Sei sulla pagina 1di 15

Cities, Vol. 24, No. 1, p.

115, 2007
2006 Elsevier Ltd.
doi:10.1016/j.cities.2006.10.002 All rights reserved.
0264-2751/$ - see front matter

www.elsevier.com/locate/cities

Global cities of the South:


Emerging perspectives on growth
and inequality
Gavin Shatkin *
Urban and Regional Planning Program, University of Michigan, 2000 Bonisteel Boulevard,
Ann Arbor, MI 48109, United States

Received 15 December 2005; received in revised form 26 September 2006; accepted for publication 7 October 2006
Available online 23 January 2007

This paper attempts to reframe debates on the equity implications of spatial, socioeconomic,
and political change in global cities in developing countries through a review of recent literature
on this topic. It begins by critiquing the view that global cities in developing countries are con-
verging around a model of development similar to that of the prototypical global cities of the
United States, Europe, and Japan. It argues that three emerging perspectives hold the key to an
analysis that better accounts for local agency and divergent outcomes in such cities: a focus on
the diversity of cities experience with globalization; recognition of the inherently negotiated
nature of global impacts on urban outcomes; and a focus on actor-centered perspectives in
urban analysis. The combined influence of these ideas amounts to a shift from a focus on global
city models to an examination of the interaction between global and local actors and institu-
tions in a particular setting. Building on this literature review, the paper suggests an alternate
framework for analyzing the link between global city development and inequality that focuses
on three processes of change: the formation of publicprivate partnerships in urban governance,
the spatial implications of the privatization of planning, and the flexiblization of labor. It argues
that a focus on these processes has important implications for both theory and practice, as it
allows us to understand similarity and difference in urban development, and more importantly,
to understand the actors, institutions and interests that are driving change.
2006 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Global cities, developing countries, equity

Introduction 1998; Cowherd and Heikkila, 2002; Leichencko


The literature on global and world cities asserts that and Solecki, 2005). This assertion has proven contro-
versial, however, and a growing chorus has argued
the spatial, social, and political development of cer-
that the global/world city concept overstates the
tain cities is profoundly shaped by their function as
power of actors and institutions operating at a global
command and control centers in the global econ-
level, and underestimates local agency and contin-
omy. Very large cities in developing countries have
gency (Robinson, 2002; Flusty, 2004; Hill, 2004;
increasingly been analyzed under this rubric, and
Roy, 2005). The question at the center of this debate
some have argued that we are seeing a convergence
is: How do we understand change in global cities,
of global/world cities around a model of urbaniza-
and how do we account for local contingency and
tion that originates in the West, and particularly in
agency in our analysis? Given the pace of urbaniza-
the United States (Cohen, 1996; Dick and Rimmer,
tion in developing countries, the unprecedented
scale of emerging urban regions, and their economic
and political importance for their countries, address-
*
Tel.: +1-734-763-2075; fax: +1-734-763-2322; e-mail: shatkin@ ing this question would appear to be a central task of
umich.edu. contemporary urban theory.

1
Global cities of the South: Emerging perspectives on growth and inequality: G Shatkin

In this paper, I add to critiques of the idea of non of gated communities, and the formation of
convergence, and, through a review of recent stud- central city ghettoes of the poor (Marcuse, 1997;
ies, identify alternative models for analyzing global Marcuse and van Kempen, 2000a).
city development in developing countries that I be-  Finally, political inequality refers to the process by
lieve better account for local agency and variation which urban politics comes to be dominated by
in outcomes.1 The problem with prevailing perspec-
interest groups who favor growth-oriented policies
tives on convergence, I argue, is that they are too
over the interests of neighborhoods (Logan and
quick to zoom in on observed similarities in urban
trends, and gloss over important sources of differ- Molotch, 1987).
ence rooted in cultural, geography, and institutional Several recent studies have argued that these out-
dynamics. In other words, many studies begin with comes are also apparent in cities like Jakarta, Shang-
outcomes in a few paradigmatic cases such as New hai, Istanbul, and Mexico City. While certain
York, London, and Los Angeles, and then look to similarities do indeed exist, I argue that focusing on
see whether this global city shoe fits in places like these similarities distracts us from an examination
Shanghai, Mexico City, or Buenos Aires. In the of important differences, and also from asking ques-
first section of the paper, I provide a brief review tions about what is causing change. Drawing on the
of critiques of the perspective of convergence, literature review presented in the first half of the pa-
and then identify three emerging trends in theoriz- per, I endeavor to reframe the global city-inequality
ing global cities that hold the key to analysis that hypothesis by employing an actor-centered, histori-
better accounts for local agency: a growing focus cally informed, and contextually grounded approach.
on the diversity of cities experience with globali- I propose alternative conceptualizations of spatial,
zation; recognition of the inherently negotiated political and socioeconomic inequality in global cit-
nature of global impacts on urban outcomes; and ies that avoid the assumption that such cities in
a focus on actor-centered perspectives in urban developing countries will inevitably follow the trajec-
analysis. The combined influence of these ideas tory of the global cities of the advanced economies.
amounts to a shift from a focus on global/world city
models to a more grounded examination of the
interaction between global and local actors and
Refocusing the global/world cities lens
institutions in a particular setting. This is an impor- Robinson (2002, p. 531) has argued that one of the
tant development for theory as it allows for a much central contradictions in contemporary urban the-
more precise understanding of urban development, ory is that cities throughout the world are consis-
and also for policy and planning, because it more tently analyzed with reference to the (usually
accurately identifies the actors who shape and legit- unstated) experiences of a relatively small group
imize urban change, and strategies they employ in of (mostly western) cities. This observation is par-
doing so. ticularly relevant to the literature on global and
In the final section, the paper draws on these alter- world cities, which has brought attention to the
native perspectives to reassess one of the central emerging function of certain cities as command
hypotheses of the global cities literaturethat cer- points in the world economy and as locations for
tain social inequalities are inherent to the process specialized business firms (Sassen, 2001). A number
of global city development. Three specific manifesta- of empirical studies, notably those of the Globaliza-
tions of inequality have been a focus of attention: tion and World Cities group (GAWC), have catego-
rized many large developing country cities as
 The rst is social inequality, which emerges as
global/world cities based on their economic function
social classes in the global city become polarized and the presence of global headquarters and pro-
between a wealthy professional class and an ducer service firms. One oft-cited study found that
impoverished low-wage service sector class (Mol- 18 of the 25 largest cities outside of Europe, the
lenkopf and Castells, 1991; Friedmann, 1995; Sas- United States and Japan ranked somewhere on
sen, 1998). the roster of world cities (Beaverstock et al.,
 The second is uneven development, which occurs 1999see Table 1 for a detailed breakdown). These
as social polarization becomes embedded in the cities tend to achieve global/world city status due to
spatial form of the city in the form of socioeco- their role in coordinating the integration of their
nomic segregation and unequal access to livable national economies into the global economy, and
space. This is manifest in the American context in often lie at the center of large global city-regions
(Scott et al., 2001). For example, Metro Manila,
the suburbanization of the wealthy, the phenome-
Bangkok and Jakarta have emerged as gamma
world cities as they have become the center for
1 national headquarters of transnational corporations
The focus throughout the paper will primarily be on cities in Asia,
although examples will be drawn from other regions. This reects
and producer service firms that coordinate manufac-
both my own background and the greater prevalence of studies on turing production, and increasingly export-oriented
Asian cities. services, in their extended metropolitan regions.

