Sei sulla pagina 1di 18

JOURNAL OF THE EXPERIMENTAL ANALYSIS OF BEHAVIOR 19841 42, 435-452 NUMBER 3 (NOVEMBER)

BEHA VIORAL ECONOMICS


STEVEN R. HURSH
WALTER REED ARMY INSTITUTE OF RESEARCH

Economics, like behavioral psychology, is a science of behavior, albeit highly organized


human behavior. The value of economic concepts for behavioral psychology rests on (1)
their empirical validity when tested in the laboratory with individual subjects and (2) their
uniqueness when compared to established behavioral concepts. Several fundamental con-
cepts are introduced and illustrated by reference to experimental data: open and closed
economies, elastic and inelastic demand, and substitution versus complementarity.
Changes in absolute response rate are analyzed in relation to elasticity and intensity of de-
mand. The economic concepts of substitution and complementarity are related to tradi-
tional behavioral studies of choice and to the matching relation. The economic approach
has many implications for the future of behavioral research and theory. In general,
economic concepts are grounded on a dynamic view of reinforcement. The closed-
economy methodology extends the generality of behavioral principles to situations in
which response rate and obtained rate of reinforcement are interdependent. Analysis of
results in terms of elasticity and intensity of demand promises to provide a more direct
method for characterizing the effects of "motivational" variables. Future studies of choice
should arrange heterogeneous reinforcers with varying elasticities, use closed economies,
and modulate scarcity or income. The economic analysis can be extended to the study of
performances that involve subtle discriminations or skilled movements that vary in ac-
curacy or quality as opposed to rate or quantity, and thus permit examination of time/ac-
curacy trade-offs.
Key words: economics, demand, elasticity, open economies, closed economies,
substitutes, complements, income, reinforcer value, response rate, choice, generalized
matching, discrimination, observing response

"Why economics?" is a question frequently Lewin's (1951) analogy to physical field


asked of those interested in the relevance of theory, and, more recently, analogies to
economic theory for behavior analysis. The physics (Nevin, Mandell, & Atak, 1983) and
practice of looking to another discipline for control theory in engineering (McFarland,
useful ways to analyze behavior is certainly 1971). In contrast to these earlier theories,
not without precedent. Consider Descartes' economic theory is more than an analogy to
(1662/1965) hydraulic analogy, John Stuart behavioral psychology; economics is also a
Mill's (1843/1965) chemical analogy, Kurt science of behavior, albeit that of highly
organized human behavior. Unlike behav-
This paper is dedicated to the memory of Don Hake, ioral psychology, it lacks a rigorous empiri-
a pioneer in the effort to close the gap between cal base in controlled experimentation with
laboratory analysis of behavior and behavior in the individual subjects. This paper describes re-
natural environment. I wish to thank Richard Bauman cent attempts to provide that base and the
and James Morrison for their assistance in conducting resulting benefits to behavioral psychology
the experiments described and in the preparation of in terms of increased generality of our prin-
this manuscript. The views of the authors do not pur-
port to reflect the position of the Department of the ciples.
Army or the Department of Defense (para 4-3, AR The value of economic concepts for be-
360-5). Reprints may be obtained from the author at havioral psychology rests on (1) their em-
Department of Medical Neurosciences, Division of pirical validity when tested in the laboratory
Neuropsychiatry, Walter Reed Army Institute of with individual subjects and (2) their utility
Research, Walter Reed Army Medical Center,
Washington, DC 20307. when compared to established behavioral
435
436 STEVEN R. HURSH
concepts. Validity will be measured as the
consistency of economic predictions with the
results of behavioral experiments. Utility
will be evaluated as a demonstrable dif-
ference between, on the one hand, economic
concepts and the phenomena they describe,
and, on the other hand, current behavioral
principles. If it meets these criteria, behav-
ioral economics can appropriately shape D4000 CONSTANT ,o 2000 ,
what we do in the future in the behavioral = ~~~FOODa
laboratory, shape our descriptions of behav-
ioral processes, and affect the generality of z 2000
BO)
100 s
CIO
our predictions.
z24000 /i20
THE VALIDITY AND UTILITY
OF ECONOMIC CONCEPTS 4000 {J VI 60) 20002 0
Many of the concepts described here were CDIAL CODV SHDL
developed as an outgrowth of other studies 2000 & -1000
conducted at the Walter Reed Army Insti- CONSTANT I.
tute of Research. The subjects were mon- WATER
keys that were housed in their test chambers, MV 60)
120 2 40 480~
p a a I

a practice that permitted multiple test ses- 30 60


sions each day as well as continuous testing. VARIABLE FOOD VI SCHEDULE
It was not feasible or necessary to keep the (sec)
animals at some prescribed weight (i.e., Fig. 1. Absolute response rate (responses per hr) of
80% ad lib); rather, their total daily ration two monkeys (SM2, filled circles; SM3, unfilled
was given during the course of a day's test- circles) in a closed economy under three concurrent VI
ing. The maximum ration or the length of schedules shown as a function of the mean value of one
the sessions was usually set to ensure an ade- of the schedules. Top panel: responsing on a variable
VI schedule of food-pellet delivery as a function of the
quate rate of responding. Under these condi- mean schedule value along the x axis. Middle panel:
tions, I confirmed the informal "lab lore" of responding on a constant VI 60-s schedule of food-
this laboratory: To increase response rate, pellet delivery as a function of the value of the chang-
one increased the size of the fixed-ratio (FR) ing VI food schedule. Bottom panel: responding under
or variable-interval (VI) schedule, or the constant VI 60-s schedule of water delivery as a
decreased the size of the reinforcer. This function of the value of the changing food schedule.
Data are from Hursh (1978).
relationship held true for conventional rein-
forcers such as food and water as well as for total ration of food and water during the ses-
reinforcement by drug self-administration sions (a closed economy). The basic pro-
(e.g., heroin and morphine). This phenom- cedure was a three-lever concurrent sched-
enon appeared to contradict current theories ule. Two schedules were held constant at VI
of simple action (Catania, 1963; Herrnstein, 60 s, one providing single pellets of food and
1970); certainly our manipulations reduced the other providing single squirts of water;
the amount of reinforcement, yet the rate of the third VI schedule provided identical
responding increased. This observation led pellets of food and its mean value was varied
to a more extensive experiment (Hursh, in five steps from 30 s to 480 s.
1978) in which two monkeys (SM2 and Figure 1 summarizes the changes in re-
SM3), housed in their experimental cham- sponse rate. Responding on the two food
bers, were studied. They were tested for schedules (top two panels) generally increased
about 100 min per day and received their as the VI schedules were lengthened (except
BEHA VIORAL ECONOMICS 437

