Sei sulla pagina 1di 24

Academy of Management Review

2007, Vol. 32, No. 3, 794816.

STAKEHOLDER INFLUENCE CAPACITY AND


THE VARIABILITY OF FINANCIAL RETURNS TO
CORPORATE SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY
MICHAEL L. BARNETT
University of South Florida

I argue that research on the business case for corporate social responsibility must
account for the path-dependent nature of firm-stakeholder relations, and I develop the
construct of stakeholder influence capacity to fill this void. This construct helps
explain why the effects of corporate social responsibility on corporate financial
performance vary across firms and time. I develop a set of propositions to aid future
research on the contingencies that produce variable financial returns to investment in
corporate social responsibility.

John Hyde, a retiree in Placerville, Calif., says its tions draw resources from society, they have a
hard to believe Philip Morris is a good guy just moral obligation to give back to society,
because it donates water to flood victims, or
helps the hungry (Alsop, 2002: 1). whereas others counter that corporations are in-
efficient and inappropriate agents of social
There is a lot of skepticism out there when a change, and any voluntary contributions to so-
company like McDonalds starts to talk about sal-
ads, because people know McDonalds is not es- cial causes are misappropriations of sharehold-
pecially concerned about the health of America ers funds (Friedman, 1970).
(Rich Polt, consultant, quoted in Dressel, 2003: 1). Given the intractability of this ongoing ethical
I guess it depends if its [the firms participation debate, many researchers have turned to exam-
in an act of corporate social responsibility] part of ination of the business case for corporate so-
the total picture and [if] they really go out of their cial responsibility (CSR). A large and ever-
way. Like with Kroger, it isnt a one-time shot, growing body of literature has investigated
theyre always doing stuff for Egleston [Chil- whether the financial benefits to the corporation
drens Hospital], or theyve got the big barrels out
there for the people to bring cans for the home- can meet or exceed the costs of its contributions
less or something at Thanksgiving and Christ- to social welfare (for recent reviews, see Margo-
mas. It just seems more a way of business for lis & Walsh, 2003, and Orlitzky, Schmidt, &
them, continuously, so in that case, thats fine. . . . Rynes, 2003). If so, CSR can be justified as a wise
But if somebodys doing it just for the publicity, investment; if not, CSR can be condemned as an
then that would not make me think better of them
(survey respondent quoted in Webb & Mohr, 1998: agency problem. The result is that after more
235). than thirty years of research, we cannot clearly
conclude whether a one-dollar investment in so-
Should public corporations serve as agents of cial initiatives returns more or less than one
progressive social change? For example, should dollar in benefit to the shareholder.
Levi Strauss fund a campaign to end racism? The lingering murkiness of the business case
Should Ford contribute to finding a cure for has been attributed to a variety of shortcomings
AIDS? If so, how much should these corporations present in the research of scholars approaching
contribute to these social causes? Because there the topic from myriad (a)theoretical angles (Grif-
are ethical considerations inherent in answer- fin & Mahon, 1997; Ullmann, 1985). Yet even as
ing these questions, reasonable people can and the rigor of CSR studies has increased to ad-
do disagree. Some argue that because corpora- dress these shortcomings, the link between CSR
and financial performance has become only
murkier. Margolis and Walsh recently described
I thank John Jermier, Rob Salomon, Sandra Waddock, Tim this body of research as self-perpetuating: each
Fort, and the anonymous reviewers for advice on assorted
aspects of this manuscript. I also thank the College of Busi-
successive study promises a definitive conclu-
ness Administration at the University of South Florida for sion, while also revealing the inevitable inade-
summer financial support. quacies of empirically tackling the question
794
Copyright of the Academy of Management, all rights reserved. Contents may not be copied, emailed, posted to a listserv, or otherwise transmitted without the copyright
holders express written permission. Users may print, download, or email articles for individual use only.
2007 Barnett 795

(2003: 278). As a result, it reinforces, rather than as a result of stakeholder influence capacity, a
relieves, the tension surrounding corporate re- construct that captures variation across and
sponses to social misery (Margolis & Walsh, within firms in their ability to use CSR to prof-
2003: 278). Thus, the seemingly tractable busi- itably improve relationships.
ness case for CSR remains just as debatable as I next present an overview of the business
the associated ethical dilemma. case for CSR. I then distinguish CSR from sev-
The continuing chaos surrounding the busi- eral related and sometimes confounded con-
ness case should not come as a surprise. The cepts. Thereafter, I introduce the construct of
unique and dynamic characteristics of firms and stakeholder influence capacity, embed it within
their environments preclude stability in finan- a conceptual framework, and elaborate the
cial returns to CSR across firms and time, so we bounds of this framework through a set of prop-
should not expect to empirically discern a con- ositions. The paper concludes with an extended
sistent financial benefit essentially, a univer- discussion of the implications of stakeholder in-
sal rate of returnto a generic corporation for fluence capacity for the future of CSR research
some given unit of social investment. Consider and practice.
McDonalds and Subway restaurants. Although
they are both in the same industry and so face
THE BUSINESS CASE FOR CSR
similar competitive conditions, were each to
contribute $1 million to efforts to curb obesity, it CSR is often described as any discretionary
is unlikely they would experience identical fi- corporate activity intended to further social wel-
nancial returns. In fact, their returns could differ fare. For example, Target reported that it do-
radically, with one achieving a positive return nates more than $2 million each week to the arts,
and the other experiencing losses. Even within education, and social services in the communi-
the same firm, identical levels of CSR invest- ties in which its stores operate. The presence of
ment over different time periods are likely to discretion is key. Many corporate activities that
lead to different financial returns, such as be- further social welfare are mandated by law,
fore and after lawsuits, intense media scrutiny, such as equal employment opportunity and
or other external shocks (cf. Alsop, 2002; Hoff- medical leave. But why, in the face of often-
man, 1997). Thus, efforts to universally legitimize fierce competition, do for-profit firms voluntarily
or condemn the business case are theoretically allocate additional limited resources to social
untenable (Rowley & Berman, 2000: 406). welfare as an almost universal practice
Researchers have often overlooked the many (Dressel, 2003: 1)? Certainly, these resources
contingencies that cause variability in returns could be put to better use in improving the effi-
to CSR, perhaps in their zeal to legitimize or ciency of the firm, or could be returned to share-
discredit the business case (Rowley & Berman, holders.
2000; Ullmann, 1985). As a result, the business This is the core of the argument against CSR.
case has been neither made nor discredited, Critics of CSR contend that expending limited
despite extensive research (Margolis & Walsh, resources on social issues necessarily de-
2003). My goal for this paper is to help reorient creases the competitive position of a firm by
CSR research away from the long-fought battle unnecessarily increasing its costs. Furthermore,
for replicable empirical findings of the financial even if a firm has slack resources but no favor-
returns to CSR in general and toward a quest for able investment opportunities, and even if the
deeper understanding of the underlying drivers costs of CSR are not ample enough to put the
of whether and when particular firms may earn firm at a competitive disadvantage, the firm
positive financial returns from CSRin short, to should still refrain from CSR. Devoting corpo-
make the business case firm specific, not uni- rate resources to social welfare is tantamount to
versal. In furtherance of this goal, I present a an involuntary redistribution of wealth, from
conceptual framework that illustrates how firms shareholders, as rightful owners of the corpora-
generate financial returns from acts of CSR. tion, to others in society who have no rightful
Building on the stakeholder theory argument claim. Thus, CSR, although almost universally
that firms can benefit financially from attending practiced, is considered by some to be an
to the concerns of their stakeholders (Freeman, agency loss; managers pursue CSR for personal
1984), I discuss how these financial benefits vary gain, not shareholder benefit (Friedman, 1970).
796 Academy of Management Review July

McWilliams and Siegels definition of CSR, Walsh (2003) tallied thirteen reviews since 1978.
though they argue for a neutral relationship be- In one of the earlier instances, Ullmann (1985)
tween CSR and financial performance, exempli- described this body of research as data in
fies the agency loss perspective: We define search of a theory. A dozen years later, Griffin
CSR as actions that appear to further some so- and Mahon (1997) entitled their review Twenty-
cial good, beyond the interests of the firm and Five Years of Incomparable Research. Roman,
that which is required by law (2001: 117; empha- Hayibor, and Agle (1999) repainted the portrait
sis added). Simply put, critics contend that CSR they ascribed to Griffin and Mahons (1997) crit-
is not in the firms interests and so should not be ical study to recast it as more supportive of the
countenanced. business case, but Mahon and Griffin (1999) im-
CSR proponents counter that when one takes mediately repainted that repaint so as to return
a more enlightened view of how firms achieve the portrait to its original critical state. Most
competitive advantage, one can see that CSR is, recently, Orlistky et al. (2003) performed a meta-
in fact, in firms best interests. Stakeholder the- analysis of the population of quantitative stud-
ory (Freeman, 1984), the cornerstone of the busi- ies to date and found support for the business
ness case for CSR, highlights the importance of case. Margolis and Walsh (2003: 278), however,
a firms relationships with a broad set of indi- argued that any conclusion that the business
viduals and organizations, beyond just share- case is now established because more empirical
holders. Instrumental stakeholder theory (Jones, studies have been published in support of it
1995) further clarifies how CSR contributes to the than against it is illusory.
bottom line via its favorable influence on the The question remains without a definitive an-
firms relationships with important stakehold- swer. The mixed findings have been attributed
ers. The importance of stakeholders can be de- to a variety of shortcomings: a lack in theory,
termined by their relative power, legitimacy, inappropriate definition of key terms, and defi-
and urgency (Mitchell, Agle, & Wood, 1997). The ciencies in the empirical data bases currently
overall logic is that CSR (e.g., philanthropy) in- available (Ullmann, 1985: 540); stakeholder mis-
creases the trustworthiness of a firm and so matching (Wood & Jones, 1995); conceptual, op-
strengthens relationships with important stake- erationalization, and methodological differ-
holders (e.g., increases employee satisfaction), ences in the definitions of social and financial
which decreases transaction costs and so leads performance (Griffin & Mahon, 1997: 6); failure
to financial gain (e.g., decreased employee turn- to control for risk, industry affiliation, and asset
over, more eager talent pool, union avoidance). age (Cochran & Wood, 1984); and failure to con-
CSR can differentiate a firms products (Porter, trol for investment in R&D (McWilliams & Siegel,
1991), reduce its operating costs (King & Lenox, 2000). Many of these shortcomings have been
2000), and serve as a platform for future oppor- repeated in subsequent studies, but many have
tunities, as well as a buffer from disruptive also been corrected as they have been brought
events (Fombrun, Gardberg, & Barnett, 2000). to light.
Thus, from this angle, one can view CSR as an CSR studies have improved over time, offering
investment, perhaps with sizable financial re- stronger theoretical rationales, more relevant
turns, in addition to or despite any benefits that operationalizations, and more and better con-
might accrue to society. In short, CSR supporters trols for previously omitted variables. Yet the
argue that there is ample private incentive for improved rigor has only produced rigor mortis.
improving social welfare. Mahon and Griffin have argued that twenty-five
So, does CSR build or destroy corporate years of research has not produced a solution
wealth? Over the last three decades, many re- but, rather, isolated islands of partial insight
searchers have taken on the task of empirically about an unseen larger picture, akin to the fa-
testing the business case. According to Orlitzky ble of the five blind Indian men (1999: 126). As
et al. (2003), fifty-two quantitative studies have Rowley and Berman put it, Researchers have
been published on this topic. Margolis and combined various mishmashes of uncorrelated
Walsh (2003) put this figure at 127. For more than variables, which render correlation and ordi-
two decades, researchers have also taken on the nary least squares regression results indiscern-
task of reviewing these many studies and be- ible (2000: 405). Margolis and Walsh (2003) con-
moaning the mixed findings. Margolis and cur that, even after thirty years of research, with
2007 Barnett 797

