Sei sulla pagina 1di 27

Vijay Mahajan, Eitan Muller, & Frank M.

Bass
* ' .rf.

New Product Diffusion Models in


Marketing: A Review and
for Research
Since the publication of the Bass model in 1969, research on the modeling of the diffusion of innovations
has resulted in a body of literature consisting of several dozen articles, books, and assorted other pub-
lications. Attempts have been made to reexamine the structural and conceptual assumptions and esti-
mation issues underlying the diffusion models of new product acceptance. The authors evaluate these
developments for the past two decades. They conclude with a research agenda to make diffusion models
theoretically more sound and practically more effective and realistic.

T HE diffusion of an innovation traditionally has been


defined as the process by which that innovation
"is communicated through certain channels over time
including nonverbal observations, are important influ-
ences in determining the speed and shape of the dif-
fusion process in a social system.
among the members of a social system" (Rogers 1983, Since its introduction to marketing in the 1960s
p. 5). As such, the diffusion process consists of four (Amdt 1967; Bass 1969; Frank, Massy, and Morrison
key elements: innovation, communication channels, 1964; King 1963; Robertson 1967; Silk 1966), inno-
time, and the social system. vation diffusion theory has sparked considerable re-
As a theory of communications, diffusion theory's search among consumer behavior, marketing manage-
main focus is on communication channels, which are ment, and management and marketing science scholars.
the means by which infonnation about an innovation Researchers in consumer behavior have been con-
is transmitted to or within the social system. These cerned with evaluating the applicability of hypotheses
means consist of both the mass media and interper- developed in the general diffusion area to consumer
sonal communications. Members of a social system research (Gatignon and Robertson 1985). The mar-
have different propensities for relying on mass media keting management literature has focused on the im-
or interpersonal channels when seeking information plications of these hypotheses for targeting new prod-
about an innovation. Interpersonal communications. uct prospects and for developing marketing strategies
aimed at potential adopters (see, e.g., Engel, Blackwell,
and Miniard 1986, Chap. 20; Kotler and Zaitman 1976;
McKenna 1985, Chap. 4). Researchers in manage-
Viiay Mahajan is Herman W. Lay Chair Professor of Marketing, Edwin ment and marketing science have contributed to the
L. Cox School of Business. Southern Methodist University. Eitan Muller development of diffusion theory by suggesting ana-
is Associate Professor, Recanati Graduate School of Business Admin- lytical models for describing and forecasting the dif-
istration. Tel-Aviv University, Israel. Frank M, Bass is University of Texas
System Eugene McDermott Professor of Management, University of Texas
fusion of an innovation in a social system. More re-
at Dallas. The authors thank Roger Kerin, Dipak Jain, David Schmittlein. cently, this literature also has been concerned with
Rabikar Chatteriee (especially for his help with Table 2), Subatra Sen, developing normative guidelines for how an innova-
Mike Hanssens. and Josh Eliashberg for their helpful comments, An un- tion should be diffused in a social system.
abridged version of the article can be obtained from the authors.
We focus on the contributions of management and

Journal of Marketing
Vol. B4 (Januarv 19901, 1-26 New Product Diffusion Models in Marketing / 1
marketing science literature to the cumulative under- (1969), Fourt and Woodlock (1960), and Mansfield
standing of the dynamics of innovation diffusion. The (1961). These early models attempted to describe the
main impetus underlying these contributions is a new penetration and saturation aspects of the diffusion pro-
product growth model suggested by Bass (1969). The cess. After briefly reviewing the original formulations
Bass model and its revised forms have been used for of these models, we review the recent developments
forecasting innovation diffusion in retail service, in- that further evaluate their basic structure.'
dustrial technology, agricultural, educational, phar-
maceutical, and consumer durable goods markets The Bass Model
(Akinola 1986; Bass 1969; Dodds 1973; Kalish and
Lilien 1986a; Lancaster and Wright 1983; Lawton and The main impetus underlying diffusion research in
Lawton 1979; Nevers 1972; Tigert and Farivar 1981). marketing is the Bass model. Subsuming the models
Representative companies that have used the model proposed by Fourt and Woodlock (1960) and Mansfield
include Eastman Ktxlak, RCA, IBM, Sears, and AT&T (1961), the Bass model assumes that potential adop-
(Bass 1986). ters of an innovation are influenced by two means of
Since publication of the Bass model, research on communicationmass media and word of mouth. In
the modeling of the diffusion of innovations in mar- its development, it further assumes that the adopters
keting has resulted in an extensive literature. Contri- of an innovation comprise two groups. One group is
butions of this literature through the 1970s were re- influenced only by the mass-media communication
viewed by Mahajan and Muller (1979). However, in (external influence) and the other group is influenced
the ensuing decade a plethora of studies has contrib- only by the word-of-mouth communication (intemal
uted to our understanding of the structural, estima- influence). Bass termed the first group "Innovators"
tion, and conceptual assumptions underlying diffusion and the second group "Imitators." Unlike the Bass
models. Though some of these recent developments model, the model proposed by Fourt and Woodlock
have been documented by Mahajan and Peterson (1985) (1960) assumes that the diffusion process is driven
and Mahajan and Wind (1986a), we now extend these primarily by the mass-media communication or the
efforts by presenting a critical evaluation of the cu- extemal influence. Similarly, the model proposed by
mulative developments since Che Bass (1969) and Ma- Mansfield (1961) assumes this process is driven by
hajan and Muller (1979) articles. Table 1 is a sum- word of mouth.
mary of these developments over the last two decades Figure 1 is a plot of the conceptual and analytical
across five subareas: basic diffusion models, param- structure underlying the Bass model. As noted in Fig-
eter estimation considerations, flexible diffusion ure I A, the Bass model conceptually assumes that
models, refinements and extensions, and use of dif- "Innovators" or buyers who adopt exclusively be-
fusion models. cause of the mass-media communication or the exter-
nal influence are present at any stage of the diffusion
process. Figure IB shows the analytical structure un-
The Basic First-Purchase derlying the Bass model. As depicted, the noncu-
Diffusion Models mulative adopter distribution peaks at time T*, which
Mahajan and Muller (1979) have stated that the ob- is the point of inflection of the S-shaped cumulative
jective of a diffusion model is to present the level of adoption curve. Furthermore, the adopter distribution
spread of an innovation among a given set of pro- assumes that an initial pm (a constant) level of adop-
spective adopters over time. The purpose of the dif- ters buy the product at the beginning of the diffusion
fusion model is to depict the successive increases in process. Once initiated, the adoption process is sym-
the number of adopters and predict the continued de- metric with respect to time around the peak time T*
velopment of a diffusion process already in progress. up to 2T*. That is, the shape of the adoption curve
In the product innovation context, diffusion models from time T* to 2T* is the mirror image of the shape
focus on the development of a life cycle curve and of the adoption curve from the beginning of the dif-
serve the purpose of forecasting first-purchase sales
of innovations. That is, in the first-purchase diffusion 'Related to the Mansfield model is the imitation model suggested
by Fisher and Pry (1971) and the Gompertz curve. For applications
models one assumes that, in the product planning ho- of the Gompertz curve and its comparison with the Mansfield miidel,
rizon being considered, there are no repeat buyers and see Hendiy (1972). Dixon (1980), and Ziemer (1988). Several other
purchase volume per buyer is one unit. The number growth models also have been proposed in the marketing, economics,
and technological substitution literature!^ to depict the growth phe-
of adopters defmes the unit sales for the product. Dif- nomenon (e.g., the Weibull distribution). As some of these models
fusion models, by defmition, are concerned with rep- either do not explicitly consider the diffusion effect in their formu-
resenting the growth of a product category. lation or combine oiher models, they are not included in our review.
For applications of such models to new product growth situations, see
The best-known first-purchase diffusion models of DeKIuyver (1982), Sharif and Islam (1980). Meade (1984). L^e and
new product diffusion in marketing are those of Bass Lu (1987), and Skiadas (1985, 1986).

2/Journal of Marketing, January 1990


TABLE 1
Emergence of Diffusion Modeling Literature in Marketing
Time Period
Research Areas 19605 1970s 1980s
Basic diffusion Formulation of relationship Unbundling of adopters
models between imitators and Definition of innovators/imitators
innovators over time Development of diffusion models from
Saturation effect individual-level adoption decisions
Parameter Estimation when data are Estimation when no prior data are
estimation available: available:
considerations Ordinary least squares Algebraic estimation procedures
estimation procedure Product/market attribute-based analogical
estimation procedures
Estimation when data are available:
Time-invariant parameter estimation
procedures (maximum likelihood,
nonlinear least squares)
Time-varying parameter estimation
procedures (Bayesian estimation,
feedback fitters!
Flexible diffusion Systeniatic (or random) variation in
models diffusion model parameters over time
Flexible diffusion patterns in terms of
timing and magnitude of peak of
adoption curve
Refinements and Dynamic diffusion models: Multigeneration models: timing and
extensions market saturation changes adoption of different generations of an
over time innovation
Multi-innovation diffusion Multistage diffusion models: effect of
models: other innovations negative word of mouth in the innovation
influence diffusion of an decision process
innovation Diffusion models with marketing mix '
Space/time diffusion variables: effect of price (linkage with
models: diffusion of an experience curves), advertising, personal
innovation occurs selling, distribution, and timing of new
simultaneously in space product introduction on diffusion patterns
and time Product/market attribute-based diffusion
Multistage diffusion models: models: effect of social system
adopters pass through a characteristics and perceived product <
series of stages in the attributes on diffusion patterns
innovation-decision Controlled diffusion models: effect of
process supply restrictions on diffusion patterns
Multiadoption diffusion models:
incorporation of repeat sales and
replacment sales in diffusion patterns
Competitive diffusion models: effect of
competitive actions in terms of pricing,
advertising, and number of brands on
diffusion patterns
Use of diffusion Forecasting Forecasting: problems in use Forecasting: problems in the use of
models of diffusion models for diffusion models for forecasting
forecasting Descriptive: testing of hypotheses related to
diffusion of innovations across countries,
effect of product/market attributes on
diffusion patterns, relationship between
innovation diffusion and market structure
factors such as the experience curve
phenomenon and proliferation of number
of brands
Normative: derivation of optimal pricing,
advertising, and timing strategies in
monopoly and oligopoly markets

fusion process up to time T* (Mahajan, Muller, and at time t is given by F(t). This basic premise states
Srivastava 1990). that the conditional probability of adoption at time t
The Bass model derives from a hazard function (the fraction of the population that will adopt at time
(the probability that an adoption will occur at time t t) is increasing in the fraction of the population that
given that it has not yet occurred). Thus, f(t)/ll - has already adopted. Therefore, the basic premise states
F(t)] ~ p + qF(t) is the basic premise underlying the that part of the adoption influence depends on imita-
Bass model. The density function of time to adoption tion or "learning" and part of it does not. The param-
is given by f(t) and the cumulative fraction of adopters eter q reflects that influence and the parameter p re-

New Product Diffusion Models in Marketing / 3


FIGURE 1
The Bass New Product Diffusion Model

A. Adoptions Due to External and Internal Influences in the Bass Model

c
ions.

/ X
ive Adc

/ Adoptions ^v
/ Due to \ ^
^ Internal Influence X^
-^ pm
E Adoptions Due to ^'^s^,,,^^
o External Influence ^ ^ ^ ^
o
Time

B. Anaiyical Structure of the Bass Model

Time
Time

tlects an influence that is independent of previous The first term. p[m - N(t)], in equation 1 represents
adoption. If q is zero, f(t) will follow the negative adoptions due to buyers who are not influenced in the
exponential distribution. If m is the potential number timing of their adoption by the number of people who
of ultimate adopters, the number of adopters at time already have bought the product. Bass (1969) referred
t will be mf(t) = n(t) and the cumulative number of to p as the "coefficient of innovation." The second
adopters at time t will be mF(t) = N(t). The basic term in equation 1, q/m N(t)[m - N(t)l. represents
premise of the Bass model can be manipulated, along adoptions due to buyers who are influenced by the
with the definitions just provided, to yield number of previous buyers. Bass (1969) referred to q
as the "coefficient of imitation." Note in equation 1
dN(t) q that at time t = 0, n(0) = pm.
^ N(t)[m - (1)
dt m Equation 1 is a first-order differential equation. It

4 / Journal of Marketing, January 1990


can be integrated to yield the S-shaped cumulative temal influence at any time in the diffusion process:
adopter distribution, N(t). Once N(t) is known, fur-
ther differentiation yields expressions for the noncu-
mulative number of adopters, n(t), and the time (T*)
and magnitude (n(t*) and N(t* of the peak of the N,(t) = m - In
adoption curve.' q
Given the basic structure of the Bass diffusion
model, three questions can be raised: where N|(t) represents adoptions due to extemal in-
fluence. Hence, adoptions due to intemal influence
How does the Bass model compare with the elassical
nonnal distribution model proposed by Rogers (1983)? are N2(t) = N(t) - N,(t).
Is the Bass model complete in capturing the commu-
Second, Mahajan, Muller, and Srivastava (1990)
nication structure between the two assumed distitict suggest that because one standard deviation away from
groups of innovators and imitators? the mean of the normal distribution represents its points
How can the Bass model, which captures diffusion at of inflection (the analytical logic underlying the cat-
the aggregate level, be linked to the adoption decisions egorization scheme proposed by Rogers), the same
at the individual level? analytical logic can be used to develop adopter cate-
gories for the Bass model. This scheme also yields
Recent developments that address these three ques- five adopter categories with the number of buyers (pm)
tions are discussed next. who initiate the Bass model being defined as inno-
vators. Examining the diffusion of personal com-
Unbundling of Adopters puters, Mahajan, Muller, and Srivastava (1990) show
how the adopter categories based on the Bass model
Rogers (1983, p. 244) has articulated that because of can be used to study differences among their profiles.
the interpersonal interaction, the adoption curve should
have a normal distribution. In fact, using two basic
statistical parameters of the normal distributionmean Innovators Versus Imitators
and standard deviationRogers has proposed an Irrespective of the term "Innovators" used to label
adopter categorization scheme dividing adopters into buyers who adopt because of extemal influence in the
five categories of Innovators, Early Adopters, Early Bass model, a question can be raised as to whether
Majority, Late Majority, and Laggards. the Bass model really captures the communication
To establish the linkage between the Bass model stmcture between the two assumed groups of adopters
and the classical normal distribution model. Mahajan, called "Innovators" and "Imitators." Emphasizing this
Muller. and Srivastava (1990) compared the two ap- argument. Tanny and Derzko (1988) suggest that the
proaches. In their comparison, they highlight two communication stmcture assumed in the Bass model
points. First, they argue that adopters termed "Inno- is not complete. They propose an extension of the Bass
vators" in the Bass model should not be called in- model wherein (I) potential adopters are divided into
novators because they are not necessarily the first two distinct groups of Potential Innovators (say m,)
adopters of an innovation, as defined by Rogers. Fol- and Potential Imitators (say ms), (2) both Potential In-
lowing Lekvall and Wahlbin (1973), they suggest that novators and Potential Imitators are influenced by the
because the Bass model captures the spread of an in- mass-media communication, and (3) only Potential
novation due to the mass media and interpersonal Imitators are influenced by word of mouth due to In-
communication channels, the Bass model coefficients novators and Imitators. To appreciate the linkage be-
p and q should be referred to as the coefficient of ex- tween the Bass mcKlel and its extension proposed by
ternal intluence and the coefficient of intemal influ- Tanny and Derzko (1988), consider the following rate
ence, respectively. (We use these labels in the rest of equations they proposed.
this anicle.) They also provide an explicit expression
to estimate the total number of adoptions due to ex-
Innovators; - N,(t)] (2)
dt
^These expressions are given by:
r 1 _ e'p-")" g-(p*q""|