R economy," Hursh, 1980). Food responding


5,000 decreased slightly across increases in VI
schedule as indicated in Figure 2, labeled
"open economy." Included in Figure 2 for
4,000 comparison are dashed lines indicating the
C=
x
average change in response rate under
LU
3,000 similar VI schedules reported by Catania
C-,
LU
(1963, squares) and by Catania and
CO)
z
2,000
Reynolds (1968, Xs) for pigeons held at
CL 80% of their free-feeding weights (i.e., an
open economy). These results parallel the
1,000 open-economy data from the monkeys and
implicate the manner of controlling sessions
as an important variable. Other examples
20 30 40 50 60 P exist in the literature (e.g., Collier, Hirsch,
VARIABLE INTERVAL ISEC) & Hamlin, 1972; Findley, 1959) and other
Fig. 2. Average absolute response rate (responses experiments with rats have extended it (see
per hr) on VI food schedules of two monkeys in either a Hursh & Natelson, 1981). The distinction
closed economy (filled circles) or an open economy between open and closed economies has
(unfilled circles), shown as a function of the program- become common (see Brady, 1982; Collier,
med mean VI duration (s). Average response rate and 1983; Delius, 1983; Lucas, 1981; Mellitz,
programmed VI value were calculated as the sum of
performance and reinforcement from two separate Hineline, Whitehouse, & Laurence, 1983;
concurrent VI schedules (see Hursh 1978, 1980). Also Norborg, Osborne, & Fantino, 1983;
shown for comparison are the mean changes in response Rachlin, 1982).
rate over the same range of VI values observed in two The economic concept of demand elastic-
previous studies of pigeons in open economies,
Catania (1963, squares) and Catania & Reynolds ity predicts these results (e.g., Samuelson,
(1968, Xs). 1976; Watson & Holman, 1977); the inverse
relation between response rate and rein-
SM3, variable food schedule). The greatest forcement rate or probability is derivable
increase occurred under the constant VI from the concept of inelastic demand (Hursh,
schedule. Responding under the VI water 1980). Inelastic demend specifies that large
schedule decreased as the VI food schedule increases in price (increases in FR or de-
increased (bottom panel). creases in probability) will produce small
These results showed that when subjects decreases in consumption. This minimization
obtain their total daily food ration by of consumption loss can be achieved only by
responding during the test session, response increases in total expenditure-in this case,
rate is inversely related to rate of reinforce- response rate. It can be shown that the same
ment. This relation is summarized in Figure applies to increases in VI schedules because
2, labeled "closed economy." The increase in price and interval length are directly cor-
responding for food could not be explained related (see Hursh, 1980, Figure 18). While
by appeal to either progregsive deprivation VI schedules set a limit on consumption, ob-
effects across VI schedules or satiation tained rate of reinforcement can vary with
within sessions; the increase in response rate overall response output if the sessions are
occurred despite constant overall food intake sufficiently long and if the subjects are not so
(SM3) and even when only the first 15 min deprived as to respond at nearly maximal
of each session were considered. The experi- rates. In the experiment just described, in-
ment was repeated (Hursh, 1978, Experi- creases in response rate with decreases in
ment II) with provisions to hold daily food reinforcer availability increased the deliv-
and water intake constant and independent ered rate of reinforcement from about 50 %
of responding during the sessions ("open to nearly 100% of the maximum available.
438 STEVEN R. HURSH
This kind of inelastic demand would be ex-
pected only in cases involving an essential
commodity such as food and in which no 0.5
other source of the commodity is available. *SM 2
The direct relation between response rate o SM 3
CN
0 0
and reinforcement rate or probability is 0.0
IL.L
derivable from the concept of elastic demand, -a
LA.

which specifies that small increases in price


(e.g., FR or VI schedule) will produce large 0D -0.5
decreases in consumption. In this case, total
expenditure, or response rate, decreases
with increasing schedule size. With essential
commodities such as food, this would be ex-
pected when there is a substitutable supply
as in an open economy. Elastic demand LOG( RFOOD1
FOOD2 )
might also be expected of nonessential com-
modities such as brain stimulation or sac-
charin (see Figure 4). 1.0
A second implication of the experiment
was the contrasting changes with food and
water reinforcement. Referring again to 0.5
Figure 1, the variable food schedule (top
panel) was concurrent with, and served as
the context for, responding under two con-
stant VI schedules, one for food and one for
0
3~ 0.0
water. Responding under the constant food 0-I-
CD
schedule increased and responding under cm -0.5
the constant water schedule decreased. __

These results contradict any choice theory


that predicts contextual effects without
regard to the nature of the reinforcers (see
Herrnstein, 1970, 1974; Rachlin, 1973).
This point is illustrated in Figure 3. In the
top panel the ratio of Food 2 lever presses LOG( RWATER
RFOOD )
(P2) to Food 1 lever presses (P1) is plotted as
a function of the ratio of Food 2 reinforcers Fig. 3. Top panel: For two monkeys in a closed
economy (SM 2, filled circles; SM 3, unfilled circles)
(R2) to Food 1 reinforcers (R1), each in the log ratio of performance (P) for Food 2 to Food 1,
logarithmic units. The major diagonal in- shown as a function of the log ratio of obtained rein-
dicates perfect matching; actual data are a forcers (R) from Food 2 to Food 1. Bottom panel: For
close approximation, with a commonly re- the same subjects in the same experiment the log ratio
ported tendency to "undermatch" (Baum, of performance for Food (Food 1 plus Food 2) to
Water, shown as a function of the log ratio of obtained
1974, 1979; Myers & Myers, 1977). The food reinforcers (Food 1 plus Food 2) to obtained water
bottom panel depicts the ratio of total food to reinforcers. Data are from Hursh (1978).
water presses as a function of food to water
reinforcers, again in log units. Here the minimized changes in the ratio of food to
distribution of responses is negatively related water consumption (x axis); stated another
to the distribution of reinforcers, a case of way, the subjects defended a certain "water
countermatching. The nearly vertical func- balance." This was possible because in a
tion suggests that responses were distributed closed economy, subjects have control of
to food and water schedules in a way that their daily intakes, even under VI schedules.
BEHA VIORAL ECONOMICS 439
As one food schedule was restricted, re- Elasticity and Absolute Response Rate
sponding increased in a way that minimized
reductions in intake. As indicated above, The concept of elasticity has proven useful
percentage of available reinforcers actually in subsequent research. Hursh and Natelson
obtained increased from about 50% to nearly (1981) described an experiment in which
100%. At the same time responding for three rats lived in two-lever test chambers.
water decreased. This dynamic process had One lever provided, according to a VI
the effect of minimizing changes in the ob- schedule, two 0.5-s trains of electrical brain
tained ratio of food to water reinforcers stimulation (EBS). The other lever pro-
through large counteradjustments in the vided, according to an identical VI schedule,
ratio of food to water responses. The out- a 45-mg food pellet. Across conditions of the
come was the strong countermatching seen experiment, both VI schedules were in-
in the bottom panel of Figure 3. creased in mean length from 3 s to 60 s. In
The function in the top panel illustrates the first phase of the experiment the intensity
the economic concept of substitutes. Food of the EBS was chosen such that response
from Source 1 substituted for food from rates for EBS and food were about equal at
Source 2; as the quantity from Source 2 was VI 15 s, labeled low current (LO). In the
reduced, responding to Source 1 increased second phase, the intensity of the EBS was
(Hursh, 1980). In economic terms, strict increased to a level just below that which
matching presumes perfect substitutability elicited gross motor movements, approx-
and is a narrow subset of all choice possi- imately 2.5 times the low-current value,
bilities accommodated by the economic labeled high current (HI). The response-rate
theory of consumer demand (Rachlin, functions maintained by these different rein-
Kagel, & Battalio, 1980). The bottom panel forcers are shown in Figure 4A. Response
shows an example of the economic concept rates maintained by EBS (solid lines) and
of complements. Water complements the util- food (dashed line) are plotted as a function of
ity of food; as food becomes more abundant, VI value (note the log units). In both phases
responding for water increases relative to of the experiment (LO and HI current), re-
responding for food, thus minimizing sponding for EBS was inversely related to VI
changes in the ratio of the two levels of con- value and responding for food was directly
sumption (see Hursh, 1980). The gener- related to VI value. This result is surprising
alized matching law (Baum, 1974, 1979) ac- for two reasons. First, the two reinforcers
commodates this kind of "countermatching" did not maintain comparable performances
if the exponent takes negative values - in in the face of comparable schedule changes.
this case -10. Interestingly, Rachlin et al. This, again, presents a challenge to any law
(1980) have shown that generalized match- of simple action that does not take into ac-
ing can be derived from economic utility count the nature of the reinforcer (Catania,
theory (Barten, 1977; Samuelson, 1976; 1973; Herrnstein, 1970; see also de Villiers,
Watson & Holman, 1977) and, furthermore, 1977). Second, performance that produced
utility theory provides a rationale for food in this closed economy increased with
changes in the exponent in terms of "substi- decreasing reinforcer availability, similar to
tutability." Generalized matching, on the that seen with monkeys' food-reinforced
other hand, does not by itself lead to responding in a closed economy but contrary
economic utility theory. The more general to that seen for subjects working in an open
nature of utility theory opens the possibility economy (e.g., Catania, 1963; Catania &
of prediction of other novel phenomena Reynolds, 1968).
beyond the scope of the generalized match- These confusing distinctions in terms of
ing law. These are powerful indications that response rate make sense in terms of elastic-
economic theory can serve as a useful guide ity of demand. The demand curves relating
to new behavioral phenomena. consumption to price (responses per rein-
440 STEVEN R. HURSH