scholars increasing the depth and breadth of al., 2003) of the business case, all refer to CSP
their databases, differences in perspective have studies. Although CSR and CSP are often
only cumulated, not dissipated, thereby further used interchangeably, there is an important dis-
obscuring the big picture. tinction. CSP may be described as a snapshot of
Rowley and Berman (2000) further argue that a firms overall social performance at a particu-
efforts to universally prove the business case lar point in timea summary of the firms ag-
are doomed to failure, no matter how ingenious gregate social posture. For example, Woods
the theory, crystal clear the terminology, or rig- commonly cited definition of CSP is a business
orous the data and methodology. They contend organizations configuration of principles of so-
that the thirty-year quest represents an attempt cial responsibility, processes of social respon-
to legitimize the researcher and the business siveness, and policies, programs, and observ-
and society field, rather than build understand- able outcomes as they relate to the firms social
ing (2000: 401). Theory and empirics that sug- relationships (1991: 693). Many researchers
gest a universally favorable rate of return to have attempted to gauge a firms CSP at a point
CSR validate the business case and so help to in time and, more rarely, over time, through such
legitimize the business and society field. Yet it measures as reputation rankings and stake-
is clear that CSR cannot universally produce holder surveys, and then correlate these proxies
favorable returns for all firms all the time, so for CSP to CFP (Margolis & Walsh, 2003).
favorable findings will never be replicable Although certainly of interest, this body of re-
across all data sets. Returns to CSR are contin- search does not directly aid managers in mak-
gent, not universal (Ullmann, 1985). Although ing decisions about devoting limited resources
some studies have begun to empirically tease to socially responsible actions in the face of
apart these contingencies (Barnett & Salomon, competing demands. Rather, CSPCFP studies
2006; McWilliams & Siegel, 2000; Orlitzky et al., address the financial benefits of having
2003), Rowley and Berman (2000) argue that the achieved a certain socially responsible posture
results of such studies are not interpretable be- at a particular point in time. Either a firm has
cause the theoretical underpinnings to explain achieved this posture, and so might expect these
which contingencies are relevant have not yet benefits (or harms), or a firm has not achieved
been established. Therefore, researchers should this posture, and so should not expect them.
attempt to develop theory that explains hetero- Often unexplained and untested are the costs
geneity in financial returns to CSR. In the re- and benefits of gaining this posturethe incre-
mainder of this paper I heed this call. mental steps toward attainment of a certain
strategic CSP posture, or the value of discrete or
less directed socially oriented activities under-
THE BOUNDARIES OF CSR
taken as a firm muddles (Lindblom, 1959) its
CSR research has often been criticized for run- way through its strategy.
ning fast and loose with its concepts (Griffin & Firms are not imbued with a certain CSP state.
Mahon, 1997; Ullmann, 1985). In this section I There is no market for CSP wherein such a
define CSR and demarcate its boundaries by state can be purchased. Rather, firms make in-
distinguishing it from related concepts. vestments that, over time, aggregate into certain
CSP postures. These investments are CSR. For
example, Ben & Jerrys created a favorable CSP
Distinguishing CSR from Corporate Social
posture through the CSR activities of its Ben &
Performance
Jerrys Foundation and its involvement in a va-
This study explores the business case for CSR riety of specific campaigns, such as One Sweet
by examining how acts of CSR influence corpo- Whirled and Rock the Vote. Was each of these
rate financial performance (CFP). In contrast, activities a wise corporate investment? That is
most studies of the business case have exam- the question of interest in this paper, so CSR is
ined the relationship between corporate social used.1
performance (CSP) and CFP. For example, re-
cent comprehensive reviews, both critical (Grif-
fin & Mahon, 1997; Margolis & Walsh, 2003; Row- 1
Nonetheless, CSP and CSR are both important factors in
ley & Berman, 2000) and supportive (Orlitzky et predicting the marginal returns to social investment oppor-
798 Academy of Management Review July

Distinguishing CSR from Other Corporate can be considered an investment. In order to


Resource Allocations increase CFP, an act of CSR must ultimately
increase a firms revenues or decrease its costs.
Recent scandals have channeled a great deal
Unfortunately, the mechanisms by which CSR
of attention toward acts of CSR, but these con-
can do this are not always clear. Many early
stitute only a subset of the many activities in
studies did not offer a theoretical framework to
which corporations engage. Arguably, all law-
demonstrate this and were therefore dismissed
abiding and profit-maximizing corporate activi-
as atheoretical (Ullmann, 1985). The advent of a
ties have a social component because they help
stakeholder perspective (Freeman, 1984) helped
to improve the economic conditions that support
dampen these criticisms but did not silence
society. As Friedman put it, There is one and
them because its vague boundaries frustrated
only one social responsibility of businessto
the development of a viable stakeholder theory
use its resources and engage in activities to
of the firm (Donaldson & Preston, 1995). Instru-
increase its profits so long as it stays within the
mental stakeholder theory (Jones, 1995) brought
rules of the game (1970: 126). Yet such a broad
stronger theoretical underpinnings to the busi-
conception of CSR only confounds the study of
ness case, primarily by linking it to transaction
the business case. In terms of social responsi-
cost economics (Williamson, 1975):
bility, is the construction of a new plant, with an
attendant increase in employment, akin to the Certain types of corporate social performance are
establishment of a company day care center or a manifestations of attempts to establish trusting,
donation to a local charity? Relatively few cooperative firm/stakeholder relationships and
scholars have interpreted CSR as broadly as should be positively linked to a companys finan-
Friedman (1970), but CSR scholars have made cial performance. . . . firms that contract with
their stakeholders on the basis of mutual trust
generous use of the concept. Where do the ap-
and cooperation will have a competitive advan-
propriate boundaries lie? tage over firms that do not. . . . [This advantage
Within the boundaries of CSR. There are two stems from] reduced agency costs, transaction
characteristics that distinguish acts of CSR from costs, and costs associated with team production.
other corporate investments: social welfare ori- More specifically, monitoring costs, bonding
costs, search costs, warranty costs, and residual
entation and stakeholder relationship orienta-
losses will be reduced (Jones, 1995: 422, 430).
tion. The most obvious and distinctive charac-
teristic of an act of CSR is its focus on increasing
Others have augmented stakeholder theory with
social welfare. Whereas other corporate invest-
aspects of resource dependence theory (Pfeffer &
ments, at least from a normative perspective,
Salancik, 1978) so as to clarify who and what
are focused on improving the wealth of the own-
really counts (Mitchell et al., 1997) in regard to
ers of the corporation, CSR activities involve
stakeholder relationships, and resource-based
efforts to improve social welfare. Research on
theory (Barney, 1991; Penrose, 1959; Wernerfelt,
the business case seeks a link to profitability,
1984) to elicit how favorable stakeholder rela-
but any financial gains from CSR activities (e.g.,
tionships produce not only cost savings but also
corporate philanthropy) are necessarily by-
increased revenues (Russo & Fouts, 1997).
products of these direct contributions to social
There is now a substantive theoretical frame-
welfare. It is this aspect of CSR that makes it so
work to explain how CSR produces increases in
controversial.
CFP. The basic premise is that CSR improves
Stakeholder relationship orientation is an es-
CFP by improving a firms relationships with
sential yet often implicit characteristic of the
relevant stakeholder groups. As these relation-
business case for CSR. The business case tries
ships improve and trust builds, transaction costs
to move beyond the contentious ethical debate
decline and certain risks decline or are elimi-
by claiming that CSR, even if focused on improv-
nated. For example, certain types of CSR may
ing social welfare, also increases CFP and so
lead to more trusting labor relations, which can
increase employee retention rates and so de-
crease labor costs (Greening & Turban, 2000). On
tunities. The core premise of this paper is that the financial
returns to CSR depend on a firms history. Measures of CSP
the revenue side, improved stakeholder rela-
can proxy for a firms history. See the discussion section for tionships can bring in new customers and new
more detail. investment opportunities and can enable a firm
2007 Barnett 799

to charge premium prices (Fombrun et al., 2000; proving the corporations relations with impor-
Porter, 1991; Porter & van der Linde, 1995). tant stakeholders, than any near- or even long-
The key point is that CSR improves CFP by term increase in CFP is unlikely; it is neither
first improving relationships with key stake- countenanced nor accounted for.
holders. This indirect relationship between CSR Resource allocations without concern for
and CFP inherent in the business case is dis- shareholder value maximization were what dis-
tinct from corporate investments that have a di- turbed Friedman (1970). One cannot argue that
rect impact on CFP, as well as those that indi- the benefits to the corporation from such activi-
rectly impact CFP through channels other than ties outweigh their costs, because the benefits
stakeholder relationship building and the ad- accrue to management or to society, not to
vancement of social welfare. The nature of CSR shareholders. These are straightforward agency
and the relevance of both characteristics losses (Jensen & Meckling, 1976). Because there
social welfare orientation and stakeholder rela- is no question about their effect on CFP, these
tionship orientation become more apparent types of resource allocations are not of interest
when contrasted with those corporate activities to the business case. Therefore, corporate re-
that do not meet these criteria, as discussed source allocations that aid social welfare but
next. are not instrumental in improving key stake-
Outside the boundaries of CSR. Much that is holder relationships (and thereby increasing
often lumped in with CSR actually falls outside CFP) should be at the center of the ethical de-
its bounds, as illustrated in Figure 1. Let us first bate over the role of the corporation in society,
examine the upper left quadrant of Figure 1, but they should not be confounded with the
Agency loss. Some types of social spending business case for CSR.
are not intended to directly or even indirectly Direct influence tactics, as listed in the
increase CFP. They may be acts of pure corpo- lower right corner of Figure 1, are also distinct
rate altruism or pet projects of management. A from CSR. This category includes political lob-
substantial donation to a small charity headed bying and campaign donations, the establish-
by the spouse of the CEO or an anonymous ment of contractual relationships, and other
donation to any charity would fall into this cat- means of directly influencing or capturing reg-
egory. These allocations may improve manag- ulators, legislators, nongovernmental organiza-
ers welfare by increasing their self-image, so- tions (NGOs), and other stakeholders who can
cial standing, or career prospects. However, if affect the discretion and performance of a firm.
these allocations are not instrumental to im- Firms have long allocated significant resources
to lobbying and political campaigns in order to
curry favor with those who control legislative
FIGURE 1 and regulatory agendas (de Figueiredo, 2002;
Types of Corporate Resource Allocations Hillman, Keim, & Schuler, 2004). Green alli-
ances and other forms of cooperation between
firms and NGOs have become increasingly com-
mon (Stafford & Hartman, 1996). These coopera-
tive relationships can include the payment of
fees and royalties to NGOs in exchange for their
endorsement of a firms products and services
(Hartman & Stafford, 1997). Such direct influence
tactics are focused on improving relationships
with important stakeholders, but they are not
necessarily focused on improving social wel-
fare. In fact, corporate efforts to capture regula-
tors and legislators and co-opt activist NGOs
can be instrumental in reducing a firms contri-
butions to social welfare (Baron, 1995; Baysinger,
1984; Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978; Stigler, 1971).
Direct influence tactics can best be distin-
guished from CSR activities by noting to whom
800 Academy of Management Review July

