human nature to be rewarded and promoted
his colleagues have pointed the way towards docu- while other aspects are punished or suppressed. Rec-
menting how the enormous number of micro-options ognizing and more deeply understanding this process
provided within the ACC framework can interfere with is critical to a full psychological analysis of any eco-
certain aspects of freedom. In addition, Dittmar (2007) nomic system.
cogently shows how the identity options provided by As these considerations suggest, it is important for
consumer culture often create a “cage within” that lim- psychologists to question whether the ideologies and
its opportunities for self-direction and self-acceptance. institutions present in our economic system foster the
The study of these and other topics will certainly help values, beliefs, and behaviors toward which society
to distinguish the types of freedoms that ACC does and wishes its members to move. Given that our target ar-
does not provide. ticle and some of the commentaries raise significant
concerns about the costs of ACC, we hope that psy-
chologists will begin to study not only the processes
Towards a Psychological Science by which certain economic structures create alien-
of Economic Systems ation, stress, and unhappiness, but also how economies
can be designed that might better promote the fea-
In the opening sentence of his comment on our tar- tures of humans that will bring them greater happi-
get article, Henrich (2007) notes that we “ . . . pose an ness, more social cohesion, and greater environmental
important and often unaddressed question: how do dif- sustainability. How might the discipline set about this
ferent institutional forms, or economic systems, shape formidable and interesting task?
the beliefs, motivations, and practices of their members Some of the responses to our article begin to an-
or participants . . . ?” (p. 36) Indeed, our target article swer this question by noting examples in which cer-
and most of the comments on it were focused on the tain companies are not consumed by the profit motive
psychological consequences of economic institutions. (Myers, 2007) or by comparing nations highly oriented
68
AUTHORS’ RESPONSE

towards ACC with those that have less competitive ganizing investigations exclusively around capitalism
forms of capitalism (S. Schwartz, 2007). Such ap- would significantly curtail the field’s ability to address
proaches rightly recognize that there are various forms some of the most pressing and interesting questions
of capitalism and various ways of living within an eco- in this area. Instead, a broader approach is required
nomic framework such as ACC that might bear fewer that explores non-capitalistic systems as well. That is,
of the costs we describe. To give another example, just as Martin and Shirk (2007) have pointed out that
some research has begun to examine topics such as our understanding of the self and social interactions
ethical consumption, whereby people privilege non- are limited by the fact that almost all studies of these
financial values in their economic decisions (Shaw and topics take place in “highly technological countries,
Shiu, 2003), and Voluntary Simplicity, whereby peo- [that are] ultimately dependent on intensive agricul-
ple reject the high-stress, high-pay, high-consumption ture for their subsistence, are relatively sedentary (in
lifestyle encouraged by ACC for a life oriented around the sense of being non-nomadic), and are subject to the
personal growth, family, community involvement, and pressures of living in relatively dense populations,” a
oftentimes spiritual development (Brown and Kasser, full understanding of the psychology of economic sys-
2005). By examining such topics, psychologists can tems can not be based solely on work conducted with
begin to point towards ways that people might avoid people who live in cultures that are organized around
some of the costs of ACC even when they still live the capitalistic economic system, with its concomitant
within that system. ideology and institutions.
Psychologists can also study social systems and the What is therefore necessary instead is to study indi-
individuals within them who resist forces of globaliza- viduals who exist under other types of economic orga-
tion by examining individuals who participate in local nization. For example, it would be useful to examine
economies. Myers (2007), for example, pointed to the people who live in “immediate-return societies” (Mar-
ability of local ownership to limit the excesses of large tin and Shirk, 2007) or operate on “gift economies”
corporations. Other aspects of a local, rather than a (Hyde, 1983), especially since anthropological work
global, economy might also work against the costs of suggests that these social organizations typify the expe-
ACC. For example, opponents of globalization have rience of our human ancestors. In contrast to modified
supported local currency movements (Helleiner, 2002) forms of ACC, which focus on striking a balance be-
and have proposed that economies be organized around tween cooperation and generosity on the one hand and
the principle of “subsidiarity,” such that: competition and self-interest on the other, these older
social systems typically assume that humans flour-
whatever decisions and activities can be undertaken lo- ish when cooperation and sharing within the group
cally should be. Whatever power can reside at the local form the basis of social and economic activity. Such
level should reside there. Only when additional activ- economies also do not value private property and ma-
ity is required that cannot be satisfied locally should terial wealth nearly as much as even modified versions
power and activity move to the next highest level, that of ACC. To fully understand the psychological signif-
of regional, national, and finally, world. (Cavanagh icance of all of the factors we have been discussing—
and Mander, 2004, p. 83) cooperation, competition, generosity, selfishness, love,
freedom, and values—it is necessary to examine indi-
Proponents of such local economic arrangements ar- viduals living in non-capitalist economies.
gue they foster more environmentally sound business
practices as they require, for example, far less trans-
portation of goods—one of the largest sources of eco- Conclusion
logical destruction. And as Myers points out (2007),
local ownership means owners have more involvement We were gratified that the comments on our tar-
in the community and more at stake in local affairs, get article were mostly supportive of our call for
and as a result are likely to be more responsive to local psychology to focus its attention on economic sys-
needs than are large, multi-national corporations with tems, and in particular, on the costs and benefits of
distant owners. Finally, as our discussion of distancing ACC. We sincerely hope that fifteen or twenty years
(Princen, 2002) suggested, consumers in such locally- from now, when scholars conduct a PsychInfo search
oriented systems may be more apt to make decisions on “capitalis*” they will not be met with the same
that are more informed by non-financial values when paucity of research we reported in Table 1 of our target
they purchase a locally-made product from a neighbor. article, but will instead find myriad studies utilizing the
These are all empirical questions that can certainly be many methodological approaches and theoretical per-
tested by psychologists. spectives that characterize the field. Such an outcome,
As much promise as these approaches hold, we hope we believe, would benefit both psychology and soci-
that psychology will not limit itself to solely exam- ety as a whole. Psychology will have integrated into
ining sub-systems within capitalistic societies, as or- its nomological network of constructs a social factor
69
KASSER, KANNER, COHN, RYAN