N(t) = m n(t) = m Imitators:


1+3, (p + q e dt
(3)
n(T*) = (p + qr, N(T*) =
4q Tf we assume that pi = P2 = p (i e., the coefficient
of extemal influence is the same for both groups), the
T*= - total adoptions can be represented by summing the two

New Product Diffusion Models in Marketing / 5


rate equations (and noting that + mj = m and N(t) and Eliashberg (1989), and Lattin and Roberts (1989)
= N,(t) + N2(t)). to develop diffusion models by specifying adoption
decisions at the individual level. In these mode!s one
dN(t)
= plm, , - N,(t) - assumes that, at any time t. a potential adopter's util-
dt ity for an innovation is based on his uncertain per-
ception of the innovation's performance, value, or
benefits. The potential adopter's uncertain perceptions
= p[m - N(t)] (4)
about the innovation, however, change over time as
Note that equation 4 is identical to the Bass model, he learns more about the innovation from extemal
equation 1, except for the fact that equation 4 con- sources (e.g.. advertising) or intemal sources (e.g.,
siders the word-of-mouth influence on the potential word of mouth). Therefore, because of this leaming,
adopters who are Potential Imitators rather than on all whenever his utility for the innovation becomes greater
of the potential adopters as is done in the Bass model. than the status quo (he is better off with the innova-
In their empirical work on some of the consumer du- tion), he adopts the innovation. Aggregation across
rable products analyzed by Bass (1969), Tanny and the various potential adopters yields the cumulative
Derzko (1988) did not fmd satisfactory results for their adoption curve.
proposed extension (the mode! either reduced to the Table 2 contrasts the various individual-level dif-
Bass model or it failed to provide estimates for the fusion models on several dimensions. Of all the models
additional model coefficients). These empirical results compared in Table 2, only three provide explicit func-
are not surprising because as the diffusion process tions for aggregate diffusion models. Depending on
progresses, the population of potential adopters mostly the assumptions made about the distribution of param-
comprises Potential Imitators, justifying the parsi- eters that measure heterogeneity across individuals,
monious model suggested by Bass. the model by Chatterjee and Bliashberg (1989) yields
several basic diffusion models. If risk aversion across
Diffusion Models From Individual Adoption potential adopters is assumed to follow a negative ex-
Decisions '. ' ponential distribution, the model by Oren and Schwartz
A key aspect of the Bass mode! is that it addresses (1988) reduces to the Mansfield model. If the per-
the market in the aggregate. The typical variable mea- ceived differences in the potential benefits of the product
sured is the number of adopters who purchase the across potential adopters are assumed to follow a uni-
product by a certain time t. The emphasis is on the form distribution, Lattin and Roberts (1989) suggest
total market response rather than an individual cus- the following model.
tomer. This approach is convenient in practical terms
but it raises the following issue: Can the diffusion model N(t) = a + bN(t- 1) - (5)
be built by aggregating demand from consumers who c + N(t - 1)
behave in a neoclassical microeconomic way? That is,
assume that potential adopters are smart and are not where a. b, c, and d are constants. Using the data on
just carriers of information. They therefore maximize several consumer durable products, they indicate that
some objective function such as expected utility or their mode! provides a better fit to the data than the
benefit from the product, taking into account the un- Bass model. Their model contains four parameters,
certainty associated with their understanding of its at- however (vs. three in the Bass model) and, unlike the
tributes, its price, pressure from other adopters to adopt Bass model, it does not provide N(t) as an explicit
it, and their own budget. Because the decision to adopt function of time, which limits its long-term forecast-
the innovation is individual-specific, all potential ing ability.
adopters do not have the same probability of adopting
the product in a given time period. !s it possib!e to
develop the adoption curve at the aggregate market Parameter Estimation
!evel, given the heterogeneity among potentia! adop- Considerations
ters in terms of their probability of adopting the prod- The use of the Bass mode! for forecasting the diffu-
uct at any time t? Development of a model that an- sion of an innovation requires the estimation of three
swers this question can potentially assist in ascertaining parameters: the coefficient of extemal influence (p),
the effect of marketing mix and other variables on de- the coefficient of intemal influence (q), and the mar-
mand for the product via their effect on individual ket potential (m). Though the estimate for the market
consumers. potential of a new product can be derived from the
In recent years, attempts have been made by Hiebert diffusion time-series data, recent applications of dif-
(1974), Stoneman (1981), Feder and O'Mara (1982), fusion models have obtained better forecasting results
Jensen (1982), Oren and Schwartz (1988), Chatterjee by using exogenous sources of information (such as

6 / Journal of Marketing, January 1990


TABLE 2
Characteristics of Diffusion Models Based on Individual Adoption Decisions
Chatterjee
Feder and Oren and and Lattin and
HIebert Stoneman O'Mara Jensen Schwart2 Eliashberg Roberts
(1974) (1981) (1982) (1982) (1988) (1989) (1989)
l^ature of Innovation High yield- New tech- New tech- Exogenously Any new Durable Durable
Studied ing seed va- nology (in- nology (ag- developed product goods goods
rieties (agri- dustrial) ricultural) innovation that is po-
cultural) (industrial) tential sub- f
stitute for
current
product
Perceptions Net income Return Profit Success rate Perfor- Benefit
Type of uncertain
attribute/benefit mance
Perceptual uncer- No specific Normal dis- Normal dis- Discrete: bi- Beta distri- Normal dis- Normal dis-
tainty model (dis- model: tribution tribution nary (inno- bution tribution tribution
tributional as- uncertainty vation is
sumption) due to im- profitable or 1
perfect infor- unprofita-
mation ble; uncer-
about yield tainty cap-
response to tured via
inputs (e.g., subjective
fertilizer) probability
of innova- , il
tion being
profitable)
Preference Structure
Attributels) incorpo- Net income Returns Profit Expected re- Success Perfor- Benefit
rated in utility from new turn rate mance,
function and old price
technolo-
gies, adjust-
ment costs
Assumption about No specific Risk averse Risk neutral Risk neutral Risk averse Risk averse Risk averse
attitude toward assumption:
risk different atti-
tudes con-
sidered
Adoption Decision Maximize Maximize Expected Expected re- Expected Expected Expected
Rule expected utility to profit from turn from utility for utility for utility for
utility (par- determine new tech- adoption is new prod- new prod- new prod-
tial adoption proportion nology ex- greater than uct exceeds uct exceeds uct exceeds
of innova- of output ceeds profit expected expected expected expected
tion possi- produced from cur- value of utility for utility for utility for
ble) on new rent tech- continuing current status quo status quo
technology nology waiting for product
additional
information
Learning Bayesian Bayesian Bayesian Bayesian Bayesian
Not explicit: Bayesian
Learning model
learning re-
duces uncer-
Source of informa- tainty Previous Internal External Internal Both inter- Internal
tion experience (previous (previous nal and ex- (previous
with new adopters) adopters) ternal adopters)
technology
Aggregation No aggrega- Not applica- Mean of ini- Initial sub- Risk aver- Initial per- Difference
Heterogeneity
rion on whichcrite-
ag- tion ble: consid- tial percep- jective prob- sion param- ceptions in mean of
gregation is done ers only in- tions about ability of in- eter (note: (both ex- perceptions
across potential trafirm profitability novation model as- pectation about bene-
adopters diffusion being profit- sumes con- and degree fit from sta-
able stant flow of uncer- tus quo
of con- tainty); per-
sumers so ceived reli-
that aggre- ability of
gation informa-
yields mar- tion; risk
ket share aversion
rather than parameter;
cumulative price/per-
penetration) formance
tradeoff

New Product Diffusion Models in Marketing / 7


market surveys, secondary sources, management guess the adoption level for the first time period, how
judgments, or other analytical models) for estimating does one guess the p + q value? A record of the pa-
m (see, e.g.. Heeler and Hustad 1980; Mesak and rameter values of earlier new products may provide a
Mikhail 1988; Oliver 1987; Souder and Quaddus 1982; basis, by analogy, for guessing p + q. From an anal-
Teotia and Raju 1986). ysis of the diffusion pattems of several products,
In the 1980s, several estimation procedures were Lawrence and Lawton (1981), for example, recom-
proposed to estimate the Bass model parameters {see mend using a value of .66 for industrial product in-
Table 1). Meta-analyzing the results of 15 such dif- novations and a value of .50 for consumer product
fusion studies. Sultan, Farley, and Lehmann (1990) innovations (for an application of this procedure to
report average values of .03 and .38 for the coeffi- consumer durable products, see DeKIuyver 1982). Such
cients of external influence and intemal influence, re- a recommendation may be too general, however, and
spectively. Their analyses further suggest that the val- does not consider indosyncratic characteristics of a
ues of these coefficients are influenced by the type of particular diffusion situation. Thomas (1985) there-
estimation procedure used to estimate them. For a fore has recommended that, for a new product under
practitioner, the main question is which of the several consideration, the parameters can be estimated by tak-
estimation procedures should be used and why. The ing a weighted sum of the parameters of analogous
answer to this question depends partially on the amount products where weights are determined by establish-
of data available to estimate these parameters. We re- ing the similarity/dissimilarity relationships between
view estimation procedures that are designed to de- the new product and the various analogous products
velop estimates both in the absence of and in the pres- on five bases of comparison: environmental situation,
ence of time-series diffusion data. (A brief analytical market structure, buyer behavior, marketing mix
description of these procedures is given in an appen- strategy, and characteristics of innovation itself. In fact,
dix in the unabridged version of this article.) to consider idiosyncratic characteristics of a new product
in a particular social system, recent analogical ap-
No Prior Data Available proaches estimate its coefficients of extemal influence
and intemal influence from regression models that ex-
If no data are available, parameter estimates can be press a historical empirical relationship between these
obtained by using either management judgments or the coefficients and product or market attributes of sev-
diffusion history of analogous products. eral current products. Once this relationship has been
One procedure that exclusively uses management established, the values for the coefficients of a new
judgments to estimate the diffusion parameters is an product can be estimated by knowing its characteris-
algebraic estimation procedure suggested by Mahajan tics. Four such approaches for the Bass model have
and Sharma (1986). The implementation of this pro- been suggested by Srivastava et al. (1985), Gatignon,
cedure requires information from managers on three Eliashberg, and Robertson (1989), Sultan, Farley, and
items: (1) the market size (m), (2) the time of the peak Lehmann (1990), and Montgomery and Srinivasan
of the noncumulative adoption curve, and (3) the (1989).
adoption level at the peak time (n*). That is, the key
information required by the estimation procedure is in studying parameter estimates of the Bass mtxlel,
the peak of the noncumulative adoption curve. Know- Lawrence and ilawton (1981) found that p + q ranged
ing this information, one can estimate the coefficients from .3 to .7 over several innovations. They note that
of extemal influence and intemal influence. Though first year sales, Sj. can be expressed as m(l - e"'""**)/
the algebraic estimation procedure has been imple- [1 + (q/p)e'"''*^'^'l and hence q/p can be expres.sed as
mented in actual applications by some firms (e.g.. In- [m(l - e'P^"') - S.l/S.e'P^"*. It is possible to use
stitute for the Future), Bass (1986) has questioned its judgment in guessing m and Si. In strategic terms,
desirability, suggesting that one of the key outputs of probably the most critical forecast deriving from the
the diffusion model is the prediction of the timing and Bass model is the time of peak of adoptions, T*. This
magnitude of the peak. Therefore, if one can guess value is given by 11/(p + q)]Ln(q/p). Because p + q
these items, there is no need to estimate model pa- varies over a relatively narrow range and has a mode
rameters. around ,5, for consumer products, guesses of p + q,
An alternative algebraic estimation procedure has m, and S, may provide good estimates of T*. Lawrence
been suggested by Lawrence and Lawton (1981). This and Lawton (1981, p. 535) report good results with
procedure also involves obtaining information from this method.
managers on three items: (I) the potential market size
(m), (2) the number of adoptions in the fu-st time pe- Availability of Data
riod, and (3) an estimate of the sum of the coefficients Because the Bass model contains three parameters (p,
of extemal influence and intemal influence, that is, q, and m), adoption data for a minimum of three time
the p + q value. Though managers may be able to periods are required to estimate these parameters. Re-