2
Global cities of the South: Emerging perspectives on growth and inequality: G Shatkin
Table 1 The world city status of the 25 largest cities in developing countries according to Beaverstock et al.s Roster of World Cities

City Population (thousands) Beaverstock et al. rankinga

Mexico City, Mexico 19,013 Beta


Mumbai (Bombay), India 18,336 Evidence
Sao Paulo, Brazil 18,333 Beta
Delhi, India 15,334 Evidence
Calcutta, India 14,299 N/A
Buenos Aires, Argentina 13,349 Gamma
Jakarta, Indonesia 13,194 Gamma
Shanghai, China 12,665 Gamma
Dhaka, Bangladesh 12,560 N/A
Rio de Janeiro, Brazil 11,469 Evidence
Cairo, Egypt 11,146 Evidence
Lagos, Nigeria 11,135 N/A
Beijing, China 10,849 Gamma
Metro Manila, Philippines 10,677 Gamma
Karachi, Pakistan 10,032 N/A
Istanbul, Turkey 9760 Gamma
Seoul, South Korea 9592 Beta
Tianjin, China 9346 N/A
Lima, Peru 8180 Evidence
Bogota, Colombia 7594 Evidence
Tehran, Iran 7352 Evidence
Hong Kong, China 7182 Alpha
Chennai (Madras), India 6915 N/A
Bangkok, Thailand 6604 Gamma
Bangalore, India 6532 N/A

Source: Derived from Beaverstock et al. (1999) and UN Habitat (2005).


a
Alpha city status means that a city is a prime center for producer service firms, while beta and gamma refer, respectively, to major
and minor centers for such firms. Evidence means that there is evidence of world city formation. These rankings are based on an
empirical evaluation of the office locations of multinational accounting, advertising, banking and law firms.

Focus on these cities role as command and con- their functions in the global economy, and in their
trol sites has led to questions about the implications development. This study is not the first to argue
of this function for their development. A growing set that the search for a specific and universal set of
of studies has attempted to apply frameworks devel- outcomes may be fruitless. In a seminal compara-
oped primarily in the United States, examining so- tive study, for example, Marcuse and van Kempen
cial polarization, the development of urban (2000a) propose abandoning the term global city
regimes, and emergent consumer landscapes in a altogether, instead adopting the more general term
wide range of contexts (Dick and Rimmer, 1998; Fir- globalizing cities. Inasmuch as all cities in todays
man, 1998; Pirez, 2002; Graizborg et al., 2003; Chiu world could be said to be globalizing in some way
and Lui, 2004; Firman, 2004; Salcedo and Torres, or another, however, this alternative concedes
2004; Wu and Webber, 2004; Keyder, 2005; Lei- important observations about the role of certain
chencko and Solecki, 2005). Many of these studies cities as points of coordination of global production
have argued for a convergence of urban form and and in the process of production. I argue for keep-
politics, although there is considerable variation in ing the terms global and world city, but thinking
the degree to which the causes of convergence are more carefully about the implications of these roles
theorized and potential sources of difference are for a citys development.
explored. The strength and appeal of the global/world cities
While the methodology of quantitative studies literature is that it provides a coherent and theoret-
measuring global/world city functions undertaken ically grounded account of the dramatic processes of
by the GAWC and others can and should be ques- change that many cities have undergone in the past
tioned, this paper does not deny that cities play half century. In this account, the restructuring of
such command and control functions, and that this the global economy has created a need for new types
has a profound impact on their spatial, social and of cities that coordinate decentralized forms of pro-
political development. Rather, it argues that many duction by playing host to highly centralized coordi-
studies have privileged similarity with the experi- nating functions such as corporate headquarters,
ence of cities in the West, notably New York and legal and financial services, and research and devel-
London, and their analysis is consequently skewed. opment (Friedmann, 1995; Sassen, 2001). The modi-
I hypothesize that global/world cities in fact have fication of cities to these new roles has a profound
quite diverse experiences with global integration effect on social and cultural change, leading specifi-
and may be diverging along some parameters in cally to the emergence of a new class of highly

3
Global cities of the South: Emerging perspectives on growth and inequality: G Shatkin

skilled professionals, and the marginalization of the tion into the world economy, most notably depen-
old industrial working class and immigrants, who are dency theory. She questions the recent rediscovery
relegated to low-wage jobs in the service economy of such links during the current era of market trium-
(Mollenkopf and Castells, 1991; Friedmann, 1995; phalism, and argues that the global cities literature
Sassen, 1998). These economic functions also create has started down the slippery slope of past theories
an impetus for the retrofitting of the built environ- of development, and particularly modernization the-
ment of cities, as developers create new types of ory, which view the advanced economies as an end
office, residential and commercial space to meet state that developing countries are inexorably
the demands of business and the new elite (Marcuse, advancing towards.
1997; Marcuse and van Kempen, 2000a). Simulta- At the core of each of these critiques is the con-
neously, the politics of redevelopment require tention that the global city models have failed to ex-
a new type of governance, one that is able to identify plain social change, or to prescribe appropriate
the shifting demands of capital in an unstable and paths towards desired change, because they have
rapidly changing economic climate and bring failed to understand both the contingency of local
capital to the table in pushing a redevelopment change on dynamics rooted in history and culture,
agenda (Logan and Molotch, 1987; Fainstein, 1995). and the shifting nature of the world economy (Davis,
The result is increasingly entrepreneurial local 2005a). In response, proponents have defended the
governments. global/world cities concept by arguing that the
This narrative has largely been formulated with gains [of generalizing about global/world cities] have
reference to a select number of cities in advanced far outweighed the losses (Taylor et al., 2002, p.
industrial economies. Yet it is arguably a rather 231). While this may be true, there is certainly scope
blunt instrument for understanding change, as it for a more fine-grained analysis. As Yeoh (1999, p.
tends gloss over obvious sources of diversity rooted 613) argues, even as we might accept the core pre-
in history, culture, institutions, and geography mises of the global cities concept:
(Abu-Lughod, 1999). Three specific critiques of the
. . .the need exists for theorizations of the global city
application of the global city model are notable.
which weave together historical, economic, cultural,
The first questions the narrowness of the focus on sociopolitical and discursive dimensions. This is an
certain stylish sectors of the global economy,
urgent task, if both the global and the urban are
notably producer and business services and high
not simply to be reduced to articles of faith. The fact
technology industries, as the dominant sectors shap- that the term global city is increasingly accepted as
ing contemporary urban development (Robinson, common currency does not necessarily imply theoret-
2002, p. 532). It questions the dualistic portrayal in ical rigour; instead, the metaphorical hubris, with
the urban studies literature between places that are which the term is often invested, signals the need to
being transformed by these sectors and others which knuckle down to making real sense of what has been
are presumed to be shaped by exclusion and margin- frequently called the new sensibility informing
alization. The implicit critique is that, given the var- urban futures.
ied ways in which cities articulate with global flows
of money, goods, people, and ideas, the meaning One important step in this direction is an effort to
of globalization is not adequately captured by a fo- find ways to generalize about the experience of glo-
cus on the location decision of a small number of bal cities that do not depend on myopia with respect
multinational producer service firms. to difference and contingency. The next section re-
The second critique argues that the global cities views some of the growing number of studies that
literature as a whole is tinged with ethnocentrism have undertaken this task. It identifies three central
as it assumes that all such cities will follow the tra- themes that emerge from these studies: recognition
jectory of New York and London, when in fact these of the diversity of cities experience with global eco-
cities are uniquely shaped by a liberal economic ide- nomic integration; adoption of a perspective that
ology, a consumerist culture, and a polarized social views urban change as a negotiated rather than a
structure (White, 1998; Hill and Kim, 2000; Hill, top-down process; and a focus on actors in analyzing
2004). In societies where the state is more inclined the global-urban interface.
to intervene in social issues, the hypothesized out-
comes for socioeconomic, political, and spatial Recognizing diversity in forms of integration into
polarization in cities are not nearly as pro- the global economy
nouncedParis, Tokyo, and Seoul have been used Robinsons (2002, p. 535) important critique of the
as examples to illustrate this. As White (1998, p. global city model argues that the exclusive focus
464) puts it, states can allow or disallow a city to on command and control functions of cities results
globalize and dualize. in a perspective in which millions of people and
A third critique argues that much of the global hundreds of cities are dropped off the map. . .to ser-
city literature is ahistorical. Davis (2005a) points to vice one particular and very restricted view of the
a long tradition of studying cities in developing significance or (ir)relevance to certain sections of
countries in ways that link urban change to integra- the global economy. There are three main reasons