that clearly influences human behavior and experience. pirical analysis. MPIfG Discussion Paper 04/5. Max Planck
And such psychological work may well help society Institute for the Study of Societies: Cologne, Germany.
Heilbroner, R. L. (1985). The nature and logic of capitalism. NY:
begin pursuing paths less damaging to its own health,
Norton Books.
the health of its citizens, and the health of the Earth’s Helleiner, E. (2002). Think globally, transact locally: The local-
ecosystem. currency movement and Green political economy. In T. Princen,
M. Maniates, & K. Conca (Eds.), Confronting consumption (pp.
255–273). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Henreich, J. (2007). Behavioral data, cultural group selection, and
Note genetics. Psychological Inquiry, 18, 36–37.
Hochschild, A. R. (1997). The time bind: When work becomes home
and home becomes work. New York: Metropolitan Books.
Address correspondence to Tim Kasser, Box K-83,
Hyde, L. (1983). The Gift. New York: Random House.
2 East South Street, Knox College, Galesburg, IL Kasser, T., & Ryan, R. M. (1993). A dark side of the American dream:
61401. E-mail: tkasser@knox.edu Correlates of financial success as a central life aspiration. Jour-
nal of Personality and Social Psychology, 65, 410–422.
Kasser, T., & Ryan, R. M. (2001). Be careful what you wish for:
References Optimal functioning and the relative attainment of intrinsic
and extrinsic goals. In P. Schmuck and K. M. Sheldon (Eds.),
APA Task force on Advertising and Children (2004). Report Life goals and well-being: Towards a positive psychology of
of the APA Task Force on Advertising and Children. human striving (pp. 116–131). Goettingen, Germany: Hogrefe
http://www.apa.org/releases/childrenads.html & Huber Publishers.
Bakan, J. (2004). The corporation: The pathological pursuit of profit Kohn, M. L. (1977). Class and conformity: A study in values (2nd
and power. New York: Free Press. ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Bello, W., Cunningham, S., & Poh, L. K. (1998). A Siamese tragedy: Kuna, D. P. (1976). The concept of suggestion in the early history of
Development and disintegration in modern Thailand. New advertising psychology. Journal of the History of the Behavioral
York: Zed Books. Sciences, 12, 347–353.
Bordwell, M. (2002). Jamming culture: Adbusters’ hip media cam- Kuna, D. P. (1979). Early advertising applications of the Gale-Cattell
paign against consumerism. In T. Princen, M. Maniates, and K. order-of-merit method. Journal of the History of the Behavioral
Conca (Eds.), Confronting consumption (pp. 237–253). Cam- Sciences, 15, 38–46.
bridge, MA: MIT Press. Lane, R. E. (2000). The loss of happiness in market democracies.
Bowles, S., & Gintis, H. (1976). Schooling in capitalist America: New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Educational reform and the contradictions of economic life. Locke, E. (2007). What is capitalism? Some comments on Kasser,
New York: Basic Books. Cohn, Kanner, and Ryan. Psychological Inquiry, 18, 38–42.
Braverman, H. (1974). Labor and monopoly capital: The degra- Martin, L. L., & Shirk, S. (2007). Immediate-return societies: What
dation of work in the twentieth century. New York: Monthly can they tell us about the self and social relationships in our
Review Press. society? In J. V. Wood, A. Tesser, & J. G. Holmes (Eds.), The self
Brown, K. W., & Kasser, T. (2005). Are psychological and ecological and social relationships (pp. 1–182). New York: Psychological
well-being compatible? The role of values, mindfulness, and Press.
lifestyle. Social Indicators Research, 74, 349–368. McHoskey, J. W. (1999). Machiavellianism, intrinsic versus extrinsic
Buckley, K. W. (1982). The selling of a psychologist: John Broadus goals, and social interest: A self-determination theory analysis.
Watson and the application of behavioral techniques to adver- Motivation and Emotion, 23, 267–283.
tising. Journal of the History of the Behavioral Sciences, 18, Miller, D. T. (1999). The norm of self-interest. American Psycholo-
207–221. gist, 54, 1053–1060.
Cavanagh, J., & Mander, J. (2004). (Eds.). Alternatives to economic Myers, D. G. (2007). Costs and benefits of American corporate
globalization: A better world is possible (2nd ed.). San Fran- capitalism. Psychological Inquiry, 18, 43–47.
cisco: Berrett-Koehler. Nartsupha, C. (1999). The Thai village economy in the past. Chiang
Clapp, J. (2002). The distancing of waste: Overconsumption in a Mai, Thailand: Silkworm Books.
global economy. In T. Princen, M. Maniates, & K. Conca (Eds.), Petty, R. E., & Cacioppo, J. T. (1986). Communication and persua-
Confronting consumption (pp. 155–176). Cambridge, MA: MIT sion: Central and peripheral routes to attitude change. New
Press. York: Springer-Verlag.
Dittmar, H. (2007). The costs of consumer culture and the “cage The Pew Research Center. (2007). A portrait of “Generation Next”:
within”: The impact of the material “good life” and “body How young people view their lives, futures and politics. Wash-
perfect” ideals on individuals’ identity and well-being. Psycho- ington, DC: Author.
logical Inquiry, 18, 23–31. Phatharathananunth, S. (2006). Civil society and democratization:
Easterlin, R. A. (2007). The escalation of material goals: Fingering Social movements in Northeast Thailand. Copenhagen: Nias
the wrong culprint. Psychological Inquiry, 18, 31–33. Press.
The Economist (2001). Pocket world in figures. London: Profile Princen, T. (2002). Distancing: Consumption and the severing of
Books, Ltd. feedback. In T. Princen, M. Maniates, & K. Conca (Eds.), Con-
Frey, B. S., & Stutzer, A. (2002). Happiness and economics. Prince- fronting consumption (pp. 103–131). Cambridge, MA: MIT
ton: Princeton University Press. Press.
Grouzet, F., Kasser, T., Ahuvia, A., Fernandez-Dols, J. M., Kim, Y., Ryan, R. M., & Deci, E. L. (2006). Self-regulation and the prob-
Lau, S., Ryan, R. M., Saunders, S., Schmuck, P., & Sheldon, lem of human autonomy: Does psychology need choice, self-
K. M. (2005). The structure of goal contents across fifteen cul- determination and will? Journal of Personality, 74, 1557–
tures. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 89, 800– 1586.
816. Schor, J. B. (1991). The overworked American. NY: Basic Books.
Hall, P. A., & Gingerich, D. W. (2004). Varieties of capitalism and Schwartz, B. (2004). The paradox of choice: Why more is less. NY:
institutional complementarities in the macroeconomy: An em- Ecco Books.

