Sei sulla pagina 1di 49

Ross Levine, "Financial Development and Economic Growth: Views and Agenda",

Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 35, No. 2 (Jun., 1997), pp. 688-726

Journal of Econonzic Literature


Vol. XXXV (June 1QQ7),pp. 688-726

Financial Development and Economic

Growth: vi6ws and Agenda

Ross LEVINE
University of Virginia

I thank, u ~ t h o u zmplzcat~ng,
t Gerard Capno, iMarza Carkoo~c,Daozd Cole, Robert Cull, WII-
lzam Easterly, Mark Gertler, Fabzo Schzantarellz, Mary Shzfley, Bruce Smzth, and Kenneth
Sokolofffor crztzczsms, guzdance, and encouragement T h ~ ps aper was wrltten u,lz~le I was at
the World Bank Opznzons expressed are those of the author and do not necessarzly reflect the
ozews of the World Bank, zts staff, or nrember countries

DoesJ'znance make a difference . . .? Raymond Goldsmith (1969, p. 408)

I. Introduction: Goals and Boundaries of financial factors in economic growth,


while development economists fre-

E CONOMISTS HOLD startlingly dif-


ferent opinions regarding the im-
portance of the financial system for eco-
quently express their skepticism about
the role of the financial system by ignor-
ing it (Anand Chandavarkar 1992). For
nomic growth. Walter Bagehot (1873) example, a collection of essays by the
and John Hicks (1969) argue that it "pioneers of development economics,"
played a critical role in igniting industri- including three Nobel Laureates, does
alization in England by facilitating the not mention finance (Gerald Meir and
mobilization of capital for "immense Dudley Seers 1984). Furthermore,
works." Joseph Schumpeter (1912) con- Nicholas Stern's (1989) review of devel-
tends that well-functioning banks spur opment economics does not discuss the
technological innovation by identifying financial system, even in a section that
and funding those entrepreneurs with lists omitted topics. In light of these con-
the best chances of successfully imple- flicting views, this paper uses existing
menting innovative products and pro- theory to organize an analytical frame-
duction processes. In contrast, Joan Rob- work of the finance-growth nexus and
inson (1952, p. 86) declares that "where then assesses the quantitative impor-
enterprise leads finance follows." Ac- tance of the financial system in economic
cording to this view, economic develop- growth.
ment creates demands for particular Although conclusions must be stated
types of financial arrangements, and the hesitantly and with ample qualifications,
financial system responds automatically the preponderance of theoretical reason-
to these demands. Moreover, some ing and empirical evidence suggests a
economists just do not believe that the positive, first-order relationship between
finance-growth relationship is important. financial development and economic
Robert Lucas (1988, p. 6) asserts that growth. A growing body of work would
economists "badly over-stress" the role push even most skeptics toward the be-
688

Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 689

lief that the development of financial ing the trading of risk, allocating capital,
markets and institutions is a critical and monitoring managers, mobilizing sav-
inextricable part of the growth process ings, and easing the trading of goods,
and away from the view that the financial services, and financial c o n t r a c t s . V h e
system is an inconsequential side show, basic functions remain constant through
responding passively to economic growth time and across countries. There are
and industrialization. There is even evi- large differences across countries and
dence that the level of financial devel- time, however, in the quality of financial
opment is a good predictor of future services and in the types of financial in-
rates of economic growth, capital accu- struments, markets, and institutions that
mulation, and technological change. arise to provide these services. While fo-
Moreover, cross country, case study, in- cusing on functions, this approach does
dustry- and firm-level analyses document not diminish the role of institutions. In-
extensive periods when financial devel- deed, the functional approach highlights
opment-or the lack thereof-crucially the importance of examining an under-
affects the speed and pattern of eco- researched topic: the relationship be-
nomic development. tween financial structure-the mix of
To arrive at these conclusions and to financial instruments, markets, and insti-
highlight areas in acute need of addi- tutions-and the provision of financial
tional research, I organize the remainder services. Thus, this approach discourages
of this paper as follows. Section I1 ex- a narrow focus on one financial instru-
plains what the financial system does and ment, like money, or a particular institu-
how it affects-and is affected by-eco- tion, like banks. Instead, the functional
nomic growth. Theory suggests that fi- approach prompts a more comprehen-
nancial instruments, markets, and insti- sive-and more difficult-auestion: what
1

tutions arise to mitigate the effects of is the relationship between financial


information and transaction costs.' Fur- structure and the tunctioning of the fi-
thermore, a growing literature shows nancial system?3
that differences in how well financial Part I11 then turns to the evidence.
systems reduce information and transac- While many gaps remain, broad cross-
tion costs influence saving rates, invest- country comparisons, individual country
ment decisions, technological innova- studies, industry-level analyses, and
tion, and long-run growth rates. Also, a firm-level investigations point in the
comparatively less developed theoretical
literature demonstrates how changes in 2For different ways of categorizing financial
economic activity can influence financial functions, see Cole and Betty Slade (1991) and
systems. Robert C. Merton and Zvi Bodie (1995).
3 The major alternative approach to studying fi-
Section I1 also advocates the func- nance and economic growth is based on the semi-
tional approach to understanding the nal contributions of John Gurley and Edward
role of financial systems in economic Shaw (1955), James Tobin (1965), and Ronald
McKinnon (1973). In their mathematical models,
growth. This approach focuses on the as distinct from their narratives, they focus on
ties between growth and the quality of money. This narrow focus can restrict the analysis
the functions provided by the financial of the finance-growth nexus, and lead to a mis-
leading distinction between the "real" and finan-
system. These functions include facilitat- cial sectors. I n contrast, the functional a proach
highli hts the value added of the financiarsector.
The Enancia1 system is a "real" sector: it re-
1 These frictions include the costs of acquiring searches firms and managers, exerts corporate
information, enforcing contracts, and exchanging control, and facilitates risk management, ex-
goods and financial claims. change, and resource mobilization.
690 Journal of Economic Literatr are, Vol. XXXV (June 1997)

same direction: the functioning of finan- of the geographic source of those ser-
cial systems is vitally linked to economic vices. In measuring financial develop-
growth. Specifically, countries with ment, however, researchers often do not
larger banks and more active stock mar- account sufficiently for international
kets grow faster over subsequent de- trade in financial services. Second, the
cades even after controlling for many paper does not discuss policy. Given the
other factors underlying economic links between the functioning of the fi-
growth. Industries and firms that rely nancial system and economic growth, de-
heavily on external financing grow dis- signing optimal financial sector policies
proportionately faster in countries with is critically important. A rigorous discus-
well-developed banks and securities sion of these policies, however, would
markets than in countries with poorly require a long article or book by itself.5
developed financial systems. Moreover, Instead, this paper seeks to pull together
ample country studies suggest that dif- a diverse and active literature into a co-
ferences in financial development have, herent view of the financial system in
in some countries over extensive periods, economic growth.
critically influenced economic develop-
ment. Yet, these results do not imply 11. The Functions o f t h e Financial
that finance is everywhere and always ex- System
ogenous to economic growth. Economic
A. Functional Approach: Introduction
activity and technological innovation un-
doubtedly affect the structure and qual- The costs of acquiring information and
ity of financial systems. Innovations in making transactions create incentives
telecommunications and computing have for the emergence of financial markets
undeniably affected the financial ser- and institutions. Put differently, in a
vices industry. Moreover, "third factors," Kenneth Arrow (1964)-Gerard Debreu
such as a country's legal system and po- (1959) state-contingent claim framework
litical institutions certainly drive both fi- with no information or transaction costs,
nancial and economic development at there is no need for a financial system
critical junctures during the growth pro- that expends resources researching proj-
cess. Nevertheless, the weight of evi- ects, scrutinizing managers, or designing
dence suggests that financial systems are arrangements to ease risk management
a fundamental feature of the process of and facilitate transactions. Thus, any the-
economic development and that a satis- ory of the role of the financial system in
factory understanding of the factors un- economic growth (implicitly or explic-
derlying economic growth requires a itly) adds specific frictions to the Arrow-
greater understanding of the evolution Debreu model. Financial markets and
and structure of financial systems. institutions may arise to ameliorate the
As in any critique, I omit or treat cur- problems created by information and
sorily important issues. Here I highlight transactions frictions. Different types
First, I do not discuss the relation- and combinations of information and
ship between international finance and transaction costs motivate distinct finan-
growth. This paper narrows its concep- cial contracts, markets, and institutions.
tual focus by studying the financial ser-
vices available to an economy regardless " The financial policy literature is immense. See,
for example, Philip Brock (1992), Alberto Giovan-
4 Also, the theoretical review focuses on purely nini and Martha D e Melo (1993), Caprio, Isak Ati-
real economies and essentially ignores work on fi- yas, and James Hanson (1994), and Maxwell Fry
nance and growth in monetary economies. (1995).
In arising to ameliorate transaction
and information costs, financial systems
serve one primary function: they facili-
tate the allocation of resources, across
space and time, in an uncertain environ-
ment (Merton and Bodie 1995, p. 12).
To organize the vast literature on fi-
nance and economic activity, I break this
primary function into five basic func-
tions.
Specifically, financial systems
- facilitate the trading, hedging, diver-
sifying, and pooling of risk,
- allocate resources,
- monitor managers and exert corpo-
rate control,
- mobililize savings, and
- facilitate the exchange of goods and
services.
This section explains how particular
market frictions motivate the emergence
of financial markets and intermediaries
that provide these five functions, and ex-
plains how they affect economic growth.
I examine two channels through which
each financial function may affect eco-
.
Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth

&
.
I
- information costs
- transaction costs

Financial markets

and intermediaries

Financial functzons
- mobilize savings
- allocate resources
- exert corporate control
- facilitate risk management
- ease trading of goods,

-
senices, contracts

Channels to growth
- capital acculnulation
technological innovation

Growth

Figure 1. A Theoretical Approach to Finance


and Growth
691

nomic growth: capital accumulation and Aghion and Peter Howitt 1992). In these
technological innovation. On capital ac- models, the functions performed by the
cumulation, one class of growth models financial system affect steady-state
uses either capital externalities or capital growth by altering the rate of technologi-
goods produced using constant returns cal innovation. Thus, as sketched in Fig-
to scale but without the use of nonrepro- ure 1, the remainder of this section dis-
ducible factors to generate steady-state cusses how specific market frictions
per capita growth (Paul Romer 1986; motivate the emergence of financial con-
Lucas 1988; Sergio Rebelo 1991). In these tracts, markets, and intermediaries and
models, the functions performed by the how these financial arrangements pro-
financial system affect steady-state growth vide five financial functions that affect
by influencing the rate of capital forma- saving and allocations decisions in ways
tion. The financial system affects capital that influence economic growth.
accumulation either by altering the sav-
B. Facilitating Risk Amelioration
ings rate or by reallocating savings among
different capital producing technologies. In the presence of specific information
On technological innovation, a second and transaction costs, financial markets
class of growth models focuses on the in- and institutions may arise to ease the
vention of new production processes and trading, hedging, and pooling of risk.
goods (Romer 1990; Gene Grossman and This subsection considers two types of
Elhanan Helpman 1991; and Philippe risk: liquidity and idiosyncratic r i s k .
692 Journal of Economic Literatrare, Vol. XXXV (Tune 1997)

Liquidity is the ease and speed with market liquidity. With liquid capital mar-
which agents can convert assets into pur- kets, savers can hold assets-like equity,
chasing power at agreed prices. Thus, bonds, or demand deposits-that they
real estate is typically less liquid than can sell quickly and easily if they seek
equities, and equities in the United access to their savings. Simultaneously,
States are typically more liquid than capital markets transform these liquid fi-
those traded on the Nigerian Stock Ex- nancial instruments into long-term capi-
change. Liquidity risk arises due to the tal investments in illiquid production
uncertainties associated with converting processes. Because the industrial revolu-
assets into a medium of exchange. Infor- tion required large commitments of capi-
mational asymmetries and transaction tal for long periods, the industrial revo-
costs may inhibit liquidity and intensify lution may not have occurred without
liquidity risk. These frictions create in- this liquidity transformation. "The indus-
centives for the emergence of financial trial revolution therefore had to wait for
markets and institutions that augment li- the financial revolution" (Valerie Ben-
quidity. Liquid capital markets, there- civenga, Bruce Smith, and Ross Starr
fore, are markets where it is relatively 1966, p. 243).6
inexpensive to trade financial instru- Economists have recently modeled the
ments and where there is little uncer- emergence of financial markets in re-
tainty about the timing and settlement of sponse to liquidity risk and examined
those trades. how these financial markets affect eco-
Before delving into formal models of nomic growth. For example, in Douglas
liquidity and economic activity, some in- Diamond and Philip Dybvig's (1983)
tuition and history may help motivate seminal model of liquidity, a fraction of
the discussion. The link between liquid- savers receive shocks after choosing be-
ity and economic development arises be- tween two investments: an illiquid, high-
cause some high-return projects require return project and a liquid, low-return
a long-run commitment of capital, but project. Those receiving shocks want ac-
savers do not like to relinquish control of cess to their savings before the illiquid
their savings for long periods. Thus, if project produces. This risk creates in-
the financial system does not augment centives for investing in the liquid, low-
the liquidity of long-term investments, return projects. The model assumes that
less investment is likely to occur in the it is prohibitively costly to verify whether
high-return projects. Indeed, Sir John another individual has received a shock
Hicks (1969, pp. 143-45) argues that the or not. This information cost assumption
capital market improvements that miti- rules out state-contingent insurance con-
gated liquidity risk were primary causes tracts and creates an incentive for finan-
of the industrial revolution in England. cial markets-markets where individuals
According to Hicks, the products manu- issue and trade securities-to emerge. In
factured during the first decades of the Levine (1991), savers receiving shocks
industrial revolution had been invented
much earlier. Thus, technological inno-
vation did not, spark sustained growth. 6The financial revolution included the emer-
gence of joint-stock com anies with nonredeem-
Many of these existing inventions, how- able capital The DutcR East India Company
ever, required large injections and long- made capital ermanent in 1609, and Cromwell
run commitments of capital. The critical made the Eng8sh East India Company capital per-
manent in 1650. These financial innovations
new ingredient that ignited growth in formed the basis of liquid equity markets (Larry
eighteenth century England was capital Neal 1990).
Levine: Financial Development a n d Economic Growth 693

can sell their equity claims on the profits mediaries-coalitions of agents that com-
of the illiquid production technology to bine to provide financial services-may
others. Market participants do not verify also enhance liquidity and reduce liquid-
whether other agents received shocks or ity risk. As discussed above, Diamond
not; participants simply trade in imper- and Dybvig's (1983) model assumes it is
sonal stock exchanges. Thus, with liquid prohibitively costly to observe shocks to
stock markets, equity holders can readily individuals, so it is impossible to write
sell their shares, while firms have perma- incentive compatible state-contingent in-
nent access to the capital invested by the surance contracts. Under these condi-
initial shareholders. By facilitating trade, tions, banks can offer liquid deposits to
stock markets reduce liquidity risk.7 As savers and undertake a mixture of liquid,
stock market transaction costs fall, more low-return investments to satisfy de-
investment occurs in the illiquid, high- mands on deposits and illiquid, high-re-
return project. If illiquid projects enjoy turn investments. By providing demand
sufficiently large externalities, then deposits and choosing an appropriate mix-
greater stock market liquidity induces ture of liquid and illiquid investments,
faster steady-state growth. banks provide complete insurance to sav-
Thus far, information costs-the costs ers against liquidity risk while simulta-
of verifying whether savers have re- neously facilitating long-run investments
ceived a shock-have motivated the ex- in high-return projects. Banks replicate
istence of stock markets. Trading costs the equilibrium allocation of capital that
can also highlight the role of liquidity. exists with observable shocks. By elimi-
For example, different production tech- nating liquidity risk, banks can increase
nologies may have a wide array of gesta- investment in the high-return, illiquid
tion periods for converting current out- asset and accelerate growth (Bencivenga
put into future capital, where longer-run and B. Smith 1991). There is a problem,
technologies enjoy greater returns. In- however, with this description of the role
vestors, however, may be reluctant to re- of banks as reducing liquidity risk. The
linquish control of their savings for very banking equilibrium is not incentive
long periods. Thus, long-gestation pro- compatible if agents can trade in liquid
duction technologies require that owner- equity markets; if equity markets exist,
ship be transferred throughout the life all agents will use equities; none will use
of the production process in secondary banks (Charles Jacklin 1987). Thus, in
securities markets (Bencivenga, B. Smith, this context, banks will only emerge to
and Starr 1995). If exchanging owner- provide liquidity if there are sufficiently
ship claims is costly, then longer-run large impediments to trading in securi-
production technologies will be less at- ties markets (Gary Gorton and George
tractive. Thus, liquidity-as measured by Pennacchi 1990).8
secondary market trading costs-affects
production decisions. Greater liquidity 8Goldsmith (1969, p . 396) notes that "Claims
against financial institutions are generally easier to
will induce a shift to longer-gestation, liquidate (i.e., to turn into cash without or with
higher- return technologies. only insignificant delay, formality, and cost) than
Besides stock markets, financial inter- are primary debt securities. They have the addi-

'Frictionless stock markets, however, do not a


tional reat advantage of being completely divis-
ible, w ereas primary securities are usually issued
in fixed amounts and often in amounts that make
eliminate liquidity risk. That is, stock markets do them very inconvenient for purchase and sale
not replicate the equilibrium that exists when in- when lenders have small resources and when nu-
surance contracts can be written contingent on ob- merous individual purchase and sale transactions
serving whether an agent receives a shock or not. are involved."
694 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (June 1997)

