Sei sulla pagina 1di 10

ARTICLE IN PRESS

Energy Policy 37 (2009) 47874796

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Energy Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/enpol

Energy saving and energy efciency concepts for policy making


V. Oikonomou a,, F. Becchis b, L. Steg c, D. Russolillo d
a
SOM, University of Groningen, PO Box 800, 9700 AV Groningen, the Netherlands
b
POLIS Department, University of East Piedmont, via Duomo, 6-13100 Vercelli, Italy
c
Faculty of Behavioural and Social Sciences, University of Groningen, P.O. Box 72 9700 AB, the Netherlands
d
Fondazione per l Ambiente T. Fenoglio, Via Gaudenzio Ferrari 1, I-10124 Torino, Italy

a r t i c l e in fo abstract

Article history: Departing from the concept of rational use of energy, the paper outlines the microeconomics of end-use
Received 9 March 2009 energy saving as a result of frugality or efciency measures. Frugality refers to the behaviour that is
Accepted 9 June 2009 aimed at energy conservation, and with efciency we refer to the technical ratio between energy input
Available online 5 July 2009
and output services that can be modied with technical improvements (e.g. technology substitution).
Keywords: Changing behaviour from one side and technology from the other are key issues for public energy policy.
Energy saving In this paper, we attempt to identify the effects of parameters that determine energy saving behaviour
Energy efciency with the use of the microeconomic theory. The role of these parameters is crucial and can determine the
Energy policy outcome of energy efciency policies; therefore policymakers should properly address them when
designing policies.
& 2009 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction In many policy cases, energy efciency improvement is set as


an environmental target with strong assumptions on the
Energy efciency is a term widely used, often with different rationality of end-users and their responsiveness to price signals,
meanings in public policy making. A clear distinction between while such ex-ante assumptions should be veried with ex-post
energy efciency and energy conservation is that the former refers data, already appearing in the literature. Naturally, rationality of
to adoption of a specic technology that reduces overall energy energy behaviour can be related to more parameters, as for
consumption without changing the relevant behaviour, while the instance effort, status, income, and many others. Energy efciency
latter implies merely a change in consumers behaviour. In policy instruments are mostly designed based on a normative
psychology, this has been labelled as efciency and curtailment perspective of market behaviour of economic actors, which are
behaviour (Gardner and Stern, 2002). Many aspects and inuen- assumed to receive the market signals and act on the grounds of
cing parameters on the total outcome of an energy system, from their own rationality. Still, the economic rationality in energy use
the demand and the supply side, have to be taken into and energy saving behaviours is an often entangled topic and
consideration, hence energy efciency improvement estimation depends on various parameters.
demands analytical processes. In this respect, economic literature The purpose of this paper is to identify the relationships
has frequently taken as given the microeconomic parameters between various economic variables that determine the behaviour
affecting energy efciency and energy conservation (Howarth and towards energy efciency. More specically, departing from the
Andersson, 1993; Sanstad and Howarth, 1994; IEA, 1997; Mintel microeconomic theory, we attempt to unveil some parameters
International Group Ltd., 1997; Howarth et al., 2000; Clinch et al., that should be taken into account by social planners, when
2000; Poortinga et al., 2003; Sorrell, 2004; Bor, 2008). Never- designing policies for energy efciency improvement.
theless, actual practice demonstrates that economic and techno- The structure of this paper is as follows. In Section 2, we
logical assumptions (of perfect information and absence of provide some basic denitions of somehow overlapping concepts
transaction costs) on these parameters do not necessarily hold of energy savings and energy efciency. Section 3 refers to a
in the market, which shifts energy efciency patterns (Jaffe and microeconomic analysis of energy saving, rational use of energy,
Stavins, 1994). Policymakers often decide on specic policies and energy services, and the effects of time into energy savings.
instruments on the ground of standardized assumptions of energy Furthermore, Section 4 deals solely with microeconomics
use and energy saving behaviour of end-users. of energy efciency, incorporating concepts of rebound effects,
real and shadow energy demand, the effects of time dimension
in energy efciency. Section 5 provides a discussion on energy
 Corresponding author. Tel.: +31 645380712. saving and energy efciency components as economic value
E-mail addresses: vlasis@jiqweb.org, v.oikonomou@rug.nl (V. Oikonomou). reservoirs. Finally, in Section 6, we wrap up our theoretical