70
AUTHORS’ RESPONSE

Schwartz, B. (2007). There must be an alternative. Psychological Sheldon, K. M., Sheldon, M. S., & Osbaldiston, R. (2000). Prosocial
Inquiry, 18, 48–51. values and group assortation in an N-person prisoner’s dilemma.
Schwartz, S. H. (1992). Universals in the content and structure of Human Nature, 11, 387–404.
values: Theory and empirical tests in 20 countries. In M. Zanna Smith, A. (1776/1976). An inquiry into the nature and causes of the
(Ed.), Advances in experimental social psychology, (Vol. 25) wealth of nations. New York: Random House.
(pp. 1–65). New York. Solberg, E. C., Diener, E., & Robinson, M. D. (2004). Why are
Schwartz, S. H. (2007). Cultural and individual value correlates of materialists less satisfied? In T. Kasser and A. D. Kanner (Eds.),
capitalism: A comparative analysis. Psychological Inquiry, 18, Psychology and consumer culture: The struggle for a good life
52–57. in a materialistic world (pp. 29–48). Washington, DC: APA.
Shaw, D., & Shiu, E. (2003). Ethics in consumer choice: A mul- Ungpakorn, J. G. (Ed.). (2003). Radicalizing Thailand: New political
tivariate modeling approach. European Journal of Marketing, perspectives. Bangkok: White Lotus.
37, 1485–1498. Vohs, K. D., Mead, N. L., & Goode, M. R. (2006). The psychological
Sheldon, K. M., & McGregor, H. (2000). Extrinsic value orientation consequences of money. Science, 314, 1154–1156.
and the tragedy of the commons. Journal of Personality, 68, Whybrow, P. C. (2007). Adam Smith’s American dream. Psycholog-
383–411. ical Inquiry, 18, 57–59.

71

Potrebbero piacerti anche