8 / Journal of Marketing, January 1990


cent empirical studies, however, have documented that directly from the solution of the differential equation
estimates of these parameters, and hence the adoption specification of the Bass model. This procedure also
forecasts, are sensitive to the number of datapoints has limitations, however. For example, Srinivasan and
used to estimate them (see, e.g., Hyman 1988; Tigert Mason (1986) point out that because the maximum
and Farivar 1981). In fact, these studies suggest that likelihood procedure considers only sampling errors
stable and robust parameter estimates for the Bass model and ignores all other errors such as the effects of ex-
are obtained only if the data under consideration in- cluded marketing variables that influence the diffu-
clude the peak of the noncumulative adoption curve sion process, it underestimates the standard errors of
(Heeler and Hustad 1980; Srinivasan and Mason 1986). the estimated parameters, resulting in possible wrong
Because of these concerns, attempts have been made inferences about the statistical significance of the pa-
in recent years to develop estimation procedures that rameters. To overcome this shortcoming, they suggest
update parameter estimates as additional data become a formulation by means of which estimates of p, q,
available after the initiation of the diffusion process. and m can be obtained by using any appropriate non-
These procedures include Bayesian estimation pro- linear regression package (a similar formulation has
cedures and adaptive filtering approaches that provide been suggested by Jain and Rao 1989). This formu-
time-varying parameter estimates. lation aiso uses the solution to the differential equa-
tion specification of the Bass model for parameter es-
Time-invariant estimation procedures. One of the timation.
first procedures suggested to estimate the diffusion
From the preceding descriptions, it is clear that
parameters is the ordinary least squares (OLS) pro-
both the maximum likelihood and the nonlinear esti-
cedure proposed by Bass. The OLS procedure in-
mation procedures offer better choices than the OLS
volves estimation of the parameters by taking the dis-
procedure. An empirical comparison of these esti-
crete or regression analog of the differential equation
mation procedures (along with the algebraic estima-
formulation of the Bass model (i.e., equation 1). In
tion procedure suggested by Mahajan and Sharma 1986)
fact, rearrangement of equation 1 yields:
by Mahajan, Mason, and Srinivasan (1986) suggests
an overall superiority of the nonlinear estimation pro-
N(t -I- 1) - N(t) = pm -I- (q - p)N(t) cedure, but the maximum likelihood procedure per-
m forms equally well when survey-type diffusion data
n{t + 1) = a, + + (6) are used to estimate the parameters because of the
dominance of sampling errors (Mahajan, Mason, and
where aj = pm, a2 = q ~ P- ^^^ ^i = "Q/m- That Srinivasan 1986; Srinivasan and Mason 1986).
is, regression analysis is used to estimate a j , a2, and
03 in equation 6. Once a's are known, p, q, and m Parameter estimation for diffusion models is pri-
can be estimated. If one has reason to believe that all marily of historical interest; by the time sutTicient ob-
datapoints in the diffusion time series should not have servations have developed for reliable estimation, it
an equal weighting in the least squares procedure, dis- is too late to use the estimates for forecasting pur-
counted least squares can be used for estimating a's poses. The estimates can be used for model testing
(for an application of discounted least squares to the and for comparison across products. Considered in such
discrete analog of the Bass model, see Young and Ord a context, the methods often yield estimates that do
1985). not differ greatly.
The OLS procedure, however, has three short- Time-varying estimation procedures. These pro-
comings (Schmittlein and Mahajan 1982): cedures are designed to update parameter estimates as
Because of the likely mukicollinearity between inde- new data become available.^ The updating of param-
pendent variables in equation 6, that is, N(t) and N^(t),
the procedure may yield parameter estimates that are *rhe idea ihai coefficients of a market response model should change
unstable or have wrong signs. over time is not new in marketing. In fact, several iheoreiical ap-
The procedure does not directly provide standard errors proaches ihal assisi in developing market response models when model
for the estimated parameters p, q, and m (and. hence, coefficicnls have a time-varying behavior have been applied and doc-
umented in Ihe marketing literature (see, e.g., Mahajan, Bretschneider,
statistical significance of these estimates cannot be as- and Bradford 1980; Witdt and Winer 1978). Two such approaches
sessed). also have been examined in the context of diffusion models: the sys-
There is a time-interval bias because discrete time-series tematic parameter variation methods and the random coefficient mcth-
data are used for estimating a continuous model (i.e., IX1.S. The systematic parameter variations assume a priori the time
path of the model coefficients. These methods have generated a new
the solution of the differential equation specification of set of diffusion models termed 'flexible diffusion models" (Mahajan
the Bass model). and Peterson 1985) that are reviewed here.
In the random coefficient methods, the random parameters are as-
To overcome these shortcomings, Schmittlein and sumed to constitute a sample from a common multivariate distribution
Mahajan (1982) have suggested a maximum hkeh- with an estimated mean and variance-covariance structure. Following
hood estimation procedure to estimate the parameters Karmeshu and Pathria (1980a. b), Eliashberg, Tapiero. and Wind (1987)

New Product Diffusion Models in Marketing / 9


eters is achieved either with the Bayes procedure or dinary least squares procedure.*
feedback filters.
Such procedures have been applied in various dif- Flexible Diffusion Models
fusion settings by Sultan, Farley, and Lehmann (1990),
Lenk and Rao (1989), and Bretschneider and Mahajan The basic structure of a diffusion model can be char-
(1980). All of these procedures have two elements in acterized in terms of two mathematical properties, point
common: (1) they require an initial estimate of the of inflection and symmetry. The point of inflection on
diffusion model parameters before the diffusion data a diffusion curve occurs when the maximum rate of
become available and (2) they specify an updating for- diffusion is reached. If the diffusion pattem after the
mula to upgrade the initial estimates as additional dif- point of inflection is the mirror image of the diffusion
fusion data become available. pattem before the point of inflection, the diffusion curve
is characterized as being symmetric. For example, as
In the Bayesian estimation procedure advocated depicted in Figure IB, the adopter distribution for the
by Sultan. Farley, and Lehmann (1990), statistical re- Bass model peaks at time T*, which is the point of
sults of their meta-analysis study are used to develop inflection of the S-shaped cumulative adoption curve,
initial estimates for the coefficients of extemal influ- and is symmetric with respect to time around the peak
ence and intemal influence for a new product. For each time T* up to time 2T*. Furthermore, the Bass model
of these two coefficients, the procedure updates the assumes that the maximum penetration rate cannot oc-
initial estimates by taking a weighted sum of its two cur after the product has captured 50% of the market
values, the initial estimate and the estimate developed potential. In practice as well as in theory, the maxi-
from the actual data (by using any procedure such as mum rate of diffusion of an innovation should be able
the nonlinear estimation procedure of Srinivasan and to occur at any time during the diffusion process. Ad-
Mason 1986). The weights in the updating formula ditionally, diffusion patterns can be expected to be
are expressed as a function of the variation in the pa- nonsymmetric as well as symmetric.
rameter estimates from the actual data so that as these
time-varying estimates stabilize, the weight for the Easingwood, Mahajan, and Muller (1983) have
initial estimate based on the meta-analysis goes to zero. suggested that flexibility can be achieved in the dif-
A Bayesian estimation procedure also has been re- fusion models by recognizing an important underlying
ported by Lenk and Rao (1989). Their procedure ex- assumption. In most of the diffusion models, the im-
plicitly considers the between-product and within- pact of the word of mouth on potential adopters is
product variations in establishing initial estimates for assumed to remain constant throughout the diffusion
the new product. span. This assumption is tenuous because, for most
innovations, the word of mouth is likely to increase,
An altemative approach to updating the diffusion
decrease, or remain constant over time (Hemes 1976).
model parameters for the Bass model has been dem-
Easingwood. Mahajan, and Muller (1983) suggest that
onstrated by Bretschneider and Mahajan (1980). It es-
the time-varying nature of the word-of-mouth effect
timates the time-varying values of the Bass model pa-
can be incorporated in the Bass model by specifying
rameters by updating the regression coefficients in the
the coefficient of intemal influence as systematically
discrete analog of the Bass model, equation 6. The
varying over time as a fimction of penetration level.
updating formula is based on a feedback filter sug-
That is,
gested by Carbone and Longini (1977). This feedback
filter estimates an adjustment to the current values of
parameters at time t based on the error between the w(t) = m
actual and the predicted values of the noncumulative
number of adopters at time t. Though the procedure where a is a constant and w(t) is the time-varying
provides time-varying estimates for the diffusion model coefficient of extemal influence. Substitution of equa-
coefficients, it has the same shortcomings as the or- tion 7 into the Bass model, equation 1, yields the won-
niform-influence (NUI) model suggested by those
authors (in terms of the cumulative fraction of adop-
explored the applicability of these methods to the Bass ditfusion inodel. ters):
They consider the coefficients of innovation (p) and imitation (q) in
the Ba.ss model as stochastic and hence time-varying by assuming that dF(t)
p = p + ep(t) and q = q + e,,(t), where p and q denote constant means (8)
and Cp and e, denote normally distributed error ierm.s surrounding those dt
means such that their means are zero and the variances are constant.
Their empirical results suggest that their stochastic tomiulation of the *For an application of this approach to the diffusion of robotics in
Bass model does as well as the deterministic version of the Bass model. the State of New York, see BreLschneider and Bozcman (1986). Other
There are other types of stochastic diffusion mixlels, but they are not feedback filters also can be used to estimate time-varying diffusion
included in our review. Reviews of such models are given by parameters. For example, the use of the Kalman filter to estimate the
Bartholomew (1982), Elii^hberg and Chatterjee (1986), and Boker time-varying coefficients for the Mansfield model has been reported
(1987). by Meade (1985).

10 / Journal of Marketing, January 1990


where F(t) = N(t)/m and a + 1 ^ 6. When p = 0 Refinements and Extensions of the
(i.e., coefficient of extemal influence is zero), equa- Bass Diffusion Model
tion 8 or 9 yields a flexible extension of the Mansfield
model termed on.symmetric responding /ogistic Several assumptions underlie the Bass model. Most
(NSRL) by Easingwood, Mahajan, and Muller (1981). are simplifying assumptions that provide a parsimon-
An interesting alternative interpretation of the NSRL ious analytical representation of the diffusion process.
model in terms of experience curve and price elastic- However, recognition of these assumptions is impor-
ity is provided by Sharp (1984). tant to properly understand and interpret the dynamics
In addition to the NUI and NSRL models. Table of innovation diffusion captured by the Bass model.
3 reports characteristics of nine other diffusion models. Table 1 lists several of these assumptions that have
The following observations are warranted from this been of concem to diffusion modelers in the 1970s
table. and 1980s. Nine of these assumptions warrant atten-^
In addition to the NUI and NSRL models, only two tion.
models offer complete flexibility in capturing diffusion
pattems (i.e.. point of infiection can occur from 0% to Market potential of the new product remains con-
1(X)% penetration and the diffusion pattems can be sym-
metric or nonsymnnetric). These are the models pro- stant over time. The Bass model assumes that the
posed by Von Bertalanffy (1957) (an identical model market potential (m) of a new product is determined
has been proposed by Nelder 1962) and Bewley and at the time of introduction and remains unchanged over
Fiebig (1988). its entire life (Kalish 1985; Mahajan and Peterson 1978;
Like the NUI and NSRL models proposed by Easing- Sharif and Ramanathan 1981). Theoretically, there is
wood. Mahajan, and Muller (1981. 1983), the model no rationale for a static potential adopter population.
by Von Bertalanffy expresses the coefficient of intemal
influence as systematically changing over time as a
Instead, a potential adopter population continuously
function of penetration level, that is. in flux is to be expected.
Extensions of the Bass model that address this as-
sumption have attempted to relax it by specifying the
market potential as a function of relevant exogenous
where <|) is a constant. Unlike the NUI and NSRL models, and endogenous variablescontrollable as well as
the differential equation used to specify the diffusion
process by the Von Bertalanffy model has a closed-form uncontrollablethat affect the market potential. Ex-
solution enabling one to represent cumulative adoption amining the diffusion of a durable product, Kalish
as an explicit function of time. This model, however, (1985), for example, specified the dynamics of the
assumes that the word-of-mouth effect decreases over market potential as a function of price of the product
time. The NUI and NSRL models can accommodate the and reduction of uncertainty associated with the prod-
word-of mouth effect that increases, decreases, or re-
mains constant over time. uct with its increased adoption. Assuming full product
In comparison with the models suggested by Easingwood,
awareness in the population, he specified
Mahajan. and Muller(1981. 1983) and Von Bertalanffy
(1957), the FLOG (/lexible /ogistic growth) model sug-
gested by Bewley and Fiebig (1988) expresses the sys- m(t) = mo exp -dP(t) (H)
tematic variation in the coefficient of intemal influence N(t)
as a function of time, that is. a -I-

where k and |i are constants. The FLOG model offers


a closed-form solution and, like the NUI and NSRL where a and d are constants, nv, is the size of the mar-
models, can accommodate the time-varying word-of- ket potential at the time of product introduction, P(t)
mouth effect. is the product price, and the term [(a + l)/(a + N(t)/
Though some evidence suggests that, in compar- mo)] represents the effect of market penetration in in-
ison with the basic diffusion models (such as the Bass creasing the size of market potential due to the word-
model), the flexible models provide a better fit to dif- of-mouth effect. Other applications have represented
fusion data (see Easingwood 1987, 1988; Lattin and the market potential as a function of growth in the
Roberts 1989; McGowan 1986; Rao 1985), this ad- number of households (Mahajan and Peterson 1978),
vantage is obtained by incorporating additional pa- population growth (Sharif and Ramanathan 1981),
rameters. Hence these models are more difficult to use product profitability (Lackman 1978), price (Chow
in the absence of diffusion time-series data (using the 1967; Jain and Rao 1989; Kamakura and Balasubra-
historical data on existing products, however, Easing- manian 1988), growth in Ihe number of retailers mak-
wood 1989 has demonstrated how the NUI model can ing the product available to potential customers (Jones
be used to develop analogical parameter estimates for and Ritz 1987), and income distribution, price, and
a new product). product uncertainty (Horsky 1990).