0301-4215/$ - see front matter & 2009 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2009.06.035
ARTICLE IN PRESS
4788 V. Oikonomou et al. / Energy Policy 37 (2009) 47874796

analysis and come up with some recommendations for policy The function f corresponds to an overall set of technology
making. transformation processes and to the related boundary conditions
in which these processes develop in order to accomplish energy
end-uses in dened environments (houses, ofces, etc.). One can
2. Denitions omit the formalization of the relationship between these
processes, the conditions of the dened environments and
In this section, we provide a general overview of the terms met services produced, because investigating technology transforma-
in the literature of energy efciency, which can often overlap and tion functions, is out of the scope of the paper that is instead
create confusion. Consumer behaviour and lifestyle choices are focused on the combined effect of energy conservation and energy
strongly related to the concept of the rational use of energy, the efciency actions.
end-use (nal) energy saving and the end-use energy efciency. At a second step, we express the nal consumption as a
Energy savings and energy efciency refer to two microeconomic function of energy services (Eq. (1))
situations, which deserve to be differentiated. Energy efciency 1
concerns the technical ratio between the quantity of primary or Qe f Qs (2)
nal energy consumed and the maximum quantity of energy The same function, with the strong assumption of linearity, can
services obtainable (heating, lighting, cooling, mobility, and be expressed as
others), whilst end-use energy saving addresses the reduction of
nal energy consumption, through energy efciency improve- Qe bQs (3)
ment or behavioural change. where b is the technical parameter expressing the conversion
In many studies, the energy conservation concept refers to the efciency of technologies in which we can add a disturbance
reduction of energy consumption associated with a frugal lifestyle factor, thus enabling us to take human behaviour into considera-
that includes a form of regulation (i.e. speed limitations, reduced tion
domestic heating, and so on) or spontaneous changes in
Qe bQs u (4)
consumers preferences resulting in behavioural changes. This
concept often implies a more moral aspect of behaviour rather where u is the exogenous variable related to human behaviour and
than a strictly economic one, since effort is required from the end- to organisational processes (measured in GJ of energy used).
users side in order to engage in energy saving. An extensive Eq. (4) practically implies that nal energy end-use is
literature review on the matter of sufciency can be found in dependent on demand for energy services but forecasting its
Alcott (2008) and on sustainable consumption in Jackson (2007). evolution must take into account social parameters. In particular,
Nevertheless, energy conservation can be enhanced via changes in it can be noted that the linear relationship expressed with the
the context (including regulations and energy price increases) and parameter b, between the quantity of end-use energy consumed
changes in motivations of people (including environmental and the quantity of services obtained, is reasonable if we consider
concerns, and feelings of moral obligation to reduce energy non-linear relationships as linearized (i.e. linear approximations):
consumption). An exhaustive literature survey on the matter can the rst derivative of the linear approximation is a multiple-step
be found in Herring (2004) and Steg (2008). Policies in this aspect function where the base of each step is the linearization range
can target either investments towards energy-efcient goods (as that has to be dened accordingly to each technology transforma-
for instance subsidies) or behavioural changes (feed-in tariffs for tion. As stated before, the in-depth investigation of the technology
energy savings, see Bertoldi et al. (2009)), or both. transformation is out of the scope of the paper, but it may indeed
In this study, strictly conned to the eld of end-use energy represent an interesting development for further research, for
demand, the two concepts of energy savings and energy efciency instance focused on a specic sector like household appliances.
are used in a specic and distinct way. In some cases, never- In the short-term, with given domestic technologies, para-
theless, the energy saving concept is also used with its general and meter b is exogenous. Nevertheless, as shown later, it is affected
widespread meaning such as the reduction of energy consump- by investments in energy efciency and endogenized in the
tion. As mentioned above, in this paper, strictly energy end-uses model. Moreover, this parameter depends on the considered
are considered: complex efciency implications in the upstream sector (heating, lighting, cooling, mobility, and others). Hence, a
phases of transformation, transmission, and distribution are family of sectoral parameters can be imagined: ba, bb, bc, bd, y, bn.
beyond the scope of this paper. Subsets of parameters in the same sector can be expressed as
follows: ba1, ba2, ba3, y, bam (for example, different kinds of lamps
in the lighting sector).
3. Microeconomics of energy saving The exogenous term u expresses the effect of human behaviour
and the organisational practices on end-use energy. For instance,
In this section, we present the basic microeconomic variables the attention paid to switch off lights left carelessly on, the
and functions of energy saving, which describe the parameters regulation of heating or cooling, the personal driving style, the
inuencing positively or negatively energy saving trends. These usage of a certain device, the habit of managing indoor air comfort
functions are built upon energy services, energy savings, and the conditions with outdoor air (opening doors and windows). This
effect of time horizon on energy efciency. parameter gains signicant attention by policymakers and should
be always targeted by policy instruments. The values of this
3.1. Energy services parameter are quite hard to quantify and they depend on the
types of services (for instance, in cheaper technologies where
In order to analyze energy savings and energy efciency, we energy saving is not very obvious, this parameter is expected
start from a very basic model on energy services expressed in the much higher than in more expensive technologies). Here, we
following function: make use of a typical rationalist information decit model1