4
Global cities of the South: Emerging perspectives on growth and inequality: G Shatkin

that the focus on finance and producer services is economic segregation. However, urban tourism
inadequate to explain the diversity of outcomes for also provides broad-based economic opportunity
cities in developing countries. First, because they as the tourism economy may support a large num-
function as command and control centers of a ber of small enterprises such as guest houses, shops,
much lower order than New York or London, multi- restaurants and craft production (Mullins, 1999).
national corporate headquarters and producer ser-
 The growth of business process outsourcing (BPO)
vice firms shape their development to a far lesser
is having a profound impact on urban develop-
degree. Roberts (2005), for example, finds that pro-
ducer services aimed at organizing production for ment and real estate markets in a growing number
global markets simply do not constitute as significant of cities, with some of the more notable examples
a factor in the urban economies of Latin American being Bangalore, Guadalajara, and the planned
cities as is predicted by the global cities literature. high-tech city of Cyberjaya outside of Kuala Lum-
Second, as Chakravorty (2000) argues, globalization pur (Bunnell, 2002; Audirac, 2003). This form of
has accompanied the industrialization of many cities development has signicant implications for urban
in developing countries, and they are consequently development, as it fosters the creation of a new
unlikely to exhibit the same spatial and social char- class of highly educated worker, and also creates
acteristics of post-Fordist cities, such as the decay a powerful imperative for new forms of real estate
of old central city industrial districts. Finally, while
development and infrastructure.
the global cities literature focuses on cities role in
coordinating manufacturing production for the glo- The development of cities may be shaped by other
bal market, cities in fact export an increasingly di- global forces, including integration into markets for
verse array of products and services, each of which natural resource extraction, through the global crim-
has their own spatial logic. Some examples are listed inal economy, through foreign aid, and through
below: international institutions and non-governmental
organizations (Simon, 1995; Shatkin, 1998; Robin-
 Labor has become an increasingly important
son, 2002; Taylor, 2005).
export commodity produced by global/world cit- The recognition of this diversity has several
ies, and remittances to developing countries from implications for our understanding of equity issues
overseas workers totaled an estimated $125 billion in global cities. While the distribution of the costs
in 2004 (Maimbo and Ratha, 2005). In many and benefits of these different forms of integration
countries this has far outstripped other sources varies, each has created economic opportunity for
of foreign investmentin the Philippines, for a large segment of urban populations. Nonetheless,
example, remittances amounted to seven times these various forms of integration all carry with
the amount of foreign direct investment in recent them the instability and intense competition for
years (Maimbo and Ratha, 2005). Popular percep- investment that characterize economic develop-
ment in a globalizing world, and each subsequently
tions aside, in many countries migrants are dispro-
brings with it the potential for new forms of eco-
portionately urban and educated, and the labor nomic insecurity. Hence the equity implications
export industry is often highly concentrated in of these new economic activities are not immedi-
large cities (Tyner, 2000). Researchers have only ately apparent, and are contingent on the eco-
recently begun to examine the implications of this nomic activity in question, and the context of the
phenomenon for urban development, but in Metro society.
Manila, for example, overseas contract workers
and their families have supported a boom in resi- Historicizing analysis and understanding urban
dential and commercial real estate at a time when change as a negotiated process
economic growth in other areas has stagnated Studies rooted in a variety of disciplinary back-
(Burgess and Haksar, 2005). grounds have called for a grounding of global and
 Tourism is the second largest export sector in the world city studies in an understanding of local his-
world, and the construction of tourism enclaves is tory, and a view of urban change not as imposed
often an important impetus for urban redevelop- from above but rather as an inherently negotiated
ment (Fainstein and Judd, 1999). This is certainly process (Abu-Lughod, 1999; AlSayyad, 2001a; Kusno,
true in most large Asian cities, which have experi- 2000; Nasr and Volait, 2003b; Hill, 2004). They have
employed a range of theoretical frameworks to do
enced dramatic increases in tourist arrivals, and
so, including: one that examines structures of global
which tend to view the promotion of urban tourism political and economic power as a nested hierarchy
as part of a larger agenda of place-marketing. In in which parts and wholes are not subordinated to
their eorts to construct a positive image and foster one another, and cities therefore both facilitate
tourist consumption, public and private sector the globalization process and follow their own rela-
actors may create enclaves that exacerbate socio- tively autonomous trajectories (Hill, 2004, p. 374);

5
Global cities of the South: Emerging perspectives on growth and inequality: G Shatkin

examination of the role of planning culture in shap- enced urban planning in many parts of the world,
ing planning outcomes (Sanyaled, 2005); and an including India. Yet, in the Indian context, extra-le-
examination of cultural hybridity and the develop- gal modifications of neighborhood layouts over time
ment of a third space between the local and the have led to such a dramatic physical transformation
global as people in localities reshape cities according that the influence of this model is no longer apparent
to local social, cultural and political imperatives in most cities today (Vidyarthi, 2005).2 Similarly,
(Kusno, 2000; AlSayyad, 2001a). The common although political institutions in many postcolonial
thread in these frameworks is an effort to restore societies are often modeled on those of the metro-
agency to urban analysis, and refute perspectives pole, and have been influenced in many contexts
that depict local residents as impotent, passive by the diffusion of international models, outcomes
and guileless. . ..spectators observing physical and for the distribution of power in society can vary
spatial [as well as social and political] changes that quite dramatically. It is necessary therefore to avoid
they neither control nor understand (Nasr and premature conclusions about the convergence of ur-
Volait, 2003b). ban form or politics, and shift our focus to these pro-
This emphasis on negotiation between the local cesses of adaptation, if we are to understand the
and the global has been applied most prominently impacts of globalization.
to studies of the built environment (AlSayyad,
2001a; Nasr and Volait, 2003a; King, 2004). In one Grounding our understanding of globalization in
recent example, Kusno (2000) demonstrates how actors and actions
the Suharto regime in Indonesia sought to rearticu- Closely related to the emerging perspective of
late both local and colonial/global references in hybridity is the employment of actor-centered
architecture and urban design in Jakarta to create frameworks of urban analysis, which, it has been ar-
a national memory that suited its own agenda of ex- gued, provide a more concrete understanding of how
port-oriented growth and authoritarian politics. In global forces shape and are shaped by local forces,
the realm of urban politics, studies have contested and how local contingency and agency play a role
the tendency to deny local agency both in critical in urban development (Yeoh, 1999; Olds, 2001;
studies, and in a prescriptive literature emerging Markusen, 2004). An actor-centered perspective fo-
from the World Bank and other organizations, cuses on the social power actors employ and the
which argues that the demands of globalization mer- interests and ideologies they pursue. It views local
it the empowerment of private sector interests and a actors as active participants both responding to pres-
modest and deferential role for local government sures in their external environment and trying to
(World Bank, 2000). In Asia specifically, studies shape them to their own ends. This is therefore a
have argued that developmental states are capable view in which (s)tructure and agency are not con-
of creating growth and moderating socioeconomic trasted, but complexified and integrated (Nasr
inequity where there is political accountability, and and Volait, 2003b). It is also one that stresses a need
that such accountability emerges where there exist for deep historical analysis as a basis for understand-
widely held cultural norms concerning statesociety ing the interests of actors and their basis of power in
relations and close ties between the state and civil institutions, social networks, and cultural beliefs.
society (Douglass, 1994; Douglass, 1995; Hill and In general, attention has focused on how actors
Kim, 2000). Two notable examples are Hong Kong operating at a global level have shaped urban devel-
and Singapore, which Castells et al. (1990, p. 331) ar- opment, including corporate actors (Beaverstock
gue have managed to achieve steady economic et al., 1999; Grant and Nijman, 2002), principals at
growth in part by building social cohesion through international architectural firms (Olds, 2001; Mar-
interventions in the realm of collective consumption, shall, 2003; Sklair, 2005), and representatives of inter-
most importantly through the development of public national aid and lending organizations (Burgess et al.,
housing. They attribute their ability to do so to his- 1997). However, local actors, or actors whose inter-
torical conditions that led to the emergence of ests straddle geographic scales, play a key role in
strong states in these two city-states. shaping outcomes as well. These include local devel-
Two observations emerge from these perspectives. opers and realtors (Dick and Rimmer, 1998; Haila,
First, it is apparent that models of urban form and 2000; Sajor, 2003; Sajor, 2005), and an emerging con-
politics that are transmitted by actors operating at a sumer classes (Davis ed, 2000). Perhaps most impor-
global level inevitably go through a process of adap- tantly, local and national governments play a key
tation and reinterpretation, and sometimes rejec- role in providing the legal, policy and regulatory
tion, as they meet local cultures, institutional framework in which development occurs (Firman,
dynamics, and social formations. Second, these mod- 1997; Kelly, 2001). There is also a growing realization
els may go through a process of transformation over that the interests and preferences of these actors can-
time as local actors gradually reshape them to their not be understood with reference to the transmission
own needs. History provides many examples of such
transformation. For example, Clarence Perrys
2
neighborhood unit concept has profoundly influ- I am indebted to Sanjeev Vidyarthi for this observation.