New Product Diffusion Models in Marketing / 1 1


TABLE 3
Flexible Diffusion Models
Model Equation Point of
(dF/ = ) Model Solution Inflection Coefficient of Illustrated Reported
Model dt (F= ) Symmetry' Internal Influence Applications
1. Bass (1969)" (p + qF)(1 ~ F) .0-.5 NS Constant Consumer durable
goods; retail service,
agricultural,
education, and
industrial
innovations;
electronics,
photographic
products, industrial
processes
2. Gompertz .37 NS Constant Consumer durable
curve*" (see goods, agricultural
Hendry 1972; innovations
Dixon 1980)
3. Mansfield qF(1 - F) .5 Constant Industrial, high
(1961) technology, and
1+
administrative
innovations
4. Floyd (1962) qRl - F)= NS Decreasing to
zero Industrial innovations
5. Sharif and qF(1 - F)' .33-.5 S or NS Constant or
Kabir (1976)" 1 - F(1 - a) decreasing to zero Industrial innovations
6. Jeuland (P + qF)(1 - F)'^^ .0-.5 S or NS Constant or Consumer durable
decreasing to zero goods
7. Nonuniform .0-1.0 S or NS increasing, Consumer durable,
influence (NUI) decreasing, or retail service, and
(Easingwood, (p + qF')(1 - F) constant education
Mahajan, and innovations
Muller 1983)
Nonsymmetric .0-1.0 S or NS Increasing, Medical innovations
responding decreasing, or
logistic (NSRL, constant
qF'd - F)
p = 0 in NUI)
(Easingwood,
Mahajan, and
Muller 1981)
8. Nelder*" (1962; qF(1 - F*) .0-1.0 S or NS Decreasing to a Agricultural
see McGowan constant innovations
1986)
Von .0-1.0 S or NS Decreasing to a
Bertalanffy" p(1 constant
1 -
(1957; see
Richards 1959)
9. Stanford .0-.5 NS Decreasing to Energy-efficient
Research' ^F(1 zero innovations
Institute (e.g.,
Teotia and Raju
1986)
10. Flexible logistic' .0-1.0 S or NS Increasing, Telecommunication
growth (FLOG; decreasing, or innovations
(Bewley and constant
Fiebig 1988)
'S = symmetric, NS = nonsymmetric,
"The model is symmetric around the peak time T" up to 2T*.
^c is a constant
^ S ff S 1.
y 2r 0 , "
*The mode! suggested by Nelder (1962) is identical to the model originBlly suggested by Von Bertalanffy (1957). The equivalence between the two
can be shown by substituting * - fl - 1 in the Von Bertalanffy model.
c is a constant; model reduces to Mansfield model for (^ = 1 and the Gompertz curve as * approaches zero.
"c is a constant; fl s 0; model reduces to Mansfield model when fl = 2 and the Gompertz curve as fi approaches 1.
The model is not invariant to the choice of time scale. A linear transformation of tinne t is required to make it time-scale independent. T* is time of
50% penetration. See Bewley and Fiebig (1988).
'li and k are constants and t(^t,k) = {Id + kt)"-"")" - 1}/(i, ji. ?* 0, k ?* 0, t((i..k) = (I/W log (1 + kt), n = 0, k s* 0, t(M.,k) = (e''' - l ) / n , ;x # 0, k = 0,
t(|i,k) = t, n = 0, k = 0.

12/Journal of Marketing, January 1990


Diffusion of an innovation is independent of all second generation product, S| and S2 are their ship-
other innovations. The Bass model assumes that the ments at time t, and F,(t) and F2(t) are fractions of
adoption of an innovation does not complement, sub- adoptions for each generation and are given by the
stitute for, detract from, or enhance the adoption of Bass model (solution of equation I). In equations 12
any other innovation (and vice versa) (Peterson and and 13, the term m|Fi(t)F2(t T2) represents the can-
Mahajan 1978). In reality, however, an innovation is nibalization or substitution effect.
not introduced into a vacuum nor does it exist in iso-
lation. Other innovations are present in the market- The geographic boundaries of the social system do
place and may have an influence (positive or negative) not change over the diffusion process. Despite the fact
on ils diffusion. Consideration of simultaneous dif- that the diffusion of an innovation occurs simulta-
fusion of multiple innovations is especially critical if neously in space and time, research on these two di-
the diffusion of one innovation is contingent upon the mensions of diffusion seldom has been integrated in
diffusion of another innovation (e.g., compact disc a marketing context. For example, the new product
software and compact disc hardware) or if the diffu- rollout is clearly a popular option used by many firms
sion of one innovation complements the diffusion of to diffuse their products from market to market over
another innovation (e.g., washers and dryers). time (in both the national and the intemational mar-
kets). Such a new-product launch strategy enables a
Following the contingent diffusion model sug- firm to capitalize on word-of-mouth communication,
gested by Peterson and Mahajan (1978), Bayus (1987), referred to as the "neighborhood effect" (Brown 1981;
for example, conducted an empirical study examining Gore and Lavaraj 1987), across markets. Simulta-
the diffusion dependence between compact disc soft- neous assessment of market penetration within a mar-
ware and compact disc hardware. In the contingent ket and across markets therefore is necessary.
diffusion model, the market potential of the dependent
One application that addresses diffusion from a joint
product is contingent upon the diffusion of the pri-
space and time perspective has been reported by
mary product. That is, in the Bass model represen-
Mahajan and Peterson (1979). In examining the adop-
tation of its growth, equation 1, its market potential
tion of tractors in 25 states in the central agricultural
is specified as (N,(t) - N2(t)) where N,(t) is the cu-
production region of the United States for the period
mulative number of adopters of the primary product
1920-1964, they extend the Bass model by assuming
(e.g., compact disc hardware) and N2(t) is the cu-
that (1) the innovation is introduced initially in one
mulative number of adopters of the contingent product
market and (2) the relative number of total adoptions
(e.g., compact disc software).
is greater in markets that are closest to the market of
Nature of an innovation does not change over time. innovation orgination (i.e., the neighborhood effect
Manufacturers of high technology products usually diminishes with increased distance from the market of
achieve diffusion in the marketplace by offering suc- innovation orgination, decreasing the size of market
cessive generations of an innovation. Each generation potential across markets).
is positioned to be better than its predecessors on rel-
evant product attributes. Assessment of market pen- The diffusion process is binary. The Bass model
etration therefore is critical for successive generations assumes that potential adopters of an innovation either
of a high technology product. In addition to creating adopt or do not adopt the innovation. As a conse-
its own demand, each generation of the product can- quence of this assumption, the Bass model does not
nibalizes the diffusion of its predecessors. The im- take into account stages in the adoption process (e.g.,
piirtant application of diffusion models for assessing awareness, knowledge, etc.). Some of the attempts to
technological substitution has been demonstrated by extend the two-stage models to incorporate the mul-
Norton and Bass (1987) for the growth of two basic tistage (or polynomial) nature of the diffusion process
types of integrated circuits, memory and logic cir- include models by Midgley (1976), Dodson and Muller
cuits. If T2 represents the time of the introduction of (1978). Sharif and Ramanathan (1982), Mahajan,
the second generation, Norton and Bass suggest that Muller, and Kerin (1984), and Kalish (1985). Most
the word-of-mouth effect within each generation and of these extensions tend to characterize stages in which
substitution effects across successive generations can positive, negative, or neutral information is commu-
be represented by the following extension of the Bass nicated about the prtxiuct. The implementation of these
model. models is rather cumbersome as they require detailed
information about the customer flow across the var-
S,(t) = m,F,(t) - m,F,(t)F2(t - T^) (12) ious stages. In empirical applications, the developers
of these models therefore either collapse the various
S^ii) = m2F2(t - T2) + m,F,(t)F2(t - T^) (13) stages (Kalish 1985 assumes full product awareness),
where equation 12 is the diffusion equation for the attempt to derive the population in various stages by
first generation product and equation 13 represents the decomposing the time-series diffusion data (Midgley

New Product Diffusion Models in Marketing/ 13


1976; Sharif and Ramanathan 1982) with too many a good fit to their diffusion data, supporting their ar-
parameters to be estimated with the limited available guments about incorporation of the cumulative effect
data (Silver 1984), or trace the intiovation diffusion of advertising into the coefficient of imitation.
with the panel data (Mahajan. Muller, and Kerin 1984; The question of the inclusion of price in the Bass
Mahajan, Muller, and Sharma 1984). model intrigued diffusion analysts in the 1970s and
1980s. Examining the diffusion of a (unmentioned)
Diffusion of an innovation is not influenced by durable product, Kalish (1985) suggested that price
marketing strategies. Since the pioneering work of affects the market potential of a product (see equation
Robinson and Lakhani (1975) that incorporated the 11). However, recent empirical studies by Kamakura
impact of price in the Bass model, several efforts have and Balasubramanian (1988) and Jain and Rao (1989),
been made to study systematically the impact of mar- employing data on several consumer durable prod-
keting mix variables such as price, advertising, pro- ucts, show that price affects the rate of diffusion (via
motion and personal selling, and distribution on prod- the coefficients of external influence and internal in-
uct growth (efforts related to price and advertising are fluence) rather than the market potential.
reviewed extensively by Kalish and Sen 1986). As the
Bass mcxlel contains three parameters (coefficients of Product and market characteristics do not influ-
external influence and internal influence, and the mar- ence diffusion patterns. The Bass model does not con-
ket potential), the impact of marketing mix variables sider explicitly the impact of product and market char-
has been incorporated into the Bass model by repre- acteristics on diffusion patterns. Empirical studies
senting these parameters as a function of relevant vari- reported in the innovation diffusion literature, how-
ables. Attempts have been made to represent the mar- ever, have found that product and market character-
ket potential as a function of price (e.g., Kalish 1983, istics have a substantial impact on innovation diffu-
1985) and distribution growth (Jones and Ritz 1987). sion patterns (Rogers 1983; Tomatzky and Klein 1982).
Other attempts to incorporate marketing mix variables Three empirical studies (Gatignon, Eliashberg, and
have been concerned with representing the coeffi- Robertson 1989; Kalish and Lilien 1986a; Srivastava
cients of external influence and internal influence as et al. 1985) have attempted to incorporate product and
a function of diffusion-influencing variables. Though market characteristics into the Bass model by express-
analytically very elegant, most of these modeling ef- ing the coefficients of external influence and/or in-
forts lack empirical validation (Mahajan and Wind ternal influence as a function of these characteristics.
1986b). However, they can be useful in establishing Whereas Srivastava et al. (1985) and Kaiish and Lilien
working hypotheses to examine the likely impact of (1986a) examine the impact of product characteristics
marketing mix variables on innovation diffusion. As on diffusion patterns, Gatignon, Eliashberg, and Rob-
these hypotheses are presented in the next section, we ertson (1989) study the impact of market character-
briefly comment here on studies that have provided istics on the diffusion of a product across markets.
some empirical support for their extensions. Only Kalish and Lilien (1986a), however, explicitly
consider the changing consumer perceptions of the
Two empirical studies by Horsky and Simon (1983) product characteristics as the product is accepted over
and Simon and Sebastian (1987), respectively, have time. They define the coefficient of imitation as
examined the impact of advertising on innovation dif- changing over time due to changes in the product
fusion. Studying the diffusion of a new banking ser- characteristics.
vice, Horsky and Simon argue that because advertis-
ing provides infonnation to innovators, the coefficient There are no supply restrictions. The Bass model
of external influence in the Bass model should be rep- is a demand model. If the demand for a product can-
resented as a function of advertising expenditures (with not be met because of supply restrictions, such as the
diminishing returns). Their empirical results provided unavailability of the product due to limitations on pro-
a gotni fit to their diffusion data, supporting their ar- duction capacity or difficulties in setting up distribu-
gument. Studying the diffusion of new telephones in tion systems, the excess unmet demand is likely to
West Germany, Simon and Sebastian suggest that, generate a waiting line of potential adopters (Simon
though advertising may influence innovators (and hence and Sebastian 1987). In such a situation, the adopter
the coefficient of external influence) in the early stage distribution is the same as the supply distribution and
of the product life cycle, it is more likely to influence applying the Bass model to these adoption data is in-
the coefficient of imitation in the intermediate life cycle appropriate. Therefore the Bass mode! must be ex-
stage of a new product because the objective of the tended to integrate the demand-side dynamics with the
advertising content in the intermediate stage is to in- supply-side restrictions.
fluence potential customers through evaluation by A model that captures innovation diffusion dy-
customers and social pressure. Furthermore, the ad- namics in the presence of supply restrictions has been
vertising effect is cumulative over time. They report suggested by Jain, Mahajan, and Muller (1989). Their

14 / Journal of Marketing, January 1990


model conceptualizes diffusion as a three-stage pro- (1988) use diffusion models to test hypotheses related
cess: potential adopters waiting adopters -* adop- to the life-cycle dynamics of a new product. Finally,
ters. They have demonstrated the application of their Mahajan, Sharma, and Bettis (1988) evaluate the hy-
model for the diffusion of new telephones in Israel. pothesis that any S-shaped curve may not be a result
There is only one adoption by an adopting unit. of the imitation process. The preceding studies clearly
The objective of a diffusion model is to represent the demonstrate how the diffusion models can be used to
level or spread of an innovation among a given set of evaluate hypotheses related to the dynamics of inno-
prospective adopters. For a great many product in- vation diffusion.
novations, the increase in the number of adopters may
consist of first-time buyers as well as repeat buyers. Normative Uses
The Bass model, however, captures only the first-time Though diffusion models are concemed with repre-
buyers. senting the growth of a product category, that growth
In recent years, five empirical studies have been can be influenced by the individual or by collective
reported that capture the re peat/replacement dynam- actions of competitors that have long-term effects on
ics of innovation diffusion. Two of these studies, by the growth or decline of the market. Alternatively, even
Lilien, Rao, and Kalish (1981) and Mahajan, Wind, if there is only one firm in the industry, it must con-
and Sharma (1983), include repeat purchase in the Bass sider the life cycle dynamics over time to determine
model to examine diffusion of ethical drugs. Two other optimal marketing mix strategy for maximizing its
studies, by Olson and Choi (1985) and Kamakura and profitability. That is, it must find out what trajectory
Balasubramanian (1987), include product replace- (pattem or strategy) of the relevant marketing mix
ments in the Bass model to assess long-term sales for variables it should follow to maximize its discounted
consumer durable products. Norton and Bass (1987) profits over the planning period given the constraint
assume that adopters continue to buy and that the av- that the life cycle of the product follows a certain growth
erage repeat buying rate over the population of adop- pattem. It therefore solves the following dynamic op-
ters is constant. timization problem.