the benefits accrue. The benefits of direct influ- within one box. A single investment can focus
ence tactics contributions, royalties, licensing on both social welfare and stakeholder relation-
feesaccrue directly to the stakeholders the ships yet can also entail aspects of direct influ-
firm seeks to influence; the benefits of CSR do ence, process improvement, and even agency
not. The business case for CSR implies that as loss. For example, one might classify a $1 mil-
stakeholders observe a firms socially responsi- lion donation by a large financial institution to a
ble behaviors, they will deem the firm a more preschool as a clear example of CSR, conclud-
favorable party with which to conduct their own ing that the financial institution wished to dem-
transactions. For example, Turban and Green- onstrate a commitment to education to its cus-
ing (1997) found that firms with favorable social tomers and the community in which it operates.
performance records were more attractive to po- However, if one of the financial institutions co-
tential employees, and Brown and Dacin (1997) CEOs spent the $1 million in order to directly
found that such firms were also more attractive influence one of its analysts, using the donation
to customers. to get the analysts child placed into this presti-
Trust arises and relationships improve as gious preschool so that the analyst would up-
stakeholders observe a firms CSR activities, not grade a stock, so that the CEO of the firm whose
as a consequence of a firms use of direct influ- stock rating improved, a member of the financial
ence tactics to capture their favor. Direct influ- institutions board of directors, would then vote
ence tactics, or perceptions of attempts at direct to oust the financial institutions other co-CEO
influence, can actually reduce trust (cf. (Gasparino, 2005), then one might also classify
OSullivan, 1997; Varadarajan & Menon, 1988) or this $1 million investment as a direct influence
simply make trust less relevant by substituting tactic (direct payment to improve relations with
financial payouts and direct contractual ties (cf. an important stakeholder, the analyst) and as an
Oliver, 1990). Direct influence tactics are of no agency loss (a clear misappropriation of share-
less interest or importance to understanding holder funds, for management gain). Less sala-
CFP than is CSR (Shaffer, Quasney & Grimm, cious but also complex could be a companys
2000), but in seeking to clarify the business case decision to invest $1 million in office and plant
for CSR, it is essential to factor out those activ- design technologies that reduce energy con-
ities that affect CFP through other mechanisms. sumption. Although previously described as a
Shown in the lower left corner of Figure 1, process improvement effort, advertising and
more commonly confounded with CSR are pro- public relations arms of the firm may tout the
cess improvement efforts such as energy conser- environmental benefits of such actions in hopes
vation, waste reduction, and pollution abate- of improving relationships with stakeholders
ment (Hart, 1995; Klassen & Whybark, 1999). (CSR). The $1 million project could also include
Social welfare gains can certainly arise from funding for a partnership with an energy con-
corporate efforts to improve processes and so servation NGO that had been pressuring the
lessen waste and harm to the natural environ- firm and so could function as a means of co-
ment. However, the link sought between the in- opting that group (direct influence tactic), or it
vestment and the financial return is direct, and could be an inflated contract awarded to a rel-
thus again distinct from the indirect mechanism ative of the CEO (agency loss).
of the business case (cf. Windsor, 2001). That is, Examples such as these illustrate that classi-
the gains to CFP are sought through cost sav- fication can be tricky, but the complex nature of
ings achieved from improving the efficiency of some investments makes classification particu-
operations (King & Lenox, 2002), not from im- larly important. Complex investments confound
provements in stakeholder relations. Therefore, the relationship between CSR and CFP. If
such process improvement efforts merit catego- agency losses are confounded with CSR, find-
rization with other standard corporate invest- ings may be biased toward a negative relation-
ments in improving operational efficiency. ship and so toward refutation of the business
Complex investments and hidden motives. case. However, confounding CSR with direct in-
Figure 1 and the above discussion provide a fluence tactics and especially process improve-
useful conceptual distinction to help sort out the ment gains may bias findings toward a positive
myriad activities often confounded with CSR, relationship and so toward support for the busi-
but many corporate investments do not fit neatly ness case. It is therefore beneficial to parse out
2007 Barnett 801

the CSR portion of complex investments. For ficial activities. An effort to ultimately enhance
example, the $1 million investment in energy CFP by demonstrating social responsibility to
conservation previously mentioned could be important stakeholders is much different from
disaggregated into process improvement and an effort to enhance CFP by squeezing more
CSR components. To measure the net financial efficiency and effectiveness out of processes
benefits that accrued to CSR, the costs of the and machinery or by directly capturing key
process improvement expenditures could be stakeholders. Once these other types of resource
separated from any resources expended to inter- allocations are cleared from our view of the
nally and externally publicize this program, and business case, the mechanisms of true interest
the efficiency gains could be culled from the become more visible and subject to scrutiny.
total financial gains from this investment, net-
ting the financial gains attributable to improved
EXPLAINING HETEROGENEITY IN THE
stakeholder relations. Such parsing can be sub-
FINANCIAL RETURNS TO CSR
jective, but no more so than commonly accepted
practices involved in accounting for intangibles The theoretical framework underlying the
(Lev, 2001). business case proposes that CSR improves key
Another tool is real options analysis (Barnett, stakeholder relationships, which decreases
2003, 2005; Bowman & Hurry, 1993; Kogut & Kula- costs and increases income and so increases
tilaka, 2001; McGrath, 1997). Fombrun et al. (2000) CFP. However, an extensive amount of empiri-
have suggested that firms view investments in cal testing has failed to conclusively support the
social responsibility as opportunity platforms business case. Does this mean that the theory is
that generate future opportunities, or real op- flawed? As argued below, I assert that the basic
tions (cf. Kogut & Kulatilaka, 1994). From this theoretical underpinnings of the business case
perspective, the $1 million energy conservation are correct, but a key construct that moderates
project would be treated as a platform invest- the transformation of CSR into improved stake-
ment, and the additional opportunities it pro- holder relationships is missing. This section out-
duces to enhance stakeholder relations would lines this key construct and embeds it within a
be valued as real options. A variety of tech- conceptual framework that better explains the
niques exist to place a separate financial value relationship between CSR and CFP.
on these real options (Copeland & Antikarov, CSR has a variable effect on CFP. Equal in-
2003; Trigeorgis, 1996). vestments by different firms, or even the same
A further complication is determination of mo- firm at different points in time, do not return
tives. Particularly regarding social responsibil- equal amounts of financial gain, as implied by
ity, firms may disguise the motives behind an thirty years of inconsistent findings. How can
action or even misrepresent them (Beder, 1997; this variability be explained? Over the past sev-
Greer & Bruno, 1996; Laufer, 2003). This is not eral decades scholars have added myriad con-
problematic for managerial decision making, trol variables to their studies to capture varia-
since managers are aware of their own motives tion, but they have done so in an ad hoc fashion,
and can therefore make informed cost-benefit leaving critics to contend that the end result is
projections about even the most Machiavellian nothing more than a mishmash (Rowley & Ber-
of acts. However, it does present a serious chal- man, 2000: 405) of variables. We now understand
lenge to observers, such as researchers. In the the effects of isolated pieces of the overall puz-
discussion section I suggest research methods zle, ceteris paribus, but the dots remain uncon-
to cope with this issue. nected through any theoretical framework that
As described above, then, CSR may be more adequately explains the contingent nature of
narrowly defined as a discretionary allocation the business case (Mahon & Griffin, 1999; Mar-
of corporate resources to improving social wel- golis & Walsh, 2003).
fare that serves as means of enhancing relation- McWilliams and Siegel (2001) made one nota-
ships with key stakeholders. Research on the ble attempt at connecting the dots. They con-
business case for CSR extends the link to CFP, structed a supply and demand model of CSR
seeking to measure financial outcomes and so that explained how size, level of diversification,
determine whether there is ample private incen- R&D, advertising, government sales, consumer
tive for firms to engage in these publicly bene- income, labor market conditions, and stage in
802 Academy of Management Review July

the industry life cycle influenced the level of structural conditions that produce spending on
CSR output by a given firm. Their theory of the basic research and toward a quest to gain a
firm perspective assumed, however, that each deeper understanding of how basic research
firm makes optimal choices, which means that can serve as a form of organizational learning
each produces at a profit-maximizing level of that mediates and moderates financial returns
output (McWilliams & Siegel, 2001: 125). Under to R&D. Although costly R&D activities can in-
this logic, since CSR is an almost universal crease social welfare by generating public
practice (Dressel, 2003: 1), it must also be an knowledge, absorptive capacity helped explain
almost universally wise investment. Support for how such activities can also benefit the spon-
the business case is an assumption of the soring firm and, moreover, how these benefits
model, since each firm makes only optimal vary across firms and time. In effect, the con-
choicesif CSR did not maximize profit, then struct of absorptive capacity solidified what
firms would not engage in it. Thus, while offer- could be called the business case for basic
ing an economic rationale for why firms supply R&D by demonstrating the contingent link be-
CSR (because there is profitable demand for its tween R&D and CFP.
supply), such a model fails to explain why or As Lane, Koka, and Pathak declared, Absorp-
even acknowledge that some firms might earn tive capacity is one of the most important con-
negative financial returns from CSR activities. structs to emerge in organizational research
In their call for theoretical development of a over the past decades (2002: M1). It clarified the
contingent approach to the business case, Row- cumulative and path-dependent nature of learn-
ley and Berman (2000: 410) outlined a model of ing, arguing that the stronger the base in learn-
heterogeneity in financial returns to CSR that ing, the greater the payoff to future investments
proposed some of the dimensions that drive in learning: Prior knowledge permits the assim-
stakeholders to action. The conceptual frame- ilation and exploitation of new knowledge. . . .
work I develop in this section builds on the in- Accumulating absorptive capacity in one period
sights of Rowley and Berman (2000) regarding will permit its more efficient accumulation in
the importance of stakeholder action in making the next (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990: 135136).
the business case. However, it was McWilliams Without absorptive capacity, new knowledge
and Siegels (2000) call for the use of R&D mea- has no context, no way to associate and embed.
sures in CSR studies that sparked the develop- It is analogous to soil; its presence is required
ment of the key construct in this framework. for a seed to grow, and the richer the soil, the
McWilliams and Siegel (2000) argued that previ- greater the growth. An extensive body of theo-
ous CSR studies were misspecified because retical and empirical research now attests that
they failed to control for R&D, a known predictor some firms have more absorptive capacity than
of CFP. others and so are able to transform a given unit
The use of R&D as a predictor of CFP elicits an of investment in learning into greater financial
interesting comparison with research on the link gains than others (Zahra & George, 2002). There-
between organizational learning and innova- fore, the business case for basic R&D is contin-
tion. One of the fundamental issues in the liter- gent (on absorptive capacity), not universal.
ature on innovation concerns why so many firms The relationship between CSR and CFP is, in
invest in basic R&D even though the fruits of many ways, like that between learning and in-
such efforts are public goods. The prevailing novation as addressed in the absorptive capac-
logic for several decades was that basic R&D ity literature. One of the fundamental issues in
was primarily the province of well-diversified the CSR literature is to explain why so many
firms, since such firms are able to capture a firms devote resources to CSR given that the
larger share of these otherwise public benefits benefits are public and the costs private. The
(Nelson, 1959). However, Cohen and Levinthals long-standing assumption of the business case
(1990) introduction of the absorptive capacity (normative and agency issues aside) has been
construct, which they defined as the ability of a that those firms that can capture more of the
firm to recognize the value of new, external in- private benefits of CSR will invest more in it.
formation, assimilate it, and apply it to commer- Therefore, researchers have sought to clarify the
cial ends (1992: 128), shifted innovation re- structural conditions under which firms might
search away from a quest to elucidate the receive private gains from CSR. We now have
2007 Barnett 803

