Sei sulla pagina 1di 21

Behavioral Economics:

A Tutorial for Behavior Analysts in Practice

Derek D. Reed, Christopher R. Niileksela, & Brent A. Kaplan


University of Kansas

Practice points
The present tutorial describes behavior analytic concepts relevant to behavioral economics that
have implications for effective service delivery.
These concepts consist of: demand functions, reinforcer competition, open versus closed
economies, and discounting.

Keywords: : behavioral economics, demand, discounting, tutorial

34 BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS Behavior Analysis in Practice, 6(1), 34-54


In recent years, behavioral economics has gained much attention in psychology and public
policy. Despite increased interest and continued basic experimental studies, the application
of behavioral economics to therapeutic settings remains relatively sparse. Using examples
from both basic and applied studies, we provide an overview of the principles comprising
behavioral economic perspectives and discuss implications for behavior analysts in practice.
A call for further translational research is provided.

The field of study known as behavioral economics ini- decision making and behavior that integrates behavioral
tially began as a purely academic attempt at modeling science with economic principles (see Camerer, Loew-
irrational consumer choices, thereby challenging the enstein, & Rabin, 2004). Traditional economics, ac-
notion of the rational consumer of traditional econom- cording to the classic philosopher and economist John
ics. However, recent events have launched behavioral Stuart Mill (see Persky, 1995), assumes that humans
economics from a purely academic pursuit to the fore- exhibit behavior commensurate with a homo economicus
front of public policy and pop psychology. Mass media profile (the economic human). As a homo economicus,
books promoting behavioral economic concepts such as individuals are assumed to be completely aware of the
Thaler and Sunsteins Nudge: Improving Decisions about costs and benefits associated with all possible actions.
Health, Wealth, and Happiness (2008) and Dan Arielys Thus, people will subsequently behave in a way that
Predictably Irrational: The Hidden Forces That Shape fully maximizes their long-term gain (i.e., humans are
Our Decisions (2008) and The Upside of Irrationality: analogous to walking calculators, constantly considering
The Unexpected Benefits of Defying Logic at Work and the pros and cons of their actions and computing the
at Home (2010) have gained critical acclaim and wide- best behavioral alternatives for the situation). All behav-
spread publicity. Thaler and Sunsteins Nudge caught the iors are, in this sense, carefully calculated and entirely
interest of President Barack Obama (Grunwald, 2009), rational. Although this perspective is laudable and gives
prompting him to appoint Sunstein as the administra- the benefit of the doubt to the choices made by human
tor of the Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs. consumers, it is clear that people do not always make
Suffice it to say, behavioral economics has become a decisions that maximize their long-term gain. Of course,
staple in the understanding of ways to engineer envi- this is an empirical question, and one that behavioral
ronments to promote sustainable and positive behavior economics has attempted to reconcile.
changes. It is because of these attributes that we propose Behavioral economists assume a contrarian stance
that a behavioral economic approach to service deliv- that individualsno matter their age or intelligence
erybased upon the principles of behavior analysis, are rather myopic with respect to what is best for them.
rather than traditional behavioral economics derived Behavioral economics assumes irrationality in decision
from psychology and economicscan lead to a greater making. As such, individuals are susceptible to tempta-
understanding of behavior in academic or therapeutic tions and tend to make poor and rash decisions, even
settings. though it is clear there are better options that will im-
Before we provide examples of how behavioral prove long-term outcomes. Thaler and Sunstein (2008)
economic concepts may be applied to academic or propose that the term Homer economicus replace the
therapeutic settings, it is imperative to understand the homo economicus of traditional economics when describ-
assumptions of both traditional and behavioral ap- ing humans, as most decision makers resemble the fic-
proaches to economics. Collectively, the term behav- tional Homer Simpson (e.g., they live for the moment,
ioral economics describes an approach to understanding discount delayed consequences, pay poor attention to

, 34-54 BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS 35


detail, and are relatively uninformed of behavioral costs/ approach the reinforcer pathology model, suggesting
benefits). An astute observer of human behavior will that pathological patterns of responding for differen-
undoubtedly agree that many behaviors are less-than-ra- tially valued reinforcers may be a more parsimonious
tional. Undergraduates check social media pages, rather and conceptually systematic explanation for irrational
than take notes during lecture, despite the resulting behaviors than mentalistic constructs (Bickel, Jarmolo-
loss in knowledge acquisition and possible detriment to wicz, Mueller, & Gathalian, 2011). For the remainder
their chances of doing well in the class. Children choose of this tutorial, we will speak exclusively of behavioral
a brownie over an apple in the lunch line, despite the economics using the behaviorist perspective for two rea-
long-term decrements in health. Teachers and admin- sons. First, while behavioral economics stemming from
istrators deviate from psychology and economics
empirically supported feature an interesting and
curricula to gain student Notwithstanding the dense literature base, the
approval or make lesson behaviorist perspective is
plans easier to implement, consensus that behavioral parsimonious and does not
despite the loss in student require abstract theoretical
learning and subsequent economics accounts for explanations that are diffi-
dips in evaluations of cult to empirically evalu-
teaching efficacy.
irrational behaviors, ate and observe. Because
Notwithstanding the behavioral economics is
consensus that behavioral
a wide continuum exists expressed in the language
economics accounts for ir- within this field with of operant learning, a
rational behaviors, a wide language that is famil-
continuum exists within respect to the principles iar to behavior analysts,
this field with respect to the behaviorist approach
the principles that may that may explain provides a framework that
explain such irrational- is easily understood and
ity. On one end of the such irrationality. recommendations on how
continuum, theorists take environments can be al-
a more cognitive perspec- tered in ways that promote
tive, and contend that irrational behaviors are the result positive behavior change can be implemented relatively
of mentalistic or psychological causes such as stereotype quickly. Second, recent research has begun to suggest
biases, cognitive fallacies, or psychological predisposi- that behaviorist perspectives of economic principles can
tions (see Camerer, 1999; Kahneman, Slovic, & Tver- succinctly explain the findings of the more mentalistic
sky, 1982). On the opposite side of the continuum lie approaches to irrational behaviors (e.g., Kohlenberg,
the behaviorists perspective that irrationality is ground- Hayes, & Hayes, 1991; Reed, DiGennaro Reed, Chok,
ed in principles of operant learning (see Madden, 2000; & Brozyna, 2011). By using a perspective that is con-
Skinner, 1953), assuming that environmental influences ceptually systematic with radical behaviorism to explain
establish particular negative consequences (those associ- these irrational behaviors, environmental influences of
ated with irrational or problematic behaviors; e.g., risk irrational behaviors are analyzed, which in turn suggest
taking, cheating on tests, unhealthy food choices) as that environmental solutions can be employed to help
having more reinforcing value than other more positive improve decision making.
consequences (those associated with rational or desirable The behaviorist approach to behavioral econom-
behaviors; e.g., self-control, studying for a test, healthy ics was explicitly summarized by Hursh (1980), who
food choices). Behavioral economists have termed this proposed that economic concepts could better advance