A forcer) are shown in Figure 4B. Elasticity is


defined as the slope of these functions plotted
HI EBS in log-log coordinates. Equal relative changes
in consumption and price produce parallel
cr-
D changes in the demand curve plotted in log-
0
I
log coordinates, independent of absolute level
cr- of demand. Figure 4B shows that food con-
LU 100 sumption declined only slightly with price,
and demand therefore was inelastic. In con-
LU
0 trast EBS consumption declined steeply with
z
0
price, and demand therefore was elastic.
Furthermore, increasing EBS intensity in-
LUJ
cr-
creased the level of intensity of demand but
had little effect on elasticity of demand.
10 Elasticity as a Behavioral Concept
3 7.5 15 30 60 The next question is whether the concept
of elasticity is distinct from other behavioral
concepts or whether it is simply an economic
name for a current behavioral term. Rein-
o H E BS B forcer
amountvalue has been variously
of reinforcement defined as
(Herrnstein, the
1974)
3000 LO
~\ \* or the amount of behavior maintained by the
1i EBS reinforcer (e.g., Premack, 1965; Rachlin,
N, 1971). According to either definition, when
z A*\ b \ the level of EBS was increased in the second
1000
LLI \ \ phase of the study by Hursh and Natelson
FOOD \ * (1981), EBS increased in value. The solid
z -g- - lines of Figure 4A show that responding dur-
0
300 - \
* \ ing EBS was increased by a factor of about
seven. Despite this increase in value, the
:D
z
elasticity of demand for EBS shown in
0
C) I00 Figure 4B was not altered and the downward
* slope of the demand curve with increasing
I price was identical under both low- and
2 4 8 high-current conditions. Because value was
PRICE (RESPONSES / REINF.) manipulated without changing elasticity,
Fig. 4. Panel A: In log-log coordinates, average these two concepts are distinct; value is more
response rsate (responses per hr) of three rats in a closed closely related to the level of consumption or
economy lunder two concurrent VI schedules of re- intensity of demand while elasticity is a
sponse-prc)duced electrical brain stimulation (EBS, measure of the slope or rate of change in
solid lines) and food pellets (dashed line), shown as a
function off the mean value of both schedules. EBS was consumption
studied at two intensities indicated as low (LO) and Similarly, comparing the level of respond-
high (HI). Data are from Hursh & Natelson (1981). ing for EBS and food with minimal con-
Panel B: Iin log-log coordinates, the average consump- straint (VI 3 s), one concludes that EBS was
tion per d ay of EBS and food by the same three rats valued more than food at both intensities.
plotted as a function of the price, defined as the ,
responses emitted per day divided by the reinforcers Nevertheless, demand for EBS in the face of
obtained p)er day. Lines of best fit are drawn through increasing constraint was more elastic than
the points indicating the approximate slope or "elastic- demand for food. Thus, a high level of con-
ity" of thesse demand curves. sumption or performance for a commodity
BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS 441
implying high reinforcer value does not imply "essential" commodity with few substitutes,
inelastic demand in economic terms. The but EBS may be a "nonessential" commodity
two terms are clearly distinct. with many substitutes. Likewise, the dif-
Elasticity is also distinct from the concept ference between open and closed economies
of response strength or momentum (Nevin et can be related to a more elastic demand
al., 1983). Although both are rate-of-change curve in the open economy resulting from
measures, response strength refers to changes the availability of substitute food outside the
in response rate as a function of some disrupter constraints of the schedule. In both cases
while elasticity measures changes in consump- consumption was a downward sloping func-
tion as a function of price. A performance tion of price; the availability of substitutes
that declines less in the face of a disrupter modulated the magnitude of that slope.
compared to another performance is said to This experiment also indicated that elas-
have greater strength. This is analogous to, ticity is not a property of the reinforcer. It is
but distinct from, saying that when con- a property of the demand curve that de-
sumption of one commodity declines less in scribes the adaptation process that can in-
the face of increasing price, compared to clude the composition of the reinforcer as a
consumption of another commodity, it has controlling variable. Figure 2 indicated that
less elastic demand. In some cases the two monkeys working for food would, in a closed
are mathematically related, as with changes economy, show inelastic demand; in an open
in consumption and response rate under economy, they would show elastic demand.
varying FR schedules. In other cases, re-
sponse strength appears to provide a par- Substitution, Complementarity, and Choice
ticularly fitting description of the results, as The observation of complementarity be-
when response rate changes with increases in tween food and water (Figure 3, bottom
punishment intensity. In yet other cases, the panel) poses a problem for the standard be-
concept of response strength seems less suit- havioral theories of choice but is not surpris-
able than elasticity, as in the experiment ing in relation to physiological studies of
with EBS and food. Here the same variable feeding and drinking. The standard physio-
(VI size) increased the response rate for food logical technique for studying this interac-
and reduced the response rate for EBS. A tion is to deprive subjects of food or water
similar contradiction is illustrated in Figure and to observe changes in the intake of the
2. In this experiment, the same variable (VI other. Only several levels of deprivation are
schedule) for the same reinforcer (food) pro- studied and intake of the other commodity is
duced opposite changes in response rate usually studied under free-feeding condi-
depending on the economic context, either tions (Bolles, 1961; Collier & Knarr, 1966;
open or closed. Kutscher, 1969).
These apparent contradictions are explic- Economic analysis provides a tool for
able in terms of demand and elasticity. Con- studying in more detail this kind of interac-
sumption of both EBS and food was reduced tion. By varying the price of food or water,
by the increase in VI schedule (see Figure one can alter consumption and plot a demand
4B); the change was large for EBS (elastic) curve. At the same time, one can plot the
and slight for food (inelastic). The associated "cross price" change in demand of the other
(and opposite) changes in response rate can commodity by monitoring parallel changes
be viewed as merely instrumental in sup- in its consumption. This method provides
porting the more fundamental demand rela- continuous functions relating, for example,
tionship. The difference in the rate of change water consumption to the price of food. Sub-
in consumption (elasticity) between EBS and sequent experiments alter the price of water,
food is not a contradiction within this the total time available to work, or mix
framework because what was consumed was flavoring such as saccharin with the water to
different. Food could be viewed as an modulate the complementary relation.
442 STEVEN R. HURSH
Determining each demand curve requires stabilized, the schedule value is then in-
the observation of consumption under a creased by a fixed percentage each day up to
series of supply schedules. The most direct some limit (e.g., FR 300). This procedure
method is to use FR schedules because they can provide a complete demand curve in 40
directly set the price of the commodity. The days with approximately 40 price levels.
usual practice in behavioral experiments is Changing a second variable, such as alter-
to study stable performance under each FR native commodities, deprivation level, or
schedule, approximately 30 to 40 days per drug doses, becomes feasible, taking no
schedule. To obtain a demand curve with five longer than the usual time to conduct a
points would take 5 to 6 months; additional behavioral experiment-4 to 6 months. It is
experiments studying the effects of other an open question whether these demand
variables could each take more than a year curves have the same slope and elevation as
to complete. This method is impractical. In- demand curves obtained after stable perfor-
stead, we have adopted a rapid method for mance at each ratio. This problem is of little
determining demand curves. After perfor- concern, however, because the objective is to
mance on a base FR value (e.g., FR 10) is determine shifts in demand curves all deter-