insight regarding why firms supply CSR (McWil- tionship building can limit the scope of future
liams & Siegel, 2001). However, we still have no profitable CSR opportunities.
theoretical framework to explain heterogeneous Figure 2 places SIC within a conceptual
returns to CSR (Rowley & Berman, 2000). framework illustrating the business case for
To fill this void, I introduce the construct of CSR.2 In the remainder of this section I discuss
stakeholder influence capacity (SIC): the ability the mechanisms of this framework.
of a firm to identify, act on, and profit from op-
portunities to improve stakeholder relationships
CSR Flows Build SIC Stocks
through CSR. Similar to the way that the ability
of a firm to notice, assimilate, and exploit new The core of Figure 2 illustrates the mediated
knowledge depends on its prior knowledge, the relationship that defines CSR. CSR does not di-
ability of a firm to notice and profitably exploit rectly contribute to CFP but, instead, affects CFP
opportunities to improve stakeholder relations through its influence on stakeholder relations.
through CSR depends on its prior stakeholder As previously discussed, corporate activities
relationships. The basic premise is that stake- that directly affect CFP or that indirectly affect
holders draw from their prior knowledge of a CFP in ways other than through stakeholder re-
firm when they assess the implications of new lationship building are not CSR. In addition to
information generated by that firms CSR activ- its effects on stakeholder relations, an act of
ities. In short, the actions of a firm and the re- CSR produces a substantial by-productit con-
sponses by its stakeholders in regard to CSR are tributes to a firms SIC. Dierickx and Cool (1989)
path dependent such that different firms obtain pointed out that many strategically valuable as-
different results from CSR, depending on their sets such as trust and reputation cannot be
unique histories. SIC is an umbrella construct bought on strategic factor markets (Barney,
that accounts for those factors that forge this 1986) but must be built over time instead through
history and so influence how stakeholders react a series of investments. These discrete invest-
to new CSR initiatives, as well as limit the range ments are the flows that contribute to the at-
of CSR initiatives a firm will pursue. tainment of a certain asset stock at a particu-
If a firms CSR activity is to alter its relation- lar point in time. Accordingly, CSR flows forge
ship with a stakeholder, that stakeholder must SIC stocks.
notice, interpret, and act on the information con- But what constitutes an SIC stock? SIC is a
veyed by the CSR activity. The SIC construct multidimensional, firm-level construct com-
augments interest-based (Frooman, 1999) and posed of the dynamic relationships a firm has
identity-based (Rowley & Moldoveanu, 2003) with its myriad stakeholders. Each stakeholder
views of stakeholder action by pointing out that has his or her own fluid relationship with a firm.
the likelihood a stakeholder will notice a firms When these individual relationships are aggre-
CSR act, the way a stakeholder will interpret a gated at some point in time, they form an intan-
noticed act of CSR, and a stakeholders reaction gible asset that a firm possessesits SIC stock.
to that interpretation are all influenced by the That is, although SIC is revealed in the dynamic
history of the focal firm. The path-dependent relationships between a firm and its myriad
nature of stakeholder relations means that a stakeholders, it can be treated in the aggregate
given investment in CSR may provoke different as a firm-level intangible resource; a firm pos-
stakeholder reactions and yield different finan- sesses a certain stock of SIC.
cial results for different firms at different points Other common constructs are conceptualized
in time. Moreover, a firms history affects the in a similar fashion. For example, absorptive
degree to which it will be presented with CSR capacity is considered a firm-level intangible
investment opportunities, be cognizant of their
presence, and be willing and able to exploit
them. Therefore, similar to Cohen and 2
Figure 2 is not a complete model of the business case for
Levinthals argument that lack of investment in CSR. Rather, it is a framework that illustrates the effects of a
discrete act of CSR, as discussed in Propositions 1 through 5.
an area of expertise early on may foreclose the
Stated differently, the box containing Corporate social re-
future development of a technical capability in sponsibility refers to a discrete act of CSR, and the remain-
that area (1990: 128), the SIC construct points der of the figure illustrates the effects that this discrete act
out that lack of investment in stakeholder rela- has on the status of the other variables.
804 Academy of Management Review July

FIGURE 2
A Conceptual Framework Underlying the Business Case for CSR

resource (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990), yet its stock 1998) and corporate reputation (Wartick, 2002).
is a function of the knowledge present in the The merits and methods of disaggregating SIC
minds of individuals and the ability of those are addressed in the discussion section.
individuals to interrelate with other sources of As addressed earlier, the construct of SIC was
knowledge (Lane & Lubatkin, 1998). Another ex- inspired by research on absorptive capacity, but
ample is corporate reputation, a collective rep- it shares a close affiliation with corporate repu-
resentation of a companys past actions and fu- tation, given that both concern how a firms his-
ture prospects that describes how key resource tory affects current perceptions and thereby in-
providers interpret a companys initiatives and fluences behavior toward that firm. However,
assess its ability to deliver valued outcomes SIC and corporate reputation differ in signifi-
(Fombrun, 2001: 293). Each key resource pro- cant ways. The dominant component in mea-
vider has his or her own unique image of a sures of corporate reputation is financial, not
firm, but these images can be aggregated into a social, performance (Brown & Perry, 1994). More-
collective representation. This collective repre- over, as Fombruns (2001) definition states, cor-
sentation, corporate reputation, is treated as a porate reputation entails an assessment of the
firm-level intangible asset (Fombrun, 1996). Cre- firms ability to deliver valued outcomes. These
ating an aggregate firm-level intangible asset valued outcomes tend to depend on the self-
is perhaps the only pragmatic means of dealing interests of each of the key resource providers
with a construct of this nature (Wartick, 2002: who assess the firm.
375). However, an aggregate measure can mask Brown and Dacin made a parallel distinction
variation that may be relevant to the relation- in subdividing consumer opinions about a firm
ship of interest. Such criticism has been leveled into two distinct dimensions: Corporate ability
against absorptive capacity (Lane & Lubatkin, associations are those associations related to
2007 Barnett 805

the companys expertise in producing and deliv- Proposition 1: A firms current stock of
ering its outputs. Corporate social responsibility SIC is positively related to its prior
associations reflect the organizations status CSR activity.
and activities with respect to its perceived soci-
Flows to SIC from acts of CSR are generally
etal obligations (1997: 68). Thus, corporate rep-
incidentala by-product of the firms intentions
utation is instrumental to answering the ques-
to improve stakeholder favor but firms may
tion Given how this firm has performed (mostly
make direct investments in SIC. Such invest-
financially) in the past (summed up by its cor-
ments do not return near-term increases in
porate reputation), is it likely to deliver value to
stakeholder favor, but a firm might directly in-
me in the future? In contrast, SIC is more an
vest in SIC in order to build the necessary plat-
overall assessment of the soul of a business
form to create future CSR opportunities (Fom-
(Chappell, 1993) wherein observers ascribe char-
brun et al., 2000). Such SIC-building investments
acter to the firm (Sen & Bhattacharya, 2001) that
include hiring personnel and establishing or-
helps them to answer the question Given how
ganizational structures that facilitate timely rec-
this firm has behaved (mostly socially) in the
ognition and execution of emergent CSR oppor-
past (summed up by its SIC), can I trust it in the
tunities. Corporate owners must be vigilant,
future?
however, to maintain discipline in allowing
Nevertheless, corporate reputation is an ill-
management to cast activities into this vague
defined construct that has been broadly concep-
role, lest agency losses arise (cf. Adner &
tualized and whose definition continues to
Levinthal, 2004).
evolve (Barnett, Jermier, & Lafferty, 2006;
Wartick, 2002). Popular measures of corporate
reputation have weighted financial perfor- Effects of Social Change on SIC
mance heavily, leading researchers to conclude
If an act of CSR is characterized by its focus on
that corporate reputation ratings such as For-
social welfare, an obvious and relevant ques-
tunes Most Admired Corporations result from,
tion is Does CSR improve social welfare?
rather than predict, CFP (Brown & Perry, 1994).
Oddly enough, this question is seldom asked or
However, more recent approaches have sug-
answered.3 Studies of the business case typi-
gested more focus on stakeholder relationships,
cally do not measure the actual social benefits
beyond just shareholders (Mahon, 2002). Thus,
created by CSR, and there is seldom any ac-
the argument that corporate reputation focuses
countability (Margolis & Walsh, 2003). Given the
on financial performance to the detriment of
role of SIC in the business case for CSR, how-
concern for a firms relationships with other
ever, it can be in a firms interest to provide
stakeholders is increasingly a strawman. It is
evidence of the gains to social welfare brought
entirely possible that corporate reputation could
about by its CSR efforts.
be enlarged so as to effectively encompass the
A firms SIC is an aggregate representation of
domain herein ascribed to SIC. However, such a
how stakeholders perceive the character or
possibility makes development of the SIC con-
soul of that firm, and acts of CSR shape these
struct no less important. Whether SIC is treated
perceptions over time. However, as the opening
as an independent construct or as part of an
quotes of this paper anecdotally evidence, acts
enlarged conceptualization of corporate reputa-
of CSR are often met with pessimism. Webb and
tion, its distinctive nature needs to be clearly
Mohr categorized more than 20 percent of con-
specified.
sumers as skeptics whose views are typified
To summarize, charitable donations, support
by responses such as You show me something
of social causes, and other CSR acts are a
that shows exactly what people give and where
means of improving stakeholder relations. As
it goes to and have someone to do this study that
firms engage in CSR acts to improve stake-
holder relations, a record of social performance
incidentally accrues, forging a firms SIC 3
stockmuch as R&D investments, although in- The literature on the natural environment is the primary
exception to this rule, often seeking to distinguish discre-
tended to further innovation, incidentally con- tionary corporate acts that improve the natural environment
tribute to a firms absorptive capacity (Cohen & from mere greenwashing (e.g., Greer & Bruno, 1996; Laufer,
Levinthal, 1990). 2003).
806 Academy of Management Review July