Theory, however, suggests that en- turn projects. Thus, financial markets
hanced liquidity has an ambiguous affect that ease risk diversification tend to in-
on saving rates and economic growth.9 In duce a portfolio shift toward projects
most models, greater liquidity (a) with higher expected returns (Gilles
increases investment returns and (b) Saint-Paul 1992; Michael Devereux and
lowers uncertainty. Higher returns am- Gregor Smith 1994; and Maurice
biguously affect saving rates due to well- Obstfeld 1994). Greater risk sharing and
known income and substitution effects. more efficient capital allocation, how-
Further, lower uncertainty ambiguously ever, have theoretically ambiguous ef-
affects savings rates (David Levhari and fects on saving rates as noted above. The
T. N. Srinivasan 1969). Thus, saving savings rate could fall enough so that,
rates may rise or fall as liquidity rises. when coupled with an externality-based
Indeed, in a model with physical capital or linear growth model, overall economic
externalities, saving rates could fall growth falls. With externalities, growth
enough, so that growth actually deceler- could fall sufficiently so that overall wel-
ates with greater liquidity (Tullio Jap- fare falls with greater risk diversifica-
pelli and Marco Pagano 1994).10 tion.
Besides reducing liquidity risk, finan- Besides the link between risk diversifi-
cial systems may also mitigate the risks cation and capital accumulation, risk di-
associated with individual projects, versification can also affect technological
firms, industries, regions, countries, etc. change. Agents are continuously trying
Banks, mutual funds, and securities mar- to make technological advances to gain a
kets all provide vehicles for trading, profitable market niche. Besides yielding
pooling, and diversifying risk.11 The fi- profits to the innovator, successful inno-
nancial system's ability to provide risk di- vation accelerates technological change.
versification services can affect long-run Engaging in innovation is risky, however.
economic growth by altering resource al- The ability to hold a diversified portfolio
location and the saving rates. The basic of innovative projects reduces risk and
intuition is straightforward. While savers promotes investment in growth-enhanc-
generally do not like risk, high-return ing innovative activities (with sufficiently
projects tend to be riskier than low-re- risk averse agents). Thus, financial sys-
tems that ease risk diversification can ac-
9 T h e analyses described thus far focus on the celerate technological change and eco-
links between liquidity and ca ital accumulation. nomic growth (Robert King and Levine
Yet, liquidity may also affect 8 e rate of techno-
logical change if long-run commitments of re- 1993~).
sources to research and development promote
technolo ical innovation. C. Acquiring Information About
l o sim8arly, although greater liquidity unambi- Investments and Allocating
guously raises the real return on savings, more li- Resources
quidim ~ ay induce a reallocation of investment
out o initiating new capital investments and into I t is difficult and costly to evaluate
purchasing claims on ongoing projects. This ma
lower the rate of real investment enough to dece[ firms, managers, and market conditions
erate growth (Bencivenga, B. smith: and Starr as discussed by Vincent Carosso (1970).
1995). Individual savers may not have the time,
1lAlthough the recent uses of options and fu-
tures contracts to hedge risk have been well publi- capacity, or means to collect and process
cized, the development of these financial con- information on a wide array of enter-
tracts is by no means recent. Josef Penso de la prises, managers, and economic condi-
Vega published a treatise on options contracts, fu-
tures contracts, and securities market speculation, tions. Savers will be reluctant to invest in
Confusion de Confusiones, in 1688! activities about which there is little reli-
Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 695

able information. Consequently, high in- ventures than most countries in the mid-
formation costs may keep capital from 1800s, which helped it enjoy compara-
flowing to its highest value use. tively greater economic success.12
Information acquisition costs create Besides identifying the best produc-
incentives for financial intermediaries to tion technologies, financial intermediar-
emerge (Diamond 1984; and John Boyd ies may also boost the rate of technologi-
and Edward Prescott 1986). Assume, for cal innovation by identifying those
example, that there is a fixed cost to entrepreneurs with the best chances of
acquiring information about a product- successfully initiating new goods and
ion technology. Without intermediaries, production processes (King and Levine
each investor must pay the fixed cost. In 1 9 9 3 ~ )As
. eloquently stated by Schum-
response to this information cost struc- peter (1912, p. 74),
ture, however, groups of individuals may The banker, therefore, is not so much pri-
form (or join or use) financial intermedi- marily a middleman, . . . He authorises peo-
aries to economize on the costs of ac- ple, in the name of society as it were, . . . [to
quiring and processing information innovate].
about investments. Instead of each indi- Stock markets may also influence the
vidual acquiring evaluation skills and acquisition and dissemination of infor-
then conducting evaluations, an interme- mation about firms. As stock markets be-
diary can do it for all its members. come larger (Sanford Grossman and
Economizing on information acquisition Joseph Stiglitz 1980) and more liquid
costs facilitates the acquisition of infor- (Albert Kyle 1984; and Bengt Holm-
mation about investment opportunities strom and Jean Tirole 1993), market par-
and thereby improves resource alloca- ticipants may have greater incentives to
tion. acquire information about firms. Intui-
The ability to acquire and process in- tively, with larger more liquid markets, it
formation may have important growth is easier for an agent who has acquired
implications. Because many firms and information to disguise this private
entrepreneurs will solicit capital, finan- information and make money. Thus,
cial intermediaries, and markets that are large, liquid stock markets can stimulate
better at selecting the most promis- the acquisition of information. More-
ing firms and managers will induce a over, this improved information about
more efficient allocation of capital and firms should improve resource alloca-
faster growth (Jeremy Greenwood and tion substantially with corresponding
Boyan Jovanovic 1990). Bagehot (1873, implications for economic growth (Mer-
p. 53) expressed this view over 120 years ton 1987). However, existing theories
ago. have not yet assembled the links of the
[England's financial] organization is so useful chain from the functioning of stock mar-
because it is so easily adjusted. Political kets, to information acquisition, and fi-
economists say that capital sets towards the nally to aggregate long-run economic
most profitable trades, and that it rapidly growth.
leaves the less profitable non-paying trades.
But in ordinary countries this is a slow pro-
12 Indeed, England's advanced financial system
cess, . . . In England, however, . . . capital also did a good job at identifying profitable ven-
runs as surely and instantly where it is most tures in other countries, such as Canada, the
wanted, and where there is most to be made United States, and Australia during the 19th cen-
of it, as water runs to find its level. tury. England was able to "export" financial ser-
vices (as well as financial ca ital) to many econo-
England's financial system did a better mies with underdevelopeg financial systems
job at identifying and funding profitable (Lance Davis and Robert Huttenback 1986).
696 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (June 1997)

Debate still exists over the importance investments (Stiglitz and Andrew Weiss
of large, liquid, efficient stock markets in 1981, 1983). Because this vast literature
enhancing the creation and distribution has been carefully reviewed (Gertler
information about firms. Stock markets 1988; and Andrei Shleifer and Robert
aggregate and disseminate information Vishny, forthcoming), this subsection (1)
through published prices. Even agents notes a few ways in which financial con-
that do not undertake the costly pro- tracts, markets, and institutions improve
cesses of evaluating firms, managers, and monitoring and corporate control, and
market conditions can observe stock (2) reviews how these financial arrange-
prices that reflect the information ob- ments for monitoring influence capital
tained by others. This public goods as- accumulation, resource allocation, and
pect of acquiring information can cause long-run growth.
society to devote too few resources to in- Consider, for example, the simple as-
formation acquisition. The public goods sumption that it is costly for outsider
feature of the information thus disclosed investors in a project to verify project
may be sufficiently large, that informa- returns. This creates important frictions
tion gains from large, liquid stock mar- that can motivate financial development.
kets are small. Stiglitz (1985) argues that, Insiders have incentives to misrepresent
because stock markets quickly reveal in- project returns to outsiders. Given verifi-
formation through posted prices, there cation costs, however, it is socially ineffi-
will be few incentives for spending private cient for outsiders to monitor in all
resources to acquire information that is circumstances. With "costly state verifi-
almost immediately publicly available. cation" (and other assumptions including
risk-neutral borrowers and verification
D. Monitoring Managers and Exerting
costs that are independent of project
Corporate Control
quality), the optimal contract between
Besides reducing the costs of acquir- outsiders and insiders is a debt contract
ing information ex ante, financial con- (Robert Townsend 1979; and Douglas
tracts, markets, and intermediaries may Gale and Martin Hellwig 1985). Specifi-
arise to mitigate the information acquisi- cally, there is an equilibrium interest
tion and enforcement costs of monitor- rate, r, such that when the project return
ing firm managers and exerting corpo- is sufficiently high, insiders pay r to out-
rate control ex post, i.e., after financing siders and outsiders do not monitor.
the activity. For example, firm owners When project returns are insufficient,
will create financial arrangements that the borrower defaults and the lenders
compel firm managers to manage the pay the monitoring costs to verify the
firm in the best interests of the owners. project's return. These verification costs
Also, "outside" creditors-banks, equity, impede investment decisions and reduce
and bond holders-that do not manage economic efficiency. Verification costs
firms on a day-to-day basis will create fi- imply that outsiders constrain firms from
nancial arrangements to compel inside borrowing to expand investment because
owners and managers to run firms in ac- higher leverage implies greater risk of
cordance with the interests of outside default and higher verification expendi-
creditors. The absence of financial ar- tures by lenders. Thus, collateral and fi-
rangements that enhance corporate con- nancial contracts that lower monitoring
trol may impede the mobilization of sav- and enforcement costs reduce impedi-
ings from disparate agents and thereby ments to efficient investment (Stephen
keep capital from flowing to profitable Williamson 1987b; Ben Bernanke and
Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 697

Gertler 1989, 1990; Ernst-Ludwig von more, as financial intermediaries and


Thadden 1995).13 firms develop long-run relationships, this
Besides particular types of financial can further lower information acquisi-
contracts, financial intermediaries can tion costs. The reduction in information
reduce information costs even further. If asymmetries can in turn ease external
borrowers must obtain funds from many funding constraints and facilitate better
outsiders, financial intermediaries can resource allocation (Sharpe 1990).15 In
economize on monitoring costs. The fi- terms of long-run growth, financial ar-
nancial intermediary mobilizes the sav- rangements that improve corporate con-
ings of many individuals and lends these trol tend to promote faster capital accu-
resources to project owners. This "dele- mulation and growth by improving the
gated monitor" arrangement economizes allocation of capital (Bencivenga and B.
on aggregate monitoring costs because a Smith 1993).
borrower is monitored only by the inter- Besides debt contracts and banks,
mediary, not all individual savers (Dia- stock markets may also promote corpo-
mond 1984). Besides reducing duplicate rate control (Michael Jensen and Wil-
monitoring, a financial system that facili- liam Meckling 1976). For example, pub-
tates corporate control "also makes pos- lic trading of shares in stock markets that
sible the efficient separation of owner- efficiently reflect information about
ship from management of the firm. This firms allows owners to link managerial
in turn makes feasible efficient speciali- compensation to stock prices. Linking
zation in production according to the stock performance to manager compen-
principle of comparative advantage" sation helps align the interests of manag-
(Merton and Bodie 1995, p. 14). The ers with those of owners (Diamond and
delegated monitor arrangement, how- Robert Verrecchia 1982; and Jensen and
ever, creates a potential problem: who Kevin Murphy 1990). Similarly, if take-
will monitor the monitor (Stefan Krasa overs are easier in well-developed stock
and Anne Villamil 1992)? Savers, how- markets and if managers of under-per-
ever, do not have to monitor the inter- forming firms are fired following a take-
mediary if the intermediary holds a di- over, then better stock markets can pro-
versified portfolio (and agents can easily mote better corporate control by easing
verify that the intermediary's portfolio is takeovers of poorly managed firms. The
well diversified). With a well-diversified threat of a takeover will help align mana-
portfolio, the intermediary can always gerial incentives with those of the own-
meet its promise to pay the deposit in-
terest rate to depositors, so that deposi-
tors never have to monitor the bank. (1986) shows how intermediaries arise endogen-
ously. Furthermore, I have only discussed models
Thus, well-diversified financial inter- in which state verification roceeds nonstochasti-
mediaries can foster efficient investment cally: if borrowers default, i n d e r s verify Stochas-
by lowering monitoring costs.l4 Further- tic monitoring, however, may further reduce veri-
fication costs (Bernanke and Gertler 1989; and
Boyd and B. Smith 1994).
13 Costly state verification can produce credit 1s The long-run relationships between a banker
rationing. Because higher interest rates are linked and client ma impose a cost on the client. Be-
with a higher probability of default and monitor- cause the h a d is well informed ahout the firm,
ing costs, intermediaries may keep rates low and the bank may have bar aining power over the
ration credit using non-price mechanisms (Wil- firm's profits. if the ban% breaks its ties to the
liamson 1986, 1987a). firm, other investors will be reluctant to invest in
14Diamond (1984) assumes that intermediaries the firm. Firms may therefore diversify out of
exist and shows that the intermediary arrangement bank financing to reduce their vulnerability
economizes on monitoring costs. Williamson (Raghurman Rajan 1992).
698 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (June1997)

ers (David Scharfstein 1988; and Jeremy the hopes of taking them over. Third,
Stein 1988). I am not aware of models current managers often can take strate-
that directly link the role of stock mar- gic actions to deter takeovers and main-
kets in improving corporate governance tain their positions. This argues against an
with long-run economic growth. important role for liquid stock markets in
There are disagreements, however, promoting sound corporate governance.
about the importance of stock markets in Moreover, liquid equity markets that
corporate control. Inside investors prob- facilitate takeovers may hurt resource al-
ably have better information about the location (Shleifer and Lawrence Sum-
corporation than outsiders. Thus, if well- mers 1988; and Randall Morck, Shleifer,
informed owners are willing to sell their and Vishny 1990). A takeover typically
company, less well informed outsiders involves a change in management. Exist-
may demand a premium to purchase the ing implicit contracts between former
firm due to the information asymmetry managers and workers, suppliers, and
(Stewart Myers and Nicholas Majluf other stakeholders in the firms do not
1984). Thus, asymmetric information bind new owners and managers to the
may reduce the efficacy of corporate same extent that they bound the original
takeovers as a mechanism for exerting managers. Thus, a takeover allows new
corporate control. Stiglitz (1985) makes owners and managers to break implicit
three additional arguments about take- agreements and transfer wealth from
overs. First, if an acquiring firm expends firm stakeholders to themselves. While
lots of resources obtaining information, new owners may profit, there may be a
the results of this research will be ob- deterioration in the efficiency of re-
served by other market participants source allocation. Overall welfare may
when the acquiring firm bids for shares. fall. To the extent that well-functioning
This will induce others to bid for shares, equity markets help takeovers, this may
so that the price rises. The firm that ex- allow hostile takeovers that lead to a fall
pended resources obtaining information in the efficiency of resource allocation.
must, therefore, pay a higher price than Furthermore, liquid stock markets may
it would have to pay if "free-riding" reduce incentives for owners to monitor
firms could not observe its bid. Thus, the managers (Amar Bhide 1993). By reduc-
rapid public dissemination of costly in- ing exit costs, stock market liquidity en-
formation will reduce incentives for ob- courages more diffuse ownership with
taining information and making effective fewer incentives and greater impedi-
takeover bids. Second, there is a public ments to actively overseeing managers
good nature to takeovers that may de- (Shleifer and Vishny 1986). Thus, the
crease the incentives for takeovers. If theoretical signs on the links in the chain
the takeover succeeds, and the share from improvements in stock markets to
price rises, then those original equity better corporate control to faster eco-
holders who did not sell make a big nomic growth are still ambiguous.16
profit without expending resources. This
E . Mobilizing Savings
creates an incentive for existing share-
holders to not sell if they think the value Mobilization-pooling-involves the
of the firm will rise following the take- agglomeration of capital from disparate
over. Thus, value-increasing takeovers
may fail because the acquiring firm will 16Some research also suggests that excessive
stock trading can induce "noise" into the market
have to pay a high price, which will re- and hinder efficient resource allocation (Bradford
duce incentives for researching firms in De Long e t al. 1989).
Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 699

savers for investment. Without access to ings to the intermediary (De Long 1991;
multiple investors, many production pro- and Naomi Lamoreaux 1994).
cesses would be constrained to economi- In light of the transaction and infor-
cally inefficient scales (Erik Sirri and mation costs associated with mobilizing
Peter Tufano 1995). Furthermore, mobi- savings from many agents, numerous fi-
lization involves the creation of small nancial arrangements may arise to miti-
denomination instruments. These instru- gate these frictions and facilitate pool-
ments provide opportunities for house- ing.17 Specifically, mobilization may
holds to hold diversified portfolios, in- involve multiple bilateral contracts be-
vest in efficient scale firms, and to tween productive units raising capital
increase asset liquidity. Without pooling, and agents with surplus resources. The
household's would have to buy and sell joint stock company in which many indi-
entire firms. By enhancing risk diversifi- viduals invest in a new legal entity, the
cation, liquidity, and the size of feasible firm, represents a prime example of mul-
firms, therefore, mobilization improves re- tiple bilateral mobilization. To econo-
source allocation (Sirri and Tufano 1995). mize on the transaction and information
Mobilizing the savings of many dispa- costs associated with multiple bilateral
rate savers is costly, however. It involves contracts, pooling may also occur
(a) overcoming the transaction costs as- through intermediaries as discussed
sociated with collecting savings from dif- above, where thousands of investors en-
ferent individuals and (b) overcoming trust their wealth to intermediaries that
the informational asymmetries associated invest in hundreds of firms (Sirri and
with making savers feel comfortable in Tufano 1995, p. 83).
relinquishing control of their savings. In- Financial systems that are more effec-
deed, much of Carosso's (1970) history tive at pooling the savings of individuals
of Investment Banking in America is a can profoundly affect economic develop-
description of the diverse and elaborate ment. Besides the direct effect of better
means employed by investment banks to savings mobilization on capital accumu-
raise capital. As early as the mid-1880s, lation, better savings mobilization can
some investment banks used their Euro- improve resource allocation and boost
pean connections to raise capital abroad technological innovation (Bagehot 1873,
for investment in the United States. pp. 3-4):
Other investment banks established close We have entirely lost the idea that any under-
connections with major banks and indus- taking likely to pay, and seen to be likely, can
trialists in the United States to mobilize perish for want of money; yet no idea was
capital. And, still others used newspaper more familiar to our ancestors, or is more
common in most countries. A citizen of Long
advertisements, pamphlets, and a vast in Queen Elizabeth's time . . . would have
sales force that traveled through every thought that it was no use inventing railways
state and territory selling securities to (if he could have understood what a railway
individual households. Thus, mobilizing meant), for you would have not been able to
resources involved a range of transaction collect the capital with which to make them.
At this moment, in colonies and all rude
costs. Moreover, "mobilizers" had to countries, there is no large sum of transfer-
convince savers of the soundness of the able money; there is not fund from which you
investments. Toward this end, interme- can borrow, and out of which you can make
diaries are generally concerned about es- immense works.
tablishing stellar reputations or govern-
ment backing, so that savers feel 17See Sections 1I.C and 1I.D for citations on
comfortabl; about entrusting their sav- the emergence of financial intermediaries.
700 Journal of Economic Literat~
ure, Vol. XXXV (June 1997)