0 0

6401 0
000 0
0
~~0
0

* 0 0 00 00 0

*** WATER -0%o


(FR 10)
0 , WATER
160_ 0
(FR 10)
w
0.

z
0 80F .
'FOOD
(I)
40F FOOD
z
0
L.)
201- M4 M5

10L L I I Il l

30,000r
' FOOD

10,000O 0
{
FOOD
a: S
0

w 0

a-

(I)
*21
w

z
0 3,0001
a-

nk

I oooL L0L I I I I i

) 20 40 80 160 320 10 20 40 80 160 320


PRICE OR FIXED-RATIO SCHEDULE
Fig. 5. Top panels: In log-log coordinates, consumption per day of food (filled circles) and water (unfilled
circles) by two monkeys (M4 left panel and M5 right panel) in a closed economy, shown as a function of the FR
food schedule. The FR value was increased 10%o each day from FR 10 to FR 308. Bottom panels: in log-log coor-
dinates, the responses emitted per day on the food schedule under the conditions described for the top panels.
BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS 443
mined using this rapid method of determina- substitution available from other alter-
tion. Research so far indicates that excess natives. One would predict a high degree of
variability is not a problem compared to the elasticity of demand for one food with
more traditional method. another food source available and decreasing
Figure 5 displays the results of one such levels of elasticity as alternatives become less
demand curve determination. The FR for substitutable. More recent tests have ex-
food was increased by 10 % each day from tended the results shown in Figure 5. Sac-
FR 10 to FR 308. Two monkeys served as charin-sweetened water instead of plain
subjects and had 24-hr access to both food water was provided concurrently with food.
and water. The top two panels show the de- The size of the food FR was increased in the
mand curves for food of both subjects, along same manner as described above. For both
with the accompanying levels of water con- subjects the slope of the demand curve was
sumption. The demand curves for food indeed steeper or more elastic, as one would
showed increasing elasticity as the FR was expect if sweetened water functioned as a
increased. The curves are generally inelastic partial substitute for food. Nevertheless, the
at prices less than approximately FR 200 saccharin consumption curve was not con-
and response rate increased with increasing sistently different from the prior water con-
price (shown in the bottom panels). The sumption curve, providing no evidence for
curves become elastic at higher prices and physiological substitution.
the response rate functions turn downward. Complementarity of food and water may
Ratios higher than FR 308 were not studied not require change in consumption. Follow-
because levels of consumption became dan- ing the clear case of complementarity shown
gerously low for these large animals. It in Figure 3, another experiment was con-
would not be appropriate to describe behav- ducted with provisions to increase the price
ior under these higher ratio as indicative of of food without necessarily reducing the
behavioral strain, however; response rate at overall consumption. The procedure was
FR 308 was well above the rate at FR 10. similar to that reported by Hursh (1978) ex-
Water consumption showed the expected cept that the three concurrent VI schedules
complementary change downward as food for two foods and one water were all equal at
consumption decreased. This was accom- VI 120 s. The price of one food was altered
panied by a decline in water responding (not by imposing a terminal-link FR requirement
shown), a change entirely consistent with prior to delivery of the food pellet. During
our physiological understanding of feeding this FR the levers and lights correlated with
and drinking but difficult to accommodate the other alternatives were inoperative and
by any theory of choice that treats all rein- the session timer was halted so that this extra
forcers as qualitatively homogeneous. Were work did not count against total session time
food and water equivalent reinforcers, an in- and consequently did not reduce the overall
crease in FR for food should have increased availability of food and water. The duration
water-reinforced responding and consump- of each session was three hours. Because the
tion of water. three concurrent VI schedules were equal
Future studies with this method could ar- and access time to them was constant, total
range for a variety of alternatives besides opportunities to eat and drink remained con-
water-saccharin, wheel running, nesting, stant so long as some responding was main-
or social-oriented behavior. One would ex- tained by all three schedules. The terminal-
pect a variety of cross-demand relations link FR for one food was varied in eight
ranging from complementarity, as in this ex- steps from FR 1 to FR 240. Except at FR
ample, to substitution, as in cases in which 240, total consumption of food and water
the alternative is another food. In addition, was constant. Figure 6 shows the changes in
the elasticity of demand for the target com- response rate plotted similarly to Figure 1.
modity should be sensitive to the degree of Each point is a mean of two replications. Of
444 STEVEN R. HURSH
One subject (SM2) showed the former
tendency predominantly; the other subject
(SM3) showed the latter tendency predom-
inantly. In both cases, however, the distri-
bution of food responses shifted away from
the variable schedule toward the fixed
schedule.
m
Co
m
Co
IMPLICATIONS FOR
LU
z
co FUTURE RESEARCH
Co m
uz
c- Co
The economic concepts introduced so far
Co have been validated in initial laboratory ex-
LA
perimentation and, in addition, appear to
cn 9 describe relationships that have no parallel
6 within the current behavioral vocabulary. In
this sense these concepts are useful for
describing and interpreting phenomena that
lie outside the domain of current behavioral
WATER > terminology. This section will describe the
(FR 1) utility of economic concepts for broadening
1 4 16 64 240 the generality of behavioral principles and
VARIABLE FOOD FR SCHEDULE the implications of those concepts for future
research.
Fig. 6. In a manner similar to Figure 1, the ab-
solute response rate (responseg per hr) of two monkeys
(SM 2, filled circles; SM 3, unfilled circles) working in A Dynamic View of Reinforcement
a closed economy under three concurrent VI 120-s
schedules, shown as a function of the terminal-link FR
The economic approach to behavior
schedule (log scale) appended to one of the VI food typified by emphasis on the demand curve
schedules. The top panel shows performance under the encourages the researcher to view consump-
VI schedule leading to the terminal-link FR schedule tion or obtained rate of reinforcement as a
that varied in value as shown along the x axis. The major outcome of behavioral adaptation and
middle panel shows performance under the VI food to focus on the manipulated conditions of the
schedule that led to a constant terminal link FR 1. The experiment (e.g., fixed-ratio schedule or
bottom panel shows performance under the VI water
schedule that also led to a constant terminal-link FR 1. price, available substitutes, supplemental
feeding) as the important controlling vari-
principle interest in the complementary ables. Both response rate and reinforcement
change in water responding in the bottom rate are products of a dynamic adaptation
panel. Although the decline is not as process and it makes little sense to explain
uniform and large as it was in Figure 1, com- the final equilibrium level of one in terms of
plementarity was clear for both subjects even the other. For example, to say that "the in-
at FR values less than 240, which did not creased rate of reinforcement led to an in-
alter food and water consumption. creased rate of responding" is an inadequate
Food-reinforced responding varied in a way to describe a situation in which rein-
manner indicative of mutual substitution forcement and responding are mutually in-
between the two foods. One would expect a terdependent. This problem has by no
reduced tendency to respond on the alter- means been ignored by behavioral research-
native with the increasing FR terminal link ers. The solution typically has been to in-
(variable food), and an increased tendency terupt this interdependence with special pro-
to respond on the alternative with the con- cedures such as short sessions with constant
stant FR-1 terminal link (constant food). deprivation (open economies) and interval-
BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS 445
based schedules of reinforcement. Unfor- 1980) as an "ideal state when daily consump-
tunately, the result has been a behavioral tion is the result of the equilibrium of supply
theory that lacks generality to situations of and demand" (p. 223) or daily consumption
mutual interdependence of these variables is solely the result of the subject's behavior in
typified by the closed economy. The experi- interaction with the schedules of reinforce-
mental results described so far show clearly ment. An open economy is "any of a variety