36 BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS
a science of human behavior. Hursh (1984) further ad- time (Martens & Kelly, 1993). Finally, and perhaps
vised that operant concepts could help explain princi- most importantly, behavioral economic approaches
ples of behavioral economics. In short, behavior analysis are inherently efficient because they focus on relatively
provides both complementary and explanatory solutions simple environmental factors that can promote positive
to behavioral economic concepts. The concepts outlined behavior change. In an era of economic uncertainty and
by Hursh (1980, 1984) for understanding behavioral budgetary constraints, cost-effective empirically sup-
economics include (a) demand functions, (b) reinforcer ported interventions are at a premium. Applying behav-
competition, and (c) open versus closed economies. In ioral economic concepts to service delivery settings may
recent years, behavior analysts have also added the con- be an ideal solution for todays economic challenges.
cept of discounting to this list (see Francisco, Madden, This tutorial will detail each of the behavioral eco-
& Borrero, 2009). nomic concepts that have been discussed in both the ex-
The present tutorial explores how each of these four perimental and applied literature. We will describe each
concepts can contribute to an understanding of the concept using lay examples, supplementing these discus-
ecology of applied settings. Also, these concepts can sions with examples from basic and applied research.
help establish a number of theoretical underpinnings for Finally, we will provide implications of each concept for
effective behavior management procedures. We believe behavior analysts in practice when evaluating their own
that behavioral economics is particularly suited for ap- settings or intervention strategies.
plication in practical settings for several reasons. First,
behavioral economics has a large and dense evidence General Principles and Basic Terminology
base supporting its use and efficacy in laboratory stud- A number of economic terms will be used through-
ies, thus the principles discussed here are well estab- out the remainder of the tutorialterms such as
lished through empirical research. Second, although commodity, consumption, cost, benefit, price, and unit
behavioral economics has experienced a relative boom price. Therefore, it is important that these terms be de-
in experimental support, its applied utility remains fined before proceeding. We will use a running example
largely undocumented in less controlled therapeutic throughout this section to aid in defining and elucidat-
settings. A secondary purpose of this tutorial, therefore, ing the core concepts associated with behavioral eco-
is to challenge behavioral practitioners and researchers nomic analyses. For this example, consider a child who
to integrate these principles and concepts into their own is working to obtain tokens exchangeable for backup
practices to broaden the applied knowledge base of be- reinforcers. Tokens are contingent upon a number of
havioral economic concepts in academic and therapeu- words read correctly per minute during a reading inter-
tic settings. We believe that behavioral economics has vention.
much to offer, despite the relative paucity of research Commodity. In traditional economics, a commod-
and seemingly esoteric nature of this topic. Novel re- ity is a good or event that is available in the market
search applying behavioral economic principles to chal- for purchase/consumption. In behavioral economics,
lenges in therapeutic settings is well overdue. Thirdly, the term commodity refers to the reinforcer or item
because behavioral economics considers the interplay of for which an individual will work to obtain. Similar to
economic systems and multiple ecologies of reinforce- reinforcers, commodities may range from tangible (e.g.,
ment, this approach is an excellent complement to toys) to intangible goods (e.g., teacher attention). In our
Sheridan and Gutkins (2000) and Burns (2011) call for example above, the primary commodity of interest is
ecological approaches to assessment and intervention tokens (obtained via correctly read words). One could
conceptualization in treatment settings. By doing so, also consider the backup reinforcers as a secondary com-
behavioral economic considerations fall squarely within modity (obtained via expenditure of tokens).
the behavior analytic approach to therapeutic services Consumption. In economic analyses, consump-
that behavior analysts have been advocating for some tion is the process of engaging with the commodity of

BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS 37
interest following a purchase, given its cost. In behav- Rather than one word correct for one token (a unit
ioral economics, the term consumption refers to the price of 1.00), the behavior analyst may require two
amount of a commodity obtained in a given session words correct in a minute to access a token (two words
or observation (e.g., number of tokens or praise state- divided by one token equals a unit price of 2.00). Ex-
ments earned). Most often we are concerned with total changing the tokens for other goods also operates using
consumption, or the overall amount of a commodity unit prices. For example, if 10 tokens equal 10 minutes
obtained within a session. Using the previous example, of computer time, the unit price is 1.00. However, 20
reading a prespecified number of words correctly per tokens may access 40 minutes of computer time, equat-
minute during the intervention enables the consump- ing to a unit price of .50.
tion of tokens by the student. Exchanging the tokens for The Law of Demand. At the crux of behavioral
other items or activities results in the consumption of economics is the law of demand, which suggests that
backup reinforcers. consumption declines when the unit price of a given
Cost, benefit, and unit price. To consume a com- commodity increases (Samuelson & Nordhaus, 1985).
modity, an individual or group of individuals must Using the reading intervention example, consider what
meet some requirement related to cost, benefit, and unit might happen if the unit price of a token became very
price. When we speak of cost in behavioral economic high. Suppose that 100 words read correctly per minute
terms, we are referring to some requirement an individ- resulted in the consumption of one token. At such a
ual has to meet in order to obtain a given commodity high unit price, the student may stop responding and
(Hursh, Madden, Spiga, DeLeon, & Francisco, 2013). no longer consume reinforcers (tokens and the backup
Most commonly, cost is quantified by the number of reinforcers). The law of demand suggests that any
responses required to obtain the commodity (e.g., ten reinforcer, regardless of the strength of preference for
responses or fixed ratio [FR] 10) but may also be mea- that commodity, will lose its relative reinforcing efficacy
sured in other characteristics, such as the expenditure of if the unit price becomes too large. Loss of reinforcing
effort, the amount of money exchanged, or the amount efficacy suggests that the commoditys classification as
of time that passes until the delivery of a reinforcer. a reinforcer will be lost and responding to access that
The term benefit refers to the amount of a commodity commodity will no longer persist.
that can be obtained (Hursh et al., 2013). For example,
ten responses may allow a person to obtain one token. Demand Functions
Together, the cost and benefit of a commodity comprise In any kind of economy, the price-setting agent (i.e.,
the price of a commodity. In behavioral economics, the the retailer, the behavior analyst) seeks to identify the
price is calculated as a ratio of costs and benefits and is highest price that consumers will tolerate assuming the
referred to as unit price (for the remainder of this tuto- commodity of interest is sensitive to the law of demand.
rial, price and unit price will be used interchangeably). In the reading example above, the behavior analyst
Within our running example, the cost of each token is would be interested in the highest number of words the
to correctly read the specified number of words within student will read in order to earn each token. The de-
a minute. The cost of each backup reinforcer is the gree to which consumption remains stable across price
number of tokens exchangeable for the item or activity. increases is considered the consumers demand. Demand
During the first phase of the intervention, the behavior that maintains a stable level of consumption across price
analyst may require one word read correctly per minute increases is considered inelastic. For example, the stu-
to access a token; thus, the unit price equals the cost dent above may consume just as many tokens if the to-
(one word read correctly per minute) divided by the kens cost three words per minute or six words per min-
benefit (one token), which equals 1.00. As the interven- ute. That is, consumption does not change as a function
tion progresses, the behavior analyst may start to fade of price. When a price becomes too high and exceeds
the tokens, thereby increasing the unit price of tokens. the consumers threshold of acceptability, consumption

38 BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS
Figure 1. Left panel depicts consumption as a function of price (a demand function). Right panel depicts responses as a
function of price (a work function). See text for details. Note the double logarithmic axes on both panels to standardize the
data for simpler visual inspection.

of the commodity decreases, resulting in elastic demand. approximately 20. Conceptually, this indicates that the
This falls within the assumptions of the law of demand. peak level of responding is associated with the highest
Elastic demand is depicted in the demand curve in the unit price that sustained consumption.
left panel of Figure 1. As Figure 1 illustrates, consump- Comparisons of reinforcer demand are one way to
tion of the target commodity is plotted on the y-axis as examine relative reinforcer efficacy. Researchers have
a function of unit price (which is plotted on the x-axis). likened this measure as an index of behavior-mainte-
In the simulated data comprising Figure 1, consump- nance potency (Griffiths, Brady, & Bradford, 1979, p.
tion remains relatively constant until a unit price of 192), suggesting that reinforcers under strong demand
approximately 20; this constitutes the inelastic portion will maintain behavior at higher response requirements
of the demand curve. Consumption subsequently de- than alternative reinforcers of lesser demand. An impor-
creases as unit prices become higher than 20, indicating tant consideration when evaluating reinforcers is that
elasticity. The unit price at which zero commodities or reinforcer efficacy is a multifaceted construct (Bickel,
reinforcers are consumed is termed the breakpoint. Marsch, & Carroll, 2000; Johnson & Bickel, 2006).
A second way to examine the relationship between Thus, behavior analysts must consider the collective
consumption and price is with the work function, factors of derived response rates, demand elasticity, and
depicted in the right panel of Figure 1. The work func- breakpoints for each reinforcer examined, taking special
tion illustrates how respondingrather than consump- precautions to ensure that the context of the evaluation
tionincreases and decreases with increases in price. is held constant to permit comparisons of relative rein-
Similar to the demand curve plot (left panel of Figure forcer efficacy using demand curve analyses.
1), responding is depicted as a function of unit price. Hursh and colleagues (Hursh, Raslear, Shurtleff,
The reader will note that the point in which the pat- Bauman, & Simmons, 1988) provided a seminal study
tern moves from inelastic to elastic is equal across the on the utility of demand curves when considering
demand and work functions of Figure 1; a unit price of demand for preferred commodities in their paper us-

BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS 39
ing rats working for food pellets. The price was set by
Practical Considerations for Demand Functions
manipulating the number of responses necessary to earn
access to the food. As the price increased, the rats con- Whether intentional or not, behavior analysts ma-
sumption of food (demand) and numbers of responses nipulate demand functions on a daily basis. This con-
(work) initially increased (inelastic), but eventually re- cept is not restricted to incentive-based programs such
sulted in a point of elasticity wherein consumption and as token economies or reinforcement schedules; the
responding decreased, similar to the example demand mere programming of reinforcers contingent on target
and work functions in Figure 1. behaviors evokes demand functions. Despite the ubiqui-
Borrero and colleagues (Borrero, Francisco, Haber- ty of demand characteristics in academic or therapeutic
lin, Ross, & Sran, 2007) applied the logic of a cost-ben- settings, there are two key ways that behavior analysts
efit analysis to reinforcer can effectively capitalize on
demand using descriptive this concept. First, the no-
data on childrens severe Whether intentional or not, tion of a unit price can be
problem behavior. These applied to clients individ-
researchers first calculated behavior analysts ualized treatment plans by
prices for reinforcers by implementing a progres-
dividing the number of manipulate demand sive ratio (PR) schedule of
problem behaviors ob- reinforcement and as-
served (cost) by the num- functions on a daily basis. sessing the clients break-
ber of reinforcers obtained points. In a PR schedule,
during an observation
This concept is not the cost of the reinforcer
interval (benefit). This restricted to incentive-based increases across subsequent
calculation resulted in a deliveries; that is, the unit
unit price for the reinforc- programs such as price escalates over time or
ers. They then plotted across repeated responses.
consumption of reinforc- token economies or For example, you might
ers across unit prices and ask a client to complete
yielded demand curve reinforcement schedules. a work task (e.g., a math
functions akin to those problem, items sorted) to
described above. The find- earn access to a reinforcer.
ings from the Borrero et al. study suggest that childrens On the next trial, the client must complete two work
problem behavior can be assessed within an economic tasks to obtain the reinforcer. Then the client must
framework, similar to studies done in basic experimental complete four, eight, and so on, doubling the response
laboratories. In a proactive approach to treatment con- requirement each time the client earns the reinforcer (al-
ceptualization within an economic framework, Roane, ternatively, the response requirement can increase by 1
Lerman, and Vorndran (2001) applied demand analyses each time if the context of the demand warrants a small
to the examination of reinforcer efficacy in children step size). This progression continues until the client no
with developmental disabilities. Toys previously identi- longer accesses the reinforcer. The last response require-
fied as highly preferred generated higher breakpoints ment that resulted in the client accessing a reinforcer
than toys identified as less-preferred as the unit price of is thus considered the breakpoint, and the response
these commodities were increased. The highly preferred requirement just before the breakpoint can be used
toys that produced higher breakpoints served as more as a guide to set the price for the reinforcer. In other
effective reinforcers in treating problem behavior. words, this process helps determine the highest unit

40 BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS
price that the consumer (the client) is willing to spend values and step sizes used (see Poling, 2010; Roane,
(the amount of work they will complete) to obtain the 2008). These limitations may put fragile populations at
commodity (access to the reinforcer). This procedure is undue risk given the potentially aversive nature of large
equivalent to retailers assessing the highest price con- step sizes and unsettled applied research on these topics
sumers are willing to spend on a commodity. By deter- (Poling, 2010).
mining breakpoints for particular reinforcers, behavior Due to some possible limitations of PR schedules in
analysts can obtain direct information on how much practice, we advocate that behavior analysts consider the
work the client will complete to obtain the reinforcer. concept of unit price to guide practice without neces-
This may help to efficiently inform cost-effective treat- sarily conducting long formal assessments. The most
ment strategies that (a) maintain responding, (b) reduce pertinent practical consideration of unit price is that
costs associated with the reinforcers follow the law
purchase of reinforcers, of demand and will ulti-
and (c) reduce time spent Due to some possible mately lose value once unit
engaging in reinforcer prices become too large.
delivery and thereby in- limitations of PR schedules Key to this assumption is
creases the percentage of the notion that consump-
the day spent engaged in in practice, we advocate tion is not uniform across
therapeutic activities. prices. Reinforcers may
While the use of PR that behavior analysts be of high demand at low
schedules is intuitively ap- prices, but consumption
pealing, such procedures
consider the concept becomes relatively lower
present a number of issues of unit price to guide once demand becomes
when generating demand elastic. Thus, relying on re-
curves that may prove too practice without necessarily inforcer assessments using
demanding or problem- only low response require-
atic for use in academic conducting long formal ments (i.e., low unit price)
or therapeutic settings. may not fully capture
First, PR schedules take a assessments. the potency of that rein-
fair amount of time and forcer for larger response
resources to appropriately requirements. Consider a
evaluate relative reinforcer efficacy. Conclusive research situation in which a behavior analyst aims to identify
has not yet demonstrated the benefits of this procedure potential reinforcers for a child on her caseload. Based
outweigh the cost of resources; further research on the on parental report, engagement with an action figure or
efficiency of PR schedules for guiding practical consid- race car are potential reinforcers. The behavior analyst
erations is much needed. Second, although breakpoints collects data over several days using various prices asso-
and demand curves may be derived from PR schedules, ciated with a childs educational goal of sorting objects
these metrics do not necessarily result in equivalent into bins. The price is the number of items required
findings using a series of response requirements inde- to correctly sort before earning 30 s access to the rein-
pendently (i.e., not in a progressive fashion; see Bickel forcer. During one session, the unit price is 1.00 over
et al., 2000; Johnson & Bickel, 2006). Finally, recent a repeated number of trials. Other sessions consist of
discussions of PR schedules have highlighted the fact prices of 2.00, 5.00, 10.00, 20.00, and 30.00. The con-
that progressively increasing response requirements lack sumption of both reinforcers is plotted as a function of
sufficient research regarding the kinds of initial ratio price in Figure 2. As Figure 2 illustrates, both the action

BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS 41
figure and race car conform to the law of demand in 5.00 to identify the point at which the demand became
that elasticity is observed. At a unit price of 1.00, there elastic for the action figure.
is relatively more consumption of action figure play, Finally, the consideration of unit price is paramount
suggesting that this commodity is potentially more re- in the systematic fading of an intervention. Intensive
inforcing than the race car. However, as price increases, individualized interventions may be hard to sustain over
it is clear that demand is stronger for the race car since long periods of time. Without careful consideration of
consumption persists relative to the action figure. The demand characteristics, the withdrawal of the interven-
breakpoint for the race car is at a unit price of 30.00, tion may result in rapid decrements in student behavior.
compared to the breakpoint of 10.00 for the action The concept of unit price suggests that the thinning of
figure. By examining reinforcer demand across differing a reinforcement schedule (e.g., increasing the number
unit prices, the behavior analyst can make judgments re- of responses/duration required to access a reinforcer)
garding which reinforcer to use under different price ar- should include simultaneous increases in reinforcer
rangements. Unfortunately, many reinforcer assessments magnitude. By increasing reinforcer magnitude while
use exclusively low prices (e.g., FR1) and may result in thinning the reinforcement schedule, unit price is held
erroneous conclusions about the potency of a reinforcer constant, thereby maintaining the desired behavior (e.g.,
when prices become higher. This hypothetical example Roane, Falcomata, & Fisher, 2007).
highlights the importance of testing relative reinforcer
demand at both low and high prices. For example, had Reinforcer Competition
the behavior analyst in the sorting example tested a In economics, commodities compete for consumers
unit price of 1.00 and 10.00, she would have identified spending or resources. This competition is what fuels
differential demand across prices. The behavior analyst the supply and demand effects previously discussed.
could then evaluate mid-range prices such as 2.00 or Multiple commodities are at work in any given environ-

Figure 2. Hypothetical demand curve data for two reinforcers (action figure and race car) contingent on sorting across
increasing unit prices (that is, the number of items required to sort to obtain 30 s access to the reinforcer). Despite
initially higher consumption of the action figure at low unit prices, demand persists at higher unit prices for the race
care but not the action figure, highlighting the complex and multifaceted nature of reinforcer demand.