Thus, by effectively mobilizing resources The critical issue for our purposes is
for projects, the financial system may that the financial system can promote
play a crucial role in permitting the specialization. Adam Smith argued that
adoption of better technologies and lower transaction costs would permit
thereby encouraging growth. This intu- greater specialization because specializa-
ition was clarified 100 years later by tion requires more transactions than an
McKinnon (1973, p. 13): autarkic environment. Smith phrased his
The farmer could provide his own savings to argument about the lowering of transac-
increase slightly the commercial fertilizer tion costs and technological innovation
that he is now using, and the return on this in terms of the advantages of money over
marginal new investment could be calculated. barter (pp. 26-27). Information costs,
The important point, however, is the virtual
impossibility of a poor farmer's financing
however, may also motivate the emer-
from his current savings the whole of the bal- gence of money. Because it is costly to
anced investment needed to adopt the new evaluate the attributes of goods, barter
technology. Access to external financial re- exchange is very costly. Thus, an easily
sources is likely to be necessary over the one recognizable medium of exchange may
or two years when the change takes place.
Without this access, the constraint of self-
arise to facilitate exchange (King and
finance sharply biases investment strategy to- Charles Plosser 1986; and Williamson
ward marginal variations within the tradi- and Randall Wright 1994).18
tional technology. The drop in transaction and informa-
tion costs is not necessarily a one-time
F. Facilitating Exchange fall when economies move to money,
Besides easing savings mobilization however. For example, in the 1800s, it "

and thereby expanding the of set pro- was primarily the development of insti-
duction technologies available to an tutions that facilitated the exchange of
economy, financial arrangements that technology in the market that enabled
lower transaction costs can promote spe- creative individuals to specialize in and
cialization, technological innovation, and become more productive at invention"
growth. The links between facilitating (Lamoreaux and Sokoloff 1996, p. 17).
transactions, specialization, innovation, Thus, transaction and information costs
and economic growth were core ele- may continue to fall through a variety of
ments of Adam Smith's (1776) Wealth of mechanisms, so that financial and insti-
Nations. Smith (1776, p. 7) argued that tutional development continually boost
division of labor-specialization-is specialization and innovation via the
the principal factor underlying produc- same channels illuminated over 200
tivity improvements. With greater spe- years ago by Adam Smith.19
cialization, workers are more likely to in- l*This focus on money as a medium of ex-
vent better machines or production change that lowers transaction and information
processes. costs by overcomin the "double coincidence of
wants problem" a n f by acting as an easily recog-
I shall only observe, therefore, that the in- nizable medium of exchange enjoys a long history
vention of all those machines by which labour in monetary theory, from Adam Smith (1776), to
is so much facilitated and abridged, seems to Stanley Jevons (1875), to Karl Brunner and Allan
have been originally owing to the division of Meltzer (1971), to more formal models as re-
labour. Men are much more likely to discover viewed by Joseph Ostroy and Starr (1990).
19 Financial systems can also promote the accu-
easier and readier methods of attaining any mulation of human capital by lowering the costs of
object, when the whole attention of their intertemporal trade, i.e., b facilitating borrowin
minds is directed towards that single object, for the accumulation of skihs (Thomas Cooley a n 3
than when it is dissipated among a great vari- B. Smith 1992; and Jose D e Gregorio 1996). If
ety of things. (Smith 1776, p. 3) human capital accumulation is not subject to di-
Leuine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 70 1

Modern theorists have attempted to il- poorly, and what are the implications for
luminate more precisely the ties be- economic activity of the emerging finan-
tween exchange, specialization, and in- cial arrangements?
novation (Greenwood and B. Smith
G. A Parable
1997). More specialization requires more
transactions. Because each transaction is Thus far, I have discussed each finan-
costly, financial arrangements that lower cial function in isolation. This, however,
transaction costs will facilitate greater may encourage an excessively narrow fo-
specialization. In this way, markets that cus on individual functions and impede
promote exchange encourage produc- the synthesis of these distinct functions
tivity gains. There may also be feedback into a coherent understanding of the
from these productivity gains to finan- financial system's role in economic de-
cial market development. If there are velopment. This is not a necessary impli-
fixed costs associated with establishing cation. In fact, by identifying the individ-
markets, then higher income per capita ual functions performed by the financial
implies that these fixed costs are less system, the functional approach can fos-
burdensome as a share of per capita in- ter a more complete understanding of fi-
come. Thus, economic development can nance and growth.
spur the development of financial mar- Earlier authors often provided illustra-
kets. tive stories of the ties between finance
This approach to linking financial mar- and development. For example Schum-
kets with specialization has not yet for- peter (1912, pp. 58-74) and McKinnon
mally completed Adam Smith's story of (1973, pp. 5-18) provide broad descrip-
innovation. That is, a better market-a tions-parables-of the roles of the fi-
market with lower transactions costs- nancial system in economic develop-
does not stimulate the invention of new ment. Just as Smith (1776) used the pin
and better production technologies in factory to illustrate the importance of
Greenwood and B. Smith's (1997) specialization, Schumpeter used the re-
model. Instead, lower transaction costs lationship between banker and industri-
expand the set of "on the shelf' produc- alist to illustrate the importance of the
tion processes that are economically at- financial system in choosing and adopt-
tractive. Also, the model defines better ing new technologies, and McKinnon
"market" as a system for supporting highlighted its importance in promoting
more specialized production processes. the use of better agricultural techniques.
This does not explain the emergence of However, even Schumpeter and McKin-
financial instruments or institutions that non did not amalgamate all of the finan-
lower transaction costs and thereby pro- cial functions into their stories of finance
duce an environment that naturally pro- and development. Consequently, this
motes specialized production technolo- subsection synthesizes the individual fi-
gies. This is important because we want nancial functions into a simple parable
to understand the two links of the chain: about how the financial system affects
what about the economic environment economic growth.
creates incentives for financial arrange- Consider Fred, who has just devel-
ments to arise and to function well or oped a design for a new truck that ex-
tracts rocks from a quarry better than ex-
isting trucks. His idea for manufacturing
minishing returns on a social level, financial ar-
rangements that ease human capital creation help
trucks requires an intricate assembly line
accelerate economic growth. with specialized labor and capital.
702 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (June 1997)

Highly specialized production processes mies of scope, and experience. Thus,


would be difficult without a medium of Fred may seek the help of a financial in-
exchange. He would find it prohibitively termediary to mobilize savings for his
costly to pay his workers and suppliers new truck plant.
using barter exchange. Financial instru- Two additional problems ("frictions")
ments and markets that facilitate trans- may keep savings from flowing to Fred's
actions will allow and promote special- project. To fund the truck plant, the fi-
ization and thereby permit him to nancial intermediaries-and savers in fi-
organize his truck assembly line. More- nancial intermediaries-require informa-
over, the increased specialization in- tion about the truck design, Fred's
duced by easier transactions may foster ability to implement the design, and
learning-by-doing and innovation by the whether there is a sufficient demand for
workers specializing on their individual better quarry trucks. This information is
tasks. difficult to obtain and analyze. Thus, the
Production requires capital. Even if financial system must be able to acquire
Fred had the savings, he would not wish reliable information about Fred's idea
to put all of his savings in one risky in- before funding the truck plant. Further-
vestment. Also, he wants ready access to more, if potential investors feel that
savings for unplanned events; he is re- Fred may steal the funds, or run the
luctant to tie up his savings in the truck plant poorly, or misrepresent profits,
project, which will not yield profits, if it they will not provide funding. To finance
does yield profits, for a long time. His Fred's idea, outside creditors must have
distaste for risk and desire for liquidity confidence that Fred will run the truck
create incentives for him to (a) diversify plant well. Thus, for Fred to receive
the family's investments and (b) not funding, the financial system must moni-
commit too much of his savings to an il- tor managers and exert corporate con-
liquid project, like producing a new trol.
truck. In fact, if Fred must invest dispro- While this parable does not contain all
portionately in his illiquid truck project, aspects of the discussion of financial
he may forgo his plan. Without a mecha- functions, it provides one cohesive story
nism for managing risk, the project may of how the five financial functions may
die. Thus, liquidity, risk pooling, and di- interact to promote economic develop-
versification will help him start his inno- ment.
vative project.
H . T he Theory of Finance and
Moreover, Fred will require outside
Economic Growth: Agenda
funding if he has insufficient savings to
initiate his truck project. There are In describing the conceptual links be-
problems, however, in mobilizing savings tween the functioning of the financial
for Fred's truck company. First, it is very system and economic growth, I high-
costly and time consuming to collect sav- lighted areas needing additional re-
ings from individual savers. Fred does search. Two more areas are worth em-
not have the time, connections, and in- phasizing. First, we do not have a
formation to collect savings from every- sufficiently rigorous understanding of
one in his town and neighboring commu- the emergence, development, and eco-
nities even though his idea is sound. nomic implications of different financial
Banks and investment banks, however, structures. Financial structure-the mix
can mobilize savings more cheaply than of financial contracts, markets, and insti-
Fred due to economies of scale, econo- tutions-varies across countries and
Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth

changes as countries develop (Boyd and 111. Evidence


B. Smith 1996). Yet, we do not have
adequate theories of why different finan- A. The Questions
cial structures emerge or why financial Are differences in financial develop-
structures change. Differences in legal ment and structure importantly associ-
tradition (Rafael LaPorta et al. 1996) and ated with differences in economic
differences in national resource endow- growth rates? To assess the nature of the
ments that produce different political finance-growth relationship, I first de-
and institutional structures (Stanley scribe research on the links between the
Engerman and Sokoloff 1996) might be functioning of the financial system and
incorporated into future models of finan- economic growth, capital accumulation,
cial development. Furthermore, econo- and technological change. Then, I evalu-
mists need to develop an analytical basis ate existing evidence on the ties between
for making comparisons of financial struc- financial structure-the mix of financial
tures; we need models that elucidate the markets and intermediaries-and the
conditions, if any, under which different functioning of the financial system. A
financial structures are better at mitigat- growing body of work demonstrates a
ing information and transaction costs. strong, positive link between financial
A second area needing additional development and economic growth, and
research involves the influence of the there is even evidence that the level of
level and growth rate of the economy financial development is a good predic-
on the financial system. Some models tor of future economic development.
assume that there is a fixed cost to join- Evidence on the relationship between fi-
ing financial intermediaries. Economic nancial structure and the functioning of
growth then reduces the importance of the financial system, however, is more
this fixed cost and more people join. inconclusive.
Thus, economic growth provides the
means for the formation of growth-pro- B. The Level of Financial Development
moting financial intermediaries, while and Growth: Cross-Country Studies
the foymation of financial intermediaries
accelerates growth by enhancing the al- Consider first the relationship be-
location of capital. In this way, financial tween economic growth and aggregate
and economic development are jointly measures of how well the financial sys-
determined (Greenwood and Jovanovic tem functions. The seminal work in this
1990). Economic development may af- area is by Goldsmith (1969). He uses the
fect the financial system in other ways value of financial intermediary assets di-
that have not yet been formally modeled. vided by GNP to gauge financial devel-
For example, the costs and skills re- opment under the assumption that the
quired to evaluate production technolo- size of the financial system is positively
gies and monitor managers may be very correlated with the provision and quality
different in a service-oriented economy of financial services. Using data on 35
from that of a manufacturing-based countries from 1860 to 1963 (when avail-
economy or an aericultural-based econ- able) Goldsmith (1969, p. 48) finds:
omy. ~ k i l d i no~ h ~ u Patrick
~ h (1966), (1) a rough parallelism can be observed be-
creenwood and J~~~~~~~~ (1990), and tween economic and financial development if
periods of several decades are considered;
Greenwood and Smith (1997), future re-
search may improve our understanding of (2) there are even indications in the few
the impact of growth on financial systems. countries for which the data are available that
704 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (June1997)
periods of more rapid economic growth have functioning of the financial system than
been accompanied, though not without ex- Goldsmith's size measure. Table 1 sum-
ception, by an above-average rate of financial
development.
marizes the values of these measures
relative to real per capita GDP (RGDP)
Goldsmith's work, however, has sev- in 1985. The first measure, DEPTH,
eral weaknesses: (a) the investigation in- measures the size of financial intermedi-
volves limited observations on only 35 aries and equals liquid liabilities of the
countries; (b) it does not systematically financial system (currency plus demand
control for other factors influencing eco- and interest-bearing liabilities of banks
nomic growth (Levine and David Renelt and nonbank financial intermediaries)
1992); (c) it does not examine whether divided by GDP. As shown, citizens of
financial development is associated with the richest countries-the top 25 per-
productivity growth and capital accumu- cent on the basis of income per capita-
lation; (d) the size of financial intermedi- held about two-thirds of a year's income
aries may not accurately measure the in liquid assets in formal financial inter-
functioning of the financial system; and mediaries, while citizens of the poorest
(e) the close association between the size countries-the bottom 25 percent-held
of the financial system and economic only a quarter of a year's income in liq-
growth does not identify the direction of uid assets. There is a strong correlation
causality.20 between real per capita GDP and
Recently, researchers have taken steps DEPTH. The second measure of finan-
to address some of these weaknesses. cial development, BANK, measures the
For example, King and Levine (1993a, degree to which the central bank versus
1993b, 1993c) study 80 countries over commercial banks are allocating credit.
the period 1960-1989, systematically BANK equals the ratio of bank credit di-
control for other factors affecting long- vided by bank credit plus central bank
run growth, examine the capital accumu- domestic assets. The intuition underly-
lation and productivity growth channels, ing this measure is that banks are more
construct additional measures of the likely to provide the five financial func-
level of financial development, and ana- tions than central banks. There are two
lyze whether the level of financial de- notable weaknesses with this measure,
velopment predicts long-run economic however. Banks are not the only finan-
growth, capital accumulation, and pro- cial intermediaries providing valuable fi-
ductivity growth. (Also, see Alan Gelb nancial functions and banks may simply
1989; Gertler and Andrew Rose 1994; lend to the government or public enter-
Nouriel Roubini and Xavier Sala-i- prises. BANK is greater than 90 percent
Martin 1992; Easterly 1993; and the in the richest quartile of countries. In
overview by Pagano 1993.) They use four contrast, commercial banks and central
measures of "the level of financial devel- banks allocate about the same amount of
opment" to more precisely measure the credit in the poorest quartile of coun-
tries. The third and fourth measures par-
20Goldsmith (1969) recognized these weak- tially address concerns about the alloca-
nesses, e.g., "there is no possibility, however, of tion of credit. The third measures,
establishing with confidence the direction of the
causal mechanisms, i.e., of deciding whether fi- PRIVATE, equals the ratio of credit allo-
nancial factors were responsible for the accelera- cated to private enterprises to total do-
tion of economic development or whether finan- mestic credit (excluding credit to banks).
cial development reflected economic growth
whose mainsprings must be sought elsewhere" (p. The fourth measure, PRIVY, equals
48). credit to private enterprises divided by
Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 705

TABLE 1
FINANCIAL
DEVELOPMENT
AND REALPERCAPITA
GDP IN 1985

Correlation
with Real per
Capita GDP in
Indictors Very rich Rich Poor Very poor 1985 (P-value)
DEPTH 0.67 0.51 0.39 0.26 0.51 (0.OOOl)
BANK 0.91 0.73 0.57 0.52 0.58 (0.0001)
PRIVATE 0.71 0.58 0.47 0.37 0.51 (0,0001)
PRIVY 0.53 0.31 0.20 0.13 0.70 (0.0001)
RGDP85 13053 2376 754 241

Observations 29 29 29 29

Source: King and Levine (1993a)


Very rich: Real GDP per Capita > 4998
Rich: Real GDP per Capita > 1161 and < 4998
Poor: Real GDP per Capita > 391 and < 1161
Very poor: Real GDP per Capita < 391

DEPTH = Liquid liabilities to GDP


BANK = Deposit money bank domestic credit divided by deposit money bank + central bank domestic credit
PRIVATE = Claims on the non-financial private sector to domestic credit
PRIW = Gross claims on private sector to GDP
RGDP85 = Real per capita GDP in 1985 (in constant 1987 dollars)

GDP. The assumption underlying these as follows: (1) the average rate of real
measures is that financial systems that per capita GDP growth, (2) the average
allocate more credit to private firms are rate of growth in the capital stock per
more engaged in researching firms, ex- person, and (3) total productivity
erting corporate control, providing risk growth, which is a "Solow residual" de-
management services, mobilizing sav- fined as real per capita GDP growth mi-
ings, and facilitating transactions than fi- nus (0.3) times the growth rate of the
nancial systems that simply funnel credit capital stock per person. In other words,
to the government or state owned enter- if F ( i ) represents the value of the ith in-
prises. As depicted in Table 1, there is a dicator of financial development
positive, statistically significant correla- (DEPTH, BANK, P R I W , PRIVATE) av-
tion between real per capita GDP and eraged over the period 1960-1989, GO')
the extent to which loans are directed to represents the value of the jth growth in-
the private sector. dicator (per capita GDP growth, per cap-
King and Levine (199310, 1993c) then ita capital stock growth, or productivity
assess the strength of the empirical rela- growth) averaged over the period 1960-
tionship between each of these four indi- 1989, and X represents a matrix of condi-
cators of the level of financial develop- tioning information to control for other
ment averaged over the 1960-1989 factors associated with economic growth
period, F , and three growth indicators (e.g., income per capita, education, po-
also averaged over the 1960-1989 pe- litical stability, indicators of exchange
riod, G. The three growth indicators are rate, trade, fiscal, and monetary policy),
706 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (June1997)

TABLE 2

AND CONTEMPORANEOUS
GROWTH FINANCIAL
INDICATORS, 1960-1989

Dependant Variable DEPTH BANK PRIVATE PRIVY


Real Per Capita GDP Growth 0.024""" 0.032""" 0.034""" 0.032"""
[0.007] [0.005] [0.002] [0.002]
R2 0.5 0.5 0.52 0.52
Real Per Capita Capital Stock Growth 0.022""* 0,022"" o.o~o"" 0.025"""
[0.001] [0.012] [0.011] [0.001]
R2 0.65 0.62 0.62 0.64
Productivity Growth

R2

Source: King and Levine (1993b)

" significant at the 0.10 level, "" significant at the 0.05 level, """ significant at the 0.01 level.