has nothing to do with that business and then I in the socially responsible manner advertised
will listen to it. Otherwise, I just . . . I dont be- (Entine, 1994). Thus, firms that engage in sym-
lieve it at all (1998: 234). Currall and Epstein bolic CSR increase their risk and so effectively
claimed, Because trust tends to be a very evi- decrease their risk-adjusted returns to CSR. De-
dentiary decision, most of us behave as if we are spite the frequent effectiveness of symbolic
from the Show Me state of Missouri; we wish to adoption (Westphal & Zajac, 1994), when risk is
see the evidence that someone is trustworthy factored in, the following proposition holds.
(2003: 195). Thus, in the absence of evidence,
many stakeholders discount or ignore a firms Proposition 2: The effects of an act of
CSR acts. CSR on stakeholder relations and SIC
This, in effect, implicit discount rate for acts of are amplified in the presence of evi-
CSR can be diminished or overcome if firms dence of its effects on social welfare.
provide evidence that their CSR efforts have
produced social change. The stronger the evi- As dubious corporate behaviors come to light,
dence, the smaller the discount rate will be, and public trust in business declines. Some dubious
so the stronger the effects of the CSR act will be corporate behaviors are sufficient to produce a
on both stakeholder relations and SIC. This ef- shock that destroys public trust and brings
fect can be negative, however, for firms that about government regulation. For example, re-
make their CSR processes and outcomes more cent accounting scandals quickly led to the im-
transparent but fail to produce ample results plementation of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002,
that is, transparency is double edged. Firms that which placed additional burdens on firms. Oth-
claim to engage in acts of CSR but fall short of ers have more gradual effects. Expectations of
their rhetoric can face lawsuits claiming decep- corporate environmentalism shifted from her-
tive advertising, as Nike recently faced in re- esy to dogma (Hoffman, 1997) over several de-
gard to its allegedly false claims of eliminating cades as evidence of industrial harm to the nat-
child labor in its subcontracted manufacturing ural environmental mounted. These shifts in
facilities. The more transparent a firms CSR formal and informal expectations of the social
acts, the easier it is for activists to find evidence obligations of business can occur across entire
of their ineffectiveness and either file lawsuits economies, as with Sarbanes-Oxley, or can be
or bring forth other public challenges to the isolated to specific sectors or industries, as with
trustworthiness of the firm. the petrochemical sector in Hoffmans (1997)
Yet despite considerable evidence that many study.
firms CSR efforts are largely symbolic and These changes in societal expectations are
sometimes even fraudulent (e.g., greenwashing; not entirely exogenousfirms and industries in-
Beder, 1997; Greer & Bruno, 1996; Laufer, 2003), fluence the social standards by which they are
most stakeholders are willing to accept CSR judged. When a firm increases its CSR activi-
acts at face value (Webb & Mohr, 1998). However, ties, its rivals feel pressure to increase theirs as
those firms that engage in symbolic-only acts of well, since, all else being equal, most consum-
CSR are taking a risk. Trust is an asset that is ers prefer to buy from the most socially respon-
built slowly but destroyed quickly (Currall & sible firm (Mohr, Webb, & Harris, 2001). Firms
Epstein, 2003). If it is revealed that a CSR activity also influence societal expectations through di-
was insincere or fraudulent, any trust gained rect influence tactics. McWilliams, Van Fleet,
from the CSR act will be lost, and the firms and Cory (2002) have outlined the ways in which
stakeholder relations may be seriously de- firms use political strategy to lobby for new
graded. laws that increase social obligations in certain
Many recent examples of insincere and out- industries so as to place their less capable ri-
right fraudulent corporate activity underscore vals at a competitive disadvantage. Accidental
the risk inherent in pursuing symbolism over behaviors, such as Union Carbides disaster in
substance. For example, The Body Shop, long Bhopal, India, and the Alaskan oil spill of the
hailed as the Mother Theresa of capitalism Exxon Valdez, can also lead to change in the
(Entine, 2002), suffered a staggering loss of im- formal and informal societal expectations fac-
age, and profits thereafter, following a report ing those firms responsible for the acts, as well
that many of its products were not manufactured as their rivals (King, Lenox, & Barnett, 2002).
2007 Barnett 807

When expectations of CSR increase, the value unfavorable view of Wal-Mart because of its
of the status quo necessarily declines. In stock questionable labor practices, and yet another
and flow terms, increasing societal expectations stakeholder may have a consistently mixed
about CSR enlarge the hole in the bathtub view because of the conflicting facets of Wal-
that holds the stock of SIC, therein requiring Marts social efforts.
additional flows of CSR to maintain a constant SIC acts as an aggregate gauge of these cog-
level (Dierickx & Cool, 1989: 1506). Overall, this nitive representations, or perceptual filters
points to a Red Queen effect (Barnett & Han- (Starbuck & Milliken, 1988), through which new
sen, 1996) in CSR, whereby stationary firms lose information about the firms CSR practices flows
ground because of increasingly stringent soci- to stakeholders. Firms with poor SIC may have
etal expectations. However, firms can also take their CSR efforts overlooked or, if noticed, met
part in collective efforts, through trade associa- with skepticism, or they may even experience
tions, to forestall and decrease the formal and degradation in stakeholder relations in re-
informal social burdens placed on their indus- sponse to CSR. People are loath to update their
tries (King & Lenox, 2000; Miles, 1982; Rees, 1994, prior convictions even in the face of disconfirm-
1997). When effective, these collective efforts in- ing evidence (Staw, 1981). They are unlikely to
crease firms SIC. notice activities that they consider out of char-
acter with the actor. If they do notice such activ-
Proposition 3: As societal expectations ities, they may react with cynicism, discounting
of a firms social obligations increase them as self-serving. Therefore, their trust in the
(decrease), all else being equal, that firm is unlikely to increase, and could even de-
firms SIC will decrease (increase). crease, as they come to believe that the firm will
do anything to appear socially responsible
(Varadarajan & Menon, 1988; Webb & Mohr,
SIC As Moderator
1998).
As individuals, we are limited in our ability to A variety of studies have suggested that
process the unlimited stimuli that surround us stakeholder beliefs about the character of a firm
(Simon, 1955). To cope, we reduce complex situ- affect how stakeholders notice, interpret, and
ations to simplified cognitive representations, react to new information about that firm. Brown
take action based on heuristics, and develop and Dacin (1997) determined that consumer
routines (Cyert & March, 1963; Nelson & Winter, evaluations of new product offerings were con-
1982; Tversky & Kahneman, 1986). These simpli- tingent on their beliefs about the social respon-
fications allow us to lessen cognitive loads, but sibility of the firm; if the consumer believed the
they also restrict our search for new information. firm was socially responsible, his or her assess-
We interpret and assess information according ment of its new product was more favorable, but
to existing cognitive representations, and we if the consumer believed the firm was not so-
often overlook disconfirming evidence (Dutton & cially responsible, his or her assessment was
Dukerich, 1991; Weick, 1995). As a result, our unfavorable. Sen and Bhattacharya (2001) con-
cognitive representations are hard to change nected stakeholder perceptions of the social
once established. posture of a firm to purchase intentions, finding
Such is the case with SIC. Stakeholders are that CSR can actually reduce purchase inten-
boundedly rational and therefore rely on a sim- tions for consumers with unfavorable opinions
plified cognitive representation to proxy for a of a firms social posture. Linxwiler, Shover, and
complex reality. Each stakeholders reaction to Clelland found that when regulatory personnel
an act of CSR by a firm is conditioned on his or perceive clients to be responsive to regulatory
her cognitive representation of the character of demands, their enforcement responses are more
that firm. These cognitive representations affect likely to demonstrate forbearance. The net result
which CSR actions stakeholders notice and how is leniency (1983: 434). Thus, a firms perceived
they make sense of those actions. Each stake- character can even affect formal relationships.
holder has his or her own unique and subjective
representation. One stakeholder may view, say, Proposition 4: SIC moderates the effect
Wal-Mart favorably because of its contributions of an act of CSR on stakeholder rela-
to local charities, another may have an enduring tions.
808 Academy of Management Review July

The Paradox of Performance This suggests a self-regulating cycle that


places upper bounds on CSR contributions.
The business case for CSR has been charac-
Many studies have suggested a virtuous cycle
terized as searching for an answer to the ques-
without limits: Financially successful compa-
tion Can you do well while doing good?
nies spend more [on CSR] because they can af-
(Hamilton, Jo, & Statman, 1993). Although the
ford it, but CSP also helps them become a bit
answer remains in dispute, many studies have
more successful (Orlitzky et al., 2003: 424).5 But if
shown the reverse to holdthat strong CFP (i.e.,
CSR has a universally favorable rate of return,
doing well) is associated with increased CSR
why would a firm ever stop investing in CSR?
(i.e., doing good; see Margolis & Walsh, 2003, for
While not completely explaining the upper
a summary). But how are acts of CSR received
bounds of CSR investments, the negative effect
when they come from a firm with strong CFP?
of CFP on SIC highlights one way in which
Anecdotal evidence suggests that if a firm does
gains to CSR eventually extinguish themselves.
particularly well (CFP), its efforts at doing good
This mechanism also helps to explain the find-
(CSR) may be perceived negatively. For exam-
ings of Seifert, Morris, and Bartkus that there is
ple, Microsoft has a strong record of philan-
a positive relationship between available re-
thropy, but because of its yet stronger record of
sources and giving to charity, but neither a sig-
profitability, some expect even more philan-
nificant positive nor a significant negative rela-
thropy, making it a no-win situation, as Alsop
tionship between giving to charity and financial
exemplified with a quote from a stakeholder: I
returns (2003: 208).
also think they donate far less than they could
given Bill Gatess billions (2002: 2). Whereas a
donation of $1 million from a small firm might DISCUSSION
trigger a favorable stakeholder response, the
Consider your reaction were Union Carbide to
same donation from a large and highly profit-
announce a $10 million donation to community
able firm such as Microsoft might engender lit-
hospitals in Bhopal, India, or were Exxon to an-
tle attention or even pessimism.
nounce a $10 million donation to improve wild-
SIC provides an explanation for why doing
life habitats along the Alaskan coast. Now con-
well may decrease the financial benefits of do-
sider your reaction were Ben & Jerrys to do
ing good. Doing too well can lead stakeholders
either of the above. The simple premise of this
to perceive that a firm is not doing enough good.
paper is that your reactions would differ be-
Excessive CFP indicates that a firm is extracting
cause of your prior beliefs about the character-
more from society than it is returning and can
istics of each of the donating firms. The path-
suggest that profits have risen because the firm
dependent nature of firm-stakeholder relations
has exploited some of its stakeholders in order
helps to explain why the financial returns to
to favor shareholders and upper management.
CSR differ across firms and time, and serves as
This can indicate untrustworthiness to stake-
the cornerstone of a contingent framework for
holders looking to establish or maintain rela-
the business case, offered to supplant a long-
tions with the firm. As a result, increases in CFP
standing quest for a universal business case for
can lead to decreases in SIC.4 This lower stock
CSR.
of SIC dampens the value of future acts of CSR.
The precise payoff for a particular CSR act for
Overall, more profitable firms are expected to do
a particular firm at a particular point in time is
more good but get less financial reward in re-
not particularly predictable, however. There are
turn.
many factors to consider. In this paper I focused
Proposition 5: Excessive CFP de- on the role that a firms unique history plays in
creases SIC. eventually transforming an act of CSR into CFP.
I did not distinguish between types of CSR, but