42 BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS
ment, and these commodities can interact with each tion for both commodities in the context of one com-
other in several different ways. We can categorize the moditys increase in unit price, we would functionally
status of a commodity as being (a) substitutable, (b) com- define video game play and salty snack foods as comple-
plementary, or (c) independent based upon their effects mentary reinforcers. Finally, independent reinforcers
on spending (see Green & Freed; 1993, Hursh, 2000; feature no change in consumption, despite changes in
Madden, 2000). Commodities are substitutable if and consumption of a concurrently available alternative
when increases in one commoditys unit price conforms commodity as a function of unit price manipulations.
to the law of demand (i.e., consumption of that com- An example of independence using the previous exam-
modity decreases as a function of increased unit price) ple would be where increases in the unit price of video
while there is a simultaneous increase in consumption game access have no effect on consumption of water.
of a second concurrently available commodity at a lower These two reinforcers are not related to each other, so
unit price. An example of substitutability may be a changes in unit price for either one would have no effect
situation wherein a client on consumption of the
initially demonstrates other. In sum, these con-
indifference for cherry and When the price was equal, cepts categorize the effects
strawberry flavored can- of multiple reinforcers on
dies, the client likes both the rats preferred root beer. behavior. When new com-
and chooses each of them modities are introduced
equally. However, when However, as the price of the into the economic system,
strawberry candies un- it is useful to determine
dergo a unit price increase root beer increased and the status of new commodities
(e.g., more responses or to determine how it inter-
tokens are required to ac-
Tom Collins mix remained acts with other commodi-
cess the strawberry candy), relatively low, the rats exhibited a ties already at work in the
preference shifts to cherry environment.
candies. Complemen- preference for Tom Collins mix; To understand the role
tary reinforcers are those of competitive reinforc-
that feature simultane- thus, root beer and Tom Collins ers, behavioral economists
ous increases or decreases typically employ demand
in consumption of both mix were considered substitutable. curve analyses as described
commodities, despite unit above (see Bickel et al.,
price manipulations on 2000; Johnson & Bickel,
only one of the commodities. Consider a situation in 2006). In one example of the substitutability of rein-
which a behavior analyst works to increase her clients forcers, Rachlin, Green, Kagel, and Battalio (1976)
physical activity as part of a weight loss program by provided rats the choice between root beer and Tom
increasing the price required to play video games. As the Collins mix when both were associated with an equal
unit price of video game access increases, its consump- and low response requirement (i.e., the number of lever
tion decreases, along with decreases of consumption of presses necessary to obtain the drink). When the price
salty snacks despite no unit price manipulation on the was equal, the rats preferred root beer. However, as
snacks. That is, salty snacks often go along with playing the price of the root beer increased and the Tom Col-
video games, so decreases in video game consumption lins mix remained relatively low, the rats exhibited a
result in concomitant decreases in salty snack consump- preference for Tom Collins mix; thus, root beer and
tion. Because consumption changed in the same direc- Tom Collins mix were considered substitutable. In this

BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS 43
Figure 3. Hypothetical demand curve data representing substitutable (left panel) and complementary (right panel)
reinforcers (tokens and attention) contingent on academic behavior when the unit price for one commodity increases
(tokens) while the unit price for the alternative commodity (attention) remains fixed. In both cases, inelastic demand
shifts to elastic between unit prices of 20 and 40. See text for details. Note the double logarithmic axes on both panels to
standardize the data for simpler visual inspection.

comparison, Rachlin and colleagues provided the first to tater tots or social time with familiar or unfamiliar
demonstration of the interplay between demand and peers. When the response requirement (the price) for
substitutability in operant behavior. food increased while that for social time with an unfa-
In Figure 3, example illustrations of both substitut- miliar peer remained constant, the participants worked
able and complementary reinforcers are provided. In the harder and earned more social time. Alternatively, when
left panel, substitutable reinforcers are illustrated (e.g., the price of social time with unfamiliar peers increased
tokens and peer attention). As the price of Commodity (and that of food remained constant), participants
A (e.g., tokens) increases, consumption of that com- worked harder and earned more food. Interestingly, the
modity eventually becomes elastic and decreases. Con- researchers found that food and social time with familiar
currently, Commodity B (e.g., peer attention)which peers (friends) were independent. That is, participants
has a lower unit price that has not increasedbegins to always worked harder to engage in social time with
be consumed relatively more often when Commodity A friends, regardless of the price for social time or food.
reaches a point of elasticity due to the increase in price. Collectively, these data imply that food and social time
In the right panel of Figure 3, a complementary rela- with unfamiliar peers may be substitutable reinforcers,
tion is depicted (e.g., token delivery and praise), where and that social time with friends is always more rein-
increases in price for Commodity A result in decreased forcing than food. This offers behavior analysts impor-
consumption of both Commodities A and B. tant practical implications for designing interventions to
In an interesting translation of reinforcer competi- counter obesity in school-aged children.
tion, Salvy, Nitecki, and Epstein (2009) examined the
Practical Considerations for Reinforcer Competition
degree to which social activities and food serve as substi-
tutable reinforcers for both lean and overweight pre- To further elucidate the concepts of reinforcer
adolescent youth. The preparation consisted of having competition, consider a students behavior in the class-
the youth press a computer mouse button to earn access room. In this classroom, the teacher provides tokens

44 BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS
for attending to the blackboard during instruction. The for effective treatment planning. For example, Broussard
student is very skilled at spelling and diligently attends and Northup (1997) demonstrated that the disruptive
to instruction during spelling class. Thus, the student behaviors of some students were motivated by peer,
earns many tokens during spelling, despite attempts by rather than teacher, attention. To effectively intervene,
her peers to whisper to her and pass notes. The student Broussard and Northup capitalized on the notion of
struggles in math, however, and has difficulty under- complementary reinforcers and provided students with
standing the concepts the teacher presents. During coupons contingent upon appropriate classroom behav-
math class, the student attends to her peers whisper- ior that were exchangeable for preferred activities with
ing and engages in note-passing, thereby earning few a friend. Substitutable reinforcers are also an efficient
tokens but receiving lots of peer attention. This behav- means of changing classroom behaviors. Work by Nancy
ior suggests that the two consequences (tokens and peer Neef and colleagues (e.g., Neef & Lutz, 2001; Neef,
attention) are substitutable because the increased unit Shade, & Miller, 1994) suggests that various dimensions
price of attending during math class (i.e., the effort of of reinforcers compete against each other in academic-
attending during math is greater than spelling given the related behavior. For example, an immediate low quality
students math abilities) reduced consumption of tokens reinforcer may serve as a more potent reinforcer than a
and increased consumption of peer attention. delayed high quality reinforcer for some children. When
Complementary reinforcers are distinguished by preference for a reinforcer shifts as a function of effort,
examining whether rates of consumption of two rewards delay, rate, or quality, these reinforcers would be consid-
both decrease as the price of the behavior increases. In ered substitutable. By isolating the preferred reinforcer
this case, teacher praise and delivery of a token may dimensions associated with academic-related behaviors,
be viewed as complementary if the increased effort school-based practitioners can determine the kinds of
requirement of academic behavior reduces the number substitutable reinforcers available in the classroom and
of praise statements and tokens obtained by the stu- manipulate contingencies to favor appropriate respond-
dent. For the student above, math is difficult and the ing. For example, if functional behavioral assessments
effort required to pay attention during math is high, so (FBAs) determine that teacher attention maintains dis-
the student would need to pay a high price for teacher ruptive student behavior, the teacher can provide high
praise and tokens. If both teacher praise and the number quality praise immediately contingent upon appropriate
of tokens earned by the student decrease during math, student behavior while ignoring or providing low qual-
these reinforcers are complementary to one another, ity attention contingent upon disruption as a way to
that is, a decrease in one is related to a decrease in the reduce disruptive behavior.
other. Should an increase in the price of attending (e.g.,
due to more effort) in one academic subject be associ- Open and Closed Economies
ated with a decrease in token delivery but no change in One of the most commonly known and recited
praise, these reinforcers would be considered indepen- economic principles is that of supply and demand.
dent commodities. This means that tokens and teacher John Locke succinctly described this principle in 1691
praise are not related to one another, where the teacher by writing that:
delivers praise independently of providing tokens.
the measure of the value of Money, in proportion
Any behavior analyst practicing in classroom settings
to any thing purchasable by it, is the quantity of the
can attest that neurotypical students tend to enjoy con-
ready Money we have, in Comparison with the quan-
suming reinforcers with preferred peers. That is, certain
tity of that thing and its Vent; or which amounts to
reinforcers are more valuable when shared with a friend
the same thing, The price of any Commodity rises or
(i.e., they are complementary). Such reinforcers are not
falls, by the proportion of the number of Buyers and
always under the control of the behavior analyst, how-
Sellers. [sic] (p. 16)
ever, necessitating an analysis of reinforcer competition

BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS 45
In sum, when a commodity is in short supply, its val- results indicated substantially higher rates of responding
ue increases. Tokens, for example, are effective in chang- in the closed economy conditions. Collier, Johnson, and
ing behavior because they are in short supply. However, Morgan (1992) yielded similar open vs. closed economy
if a behavior analyst offered tokens on a noncontingent effects, but also documented a reward magnitude effect
schedule, there would be a diminished demand for to- in the closed economy wherein smaller reward magni-
kens such that the clients no longer emit the behaviors tudes generated higher rates of responding than larger
that previously resulted in contingent token delivery. ones.
In his seminal papers on the application of economic In academic or therapeutic contexts, all academic
principles to the experimental analysis of behavior, or behavioral interventions fall into either an open or
Hursh (1980, 1984) described any behavioral experi- closed economy classification. Given the experimental
mentin the present case, any behavioral interven- findings from nonhuman studies on this topic and the
tion programas being an economic system. In such implications they have on the way classroom contin-
economies, the value of the reinforcer depends on its gencies are designed, it is unfortunate that no studies
relative availability both within and outside the system. (that we are aware of ) have explicitly compared open
When reinforcers are available only in the target system, and closed economies in traditional classrooms with
the economy is considered closed. For example, a set- neurotypical students. While very few in number, there
ting where staff attention is only available via functional are fortunately two articles that address open and closed
communication would constitute a closed economy. economies with individuals with developmental disabili-
On the contrary, economies that permit supplemental ties in applied settings using academic tasks as operants.
access to the reinforcer outside the target system are Roane, Call, and Falcomata (2005) compared re-
considered open. In a setting with an open economy, sponding under open and closed economies for both an
staff attention would be available through many modes adult and an adolescent with developmental disabilities.
of communication, ranging from appropriate functional The behavior of interest for the adult was a vocational
communication to inappropriate forms of attention- task (mail sorting) while the behavior of interest for the
motivated behaviors such as self-injury or aggression. adolescent was math problem completion. Prior to the
As the notion of supply and demand suggests, supple- experimental manipulation, the researchers recorded
mental access to the reinforcer outside the target sys- the amount of time the participants spent engaging in
tem increases its supply and subsequently decreases its preferred activities; video watching for the adult, video
demand. In classroom settings where extra credit points game playing for the adolescent. These observations
are abundantly available (open economies), assignment were used to fix the percentage of time the participants
completion may be low because there is plenty of op- could engage in the activity during open economy
portunity to access class points outside of the bounds of conditions (approximately 75%). During both open
the in-class assignments and homework. In a classroom and closed economy conditions, participants could earn
where there is no extra credit available (closed econo- access to their preferred activity by meeting response
mies), assignment completion may be high because the requirements programmed on PR schedules. Partici-
students must work within the bounds of the in-class pants received supplemental access to preferred activities
assignments and homework to earn their points. following experimental sessions in the open economy
In a basic example of open and closed economies, condition. The degree of post-session supplemental ac-
LaFiette and Fantino (1989) compared pigeons re- cess varied depending on the amount of reinforcement
sponding under conditions in which sessions were run obtained during the sessions, with each daily amount
for either (a) 1 h while maintained at 80% free-feeding equaling 75% of the pre-experimental observation
body weight with free postsession access to food (i.e., an lengths. In the closed economy, no supplemental access
open economy) or (b) 23.5 h without a food depriva- to the preferred activities was provided outside of the
tion procedure (i.e., a closed economy). As predicted, sessions. Results replicated those obtained in nonhu-

46 BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS
man studies; both open and closed economies increase the clinical setting is a closed economy for that par-
responding from baseline levels, with relatively higher ticular reinforcer. Making the same reinforcer available
rates of responding occurring in closed economy condi- outside of the clinical setting would create a more open
tions. Moreover, Roane and colleagues demonstrated economy and possibly decrease the target behavior in
that PR breakpoints were substantially higher in the the classroom. For instance, if a child is engaging in
closed economies, supporting the notion that limited problem behaviors to receive teacher attention during
supply increases the potency/demand of the reinforcer. class because that is the only time she receives teacher
In an extension to Roane et al.s (2005) study, attention, it might be beneficial for the teacher to try to
Kodak, Lerman, and Call (2007) evaluated the ef- incorporate a plan that allows the student to also receive
fects of reinforcer choice under open (i.e., post-session teacher attention outside of class (e.g., during playtime,
reinforcement available) and closed economies on math lunch, snack).
problem completion for three children with develop- Creating economic systems that are either open or
mental disabilities. The general procedure mimicked closed may also be an important component in the
that of Roane and colleagues, with the exception of a development of a behavior intervention plan. If extra
choice of math problems to be completed and the use computer time is being used as a reinforcer to increase
of edible reinforcers. Two stacks of math problems were work completion in the academic or therapeutic setting,
present during both open and closed economies; one this may not be an effective reinforcer if the client is
stack of problems was associated with the top-ranked able to spend as much time as he likes on the computer
edible from a preference assessment, and the other stack at home. Choosing reinforcers that are unique to a par-
was associated with the second-ranked edible. Again, re- ticular context may be helpful in making the reinforcer
sponding was highest under closed economy conditions. more effective, thereby resulting in a more successful
Interestingly, participants switched preference away behavior plan.
from the top-ranked edible to the second-ranked edible Including multiple contexts in behavior plans might
when the PR schedules for the top-ranked edible were be necessary to help account for open and closed econo-
relatively high in the closed economy condition. These mies. One method of consultation available to behavior
findings provide further confidence in the cross-species analysts in practice is conjoint behavioral consultation,
generality of the open vs. closed economy phenomena, where both the caregiver and clinician (behavior ana-
and provide a more ecologically valid depiction of how lysts or teacher) are involved in the consultation process
open and closed economies might function in applied (Sheridan, Kratochwill, & Bergan, 1996). This method
settings when more than one reinforcer may be concur- provides an opportunity for behavior analysts to use the
rently available for a target behavior. concept of open and closed economies when designing
interventions with caregivers and clinicians. Using both
Practical Considerations for Open and
the clinical and home environments, it can be decided
Closed Economies
if the same reinforcers should be available in both the
When conducting a functional assessment, the con- home and target settings, or if certain reinforcers should
cept of open and closed economies may help illuminate be associated with home, while others are associated
why certain reinforcers are more or less effective for a with the clinic and/or school. The decisions made about
given client. If a client exhibits a higher rate of a target the availability of reinforcers across settings will likely
behavior in the clinical setting, it would be beneficial to influence behavior (for better or worse). Strategic use of
assess whether the reinforcer the client is obtaining for economic principles can nudge behavior toward desir-
that behavior is also available in other settings. If the able outcomes. Consider a student who is not complet-
reinforcer is only accessible in the clinical setting, this ing work at school. A behavior plan could be written
may be one factor contributing to the reason why the that allows a particular reinforcer (that is unavailable at
high rate of target behavior is occurring. In this case, home) to be available at school for completing school

BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS 47
Figure 4. Example of delay discounting. The subjective value of a delayed reward (in this case, $100) is plotted on the
y-axis as a function of the delay until the receipt of the reward (in months) on the x-axis. As delay to receipt of reward
increases, the subjective value (of $100) decreases.