that the distinction is significant. To the ex- of experimental arrangements that provides
tent that the natural environment resembles at least a measure of independence between
a closed more than an open economy, a shift daily consumption and the equilibrium con-
to a more dynamic approach to behavior dition" (p. 223). These terms define a con-
analysis based on studies of performance in tinuum of conditions that range from specific
closed economies will be necessary for a arrangements of between-session feeding
general theory of behavior. and control of session length that link daily
Explaining response rate in terms of the consumption and the equilibrium condi-
programmed schedule value is a form of tions to others in which daily consumption
"causation at a distance" and challenges our is totally independent of behavior under the
understanding of behavioral control. Never- test conditions. Notice that it is not between-
theless, remote causation may provide a session consumption per se that creates an
simpler and more powerful explanation. A open economy, but arrangements that make
simple notion of proximal causation with in- daily consumption independent of within-
dependent and dependent variables that im- session performance. A brief period of post-
mediately contact one another does not session access to a commodity with relatively
readily accommodate a dynamic system in long periods of access during the session may
which the variables interact in response to not diminish the importance of the within-
outside manipulations. To view response session performance for controlling the over-
strength as a direct product of reinforcement all level of consumption, and the results
is very different from the economic account from such situations may approximate those
that views responding as dynamic adapta- from a closed economy. Likewise, an exper-
tion to constraint that, in turn, determines imental arrangement in which all food is ob-
rate of reinforcement or consumption. Elas- tained during the session could function like
ticity is a measure of how sensitive consump- an open economy if the length of the sessions
tion is to the imposed constraint, and by im- were modulated so that a constant amount of
plication, of how responding adapts to that food was consumed regardless of response
constraint. The economic view has much in rate.
common with other regulatory accounts Extending our experimental horizon to in-
(Dunham, 1977; Logan, 1964; McFarland, clude the closed economy situation is re-
1971; Staddon, 1979; Timberlake, 1984) quired to increase the generality of behav-
and shares some of the same relations ioral principles. The principles discovered in
described in recent considerations of feed- the open economy do not, of course, cease to
back processes in behavior analysis operate in closed systems; processes such as
(Heyman & Luce, 1979; Prelec, 1982; shaping, discrimination, and contrast un-
Prelec & Herrnstein, 1978; Rachlin & doubtedly occur in both contexts. Yet, the
Burkhard, 1978; Staddon & Motheral, 1978; closed economy involves a form of interde-
see also Hursh, 1980). pendence between performance and rein-
forcement that is largely absent in the open
The Closed Economy economy and, therefore, introduces an addi-
In part, the economic approach en- tional source of functional control. The
courages use of closed economies in the ex- relative importance of that control will prob-
perimental analysis of behavior. I have pre- ably depend in part on the nature of the per-
viously defined a closed economy (Hursh, formance and the reinforcer. We have seen
446 STEVEN R. HURSH
that with food reinforcement the form of terms can be defined operationally, yet more
control is radically different from that seen often they are used as ad hoc explanations.
in an open economy. Where appropriate, In contrast, plotting results in terms of the
then, we must be willing to add new terms to demand curve can lead immediately to a
our current vocabulary to accommodate parametric description of a subject's perfor-
these new forms of control. mance, avoiding unnecessary inference.
The exact nature of the continuum from The two fundamental parameters of the
closed to open economy in procedural terms demand curve are (1) its slope in log-log
is a fundamental subject for future research. coordinates called elasticity of demand and
Future research may define or redirect our (2) its elevation relative to the orgin -what I
focus. For example, is it the availability of a call intensity of demand. These two param-
substitute source of the commodity that is eters are illustrated in Figure 4B, the de-
critical to defining an open economy? And is mand curves for low- and high-intensity
the delay between the end of the session and EBS and for food. The change in intensity of
this between-session consumption impor- EBS current shifts the level or intensity of
tant? Or is it the feedback relationship be- demand without altering elasticity; the
tween response rate in the test session and change in reinforcer from EBS to food alters
daily consumption that is fundamental to the slope or elasticity of demand. In a review
defining a closed economy, regardless of of the research, tentative categories of
substitution effects? Whatever that fun- variables that selectively influence either
damental variable is, it should modulate the elasticity or intensity of demand can be iden-
elasticity of demand for an essential com- tified. Those variables are discussed in the
modity such as food from elastic (open) to in- following two sections.
elastic (closed) and shift the function relating Elasticity of demand. At least four sorts of
response rate to ratio or interval size from an variables alter elasticity of demand. First,
inverse to a direct relation (see Figure 2). the nature of the commodity can determine
the slope of the demand curve or how vigor-
Demand Curve Analysis ously the subject's performance defends in-
Future behavioral analyses will un- take in the face of increasing price. The de-
doubtedly evolve a dynamic view of behav- mand curves for EBS and food in Figure 4B
ioral control mechanisms; the economic ac- illustrate this case (Hursh & Natelson,
count is one example. Whether we borrow 1981). Another example was reported by
economic terminology or formulate a Findley (1959) in which demand for food
separate framework remains a question; and water was inelastic, but demand for
regardless, the notion of a demand curve is room illumination was elastic (see Hursh,
useful as a description of one aspect of rein- 1980).
forcement. This approach will do more than A second variable altering elasticity is the
alter the way we speak about behavior. species of consumer. Boice (1984) compared
Analysis of behavior in terms of the demand demand for water by two species of packrats,
curve provides a convenient unifying one captured in a desert environment, the
framework for analyzing a variety of other captured in a more moist environ-
variables that are usually described as ment. He found that although the arid-
"motivational" in their effects on behavior. habitat packrats drank large amounts of
The advantage both experimentally and water when price was low (i.e., FR 2) com-
conceptually is that the demand curve and pared to moist-habitat packrats, they drank
the parameters describing its level and slope very little water when price was high (FR 32)
(elasticity) are descriptions of "motivational" compared to moist-habitat packrats. Thus,
effects that avoid reference to hypothetical the demand curve of water consumption was
factors such as deprivation, value, strength, far more elastic for the arid-habitat packrats
or probability. To be sure, some of these than for the moist-habitat packrats. This
BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS 447
provided an experimental quantification of and by determining the slope and intensity
the natural observation that packrats from parameters, we can characterize new vari-
the driest habitats drink the most free- ables that may have "motivational" effects.
standing water, even though they have the Examples of novel variables might be new
least "need" for water as gauged by their con- drugs, chemical toxins, brain lesions or
sumption of water when it is scarce. stimulation, and circadian or seasonal
A third variable that alters elasticity is the changes (Elsmore & Hursh, 1982). To illus-
availability of substitutes. Previously I trate this approach, consider the study of
described how availability of substitutes in hypothalamic hyperphagia in monkeys re-
an open economy can increase elasticity ported by Hamilton and Brobeck (1964).
(Figure 5) and how the elasticity of demand They reported food consumption as a func-
for food may depend on the availability of a tion of FR schedule for control subjects and
sweet-tasting alternative. Lea and Roper brain-lesioned subjects either in the dynamic