6
Global cities of the South: Emerging perspectives on growth and inequality: G Shatkin
Table 2 Reinterpreting the global/world city-social inequality link

Socioeconomic inequality Political inequality Uneven development

Diversity in the Labor relations and economic opportunity vary by While governments in market economies face a Different modes of incorporation into the global
global city experience the degree of global economic integration a city is common context of incentives to engage new economy have different spatial implications, e.g.
experiencing and the types of products it produces. actors in city-building, who these actors are different degree of centralization and
Yet global economic integration creates common and the political strategies they pursue are in decentralization, and different impacts on real
pressures to develop flexible and competitive labor part a function of the mode of insertion into estate markets.
regimes, creating an inherent tension between growth the global economy (e.g. through
and equity. manufacturing, business services, tourism, or
other export products).
Historical perspective Efforts to make cities competitive in the global The political forms that emergethe form of Spatial development also reflects the preferences
and hybridity economy play out in the forging of capital-labor publicprivate partnership and the relative of urban residents, which are shaped in part by
relations and local and national state interventions in strength of the public and private actors global influences, but also importantly by
these relations that reflect historically specific state involvedis shaped by the historical state- historical spatial patterns, household relations,
society relations. community relations and cultural norms. ethnic, class and other differences, and other
social and cultural variables.
Actor-centered The relative inclusion and exclusion of actors from Fundamental to understanding urban politics Spatial change in part reflects demands for new
perspective the benefits of globalizations economic impacts is in is an understanding of who the actors involved types of space by both firms and households,
part a function of social group relations based on in global city-building are and what their basis which in turn reflects changes in social relations in
caste, race, ethnicity, property ownership, and other of social power is. society at large. On the supply side, it also reflects
variables. new powers and imperatives to foster global city
development among developers and government.
7
Global cities of the South: Emerging perspectives on growth and inequality: G Shatkin

of ideas from the West alone, but rather reflect deep lic and private sector actors seek to build the tallest
rooted cultural norms and social patterns. Yet local building, the sleekest rail system, or the most
actors also confront incentives and imperatives in impressive airport, in an effort to draw attention to
the context of global economic and political change. their global linkages. Wealthy elites in many non-
It is through the interaction of these actors and inter- Western countries seek housing that is explicitly
ests that contemporary hybridity is constituted. modeled on what are perceived as European and
American styles. Cities throughout the world have
Towards a more flexible framework experienced trends towards political and fiscal
What emerges from these perspectives is a view of decentralization that have given them new powers.
global city development that rejects a uniform mod- Such surface similarities, however, mask important
el of change and instead focuses on the unique nat- differences. This section attempts to reframe discus-
ure of the interaction between global and local sions of the link between global city development
actors and institutions in a particular setting. Actors and inequality in a manner that recognizes urban
in cities throughout the world are presented with change as a negotiated process, allows for the possi-
certain opportunities and threats with globaliza- bility of divergence in urban outcomes, and explores
tionopportunities to realize material enrichment the role of both global and local actors in shaping
and new forms of cultural and political expression equity outcomes. I argue that there is a need to
through new forms of production and consumption, move beyond frameworks developed with reference
and threats to existing economic arrangements, to the Westspecifically, the hypothesized trends
political institutions, and ways of life from both towards political inequality/growth regime politics,
external and internal actors who have an interest socioeconomic inequality/polarization, and uneven
in global change. The preferences of actors in shap- development/segregation and spatial mismatchto
ing urban development are informed by their attrac- adopt frameworks that are more adaptable to di-
tion to or repulsion from these new ideas, images, verse circumstances. Based on a review of recent
and institutions. The power that they bring to the ta- studies, I propose three alternative ways of concep-
ble in influencing urban development is shaped by tualizing political, spatial and social development
historically formed social relationships, institutional that are intended as a first step towards a broadly
frameworks, cultural paradigms, and spatial pat- comparative framework for explaining inequity in
terns. The nature of the opportunities and threats global cities. These are: the formation of publicpri-
posed by globalization also shift with changes in vate partnerships in urban politics and planning; the
the global economy (for example the recent shift to- spatial implications of the privatization of planning;
wards the offshoring of services), and these shifts are and the flexiblization of labor.
reflected in changes in urban development.
Table 2 brings this discussion back to the ques-
The formation of publicprivate partnerships in
tion of the link between global city development
urban politics and planning
and inequity by sketching out the implications of
these three emerging perspectives for the three One process of change that is perhaps universal to
central hypotheses of global city-social inequality the experience of global cities is the increasing
theory discussed earlier. It is worth noting that role of for-profit private sector actors in urban pol-
the framework that emerges from this table is fruit- itics, and the growing tendency for local govern-
ful for examining variation in the experience of ments to seek partnership with these actors in
global cities in both developed and developing pursuing development goals. This is evident in
countries. Hence, while the specific focus of this the formation of publicprivate partnerships in ur-
paper is to question the common view of conver- ban infrastructure provision, the growing role of
gence of developing countries with the Western the private sector in building and managing urban
experience, this paper also finds common ground environments, and increased participation by the
with those who question more generally the useful- private sector in urban policy and planning deci-
ness of broad generalizations about the equity sions. This section will explore the applicability
outcomes of global city development. In the next of concepts in vogue in the United States and Eur-
section, I will build on critiques of the idea of con- ope that attempt to explain this phenomenon,
vergence and the alternative frameworks presented notably regime theory and growth regime politics,
above by attempting to reframe the link between to cities of developing countries. It argues that
global city development and inequality in global these frameworks hold a great deal of promise,
cities of developing countries. but that profound variation in the relationship be-
tween the state, the for-profit private sector, and
civil society belies any simplistic depiction of the
Understanding change and inequality in the convergence of urban politics.
global cities of developing countries Fainstein (1995, p. 35) argues that the question
In some respects, cross-national similarities in pat- of the influence of social power and the issue
terns of urban development are quite apparent. Pub- of whether urban politics can affect distributional