Maximize IT = Total discounted profits (14)


Uses of Diffusion Models over the planning period
Innovation diffusion models traditionally have been
used in the context of sates forecasting. However, as Subject to: A given life cycle growth pattem (15)
pointed out by Mahajan and Wind (1986b) and Katish The dynamic optimization formulation outlined in
and Lilien (1986a), sales forecasting is only one of expressions 14 and 15 is the general framework that
the objectives of diffusion models. In addition to fore- has been used by several authors in the 1980s to de-
casting, perhaps the most useful applications of dif- velop optimal marketing mix strategies, especially for
fusion models are for descriptive and normative pur- price and advertising. Most of these studies use the
poses. Because diffusion models are an analytical Bass model, and its extensions incorporating market-
approach to describing the spread of a diffusion phe- ing mix variables, in expression 15 to represent the
nomenon, they can be used in an explanatory mode life cycle dynamics over time. They usually consider
to test specific diffusion-based hypotheses. Further, a single marketing mix variable, such as price, to iso-
because diffusion models are designed to capture the late its effects on product growth. Before we comment
product life cycle of a new product, they can be used on these studies, a further elaboration on expressions
for normative purposes as the basis of how a product 14 and 15 is warranted.
should be marketed.
Note that the determination of trajectory of the
marketing mix variable(s) that maximizes expression
Descriptive Uses 14 depends on the specification of the growth model
Table 4 is a listing of nine illustrative studies in which used to specify the life cycle growth pattem in expres-
the diffusion modeling framework has been used to sion 15. Therefore, though most of the studies use the
test hypotheses. Srivastava et al. (1985) and Rao and Bass model to capture the word-of-mouth effect in
Yamada (1988) use diffusion models to test hy- expression 15, different optimal strategies can be ob-
potheses related to the impact of perceived product tained depending on how the relevant marketing mix
attributes on diffusion patterns. Kobrin (1985), Takada variables are incorporated in the Bass model. To high-
and Jain (1988), and Gatignon, Eliashberg, and Rob- light this point, we consider here derived optimal pric-
ertson (1989) use diffusion models to test hypotheses ing strategies for new durable goods.
related to innovation diffusion across countries. Bass When launching a new product, a firm usually can
(1980), Olshavsky (1980), and Modis and Debecker choose between two distinct pricing strategies, market

New Product Diffusion Models in Marketing / 15


TABLE 4
Illustrative Descriptive Appiications of Diffusion Modeis
Diffusion
Study By Hypothesis Tested Model Used Remarks
Bass (1980) As a result of learning and Bass Reports results for six durable products. The
accumulated experience, declining hypothesis is generally confirmed for most of
patterns of costs and prices result these products. Similar results are provided by
i^or technological innovations DeKluyver (1982).
Olshavskv (1980) Product life cycles of consumer Mansfield Study uses data from 25 consumer durable
durable goods are shortening products. Hypothesis is tested by examining
because of rapidly accelerating relationship between coefficient of imitation and
technological developments time of introduction of an innovation. Findings
confirm hypothesis.
Kobrin (1985) The pattern of oil production Bass Study examines pattern of number of countries
nationalization across countries is a per year that nationalized oil production from
"social interaction" phenomenon 1960 to 1979. Supplementing quantitative results
with detailed qualitative analyses, study confirms
hypothesis.
Srivastava et al. Potential adopters' perceptions of Bass Study examines diffusion of 14 investment
(1985) innovation attributes explain the alternatives. To explain diffusion patterns across
diffusion pattern of a product investment alternatives, coefficient of imitation is
expressed as a function of perceived product
attributes. Two attributes of perceived information
cost and perceived likelihood of loss of principal/
negative return explain those differences. Findings
confirm hypothesis.

Mahajan, Sharma, Adoption of the M-form Bass Study examines adoption of M-form organization
and Bettjs (1988) organizational structure by the U.S. structure among 127 U.S. firms from 1960 to
firms resulted from an imitation 1974. Findings question validity of the hypothesis.
behavior
Modis and There is a relationship between the Mansfield Study uses data on number of new models
Debecker {19881 number of new computer models introduced and number of new manufacturers that
and the number of new computer emerged in computer market from beginning of
manufacturers. 1958 to end of 1984. Study is also done for
personal computers. By examining relationship
between grovrth patterns of number of new
computer models and number of new computer
manufacturers, the authors conclude that, on
average, a new computer manufacturer emerges
for every five new models that appear on the
market. For the personal computers market, this
relationship is around one for every six.

Rao and Yamada Potential adopters' perceptions of Lilien, Rao, Study examines diffusion of 21 ethical drugs
(1988) innovation attributes explain the and Kalish using repeat-purchase diffusion model suggested
diffusion pattern of a product (1981) by Lilien, Rao, and Kalish. Model coefficients are
expressed as a function of six perceived attributes
of ethical drugs. Findings confirm hypothesis.
Takada and Jain Cultural differences among countries Bass Study examines diffusion of eight consumer
(1988) will lead to different diffusion durable products in Japan, Korea, and United
patterns States. By testing differences between coefficients
of innovation and imitation across the three
countries, the authors conclude that among the
three countries analyzed, a product is adopted in
Korea at a much faster rate than in either the U.S.
or in Japan. No significant differences are found
between the diffusion patterns in Japan and U.S.
Gatignon, Three dimensions explain the Bass The study examines the diffusion of six consumer
Eliashberg, and differences in the diffusion patterns durable products in 14 European countries.
Robertson (1989) across countries: level of Coefficients of imitation and innovation are
cosmopolitanism of a country, expressed as a function of variables measuring
mobility, and the role of women in the three hypothesized dimensions, and their
the society impact on the two coefficients is determined
simultaneously across products and across
countries. Findings confirm hypothesis.

skimming and market penetration. A market-skim- initially to capture a large market share.
ming strategy uses a high price initially to "skim" the Introduction of the impact of price in the Bass model
market when the market is still developing. The mar- framework generally has resulted in two types of nor-
ket penetration strategy, in contrast, uses a low price mative pricing strategies. One derived pricing strategy

16 / Journal of Marketing, January 1990


posits that price will increase at introduction, peak, Basic Diffusion Models
and decrease later (Dolan and Jeuland 1981; Jeuland Though several assumptions underlying the Bass model
and Dolan 1982; Kalish 1983; Robinson and Lakhani have been of concern in the 1980s (Mahajan and Wind
1975). Kalish and Sen's (1986, p. 94) intuitive ex- 1986a), we believe five issues warrant further inves-
planation for this pricing strategy is that if early adop- tigation.
ters have a strong positive effect on late adopters, a
low introductory ("subsidized") price should encour- Adoptions due to internal influence. One of the
age them to adopt the product. Consequently, once a key factors of the Bass model is that it explicitly con-
product is established, price can be raised because the siders the influence of internal (word of mouth) as well
contribution to sales due to additional adopters de- as external sources of communication on innovation
creases over time. Studies deriving this pricing strat- diffusion. As depicted in Figure lA, the Bass model
egy generally assume that price does not affect the assumes that adopters whose purchase decisions are
population of potential adopters and produces a mul- influenced by external sources of information are
tiplicative effect on the rate of diffusion. That is, from present at any stage of the diffusion process. Such
equation 1, adopters, however, should not be labeled "innova-
tors" because innovators, by definition, are charac-
dN(t) terized as the first adopters of an innovation (Mahajan,
- N ( t ) (m-N(t))g(P) (16)
dt Muller, and Srivastava 1990). The questions now are:
What are the characteristics of adopters who, despite
where g(P) is the price response function for the dy- a large product penetration in the marketplace, are
namic price P at time t. Equation 16 assumes that price predominantly influenced by external sources? How
affects the rate of diffusion. do they differ from innovators and other adopter cat-
The second derived pricing strategy posits that price egories on those characteristics? Because, within a
is more likely to decrease over time, supporting the certain time period in the diffusion process, the Bass
market-skimming strategy (Kalish 1983). In deriving model implies the presence of adopters due to both
this optimal strategy, some researchers have assumed internal influence and external influence, how do those
that price affects the market potential. That is: two groups differ from each other?
In a recent empirical study, Feick and Price (1987)
-N(t) (17) suggest that in any social system there are individuals
dt
who assimilate and disseminate information on prod-
The preceding analyses illustrate that we must be ucts (and therefore influence others) and tend to rely
cautious about the normative policies derived from the on external sources of information. They label these
diffusion-based dynamic optimization framework be- individuals "market mavens." On the basis of their
cause the derived policies could be simply an artifact empirical results, however, they conclude that "the
of the underlying assumptions made for analytical concepts of the market maven and the innovative con-
convenience. Despite this observation, the diffusion sumer are distinct" (1987, p. 90). Their findings raise
modeling framework has provided an excellent op- research questions about the linkage in the Bass model
portunity to develop a "theory" of life cycle analysis between market mavens and adopters who buy as a
for empirical validation. result of external influence.
Table 5 is a summary of some of the major results
Multiple adoptions. The Bass model has been de-
from various studies for optimal strategies for three
veloped to represent the conversion of potential adop-
variables: pricing, advertising, and product introduc-
ters to adopters. It explicitly assumes that each po-
tion time. We summarize these results for two indus-
tential adopter buys only one unit of the product.
try settings, monopoly and oligopoly. The major re-
However, certain innovations are bought in multiple
sults reported for each study reflect the issue raised
units by potential adopters (e.g., multiple units of
in the study.
scanners by a supermarket and multiple units of per-
sonal computers by a firm). For these innovations, the
Conclusions and Discussion sales data must be linked with the number of adopters
by using a function that explicitly takes into consid-
From our review of the emerging literature on inno- eration the multiple-unit-adoption behavior of the po-
vation diffusion modeling in marketing, we can high- tential adopters (see Norton and Bass 1987).
light research issues that must be addressed to make
these models theoretically more sound and practically Effect of consumer expectations. For certain in-
more effective and realistic. We discuss such research novations (e.g.. computers), consumer expectations
possibilities related to the five subareas of recent de- about the innovation's fiittire characteristics (e.g., price)
velopments. influence purchase intentions (see, e.g., Holak,

New Product Diffusion Models in Marketing / 1 7


TABLE 5
Optimal Marketing Mix Strategies for Innovation Diffusion
Issue and Marketing Illustrative
Mix Variable Major Assumptions/Comments Major Normative Results References
Industry Setting: Monopoly
Price
How should a monopolist 1. Price interacts with diffusion For a long planning horizon, if Robinson and
price a new product over (rate of adoption) imitation effect is dominating. Lakhani (1975), Dolan
its life cycle? 2. Demand saturation effect causes price first increases and then and Jeuland (1981),
decline in price over time and decreases Kalish (1983), Clarke,
diffusion effect causes price to Darrough, and
increase over time; experience Heineke (1982)
effect (learning by doing)
causes a decline in price over
time
Price has a multiplicative effect on Priee declines over time Kalish (1983), Bass
diffusion and interacts with and Bultez (1982)
experience curve
Price affects market potential Price declines over time Kalish (1983)
How should a monopolist Monopolist produces a new If product is not protected against Nascimento and
price over time a new product that can be copied. Market copying, price is initially high and Vanhonacker (19881
product that can be copied? potential is affected by price then decreases as copying
increases
How should a monopolist Price affects market potential 1. Price increases monotonically Feichtinger (1982),
price a repeat-purchased over time Jorgensen (1983,
product over its life cycle? 2. With experience effect, price 1986), Katish (1983),
may first increase (strong Jeuland and Dolan
imitation effect) then decrease (1982)
(strong experience effect)
How should a monopolist Price and cumulative adoption Priee increases over time Dhebar and Oren
price over time a new affect market potential (1985)
product or service whose
consumption value
increases with the
expansion of the "net-
work" of adopters referred
to as a network externality
{e.g., electronic mail)?
Advertising
How should a monopolist Advertising affects coefficients of 1. Linear response function implies Horsky and Simon
advertise a new product innovation and/or imitation; three a blitz followed by a constant (1983), Dockner and
over time? types of response functions can be maintenance level Jorgensen (1988a),
used to represent this effect: 2. If advertising affects only Mahajan and Muller
linear, concave (diminishing innovators, concave response (1986)
returns), S-shaped (increasing and function implies a policy
then diminishing returns) whereby advertising decreases
over time, gradually
approaching the maintenance
level; if advertising affects
imitators, concave response
function implies a policy
whereby advertising increases
over time
3. S-sbaped response function
implies a high intensity blitz
level followed by a pulsing
policy
Timing
When should a monopolist Members in a social system pass Optimal timing calls for advertising Mahajan, Muller, and
introduce a product if both through three stages in innovation before product is introduced and Kerin (1984)
positive and negative word decision process: unaware, withdrawal of product after end of
of mouth affect diffusion potential customers, and adopters; advertising period
process? How should both potential customers and
product be advertised over adopters circulate positive as well
time? as negative word of mouth
When should a monopolist No pricing or advertising effect In most cases, optimal timing Wilson and Norton
introduce a second decision is "now or never"; If (1989)
generation product? Should optimal introduction time exists, it
firm shelve it or introduce is early in life cycle of first product
it as soon as it is available?