(1977) have illustrated how availability of phase of weight gain or after stable obesity.
sucrose can alter elasticity of demand for These demand curves showed higher levels
food. of food consumption at low prices (FRs) for
The fourth category is the economic con- the lesioned subjects compared to controls,
text discussed earlier-either open or closed. but higher levels of consumption for controls
The effect of this variable on elasticity may at high prices. This result was considered an
be a subset of the previous variable, substi- anomaly at the time and led to the idea of
tution, or it may involve other factors as "finicky" behavior produced by hypotha-
well, such as feedback mechanisms. The dif- lamic lesions. However, in the context of
ferences in response rate between open and variables that we now know alter the de-
closed economies shown in Figure 2 are mand curve, it appears no more anomalous
directly related to inelastic demand in the than many other variables that have similar
closed economy and elastic demand in the effects on the demand curve. The effect of
open economy (see Hursh, 1980). the lesion was to increase the elasticity of de-
Intensity of demand. The level or intensity mand for food and was similar in effect to
of demand appears to be altered by at least changing the nature of the reinforcer or its
two categories of variables. First, the level of relationship to substitutable alternatives. In
deprivation can increase the level of de- some manner, the lesion shifted the elasticity
mand. Meisch and Thompson (1973) re- of demand for food in a direction toward the
ported demand curves for ethanol under elasticity of demand for electrical stimulation
food satiety or food deprivation. The de- of the hypothalamus (Hursh & Natelson,
mand curve obtained with food deprivation 1981). Studies of other "novel" variables will
was uniformly shifted upward in relation to benefit by comparison to the effects of
the curve under food satiation, indicating known variables on the parameters of the de-
that food deprivation increased the intensity mand curve.
of demand for ethanol (see Hursh, 1980).
Second, the magnitude of reinforcement Theories of Choice
may alter the intensity of demand for some Research conducted so far within the eco-
commodities. Figure 4A shows an upward nomic framework indicates clearly that be-
shift in response rate correlated with an in- havioral theories of choice must be extended
crease in brain stimulation intensity. The to and tested within a context of hetero-
related demand curves show a similar shift geneous reinforcers (e.g., Hursh, 1978;
in level or intensity shown in Figure 4B. Hursh & Natelson, 1981; Lea & Roper,
Characterizing new variables. The value of 1977; Rachlin, Green, Kagel, & Battalio,
this approach goes beyond a mere categor- 1976). When the reinforcers offered for
ization of past results. By conducting ap- choice are functionally identical and substi-
propriate experiments to measure demand tutable, economic theory predicts the usual
448 STEVEN R. HURSH
matching relationship between relative on the level of EBS responding and con-
responding and relative consumption sumption, but had virtually no effect on the
(Rachlin et al., 1980). Because nearly all level of food responding or consumption.
behavioral work on choice has used identical Although food became relatively less valu-
reinforcers for the alternatives, the matching able, absolute responding was unaffected
relation is usually found. However, when (see Herrnstein, 1970). Much future work
the reinforcers provided are not identical, remains to fully explore the range of interac-
various degrees of nonmatching or even tions that can occur, the variables that
countermatching are found (Hursh, 1978; modulate them, and the "mutuality" of these
Rachlin et al., 1976, 1980), because changes interactions. For example, food consump-
in consumption of one alternative are not ac- tion may not be as sensitive to the price of
companied by equal and opposite changes in water as water consumption is sensitive to
consumption of the other when the two are the price of food. Although this enterprise
not substitutes. That is the major implica- will undoubtedly complicate our theories of
tion of the results shown in Figure 3. choice, simplicity ought not be purchased at
Future work with a variety of reinforcers the price of accuracy. Economic theory pro-
will enhance our understanding of the many vides a relatively simple framework for ex-
forms of reinforcer interaction. Neither panding the range of interactions that can be
economic theory nor any other theory can addressed (Rachlin et al., 1976).
predict the form of interaction between two Experiments conducted so far (Hursh,
novel commodities. However, economic 1978; Hursh & Natelson, 1981) also indicate
theory provides a broader descriptive that theories of choice should be tested
framework for characterizing these interac- within the closed economy, where differ-
tions than does current behavior theory. ences in elasticity among various reinforcers
Once a specific type of interaction is iden- are most apparent. For example, Figure 4
tified, economic theory can predict a variety displays the difference between EBS and
of other relations. For example, if two com- food in a choice situation. Although the two
modities are found to be substitutes based on schedules of reinforcement were always
an analysis of cross-demand relations, it equal, increasing scarcity (increasing the
follows that elasticity of demand for one mean interval of both VI schedules) shifted
should depend on the availability of the the distribution of responding from a pref-
other. If two commodities are found to be erence for EBS to a preference for food, an
complements based on changes in price, it outcome that probably would not occur
follows that a decrease in supply (i.e., longer within an open economy, in which demand
VI schedule) or a decrease in package size for food is elastic and responding decreases
(i.e., reinforcer size or concentration) should with increasing scarcity.
produce similar complementary changes. The effect of varying elasticity on choice
Much of this proposed work with comple- was also revealed in an experiment by
ments will parallel past work with substitutes Elsmore, Fletcher, Conrad, and Sodetz
(see de Villiers, 1977, for a review). (1980) in which scarcity was manipulated by
So far, interactions among commodities varying the intertrial interval in a discrete-
have been characterized as substitution (e.g., trial choice procedure. On each trial either
food vs. food) or complementarity (e.g., food or an injection of heroin was made
food vs. water). This dimension of choice is available by means of a short FR schedule.
not dichotomous, however. One would ex- As the frequency of trials was reduced by in-
pect a variety of interactions between these creasing the time between trials, consump-
extremes, including certain reinforcers that tion of heroin was reduced greatly while con-
may be quite independent. Returning again sumption of food was largely conserved; the
to Figure 4, notice that when the intensity of proportion of trials with a food choice in-
EBS was increased, it had a dramatic effect creased as the opportunities to make a choice
BEHAVIORAL ECONOMICS 449
decreased. This finding was consistent withperformances that require subtle discrimina-
the greater elasticity of demand for herointions or skilled movements. Elsmore and
compared to food found in another experi- Hursh (1982) have noted that when discrim-
ment, and confirms again the importance of ination performances are studied in a closed
studying choice for distinctly different rein-
economy, the observed decrease in accuracy
forcers in a closed economy. of a performance in the face of some dis-
The effect of scarcity has other fundamen-
rupter is, in part, related to the severity of
tal implications for a behavioral theory offood deprivation or the availability of other
choice. The opportunity to obtain any of a sources of food. It often seemed that subjects
set of commodities is constrained by income.
would preserve a relatively high level of ac-
If money is exchanged to obtain items, thencuracy by altering some other aspect of their
total amount of money available sets the performance, such as taking longer to make
limit on consumption. If responses or time a choice. Thus, in some cases increases in
are expended, then limitations on total latency more accurately reflected the dif-
responding, either as time or number, limitficulty of the problem than decreases in ac-
consumption. Choice is the way an organism curacy. This kind of time/accuracy trade-off
can make it impossible to compare perfor-
distributes a restricted income, be that time
or money, across a range of commodities. mances in different situations that might in-