4 5
This again distinguishes SIC from corporate reputation. Generally, this virtuous cycle is said to exist between
Increases in CFP have consistently been linked to increases CSP and CFP, not CSR and CFP. Bearing in mind confusion
in common measures of corporate reputation, demonstrating and lack of distinction between CSR and CSP in prior liter-
corporate reputations emphasis on CFP (Brown & Perry, ature (as previously discussed), the same logic holds for
1994). CSR.
2007 Barnett 809

worked instead from the standpoint that a firms al., 1997)yet fall short of classification as a
history influences this relationship regardless direct influence tactic. For example, a firm
of the type of CSR. However, the nature of the might make a highly visible and substantial
CSR investment itself is also bound to have an donation to a national charity with the intent of
influence. Most tests of the business case have improving relations with government officials in
made only a binary distinction regarding a the specific community in which it seeks favor-
firms overall social posturea firm is consid- able zoning permits. This would not be a direct
ered to be socially responsible or not. The few influence tactic, as previously defined, since the
studies that have disaggregated social respon- beneficiaries of the resource allocation are not
sibility have found variance in financial returns. the parties the firm intends to influence. Yet the
For example, Berman, Wicks, Kotha, and Jones intent to direct the act toward a specific set of
(1999) found that the state of a firms employee stakeholders makes this something more than
relationships and product safety/quality were pure CSR.6
positively related to CFP, but a firms commu- Insight into the intent behind specific acts of
nity relations and support of diversity and the CSR could elicit contingencies of relevance to
natural environment were unrelated to CFP. the business case. Of course, intent can be dif-
Barnett and Salomon (2006) found a positive re- ficult to determineit can be hidden from ob-
lationship between the financial performance of servers and even be disguised within the hier-
mutual funds and their decision to exclude firms archy of the firm itself, given agency issues.
with poor community relations, but a negative Fortunately, a variety of primary methods, such
relationship when these funds excluded firms as observation, interviews, and surveys of top
with poor labor relations or poor environmental management, and secondary methods, such as
performance. But as with most prior studies, content analyses of reports by the firm and
these scholars measured CSP stocks, not CSR about the firm, court documents, and top man-
acts. Berman et al. (1999: 501) parsed the com- agement speeches, are available to aid in dis-
monly used KLD database into subcategories, cerning intent. Many of these methods are labo-
each representing a different stakeholder pos- rious, and none will perfectly reveal intent when
ture. Barnett and Salomon (2006) divided the firms and their managers wish to hide it. Argu-
universe of socially responsible mutual funds ably, though, most widely accepted methods of
by twelve measures of social responsibility, assessing firm behavior and performance suffer
each of which assessed whether firms within a this same problem (e.g., formal certified ac-
mutual funds portfolio possessed a particular counting figures, as revealed by numerous scan-
stock of social responsibility. dals). Nonetheless, to the degree that intent can
Not surprisingly, in light of the extant empha- be discerned, important contingencies may be
sis on forging a CSPCFP link, there is no well- revealed.
established means of categorizing acts of CSR. One possibility, suggested by the above dis-
It is beyond the scope of this paper to fully cussion, is that firms may intend some acts of
develop a CSR classification system, and so this CSR to be more applied than others. Analo-
substantial task is left to future research. How- gous to the distinction between forms of R&D,
ever, the framework developed here does sug- some types of CSR may be basicintended as
gest several viable directions. As previously dis- a broad indicator of the trustworthiness of a
cussed, the implicit logic behind CSR is to firmwhereas others may be appliedin-
engage in explicitly selfless acts in order to ex- tended to curry favor with a particular set of
ude general trustworthiness and so enhance re- stakeholders. In terms of the framework pre-
lationships with important stakeholders. Such sented in this paper, basic SIC would contribute
an approach is distinct from direct influence more to building SIC stock than to immediately
tactics, whereby corporate resource allocations improving stakeholder favor, whereas applied
are intended to directly influence specific stake- SIC would achieve more immediate gains to
holders (see Figure 1). Nevertheless, it is possi-
ble that a corporate resource allocation could be 6
Figure 1 actually represents a continuum, wherein acts
intended to curry favor with particular stake- vary from low to high on the dimensions of interest. The
holdersperhaps those with the highest levels polar ends of each dimension are pure forms that may never
of power, legitimacy, and urgency (Mitchell et be fully realized in practice.
810 Academy of Management Review July

stakeholder favor, with a relatively small addi- act of applied CSR, a firm may worsen its rela-
tion to SIC stocks. Such insight could help with tionships with other stakeholders. For example,
the stakeholder mismatch problem (Wood & in the past, Microsoft established a policy of
Jones, 1995) by clarifying which types of CSR are providing benefits to the same-sex partners of
most likely to be discerned in which CFP mea- its employees and openly advocating legisla-
sures. Applied CSR acts would be more likely to tive action to more broadly increase gay and
result in near-term gains and so lend them- lesbian rights. Arguably, this policy improved
selves to empirical tests with stock price as the Microsofts relationships with its employees and
CFP measure, such as event studies. Basic CSR gay and lesbian organizations, and possibly
acts would be less likely to have a short-term provided a more basic CSR benefit by softening
impact and so would be more amenable to tests Microsofts often-harsh image with other stake-
with accounting measures of CFP as the depen- holder groups. Recently, because of its support
dent variable, such as lagged multivariate re- for a Washington State antidiscrimination bill,
gression. Microsoft was threatened with a boycott led by a
Given the challenges of discerning intent, as conservative pastor. In response, Microsoft
well as the potential disparity between intent ended its support of this bill. As a result, Mi-
and outcome, researchers seeking to identify crosoft avoided the threatened boycott but
relevant categories of CSR may be more likely to harmed its relations with employees and gay
succeed by focusing on the outcomes of CSR. and lesbian organizations. A few weeks later,
The KLD database provides a good opportunity Microsoft reversed its reversed position and
for such research. This database includes an again supported this and other such bills.
annual rating, on a five-point Likert-type scale, Examples such as this demonstrate the trade-
of the state of a firms relationship with several off problem and suggest that an act of CSR
groups of stakeholders. Researchers could re- could even produce a net loss in aggregate SIC
late firms varying KLD profiles to the flows of and stakeholder relations. Thus, further study of
CSR activity that produced them, both cross- the severity of these trade-off problems is
sectionally and longitudinally. For example, clearly warranted. Given the many stakeholder
how do the prior CSR flows of a firm that scored interests that a firm must balance, study of these
a 2 on employee relations, a 1 on local com- trade-offs will necessarily be complex. Even
munity relations, and a 2 on product safety/ within themselves, stakeholders have differing
quality compare with the CSR flows of a firm interests. For example, a single stakeholder
that scored 2, 1, 2, respectively? may have multiple roles relative to a given firm,
Data on acts of CSR, or CSR flows, are pub- such as employee (works for the firm), investor
licly available by definition, since private acts (owns firm stock), community member (lives in
are herein categorized as agency losses, not the city in which the firm is located), and social
CSR. Factor or cluster analysis could help deter- activist (member of a civic group, church, or
mine the types of CSR associated with changes NGO). Researchers may rely on qualitative
in particular stakeholder relationships. For ex- methods such as interviews and surveys to
ample, if a firm is more interested in improving gauge changes in a firms relationships with
employee relations than community relations, in various stakeholder groups. Admittedly, it is of-
which types of CSR should it engage? The re- ten not feasible to obtain such data for all of a
vealed categories could help firms better target firms stakeholders. As a standard proxy for an
intended audiences without resorting to direct aggregate market reaction to a particular CSR
influence tactics, which have some negative event, researchers may employ event study
properties as previously discussed. Thus, clear methods (McWilliams & Siegel, 1997).
insight into the differing types of applied CSR Timing may also be a relevant contingency.
and their effectiveness could significantly ben- Researchers have noted a variety of ways that
efit management practice. firms can financially benefit from instituting
Studies of this nature could also illuminate processes that reduce pollution and other harms
the severity of the trade-off problem inherent in to the natural environment (Hart, 1995; King &
CSR. A firms myriad stakeholders have myriad Lenox, 2002; Klassen & Whybark, 1999; Russo &
interests. In seeking to improve relationships Fouts, 1997). Many such process improvement
with one set of stakeholders through a visible efforts have minimal or no time component
2007 Barnett 811

even late movers can improve financial perfor- firm-level intangible asset, will increase the
mance by cutting waste. However, early movers precision of studies of the business case. We
can gain greater benefit in some instances; in currently have many proxies for SIC. In particu-
particular, there are lar, measures of CSP, as snapshots of the state
avenues for early mover advantages whereby of a firms stakeholder relations at a point in
the firm can capitalize on an enviropreneurial time, are proxies for the overall state of a firms
opportunity before it is shared with or adopted by relationships with those stakeholders it wishes
competitors (Porter & van der Linde, 1995). Envi- to influence. CSP alone has not resolved the
ropreneurial initiatives that lead to complex eco-
efficiencies, patented technologies and products business case, but because it represents a firms
that are difficult for competitors to imitate could stock of SIC, CSP can play an important role in
provide firms more sustainable competitive ad- future studies of the contingent nature of the
vantages (Stafford, Polonsky, & Hartman, 2000: business case. In a contingent framework, CSP
133).
becomes a measure of the given state as we
The framework presented here provides per- advance beyond CSP to a new, more fruitful
spective, beyond the ability of first movers to question for both research and practice: Given a
forge enduring barriers around new technolo- firms SIC, which CSR acts are profitable?
gies, on why early mover advantages may exist CSP has many well-established measures,
for some types of socially responsible behavior. such as the KLD database (see Margolis &
Proposition 3 suggests that as a particular type Walsh, 2003, for a summary). Many of these are
of CSR becomes common, societal expectations firm-level measures. Such summary measures
increase.7 Firms that do not meet the increased are convenient for reporting, but they can mask
expectations suffer a decline in SIC. Given that important variations in a firms relations with its
SIC moderates the gains from an act of CSR, the myriad stakeholders. To cope with this issue,
later a firm waits to engage in that particular some CSP measures have been disaggregated
CSR act, the less it will benefit. Therefore, CSR into component relationships. However, CSP
acts may have life cycles that produce early generally has been disaggregated into compo-
mover incentives. A CSR life cycle could help nent parts without the guidance of a commonly
explain prior discrepant findings, owing to vari- accepted or even explicit theoretical rationale.
ation in sample windows, and so CSR studies Sharfman found that combinations of the sub-
should control for timing effects. To better spec- categories of the KLD measure correlate with
ify CSR life cycles, future research should exam- other common CSP measures, but noted that
ine variation in the outcomes of specific types of there is no discernible theory underlying the
CSR over time. As we further untangle CSR from choice of variables that populate these subcat-
process improvement,8 timing may take on ad- egories (1996: 288).
ditional importance in the study of the business Given the focus of the business case, relevant
case. theory must provide guidance in discerning
This paper is based on the notion that ac- which of the relationships inherent in the aggre-
counting for a firms SIC, herein treated as a gate concept have independent influence on
CFP. Measures of corporate reputation, consid-
7
Empirical testing of Proposition 3 necessitates a mea-
ering their emphasis on financial performance,
sure of change in societal expectations. Possible measures might offer insight here. Indeed, some scholars
include changes in the number and magnitude of lawsuits, have performed empirical tests with corporate
proxy fights, protests, media coverage, and congressional reputation serving as a measure of CSP
discussion concerning specific topics (cf. Hoffman, 1997).
commonly, Fortunes ranking of Most Admired
One might also take a reverse perspective and measure
changes in the amount of a firms or industrys attention to Corporations (McGuire, Sundgren, & Schnee-
certain matters, as disclosed by coverage in their trade jour- weis, 1988; Sharfman, 1996). More recently, a spe-
nals, under the assumption that firms increase attention to cial issue of Business and Society debated
matters that are of increasing importance (Hoffman & Oca- whether reputation is a relevant and useful
sio, 2001).
8
construct to integrate more explicitly into theo-
As previously discussed, process improvement efforts
are distinct from CSR (see Figure 1), but they may involve a
ries of business and society relationships
CSR component. This component may be analyzed sepa- (Logsdon & Wood, 2002: 365). The conclusion was
rately from the costs and benefits of process improvement. that, as with other measures of CSP, there is no
812 Academy of Management Review July