[p-values in brackets]

Observations = 77

DEPTH = Liquid liabilities to GDP

BANK = Deposit bank domestic credit divided by deposit money bank + central bank domestic

credit
PRIVATE = Claims on the non-financial private sector to total claims
PRIVY = Gross claims on private sector to GDP
Productivity Growth = Real Per Capita GDP Growth - (0.3)"RealPer Capita Capital Stock Growth

Other explanato y variables included i n each of the 12 regressions: log of initial income, log of initial secondary
school enrollment rate, ratio of government consumption expenditures to GDP, inflation rate, and ratio of export
plus imports to GDP.

then the following 12 regressions are run quartile of countries (0.6) would have in-
on a cross-section of 77 countries: creased its per capita growth rate by al-
most one percent h e r rear. This is large.
G ( j )= a + PF(i) + yX + E.
The difference between the slowest
There is a strong positive relationship growing 25 percent of countries and the
between each of the four financial devel- fastest growing quartile of countries is
opment indicators, F(i), and the three about five percent per annum over this
growth indicators G(i),long-run real per 30 year period. Thus, the rise in DEPTH
capita growth rates, capital accumula- alone eliminates 20 percent of this
tion, and productivity growth. Table 2 growth difference.
summarizes the results on the 12 P's. Finally, to examine whether finance
Not only are all the financial develop- simply follows growth, King and Levine
ment coefficients statistically significant, (199313) study whether the value of fi-
the sizes of the coefficients imply an nancial depth in 1960 predicts the rate
economically important relationship. Ig- of economic growth, capital accumula-
noring causality, the coefficient of 0.024 tion, and productivity improvements
on DEPTH implies that a country that over the next 30 years. Table 3 summa-
increased DEPTH from the mean of the rizes some of the results. In the three
slowest growing quartile of countries regressions reported in Table 3, the de-
(0.2) to the mean of the fastest growing pendent variable is, respectively, real per
Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth

TABLE 3
GROWTHAND INITIAL FINANCIAL
DEPTH,1960-1989

Per Capita GDP


Per Capita Capital Per Capita Productivity
Growth, 1960-1989
Growth, 1960-1989 Growth, 1960-1989
Constant 0.035"""
0.002 0.034"""
[0.001] [0.682] [0.001]
Log (Real GDP per -0.016""" -0.004* -0.015"""
Person in 1960) [0.001] [0.068] [0.001]
Log (Secondary school 0.013""" 0.007""" 0.0115**
enrollment in 1960) [0.001] [0.001] [0.001]
Government 0.07* 0.049* 0.056"
consumption/GDP in 1960 [0.051] [0.064] [0.076]
Inflation in 1960 0.037 0.02 0.029
[0.239] [0.238] [0.292]
(Imports plus Exports)/GDP -0.003 -0.001 -0.003
in 1960 [0.604] [0.767] [0.603]
DEPTH (liquid liabilities) 0.028""" 0.019""" 0.022*"*
in 1960 [0.001] [0.001] [0.001]
R2 0.61 0.63 0.58

Source: King and Levine (1993b)


sipficant at the 0.10 level, ""significant at the 0.05 level, *"" significant at the 0.01 level.
[p-values in brackets]
Observations = 57

capita GDP growth, real per capita capi- more sophisticated time series studies,
tal stock growth, and productivity growth suggest that the initial level of financial
averaged over the period 1960-1989. development is a good predictor of sub-
The financial indicator in each of these sequent rates of economic growth, physi-
regressions is the value of DEPTH in cal c a ~ i t a laccumulation, and economic
I

1960. The regressions indicate that efficiency improvements over the next 30
financial depth in 1960 is significantly years even aftkr controlling for income, ed-
correlated with each of the growth indi- ucation, political stability, and measures
cators averaged over the period 1960- of monetary, trade, and fiscal policy.22
1989." These results, plus those from
controlling for many other factors associated with
21There is an insufficient number of observa- long-run growth.
tions on BANK, PRIVATE, and PRIVY in 1960 to ZZThese broad cross-country results hold even
extend the analysis in Table 3 to these variables. when using instrumental variables-primarily indi-
Thus, King and Levine (1993b) use pooled, cross cators of the legal treatment of creditors taken
section, time series data. For each country, data from LaPorta et al. 1996-to extract the exoge-
permitting, they use data averaged over the 1960s, nous component of financial development (Levine
1970s, and 1980s; thus, there are potentially three 1997). Furthermore, though disagreement exists
observations per count They then relate the (Woo Jun 1986 and Philip Arestis and Panicos
value of growth averager'over the 1960s with the Demetriafes 1995), many time-series investiga-
value of, for example, BANK in 1960 and so on for tions find that financial sector development
the other two decades. They restrict the coeffi- Granger-causes economic performance (Paul
cients to be the same across decades. They find Wachtel Rousseau 1995). These results are
that the initial level of financial develo ment is a ticularly strong when using measures of the va?",:
good redictor of subsequent rates oPeconomic added provided by the financial system instead of
capital accumulation, and economic effi- measures of the size of the financial system (Klaus
ciency improvements over the next ten years after Neusser and Maurice Kugler 1996).
708 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (June 1997)

The relationship between the initial sample of countries and test whether the
level of financial development and industries that are more dependent on
growth is large. For example, the esti- external finance (in the United States)
mated coefficients suggest that if in 1960 grow relatively faster in countries that
Bolivia had increased its financial depth begin the sample period with better de-
from 10 percent of GDP to the mean veloped financial systems. They find that
value for developing countries in 1960 industries that rely heavily on external
(23 percent), then Bolivia would have funding grow comparatively faster in
grown about 0.4 percent faster per an- countries with well-developed interme-
num, so that by 1990 real per capita diaries (as measured by PRIVY) and
GDP would have been about 13 percent stock markets (as measured by stock
larger than it was." Thus, finance does market capitalization) than they do in
not merely follow economic activity. The countries that start with relatively weak
strong link between the level of financial financial systems. Similarly, using firm-
development and the rate of long-run level data from 30 countries, Asli Demir-
economic growth does not simply reflect guq-Kunt and Vojislav Maksimovic
contemporaneous shocks that affect both (199613) argue that firms with access to
financial development and economic more developed stock markets grow at
performance. There is a statistically faster rates than they could have grown
significant and economically large em- without this access. Furthermore, when
pirical relationship between the initial individual states of the United States re-
level of financial development and fu- laxed intrastate branching restrictions,
ture rates of long-run growth, capital this boosted bank lending quality and ac-
accumulation, and productivity improve- celerated real per capita growth rates
ments. Furthermore, insufficient finan- even after controlling for other growth
cial development has sometimes created determinants (Jith Jayaratne and Philip
a "poverty trap" and thus become a se- Strahan 1996). Thus, using firm- and in-
vere obstacle to growth even when a dustrial-level data for a broad cross-
country has established other conditions section of countries and data on indi-
(macroeconomic stability, openness to vidual states of the United States,
trade, educational attainment, etc.) for recent research presents evidence con-
sustained economic development (Jean- sistent with the view that the level of fi-
Claude Berthelemy and Aristomene nancial development materially affects
Varoudakis 1996). the rate and structure of economic de-
Some recent work has extended our velopment.
knowledge about the causal relationships Not surprisingly, these empirical stud-
between financial development and eco- ies do not unambiguously resolve the is-
nomic growth. For example, Rajan and sue of causality. Financial development
Luigi Zingales (1996) assume that finan- may predict growth simply because fi-
cial markets in the United States are nancial systems develop in anticipation
relatively frictionless. This benchmark of future economic growth. Further-
country then defines each industry's effi- more, differences in political systems, le-
cient demand for external finance (in- gal traditions (LaPorta et al. 1996), or in-
vestment minus internal cash flow). They stitutions (Engerman and Sokoloff 1996;
then examine industries across a large Douglass North 1981) may be driving
both financial development and eco-
23 These examples do not consider causal issues nomic growth rates. Nevertheless, the
or how to increase financial development. body of evidence would tend to push
Lezjine: Financial Dezjelopment and Economic Growth 709

many skeptics toward the view that the case of Scotland between 1750 and 1845.
finance-growth link is a first-order rela- Scotland began the period with per cap-
tionship and that difference in financial ita income of less than one-half of En-
development can alter economic growth gland's. By 1845, however, per capita in-
rates over ample time horizons. come was about the same. While
recognizing that the "dominant political
C. Country-Case Studies
event affecting Scotland's potentialities
Country-case studies provide a rich for economic development was the
complement to cross-country compari- Union of 1707, which made Scotland an
sons. For example, Rondo Cameron et integral part of the United Kingdom,"
al. (1967) dissect the historical relation- Cameron (1967a, p. 60), argues that
ships between banking development and Scotland's superior banking system is
the early stages of industrialization for one of the few noteworthy features that
England (1750-1844), Scotland (1750- can help explain its comparatively rapid
1845), France (1800-1870), Belgium growth.24 Other analysts disagree with
(1800-1875), Germany (1815-1870), the "facts" underlying this conclusion.
Russia (1860-1914), and Japan (1868- Some researchers suggest that England
1914). These country-case studies do not did not suffer from a dearth of financial
use formal statistical analysis. Instead, services because nonfinancial enterprises
the researchers carefully examine the le- provided financial services in England
gal, economic, and financial linkages be- that Cameron's (1967a) measures of for-
tween banks and industry during the in- mal financial intermediation omit. Oth-
dustrialization of these seven countries. ers argue that Scotland had rich natural
Typically, the case studies start by de- resources, a well-educated work force,
scribing the political system, economic access to British colonial markets, and
conditions, and financial structure at the started from a much lower level of in-
start of the period of analysis. Then, they come per capita than England. Conse-
provide a detailed description of the evo- quently, it is not surprising that Scotland
lution of the financial system during a enjoyed a period of rapid convergence
period of rapid economic development. toward England's income per capita
Finally, they document critical inter- level. Finally, still other researchers dis-
actions among financial intermediaries, agree with the premise that Scotland had
financial markets, government policies, a well-functioning financial system and
and the financing of industrialization. emphasize the deficiencies in the Scot-
While providing an informative comple- tish system (Sidney Pollard and Dieter
ment to broad cross country compari- Ziegler 1992). Thus, although Andrew
sons, country-case studies rely heavily on Kerr first argued in 1884 that Scotland
subjective evaluations of banking system enjoyed a better banking system than
performance and fail to systematically England from 1750 until 1844, the de-
control for other elements determining bate about whether Scottish banking ex-
economic development. While emphasiz- plains its faster economic growth over
ing the analytical limitations of country- the period 1750-1845 continues today.
case studies, Cameron (1967b) con-
cludes that especially in Scotland and Ja- 24It is also worth noting that Scottish banking
pan, but also in Belgium, Germany, En- was comparatively stable over this period, suffer-
gland, and Russia, the banking system ing fewer and less severe panics than its southern
neighbor. For more on Scottish banking, see Syd-
played a positive, growth-inducing role. ne Checkland (1975) and Tyler Cowen and Ran-
Debate exists, however. Consider the d a i Kroszner (1989).
710 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (June 1997)

The relationship between financial cially, McKinnon's (1973) seminal book


and economic development has been Money and Capital in Economic Devel-
carefully analyzed for many other coun- opment studies the relationship between
tries. For example, Stephen Haber the financial system and economic devel-
(1991, 1996) compares industrial and opment in Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Ger-
capital market development in Brazil, many, Korea, Indonesia, and Taiwan in
Mexico, and the United States between the post World War I1 period. McKin-
1830 and 1930. He finds that capital non interprets the mass of evidence
market development affected industrial emerging from these country-case stud-
composition and national economic per- ies as strongly suggesting that better
formance. Specifically, Haber shows that functioning financial systems support
when Brazil overthrew the monarchy in faster economic growth. Disagreement
1889 and formed the First Republic, it exists over many of these individual
also dramatically liberalized restrictions cases, and it is extremely difficult to iso-
on Brazilian financial markets. The liber- late the importance of any single factor
alization gave more firms easier access to in the process of economic growth.26
external finance. Industrial concentra- Thus, any statements about causality
tion fell and industrial production are-and will remain-largely impres-
boomed. While Mexico also liberalized sionistic and specific to particular coun-
financial sector policies, the liberaliza- tries and specific periods. Nonetheless,
tion was much more mild under the Diaz the body of country-studies suggests
dictatorship (1877-1911), which "relied that, while the financial system responds
on the financial and political support of a to demands from the nonfinancial sector,
small in-group of powerful financial well-functioning financial systems have,
capitalists" (p. 561). As a result, the de- in some cases during some time periods,
cline in concentration and the increase greatly spurred economic growth.
in economic growth was much weaker in
D. Financial Functions and Growth:
Mexico than it was in Brazil. Haber
Liquidity and Risk
(1996, p. 40) concludes that "differences
in capital market development had a sig- I now turn to evidence on the ties be-
nificant impact on the rate of growth of tween measures of the individual finan-
industry. . . . [and that a] lack of access cial functions and economic growth.
to institutional sources of capital because First, consider liquidity. Deposit-taking
of poorly developed capital markets was banks can provide liquidity by issuing
a non-negligible obstacle to industrial liquid demand deposits and making illiq-
development in the nineteenth cen- uid, long-term investments. Isolating this
t~ry."~5 liquidity function from the other finan-
Finally, but perhaps most influen- cial functions performed by banks, how-
ever, has proven prohibitively difficult.
In contrast, economists have studied ex-
25 Interestin ly these political and legal im-
pediments to &&cia1 development are appar- tensively the effects of the liquidity of an
ently difficult to change. I n Mexico, the largest individual security on its price. Substan-
three banks control the same fraction of commer- tial evidence suggests a positive correla-
cial banking activity today, about two-thirds, as
they did 100 years a o Also, Mexico has the low- tion between the liquidity of an asset
est ranking of the fegal protection of minority
shareholder rights of any country in La Porta et 2 6 F o r more on Mexico see Robert Bennett
al.'s (1996) detailed comparison of 49 countries, (1963). For more on Asia, see Cole and Yung Park
which may facilitate the concentration of eco- (1983), Park (1993), and Patrick and Park (1994).
nomic decision making. Fry (1995) provides additional citations.
Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 711

TABLE 4

STOCKMARKET
LIQUIDITY
MEASURES:
SELECTEDCOUNTRIES,
ANNUAL
AVERAGES
197&1993

Turnover Value Per Capita


Ratio Traded Ratio GDP Growth
Low-income
Bangladesh 0.015 0.000 1.89%
Cote d'lvoire 0.028 0.001 -2.50%
Emt 0.060 0.030 3.56%
India 0.537 0.036 2.43%
Nigeria 0.006 0.000 -0.11%
Pakistan 0.105 0.008 3.13%
Zimbabwe 0.059 0.010 -0.97%
Lower-middle -income
Colombia 0.087 0.004 1.95%
Costa Rica 0.013 0.001 0.89%
Indonesia 0.193 0.010 4.18%
Jordan 0.154 0.085 3.01%
Philippines 0.250 0.026 0.21%
Thailand 0.739 0.144 5.90%
Turkey 0.207 0.026 2.32%
Upper-middle-income
Argentina 0.266 0.013 0.22%
Brazil 0.355 0.041 0.65%
Chile 0.060 0.021 3.61%
Korea 0.832 0.186 9.67%
Malaysia 0.230 0.243 4.27%
Mauritius 0.059 0.003 1.76%
Mexico 0.498 0.044 0.85%
Portugal 0.108 0.014 2.85%
High-income
Australia 0.256 0.124 1.57%
Germany 0.704 0.156 0.95%
Great Britian 0.349 0.253 1.75%
Hong Kong 0.372 0.471 6.20%
Israel 0.669 0.144 1.72%
Italy 0.253 0.028 2.68%
Japan 0.469 0.406 3.42%
Netherlands 0.490 0.123 1.43%
Norway 0.318 0.059 2.48%
Spain 0.216 0.045 1.75%
Switzerland 0.467 0.442 1.16%
United States 0.493 0.299 1.67%

Sources: International Finance Corporation, and Morgan Stanley Capital International


Turnover Ratio = Value of Domestic Equities Traded on Domestic Exchanges Divided by Market Capitalization
Value Traded Ratio = Value of Domestic Equities Traded on Domestic Exchanges Divided by GDP Income
classifications from the World Bank's 1995 World Development Report
Low-income economies = average GNP per capita of $380 in 1993
Lower-middle-incomeeconomies = average GNP per capita of $1,590 in 1993
Upper-middle-income economies = average GNP per capita of $4,370 in 1993
High-income economies = average GNP per capita of $23,090 in 1993
712 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (June 1997)

and its price (e.g., Yakov Amihud and over ratios of almost 0.5, while for less
Haim Mendelson 1989; and Gregory liquid markets, such as Bangladesh,
Kadlec and John McConnell 1994). Put Chile, and Egypt they are 0.06 or less.27
differently, agents must be compensated The turnover ratio may differ from the
with a lower price for purchasing an as- value traded ratio because a small, liquid
set that is difficult to sell. These secu- market will have high turnover ratio but
rity-level studies of the relationship be- a small value traded ratio. For example,
tween the liquidity of individual India's average turnover ratio of 0.5 over
securities and their prices, however, do the 1976-1993 is greater than the
not link liquidity with national long run United States', but India's value traded
growth rates. ratio is about one-tenth the size of the
To evaluate the relationship between United States'. These measures seek to
stock market liquidity and national measure liquidity on a macroeconomic
growth rates, capital accumulation rates, scale: the objective is to measure the de-
and rates of technological change, gree to which agents can cheaply,
Levine and Sara Zervos (1996) build on quickly, and confidently trade ownership
Raymond Atje and Jovanovic's (1993) claims of a large percentage of the econ-
study and focus on two measures of liq- omy's productive technologies.28
uidity for a broad cross-section of 49 The researchers then assess the
countries over the period 1976-1993. strength of the empirical relationship
The first liquidity indicator, the value between each liquidity measure and the
traded ratio, equals the total value of three growth indicators: economic growth,
shares traded on a country's stock ex- capital accumulation, and productivity
changes divided by GDP. The value growth. They conduct a cross-country
traded ratio measures trading relative to analysis with one observation per coun-
the size of the economy. While not a di- try. Namely, six basic regressions are
rect measure of trading costs or the un- run: economic growth, capital accumula-
certainty associated with trading and set- tion, and productivity growth averaged
tling equity transactions, theoretical over the 1976-1993 period are regressed
models of liquidity and growth directly first on the value traded ratio in 1976
motivate the value traded ratio (Ben- and then on the turnover ratio in 1976
civenga, B. Smith, and Starr 1995). As while controlling for various factors asso-
shown in Table 4, the value traded ratio ciated with economic growth (initial in-
varies considerably across countries. For come per capita, education, political sta-
example, the United States had an aver- bility, indicators of exchange rate, trade,
age annual value traded ratio of 0.3 dur- fiscal, and monetary policy) to see
ing the 1976-1993 period, while for whether stock market liquidity predicts
Mexico and India it was about 0.04. The subsequent economic growth. Impor-
second indicator, the turnover ratio, tantly, the level of banking sector devel-
equals the total value of shares traded on opment (bank credit to private enter-
a country's stock exchanges divided by prises divided by GDP) measured in
stock market capitalization (the value of
listed shares on the country's ex- 27 Note, Germany's very large turnover ratio
(0.7) reflects the explosion in stock market trans-
changes). The turnover ratio measures actions during unification.
trading relative to the size of the market.
0
28Levine and Zervos 11996) also construct and
~t also exhibits substantial cross-country examine two measures of stock trading relative to
stock price movements: (1)the value traded ratio
active markets such as divided by stock return volatility, and (2) the turn-
Japan and the United States have turn- over ratio divided by stock return volatility.
Leuine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 713

TABLE 5

GROWTHAND INITIAL STOCKMARKET LIQUIDITY,


1976-1993

Value Traded Turnover


Dependant Variable Ratio Ratio
Real Per Capita GDP Growth 0.098""" 0.027"""
[0.003] [0.006]
Adjusted R2 0.33 0.34
Real Per Capita Capital Stock Growth 0.093""" 0.022"""
[0.005] [0.023]
Adjusted R2 0.38 0.35
Productivity Growth 0.075""" 0.020""
[0.001] [0.030]
Adjusted R2 0.21 0.21

Source: Levine and Zervos (1996)


' significant at the 0.10 level, "" significant at the 0.05 level, """ significant at the 0.01 level.