8
Global cities of the South: Emerging perspectives on growth and inequality: G Shatkin

outcomes lies at the core of any discussion of ur- One is a set of government institutions controlled to
ban planning and policy. The literature on plan- an important degree by popularly elected ofcials
ning in developing countries, however, retains a chosen in open and competitive contests and operat-
strong focus on the planning process, largely disre- ing within a larger context of the free expression of
garding the role of politics and power. A large competing ideas and claims. Second, the economy
prescriptive literature on urban politics, such as of a liberal order is guided mainly but not exclusively,
that coming out of the World Bank, assumes a by privately controlled investment decisions. A
pluralist conception which posits that all social regime, whether national or local, is a set of arrange-
groups have sources of power that they can use ments by which this division of labor is bridged.
to achieve their ends. The predominant paradigm
is the enablement model, which posits that a These conditions exist to some degree in the con-
decentralized, democratic, and market oriented text of most developing countries, where the vestiges
form of governance will not only provide for eco- of authoritarian regimes are gradually being cast off
nomic efficiency and global competitiveness, but in favor of electoral political systems and market-
will also provide venues for popular influence on oriented political orders. The emergence of the
government through non-governmental and com- export-oriented industrialization model of develop-
munity organizations (World Bank, 2000). Critical ment has coincided with the development in many
studies of global/world cities in developing coun- parts of the world of decentralized, democratic gov-
tries also often assume little agency for local gov- ernance frameworks. In Asia, for example, Jakarta,
ernment in the face of economic and political Taipei, Bangkok, Seoul, Kuala Lumpur, and Metro
pressures from global economic actors, local elites, Manila all have elected local leaders, are engaged
and national governments bent on growth. in intense competition for global investment, have
Recently, however, a handful of studies have varying degrees of freedom of the press, and have
endeavored to apply regime theory, the dominant increasingly embraced the orthodoxy of the public
framework for analyzing urban politics in the Uni- private partnership. Each has a contingent of non-
ted States, to a variety of developing country con- governmental organizations representing diverse
texts (Zhang, 2002; Xu and Yeh, 2005). Regime interests. Many cities have experienced recent re-
theory starts with the assumption that, in cities forms for decentralization that are premised at least
marked by competition to capture footloose capi- in part on a belief that local government will be able
tal, leaders must develop policies in concert with to bring a broader set of resources and interests into
those who have access to that capital (Fainstein, the urban development process, thus encouraging
1995). An urban regime has been defined by Stone growth (Burki et al., 1999).
(1989, p. 6) as the informal arrangements by Yet regimes elsewhere will not necessarily look
which public bodies and private interests function anything like the quintessential American urban re-
together in order to be able to make and carry gime. Regime theory as it has developed in the Uni-
out governing decisions. Yet regime theory ted States reflects a distinct context of racial politics,
avoids economic determinism by emphasizing that post-Fordist urban development, liberalism, and
government does enjoy some autonomy from cor- localism. Countries also vary in the degree to which
porate interests through the space created by dem- electoral contests actually matter. Severe restrictions
ocratic politics, and that urban politics is therefore on political mobilization outside of the ruling party
defined by: exist in some contexts (such as Singapore, Malaysia,
and China), while vote-buying and patronage poli-
. . .the creation of preferences and the translation of tics influences outcomes in others (such as Thailand
those choices into policy. There is a sophisticated rec- and the Philippines). There is also variation in the
ognition that policy is not simply the imposition of degree of freedom of expression in the press and
preferences by an economic elite but rather the shap- other forums. Nonetheless, the time seems ripe in
ing of public opinion by upper class groups. Thus, many cities to raise the questions that are central
ideology or public values become crucial to an under- to the regime theory framework, while remaining
standing of what government of the third sector can alert to contextual differences (Zhang, 2002).
or should do (Fainstein, 1995, p. 36). Two particularly important differences warrant
Regime theory thus disavows a view of urban special attention. The first is the historical and con-
planners and policy-makers as disinterested techno- temporary relationship between the central and lo-
crats, instead seeing them as political actors who can cal state. In many countries this relationship has
either promote or contest the dominance of capital been a significant source of tension, as colonial and
by shaping the discourses that surround the imple- post-colonial states have attempted to extend their
mentation growth-oriented politics. control over peripheral regions in efforts at nation-
Is regime theory applicable to the context of glo- building. Centralization further intensified in many
bal cities in developing countries? Stone (1993, p. countries during the cold war as a consequence of
2) argues that there are two conditions that regime anti-insurgency efforts. Contemporary trends towards
theory takes as given: decentralization have reflected intense struggle over

9
Global cities of the South: Emerging perspectives on growth and inequality: G Shatkin

local power by a variety of actors, including en- and political economies differ, spatial outcomes
trenched national bureaucracies, local elites, social will differ as well. Yet recent literature has focused
movements, and others. The outcomes of these on the idea of global convergence of urban form.
struggles, and the extent of control gained by these Inherent in many such analyses are two assump-
actors, have varied widely between different coun- tions: that Western urban form is directly im-
tries and cities. The second source of variation is posed on developing countries through the
the relative power and legitimacy of government, hegemony of Western planning ideas, and that
which has also been profoundly shaped both by the desires of emergent elites in developing coun-
post-colonial experiences with nation-building and tries with respect to spatial development simply
central rule, and experiences with global economic mimic those of the Western middle class. I argue,
integration. however, that cultural differences and local politi-
Understanding these two sources of variation is cal and institutional dynamics render these assump-
necessary to interpret change in a particular setting. tions untenable. A more powerful mode of analysis
For example, analysts have attributed the frag- focuses on the shared interests of local and na-
mented nature of urban governance in Metro Manila, tional governments, and both local and multina-
and the consequent capture of local government by tional investors, to maximize the profitability and
economic interests, to the power of local elites and global economic competitiveness of urban spaces.
weakness of central government, both of which have This convergence of interests has resulted in some
deep roots in the Philippines colonial and post- contexts in what I refer to as the privatization of
colonial history (Kelly, 2000). In China, by way of planning, a process that results in different spatial
contrast, national governments have exerted a great outcomes in different contexts.
deal of influence in providing incentives and auton- The idea of the privatization of planning goes be-
omy to appointed local officials to encourage them yond the simple assertion that the private sector
to pursue globalization-oriented urban redevelop- influences urban development. Friedmann has de-
ment (Xu and Yeh, 2005). Here, the lack of account- fined planning as purposeful social action in the
ability of local governments both to capital and shaping of place, and privatization has been de-
communities paradoxically leads to the potential fined as an increase in private sector ownership
for overinvestment and economic instability. of or power over activities or assets that had previ-
Analyses of this sort requires an understanding of ously been in government hands (Friedmann, 1987;
historical and social context that is taken for granted Savas, 2000). Hence I define the privatization of
in studies of urban regimes in the United States. If planning as the transfer of responsibility for and
modified to account for local contextdifferences power over the visioning of urban futures and the
in state power and legitimacy, central-local relations, exercise of social action for urban change from
social relations based on gender, ethnicity, caste, public to private sector actors. This shift has been
landownership, and other variablesregime analysis predicated on a view that the for-profit private sec-
captures better than any other conceptualization the tor is more qualified and better equipped to
ways that local governments seek to form partner- restructure urban space in order to realize the goal
ships for political change, and the constrains and of economic advancement through global economic
opportunities they confront in doing so. It may integration. This stems in part from a perception
therefore help to explain the roots of contemporary that the public sector has failed to achieve these
political inequities both in history and in contempo- goals due to its proclivity for corruption, ineffi-
rary forms of integration into the global economy, ciency and authoritarianism, and in part from a be-
and reveal the ideological constructs that perpetuate lief that the corporate sector is better attuned to
these inequalities. At the same time, regime analysis the imperatives of economic growth and the desires
retains a focus on the power of the state, and its po- of multinational corporations and an emerging con-
tential as an agent for more redistributive policy and sumer classes.
planning outcomes. It therefore enables us to ask The privatization of planning is a function of sev-
policy and planning-relevant questions about socio- eral common constraints and incentives that govern-
economic and political change in the global era: ments face in the global era:
What political and economic interests do urban
 The development of an export-oriented economy
development outcomes represent? What alternative
sources of power exist? And, how might planners has given rise to powerful new political actors,
employ these to foster more equitable outcomes? most notably foreign and domestic corporate
interests and a consumer class, who demand new
The spatial implications of the privatization of types of consumer, residential, oce and industrial
planning space that are more economically ecient and con-
In globalizing cities, urban space is shaped by the sumer-oriented. In Asia in particular, the devalua-
interaction between global networks and local ac- tion of the Japanese Yen following the Plaza
tors and institutions. Inasmuch as local cultures Accords resulted in a wave of Japanese oshoring