theoretical basis for the ways in which corpo- assumed that supply and demand for CSR al-
rate reputation has been parsed (Wartick, 2002). ways matched (or equilibrium was quickly rees-
An adequate theoretical framework must dis- tablished). However, the SIC construct explains
tinguish not only the component relationships why firms vary in the degree to which they no-
inherent in a firms overall social posture but tice and act on demand for CSR. A firm must first
also the relative importance of each component. notice and desire to act on any demand for CSR
Again, this presents a problem, since theoreti- before supplying it, and its history affects the
cal work in stakeholder management and social degree to which the firm will do this. If a firm
issues participation has yet to identify a ranking has weak SIC, it may consistently undersupply
of importance for the various stakeholder CSR.
groups and issues (Hillman & Keim, 2001: 131). The normative implications of this paper are
As with the business case in general, the factors limited only to the business casewhether or
determining who and what really counts not certain firms,9 in certain situations, should
(Mitchell et al., 1997) and how much they count invest in certain kinds of CSR in order to im-
may be too firm specific to enable the develop- prove CFP. If we assume that stockholders are
ment of useful universal categories. Regardless, the sole owners of a firm, I argue a firm should
it is beyond the scope of this paper to offer a not engage in an act of CSR that is unlikely to
well-developed categorization and weighting offer a compensating increase in stakeholder
scheme of SICs component parts and so this, favor or stakeholder influence capacity. Given
too, is left as fertile ground for future research. their histories, some firms should engage in lit-
Path dependence has implications not only for tle or no CSR at certain points in time because
how stakeholders notice and react to CSR but poor SIC prevents CSR from transforming into
also for how firms notice and react to CSR op- stakeholder favor. In fact, it can create stake-
portunities. Employees in firms with a history of holder discontent and so will be money poorly
CSR may come to have CSR enmeshed in their spent. Future research must continue to uncover
identities (Dutton & Dukerich, 1991) and are more the contingencies that determine the benefits of
likely to be cognizant of new CSR opportunities. CSR so as to allow managers to determine
Because of adjusting aspiration levels (March & whether particular acts of CSR are wise invest-
Simon, 1958), CSR-oriented firms are more likely ments for their firms.
to engage in CSR acts once opportunities are
noticed. Cohen and Levinthals discussion of ab-
CONCLUSION
sorptive capacity explains this self-reinforcing
behavior: Whether corporations are owned by their
shareholders or by society and whether they
If the firm engages in little innovative activity,
and is therefore relatively insensitive to the op- have any obligations beyond becoming increas-
portunities in the external environment, it will ingly efficient at shareholder wealth production
have a low aspiration level with regard to exploi- are topics that have long been fiercely debated.
tation of new technology, which in turn implies This debate recently intensified following many
that it will continue to devote little effort to inno-
vation. This creates a self-reinforcing cycle. Like-
well-publicized instances of dubious corporate
wise, if an organization has a high aspiration behavior. It shows no signs of resolution and
level, influenced by externally generated techni- will surely remain a contentious topic for the
cal opportunities, it will conduct more innovative foreseeable future. This paper offers no resolu-
activity and thereby increase its awareness of tion to this debate. As long as we desire capi-
outside opportunities. Consequently, its aspira-
tion level will remain high (1990: 137138).
talism with a safety net, this is a dialectic ten-
sion that our society must continuously manage,
Similarly, firms with weak (strong) histories of not resolve.
CSR are less (more) likely to notice and seek However, this paper has shed light on the
new CSR opportunities. This notion that cogni- business case for CSR. As others have surmised,
tion is a key determinant of CSR activity adds
realism to McWilliams and Siegels (2001) eco- 9
The framework applies only to public corporations, not
nomic model of CSR supply and demand to help private firms. Private firms do not face the same agency
explain enduring nonoptimal supplies of CSR issues that are integral to the definition of CSR and the
by some firms. McWilliams and Siegel (2001) framework presented here.
2007 Barnett 813

Managers should treat decisions regarding vilinear relationship between social responsibility and
financial performance. Strategic Management Journal,
CSR precisely as they treat all investment deci-
27: 11011122.
sions (McWilliams & Siegel, 2001: 125). The dif-
Barnett, M., Jermier, J., & Lafferty, B. 2006. Corporate reputa-
ficulty, however, is that the payoffs have been
tion: The definitional landscape. Corporate Reputation
unclear because researchers have struggled for Review, 9: 26 38.
several decades to demonstrate a universal rate
Barnett, W., & Hansen, M. 1996. The Red Queen in organiza-
of return in a situation that clearly calls for a tional learning. Strategic Management Journal, 17: 139
contingent perspective (Rowley & Berman, 2000; 157.
Ullmann, 1985). A contingent perspective argues Barney, J. 1986. Strategic factor markets: Expectations, luck,
that although all CSR activities are not profit and business strategy. Management Science, 32: 1231
maximizing, some may be, and so the careful 1241.
use of CSR can fulfill managements fiduciary Barney, J. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive
responsibilities. The SIC construct and the con- advantage. Journal of Management, 17: 99 120.
ceptual framework developed in this paper Baron, D. 1995. The nonmarket strategy system. Sloan Man-
bring us closer to specifying a contingent model agement Review, 37(1): 73 86.
of the business case for CSR. Baysinger, B. 1984. Domain maintenance as an objective of
In many ways the struggle to make the busi- business political activity: An expanded typology. Acad-
ness case for CSR resembles the struggle to emy of Management Review, 9: 248 258.
show the financial merit of investments in a Beder, S. 1997. Global spin: The corporate assault on envi-
variety of intangible assets. Accounting and fi- ronmentalism. White River Junction, VT: Chelsea Green.
nancial methods have developed over the years Berman, S., Wicks, A., Kotha, S., & Jones, T. 1999. Does stake-
to justify many of the gut feelings of managers holder orientation matter? The relationship between
as they invest in projects that have no immedi- stakeholder management models and firm financial
performance. Academy of Management Journal, 42: 488
ate financial return, such as R&D and advertis- 506.
ing. Given that CSR is an almost universal prac-
Bowman, E. H., & Hurry, D. 1993. Strategy through the option
tice, either we have a long-standing agency lens: An integrated view of resource investments and
problem that boards of directors and the mech- the incremental-choice process. Academy of Manage-
anisms of the free market have almost univer- ment Review, 18: 760 782.
sally been unable to correct, or we have yet to Brown, T., & Dacin, P. 1997. The company and the product:
amply demonstrate the financial merits of CSR. Corporate associations and consumer product re-
Here I advocate the latter and call for increased sponses. Journal of Marketing, 61: 68 84.
attention to a contingency perspective that af- Brown, B., & Perry, S. 1994. Removing the financial perfor-
firms the payoffs to some forms of CSR for some mance halo from Fortunes most admired companies.
Academy of Management Journal, 37: 1346 1359.
firms at some points in time. CSR cannot finan-
cially please all of the corporations all of the Chappell, T. 1993. The soul of a business: Managing for profit
and the common good. Des Plaines, IL: Bantam Books.
time, but it can please some of the corporations
some of the time. Researchers should try to fig- Cochran, P., & Wood, R. 1984. Corporate social responsibility
and financial performance. Academy of Management
ure out which ones and when.
Journal, 27: 4256.
Cohen, W., & Levinthal, D. 1990. Absorptive capacity: A new
perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative
REFERENCES Science Quarterly, 35: 128 152.
Adner, R., & Levinthal, D. 2004. What is not a real option: Copeland, T., & Antikarov, V. 2003. Real options: A practition-
Considering boundaries for the application of real op- ers guide. New York: Texere.
tions to business strategy. Academy of Management Currall, S., & Epstein, M. 2003. The fragility of organizational
Review, 29: 74 85. trust: Lessons from the rise and fall of Enron. Organiza-
Alsop, R. 2002. Perils of corporate philanthropy. Wall Street tional Dynamics, 32(2): 193206.
Journal, January 16: 12. Cyert, R., & March, J. 1963. A behavioral theory of the firm.
Barnett, M. 2003. Falling off the fence? A realistic appraisal Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
of a real options approach to corporate strategy. Journal de Figueiredo, J. 2002. Lobbying and information in politics.
of Management Inquiry, 12: 185196. Business and Politics, 4: 125129.
Barnett, M. 2005. Paying attention to real options. R&D Man- Dierickx, I., & Cool, K. 1989. Asset stock accumulation and
agement, 35: 6172. sustainability of competitive advantage. Management
Barnett, M., & Salomon, R. 2006. Beyond dichotomy: The cur- Science, 35: 1504 1513.
814 Academy of Management Review July