[p-values in brackets]

Observations = 42

Value Traded Ratio = Value of domestic equity transactions on domestic stock exchanges divided by GDP

Turnover Ratio = Value of domestic equity transactions on domestic stock exchanges divided by domestic market

capitalization.

Other explanatoy uariables included in each of the six regressions:


log of initial income, log of initial secondary school enrollment, initial ratio of government expenditures to GDF', in-
itial inflation rate, initial black market exchange rate premium, initial ratio of commercial bank lending to private
enterprises divided by GDP

1976 is included in the regressions to as- implies each Mexican would have en-
sess the independent link between stock joyed an almost 8 percent higher income
market liquidity and growth after con- in 1994. The results are consistent with
trolling for other aspects of financial de- the views that the liquidity services pro-
velopment. The results are summarized vided by stock markets are indepen-
in Table 5. The initial level of stock mar- dently important for long-run growth
ket liquidity-measured either by the and that stock markets provide different
turnover ratio or the value traded ratio- financial services from those provided by
is a statistically significant predictor of financial intermediaries (or else they
economic growth, capital accumulation, would not both enter the growth regres-
and productivity growth over the next 18 sions significantly).29
years. The sizes of the coefficients also Besides the difficulty of assigning a
suggest an economically meaningful rela- causal role to stock market liquidity,
tionship. For example, the results imply there are important limitations to mea-
that if Mexico had had the sample aver- suring it accurately (Sanford Grossman
age value traded ratio in 1976 (0.044) in- and Merton Miller 1988; and Stephen
stead of its realized 1976 value (0.004),
per capita GDP would have grown at a 29Stock market size, as measured by market
ca italization divided by GDP, is not robustly cor-
0.4 percent faster rate (0.04"0.098). Ac-
cumulating over the 18 year period, this
!'
re a ted with growth, capital accumulation, and
productivity improvements.
714 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (June 1997)

Wells 1994). Theory suggests that econo- nological, regulatory, and tax differences
mies will benefit from the ability to across countries may imply that different
trade ownership of an economy's pro- financial structures arise to provide liq-
ductive technologies easily. Stock mar- uidity and risk diversification vehicles.
kets, however, are only one mechanism For example, in one economy the costs
for providing liquidity. Banks and bond of establishing an intermediary may be
markets may also provide liquidity. Thus, high while the costs of conducting equity
measures of stock market liquidity might transactions are low. The reverse may
omit important financial arrangements hold in a second economy. The first
for providing liquidity. Moreover, the economy may provide liquidity and risk
liquidity indicators measure stock trans- diversification services primarily through
actions on a country's national stock ex- equity markets, while the second does it
changes. The physical location of the through financial intermediaries. The
stock market, however, should not neces- first economy has an active stock ex-
sarily matter. That is, Californian savers change, so that existing empirical studies
and firms would probably not have would classify it as providing substantial
greater access to liquidity if the New liquidity and risk diversification services.
York Stock Exchange were to move to In contrast, existing studies would class-
Los Angeles. Thus, measures of the trad- ify the second economy as financially un-
ing of equities on a country's exchanges derdeveloped. Thus, measuring the per-
may not gauge fully the degree of stock formance of one part of the financial
market liquidity available to the econ- system may generate a misleading indi-
omy. This measurement problem will cator of the functioning of the whole fi-
increase over time if economies be- nancial system.
come more financially integrated and
E . Financial Functions and Growth:
firms list and issue shares on foreign ex-
Information
changes.
Besides liquidity risk, the financial sys- Theory strongly suggests that financial
tem also provides mechanisms for hedg- intermediaries play an important role in
ing and trading the idiosyncratic risk as- researching productive technologies be-
sociated with individual projects, firms, fore investment and monitoring manag-
industries, sectors, and countries. While ers and projects after funneling capital
a vast literature examines the pricing of to those projects. Although it is very dif-
risk, there exists very little empirical evi- ficult to measure whether a country's fi-
dence that directly links risk diversifica- nancial system is comparatively adept at
tion services with long-run economic reducing information acquisition costs
growth. Moreover, the only study of the firm level studies provide insights into
relationship between economic growth the role played by financial intermediar-
and the ability of investors to diversify ies in easing information asymmetries
risk internationally through equity mar- (Schiantarelli 1995). Theory suggests
kets yields inconclusive results (Levine that as the costs to outsiders of acquiring
and Zervos 1996). information about a firm rise, a firm's in-
One common weakness in empirical vestment decisions become more tightly
work on liquidity, idiosyncratic risk, and constrained by retained earnings and
economic growth is that it focuses on eq- current cash flow. Thus, studies test
uity markets. Bond markets and financial whether the investment decisions of
intermediaries may also provide mecha- firms with particular traits that proxy for
nisms for diversifying risk. Indeed, tech- the costs to outsiders of acquiring infor-
Leuine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 715

mation are more sensitive to cash flow Scharfstein 1990), Italy (Schiantarelli
than firms without those traits. The sam- and Alessandro Sembenelli 1996), and
ple selection criterion varies across stud- the United States (Petersen and Rajan
ies. 1994). Furthermore, borrowers with
The empirical evidence suggests that longer banking relationships pay lower
the investment decisions of firms with interest rates and are less likely to
more severe asymmetric information pledge collateral than those with less
problems are more sensitive to cash flow mature banking relationships (Petersen
than those where it is less expensive for and Rajan 1994; and Allen Berger and
outsiders to monitor. This conclusion Gregory Udell 1995). Finally, stock price
holds when firms are classified according evidence also indicates that banks pro-
to whether they have received bond duce valuable, private information about
ratings (Toni Whited 1992; Charles borrowers. When banks sign loan agree-
Calomiris, Charles Himmelberg, and ments with borrowers, borrower-firm
Wachtel 1995), whether they are issuing stock prices respond positively (Christo-
large or small dividends (Steven Fazzari, pher James 1987; Scott Lummar and
Glen Hubbard, and Bruce Peterson McConnell 1989; and James and Peggy
1988; Hubbard, Anil Kashyap, and Weir 1990). The value of the information
Whited 1995), whether they are large or obtained by banks about firms can also
small (James Tybout 1983; Gertler and be exemplified by Continental Illinois'
Simon Gilchrist 1994), whether they troubles in the mid-1980s. Myron Slovin,
place a relatively high or low shadow Marie Sushka, and John Polonchek
value on internal funds based on their (1993) show that the banks' impending
response to taxes (Calomiris and Hub- insolvency negatively affected the stock
bard 1995), and whether regulations prices of its client firms and that the
restrict bank credit allocation (Fidel FDIC's rescue efforts positively affected
Jaramillo, Schiantarelli, Weiss 1996; the stock prices of those same clients.
John Harris, Schiantarelli, and Miranda These findings are consistent with the
Siregar 1994). In sum, when outsiders view that the durability of bank-bor-
find it expensive to evaluate and fund rower relationship is valuable. The evi-
particular firms, those firms find it dence directly indicates an important
relatively difficult to raise capital for in- role for financial intermediaries in re-
vestment and rely disproportionately on ducing informational asymmetries be-
internal sources of finance. Thus, finan- tween firm insiders and outside inves-
cial innovations or policies that lower tors. Indirectly, the evidence suggests
information asymmetries ease firm fi- that countries with financial institutions
nancing constraints on more efficient that are effective at relieving informa-
firms. tion barriers will promote faster eco-
More relevant for this section, a large nomic growth through more investment
body of work shows that when firms have than countries with financial systems
close ties to financial intermediaries, this that are less effective at obtaining and
reduces information costs and eases firm processing information.
financing constraints. Specifically, firms
F. Patterns of Financial Development
with close ties to banks tend to be less
constrained in their investment decisions I now turn to the question: Does fi-
than those with less intimate, less ma- nancial structure change as countries de-
ture banking relationships as shown for velop and does it differ across countries?
Japan (Takeo Hoshi, Kashyap, and Again, Goldsmith pioneered the cross-
716 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (June1997)

"
Financial Central Con~mercial Nonbank Stock Market Stock Market
Depth Bank Assets Bank Assets Assets Capitalization Trading

I Low Income Middle Income High Inconle

Figure 2. Financial Structure in Low-, Middle-, and High-Income Economies, 1990


Sources: IMF (International Financial Statistics), IFC (Emerging Markets Data Base), and individual
country reports by central banks, banking commissions, and stock exchanges.
Notes: (1)The data are for 12 low-income economies (Bangladesh, Egypt, Ghana, Guyana, India,
Indonesia, Kenya, Nigeria, Pakistan, Zaire, Zambia, and Zimbabwe), 22 middle-income economies
(Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, the Dominican Republic, El Salvador, Greece,
Guatemala, Jamaica, the Republic of Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Paraguay, The Philippines, Taiwan, Thailand,
Tunisia,Turkey, Uruguay, and Venezuela), and 14 high-income economies (Australia,Canada, Denmark,
Finland, Germany, Italy, Japan, The Netherlands, Singapore, Spain, Sweden, the United Kingdom, and the
United States) data permitting. In 1990, low-income economies had an average GDP per capita of $490;
middle-income economies, $2,740;and high-income economies, $20,457.
(2) Non-bank financial institutions include insurance companies, pension funds, mutual funds, brokerage
houses, and investment banks.
(3) Financial depth is measured by currency held outside financial institutions plus demand deposits and
interest-bearing liabilities of banks and nonbank financial intermediaries.
(4) For stock market trading as a percentage of GDP, Taiwan is omitted because its trading/GDP ratio in
1990 was almost ten times larger than the next highest trading/GDP ratio (Singapore). With Taiwan
included, the middle-income stock trading ratio becomes 37.3percent.

country work in this area. He traced the and economic development for approxi-
relationship between the mix of financial mately 50 countries over the period
intermediaries and economic develop- 1970-1993. This work finds that finan-
ment for 35 countries over the period cial structure differs considerably across
1860-1963. The World Bank (1989) and countries and changes as countries de-
Demirguq-Kunt and Levine (1996b) re- velop economically.
cently extended Goldsmith's work by Four basic findings emerge from
examining the association between the these studies, which are illustrated in
mix of financial intermediaries, markets, Figure 2. As countries get richer over
Levine: Financial Dezjelopment and Economic Growth 717
time or as one shifts from poor to richer financial structure and the level of GDP
countries, per capita, there are important excep-
(1) financial intermediaries get larger tions and differences within income
as measured by the total assets or groups. While one must be hesitant in
liabilities of financial intermediar- drawing conclusions about patterns of fi-
ies relative to GDP; nancial development, an even greater
(2) banks grow relative to the central degree of hesitancy is called for in link-
bank in allocating credit; ing financial structure to economic
growth.
(3) non-banks-such as insurance
companies, investment banks, fi- G. Financial Structure and Economic
nance companies, and private pen- Grou;th
sion funds-grow in importance; There exists considerable debate, with
and sparse evidence and insufficient theory,
(4) stock markets become larger, as about the relationship between financial
measured by market capitalization structure and economic growth. After
relative to GDP, and more liquid, briefly outlining the major examples
as measured by trading relative to used in discussions of financial structure,
GDP, market capitalization, and I describe the major analytical limita-
stock price variability. tions impeding research on financial
While these "patterns" pose a chal- structure and economic growth. The
lenge to financial theorists, they must be classic controversy involves the compari-
treated cautiously because the data suf- son between Germany and the United
fer from numerous problems. For exam- Kingdom. Starting early in this century,
ple, it is difficult to distinguish private economists argued that differences in
from public banks and development the financial structure of the two coun-
banks from commercial banks in many tries help explain Germany's more rapid
countries. Similarly, the definition of a economic growth rate during the latter
bank and of a non-bank are not always half of the 19th century and the first
consistent across countries. Further- decade of the 20th century (Alexander
more, there is nothing causal about these Gerschenkron 1962). The premise is as
relationships. These patterns alone do follows. Germany's bank-based financial
not suggest that poor countries can ac- system, where banks have close ties to
celerate their growth rates by changing industry, reduces the costs of acquiring
the structure of their financial systems. information about firms. This makes it
Finally, many differences exist across easier for the financial system to identify
countries at similar stages of economic good investments, exert corporate con-
development (World Bank 1989). For ex- trol, and mobilize savings for promising
ample, the assets of deposit banks com- investments than in England's more se-
posed 56 percent of financial system as- curities market oriented financial sys-
sets in France, while the comparable tem, where the ties between banks and
number in the United Kingdom was 35 industry are less intimate. Indeed, quite
percent. The assets of contractual sav- a bit of evidence suggests that German
ings institutions composed 26 percent bankers were more closely tied to indus-
of total financial system assets in the try than British bankers. Unlike En-
United Kingdom, while in France the gland, nearly all German bankers started
figure was only 7 percent in 1985. Thus, as merchants. The evolution from entre-
while there is a general trend involving preneur to banker may explain the com-
718 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (June 1997)

paratively close bonds between bankers and German bankers tend to be more in-
and industrialists. For example, German tricately involved in the management of
bankers frequently "mapped out a firm's industry than U.S. bankers (Randall
paths of growth, conceived farsighted Pozdena and Volbert Alexander 1992;
plans, decided on major technological in- Franklin Allen and Gale 1995; and
novations, and arranged for mergers and Demirguq-Kunt and Levine 1996a). Fur-
capital increases" (Gerschenkron 1968, thermore, historical evidence suggests
p. 137). Private German bankers also or- that German universal banks were more
ganized and promoted an impressive ar- efficient (lower cost of capital) than U.S.
ray of major manufacturing companies banks over the 1870-1914 period and
during the mid-19th century (Richard suffered less systemic problems than the
Tilly 1967, p. 179). Besides this en- U.S. banking system (Calomiris 1995). In
trepreneurial role, some evidence sug- contrast, the U.S. financial system is
gests that German bankers tended to be typically characterized as having a com-
more committed to the long-term fund- paratively larger, more active securities
ing of their clients than English bankers. markets with more equities held by
Short-term credits could be transformed households. These observations suggest
into longer-term securities more easily that the German bank-based system may
in Germany (Tilly 1967, pp. 178-81). reduce information asymmetries and
Thus, various pieces of evidence suggest thereby allow banks to allocate capital
a closer relationship between banker and more efficiently and to exert corporate
industrialist in Germany. While bank- control more effectively. In contrast, the
industry relationships may have been United States' securities market-based
closer in Germany, this does not imply financial system may offer advantages in
that the German financial system was terms of boosting risk sharing opportuni-
better at risk management, providing ties (Allen and Gale 1995). While this
liquidity, or facilitating exchange. functional approach highlights the rele-
Furthermore, economists disagree over vant issues, substantially more research
whether the growth differential between is needed before drawing conclusions
the two was really very large. Although about the dominance of one financial
German manufacturing production grew structure over another.30
noticeably faster than Britain's in the six Many of the arguments involving
decades before World War I, Germany's bank-based versus securities market-
overall per capita GNP growth rate was based financial systems have been used
1.55 while the U.K.'s was 1.35 over the to compare Japan and the United States.
period 1850 to 1913 (Goldsmith 1969, For example, research suggests that
pp. 406-07). Thus, aggregate growth dif- Japanese bankers are more closely tied
ferences are not very large, the signifi- to industrial clients than U.S. bankers.
cant differences that do exist are indus- This closer connection may mitigate in-
try specific, and other factors besides formation asymmetries (Hoshi, Kasyap,
differences in financial structure may ex- and Sharfstein 1990), which may foster
plain industry specific growth differen- better investment and faster growth.
tials over this period. Thus, the structure of the Japanese fi-
The debate concerning bank-based nancial system is sometimes viewed as
versus market-based systems eventually superior to the financial structure of the
expanded to include comparisons with
30 Park (1993) compares the structure and func-
the United States. German banks are tioning of the financial systems of Korea and Tai-
larger as a share of GDP than U.S. banks wan in relation to their industrial composition.
Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 719