The redistribution of income that occurs volve different economic constraints and dif-
when income is restricted implies that the ferent sorts of trade-offs. This has not been a
proportionality of responses to two alter- major problem for work on stimulus control,
natives is not solely dependent on the rela-
discrimination, and signal detection, be-
tive value of the commodities but also cause economic constraints usually have
depends on the available income (see Luce, been highly controlled. Yet, it may be that
1959). If we consider session duration in atime/accuracy trade-offs are more the rule
closed economy as an income manipulation, than the exception in more naturalistic set-
tings, and any extension of theories of stim-
this analysis predicts shifts in choice with
ulus control will have to account for this sort
session duration, provided the array of com-
modities spans a range of elasticities. Like-
of adaptation.
wise, if we increase the price of a commodity An extension of economic theory in this
with inelastic demand, the increase in ex- domain might take the following form. In
many operant studies of discrimination, the
penditure for it will reduce available income
for all other commodities. This could, in subjects must emit an observing response to
produce the sample discriminative stimuli.
turn, generate redistributions of the avail-
able income among those commodities based Let us modify the normal procedure slightly
on their elasticities of demand. This wouldso that observing responses produce only
predict that choice between any two stable brief presentations of the sample stimulus.
commodities is not independent of the con- As is usual practice, if the stimulus falls in
text of performance for other commodities one category, one type of response (e.g., a
even when the other commodities are neitherpress on the left lever) is correct and pro-
substitutes nor complements. Interactions duces food; if it falls in another category, a
different response (e.g., a press on the right
may occur as a result of changes in available
income. Future experiments on choice must lever) is correct. Across conditions of the ex-
periment, the two categories of stimuli are
involve distinctly different alternative com-
made more similar and the difficulty of the
modities to reveal the variety of interactions
that can occur, either as a consequence of discrimination is increased. One would ex-
pect, of course, that the percentage of correct
changes in price of the alternatives or as a
result of changes in income. choices would decline. One would also ex-
pect that the number of discrete observing
Qualitative Changes in Performance responses emitted would increase. With
An economic analysis can be extended to these two measures, a demand curve can be
450 STEVEN R. HURSH
constructed. A correct response is the com- intensity); it is a genuine problem with novel
modity of interest because only correct dimensions. For example, suppose we are
responses produce the reinforcer; percentage interested in a disrupter variable such as cir-
correct in this setting is equivalent to the rate cadian variations in discrimination perfor-
of consumption in a single operant situation. mance (see Elsmore & Hursh, 1982). We ob-
The price of a correct response could be serve changes in accuracy as a function of
measured as the number of observing re- time of day. In order to plot these data to in-
sponses per correct response. The demand dicate a decline in accuracy with time of day,
curve would display on the x axis the num- one needs to order the points; however, we
ber of observing responses per correct have no a priori measure of "preferred"
choice, the price variable; and on they axis, working times. The price measure based on
the number of correct responses per block of observing behavior would provide just such
trials or percentage correct, the consumption a measure. A variety of other "disrupters" of
variable. This function would have the ex- discrimination performance could be sim-
pected negative slope with higher prices ilarly scaled and compared along this com-
associated with lower numbers of correct mon dimension of price. Potential disrupters
responses. The degree of negative slope that could be studied include noise level,
(elasticity) might serve to characterize the concurrent distractor tasks, noxious stimula-
importance of this discrimination in the con- tion, sleep deprivation, drug administration,
text of alternative performances. or brain lesions. An economic analysis in
This approach helps us analyze time/ac- terms of "price equivalent units" provides a
curacy trade-offs. As a discrimination performance-based measure of difficulty or
becomes more difficult or is disrupted by disruption that is independent of our obser-
some external variable, latency to make a vation of accuracy and serves as a conven-
choice increases. In a sense, increased time ient scaler.
is expended to preserve accuracy. By con-
sidering the observation time (latency) per SUMMARY
correct response or by converting the latency
dimension to discrete units of observation The value of economic concepts for
per correct response, we obtain an indepen- behavioral psychology rests on their em-
dent measure of difficulty in terms of the pirical validity when tested in the laboratory
"price" of a correct response. When compar- with individual subjects, and on their
ing performances from different economic uniqueness when compared to established
contexts, we can analyze them in terms of behavioral concepts. These criteria were ad-
the slope of the demand curve for correct dressed here by considering data relevant to
responses, the "elasticity" of accuracy. When the concepts of open and closed economies,
comparing the effects of different disrupters, elastic and inelastic demand, and substitu-
we can distinguish between tasks of constant tion versus complementarity. The validity
difficulty (constant observations per correct) and utility of the demand curve and of the
and tasks of different difficulty that are concept of elasticity of demand were il-
masked by compensations (variations in lustrated by a consideration of the ways
observations per correct) that result in con- changes in elasticity of demand are related to
stant accuracy. changes in absolute response rate. Ex-
This analysis also permits us to scale periments were discussed that varied
percentage correct according to an indepen- elasticity by altering the reinforcer or by
dent measure of difficulty and eliminates the altering the availability of substitutes. De-
need for a priori judgment by the experi- mand elasticity was compared to the more
menter. This is usually not a problem for conventional behavioral concepts of rein-
dimensions of stimulation that affect the sub- forcer value and response strength, and was
ject as they affect us (such as sound or light found to be distinct from these.
BEHA VIORAL ECONOMICS 451
To illustrate the economic concepts of REFERENCES
substitution and complementarity, several
studies were discussed, exploring choice Barten, A. P. (1977). The systems of consumer
demand functions approach: A review.
among qualitatively different reinforcers. Econometrica, 45, 23-51.
The results indicate that the commonly Baum, W. M. (1974). On two types of deviation
observed matching relation does not always from the matching law: Bias and undermatching.
Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 22,
hold in such situations. Demonstrations of 231-242.
complementarity illustrated the existence of Baum, W. M. (1979). Matching, undermatching,
"countermatching" and the need for either an and overmatching in studies of choice. Journal of the
Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 32, 269-281.
expanded interpretation of the generalized Boice, R. (1984). Packrats (Neotoma albigula and N.
matching law or a more economic model of micropus) compared in an operant analogue of forag-
choice that subsumes the matching relation ing behaviors. Journal of Comparative Psychology, 98,
115-118.
as descriptive of choice among substitutable Bolles, R. C. (1961). The interaction of hunger and
alternatives. Demand-curve analysis pro- thirst in the rat. Journal of Comparative and
vides a direct empirical method for charac- Physiological Psychology, 54, 580-584.
Brady, J. (1982). Conceptual and methodological
terizing the effects of variables commonly approaches to long-term research requirements. In
described as "motivational." The two basic J. V. Brady (Ed.), Human behavior in space en-
parameters of demand -elasticity and inten- vironments: A research agenda (pp. 21-32). Baltimore,
MD: Johns Hopkins University School of Medi-
sity - were considered, and categories of cine.
variables were proposed that seem to selec- Catania, A. C. (1963). Concurrent performances:
tively alter these parameters. Reinforcement interactions and response in-
dependence. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of