10
Global cities of the South: Emerging perspectives on growth and inequality: G Shatkin

from the mid-1980s on that set in motion funda- changes to urban form while revealing the limita-
mental changes in the political economy of urban tions of comparisons with the racially polarized
development (Bello, 2004). landscapes of many American cities, defined as they
 At the same time, governments in many parts of are by blighted inner cities surrounded by anti-urban
the world nd themselves hemmed in by pressures sprawl. It is apparent that, even as urban regions are
being reshaped by new types of residential develop-
for scal austerity and therefore incapable of
ment and spatial expansion, the rejection of urbanity
responding to imperative to retrot cities to the
itself that characterizes urban development in many
needs of capital and consumers. Governments in American cities has yet to fully take hold in most
many parts of the world also face crises of legiti- other parts of the world, and may never do so. In
macy stemming from legacies of authoritarianism. many megacities, central city housing markets con-
 In this context, privatization has become part of tinue to be strong, and integrated megaprojects are
new models of governance advocated by interna- often quite dense and urban in character. Indeed,
tional aid and lending organizations, which some have argued that the reliance of the wealthy
emphasize scaled back government, local control in many societies on services provided by a relatively
and publicprivate partnership (Burgess et al., immobile urban poor precludes the type of spatial
1997; Miraftab, 2004a). polarization seen in the United States (Chakravorty,
 These changes have accompanied the emergence of 2000). One study in Chile finds that the development
of gated communities has actually decreased spatial
a number of multinational architectural and plan- separation of the wealthy and the poor as it allowed
ning consulting rms, and growth in domestic real the wealthy to live close to poor communities while
estate development industries. The latter has been still feeling secure, and that this proximity has had a
most notable in Asia. In Southeast Asia in partic- positive impact on interclass relations (Salcedo and
ular, developers, often of Chinese heritage, have Torres, 2004). Regardless of whether this dynamic
tapped into abundant sources of equity from inter- can be found elsewhere, the point to be made is that
national capital markets and networks of overseas local context and agency are critical to an under-
Chinese (Haila, 2000; Olds, 2001; Sajor, 2003). It is standing of spatial change.
also evident, however, in cities in Latin America Importantly, the perspective of the privatization of
and elsewhere (Pirez, 2002). planning shifts the focus from a supposedly uniform
process of adoption of Western cultural and social
In Asia, this process of privatization has been mores to policy-relevant questions about how the
manifest most clearly in the development in many goals of urban development should be defined, who
cities of private sector built integrated megaprojects should define them, and the potential roles of public
including residential, commercial and industrial and private sector interests in bringing about desired
space. Notable examples include Lippo Karawaci change. Why has the transfer of responsibility for
near Jakarta, Muang Thong Thani near Bangkok, city-building been shifted to the private sector, and
and Fort Bonifacio Global City in Metro Manila, what is the public rationale for doing so? What roles
which when initiated had projected populations do public and private actors play in redevelopment
upon completion of between 250,000 and one mil- and infrastructure projects? What levers of influence
lion (Dick and Rimmer, 1998; Hogan and Houston, does the public sector continue to employ, and to
2002; Marshall, 2003).3 These megaprojects are what ends does it use this influence? Whose interests
linked up by premium transportation infrastructure, are reflected in resulting changes to urban form,
including light rail lines and toll roads, that is also whose are disregarded, and why?
usually developed by the private sector, and some- These questions point to the important observa-
times by the developers of the megaprojects them- tion that any process of privatization must involve
selves (World Bank, 2004). Facilitated by active government facilitation through the restruc-
government assistance in land acquisition, subsidies turing of urban bureaucracies and relaxation of pub-
for transportation infrastructure, and political sup- lic influence over urban development. The potential
port, these projects represent efforts to transfer remains for the public sector to influence the direc-
responsibility for the visioning of urban futures tion of change even as the private sector plays a
and the definition of social goals to the private sec- growing role by: playing a role in defining the objec-
tor. In some cities a few large developers have begun tives of privately developed plans; mandating de-
to develop portfolios of geographically diversified sired outcomes like the development of affordable
megaprojects that are reshaping urban landscapes. housing or public participation; and shaping the pub-
A perspective of the privatization of planning lic discourse around private development projects.
helps to explain some cross-national similarities in Government can also exercise control over regional
development through land use regulation and other
forms of intervention in land markets, and through
3
It should be noted, however, that current populations are much transportation planning. There is considerable varia-
smaller. tion in the degree to which they do so.

11
Global cities of the South: Emerging perspectives on growth and inequality: G Shatkin

In sum, the idea of the privatization of planning contract and short-term labor, and the placement of
departs from a focus on convergence in that it leaves age and gender restrictions on employment, and
the door open to government and community-based the use by local government of both formal powers
agency. It leads to practical and important questions and informal social relations to reduce the power of
about the exercise of urban governance for equity unions and foster the development of a compliant la-
objectives. bor force. Research has only begun to examine the
development of what Kelly (2001) has referred to
as local labor control regimes. One exception is his
The flexiblization of labor study of labor market processes in export processing
Finally, this paper suggests the concept of the flexib- zones in the Philippines, which attempts to overcome
lization of labor as an alternative to the perspectives simplistic depictions of straightforward exploitation
of socioeconomic dualization and polarization. of abundant, cheap, and place-bound labor by space-
There are at least two reasons that the perspective controlling international capital (Kelly, 2001, p. 2).
on dualization and social polarization does not ade- His analysis reveals the ways in which labor relations
quately capture the social outcomes of globalization are shaped by norms governing local social relations
in all contexts. First, as Chakravorty (2000) notes, the that are deeply rooted in the historical development
deindustrialization that has bred the decline of the of the locality. Specifically, it points to the role of
middle class in the United States and other post-For- gender relations in Philippine households, and to
dist societies implies its opposite in developing coun- the role of local political bosses in the Philippine
tries, many of which have seen a growth in political economy, in shaping labor markets and
manufacturing production. The benefits of this working conditions.
deconcentration of industrial production have spread Another aspect of this process of flexiblization is
unevenly, with Latin America and Africa experienc- the role of the informal economy. In order to be use-
ing severe economic dislocation and less benefit than ful, the concepts of informalization and the informal
Asia, but a simple focus on polarization denies the economy must first be stripped of their ideological
significant amount of economic opportunity that this overtones. The informal economy represents neither
process has afforded. Second, the idea of polariza- heroic entrepreneurship, as represented in the work
tion, if defined based on material living conditions of DeSoto and others, nor uniform oppression, as of-
alone, does not capture the complex relationship be- ten represented by some on the political left (Roy,
tween economic well being and social status that has 2005). The informal also does not constitute a sepa-
emerged with the globalization of many urban econ- rate sector, cut off from the rest of the economy
omies. It is apparent that the rhetoric surrounding and mired in backwardness. Rather, the informal
global city development has shaped popular percep- economy should be viewed as a set of economic
tions of social class in important ways (Machimura, activities that are unregulated by the institutions
1998; Kelly, 2000). An excellent example of this is of society, in a legal and social environment in which
Auyeros (1999) poignant description of the paradox- similar activities are regulated, and that constitute
ical situation of residents of one Argentine slum, who an increasingly important part of the flexible and
have experienced gradual improvement in material adaptable labor markets that drive the global econ-
living conditions even as their employment prospects omy (Castells and Portes, 1989: 12). The informal
have become increasingly tenuous and they have economy has persisted with globalization, and grown
experienced intense discrimination due to public per- in many contexts, reflecting the strategies of eco-
ceptions of their community as economically redun- nomic actors and state institutions as they have
dant and socially dysfunctional. sought new modes of economic organization that
The concept of the flexiblization of labor attempts are conducive to export-oriented production. Cas-
to capture the coexistence of opportunity and inse- tells and Portes (1989) refer to several specific
curity that characterizes labor markets in the global- causes of informalization linked to globalization,
izing cities of developing countries. Corporations including: growing anti-union sentiment both among
face increasing competition even as they are able firms and, to a lesser degree, elements of the work-
to tap into a global labor pool, and they have reacted ing class, as a reaction to economic crisis and new
by seeking labor that is flexible, trainable, adaptable, opportunities in the global economy; reaction by
and cheap. As labor markets and legal frameworks firms and workers against state regulation of the
have responded to this imperative, practices such economy for the same reasons; and the emergence
as outsourcing, employment of home-based workers, of a particular form of industrialization in many
and contract work have become commonplace in the developing countries that relies on less regulated la-
corporate sector, and increasingly the public sector bor markets.
as well. A third aspect of flexiblization is the use of legal
An important outcome of this process has been the and illegal immigrant labor (Douglass, 2001). While
employment of a range of formal and informal insti- this has been discussed extensively in the context of
tutions by local and national governments, and firms, global/world cities in the advanced economies,
to discipline labor. These include the use by firms of immigrant labor has come to play a significant role