work, while a different reinforcer is available at home that humans (and nonhumans) are rather myopic
(and is unavailable at school) for completing homework. when faced with delayed consequences (Madden &
If the same reinforcer is being used for completing both Bickel, 2010). In these studies, researchers typically ask
schoolwork and homework, and homework is easier or participants to choose between receiving hypothetical
less time consuming for the child than schoolwork, the monetary outcomes at various delays, such as $100 in
child may do less work at school because they know 10 years, or $150 in 12 years. If the participants are like
they can easily complete their homework, and will be most people who have taken part in such studies, they
able to have access to the reinforcer at home. There probably choose the $150 (in 12 years); after all, $150
is no hard and fast rule regarding whether an open is greater than $100. Now, suppose the participants
or closed economy is best because it is likely to differ are presented with another choice; this time, they can
among individuals, but this may be an important factor choose to receive $100 right now or $150 two years
to consider in setting up behavioral contingencies in from now. When presented with this decision, many
multiple environments. individuals who previously chose the larger delayed
The concept of open and closed economies has not reward switch to preferring the smaller immediate
been examined thoroughly in applied settings. However, reward. This phenomenon is termed a preference reversal
the concept itself is well established in economics (e.g., (see Ainslie, 1974; Tversky & Thaler, 1990) and implies
Hillier, 1991). The extra step of evaluating whether or that individuals values of delayed rewards are myopic in
not the reinforcers contingent on behavior are occurring nature (e.g., Kirby & Herrnstein, 1995). Interestingly,
in an open and closed economy is a simple step that both the difference in delay and the difference in reward
may provide important information, ultimately improv- magnitude are identical in both decision-making tasks;
ing the efficacy of behavioral interventions. however, preference has reversed.
According to traditional economic theory, humans
Delay Discounting lawfully make rational choices. Given the results of the
Behavioral economic studies of intertemporal choice decision-making task above, this is clearly not the case.
and decision making have repeatedly demonstrated This notion of preference reversals may explain why

48 BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS
individuals make many less-than-optimal decisions, now and $1,000 after varying delays. At the start of
such as planning to study for a major test but instead each delay, the amount of the two alternatives is set
watching a television show, using credit cards with high equal. On each consecutive trial, the amount of the al-
interest rates to immediately purchase an item that will ternative delivered immediately decreases by an amount
take a while to pay off, or eating unhealthy foods that until the alternatives are $1 now vs. $1,000 after the de-
taste good now but ultimately harm long-term health. lay. After the descending portion is completed, the pro-
These types of irrational choices can be explained by a cedure repeats in an ascending order until the alterna-
phenomenon that behavioral economists call discounting tives are, again, both valued at $1,000. An indifference
(see Madden & Bickel, 2010). Discounting describes a point is then obtained by averaging the point in which
behavioral pattern in which contextual factors associated the participant switches from the immediate outcome to
with the reward (in this case, delay until the receipt of the delayed outcome (for the descending sequence) and
the reward) diminishes the value of a given outcome. the point at which the switch is made from the delayed
Mazur (1987) was one of the first researchers to outcome to the immediate outcome (for the ascending
assess rates of delay discounting by using an adjusting sequence). Even though these procedures typically use
delay procedure. In Mazurs procedure, pigeons repeat- hypothetical rewards, researchers have found that there
edly chose between a larger amount of food pellets after is no difference in obtained rates of discounting when
an adjusting delay and a smaller amount of food pellets real or hypothetical rewards are used (Johnson & Bickel,
after a fixed delay. If the pigeon chose the larger later re- 2002; Madden et al., 2003).
ward (LLR), the delay to the LLR would increase on the Green, Myerson, and Ostaszewski (1999) compared
subsequent trial. On the other hand, if the pigeon chose discounting rates of typically developing sixth-grade
the smaller sooner reward (SSR), the delay to the LLR children with discounting rates of older adults. Results
would decrease on the subsequent trial. This procedure suggested that children discounted more steeply, in-
was used to determine the point at which the pigeon dicating preference for smaller sooner rewards. In an
switched from choosing the LLR to the SSR. The value extension of this research, Reed and Martens (2011)
at which switching from the LLR to the SSR is termed assessed discounting rates for 46 typically developing
an indifference point because it is the point at which the sixth-grade students. The researchers then implemented
subjective values of both alternatives are deemed equal. a class-wide intervention targeting on-task behavior
Mazur used several different mathematical functions to by delivering reinforcement immediately after a class
explain the manner in which the pigeons discounted period, or tokens that could be exchanged 24 hours
delayed outcomes, and when plotted, Mazur found that later for a back-up reinforcer for on-task behavior. Reed
the obtained indifference points followed a hyperbolic and Martens found that discounting rates adequately
function. predicted on-task behavior during the intervention. In
Figure 4 illustrates a typical discounting curve that other words, for those students who showed higher dis-
follows a hyperbolic function. Various delay values are counting scores, the delayed rewards were less effective
plotted on the x-axis and the subjective value of a rein- in improving on-task behavior than immediate rewards.
forcer is plotted on the y-axis. As the delay to the receipt These studies suggest that children do indeed discount
of the reward increases, the subjective value of the re- delayed rewards, and such discounting is associated with
ward decreases. Thus, delayed outcomes are subjectively real-world outcomes of interest to school-based practi-
valued less than more immediate outcomes. tioners. These discounting effects also appear to be more
The most widely used procedures for determining pronounced in children diagnosed with attention-deficit
discounting parameters in humans have been variations hyperactivity disorder (ADHD; Barkley, Edwards, La-
on a procedure originally created by Rachlin, Raineri, neri, Fletcher, & Metevia, 2001; Scheres et al., 2006).
and Cross (1991). In this procedure, participants make The notion that preferring smaller sooner rewards
choices between two hypothetical outcomes: $1,000 over larger later ones is irrational provides an impetus

BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS 49
for practitioners to design interventions that are concep- fails to address the caregivers concerns, it would be dif-
tually systematic with respect to behavioral economics. ficult to know if the plan is not working because of the
In a classic study, Schweitzer and Sulzer-Azaroff (1988) reinforcer itself, or if the delay to the reinforcer is affect-
operationally defined self-control as preference for larger ing the value of the reinforcer.
delayed rewards. In their study, the researchers offered One obvious method to help reduce the effects of
children the choice between two boxes; one box with delay is to deliver reinforcers immediately. This may
one reinforcer, the other with three reinforcers. In a not be a viable solution for all situations, especially in
pre-assessment, the researchers documented a discount- group settings where staff must attend to numerous
ing effect wherein the children preferred to have an clients at once. For children with more severe dis-
immediately available smaller reward (the box with only abilities, this may be a possibility if staff work directly
one reinforcer) to a delayed and larger reward. They with the student during a large part of the day and are
then implemented a self-control training procedure that able to immediately reinforce appropriate behavior. In
began by asking the children to choose either box, both a school setting, the delivery of immediate reinforce-
of which were immediately available. When both were ment may disrupt the flow of the classroom and inter-
immediately available, the children chose the box associ- rupt the learning of other students. One method that
ated with more reinforcers. The procedure progressed by can decrease delay to reinforcement is to implement a
gradually increasing the durations of the delay for the token reinforcement system. This may be the best way
box with more reinforcers across subsequent sessions. At to reduce the delay between behavior and reinforce-
post-assessment, the researchers found that four out of ment in the regular classroom. With a token system, the
the five children shifted their preference for the delayed tokens can become conditioned reinforcers that may be
reinforcer away from their pre-assessment preference exchanged at a later time for other backup reinforcers.
for the immediate reinforcer. These results suggest that The tokens become a stand-in (or bridge) for backup
viewing self-control as a form of discounting may have reinforcers that will be delivered later, and they can be-
implications for classroom instruction and behavior come reinforcing in themselves as long as other reinforc-
management. More importantly, it may be possible to ers are tied to them consistently (see Hackenberg, 2009;
design behavioral interventions to promote self-control Kazdin & Bootzin, 1972). Finally, research from both
choices in children. human (Dixon, Horner, & Guercio, 2003) and nonhu-
man (Grosch & Neuringer, 1981) studies suggest that
Practical Considerations for Delay Discounting
the inclusion of an intervening stimulus may increase
The issue of delay discounting presents one of the tolerance to delay by providing an alternative response
most important, although probably least often consid- that can be emitted while waiting for the delivery of the
ered, aspects of designing an effective behavioral inter- delayed reinforcer. In practical settings, behavior ana-
vention in academic or therapeutic settings. When writ- lysts can mediate delay discounting effects by providing
ing behavioral intervention plans, reinforcers are often clients with activities or timers to assist their waiting
delivered at a time that is convenient for staff or caregiv- behavior.
ers (such as the end of a program or during breaks). The It is important to note that delay discounting affects
research described above suggests that even relatively a wide variety of important domains related to human
short delays can have a significant impact on the efficacy behavioral outcomes. Discounting has been observed in
of a reinforcer, especially for children with a low toler- health behavior (Chapman, 1996), social relationships
ance for delay. The timing of reinforcer delivery needs (Jones & Rachlin, 2006), and in academic behavior
to be considered when writing behavioral intervention (Schouwenburg & Groenewoud, 2001). Nearly any
plans. If such considerations are not made and the plan behavior for which consequences occur in the future is