United States and an important factor in Axis powers may simply have been con-
Japan's faster growth rate over the last verging to the income levels of the
four decades. Interestingly, however, the United States, such that observed
recent banking problems and slower growth rate differentials have little to do
growth in Japan have led some to argue with financial structure. Thus, before
that the absence of a credible takeover linking financial structure with economic
threat through efficient stock markets growth, researchers need to control for
has impeded proper corporate gover- other factors influencing long-run
nance and competitiveness. These con- growth.
flicting analyses highlight the need for A third factor that complicates the
better empirical measures of financial analysis of financial structure and eco-
structure and the functions provided by nomic growth is more fundamental. The
financial systems. current debate focuses on bank-based
There are severe analytical problems systems versus market-based systems.
with linking financial structure to eco- Some aggregate and firm level evidence,
nomic performance. First, existing re- however, suggest that this dichotomy is
search on financial structure does not inappropriate. The data indicate that
quantify the structure of financial sys- both stock market liquidity-as meas-
tems or how well different financial ured by stock trading relative to GDP
systems function overall. For example, and market capitalization-and the level
German bankers may have been more of banking development-as measured
closely connected to industrialists than by bank credits to private firms divided
their British counterparts, but less capa- by GDP predict economic growth over
ble at providing liquidity and facilitating subsequent decades (Levine and Zervos
transactions. Similarly, while Japanese 1996). Thus, it is not banks or stock mar-
Keiretsu may lower information acquisi- kets; bank and stock market develop-
tion costs between banks and firms, this ment indicators both predict economic
does not necessarily imply that the Japa- growth. Perhaps, the debate should not
nese financial system provides greater focus on bank-based versus market-
risk sharing mechanisms or more accu- based systems because these two compo-
rately spot promising new lines of busi- nents of the financial system enter the
ness. Furthermore, while Japan is some- growth regression significantly and pre-
times viewed as a bank-based system, it dict future economic growth. It may be
has one of the best developed stock mar- that stock markets provide a different
kets in the world (Demirguq-Kunt and bundle of financial functions from those
Levine 1996a). Thus, the lack of quanti- provided by financial intermediaries. For
tative measures of financial structure example, stock markets may primarily
and the functioning of financial systems offer vehicles for trading risk and boost-
make it difficult to compare financial ing liquidity. In contrast, banks may fo-
structures. cus on ameliorating information acquisi-
Second, given the array of factors in- tion costs and enhancing corporate
fluencing growth in Germany, Japan, the governance of major corporations. This
United Kingdom, and the United States, is merely a conjecture, however. There
it is analytically difficult-and perhaps are important overlaps between the ser-
reckless-to attribute differences in vices provided by banks and stock mar-
growth rates to differences in the finan- kets. As noted above, well-functioning
cial sector. Moreover, over the post stock markets may ameliorate informa-
World War I1 period, the devastated tion acquisition costs, and banks may
720 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (June1997)

provide instruments for diversifying risk firmed by firm-level studies. In relatively


and enhancing liquidity. Thus, to under- pooi- countries, enhanced stock market
stand the relationship between financial liquidity actually tends to boost corpo-
structure and economic growth, we need rate debt-equity ratios; stock market li-
theories of the simultaneous emergence quidity does not induce a substitution
of stock markets and banks and we need out of debt and into equity finance
empirical proxies of the functions per- (Demirgq-Kunt and Maksimovic 1996a).
formed by the different con~ponentsof However, for industrialized countries,
financial systems. debt-equity ratios fall as stock market li-
A fourth factor limiting our under- quidity rises; stock market liquidity in-
standing of the links between financial duces a substitution out of debt finance.
structure and economic growth is that The evidence suggests complex interac-
researchers have focused on a few indus- tions between the functioning of stock
trialized countries due to data limita- markets and corporate decisions to bor-
tions. The United States, Germany, Ja- row from banks that depend on the over-
pan, and the United Kingdom have all level of economic development. Thus,
basically the same standard of living. Av- we need considerably more research
eraged over a sufficiently long time pe- into the links among stock markets,
riod, they must also have very similar banks, and corporate financing deci-
growth rates. Thus, comparisons of fi- sions to understand the relationship be-
nancial structure and economic develop- tween financial structure and economic
ment using only these countries will tend growth.
to suggest that financial structure is un-
related to the level and growth rate of IV . Conclusions
economic development. Future studies
will need to incorporate a more diverse Since Goldsmith (1969) documented
selection of countries to have even a the relationship between financial and
chance of identifying patterns between economic development 30 years ago, the
financial structure and economic devel- profession has made important progress.
opment. Rigorous theoretical work carefully illu-
Finally, there are important interac- minates many of the channels through
tions between stock markets and banks which the emergence of financial mar-
during economic development that have kets and institutions affect-and are af-
not been the focus of bank-based versus fected by-economic development. A
market-based comparisons. As noted, growing body of empirical analyses, in-
greater stock market liquidity is associ- cluding firm-level studies, industry-level
ated with faster rates of capital forma- studies, individual country-studies, and
tion. Nonetheless, new equity sales do broad cross country comparisons, dem-
not finance much of this new investment onstrate a strong positive link between
(Colin Mayer 1988), though important the functioning of the financial system
differences exist across countries (Ajit and long-run economic growth. Theory
Singh and Javed Hamid 1992). Most new and evidence make it difficult to con-
corporate investment is financed by clude that the financial system merely-
retained earnings and debt. This raises and automatically-responds to industri-
a quandary: stock market liquidity is alization and economic activity, or that
positively associated with investment, financial development is an inconse-
but equity sales do not finance much of quential addendum to the process of
this investment. This quandary is con- economic growth. I believe that we will
Leuine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 72 1

not have a sufficient understanding of prehensive view of financial develop-


long-run economic growth until we un- ment and economic growth.
derstand the evolution and functioning
of financial systems. This conclusion
AGHION, PHILIPPE AND HOR'ITT, PETER. "A
about financial development and long- Model of Growth Through Creative Destruc-
run growth has an important corollary: tion," Econometrica, Mar. 1992, 60(2), pp. 323-
although financial panics and recessions 51.
ALLEN, FRANKLINA N D GALE, DOUGLAS."A
are critical issues, the finance-growth Welfare Com arison of Intermediaries and
link goes beyond the relationship be- Financial MarRets in Germany and the US,"
tween finance and shorter-term fluctua- Europ. Econ. Rev., Feb. 1995, 39(2), pp. 179-
209.
tions. AMIHUD,YAKOVA N D MENDELSON, HAIM."The
Undoubtedly, the financial system is Effects of Beta, Bid-Ask Spread, Residual Risk,
shaped by nonfinancial developments. and Size on Stock Returns," J. Finance, June
1989, 44(2), pp. 479-86.
Changes in telecommunications, com- ARESTIS,PHILIP A N D DEMETRIADES, PANICOS.
puters, nonfinancial sector policies, insti- 'Finance and Growth: Schum eter Might Be
tutions, and economic growth itself in-
"

B
Right' A Comment on King an Levine." U. of
East London mimeo, 1995.
fluence the quality of financial services ARROW,KENNETHJ. "The Role of Securities in
and the structure of the financial system. the Optimal Allocation of Risk Bearing," Rev.
Technological improvements lower Econ. Stud., Apr. 1964, (2), pp. 91-96.
ATJE, RAYMOND AND JO\7ANOVIC, BOYAN."Stock
transaction costs and affect financial ar- Markets and Development," Europ. Econ. Rev.,
rangements (Merton 1992). Monetary Apr. 1993, 37(2/3), pp. 632-40.
and fiscal policies affect the taxation of BAGEHOT,WALTER.Lombard street. Homewood,
IL: Richard D. Irwin, [1873] 1962 Edition.
financial intermediaries and the provi- BENCIVENGA, VALERIER. A N D S ~ ~ I TBRUCE H, D.
sion of financial services (Bencivenga "Financial Intermediation and Endogenous
and B. Smith 1992; Roubini and Sala-i- Growth," Rev. Econ Stud., Apr. 1991, 58(2),
pp. 195-209.
Martin 1995). Legal systems affect finan- . "Deficits. Inflation. and the Banking. Svs-
cial systems (LaPorta et al. 1996), and tem in evel lop in Countries: The 0 timrl ~ e -
political changes and national institu- P
gree of Financia Repression," Ox&d Econ.
Pap., Oct. 1992, 44(4), pp. 767-90.
tions critically influence financial devel- -. "Some Consequences of Credit Rationing
opment (Haber 1991, 1996). Further- in an Endogenous Growth Model," J. Econ. Dy-
more, economic growth alters the nam. Control, Jan.-Mar. 1993, 17(1/2), pp. 97-
122.
willingness of savers and investors to pay BENCI\'ENGA, VALERIE R.; SMITH, BRUCE D.
the costs associated with participating in A N D STARR, ROSS M. "Transactions Costs,
the financial system (Greenwood and Technolog.ica1 Choice. and Endogenous
~ r o w t h , " y .E con. ~ h e o r y Oct.
, 1995, 67(u1), pp.
Jovanovic 1990). While economists have 153-77.
made important advances, we need BENNETT,ROBERTL. "Financial Innovation and
much more research on financial devel- Structural Change in the Early Stages of Indus-
trialization: Mexico, 1945-59," J. Finance, Dec.
opment. Why does financial structure 1963, 18(4),pp. 666-83.
change as countries grow? Why do coun- BERGER,ALLEN N. A N D UDELL, GREGORYF.
tries at similar stages of economic devel- "Relationship Lending and Lines of Credit in
Small Firm Finance," J. Bus., July 1995, 68(3),
opment have different looking financial p p 351-81.
systems? Are there long-run economic BERNANKE, BEN A N D GERTLER,MARK."Agency
growth advantages to adopting legal and Costs, Net Worth, and Business Fluctuations,"
Amer. Econ. Rev., Mar. 1989, 79(1), pp. 14-.
policy changes that create one type of fi- -. "Financial Fragility and Economic Perfor-
nancial structure vis-a-vis another? mance," Quart. J. Econ., Feb. 1990, 105(1), pp.
Much more information about the deter- 87-1
. 14.
BERTHELEMY, JEAN-CLAUDE A N D VAROUDAKIS,
minants and implications of financial ARISTOMENE."Economic Growth, Conver-
structure will move us closer to a com- gence Clubs, and the Role of Financial Devel-
722 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (June1997)
opment," Oxford Econ. Pap., Apr. 1996, 48(2), systems i n developing countries. Eds.: DWIGHT
pp. 300-28. PERKINSA N D MICHAELROEMER.Cambridge,
B K D E , AMAR."The Hidden Costs of Stock Mar-
MA: Harvard U. Press, 1991, p p 3-40.
ket Liquidity," ]. Finan. Econ., Aug. 1993,
COOLEY,THOMAS F.A N D SMITH, BRUCED. "Fi-

34(1),p p -51.
nancial Markets, Specialization, and Learning

BOYD,JOHNH. A N D PRESCOTT, EDWARDC. "Fi-


by Doing." Cornell U. mimeo, 1992.

nancial Intermediar -Coalitions," J. Econ. The-


COWEN,TYLERAND KROSZNER, RANDALL.

"Scot-
ory, Apr 1986,38(2[ p p 211-32.
tish Banking Before 1845: A Model for Laissez-

OHN H. A N D SMITH, BRUCE D. "HOW Faire?" I. Moneu, Credit, Banking, - May , 1989,

Are Standard Debt Contracts? Stochastic 21 (2), p:221-.

Versus Nonstochastic Monitoring in a Costly DAVIS.LANCEE . AND HUTTENBACK. ROBERTA.

State Verification Environment," J. Bus., Oct. ~ a h m o annd the pursuit of empire: The politi-
1994, 67(4), pp. 539-61. cal economy of British imperlialism, 1869-1 912.
-. "The Co-Evolution of the Real and Finan- Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 1986.
cial Sectors in the Growth Process," World DEBREU,GERARD.Theory of value. New York:

Bank Econ. Rev., Ma 1996,10(2),pp. 371-96. Wiley, 1959.

BROCK,PHILIP L., edv If Texas were Chile: A


DE GREGORIO,JOSE. "Borrowing Constraints,
primer on banking reform. San Francisco, CA:
Human Capital Accumulation, and Growth," J.
ICS Press, 1992.
Monet. Econ., Feb. 1996, 37(1), pp. 49-71.
BRUNNER, KARLA N D MELTZER,ALLENH. "The
DE LONG, J. BRADFORD."Did J. P. Morgan's
Uses of Money: Money in the Theory of an Ex-
Men Add Value? An Economist's Perspective
change Economy," Amer. Econ. Rev., Dec.
on Financial Capitalism," in Inside the business
1971, 61(5), pp. 784-805.
enterprise: Historical perspectives on the use of
CALOMIRIS, CHARLES W. "The Costs of Rejecting
information. Ed. PETERTEMIN.Chicago: U. of
Universal Banking: American Finance in the
Chicago Press, 1991, pp. 205-36.
German Mirror, 1870-1914," in Coordination
DE LONG,J. BRADFORDET AL. "The Size and
and information: Historical perspectives on the
Incidence of the Losses from Noise Trading," J.
organization of enterprise. Eds.: NAOMI R.
Finance, July 1989, 44(3), pp. 681-96.
LAMOREAUX A N D DANIELM. G. RAFF. Chi-
DEMIRGUCS-KUNT, ASLI A N D LEVINE, ROSS.
cago: U. of Chicago Press, 1995, pp. 257-321. "Stock Market Develo ment and Financial In-
CALOMIRIS, CHARLES W.; HIMMELBERG,
termediaries: Stylized' Facts," World Bank
CHARLESP . A N D WACHTEL,PAUL. "Commer-
Econ. Rev., May 1996a, 10(2),291-322.
cial Paper, Corporate Finance, and the Busi-
-. "Stock Markets, Corporate Finance, and
ness Cycle: A Microeconomic Perspective,"
Economic Growth: An Overview," World Bank
Carnegie-Rochester Confer. Ser. Pub. Policy, Econ. Rev., May 1996b,10(2),223-40.
June 1995, 42, pp. 203-50. DEMIRGUCS-KUNT, ASLI AND MAKSIMOVIC, VO-
CALOMIRIS,CHARLESW. A N D HUBBARD,R. JISLAV. "Stock Market Development and Fi-
GLENN. "Internal Finance and Investment: nancing Choices of Firms," World Bank Econ.
Evidence from the Undistributed Profits Tax of Rev., May 1996a 10(2),pp. 341-70.
1936-37," J . Bus., Oct. 1995, 68(4), pp. 443-82. . "Financial Constraints, Uses of Funds,
CAMERON, RONDO. "Scotland, 1750-1845," 1967a and Firm Growth: An International Compari-
in RONDOCAMERON E T AL. 1967, pp. 60-99. son." World Bank mimeo, 199613.
. "Conclusion," 1967b in RONDOCAMERON DEVEREUX, MICHAELB. AND SMITH, GREGOR
ET AL. 1967, pp. 290-321. W. "International Risk Sharing and Economic
CAMERON, RONDOET AL. Bankin in the early Growth," Int. Econ. Rev., ~ u ~ . " 1 9 9 435(4),
,

stages of undustrialization: d s t u f i n compara- 535-50.

tive economic history New Yori: Oxford U. DIAMOND,DOUGLASW . "Financial Intermedia-


Press, 1967. tion and Delegated Monitoring," Rev. Econ.
CAPRIO,GERARD,JR.; ATIYAS,IZAK A N D HAN- Stud., July 1984, 51(3), pp. 393-414.
SON,JAMESA. Financial reform: Theory and ex- DIAMOND, DOUGLAS W. A N D DYBVIG,PHILIPH .
perience. New York: Cambridge U. Press, 1994. "Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity,"
CAROSSO,VINCENT. Investment banking in J. Polit. Econ., June 1983, 91(3), pp. 401-19.
America. Cambridge, MA: Harvard U . Press, DIAMOND, DOUGLAS W. A N D VERRECCHIA,
1970. ROBERTE . "Optimal Managerial Contracts and
CHANDAVARKAR, ANAND."Of Finance and Devel- Equilibrium Security Prices," J. Finance, May
opment: Neglected and Unsettled Questions," 1982,37, pp. 275-87.
World Devel., Jan. 1992,20(1),p 133-42 EASTERLY, WILLIAM."How Much Do Distortions
CHECKLAND, SYDNEY A
G Scottish %onking: his- Affect Growth?" J. Monet. ECOIL.,NOV. 1993,
tory, 1695-1973. Glasgow: Collins, 1975. 32(4), p. 187-212,
COLE,DAVIDC. A N D PARK,YUNG CHUL.Finan- ENGERMAN, STANLEYL. AND SOKOLOFF,KEN-
cial development of Korea 1945-1978. Cam- NETH L. "Factor Endowments, Institutions, and
bridge, MA: Harvard U. Press, 1983. Differential Paths of Growth Among New
COLE, DAVID C. A N D SLADE,BETTYF. "Reform World Economies: A View from Economic His-
of Financial Systems," in Reforming economic torians of the United States," in How Latin
Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 723
America fell behind. Ed.: STEPHENHABER. from the 1880s to the 1930s: The Im ossible
Stanford, CA: Stanford U. Press, 1996, pp. 260- Advance of the Banks," in Finance ansfinan-
304. ciers in European histo y 1880-1 960. Ed.
FAZZARI,STEVENM.; HUBBARD, R. GLENNA N D
YOUSSEF CASSIS.New York: Cambridge U.
PETERSEN,BRUCEC. "Financing Constraints,
Press, 1992, pp. 63-92.
and Investment,"Brookings Pap. Econ. Act.,
GURLEY,JOHN G. AND SHAW,EDWARDS. "Fi-
Aug. 1988,l, pp. 141-206.
nancial Aspects of Economic Development,"
FRY, MAXWELL J. Money, interest, and banking in
Amer. Econ. Rev., Sept. 1955, 45(4), pp. 515-
economic development. Baltimore: John Hop-
38.
kins U. Press, 1995.
HABER,STEPHENH. "Industrial Concentration
GALE, DOUGLASA N D HELLWIG,MARTIN."In-
and the Capital Markets: A Com arative Study
centive-Com atible Debt Contracts: The One-
of Brazil, Mexico, and the Unitelstates, 1830-
Period Probl%n," Rev. Econ Stud., Oct. 1985,
1930,"J. Econ. Hist., Sept 1991, 51(3), 559-80.
52(4), pp. 647-63.
--. "Capital Immobilities and Industrial De-

GELB,ALANH. "Financial Policies, Growth, and


velopment: A Comparative Study of Brazil,

Efficiency." World Bank PPR Working Paper


Mexico, and the United States, 1840-1930."

No. 202, June 1989.


Stanford U. mimeo, 1996.