12
Global cities of the South: Emerging perspectives on growth and inequality: G Shatkin

in labor markets in many cities, including Bangkok, by Sassen and others during the 1980s and early
Kuala Lumpur, Taipei, and many others. 1990s. The terms of debate appear to have hardened
As is apparent from the preceding discussion, the somewhat too early and with reference to too little
concept of the flexiblization of labor is useful in ana- data. Indeed, it would seem that local responses,
lyzing change in most parts of the world, including and the process of globalization itself, have proven
the developed economies, many of which are wit- too dynamic and complex to be understood with ref-
nessing increases in immigration, the rise of contract erence to a small set of models of change (e.g. seg-
labor, and informal economic activities. What a fo- regation, polarization, and American style growth
cus on the flexiblization of labor allows us to do, regime politics).
however, is to focus on the distinct contexts in which Underlying this discussion has been a concern
these processes play out rather than an assumed set that a focus on convergence provides a less de-
of socioeconomic outcomes modeled primarily on tailed and precise analysis that causes us to miss
the American experience. This framework draws critical issues that face global cities. Such cities
attention on the actors involved in urban economic face a number of pressing challengesintense eco-
development, including state agencies, firms, and nomic competition, a global atmosphere of market
workers, and the social institutions and external triumphalism, pressures for fiscal austerity, and
pressures that shape their behavior. It also incorpo- calls from international agencies for a scaled back
rates an understanding of the distributional impacts role for government in city-building. A critical task
of changes in labor markets, which may reflect the of urban theory is to understand how actors in cit-
influence of gender, age, race, ethnicity and other ies respond to these challenges, and who benefits
variables on social behavior (Miraftab, 2004b). It re- from the outcomes. How have new economic and
veals specific issues related to labor rights, discrimi- political pressures shaped national and local gov-
nation based on gender and other forms of ernment efforts to bring other actors into policy
difference, and the lack of representation of labor and planning? And, what are the distributional
and community interests in local governance, that outcomes of the resulting changes in governance?
provide more detail to a political agenda for equity This paper has argued that the answers to these
in urban development. questions differ significantly in different contexts,
and that there is much to be learned from these
differences for both theory and for the practice
Conclusion of urban planning and policy. This process of
This paper has argued that the growing focus on learning, however, requires that we move beyond
convergence of political, social and spatial out- generalizations based on the experience of global
comes serves to distract us from a more careful cities in the West and adopt frameworks that em-
analysis of globalization and urban change in devel- brace complexity and difference, and that contrib-
oping countries. It has reviewed a number of ute to cross-national comparison and learning.
emerging perspectives in the global/world cities lit-
erature that reveal the highly divergent experiences
that cities have had with global economic integra- Acknowledgment
tion, the ways in which the local interacts with
The research for this paper was supported by Na-
and reshapes global influences, and the importance
tional Science Foundation Grant number 0424066.
of understanding actors and interests in an analysis
of urban change. Finally, it has made a tentative at-
tempt to reframe the hypothesized link between References
global city development and social, political and
Abu-Lughod, J (1999) New York, Chicago, Los Angeles: Amer-
spatial inequality in a way that accounts for differ- icas Global Cities. University of Minnesota Press,
ence and local agency. Minneapolis.
While the paper has focused specifically on cri- AlSayyad, N (2001a) Hybrid Culture/Hybrid Urbanism: Pandoras
tiquing the strong tendency of studies of global cities Box of the Third Place. In Hybrid Urbanism, (ed.) N
AlSayyad. pp. 120. Praeger, Wesport.
in developing countries to assume that their devel- Audirac, I (2003) Information-age landscapes outside the devel-
opment is following a similar trajectory to those of oped world: Bangalore, India and Guadelajara, Mexico.
the West, it has also found common ground with cri- Journal of the American Planning Association 69(1), 1632.
tiques of generalizations about global city develop- Auyero, J (1999) This is a Lot Like the Bronx, isnt it? Lived
Experiences of Marginality in an Argentine Slum. International
ment more generally. Indeed the framework Journal of Urban and Regional Research 23(1), 4569.
developed here might be useful to rethinking global Beaverstock, J, Taylor, P and Smith, R (1999) A roster of world
city development in the context of developed coun- cities. Cities 16(6), 444458.
try cities as well. It would seem that much of the glo- Bello, W (2004) The Anti-Development State: The Political
bal cities literature is caught in a rut, repeatedly Economy of Permanent Crisis in the Philippines, Department
of Sociology. University of the Philippines, Quezon City.
revisiting the core debates that emerged from the Bunnell, T (2002) Multimedia utopia? A geographical critique of
remarkable set of observations regarding the im- high-tech development in Malaysia. Antipode: A Radical
pacts of globalization on a select set of cities made Journal of Geography 34(2), 265295.