50 BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS
in competition with behaviors for which consequences
are more immediately available. By reducing delay to
References
reinforcement, one may be increasing the efficacy of Ainslie, G. (1974). Impulse control in pigeons. Journal
reinforcement; thereby increasing the efficacy of the of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior 21, 485489.
behavior change procedure. Ariely, D. (2008). Predictably irrational: The hidden
forces that shape our decisions. New York, NY: Harper-
Conclusion Collins.
Behavioral economics represents the interplay Ariely, D. (2010). The upside of irrationality: The unex-
between economic principles and behavior change pected benefits of defying logic at work and at home.
considerations. The notion of behavioral economics New York, NY: HarperCollins.
in academic or therapeutic settings is most accurately Barkley, R. A., Edwards, G., Laneri, M., Fletcher, K., &
described as a ubiquitous concept rather than a behav- Metevia, L. (2001). Executive functioning, temporal
ior change procedure since these principles are in play discounting, and sense of time in adolescents with
regardless of whether change agents have intentionally attention deficit hyperactivity disorder (ADHD)
programmed such contingencies or interventions. As and oppositional defiant disorder (ODD). Journal of
an ever-present concept, behavior analysts in practice Abnormal Child Psychology, 29, 541556.
should seek to identify the behavioral economic princi- Bickel, W. K., Green, L., & Vuchinich, R. E. (1995).
ples actively controlling clients behaviors and find ways Behavioral economics. Journal of the experimental
to restructure contingencies to promote desired out- Analysis of Behavior, 64, 257262.
comes. Across disciplines, behavioral economic concepts Bickel, W. K., Jarmolowicz, D. P., Mueller, E. T., &
remain relatively undocumented in nonclinical settings, Gatchalian, K. M. (2011). The behavioral econom-
such as home-based services, regular education class- ics and neuroeconomics of reinforcer pathologies:
rooms, and the workplace. Applied behavioral econo- Implications for etiology and treatment of addic-
mists, behavior analysts, educators, and clinicians alike tion. Current Psychiatry Reports, 13, 406415.
would profit from integrating such concepts into topics Bickel, W. K., Marsch, L. A., & Carroll, M. E. (2000).
of everyday relevance. While scientific translation across Deconstructing relative reinforcing efficacy and situ-
these disciplines remain relatively sparse (Critchfield ating the measures of pharmacological reinforcement
& Reed, 2004; Reed, 2008), bridging the gap between with behavioraleconomics: A theoretical proposal.
behavioral science and practice represents an excellent Psychopharmacology, 153, 4456.
avenue for use-inspired research (Mace & Critchfield, Borrero, J. C., Francisco, M. T., Haberlin, A. T., Ross,
2010) to improve behavior analytic service delivery. As N. A., & Sran, S. K. (2007). A unit price evaluation
behavioral economics continues to rise in popularity in of severe problem behavior. Journal of Applied Behav-
the behavioral sciences (Bickel, Green, & Vuchinich, ior Analysis, 40, 463474.
1995; Camerer, 1999) and public policy (e.g., Grun- Broussard, C., & Northup, J. (1997). The use of func-
wald, 2009; Hursh & Roma, 2013), it would behoove tional analysis to develop peer interventions for
applied researchers and practitioners to begin proffering disruptive classroom behavior. School Psychology
examples of these concepts in both science and practice. Quarterly, 12, 6576.
The concepts offered in this article are merely starting Burns, M. K. (2011). School psychology research:
points for potentially exciting and effective applications Combining ecological theory and prevention sci-
in behavior analytic settings. ence. School Psychology Review, 40, 132139.
Camerer, C. (1999). Behavioral economics: Reunifying
psychology and economics. Proceedings of the Nation-
al Academies of Science, 96, 1057510577.

BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS 51
Camerer, C. F., Loewensein, G., & Rabin, M. (Eds.). Grunwald, M. (2009, April 2). How Obama is using
(2004). Advances in behavioral economics. Princeton, the science of change. Time Magazine, April. Re-
NJ: Princeton University Press & Russell Sage Foun- trieved from http://www.time.com.
dation. Hackenberg, T. D. (2009). Token reinforcement: A re-
Chapman, G. B. (1996). Temporal discounting and view and analysis. Journal of the Experimental Analysis
utility for health and money. Journal of Experimental of Behavior, 91, 257286.
Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 22, Hillier, B. (1991). The macroeconomic debate: Models of
771791. the closed and open economy. New York, NY: Black-
Collier, G., Johnson, D. F., & Morgan, C. (1992). The well.
magnitude-of-reinforcement function in closed and Hursh, S. R. (1980). Economic concepts for the analysis
open economies. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of behavior. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of
of Behavior, 57, 8189. Behavior, 34, 219238.
Critchfield, T., & Reed, D. D. (2004). Conduits of Hursh, S. R. (1984). Behavioral economics. Journal of
translation in behavior-science bridge research. In the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 42, 435452.
E. Ribes Iesta & J. E. Burgos (Eds.), Theory, basic Hursh, S. R. (2000). Behavioral economic concepts and
and applied research, and technological applications in methods for studying health behavior. In W.K. Bick-
behavior science: Conceptual and methodological issues el & R. E. Vuchinich (Eds.), Reframing health be-
(pp. 4584). Guadalajara, Mexico: University of havior change with behavioral economics (pp. 2762).
Guadalajara Press. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.
Dixon, M. R., Horner, M. J., & Guercio, J. (2003). Hursh, S. R., Madden, G. J., Spiga, R., DeLeon, I.
Self-control and the preference for delayed reinforce- G., & Francisco, M. T. (2013). The translational
ment: An example in brain injury. Journal of Applied utility of behavioral economics: The experimental
Behavior Analysis, 36, 371374. analysis of consumption and choice. In Madden,
Francisco, M. T., Madden, G. J., & Borrero, J. (2009). G. J., Dube, W. V., Hackenberg, T. D., Hanley, G.
Behavioral economics: Principles, procedures, and P., & Lattal, K. A. (Eds.), APA handbook of behavior
utility for applied behavior analysis. The Behavior analysis: Vol. 2. Translating principles into practice (pp.
Analyst Today, 10, 277294. 191224). Washington, DC: American Psychologi-
Green, L., & Freed, D. E. (1993). The substitutability cal Association.
of reinforcers. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Hursh, S. R., Raslear, T. G., Shurtleff, D., Bauman, R.,
Behavior, 60, 141158. & Simmons, L. (1988). A cost-benefit analysis of
Green, L., Myerson, J., & Ostaszewski, P. (1999). demand for food. Journal of the Experimental Analysis
Discounting of delayed rewards across the life span: of Behavior, 50, 419440.
Age differences in individual discounting functions. Hursh, S. R., & Roma, P. G. (2013). Behavioral eco-
Behavioural Processes, 46, 8996. nomics and empirical public policy. Journal of the
Griffiths, R. R., Brady, J. V., & Bradford, L. D. (1979). Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 99, 98124.
Predicting the abuse liability of drugs and animal Johnson, M. W., & Bickel, W. K. (2002). Within-
drug self-administration procedures: Psychomotor subject comparison of real and hypothetical money
stimulants and hallucinogens. In T. Thompson & P. rewards in delay discounting. Journal of the Experi-
B. Dews (Eds.), Advances in behavioral pharmacol- mental Analysis of Behavior, 77, 129146.
ogy (Vol. 2, pp. 163208). New York, NY: Academic Johnson, M. W., & Bickel, W. K. (2006). Replacing
Press. relative reinforcing efficacy with behavioral economic
Grosch, J., & Neuringer, A. (1981). Self-control in demand curves. Journal of the Experimental Analysis
pigeons under the Mischel paradigm. Journal of the of Behavior,85, 7393.
Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 35, 321.