GERSCHENKRON, ALEXANDER. Economic back- HARRIS,JOHN R.; SCHIANTARELLI, FABIO A N D


wardness in historical perspective-A book of SIREGAR, MIRANDA G. "The Effect of Financial
essays. Cambridge: Harvard U. Press, 1962. Liberalization on the Capital Structure and In-
Continuity in histoy and other essays. vestment Decisions of Indonesian Manufactur-
Cambridge, MA: Harvard U. Press, 1968. ing Establishments," World Bank Econ. Rev.,
GERTLER,MARK."Financial Structure and Aggre- Jan. 1994, 8(1), p 17 47
gate Economic Activity: An Overview," J . HICKS,JOHN.A tReoiyif rconomic history. OX-

Money, Credit, Banking, Aug. 1988, 20(3, Pt. ford: Clarendon Press, 1969.

2), p p 559-88. HOLMSTROM,


BENGTAND TIROLE,JEAN."Mar-
GERTLER, MARK A N D GILCHRIST, SIMON. ket Liquidity and Performance Monitoring," J.
"Monetary Policy, Business Cycles, and the Be- Polit. Econ., Aug. 1993, 101(4),pp. 678-709.
havior of Small Manufacturing Firms," Quart. J. HOSHI, TAKEO; KASHYAP, ANIL K. AND
Econ., May 1994,109(2),pp. 309-40. SHARFSTEIN, DAVIDS. "Bank Monitoring and
GERTLER,MARKA N D ROSE,ANDREW."Finance, Investment: Evidence from the Changing
Public Policy and Growth," in GERARDCAPRIO, Structure of Japanese Corporate Banking Rela-
JR., IZAK ATILJAS,AND JAMESA. HANSON. tionships," in Asymmetric information, corpo-
1994, p p 13-45. rate finance, and investment. Ed.: R.GLENN
GIOVANNINI, ALBERT0 A N D DE MELO, MARTHA. HUBBARD. Chicago: U. of Chicago Press, 1990,
"Government Revenue from Financial Repres- p p 105-26.
sion," Amer. Econ. Rev.., Sept. 1993, 83(4), pp. HUBBARD,R. GLENN;KASHYAP,ANIL K. AND
953-63. WHITED,TONI M. "International Finance and
GOLDSMITH,RAYMOND, W. Financial structure Firm Investment," J. Money Credit Banking,
and development. New Haven, CT: Yale U. Aug. 1995,27(3), pp. 683-701.
Press, 1969. INTERNATIONAL FINANCECORPORATION. Emerg-
GORTON,GARYAND PENNACCHI, GEORGE."Fi- ing markets data base. Washington, DC: Vari-
nancial Intermediaries and Liquidity Creation," ous years.
J. Finance, Mar. 1990, 45(1), pp. 49-71. JACKLIN,CHARLES J . "Demand Deposits, Trading
GREEN\4'OOD, JEREMYA N D JOVANOVIC, BOYAN. Restrictions, and Risk Sharing," in Contractual
"Financial Development, Growth, and the Dis- arrangements for intertemporal trade. Eds.:
tribution of Income," J . Polit. Econ., Oct. 1990, EDWARDD. PRESCOTTA N D NEIL WALLACE.
98(5,Pt.l),pp. 1076-1107. Minneapolis: U. of Minnesota Press, 1987, pp.
GREENWOOD, JEREMYA N D SMITH,BRUCE."Fi- 26-47.
-- -
nancial Markets in Development, and the De- JAFFEE, DWIGHT M. A N D RUSSELL,THOMAS.
velopment of Financial Markets," J. Econ. Dy- "Im erfect Information, Uncertainty, and
namics and Control, Jan. 1997, 21(1), pp. Crexit Rationing." Quart J Econ., Nov 1976,
145-81. 90(4), pp. 651-66.
GROSSMAN, GENE M. AND HELPMAN, ELHANAN. JAMES,CHRISTOPHER. "Some Evidence on the
"Quality Ladders in the Theory of Growth," Uniqueness of Bank Loans,"J Finan. Econ.,
Rev. Econ. Stud., Jan. 1991, 58(1), pp. 43-61. Dec. 1987,19(2),pp. 217-36.
GROSSMAN, SANFORDJ. A N D MILLER,MERTON JAMES,CHRISTOPHER AND WIER, PEGGY."Bor-
H. "Liquidity and Market Structure," J . Fi- rowing Relationships, Intermediation, and the
nance, July 1988,43(3), pp. 617-33. Cost of Issuing Public Securities," J. Finan.
GROSSMAN, SANFORDJ. A N D STIGLITZ,JOSEPH Econ., Nov.-Dec. 1990,28(1/2),pp. 149-71.
E. "On the Impossibility of Informationally Ef- JAPPELLI,TULLIOA N D PAGANO, MARCO."Saving,
ficient Markets," Amer. Econ. Rev., June 1980, Growth, and Liquidity Constraints," Quart. J .
70(3), pp. 393-408. Econ., Feb. 1994,109(1),pp. 83-109.
GUESLIN,ANDRE. "Banks and State in France JARAMILLO, FIDEL; SCHIANTARELLI, FABIO AND
724 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. X X X V (June1997)
WEISS, ANDREW."Capital Market Imperfec- LAMOREAUX, NAOMIA N D SOKOLOFF, KENNETH
tions, Financial Constraints and Investment: L. "Long-Term Change in the Organization of
Econometric Evidence from Panel Data for Inventive Activity," Proceedings of the A'ational
Ecuador," J. Devel. Econ., Dec. 1996, 51 (2), pp. Academy of Science, Nov. 1996, 93, pp. 12686-
367-86. 92.
JAYARATNE, JITH A N D STRAHAN, PHILIPE. "The LAPORTA, RAFAELET AL. "Law and Finance." Na-
Finance-Growth Nexus: Evidence from Bank tional Bureau of Economic Research Working
Branch Deregulation," Quart. J. Econ., Aug. Paper No. 5661. July 1996.
1996,111(3),pp. 639-70. LEVHARI,DAVIDA N D SRINIVASAN, T. N. "Opti-
JENSEN,M ICHAELAND MECKLING, WILLIAMR. mal Savings Under Uncertainty," Rev. Econ.
"Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Stud., Apr. 1969, 36(1), p 153-63.
Agency Costs, and Ownership Structure," J . Fi- LEVINE,ROSS. "Stock ~ a r k t s Growth,
, and Tax
nun. Econ., Oct. 1976, 3(4),pp. 305-60. Policy,'T. Finance, Sept. 1991, 46(4), pp. 1445-
JENSEN,MICHAELC. A N D MURPHY,KEVIN J. 65.
"Performance Pay and Top-Management Incen- . "Law, Finance, Economic Growth." U, of
tives, J. Polit. Econ., Apr. 1990, 98(2), pp. 225- Virginia mimeo, 1997.
64. LEVINE,ROSSA N D RENELT,DAVID."A Sensitiv-

JEVONS,W. STANLEY. Money and the mechanism itv Analvsis of Cross-Countrv Growth Regres-

of exchange. London: Appleton, 1875. sidns," ~ m e r Econ.


. Rev., ~ e i t 1992,
. 82(4fpp.

JUNG,WOO S. "Financial Development and Eco- 942-63...

nomic Growth: International Evidence," Econ. LEVINE,ROSS AND ZERVOS,SARA. "Stock Mar-

Devel. Cult. Change, Jan. 1986, 34(2), pp. 333- kets, Banks, and Economic Growth." World

46. Bank Policy Research Working Paper, No.

KADLEC,GREGORYB. AND MCCONNELL, JOHN 1690, Dec. 1996.

J. "The Effect of Market Segmentation and Illi- LUCAS,ROBERTE., JR. "On the Mechanics of

uidity on Asset Prices: Evidence from Ex- Economic Development," J. Monet. Econ., July

%ang. Listings.'' J Finance, June 1994, 49(2), 1988, 22(1), pp. 3-42.

p p 611-36. LUMMER,SCOTT L. AND MCCONNELL, JOHNJ.

KERR, ANDREWW. History of banking i n Scot-


"Further Evidence on the Bank Lending Pro-

land. Glasgow, 1884; 3rd ed. London: A&C


cess and the Capital Market Response to Bank

Black, 1918.
Loan Agreements," J. Finan. Econ., Nov. 1989,

KHAN,AUBHIK."Financial Development and Eco- 25(l), p p 99-122.

nomic Growth." U. of Virginia mimeo, 1994. MAYER,COLIN. "New Issues in Corporate Fi-

KING,ROBERTG. A N D LEVINE,ROSS. "Financial nance," Europ. Econ. Rev., June 1988, 32(5),

Intermediation and Economic Development," pp. 1167-83.

in Financial intermediation i n the construction MCKINNON, RONALDI. Money and capital in eco-
of Europe. Eds.: COLIN MAYERAND XAVIER nomic development. Washington, DC: Brook-
VIVES. London: Centre for Economic Policy i n g ~Institution, 1973.
Research, 1993a, p 156-89. MEIER, GERALDM. A N D SEERS, DUDLEY.Pio-
- . "Finance ancfkrowth: Schum~eterMight neers i n development. New York: Oxford U.
Be Right," Quart. J. Econ., Aug. 19b3b, 108(?3), Press, 1984.
pp. 717-37. MERTON,R OBERTC. "A Simple Model of Capital
,- "Finance. E n t r e ~ r e n e u r s h i ~and
. Growth: Market Equilibrium with Incomplete In- for-
Theory and ~Gidenc;" J. on&: Econ., Dec. mation," J. Finance, July 1987, 42(3), pp. 483-
1993c, 32(3),pp. 513-42. 510.
KING, ROBERTG. AND PLOSSER,CHARLESI. . "Financial Innovation and Economic Per-
"Money as the Mechanism of Exchange," J. formance," J. Applied Corporate Finance, Win-
Monet. Econ., Jan. 1986, 17(1), pp. 93-115. ter 1992,4(4), pp. 12-22.
KRASA,STEFAN A N D VILLAMIL,ANNEP. "Moni- MERTON,ROBERTC. A N D BODIE, ZVI. 'A Con-
toring the Monitor: An Incentive Structure for ceptual Framework for Analyzing the Financial
a Financial Intermediary," J. Econ. Theory, Environment," in The globalfinancial system: A
June 1992, 57(1), pp. 197-221. functional perspective. Eds.: DWIGHT B.
KYLE,ALBERTS. "Market Structure, Information, CRANEET AL. Boston, MA: Harvard Business
Futures Markets, and Price Formation," in School Press, 1995, pp. 3%.
International agricultural trade: Advanced MORCK, RANDALL;SHLEIFER, ANDREI AND
readings in price formation, market structure, VISHNY,ROBERTW. "Do Managerial Objec-
and price instability. Eds.: GARYG. STOREY, tives Drive Bad Acquisitions?" J. Finance, Mar.
ANDREW SCHMITZ, AND ALEXANDERH. 1990, 45(1), pp. -48
SARRIS.Boulder, CO: Westview, 1984, pp. 45- MYERS,STEWART C. AND MAJLUF,N ICHOLASS.
64. "Corporate Financing and Investment Deci-
LAMOREAUX, NAOMIR. Insider lending: Banks, sions When Firms Have Information That In-
personal connections, and economic develop- vestors Do Not Have," J. Finan. Econ., June
ment in industrial New England, New York: 1984,13(2), p . 187-221.
Cambridge U. Press, 1994. NEAL,LARRYTge rise offinancial capitalism: In-
Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 725
ternational capital markets in the age of reason. ROMER,PAULM. "Increasing Returns and Lon
New York: Cambridge U. Press, 1990. Run Growth," T. Polit. Econ., Oct. 1986, 94(557
NEUSSER, KLAUS AND KUGLER, MAURICE. pp 1002-37.
"Manufacturing Growth and Financial Develop- - "Endogenous Technological Change," J
ment: Evidence from OECD Countries." U. of Polit. Econ., Oct. 1990, 98(5, Pt 2), pp S71-
Berne mimeo, 1996. 102.
NORTH,DOUGLASS C. Structure and change in ROUBINI, NOURIEL AND SALA-I-MARTIN,
economic history. New York: Norton, 1981. XAVIER."Financial Revression and Economic
OBSTFELD,MAURICE."Risk-Taking, Global Di- Growth," J. Devel. E C O ~ . , July 1992, 39(1), pp.
versification, and Growth," Amer. Econ. Rev., 5-30.
- .
Dec. 1994, 84(5), pp. 10-29. .- "A Growth Model of Inflation, Tax Eva-
OSTROY, JOSEPHM. A N D STARR,ROSS M. "The sion, and Financial Repression," J. Monet.
Transactions Role of Money," in, Handbook of Econ., Apr. 1995, 35(2), pp. 275-301.
monetary economics. Vol. 1. Eds.: BENJAMIN SAINT-PAUL, GILLES."Technological Choice, Fi-

FRIEDMAN A ND FRANKH . HAHN.Amsterdam: nancial Markets and Economic Development,"

North-Holland, 1990, pp. 3-62. Europ. Econ. Rev., May 1992, 36(4), pp. 763-

PAGANO, MARCO. "Financial Markets and 81.

Growth: An Overview," Europ. Econ. Rev., Apr. SCHARFSTEIN,


DAVID."The Disciplinary Role of
1993, 37(2-3), pp. 613-22. Takeovers," Rev. Econ. Stud., Apr. 1988, 55(2),
PARK,YUNGCHUL."The Role of Finance in Eco- pp. 185-99.
nomic Development in South Korea and Tai- SCHIANTARELLI. FABIO. "Financial Constraints
wan," in Finance and development: Issues and and ~nvestment:A Critical Rev. Methodological
experience. Ed.: ALBERTO GIOVANNINI. Issues and International Evidence," in Is bank
Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 1993, pp. lending important for the transmission of mone-
121-50. tary policy? Eds.: JOE PEEK A N D ERIC S.
PATRICK,HUGHT. "Financial Development and ROSENGREN.Boston, MA: Federal Reserve
Economic Growth in Underdeveloped Coun- Bank of Boston Conference Series No. 39, June
tries," Econ. Devel. Cult. Change, Jan. 1966, 1995, pp. 177-214.
14(2),p p 174-89. SCHIANTARELLI, FABIO
A N D SEMBENELLI, ALES-
PATRICK,HUGHT. AND PARK,Y UNG CHUL.Fi- SANDRO. "Form of Ownership and Financial
nancial develo ment in Japan, Korea, and Tai- Constraints: Panel Data Evidence From
wan. New Yorf: Oxford U. Press, 1994. Leverage and Investment Equations." World
PENSODE LA VEGA,JOSEF.Confusion de confu- Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 1629,
siones, 1688. Boston: Baker Library, Harvard 1996.
Graduate School of Business, 1957. SCHUMPETER,JOSEPH A. Theorie der Wirt-
PETERSEN,MITCHELLA. A N D RAJAN,RAGHU- schaftlichen Entwicklung [The theory of eco-
RAM G. "The Benefits of Lending Relation- nomic development].Leipzig: Dunker & Hum-
ships: Evidence from Small Business Data," J. blot, 1912; translated by REDVERS OPIE.
Finance, Mar. 1994, 49(1), pp. 3-37. Cambridge, MA: Harvard U. Press, 1934.
POLLARD,SIDNEYA N D ZIEGLER,DIETER."Bank- SHARPE,STEVENA. "Asymmetric Information,
ing and Industrialization: Rondo Cameron Bank Lending, and Implicit Contracts: A Styl-
Twenty Years On," in Finance andfinanciers in ized Model of Customer Relationships," J. Fi-
European history 1880-1960. Ed.: YOUSEF nance, Sept. 1990, 45(4), pp. 1069-87.
CASSIS.New York: Cambridge U. Press, 1992, SHLEIFER,ANDREIA N D SUMMERS, LAWRENCE
pp. 17-38. H. "Breach of Trust in Hostile Takeovers," in
POZDENA, RANDALLJ. AND VOLBERT,ALEXAN- Corporate takeovers: Causes and consequences.
DER. "Bank Structure in West Germany," in Ed.: ALANJ. AUERBACH. Chicago: U. of Chi-
Banking structures in major countries. Ed.: cago Press, 1988, pp. 33-56.
GEORGEG. KAUFMAN. Nonvell, MA and Dor- SHLEIFER, ANDREI A N D VISHY, ROBERT W.
drecht: Kluwer, 1992, pp. 555-90. "Large Shareholders and Corporate Control," J.
RAJAN, RAGHURAM G. "Insiders and Outsiders: Polit. Econ., June 1986, 94(3), pp. 461-88.
The Choice Between Informed and Armslength "A Survey of Corporate Governance," J.
Debt," J. Finance, Sept. 1992, 47(4), pp. 1367- Finance, forthcoming.
1400. SINGH,AJIT A N D HAMID,JAVED."Corporate Fi-
RAJAN,RAGHURAM G. AND ZINGALES,LUIGI. nancial Structures in Develo ing Countries."
"Financial Dependence and Growth." U. of
Chicago mimeo, May 1996.
P
Washington, DC: Internationa Finance Corpo-
ration Technical Paper 1, 1992.
REBELO, SERGIOT. "Long-Run Policy Analysis SIRRI, ERIKR. A N D TUFANO,PETER."The Eco-
and Long-Run Growth," J . Polit. Econ., June nomics of Pooling," in The global financial sys-
1991, 99(3), pp. 500-21. tem: A functional perspective. Eds.: DWIGHTB.
ROBINSON,JOAN. "The Generalization of the CRANEET AL. Boston, MA: Harvard Business
General Theory," in The rate of interest, and School Press, 1995, pp. 81-128.
other essays. London: Macmillan, 1952, pp. 67- SLOVIN,MYRON B.; SUSHKA,MARIE E. A N D
142. POLONCHEK, JOHNA. "The Value of Bank Du-
Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (June 1997)
rability: Borrowers as Bank Stakeholders," J. Fi- TYBOUT, JAMESR. "Credit Rationing and Invest-
nance, Mar. 1993,48(1),pp. 247-66. ment Behavior in a Developing Country," Rev.
SMITH, ADAM. An inquiry into the nature and Econ. Statist., Nov. 1983, 65(4), pp. 598-607.
causes of the wealth of nations. London: W. Sta- WACHTEL,PAULAND ROUSSEAU, PETER."Finan-
han & T. Cadell, 1776. cial Intermediation and Economic Growth: A
I
STEIN, EREMY C. "Takeover Threats and Mana-
geria Myopia," J. Polit. Econ., Feb. 1988, 96(1),
p p 61-80.
Historical Comparison of the U.S., U.K., and
Canada," in An lo American financial systems:
Institutions a n 2 markets in twentieth-century
STERN,NICHOLAS."The Economics of Develop- North America and the United Kingdom. Eds.:
ment: A Survey," Econ. J . , Sept. 1989, 99(397), MICHAELD. BORDO A N D RICHARDSYLLA.
pp. 597-685. Homewood, IL: Business One Irwin, 1995, pp.
STIGLITZ,JOSEPH E. "Credit Markets and the 329-82.
Control of Capital," J . Money, Credit, Banking, WELLS,STEPHEN."Turnover Statistics and Trade
May 1985, 17(2),pp. 133-52. Re orting " London Stock Exchange Quarterly
STIGLITZ, JOSEPH E. A N D WEISS, ANDREW. w i t i Qual;tY of Markets R e v , Spring 1994, pp.
"Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect 23-26.
Information," Amer. Econ. Rev., June 1981, WHITED,TONI M. "Debt, Liquidity Constraints,
71(3), p p 393-410. and Corporate Investment: Evidence from
"Incentive Effects of Terminations: Appli- Panel Data," J. Finance, Sept. 1992, 47(4), pp.
cations to Credit and Labor Markets," Amer. 1425-60.
Econ. Rev., Dec. 1983, 73(5), pp. 912-27. WILLIAMSON, STEPHEND. "Costly Monitoring,
VON THADDEN,ERNST-LUDWIG. "Long-Term Financial Intermediation, and Equilibrium
Contracts, Short-Term Investment and Moni- Credit Rationing," J. Monet. Econ., Sept. 1986,
toring," Rev. Econ. Stud., Oct. 1995, 62(4), pp. 18(2),pp. 159-79.
557-75. -. "Costly Monitoring, Loan Contracts, and
TILLY, RICHARD. "Germany, 1815-1870," in E uilibrium Credit Rationing,"Quart. J. Econ.,
Banking i n the early stages of industrialization: F & 1987a, l O Z ( 1 ) . p p 135-45.
A study in comparative economic history. Eds.: - . "Financial Intermediation, Business Fail-
RONDOCAMERON ET AL. New York: Oxford U. ures, and Real Business Cycles," J. Polit. Econ.,
Press, 1967, pp. 151-82. Dec. 198713, 95(6), pp. 1196-1216.
TOBIN, JAMES."Money and Economic Growth," WILLIAMSON,STEVE A N D WRIGHT, RANDALL.
Econometrica, Oct. 1965, 33(4), p. 671-84. "Barter and Monetary Exchange Under Private
TOWNSEND. ROBERTM "OptimaPContracts and Information," Amer. Econ. Rev., Mar. 1994,
Competitive Markets with Costly State Verifica- 84(1), p p 104-23.
tion," J . Econ. Theory, Oct. 1979, 21 (2), pp. WORLD BANK.World development report Wash-
265-93. ington, DC: Oxford U. Press, 1989.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 1 of 10 -