13
Global cities of the South: Emerging perspectives on growth and inequality: G Shatkin
Burgess, R, and Haksar, V (2005) Migration and Foreign Grant, R and Nijman, J (2002) Globalization and the corporate
Remittances in the Philippines, IMF Working Paper Series geography of cities in the less developed world. Annals of the
Number 05/111. Association of American Geographers 92(2), 320340.
Burgess, R, Carmona, M and Kolstee, T (1997) The Challenge of Haila, A (2000) Real estate in global cities: Singapore and Hong
Sustainable Cities: Neoliberalism and Urban Strategies in Kong as property states. Urban Studies 37(12), 22412256.
Developing Countries. Zed Books, London. Hill, Richard Child (2004) Cities and nested hierarchies. Interna-
Burki, S, Perry, G and Dillinger, W (1999) Beyond the Center: tional Social Science Journal 56(181), 373384.
Decentralizing the State. World Bank, Washington, DC. Hill, R and Kim, J (2000) Global cities and developmental
Castells, M and Portes, A (1989) World underneath: the origins, states: New York, Tokyo and Seoul. Urban Studies 12(37),
dynamics, and effects of the informal economy. In The 22412256.
Informal Economy: Studies in Advanced and Less Developed Hogan, T and Houston, T (2002) Corporate Cities: Urban
Countries, (eds.) A Portes, M Castells and L Benton. pp. 11 Gateways of Gated Communities Against the City: The Case
37. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore. of Lippo, Jakarta. In Critical Reflections on Cities in Southeast
Castells, M, Goh, L and Kwok, R (1990) The Shek Kip Mei Asia, (eds.) T Bunnell, L Drummond and K Ho. pp. 43264.
Syndrome: Economic Development and Public Housing in Times Academic Press, Singapore.
Hong Kong and Singapore. Pion, London. Kelly, P (2001) The political economy of local labor control in the
Chakravorty, S (2000) From colonial city to globalizing city?: The Philippines. Economic Geography 77(1), 122.
far-from-complete spatial transformation of Calcutta. In Glob- Kelly, P (2000) Landscapes of Globalization: Human Geogra-
alizing Cities: A New Spatial Order, (eds.) P Marcuse and R phies of Economic Change in the Philippines. Routledge,
van Kempen. pp. 5677. Blackwell, London. London.
Chiu, S and Lui, T (2004) Testing the global city-social polarisation Keyder, C (2005) Globalization and social exclusion in Istanbul.
thesis: Hong kong since the 1990s. Urban Studies 41(10), 1863 International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 29(1),
1888. 124134.
Cohen, M (1996) The hypothesis of urban convergence: Are cities King, A (2004). Spaces of Global Cultures: Architecture, Urbanism,
in the north and south becoming more alike in an age of Identity. Routledge, London.
globalization? In Preparing for the Urban Future: Global Kusno, A (2000) Behind the Postcolonial. Routledge, London.
Pressures and Local Forces, (eds.) M Cohen, B Ruble, J Leichencko, R and Solecki, W (2005) Exporting the American
Tulchin and A Garland. pp. 2538. The Woodrow Wilson dream: the globalization of suburban consumption landscapes.
Center Press, Washington, DC. Regional Studies 39(2), 241253.
Cowherd, R and Heikkila, E (2002) Orange county, java: Logan, J and Molotch, H (1987) Urban Fortunes: The Political
Hybridity, social dualism and an imagined west. In Southern Economy of Place. University of California Press, Berkeley.
California and the World, (eds.) E Heikkela and R Pizarro. Machimura, T (1998) Symbolic uses of globalization in urban
Praeger, Westport. politics in Tokyo. International Journal of Urban and Regional
Davis, D (2005a) Cites in global context: A brief intellectual Research 22(2), 183194.
history. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research Maimbo, S and Ratha, D (eds.) (2005) Remittances: Development
29(1), 92109. Impacts and Future Prospects. The World Bank, Washington,
Davis, D (ed.) (2000) The Consumer Revolution in Urban China. DC.
University of California Press, Berkeley. Marcuse, P (1997) The enclave, the citadel, and the ghetto: What
Dick, H and Rimmer, P (1998) Beyond the third world city: The has changed in the post-Fordist US city. Urban Affairs Review
new urban geography of south-east Asia. Urban Studies 35(12), 33(2), 228264.
23032321. Marcuse, P and van Kempen, R (2000a) Conclusion: A new
Douglass, M (2001) Intercity competition and the question of spatial order. In Globalizing Cities: A New Spatial Order,
economic resilience: Globalization and crisis in Asia. In Global (eds.) P Marcuse and R van Kempen. pp. 249275. Blackwell,
City-Regions: Trends, Theory, Policy, (ed.) A Scott. pp. 236 London.
262. Oxford University Press, Oxford. Markusen, A (2004) The work of forgetting and remembering
Douglass, M (1995) Bringing culture in: Locality and global places. Urban Studies 41(12), 23032314.
capitalism in east Asia. Third World Planning Review 17(3), Marshall, R (2003) Emerging Urbanity: Global Urban Projects in
iiiix. the Asia Pacic Rim. Spon Press, London.
Douglass, M (1994) The developmental state and the newly Miraftab, F (2004a) Publicprivate partnerships: Trojan horse of
industrialised economies of Asia. Environment and Planning A neoliberal development? Journal of Planning Education and
26(4), 543566. Research 24(1), 89101.
Fainstein, S (1995) Politics, economics, and planning: why urban Miraftab, F (2004b) Neoliberalism and casualization of public
regimes matter. Planning Theory 14, 3441. sector services: The case of waste collection services in Cape
Fainstein, S and Judd, D (eds.) (1999) The Tourist City. Yale Town, South Africa. International Journal of Urban and
University Press, New Haven. Regional Research 28(4), 874.
Firman, T (2004) New town development in Jakarta metropolitan Mollenkopf, J and Castells, M (eds.) (1991) Dual City: Restruc-
region: A perspective of spatial segregation. Habitat Interna- turing New York. Russell Sage Foundation, New York.
tional 28(3), 349368. Mullins, P (1999) International tourism and the cities of Southeast
Firman, T (1998) The restructuring of Jakarta metropolitan area: Asia. In The Tourist City, (eds.) S Fainstein and D Judd. pp.
A global city in Asia. Cities 15(4), 229243. 245260. Yale University Press, New Haven.
Firman, T (1997) Land conversion and urban development in the Nasr, J and Volait, M (2003a) Urbanism Imported or Exported?:
northern region of West Java, Indonesia. Urban Studies 34(7), Native Aspirations and Foreign Plans. Academy Editions,
10271046. London.
Flusty, S (2004) De-Coca-Colonization: Making the Globe from Nasr, J and Volait, M (2003b) Introduction: transporting planning.
the Inside Out. Routledge, London. In Urbanism Imported or Exported?: Native Aspirations and
Friedmann, J (1995) Where we stand? A decade of world city Foreign Plans, (eds.) J Nasr and M Volait. Academy Editions,
research. In World Cities in a World System, (eds.) P Knox and London.
P Taylor. pp. 2147. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Olds, K (2001) Globalization and Urban Change: Capital, Culture,
Friedmann, J (1987) Planning in the Public Domain: From Knowl- and Pacic Rim Megaprojects. Oxford University Press,
edge to Action. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ. Oxford.
Graizborg, B, Rowland, A and Aguilar, A (2003) Mexico City as a Pirez, P (2002) Buenos Aires: Fragmentation and privatization of
peripheral global player: The two sides of the coin. The Annals the metropolitan city. Environment and Urbanization 14(1),
of Regional Science 37, 501508. 145158.

14
Global cities of the South: Emerging perspectives on growth and inequality: G Shatkin
Roberts, B (2005) Globalization and Latin American cities. Stone, C (1993) Urban regimes and the capacity to govern: A
International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 29(1), political economy approach. Journal of Urban Affairs 15(1),
110123. 128.
Robinson, J (2002) Global and world cities: A view from off the Stone, C (1989) Regime Politics: Governing Atlanta, 19461988.
map. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research University Press of Kansas, Kansas.
26(3), 531554. Taylor, P (2005) Leading world cities: Empirical evaluations of
Roy, A (2005) Urban informality: Toward an epistemology of urban nodes in multiple networks. Urban Studies 42(9), 1593
planning. Journal of the American Planning Association 71(2), 1608.
147158. Taylor, P, Walker, D, Catalano, G and Hoyler, M (2002) Diversity
Sajor, E (2005) Professionalisation or hybridisation? Real estate and power in the world city network. Cities 19(4), 231241.
brokers in Metro Cebu, the Philippines, during the boom of the Tyner, J (2000) Global cities and circuits of global labor: The
1990s. Urban Studies 42(8), 13211343. case of Manila, Philippines. Professional Geographer 52(1),
Sajor, E (2003) Globalization and the urban property boom in 6174.
Metro Cebu, Philippines. Development and Change 34(4), 713 UN Habitat (2005) Financing Urban Shelter: Global Report on
741. Human Settlements 2005. Earthscan, London.
Salcedo, R and Torres, A (2004) Gated communities in Santiago: Vidyarthi, S (2005) Informalizing the formal and localizing the
Wall or frontier? International Journal of Urban and Regional global: a theoretical framework to understand acts of appro-
Research 28(1), 2744. priation. Paper presented at the Association of Collegiate
Sanyal, B (ed.) (2005) Comparative Planning Culture. Routledge, Schools of Planning Annual Meeting, Kansas City, October
New York. 2730.
Sassen, S (1998) Globalization and its Discontents. The New Press, White, J (1998) Old wine, cracked bottle? Tokyo, Paris, and
New York. the global Cities hypothesis. Urban Affairs Review 33(4),
Sassen, S (2001) Global cities and developmentalist states: How to 451477.
derail what could be an interesting debate? A response to Hill World Bank (2004) A Tale of Three Cities: Urban Rail Conces-
and Kim. Urban Studies 38(13), 25372540. sions in Bangkok, Kuala Lumpur, and Manila. Report
Savas, E (2000) Privatization and PublicPrivate Partnerships. prepared by the Halcrow Group Limited, December 2nd.
Chatham House, New York. World Bank (2000) Cities in Transition. World Bank, Washington,
Scott, A, Agnew, J, Soja, E and Storper, M (2001) Global city- DC.
regions. In Global City-Regions: Trends, Theory, Policy, (ed.) Wu, F and Webber, K (2004) The rise of foreign gated
A Scott. Oxford University Press, Oxford. communities in Beijing: Between economic globalization and
Shatkin, G (1998) Fourth World cities in the global economy: The local institutions. Cities 21(3), 203213.
case of Phnom Penh, Cambodia. International Journal of Xu, J and Yeh, A (2005) City repositioning and competitiveness
Urban and Regional Research 22(3), 378. building in regional development: New development strategies
Simon, D (1995) The world city hypothesis: Reections from the in Guangzhou, China. International Journal of Urban and
periphery. In World Cities in a World System, (eds.) P Knox and Regional Research 29(2), 283308.
P Taylor. pp. 132155. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Yeoh, B (1999) Global/globalizing cities. Progress in Human
Sklair, L (2005) The transnational capitalist class and contempo- Geography 23(4), 607616.
rary architecture in globalizing cities. International Journal of Zhang, T (2002) Urban development and a socialist pro-growth
Urban and Regional Research 29(3), 485. coalition in China. Urban Affairs Review 37(4), 475499.

15

Potrebbero piacerti anche