52 BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS
Jones, B. & Rachlin, H. (2006). Social discounting. Madden, G. J., & Bickel, W. K. (2010). Impulsivity:
Psychological Science, 17, 283286. The behavioral and neurological science of discounting.
Kahneman, D., Slovic, A. & Tversky, A. (1982). Judg- Washington, DC: American Psychological Associa-
ment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Cam- tion.
bridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Martens, B. K., & Kelly, S. Q. (1993). A behavioral
Press. analysis of effective teaching. School Psychology
Kazdin, A. E. & Bootzin, R. B. (1972). The token Quarterly, 8, 1026.
economy: An evaluative review. Journal of Applied Mazur, J. E. (1987). An adjusting procedure for study-
Behavior Analysis, 5, 243372. ing delayed reinforcement. In M. L. Commons, J.
Kirby, K. N., & Herrnstein, R. J. (1995). Preference re- E. Mazur, J. A. Nevin, & H. Rachlin (Eds.), Quan-
versals due to myopic discounting of delayed reward. titative analyses of behavior: Vol. V. The effect of delay
Psychological Science, 6, 8389. and intervening events on reinforcement value (pp.
Kodak, T., Lerman, D. C., & Call, N. (2007). Evaluat- 5573). Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
ing the influence of postsession reinforcement on Neef, N. A., & Lutz, M. N. (2001). Assessment of
choice of reinforcers. Journal of Applied Behavior variables affecting choice and application to class-
Analysis, 40, 515527. room interventions. School Psychology Quarterly, 16,
Kohlenberg, B. S., Hayes, S. C., & Hayes, L. J. (1991). 239252.
The transfer of contextual control over equivalence Neef, N. A., Shade, D., & Miller, M. S. (1994). Assess-
classes through equivalence classes: A possible model ing influential dimensions of reinforcers on choice
of social stereotyping. Journal of the Experimental in students with serious emotional disturbance. Jour-
Analysis of Behavior, 56, 505518. nal of Applied Behavior Analysis, 27, 575583.
LaFiette, M. H., & Fantino, E. (1989). Responding Persky, J. (1995). Retrospectives: The ethology of homo
on concurrent-chains schedules in open and closed economicus. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9,
economies. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of 221231.
Behavior, 51, 329342. Poling, A. (2010). Progressive-ratio schedule and ap-
Locke, J. (1691). Some considerations of the consequences plied behavior analysis. Journal of Applied Behavior
of the lowering of interest, and raising the value of Analysis, 43, 347349.
money: In a letter sent to a member of parliament. Lon- Rachlin, H., Green, L., Kagel, J. H., & Battalio, R. C.
don: Awnsham and John Churchill. Retrieved from (1976). Economic demand theory and psychologi-
http://books.google.com cal studies of choice. In G. H. Bower (Ed.), The
Mace, F. C., & Critchfield, T. S. (2010). Translational psychology of learning and motivation (Vol. 10, pp.
research in behavior analysis: Historical traditions 129154). New York, NY: Academic Press.
and imperative for the future. Journal of the Experi- Rachlin, H., Raineri, A., & Cross, D. (1991). Subjec-
mental Analysis of Behavior, 93, 293312. tive probability and delay. Journal of the Experimental
Madden, G. J. (2000). A behavioral economics primer. Analysis of Behavior, 55, 233244.
In W. K. Bickel & R. E. Vuchinich (Eds.), Refram- Reed, D. D. (2008). The translation of basic behavioral
ing health behavior change with behavioral economics research to school psychology: A citation analysis.
(pp. 326). Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum As- The Behavior Analyst Today, 9, 143149.
sociates. Reed, D. D., DiGennaro Reed, F. D., Chok, J., & Bro-
Madden, G. J., Begotka, A. M., Raiff, B. R., & Kastern, zyna, G. A. (2011). The tyranny of choice: Choice
L. L. (2003). Delay discounting of real and hypo- overload as a possible instance of effort discounting.
thetical rewards. Experimental and Clinical Psycho- The Psychological Record, 61, 547560.
pharmacology, 11, 139145.

BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS 53
Reed, D. D., & Martens, B. K. (2011). Temporal Sheridan, S. M., Kratochwill, T. R., & Bergan, J. R.
discounting predicts student responsiveness to ex- (1996). Conjoint behavioral consultation: A procedural
change delays in a classroom token system. Journal of manual. New York, NY: Plenum Press.
Applied Behavior Analysis, 44, 118. Skinner, B. F. (1953). Science and human behavior. New
Roane, H. (2008). On the applied use of progressive- York, NY: Macmillan.
ratio schedules of reinforcement. Journal of Applied Thaler, R. H., & Sunstein, C. R. (2008). Nudge: Im-
Behavior Analysis, 41, 155161. proving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness.
Roane, H. S., Call, N. A., & Falcomata, T. S. (2005). A New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
preliminary analysis of adaptive responding under Tversky, A., & Thaler, R. H. (1990). Anomalies: Prefer-
open and closed economies. Journal of Applied Be- ence reversals. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4,
havior Analysis, 38, 335348. 201211.
Roane, H. S., Falcomata, T. S., & Fisher, W. W. (2007).
Applying the behavioral economics principle of unit Author Notes
price to DRO schedule thinning. Journal of Applied Derek D. Reed, Department of Applied Behav-
Behavior Analysis, 40, 529534. ioral Science, University of Kansas; Christopher R.
Roane, H. S., Lerman, D. C., & Vorndran, C. M. Niileksela, Department of Psychology and Research
(2001). Assessing reinforcers under progressive in Education, University of Kansas; Brent A. Kaplan,
schedule requirements. Journal of Applied Behavior Department of Applied Behavioral Science, University
Analysis, 34, 145167. of Kansas.
Salvy, S. J., Nitecki, L. A., & Epstein, L. H. (2009). Do The authors thank the various clinicians and behav-
social activities substitute for food in youth? Annals ior analysts with whom they have worked with over the
of Behavioral Medicine, 38, 205212. years that prompted the writing of this tutorial, as well
Samuelson, P. A., & Nordhaus, W. D. (1985). Econom- as Scott Wiggins and Dave Jarmolowicz for their as-
ics. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill. sistance to the authors during the course of manuscript
Scheres, A., Dijkstra, M., Ainslie, E., Balkan, J., Reyn- preparation. Finally, they acknowledge the role of their
olds, B., Sonuga-Barke, E., & Castellanos, F. X. Applied Behavioral Science (ABSC) 509 students for
(2006). Temporal and probabilistic discounting of persistently asking for examples of how basic behavioral
rewards in children and adolescents: Effects of age science translates to practice. The examples derived
and ADHD symptoms. Neuropsychologia, 44, 2092 from these conversations and discussions have been
2103. integrated throughout the tutorial.
Schouwenburg, H. C., & Groenewoud, J. T. (2001). Correspondence concerning this article should be
Study motivation under social temptation: Effects of addressed to Derek D. Reed, Department of Applied
trait procrastination. Personality and Individual Dif- Behavioral Science, University of Kansas, 4048 Dole
ferences, 30, 229240. Human Development Center, 1000 Sunnyside Avenue,
Schweitzer, J. B., & Sulzer-Azaroff, B. (1988). Self-con- Lawrence, KS 66045-7555. Email: dreed@ku.edu.
trol: Teaching tolerance for delay in impulsive chil-
dren. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior,
50, 173186.
Sheridan, S. M., & Gutkin, T. B. (2000). The ecol-
ogy of school psychology: Examining and changing
our paradigm for the 21st century. School Psychology
Review, 29, 485502.

54 BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS

Potrebbero piacerti anche