You have printed the following article:


Financial Development and Economic Growth: Views and Agenda
Ross Levine
Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 35, No. 2. (Jun., 1997), pp. 688-726.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0515%28199706%2935%3A2%3C688%3AFDAEGV%3E2.0.CO%3B2-X

This article references the following linked citations. If you are trying to access articles from an
off-campus location, you may be required to first logon via your library web site to access JSTOR. Please
visit your library's website or contact a librarian to learn about options for remote access to JSTOR.

[Footnotes]

3
Financial Aspects of Economic Development
John G. Gurley; E. S. Shaw
The American Economic Review, Vol. 45, No. 4. (Sep., 1955), pp. 515-538.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28195509%2945%3A4%3C515%3AFAOED%3E2.0.CO%3B2-8

3
Money and Economic Growth
James Tobin
Econometrica, Vol. 33, No. 4. (Oct., 1965), pp. 671-684.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0012-9682%28196510%2933%3A4%3C671%3AMAEG%3E2.0.CO%3B2-E

5
Government Revenue from Financial Repression
Alberto Giovannini; Martha de Melo
The American Economic Review, Vol. 83, No. 4. (Sep., 1993), pp. 953-963.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199309%2983%3A4%3C953%3AGRFFR%3E2.0.CO%3B2-S

14
Agency Costs, Net Worth, and Business Fluctuations
Ben Bernanke; Mark Gertler
The American Economic Review, Vol. 79, No. 1. (Mar., 1989), pp. 14-31.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28198903%2979%3A1%3C14%3AACNWAB%3E2.0.CO%3B2-U

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 2 of 10 -

14
How Good Are Standard Debt Contracts? Stochastic Versus Nonstochastic Monitoring in a
Costly State Verification Environment
John H. Boyd; Bruce D. Smith
The Journal of Business, Vol. 67, No. 4. (Oct., 1994), pp. 539-561.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0021-9398%28199410%2967%3A4%3C539%3AHGASDC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-J

16
The Size and Incidence of the Losses from Noise Trading
J. Bradford De Long; Andrei Shleifer; Lawrence H. Summers; Robert J. Waldmann
The Journal of Finance, Vol. 44, No. 3, Papers and Proceedings of the Forty-Eighth Annual Meeting
of the American Finance Association, New York, New York, December 28-30, 1988. (Jul., 1989),
pp. 681-696.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-1082%28198907%2944%3A3%3C681%3ATSAIOT%3E2.0.CO%3B2-E

26
Financial Innovation and Structural Change in the Early Stages of Industrialization:
Mexico, 1945-59
Robert L. Bennett
The Journal of Finance, Vol. 18, No. 4. (Dec., 1963), pp. 666-683.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-1082%28196312%2918%3A4%3C666%3AFIASCI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-1

References

A Model of Growth Through Creative Destruction


Philippe Aghion; Peter Howitt
Econometrica, Vol. 60, No. 2. (Mar., 1992), pp. 323-351.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0012-9682%28199203%2960%3A2%3C323%3AAMOGTC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-%23

The Effects of Beta, Bid-Ask Spread, Residual Risk, and Size on Stock Returns
Yakov Amihud; Haim Mendelson
The Journal of Finance, Vol. 44, No. 2. (Jun., 1989), pp. 479-486.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-1082%28198906%2944%3A2%3C479%3ATEOBBS%3E2.0.CO%3B2-6

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 3 of 10 -

Financial Innovation and Structural Change in the Early Stages of Industrialization: Mexico,
1945-59
Robert L. Bennett
The Journal of Finance, Vol. 18, No. 4. (Dec., 1963), pp. 666-683.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-1082%28196312%2918%3A4%3C666%3AFIASCI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-1

Relationship Lending and Lines of Credit in Small Firm Finance


Allen N. Berger; Gregory F. Udell
The Journal of Business, Vol. 68, No. 3. (Jul., 1995), pp. 351-381.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0021-9398%28199507%2968%3A3%3C351%3ARLALOC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-M

Agency Costs, Net Worth, and Business Fluctuations


Ben Bernanke; Mark Gertler
The American Economic Review, Vol. 79, No. 1. (Mar., 1989), pp. 14-31.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28198903%2979%3A1%3C14%3AACNWAB%3E2.0.CO%3B2-U

How Good Are Standard Debt Contracts? Stochastic Versus Nonstochastic Monitoring in a
Costly State Verification Environment
John H. Boyd; Bruce D. Smith
The Journal of Business, Vol. 67, No. 4. (Oct., 1994), pp. 539-561.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0021-9398%28199410%2967%3A4%3C539%3AHGASDC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-J

The Uses of Money: Money in the Theory of an Exchange Economy


Karl Brunner; Allan H. Meltzer
The American Economic Review, Vol. 61, No. 5. (Dec., 1971), pp. 784-805.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28197112%2961%3A5%3C784%3ATUOMMI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-Q

Internal Finance and Investment: Evidence from the Undistributed Profits Tax of 1936-37
Charles W. Calomiris; R. Glenn Hubbard
The Journal of Business, Vol. 68, No. 4. (Oct., 1995), pp. 443-482.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0021-9398%28199510%2968%3A4%3C443%3AIFAIEF%3E2.0.CO%3B2-4

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 4 of 10 -

The Size and Incidence of the Losses from Noise Trading


J. Bradford De Long; Andrei Shleifer; Lawrence H. Summers; Robert J. Waldmann
The Journal of Finance, Vol. 44, No. 3, Papers and Proceedings of the Forty-Eighth Annual Meeting
of the American Finance Association, New York, New York, December 28-30, 1988. (Jul., 1989),
pp. 681-696.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-1082%28198907%2944%3A3%3C681%3ATSAIOT%3E2.0.CO%3B2-E

International Risk Sharing and Economic Growth


Michael B. Devereux; Gregor W. Smith
International Economic Review, Vol. 35, No. 3. (Aug., 1994), pp. 535-550.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0020-6598%28199408%2935%3A3%3C535%3AIRSAEG%3E2.0.CO%3B2-B

Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity


Douglas W. Diamond; Philip H. Dybvig
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 91, No. 3. (Jun., 1983), pp. 401-419.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28198306%2991%3A3%3C401%3ABRDIAL%3E2.0.CO%3B2-Z

Optimal Managerial Contracts and Equilibrium Security Prices


Douglas W. Diamond; Robert E. Verrecchia
The Journal of Finance, Vol. 37, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Fortieth Annual Meeting of
the American Finance Association, Washington, D.C., December 28-30, 1981. (May, 1982), pp.
275-287.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-1082%28198205%2937%3A2%3C275%3AOMCAES%3E2.0.CO%3B2-T

Government Revenue from Financial Repression


Alberto Giovannini; Martha de Melo
The American Economic Review, Vol. 83, No. 4. (Sep., 1993), pp. 953-963.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199309%2983%3A4%3C953%3AGRFFR%3E2.0.CO%3B2-S

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 5 of 10 -

Financial Intermediaries and Liquidity Creation


Gary Gorton; George Pennacchi
The Journal of Finance, Vol. 45, No. 1. (Mar., 1990), pp. 49-71.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-1082%28199003%2945%3A1%3C49%3AFIALC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-4

Financial Development, Growth, and the Distribution of Income


Jeremy Greenwood; Boyan Jovanovic
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98, No. 5, Part 1. (Oct., 1990), pp. 1076-1107.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28199010%2998%3A5%3C1076%3AFDGATD%3E2.0.CO%3B2-D

Liquidity and Market Structure


Sanford J. Grossman; Merton H. Miller
The Journal of Finance, Vol. 43, No. 3, Papers and Proceedings of the Forty-Seventh Annual
Meeting of the American Finance Association, Chicago, Illinois, December 28-30, 1987. (Jul.,
1988), pp. 617-633.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-1082%28198807%2943%3A3%3C617%3ALAMS%3E2.0.CO%3B2-G

On the Impossibility of Informationally Efficient Markets


Sanford J. Grossman; Joseph E. Stiglitz
The American Economic Review, Vol. 70, No. 3. (Jun., 1980), pp. 393-408.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28198006%2970%3A3%3C393%3AOTIOIE%3E2.0.CO%3B2-6

Financial Aspects of Economic Development


John G. Gurley; E. S. Shaw
The American Economic Review, Vol. 45, No. 4. (Sep., 1955), pp. 515-538.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28195509%2945%3A4%3C515%3AFAOED%3E2.0.CO%3B2-8

Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring


Bengt Holmstrm; Jean Tirole
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 101, No. 4. (Aug., 1993), pp. 678-709.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28199308%29101%3A4%3C678%3AMLAPM%3E2.0.CO%3B2-F

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 6 of 10 -

Performance Pay and Top-Management Incentives


Michael C. Jensen; Kevin J. Murphy
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98, No. 2. (Apr., 1990), pp. 225-264.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28199004%2998%3A2%3C225%3APPATI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-I

The Effect of Market Segmentation and Illiquidity on Asset Prices: Evidence from Exchange
Listings
Gregory B. Kadlec; John J. McConnell
The Journal of Finance, Vol. 49, No. 2. (Jun., 1994), pp. 611-636.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-1082%28199406%2949%3A2%3C611%3ATEOMSA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-6

Long-Term Change in the Organization of Inventive Activity


Naomi R. Lamoreaux; Kenneth L. Sokoloff
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, Vol. 93, No. 23.
(Nov. 12, 1996), pp. 12686-12692.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0027-8424%2819961112%2993%3A23%3C12686%3ALCITOO%3E2.0.CO%3B2-7

Stock Markets, Growth, and Tax Policy


Ross Levine
The Journal of Finance, Vol. 46, No. 4. (Sep., 1991), pp. 1445-1465.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-1082%28199109%2946%3A4%3C1445%3ASMGATP%3E2.0.CO%3B2-N

A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions


Ross Levine; David Renelt
The American Economic Review, Vol. 82, No. 4. (Sep., 1992), pp. 942-963.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199209%2982%3A4%3C942%3AASAOCG%3E2.0.CO%3B2-J

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 7 of 10 -

A Simple Model of Capital Market Equilibrium with Incomplete Information


Robert C. Merton
The Journal of Finance, Vol. 42, No. 3, Papers and Proceedings of the Forty-Fifth Annual Meeting
of the American Finance Association, New Orleans, Louisiana, December 28-30, 1986. (Jul., 1987),
pp. 483-510.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-1082%28198707%2942%3A3%3C483%3AASMOCM%3E2.0.CO%3B2-7

Do Managerial Objectives Drive Bad Acquisitions?


Randall Morck; Andrei Shleifer; Robert W. Vishny
The Journal of Finance, Vol. 45, No. 1. (Mar., 1990), pp. 31-48.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-1082%28199003%2945%3A1%3C31%3ADMODBA%3E2.0.CO%3B2-6

Risk-Taking, Global Diversification, and Growth


Maurice Obstfeld
The American Economic Review, Vol. 84, No. 5. (Dec., 1994), pp. 1310-1329.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199412%2984%3A5%3C1310%3ARGDAG%3E2.0.CO%3B2-8

The Benefits of Lending Relationships: Evidence from Small Business Data


Mitchell A. Petersen; Raghuram G. Rajan
The Journal of Finance, Vol. 49, No. 1. (Mar., 1994), pp. 3-37.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-1082%28199403%2949%3A1%3C3%3ATBOLRE%3E2.0.CO%3B2-O

Insiders and Outsiders: The Choice between Informed and Arm's-Length Debt
Raghuram G. Rajan
The Journal of Finance, Vol. 47, No. 4. (Sep., 1992), pp. 1367-1400.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-1082%28199209%2947%3A4%3C1367%3AIAOTCB%3E2.0.CO%3B2-F

Long-Run Policy Analysis and Long-Run Growth


Sergio Rebelo
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 99, No. 3. (Jun., 1991), pp. 500-521.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28199106%2999%3A3%3C500%3ALPAALG%3E2.0.CO%3B2-M

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 8 of 10 -

Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth


Paul M. Romer
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 94, No. 5. (Oct., 1986), pp. 1002-1037.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28198610%2994%3A5%3C1002%3AIRALG%3E2.0.CO%3B2-C

Endogenous Technological Change


Paul M. Romer
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98, No. 5, Part 2: The Problem of Development: A
Conference of the Institute for the Study of Free Enterprise Systems. (Oct., 1990), pp. S71-S102.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28199010%2998%3A5%3CS71%3AETC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-8

Asymmetric Information, Bank Lending and Implicit Contracts: A Stylized Model of


Customer Relationships
Steven A. Sharpe
The Journal of Finance, Vol. 45, No. 4. (Sep., 1990), pp. 1069-1087.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-1082%28199009%2945%3A4%3C1069%3AAIBLAI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-Q

Large Shareholders and Corporate Control


Andrei Shleifer; Robert W. Vishny
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 94, No. 3, Part 1. (Jun., 1986), pp. 461-488.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28198606%2994%3A3%3C461%3ALSACC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-V

The Value of Bank Durability: Borrowers as Bank Stakeholders


Myron B. Slovin; Marie E. Sushka; John A. Polonchek
The Journal of Finance, Vol. 48, No. 1. (Mar., 1993), pp. 247-266.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-1082%28199303%2948%3A1%3C247%3ATVOBDB%3E2.0.CO%3B2-3

Takeover Threats and Managerial Myopia


Jeremy C. Stein
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 96, No. 1. (Feb., 1988), pp. 61-80.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28198802%2996%3A1%3C61%3ATTAMM%3E2.0.CO%3B2-L

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 9 of 10 -

The Economics of Development: A Survey


Nicholas Stern
The Economic Journal, Vol. 99, No. 397. (Sep., 1989), pp. 597-685.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0013-0133%28198909%2999%3A397%3C597%3ATEODAS%3E2.0.CO%3B2-K

Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information


Joseph E. Stiglitz; Andrew Weiss
The American Economic Review, Vol. 71, No. 3. (Jun., 1981), pp. 393-410.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28198106%2971%3A3%3C393%3ACRIMWI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-0

Incentive Effects of Terminations: Applications to the Credit and Labor Markets


Joseph E. Stiglitz; Andrew Weiss
The American Economic Review, Vol. 73, No. 5. (Dec., 1983), pp. 912-927.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28198312%2973%3A5%3C912%3AIEOTAT%3E2.0.CO%3B2-F

Money and Economic Growth


James Tobin
Econometrica, Vol. 33, No. 4. (Oct., 1965), pp. 671-684.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0012-9682%28196510%2933%3A4%3C671%3AMAEG%3E2.0.CO%3B2-E

Debt, Liquidity Constraints, and Corporate Investment: Evidence from Panel Data
Toni M. Whited
The Journal of Finance, Vol. 47, No. 4. (Sep., 1992), pp. 1425-1460.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-1082%28199209%2947%3A4%3C1425%3ADLCACI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-B

Financial Intermediation, Business Failures, and Real Business Cycles


Stephen D. Williamson
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 95, No. 6. (Dec., 1987), pp. 1196-1216.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28198712%2995%3A6%3C1196%3AFIBFAR%3E2.0.CO%3B2-W

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org

LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 10 of 10 -

Barter and Monetary Exchange Under Private Information


Steve Williamson; Randall Wright
The American Economic Review, Vol. 84, No. 1. (Mar., 1994), pp. 104-123.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0002-8282%28199403%2984%3A1%3C104%3ABAMEUP%3E2.0.CO%3B2-2

NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.

View publication stats

Potrebbero piacerti anche