With respect to future behavioral research Behavior, 6, 253-263.
and theory, the behavioral-economic ap- Catania, A. C. (1973). Self-inhibiting effects of
proach suggests a characterization of rein- reinforcement. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of
Behavior, 19, 517-526.
forcement processes that departs from the Catania, A. C., & Reynolds, G. S. (1968). A quan-
standard view of unidirectional causation titative analysis of the responding maintained by
with independent and dependent variables. interval schedules of reinforcement. Journal of the
Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 11, 327-383.
For example, theories that posit rate of rein- Collier, G. H. (1983). Life in a closed economy:
forcement as a fundamental independent The ecology of learning and motivation. In M. D.
variable are replaced by concepts of dynamic Zeiler & P. Harzem (Eds.), Advances in analysis of
behaviour: Vol. 3. Biological factors in learning (pp.
behavioral adaptation whereby both perfor- 223-274). Chichester, England: Wiley.
mance and obtained rate of consumption are Collier, G., Hirsch, E., & Hamlin, P. H. (1972).
viewed as outcomes of adjustment to en- The ecological determinants of reinforcement in the
rat. Physiology and Behavior, 9, 705-716.
vironmental constraints. Such a view is most Collier, G., & Knarr, F. (1966). Defense of water
important in closed economies, where there balance in the rat. Journal of Comparative and
are strong interdependencies between rates Physiological Psychology, 61, 5-10.
of responding and daily consumption. Delius, J. (1983). Learning. In M. Abs (Ed.),
Physiology and behavior of the pigeon (pp. 327-355).
Finally, economic analysis is not limited New York: Academic Press.
to the study of simple operants; it can also Descartes, R. (1965). De Homine. (T. March, Trans.,
guide our study of performances that involve from 1824 French ed.). Reprinted in R. J. Herrn-
subtle discriminations or skilled move- stein & E. G. Boring (Eds.), A source book in the
history of psychology (pp. 266-272). Cambridge, MA:
ments - performances studied in terms of ac- Harvard University Press. (Original work pub-
curacy or quality as opposed to rate or quan- lished 1662)
tity. The focus here is not on the traditional de Villiers, P. (1977). Choice in concurrent sched-
ules and a quantitative formulation of the law of ef-
notions of sensitivity and bias, but rather on fect. In W. K. Honig & J. E. R. Staddon (Eds.),
a third process that we might call "disrup- Handbook of operant behavior (pp. 233-287).
tion" of discrimination. Economic methods Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
can be used to address time/accuracy trade- Dunham, P. (1977). The nature of reinforcing stim-
uli. In W. K. Honig & J. E. R. Staddon (Eds.),
offs and to scale disrupters of discrimina- Handbook of operant behavior (pp. 98-124). Englewood
tion. Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
452 STEVEN R. HURSH
Elsmore, T. F., Fletcher, G. V., Conrad, D. G., & Mill, J. S. (1965). A system of logic, ratiocinative and
Sodetz, F. J. (1980). Reduction of heroin intake inductive, being a connected view of the principles of
in baboons by an economic constraint. Phar- evidence, and the methods of scientific investigation.
macology, Biochemistry and Behavior, 13, 729-731. Reprinted in R. J. Herrnstein & E. G. Boring
Elsmore, T. F., & Hursh, S. R. (1982). Circadian (Eds.), A source book in the history of psychology (pp.
rhythms in operant behavior of animals under 377-380). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
laboratory conditions. In F. M. Brown & R. C. Press. (Original work published 1843)
Graeber (Eds.), Rhythmic aspects of behavior (pp. Myers, D. L., & Myers, L. E. (1977). Under-
273-310). Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum. matching: A reappraisal of performance on concur-
Findley, J. D. (1959). Behavior output under rent variable-interval schedules of reinforcement.
chained fixed-ratio requirements in a 24-hour ex- Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 27,
perimental space. Journal of the Experimental Analysis 203-214.
of Behavior, 2, 258. Nevin, J. A., Mandell, C., & Atak, J. R. (1983).
Hamilton, C. L., & Brobeck, J. R. (1964). Hypo- The analysis of behavioral momentum. Journal ofthe
thalamic hyperphagia in the monkey. Journal of Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 39, 49-59.
Comparative and Physiological Psychology, 57, 271-278. Norborg, J., Osborne, S., & Fantino, E. (1983).
Herrnstein, R. J. (1970). On the law of effect. Jour- Duration of components and response rates on
nal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 13, multiple fixed-ratio schedules. Animal Learning &
243-266. Behavior, 11, 51-59.
Herrnstein, R. J. (1974). Formal properties of Prelec, D. (1982). Matching, maximizing, and the
the matching law. Journal of the Experimental Analysis hyperbolic reinforcement feedback function.
of Behavior, 21, 159-164. Psychological Review, 89, 189-230.
Heyman, G. M., & Luce, R. D. (1979). Operant Prelec, D., & Herrnstein, R. J. (1978). Feedback
matching is not a logical consequence of maximiz- functions for reinforcement: A paradigmatic ex-
ing reinforcement rate. Animal Learning & Behavior, periment. Animal Learning & Behavior, 6, 181-186.
7, 133-140. Premack, D. (1965). Reinforcement theory. In D.
Hursh, S. R. (1978). The economics of daily con- Levine (Ed.), Nebraska Symposium on Motivation (Vol.
sumption controlling food- and water-reinforced 13, pp.123-180). Lincoln: University of Nebraska
responding. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Be- Press.
havior, 29, 475-491. Rachlin, H. (1971). On the tautology of the
Hursh, S. R. (1980). Economic concepts for the matching law. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of
analysis of behavior. Journal of the Experimental Behavior, 15, 249-251.
Analysis of Behavior, 34, 219-238. Rachlin, H. (1973). Contrast and matching. Psycho-
Hursh, S. R., & Natelson, B. H. (1981). Electrical logical Review, 80, 217-234.
brain stimulation and food reinforcement Rachlin, H. (1982). Absolute and relative consump-
dissociated by demand elasticity. Physiology & tion space. In D. J. Bernstein (Ed.), Nebraska Sym-
Behavior, 26, 509-515. posium on Motivation, 1981: Vol. 29. Response
Kutscher, C. L. (1969). Species differences in the structure and organization (pp. 129-167). Lincoln:
interaction of feeding and drinking. Annals of the University of Nebraska Press.
New York Academy of Sciences, 157, 539-552. Rachlin, H., & Burkhard, B. (1978). The temporal
Lea, S. E. G., & Roper, T. J. (1977). Demand for triangle: Response substitution in instrumental
food on fixed-ratio schedules as a function of the conditioning. Psychological Record, 85, 22-47.
quality of concurrently available reinforcement. Rachlin, H., Green, L., Kagel, J. H., & Battalio, R.
Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 27, C. (1976). Economic demand theory and
371-380. psychological studies of choice. In G. H. Bower
Lewin, K. (1951). Field theory in social science: Selected (Ed.), The psychology of learning and motivation (Vol.
theoretical papers. (D. Cartwright, Ed.). New York: 10, pp. 129-154). New York: Academic Press.
Harper. Rachlin, H., Kagel, J. H., & Battalio, R. C. (1980).
Logan, F. (1964). The free behavior situation. In D. Substitutability in time allocation. Psychological
Levine (Ed.), Nebraska Symposium on Motivation (Vol. Review, 87, 355-374.
12, pp. 99-128). Lincoln: University of Nebraska Samuelson, P. A. (1976). Economics (10th ed.).
Press. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Lucas, G. A. (1981). Some effects of reinforcer
availability on the pigeon's responding in 24-hour Staddon, J. E. R. (1979). Operant behavior as
sessions. Animal Learning & Behavior, 9, 411-424. adaptation to constraint. Journal of Experimental
Luce, R. D. (1959). Individual choice behavior. A Psychology: General, 108, 48-67.
theoretical analysis. New York: Wiley. Staddon, J. E. R., & Motheral, S. (1978). On match-
McFarland, D. J. (1971). Feedback mechanisms in ing and maximizing in operant choice experiments.
animal behaviour. London: Academic Press. Psychological Review, 85, 436-444.
Meisch, R. A., & Thompson, T. (1973). Ethanol Timberlake, W. (1984). Behavior regulation and
as a reinforcer: Effects of fixed-ratio size and food learned performance: Some misapprehensions and
deprivation. Psychopharmacologia, 28, 171-183. disagreements. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of
Mellitz, M., Hineline, P. N., Whitehouse, W. G., & Behavior, 41, 355-375.
Laurence, M. T. (1983). Duration-reduction of Watson, D. S., & Holman, M. A. (1977). Price
avoidance sessions as negative reinforcement. Jour- theory and its uses (4th ed.). Boston: Houghton Mif-
nal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 40, 57-67. flin.

Potrebbero piacerti anche