18 / Journal of Marketing, January 1990


TABLE 5 (continued)
Optimal Marketing Mix Strategies for Innovation Diffusion
Issue and Marketing Illustrative
Mix Variable Major Assumptions/Comments Major Normative Results References
Industry Setting: Oligopoly
Price
How will firms in an Price has a multiplicative effect on Monopoly results extend to Thompson and Teng
oligopoly price their diffusion; demand saturation oligopoly case: if imitation effect is (1984). Clarke and
products over their life causes decline in price; diffusion strong, price increases initially, and Dolan (19841,
cycle? effect causes price increase; if planning horizon is long, it Dockner and
experience effect causes a decline decreases toward end of planning Jorgensen n988b)
in price horizon
How does an industry set a Market price is a function of Same as above Rao and Bass (1985)
price of a new product quantities set by oligopolists
class over time?
Advertising
How would firms in an Advertising affects innovators or 1. In many cases, advertising Deal (1979), Teng
oligopoly advertise their imitators: linear or concave starts with a high level that and Thompson
products over time? advertising response decreases to a constant (1983), Thompson
maintenance policy and Teng (1984),
2. Emphasis on final market Erickson (1985)
shares causes an increase in
advertising toward end of
planning horizon
3. In some cases, advertising may
Increase; moreover, in some
cases advertising for one
competitor may increase while
that of the second competitor
may decrease, or both may
increase
Timing
Does order of entry affect Multiplicative price effect on 1. Order of entry has no long-term Fershtman, Mahajan,
long-term market share? diffusion effects on final market shares and Muller (1990)
How would anticipation of 2. Monopolist who does not
entry affect investment foresee entry overcapitalizes in
decision of a monopolist? contrast to foresighted
monopolist who anticipates
entry
How would anticipation of Multiplicative price effect on Foresighted monopolist who Eiiashberg and
entry affect pricing decision diffusion anticipates entry reduces price in Jeuland (1986)
of a monopolist? contrast to a surprised monopolist
who does not foresee entry

Lehmann, and Sultan 1987; Winer 1985). For such adopter in the next instant of time). The Bass model
innovations, in addition to influencing the nature of specifies this rate as a linear function of previous
the adoption curve., consumer expectations can influ- adopters. Since the publication of the Bass model,
ence the optimal marketing mix strategy used by a however, much work developing and applying hazard
firm. For example, incorporating consumer expecta- models has appeared in the statistics, biometrics, and
tions related to price in the Bass model, Narasimhan econometrics literatures (e.g., Cox and Oakes 1984;
(1989) suggests that the optimal pricing strategy for a Kalbfleisch and Prentice 1980; for possible marketing
monopolist cycles over time and within each cycle the applications of hazard models, see Helsen and
price increases at introduction, peaks, and decreases Schmittlein 1989; for interpretation of diffusion models
later. Given the importance of consumer expectations as hazard models, see Lavaraj and Gore 1990). The
in understanding diffusion dynamics, we expect fu- key development in hazard models over the last de-
ture research to incorporate them into the Bass model. cade has been in the area of understanding covariate
effects on the hazard rate (and consequently on du-
Exploration of recent developments in hazard ration times). This development is particularly im-
models. The different diffusion models can be viewed portant because attempts to incorporate marketing mix
as making different assumptions about the "hazard rate" variables (and other covariate effects) in diffusion
for nonadopters as a function of time (the hazard rate models to date have been very limited in scope and
being the likelihood that an individual who has re- ad hoc in their choice of model specifications for those
mained a nonadopter through time t will become an effects. Exploration of recent developments in the

New Product Diffusion Models in Marketing / 19


hazard modeling framework may provide a unifyitig how can parameters in these models be calibrated prior
theme for understanding of covariate/marketing mix to launch for long-term forecasting? Further etnpirical
effects in diffusion models. work related to these questions is desirable.
Understanding of diffusion processes at the micro
Refinements and Extensions
(individual) level. Diffusion models based on individ-
tial-ievel adoption decisions offer an opportunity to W e briefly discuss 10 possibilities for further refine-
study the actual pattern of social communication and ment and extension of the Bass m o d e l .
its impact on product perceptions, preferences, and
ultimate adoption. The empirical evidence provided A decade ago, Mahajan and Muller (1979) eoncluded
that it was not clear how marketing mix variables should
by Chatteijee and Eliashberg (1989) on the develop- be incorporated into the Bass model. The few empirical
ment of aggregate diffusion models from individual- studies reported in the 1980s still do not provide con-
level adoption decisions, though limited, is encour- clusive guidelines on this question. Despite the argu-
aging. Further empirical work on such models may ments made in favor of including price in the market
potential, empirical studies on consumer durable prod-
assist in developing the aggt^gate diffusion models prior ucts by Kamakura and Balasubramanian (1988) and Jain
to launch. and Rao (1989) suggest that price affects the rate of
diffusion (by influencing the coefficients of external in-
Parameter Estimation Considerations fluence and internal influence). Similarly, in relation to
the inclusion of advertising in the Bass model, the two
In comparison with the other subareas we review, pa- reported empirical studies suggest different alternatives.
rameter estimation considerations for the Bass model Horsky and Simon (1983) recommend that it be in-
cluded in the coefficient of external influence whereas
probably received the most attention in the 1980s. These Simon and Sebastian (1987) report better results by in-
developments are timely and encouraging, but further cluding it in the coefficient of internal influence. Inter-
empirical work on the validation of meta-analysis pro- estingly, though both of these studies examine the effect
cedures (Montgomery and Srinivasan 1989; Sultan, of advertising on the diffusion of a service (a banking
Farley, and Lehmann 1990). Bayesian estimation pro- service by Horsky and Simon and a telephone service
by Simon and Sebastian), they were conducted in two
cedures (Lenk and Rao 1989; Sultan. Farley, and different markets (U.S. and West Germany) and under
Lehmann 1990), and procedures that capitalize on the different market conditions (there was a supply problem
information provided by managers and potential adop- with the availability of telephones in West Germany).
ters (e.g.. Randies 1983; Souder and Quaddus 1982) Whether these differences had an impact on the reported
results is an empirical question. Given the importance
is important. An emerging body of literature in the of including marketing mix variables in understanding
forecasting area suggests that combining parameter diffusion dynamics, we expect more empirical work in-
estimates from different estimation procedures can yield eluding other marketing mix variables such as distri-
better forecasting results (see Mahajan and Wind 1988). bution.
Empirical studies that explore the feasibility of such
findings for diffusion models are desirable (Lawrence Several of the empirical studies reported in Table 5 have
and Geurts 1984). incorporated product attributes in the Bass model. A
natural extension of these studies is to develop proce-
dures to determine optima! product design to obtain the
Flexible Diffusion Models desirable penetration rate.
Flexible diffusion models have the advantage of cap- For high technology products, the time interval between
successive generations of technologies has been de-
turing penetration patterns that are symmetric as well creasing. Norton and Bass (1987) have shown how dif-
as nonsymmetric with no restrictions on the point of fiision of successive generations interacts within the
inflection. However, among all the models reviewed context of the Bass model. Forecasting possibilities
in Table 3, only the models by Von Bertalanffy (1957) stemming from this work appear to be promising. Ex-
(or Nelder 1962) and Bewley and Fiebig (1988) offer tensions involving pricing of generations of technology
would be desirable and feasible.
closed-form solutions to the differential equations used
to specify the diffusion dynamics (i.e., express the When should a firm introduce a second generation prod-
uct? Though the analytical results of Wilson and Norton
number of adopters as an explicit function of time, (1989) suggest the answer is "now or never." they ex-
which is desirable for long-term forecasting). Fur- elude the impact of other variables such as price. Fur-
thermore, these models have a flexibility advantage ther theoretical and empirical work addressing this
by requiring estimation of additional numbers of pa- question would be weleome.
rameters. However, two important questions remain: For high technology products, the product offering of a
How much additional long-term foreca.sting accuracy firm generally includes both hardware and software, such
is provided by the flexible models, in comparison with as Nintendo hardware (keypad) and Nintendo software
(video games) for children. Because of the contingency
the basic diffusion models such as the Bass model, inherent in the relationship, it is important to develop
when controlled for the number of parameters'? Given diffusion models that examine the diffusion of the entire
the parameter estimation considerations discussed here. bundle of product offerings. In addition to forecasting.

20 / Journal of Marketing, January 1990


normative questions may relate to its optimal pricing and MacKenzie 1972; Heeler and Hustad 1980). We
and distribution. For example, how should a monopolist sympathize with such concems and believe that fur-
(e.g., Nintendo) manufacture and distribute its hard- ther empirical work is needed to identify conditions
ware and software? Should it keep a monopoly on both
of them? Should il keep a monopoly on hardware and
under which diffusion models work or do not work.
create an oligopoly for software to increase demand for For example, recent work by Jain. Mahajan. and Muller
the hardware? (1989) suggests that the use of the Bass model is in-
How do the number of competitors and the rivalry among appropriate in intemational settings where the supply
them influence the growth of a product category? Does of the product is restricted. Furthermore, as the dif-
the growth affect the entry/exit patterns of competitors? fusion models capture the dynamics of innovation dif-
Answers to these questions are within the domain of the fusion for first-time buyers, it is not clear that the same
diffusion modeling framework and provide a linkage with
the strategic planning literature. Theoretical and empir-
diffusion dynamics are applicable to replacement sales.
ical work on these questions will enhance the utility of Therefore the use of diffusion models for such adop-
diffusion models. tion data may be inappropriate (see. e.g., Bayus 1988;
Supply restrictions influence diffusion patterns. For cer- Bayus, Hong, and Labe 1989). Finally, diffusion
tain types of products (e.g., prescription drugs), it may models are imitation models. Any S-shaped curve,
be desirable to retard the diffusion process by control- however, may not be a result of the imitation process,
ling their supply and distribution. Further empirical and and alternative time-series models may be more ap-
theoretical work on this linkage would enable managers propriate for such data (Mahajan, Sharma. and Bettis
to control the life cycle of a product by managing the
supply. 1988). Even in the presence of the imitation effect, it
Market interventions (e.g., patent violations) are exter-
may be necessary to examine various diffusion models
'* nalities that can influence the growth pattern of a new systematically to identify the one that best describes
pnxlucl. Though the use of intervention analysis is well the data (Rust and SchmitUein 1985). There is also a
established in the time-series analysis literature, no at- growing body of literature on "chaos theory" sug-
tempt seems to have been made to conduct intervention gesting that for certain parameter values, diffusion
analysis with the diffusion models (Mahajan, Sharma.
and Wind 1985). Theoretical and empirical work in this models generate persistent chaotic behavior within
area could assist in assessing the impact (e.g.. assessing predictable boundaries (Gordon and Greenspan 1988).
patent violation damages in a legal case) of market in- Understanding of such phenomena may be essential
terventions on the product life cycle. to decipher the impact of changes that affect the dif-
Though integration of the time and spatial dimensions ftision dynamics-
has been of interest to geographers, their integration is
equally important in marketing to evaluate alternative The use of diffusion models to test diffusion-based
product distribution strategies across markets. Such ex- hypotheses is very encouraging. The empirical studies
tensions of the Bass model could assist in evaluating the documented in Table 4 clearly attest to their potential
impact on the growth of a new product of how and where in such applications. We expect additional empirical
the product is made available.
work employing a diffusion modeling framework to
The diffusion literature has emphasized consistently the test hypotheses related to life cycle dynamics (e.g.:
importance of negative word of mouth on the growth of
a new product (Mahajan. Muiler, and Kerin I9S4). The How does the number of competitors change over the
multistage extensions of the Bass model offer an avenue life cycle of a product? How dtes the number of brands
for considering its impact on the growth pattern. These available in a market influence the growth of a prod-
extensions lack empirical validation, however. Data uct? How does the rivalry among competitors in an
collection and estimation procedures should be devel- industry affect the life cycle of a product? Etc.)
oped to make these extensions practicable.
The use of diffusion models to derive normative
Not all new product.s are accepted by consumers at the
time of their introduction. Some products are much slower
results for the dynamics of innovation diffusion re-
than others in being accepted by potential adopters. That ceived considerable attention in 1980s. However, as
is, they differ in terms of how long it takes them to summarized in Table 5, these results are simply work-
"take off." The "take-off" phenomenon is not consid- ing hypotheses. Furthermore, the nature of these re-
ered explicitly in the Bass model. The Bass model as- sults is contingent on the assumptions made in their
sumes the presence of a certain number of consumers analytical derivation. For most of these studies, the
before "take off" (i.e.. pm). Extensions of the Bass model
that explicitly consider this phenomenon will be useful analytical elegance surpasses the empirical validation
in explaining and predicting the take-off behavior of a of the derived results. Empirical evidence is needed
new product. to find out if and when the firms use the derived nor-
mative strategies.
Use of Diffusion Models Finally, it is important to acknowledge that several
One of the critical uses of diffusion models has been firms have used diffusion models for forecasting the
for forecasting the first-purchase sales volume curve. demand of a new product. By sharing their experi-
In recent years, questions have been raised about the ences, industry users can contribute to the further val-
forecasting accuracy of diffusion models (Bernhardt idation of diffusion models.