Donaldson, T., & Preston, L. 1995. The stakeholder theory of Hoffman, A. 1997. From heresy to dogma: An institutional
the corporation: Concepts, evidence, and implications. history of corporate environmentalism. San Francisco:
Academy of Management Review, 20: 6591. New Lexington Press.
Dressel, C. 2003. For effective CSR campaigns, sincerity Hoffman, A., & Ocasio, W. 2001. Not all events are attended
starts at home. PR News, August 18: 13. equally: Toward a middle-range theory of industry at-
tention to external events. Organization Science, 12:
Dutton, J., & Dukerich, J., 1991. Keeping an eye on the mirror:
414 434.
Image and identity in organizational adaptation. Acad-
emy of Management Journal, 34: 517554. Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. 1976. Theory of the firm: Manage-
rial behavior, agency costs, and ownership structure.
Entine, J. 1994. Shattered image: Is The Body Shop too good to
Journal of Financial Economics, 3: 305360.
be true? Business Ethics, 8(5): 2328.
Jones, T. 1995. Instrumental stakeholder theory: A synthesis
Entine, J. 2002. Body flop. Toronto Globe and Mails Report on
of ethics and economics. Academy of Management Re-
Business Magazine, May 31: 1 9.
view, 20: 404 437.
Fombrun, C. 1996. Reputation: Realizing value from the cor-
King, A., & Lenox, M. 2000. Industry self-regulation without
porate image. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
sanctions: The chemical industrys Responsible Care
Fombrun, C. 2001. Corporate reputations as economic assets. program. Academy of Management Journal, 43: 698 716.
In M. Hitt, R. Freeman, & J. Harrison (Eds.), The Blackwell
King, A., & Lenox, M. 2002. Exploring the locus of profitable
handbook of strategic management: 289 312. Malden,
pollution reduction. Management Science, 48: 289 299.
MA: Blackwell.
King, A., Lenox, M., & Barnett, M. 2002. Strategic responses to
Fombrun, C., Gardberg, N., & Barnett, M. 2000. Opportunity
the reputation commons problem. In A. Hoffman & M.
platforms and safety nets: Corporate citizenship and
Ventresca (Eds.), Organizations, policy, and the natural
reputational risk. Business and Society Review, 105: 85
environment: Institutional and strategic perspectives:
106.
393 406. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Freeman, R. 1984. Strategic management: A stakeholder per-
Klassen, R., & Whybark, D. 1999. The impact of environmen-
spective. Boston: Pitman.
tal technologies on manufacturing performance. Acad-
Friedman, M. 1970. The social responsibility of business is to emy of Management Journal, 42: 599 616.
increase its profits. New York Times Magazine, Septem-
Kogut, B., & Kulatilaka, N. 1994. Options thinking and plat-
ber 13: 122126.
form investments: Investing in opportunity. California
Frooman, J. 1999. Stakeholder influence strategies. Academy Management Review, 36(2): 5271.
of Management Review, 24: 191205.
Kogut, B., & Kulatilaka, N. 2001. Capabilities as real options.
Gasparino, C. 2005. Blood on the street: The sensational in- Organization Science, 12: 744 758.
side story of how Wall Street analysts duped a genera-
Lane, P., Koka, B., & Pathak, S. 2002. A thematic analysis and
tion of investors. New York: Free Press.
critical assessment of absorptive capacity research.
Greening, D., & Turban, W. 2000. Corporate social perfor- Academy of Management Best Paper Proceedings, BPS:
mance as a competitive advantage in attracting a qual- M1M6.
ity workforce. Business and Society, 39: 254 280.
Lane, P., & Lubatkin, M. 1998. Relative absorptive capacity
Greer, J., & Bruno, K. 1996. Greenwash: The reality behind and interorganizational learning. Strategic Manage-
corporate environmentalism. New York: Apex Press. ment Journal, 19: 461 477.
Griffin, J., & Mahon, J. 1997. The corporate social performance Laufer, W. 2003. Social accountability and corporate green-
and corporate financial performance debate: Twenty- washing. Journal of Business Ethics, 43: 253261.
five years of incomparable research. Business and Soci-
Lev, B. 2001. Intangibles: Management, measurement and
ety, 36: 531.
reporting. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Hamilton, S., Jo, H., & Statman, M. 1993. Doing well while
Lindblom, C. 1959. The science of muddling through. Public
doing good? The investment performance of socially
Administration Review, 19(2): 79 88.
responsible mutual funds. Financial Analysts Journal,
49(6): 62 66. Linxwiler, J., Shover, N., & Clelland, D. 1983. The organization
and impact of discretion in a regulatory bureaucracy.
Hart, S. 1995. A natural resource-based view of the firm.
Social Problems, 30: 425 436.
Academy of Management Review, 20: 986 1014.
Logsdon, J., & Wood, D. 2002. Reputation as an emerging
Hartman, C., & Stafford, E. 1997. Green alliances: Building
construct in the business and society field: An introduc-
new business with environmental groups. Long Range
tion. Business and Society, 41: 365370.
Planning, 30(2): 184 196.
Mahon, J. 2002. Corporate reputation: A research agenda
Hillman, A., & Keim, G. 2001. Shareholder value, stakeholder
using strategy and stakeholder literature. Business and
management, and social/issues: Whats the bottom line?
Society, 41: 415 445.
Strategic Management Journal, 22: 125139.
Mahon, J., & Griffin, J. 1999. Painting a portrait. Business and
Hillman, A., Keim, G., & Schuler, D. 2004. Corporate political
Society, 38: 126 133.
activity: A review and research agenda. Journal of Man-
agement, 30: 837 857. March, J., & Simon, H. 1958. Organizations. New York: Wiley.
2007 Barnett 815

Margolis, J., & Walsh, J. 2003. Misery loves companies: Re- nuclear safety since Three Mile Island. Chicago: Univer-
thinking social initiatives by business. Administrative sity of Chicago Press.
Science Quarterly, 48: 268 305.
Rees, J. 1997. The development of communitarian regulation
McGrath, R. G. 1997. A real options logic for initiating tech- in the chemical industry. Law and Policy, 19: 477528.
nology positioning investments. Academy of Manage-
Roman, R., Hayibor, S., & Agle, B. 1999. The relationship
ment Review, 22: 974 996.
between financial and social performance: Repainting a
McGuire, J., Sundgren, A., & Schneeweis, T. 1988. Corporate portrait. Business and Society, 38: 109 125.
social responsibility and firm financial performance.
Rowley, T., & Berman, S. 2000. A brand new brand of corpo-
Academy of Management Journal, 31: 854 872.
rate social performance. Business and Society, 39: 397
McWilliams, A., & Siegel, D. 1997. Event studies in manage- 418.
ment research: Theoretical and empirical issues. Acad-
Rowley, T., & Moldoveanu, M. 2003. When will stakeholder
emy of Management Journal, 40: 626 657.
groups act? An interest- and identity-based model of
McWilliams, A., & Siegel, D. 2000. Corporate social respon- stakeholder group mobilization. Academy of Manage-
sibility and financial performance: Correlation or mis- ment Review, 28: 204 219.
specification? Strategic Management Journal, 21: 603
Russo, M., & Fouts, P. 1997. A resource-based perspective on
609.
corporate environmental performance and profitability.
McWilliams, A., & Siegel, D. 2001. Corporate social respon- Academy of Management Journal, 40: 534 559.
sibility: A theory of the firm perspective. Academy of
Seifert, B., Morris, S., & Bartkus, B. 2003. Comparing big
Management Review, 26: 117127.
givers and small givers: Financial correlates of corpo-
McWilliams, A., Van Fleet, D., & Cory, K. 2002. Raising rivals rate philanthropy. Journal of Business Ethics, 45: 195211.
costs through political strategy: An extension of re-
Sen, S., & Bhattacharya, C. 2001. Does doing good always
source-based theory. Journal of Management Studies,
lead to doing better? Consumer reactions to corporate
39: 707723.
social responsibility. Journal of Marketing Research, 38:
Miles, R. H. 1982. Coffin nails and corporate strategies. Engle- 225243.
wood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Shaffer, B., Quasney, T., & Grimm, C. 2000. Firm level perfor-
Mitchell, R., Agle, B., & Wood, D. 1997. Toward a theory of mance implications of nonmarket actions. Business and
stakeholder identification and salience: Defining the Society, 39: 126 143.
principle of who and what really counts. Academy of
Management Review, 22: 853 886. Sharfman, M. 1996. The construct validity of the Kinder, Ly-
denberg & Domini social performance ratings data. Jour-
Mohr, L., Webb, D., & Harris, K. 2001. Do consumers expect nal of Business Ethics, 15: 287296.
companies to be socially responsible? The impact of
corporate social responsibility on buying behavior. Jour- Simon, H. 1955. A behavioral model of rational choice. Quar-
nal of Consumer Affairs, 35: 4572. terly Journal of Economics, 69: 99 118.

Nelson, R. 1959. The simple economics of basic research. Stafford, E., & Hartman, C. 1996. Green alliances: Strategic
Journal of Political Economy, 67: 297306. relations between businesses and environmental
groups. Business Horizons, 39(2): 50 59.
Nelson, R., & Winter, S. 1982. An evolutionary theory of eco-
nomic change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Stafford, E., Polonsky, M., Hartman, C. 2000. Environmental
Press. NGO business collaboration and strategic bridging: A
case analysis of the GreenpeaceForon alliance. Busi-
Oliver, C. 1990. Determinants of interorganizational relation- ness Strategy and the Environment, 9: 122135.
ships: Integration and future directions. Academy of
Management Review, 15: 241265. Starbuck, W., & Milliken, F. 1988. Executive perceptual filters:
What they notice and how they make sense. In D. Ham-
Orlitzky, M., Schmidt, F., & Rynes, S. 2003. Corporate social brick (Ed.), The executive effect: Concepts and methods
and financial performance: A meta-analysis. Organiza- for studying top managers: 35 65. Greenwich, CT: JAI
tion Studies, 24: 403 441. Press.
OSullivan, T. 1997. Why charity schemes need a delicate Staw, B. 1981. The escalation of commitment to a course of
touch. Marketing Week, November 20: 22. action. Academy of Management Review, 6: 577587.
Penrose, E. 1959. The theory of the growth of the firm. Oxford: Stigler, G. 1971. The economic theory of regulation. Bell Jour-
Oxford University Press. nal of Economics, 2: 321.
Pfeffer, J., & Salancik, G. 1978. The external control of orga- Trigeorgis, L. 1996. Real options: Managerial flexibility and
nizations. New York: Harper & Row. strategy in resource allocation. Cambridge, MA: MIT
Porter, M. 1991. Towards a dynamic theory of strategy. Stra- Press.
tegic Management Journal, 12: 95118. Turban, D., & Greening, D. 1997. Corporate social performance
Porter, M., & van der Linde, C. 1995. Green and competitive: and organizational attractiveness to prospective employ-
Ending the stalemate. Harvard Business Review, 73(5): ees. Academy of Management Journal, 40: 658 672.
121134. Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. 1986. Rational choice and the
Rees, J. 1994. Hostages of each other: The transformation of framing of decisions. Journal of Business, 59: 251275.
816 Academy of Management Review July

Ullmann, A. 1985. Data in search of a theory: A critical ex- CEOs long-term incentive plans. Administrative Sci-
amination of the relationship among social perfor- ence Quarterly, 39: 367390.
mance, social disclosure, and economic performance.
Williamson, O. 1975. Markets and hierarchies. New York:
Academy of Management Review, 10: 450 477.
Free Press.
Varadarajan, P., & Menon, A. 1988. Cause-related marketing:
Windsor, D. 2001. Corporate social responsibility: A theory of
A coalignment of marketing strategy and corporate phi-
lanthropy. Journal of Marketing, 52: 58 74. the firm perspectiveSome comments. Academy of
Management Review, 26: 502504.
Wartick, S. 2002. Measuring corporate reputation: Definition
and data. Business and Society, 41: 371392. Wood, D. 1991. Corporate social performance revisited.
Academy of Management Review, 16: 691718.
Webb, D., & Mohr, L. 1998. A typology of consumer responses to
cause-related marketing: From skeptics to socially con- Wood, D., & Jones, R. 1995. Stakeholder mismatching: A the-
cerned. Journal of Public Policy and Marketing, 17: 226 238. oretical problem in empirical research on corporate so-
cial performance. International Journal of Organiza-
Weick, K. 1995. Sensemaking in organizations. Thousand
tional Analysis, 3: 229 267.
Oaks, SA: Sage.
Wernerfelt, B. 1984. A resource-based view of the firm. Stra- Zahra, S., & George, G. 2002. Absorptive capacity: A review,
tegic Management Journal, 5: 171180. reconceptualization, and extension. Academy of Man-
agement Review, 27: 185203.
Westphal, J., & Zajac, E. 1994. Substances and symbolism in

Michael L. Barnett (mbarnett@coba.usf.edu) is an assistant professor of strategic


management at the University of South Florida. He received his Ph.D. in management
and organizational behavior from New York University. In his research he tries to
enlighten the notion of self-interest by investigating how, when, and if firms can use
forecasting, real options, corporate social responsibility, industry self-regulation,
trade associations, Zen teachings, and other such perspectives, techniques, and indi-
vidual and collective forms of organizing to their long-term strategic advantage.

Potrebbero piacerti anche