New Product Diffusion Models in Marketing / 21


REFERENCES
Akinola, Amos A. (1986), "An Application of the Bass Model E>emand for Computers," American Economics Review, 57
in the Analysis of Diffusion of Coco-Spraying Chemicals (December). 1117-30.
Among Nigerian Cocoa Farmers," Journal of Agricultural Clarke, Darrel G. and Robert J. Dolan (1984), "A Simulation
Economics. 37 (3). 395-404. Model for the Evaluation of Pricing Strategies in a Dy-
Amdt, Johan (1967), "Role of Product-Related Conversations namic Environment," Journal of Business. 57 (January).
in the Diffusion of a New Product," Journal of Marketing S179-S200.
Research. 4 (August), 291-5. Clarke, Frank H., Masako N. Darrough, and John M. Heineke
Bartholomew, D. J. (1982), Stochastic Models for Social Pro- (1982), "Optimal Pricing Policy in the Presence of Expe-
cesses. 3rd ed. New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc. rience Effects," Journal of Business, 55 (4), 517-30.
Bass, Frank M. (1969), "A New Product Growth Model for Cox. D. R. and D. Oakes (1984), Analysis of Survival Data.
Consumer Durables," Management Science. 15 (January), London: Chapman and Hall.
215-27. Deal. Kenneth R. (1979). "Optimizing Advertising Expendi-
(1980), -The Relationship Between Diffusion Rates, tures in a Dynamic Duopoly, Operations Research. 27 (July-
Experience Curves, and Demand Elasticities for Consumer August), 682-92.
Durable Technological Innovations," Journal of Business, DeKluyver, Comelis A. (1982), "A Comparative Analysis of
S3 (July, part 2), 51-67. the Bass and WeibuU New Pnxiuct Growth Models for
(1986), "The Adoption of a Marketing Model: Consumer Durables," New Zealand Journal of Operations
Comments and Observations," in Innovation Diffusion of Research, 10 (July), 99-130.
New Product Acceptance. Vijay Mahajan and Yoram Wind, Dhebar, Anirudh and Shmuei S. Oren (1985), "Optimal Dy-
eds. Cambridge, MA: Baliinger Publishing Company. namic Pricing for Expanding Networks," Marketing Sci-
and Alain V. Bultez (1982). "A Note on Optimal ence. 4 (Fall). 336-51.
Strategic Pricing of Technological Innovations," Marketing Dixon, Robert (1980), "Hybrid Com Revisited," Econome-
Science. I (Fall), 371-8. trica. 48 (September), 1451-41.
Bayus, Barry L. (1987), "Forecasting Sales of New Contin- Dockner, Engelbert and Steffen Jorgensen (1988a), "Optimal
gent Products: An Application to the Compact Disc Mar- Advertising Policies for Diffusion Models of New Product
ket," Journal of Product Innovation Management. 4 (De- Innovations in Monopolistic Situations," Management Sci^
cember), 243-55. ence, 34 (January), 119-30.
(1988), "Accelerating the Durable Replacement Cycle and (1988b), "Optimal Pricing Strategies
With Marketing Mix Variables," Journal of Product In- for New Products in Dynamic Oligopolies," Marketing Sci-
novation Management. 5 (September), 216-26. ence, 1 (Fall), 315-34.
, Saman Hong, and Russell P. Labe, Jr. (1989), Dodds, W. (1973). "An Application of the Bass Model in Long-
"Developing and Using Forecasting Models for Consumer Term New Product Forecasting," Journal of Marketing We-
Durables." Journal of Product Innovation Management. 6 .veorc/i. 10 (August), 308-11.
(March). 5-19. Dodson. Joe A. and Eitan Muller (1978), "Models of New
Bcmhardt, 1. and K. M. Mackenzie (1972), "Some Problems Product Diffusion Through Advertising and Word-of-
in Using Diffusion Models for New Products." Manage- Mouth." Management Science. 24 (November), 1568-78.
ment Science. 19 (October), 187-200. Dolan, Robert J. and Abel P. Jeuland (1981), "Experience
Bewley, Ronald and Denzil G. Fiebig (1988), "A Flexible Lo- Curves and Dynamic Demand Models: Implications for Op-
gistic Growth Model With Applications in Telecommuni- timal Pricing Strategies." Journal of Marketing. 45 (Win-
cations," International Journal of Forecasting, 4 (2), 177- ter), 52-62.
92. Easingwood, Christopher J. (1987), "Early Product Life Cycle
Boker. Fred (1987), "A Stochastic First-Purchase Diffusion Fomis for Infrequently Purchased Major Products," Inter-
Mixlel: A Counting Approach, Journal of Marketing Re- national Journal of Research in Marketing. 4(1), 3-9.
search. 24 (February), 64-73. (1988). "Product Life Cycle Pattems for New In-
Bretschneider, Stuart 1. and Barry Bozeman (1986), "Adap- dustrial Products," R&D Management. 18 (1). 2 3 - 3 2 .
tive Diffusion Models for the Growth of Robotics in New (1989), "An Analogical Approach to the Long Term
York State Industry," Technological Forecasting and So- Forecasting of Major New Product Sales," International
cial Change. 30 (September), 111-21. Journal of Foreca.sting. 5, 69-82.
and Vijay Mahajan (1980), "Adaptive Technolog- , Vijay Mahajan, and Eitan Muller (1981). "A Non-
ical Substitutions Models." Technological Forecasting and symmetric Responding Logistic Model for Technological
Social Change. 18 (October), 129-39. Substitution." Technological Forecasting and Social Change.
Brown, Lawrence A. (1981), Innovation Diffusion: A New 20 (October), 199-213.
Perspective. New York: Methucn and Co. Ltd. , . and ^ (1983), "A Nonuni-
Carbone, Robert and R. L. Longini (1977), ' A Feedback Model form Influence Innovation Diffusion Model of New Product
for Automated Real Estate Assessment," Management Sci- Acceptance," Marketing Science. 2 (Summer), 273-96.
ence. 24 (November), 241-8. Eliashberg, Jehoshua and Rabikar Chatterjee (1986), "Sto-
Chatteijee, Rabikar and Jehoshua Eliashberg (1989), "The In- chastic Lssues in Innovation Diffusion Models," in Inno-
novation Diffusion Process in a Heterogeneous Population: vation Diffusion Models of New Product Acceptance. Vijay
A Micromodeling Approach." working paper. Marketing Mahajan and Yoram Wind. eds. Cambridge, MA: Baliinger
Department, Kranncrt Graduate School of Management, Publishing Company.
Purdue University. and Abel P. Jeuland (1986). "The Impact of Com-
Chow, Gregory C. (1967), "Technological Change and the petitive Entry in a Developing Market Ufjon Dynamic Pric-

22 / Journal of Marketing, January 1990


ing Strategies." Marketing Science, 5 (Winter), 20-36. Hiebert, L. Dean (1974), "Risk, Learning and the Adoption
. Charles S. Tapiero, and Yoram Wind (1987). "In- of Fertilizer Responsive Seed Varieties," American Journal
novation Diffusion Models With Stochastic Parameters: of Agricultural Economics, 56 (November), 764-8.
Forecasting and Phinning Implications." Working Paper No. Holak, Susan, Donald R. Lehmann, and Fareena Sultan (1987),
87-003, Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania. "The Role of Expectations in the Adoption of Innovative
Engel, James E., Roger D. Blackwell, and Paul W. Miniard Consumer Durables: Some Preliminary Evidence," Journal
(1986), Consumer Behavior. Hinsdale. IL: Dryden Press. of Retailing, 63 (Fall), 243-59.
Erickson, Gary M. (1985). "A Model of Advertising Com- Horsky, Dan (1990), "The Effects of Income, Price and In-
petition," Journal of Marketing Research, 22 (August), 297- formation on the Diffusion of New Consumer Durables,"
304. Marketing Science, forthcoming.
Feder. Gershon and Gerald T. O'Mara (1982). "On Infor- and Leonard S. Simon (1983). "Advertising and the
mation and Innovation Diffusion: A Bayesian Approach." Diffusion of New Products," Management Science, 1
American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 64 (Febru- (Winter), 1-18.
ary). i45-7. Hyman, Michael R. (1988), "The Timeliness Problem in the
Feichtinger, Gustav (1982). "Optimal Pricing in Diffusion Model Application of Bass-Type New Product Growth Models to
With Concave Price-Dependent Market Potential," Oper- Durable Sales Forecasting," Journal of Business Research.
ations Research Letters, 1, 236-40. 16(1), 31-47.
Feick, Lawrence F. and Linda L. Price (1987), "The Market Jain, Dipak C , Vijay Mahajan, and Eitan Muller (1989), "In-
Maven: A Diffuser of Marketplace Information," Journal novation Diffusion in the Presence of Supply Restrictions,"
of Marketing. 51 (January), 83-97. working paper. Cox School of Business, Southern Meth-
Fershtman, Chaim. Vijay Mahajan. and Eitan Muiler (1990), odist University.
"Market Share Pioneering Advantage: A Theoretical Ap- and Ram C. Rao (1989). "Effect of Price on the
proach," Management Science, forthcoming. Demand for Durables: Modeling, Estimation and Find-
Fisher, J. C. and R. H. Pry (1971), "A Simple Substitution ings," Journat of Business and Economic Statistics, forth-
Model for Technological Change," Technological Fore- coming.
casting and Social Change. 2 (May), 75-88. and Hirokazu Takada (1988), "Cross-National
Royd, A. (1962), "Trend Forecasting: A Methodology for Analysis of Diffusion of Consumer Durables," working pa-
Figure of Merit." in Technological Forecasting for Industry per. Marketing Department. Northwestern University.
atid Government: Methods and Applications. J. Bright, ed. Jensen, Richard (1982). "Adoption and Diffusion of an In-
Englewood Cliffs. NJ: Prentice-Hall. Inc., 95-105. novation of Uncertain Profitability." Journal of Economic
Fourt, L. A. and J. W. Woodlock (I960). "Eariy Prediction Theory. 27, 182-93.
of Market Success for Grocery Products," Journal of Mar- Jeuland, Abel P. (1981). "Parsimonious Models of Diffusion
keting. 25 (October), 31-8. of Innovation: Part A. Derivations and Comparisons,"
Frank, Ronald E., William F. Massy, and Donald G. Morrison working paper. Graduate School of Business, University of
(1964). "The Determinants of Innovative Behavior With Chicago.
Respect to a Branded, Frequently Purchased Food Prod- and Robert J, Dolan (1982), "An Aspect of New
uct." in Proceedings of the American Marketing Associa- Product Planning: Dynamic Pricing," in TIMS Studies in
tion, L. G. Smith, ed. Chicago: American Marketing As- the Management Sciences. Vol. 18: Marketing Planning
sociation, 312-23. Models. A. A. Zoltners. ed. New York: Elsevier Science
Gatignon. Hubert, Jehoshua Eliashberg. and Thomas S. Publishing Company, 1-21.
Robertson (1989), "Modeling Multinational Diffusion Pat- Jones, J. Morgan and Christopher J. Ritz (1987), "Incorpo-
terns: An Efficient Methodology," Marketing Science. rating Distribution Into New Product Diffusion Models,"
forthcoming. working paper. Marketing Department, University of North
and Thomas S. Robertson (1985), "A Propositional Carolina, Chapel Hill.
Inventory for New Diffusion Research." Journal of Con- jorgensen. Steffen (1983), "Optimal Control of a Diffusion
sumer Research. 11 (March), 849-67. Mtxiel of New Product Acceptance With Price-Dependent
Gordon, Theodore J. and David Greenspan (1988), Chaos and Total Market Potential," Optimal Control Applications and
Fractals: New Tools for Technological and Social Fore- Methods. 4, 269-76.
casting." Technological Forecasting and Social Change. (1986), "Optimal Dynamic Pricing in an Oligopol-
34 (August), 1-26. istic MarketA Survey," Lecture Notes in Economics and
Gore, A. P. and V. A. Lavaraj (1987), "'Innovation Diffusion Mathematical Systems. 265, 179-237.
in a Heterogeneous Population," Technological Forecast- Kalbflei.sch, J. D. and R. L. Prentice (1980), The Statistical
ing and Social Change. 32 (September), 163-7. Analysis of Failure Time Data. New York: John Wiley &
Heeler, Roger M. and Thomas P. Hustad (1980). "Problems Sons, Inc.
in Predicting New Product Growth for Consumer Dura- Kalish, Shiomo (1983), "Monopolist Pricing With Dynamic
bles," Management Science. 26 (October). 1007-20. Demand and Production Cost," Marketing Science. 2
Helsen, Kristiaan and David C. Schmittlein (1989). "Analyz- (Spring). 135-60.
ing Duration Times in Marketing Research," working pa- --(1985), "A New Product Adoption Model With
per. Marketing Department, Wharton School. University of Pricing, Advertising and Uncertainty," Management Sci-
Pennsylvania. ence, 31 (December). 1569-85.
Hendry, I. (1972), "The Three Parameter Approach to Long and Gary L. Lilien (t986a), "A Market Entry Tim-
Range Forecasting." Long Range Planning. 51 (March), ing Model for New Technologies," Management Science,
40-5. 32 (February), 194-205.
Hemes, G. (1976), "Diffusion and GrovrthThe Non-Ho- and (1986b), "Applications of Innova-
mogeneous Case," Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 78, tion Diffusion Models in Marketing," in Innovation Dif-
427-36. fusion Models of New Product Acceptance, Vijay Mahajan

New Product Diffusion Models in Marketing / 23


and Yoram Wind, eds. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Pub- "Bayesian Estimation and Control of Detailing Effort in a
lishing Company, Repeat Purchase Diffusion Environment," Management
and Subrata K. Sen (1986), "Diffusion Models and Science, 27 (May), 493-506.
the Marketing Mix for Single Products," in Innovation Dif- Mahajan. Vijay, Stuart 1. Bretschneider, and John W. Bradford
fusion Models of New Product Acceptance. Vijay Mahajan (1980), "Feedback Approaches to Modeling Structural ShifLs
and Yoram Wind. eds. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Pub- in Market Response," Journal of Marketing, 44 (Winter),
lishing Company, 71-80.
Kamakura, Wagner A. and Siva K. Balasubramanian (1987), , Charlotte H. Mason, and V. Srinivasan (1986), "An
"Long-Term Forecasting With Innovation Diffusion Models: Evaluation of Estimation Procedures for New Product Dif-
The Impact of Replacement Purchase," Journal of Fore- fusion Models." in Innovation Diffusion Models of New
casting. 6 (1), 1-19. Product Acceptance. Vijay Mahajan and Yoram Wind, eds.
' and (1988), "Long-Term View of the Cambridge. MA: Ballinger Publishing Company.
Diffusion of Durables," International Journal of Research and Eitan Muller (1979), "Innovation Diffusion and
in Marketing. 5. l - i 3 . New Product Growth Models in Marketing," Journal of
Karmeshu and R. K. Pathria (1980a), "Stochastic Evolution Marketing. 43 (Fall). 55-68.
of a Nonlinear Model of Diffusion of Information," Jour- and (1986), "Advertising Pulsing Poli-
nal of Mathematical Sociology. 7, 5 9 - 7 1 . cies for Generating Awareness for New Products," Mar-
and (1980b). "Diffusion of Information keting Science. 5 (Spring). 89-106.
in a Random Environment," Journal of Mathenuitical So- , and Roger A. Kerin (1984), "Intro-
ciology. 1, 215-27. duction Strategy for New Products With Positive and Neg-
King, Charles W., Jr. (1963). "Fashion Adoption: A Rebuttal ative Word-of-Mouth," Management Science. 30 (Decem-
to Ihe "Trickle Down' Theory." in Proceedings of the ber), 1389-404.
American Marketing Association. S. A. Greyser, ed. Chi- , , and Subhash Sharma (1984), "An
cago: American Marketing Association. 108-25. Empirieal Comparison of Awareness Forecasting Mixlels of
Kobrin, Stephen J. (1985), "Diffusion as an Explanation of New Product Acceptance," Marketing Science. 3 (Sum-
Oil Nationalization or the Domino Effect Rides Again." mer), 179-97.
Journal of Conflict Resolution. 29 (March), 3-32. , and Rajendra K. Srivastava (1990).
Koiler. Philip and Gerald Zaltman (1976), "Targeting Pros- "Using Innovation Diffusion Models to Develop Adopter
pects for a New Product," yourna/ of Advertising Research, Categories," Journal of Marketing Research, forthcoming.
16 (February). 7-20, and Robert A. Peterson (1978). "Innovation Dif-
Laekman, C. L. (1978), "Gompertz Curve Forecasting: A New fusion in a Dynamic Potential Adopter Population," Man-
Product Application," Journal of the Market Research So- agement Science. 24 (November), 1589-97.
ciety, 20 (January). 45-7. and (1979), "Integrating Time and Space
Lancaster, G. A. and G, Wright (1983), "Forecasting the Fu- in Technological Substitution Models," Technological
ture of Video Using a Diffusion Model," European Journal Forecasting and Social Change. 14 (August), 231-41.
of Marketing. 17 (2), 70-9. and (1982), "Erratum to: Innovation Dif-
Lattin, James M. and John H. Roberts (1989). "Modeling the fusion in a Dynamic Potential Adopter Population," Man-
Role of Risk-Adjusted Utility in the Diffusion of Innova- agement Science. 28 (September), 1087.
tions," Working Paper 1019, Graduate School of Business, and (1985), Models for Innovation Dif-
Stanford University, fusion, Beverly Hills. CA: Sage Publications Inc.
Lavaraj. U. A. and A. P. Gore (1990), "On Interpreting Prob- and Subhash Sharma (1986), "Simple Algebraic Es-
ability Distributions Fitted to Times of First Adoption," timation Procedure for Innovation Diffusion Models of New
Technological Forecasting and Social Change, forthcom- Product Acceptance," Technological Forecasting and So-
ing. cial Change. 30 (December), 331-46.
Lawrence, Kenneth D. and Michael Geurts (1984), "Con- , and Richard A. Bettis (1988). "The
verging Conflicting Forecasting Parameters in Forecasting Adoption of the M-Form Organizational Structure: A Test
Durable New Product Sales." Furopean Journal of Oper- of Imitation Hypothesis," Management Science. 34 (Oc-
ational Research. 16, 4 2 - 7 . tober), 1188-201.
and William H. Lawton (1981), "Applications of , and Yoram Wind (1985), "Assessing
Diffusion Models: Some Empirical Results," in New Prod- the Impact of Patent Infringement on New Product Sales,'
uct Foreca.sting. Yoram Wind. Vijay Mahajan. and R. C. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 28 (Au-
Cardozo. eds. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 529-41. gust), 13-27.
Lawton, S. B, and William H, Lawton (1979), "An Autoca- and Yoram Wind (1986a). Innovation Diffusion
talytic Model for the Diffusion of Educational Innova- Models of New Product Acceptance. Cambridge. MA: Bal-
tions." Educational Administration Quarterly. 15, 19-53. linger Publishing Company.
Lee, JackC, O. and K. W, Lu(l987), "On a Family of Data- and (1986b), "Innovation Diffusion
Based Transfonned Models Useful in Forecasting Tech- Models of New Product Acceptance: A Reexamination," in
nological Substitution," Technological Forecasting and So- Innovation Diffusion Models of New Product Acceptance.
cial Change, 31 (March), 61-78. Vijay Mahajan and Yoram Wind, eds. Cambridge, MA:
Ukvall, P. and C. Wahlbin (1973), "A Study of Some As- BaJlinger Publishing Company,
sumptions Underlying Innovation Diffusion Functions," and (1988), "New Product Forecasting
Swedish Journal of Economics, 75, 362-11. Models: Directions for Research and Implementation." In-
Lenk, Peter J. and Anibar G. Rao (1989), "New Models From ternational Journal of Forecasting. 4 (3), 341-58.
Old: Forecasting Product Adoption by Hierarchical Bayes . and Subhash Sharma (1983). "An Ap-
Procedures," Marketing Science, forthcoming. proach to Repeat Purchase Diffusion Models," AMA Pro-
Lilien. Gary L., Ambar G. Rao, and Shlomo Kalish (1981), ceedings. Series 49, Patrick E. Murphy et al., eds. Chi-

24/Journal of Marketing, January 1990


cago: American Marketing Association, 442-6. Rao, Sanjay Kumar (1985). "An Empirical Comparison of Sales
Mansfield, Edwin (1961), "Technical Change and the Rate of Forecasting Models," Journal of Product Innovation Man-
Imitation." Ecottotnetrica. 29 (October). 741-66. agement, 2 (December), 232-42.
McGowan. Ian (1986), "The Use of Growth Curves in Fore- Richards, F. J. (1959), "A Flexible Growth Function for Em-
casting Market Development," Journal of Forecasting. 5 pirical Use," Journal of Experimental Botany. 10, 290-300.
(1). 6 9 - 7 1 . Robertson. Thomas S. (1967), "Determinants of Innovative
McKenna, KQ%\S {\9%5). The Regis Tottch. Reading, MA: Ad- Behavior," in Proceedings of the American Marketing As-
dison-Wesley Publishing Company. sociation. R. Moyer, ed. Chicago: American Marketing
Meade, Nigel (1984), "The Use of Growth Curves in Fore- Association, 328-32.
casting Market Development: A Review and Appraisal," Robinson, Bruce and Chet Lakhani (1975), "Dynamic Price
Journal of Forecasting. 3 (4), 429-51. Models for New Product Planning," Management Science,
(1985), "Forecasting Using Growth Curves: An 10 (June), 1113-22.
Adaptive Approach," Journal of the Operational Research Rogers, Everen M. (1983), Diffusion of Innovations. 3rd ed.
Society. 36. 1103-15. New York: The Free Press.
Mesak. H. 1. and W. M. Mikhail (1988), "Prelaunch Sales Rust. Roland T. and David C. Schmittlein (1985), "A Bayes-
Forecasting of a New Industrial Product," Omega. 16 (1), ian Cross-Validated Likelihood Method for Comparing Al-
41-51. ternative Specifications of Quantitative Models." Market-
Midgley, David F. (1976), "A Simple Mathematical Theory ing Science. 4 (Winter), 20-40.
of Innovative Behavior," Journal of Consumer Research. Schmittlein. David C. and Vijay Mahajan (1982), "Maximum
3 (June), 31-41. Likelihood Estimation for an Innovation Diffusion Model
Modis, Theodore and Alain Debecker (1988), "Innovation in of New Product Acceptance." Marketing Science. 1 (Win-
the Computer Industry," Technological Forecasting and ter), 57-78.
Social Change, 33 (May), 267-78. Sharif, M. Nawaz and M. N. Islam (1980), "The Weibull Dis-
Montgomery, David B. and V. Srinivasan (1989), "An Im- tribution as a General Model for Forecasting Technological
proved Method for Meta Analysis: With Application to New Change," Technological Forecasting and Social Change,
Product Diffusion Models," working paper. Graduate School 18, 247-56.
of Business, Stanford University. and C. Kabir (1976), "A Generalized Model for
Narasimhan, Chakravarthi (1989), "Incorporating Consumer Forecasting Technological Substitution," Technological
Price Expectations in Diffusion Models." Marketing Sci- Forecasting and Social Change, 8, 353-64.
ence, forthcoming. ^ and K. Ramanathan (1981), "Binomial Innovation
Nascimento, Fernando and Wilfried R. Vanhonacker (1988). Diffusion Models With Dynamic Potential Adopter Popu-
"Optimal Strategic Pricing of Reproducible Consumer lation," Technological Forecasting and Social Change. 20,
Products," Management Science. 34 (August), 921-37. 63-87.
Nelder, J. A. (1962), "An Alternative Form of a Generalized and (1982), "Polynomial Innovation Dif-
Logistic Equation." Biometrics. 18 (December), 614-16. fusion Models," Technological Forecasting and Social
Nevers, J. V. (1972), "Extensions of a New Product Growth Change. 21, 301-23.
Model." Sloan Management Review. 13 (Winter), 78-9. Sharp, J. A. (1984), "An Interpretation of the Non-Symmetric
Norton, John A. and Frank M. Bass (1987), "A Diffusion Responding Logistic Model in Terms of Price and Expe-
Theory Model of Adoption and Substitution for Successive rience Effects," Jottrnal of Forecastitig. 3 (4). 453-6,
Generations of High Technology Products," Management Silk, Alvin J. (1966), "Overiap Among Self-Designated Opin-
Science. 33 (September), 1069-86. ion Leaders: A Study of Selected Dental Products and
Oliver. Robert M. (1987), "A Bayesian Model to Predict Sat- Services," Journal of Marketing Research. 3 (August),
uration and Logistic Growth," Journal of the Operations 255-9.
Research Society, 38 (1), 4 9 - 5 6 . Silver, Steven D. (1984), "A Simple Mathematical Theory of
Olshavsky, Richard W. (1980), "Time and the Rale of Adop- Innovative Behavior: A Comment," Journal of Consumer
tion of Innovations," Journal of Consumer Research, 6 Research. 10 (March), 441-4.
(March), 425-8. Simon, Herman and Kari-Heinz Sebastian (1987), "Diffusion
Olson, Jerome A. and Seungmook Choi (1985), "A Product and Advertising: The German Telephone Company." Man-
Diffusion Model Incorporating Repeat Purchases," Tech- agement Science. 33 (April), 451-66.
nological Forecasting and Social Change. 27, 385-97. Skiadas, Christos H. (1985), "Two Generalized Rational Models
Oren. Shmuel S. and Rick G. Schwartz (1988), "Diffusion of for Forecasting Innovation Diffusion." Technological
New Products in Risk-Sensitive Markets," Journal of Fore- Forecasting and Social Change. 27. 39-62.
casting. 7 (October-December), 273-87. (1986), "Innovation Diffusion Models Expressing
Peterson. Robert A. and Vijay Mahajan (1978), "Multi-Prod- Asymmetry and/or Positively or Negatively Influencing
uct Growth Models." in Research in Marketing. J. Sheth, Forces." Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 30
ed. Greenwich. CT: JAI Press, Inc., 201-31. (December), 313-30.
Randies, F. (1983), "On the Diffusion of Computer Terminals Souder. William E. and M. A. Quaddus (1982), "A Decision-
in an Established Engineering Environment," Management Modeling Approach to Forecasting the Diffusion of Long-
Science. 29 (April). 465-76. wail Mining T'echnologies," Technological Forecasting and
Rao, Ambar G. and Masataka Yamada (1988), "Forecasting Social Change. 21. 1-14.
With a Repeat Purchase Diffusion Model," Management Srinivasan. V. and Charlotte H. Mason (1986), "Nonlinear
Science, 34 (June). 734-52. Least Squares Estimation of New Pnxluct Diffusion Mtxlels."
Rao, Ram C. and Frank M. Bass (1985), "Competition, Strat- Marketing Science. 5 (Spring), 169-78.
egy, and Price Dynamics: A Theoretical and Empirical In- Srivastava, Rajendra K.. Vijay Mahajan, Sridhar N. Rama-
vestigation," Journal of Marketing Research, 22 (August), swami. and Joseph Cherian (1985), "A Multi-Attribute Dif-
283-96. fusion Model for Forecasting the Adoption of Investment

New Product Diffusion Models in Marketing / 25


Altematives for Consumers," Technological Forecasting Tigert, Douglas and Behrooz Farivar (1981), "The Bass New
and Social Change, 28 (December), 325-33. Product Growth Model: A Sensitivity Analysis for a High
Stoneman. P. (1981), "Intra-Firm Diffusion. Bayesian Learn- Technology Product." Journal of Marketing, 45 (Fall), 8 1 -
ing and Profitability," Economic Journal, 91 (June), 3 7 5 - 90.
88. Tomatzky, L. G. and R. J. Klein (1982), "Innovation Char-
Sultan. Fareena, John U. Farley, and Donald R. Lehmann acteristics and Innovation Adoption-Implementation: A Meta-
(1990), "A Meta-Analysis of Diffusion Models,' Journal AnaJysis of Findings." IEEE Transactions on Engineering
of Marketing Research, forthcoming. Management. EM-29, 28-45.
Takada, Hirokazu and Dipak Jain (1988), "Cross-National Von Bertalanffy. L. (1957), "Quantitative Laws in Metabo-
Analysis of Diffusion of Consumer Durables," working pa- lism and Growth." Quarterly Review of Biologw 32, 217-
per, Kellogg Graduate School of Business. Northwestern 31.
University. Wildt. Albert R. and Russell S. Winer (1978). "Modeling
Tanny, S. M. and N. A. Derzko (1988). "Innovators and Im- Structural Shifts in Market Response: An Overview." in
itators in Innovation Diffusion Modeling." Journal of Fore- Educator's' Proceedings, S. C. Jain. ed. Chicago: Ameri-
casting. 1 (4), 225-34. can Marketing Association. 96-101.
Teng. Jinn-Tsair and Gerald L. Thompson (1983). "Oligopoly Wilson. Lynn O. and John A. Norton (1989), "Optimal Entry
Models for Optimal Advertising," Management Science, Time for a Product Line Extension," Marketing Science. 8
29 (September), 1087-101. (Winter). 1-17.
Teotia. A. P. S. and P. S. Raju (1986). "Forecasting the Mar- Winer, Russell S. (1985), "A Price Vector Model of Demand
ket Penetration of New Technologies Using a Combination for Consumer Durables: Preliminary Developments," Mar-
of Economic Cost and Diffusion Models," Journal of Prod- keting Science. 4 (Winter), 74-90.
uct Innovation Management. 3 (December). 225-37. Young, Peg and J. Keith Ord (1985), "The Use of Discounted
Thomas, Robert J. (1985). "Estimating Market Growth for New Least-Squares in Technological Forecasting," Technologi-
Products; An Analogical Diffusion M(K1CI Approach," cal Forecasting and Social Change, 28. 263-274.
Journal of Product Innovation Management, 2 (March). 4 5 - Ziemer. Douglas R. (1988), "Marketplace Sizing and Timing
55. Scenarios." working paper. Management Department Cen-
Thompson. Gerald L. and Jinn-Tsair Teng (1984), "Optimal ter. Texas Instruments incorporated, Dallas.
Pricing and Advertising Policies for New Product Oligo-
poly Models," Marketing Science. 3 (Spring), 148-68. Reprint No. JMS4I1M

MARKETING
The peak performer S K I N N E R

Skinner knows the meaning of peak performance and his new text
proves it. More than current, his examples are provocative. They
encourage students to think critically and to debate.
Skinner prepares students fw the future by covering traditional
topics as well as the challenges facing marketers today. Going
beyond the fundamentals, he addresses marketing essentials that
renect the agenda of a generation on the verge of the 21st century-
Internal marketing Internationa! marketing
Europe in 1992 Ethics
Peak performance Service quaiity
Changing demographics
to prepare students fully for the opportunities that await them.
Skinner ateo provide an innovative support package that tncluc
among many otl>er items, mmmtmim M k M i i I B f e l
E i * ^ and 3 V d ' CreaWd for those who create the future
paciage Ironi your Hougtiton MtSiin regional oKtce

MARKETING ^<^ Houghton Mifflin


13400 Midway Rd..Odiias.TX 75244-5165
1900 S. Baiavia Ave.. Gerveva. IL 60134
STEVEN J. SKINNER Univetsity of Kentucky 925 MeddowDf,Paii3Alto,CA94303
101 Campus Dr. Princeion. NJ 08540

26 / Journal of Marketing, January 1990

Potrebbero piacerti anche