Qs f Qe (1)
1
Rational information decit model supposes that energy savings can be
where Qs is the required energy services (measured in GJ) and Qe promoted by informing people about the need to do so as well as ways and means
the nal consumption of energy (measured in GJ). to achieve that. The main assumption here is that a lack of knowledge prevents
ARTICLE IN PRESS
V. Oikonomou et al. / Energy Policy 37 (2009) 47874796 4789

(Burgess et al., 1998) in order to explain this behaviour, but we terms of energy use, this theory takes as granted that people make
also acknowledge and take into account, at a very small extent, planned, rational decisions (based on a typical cost-benet
parameters that determine the behaviour, beyond market failures: rationality approach) and that behavioural choices are motivated
awareness, trust, and commitment, moral obligation, cultural by self-interest (in terms of hassle, time, and social approval). An
norms, routine practices, and habits, social networks and fashion alternative explanation is provided by the value-belief-norm
(Owens and Drifll, 2008). In other words, Eq. (4) demonstrates theory (Stern, 2000) stating the general values of people
that the energy services obtained Qs are not equal to those determine environmentally oriented behaviour. Such values are
maximum obtainable using a given quantity of nal energy Qe, categorized in egoistic (concern for own self), altruistic (concern
because a part of this energy savings is wasted through careless or for others), and biospheric (concern for the biosphere). Based on
thoughtless behaviour.2 This behaviour still could be explained by this theory, energy saving measures are accepted by the public
the social dilemma theory,3 since reducing effort can be an when they have strong altruistic and biospheric values (Poortinga
individual benet but not a collective one. To this end, if costs of et al., 2004; De Groot and Steg, 2008). More specically, values
individual benets are lower than collective ones, maybe in a inuence awareness of energy problems and the extent to which
normative aspect, people can choose for the former, and this can individuals feel responsible for these problems, which in turn
lead to negative externalities as social costs are not incorporated inuence feelings of moral obligation to do something about it
in private costs decisions. Policies based on this principle fall are and increase the acceptability of energy policies (Steg et al., 2005).
mostly information campaigns, as imposing a cost on individual In our model, the variable u in Eq. (4) is tied up to costs that an
behaviours does not necessarily lead to common action, while end-user must sustain in order to eliminate unnecessary con-
internalizing the common benet by proper information in sumption. In this paper, we group together these costs in a
individual decisions concerning energy use can indeed lead to variable that we name effort (s). This variable represents the
energy savings in the long-run. Alternative policies that can target disutility associated with virtuous behaviours of energy saving,
at a certain extent this social dilemma could involve a form of essentially in terms of opportunity cost of time (the time
market trading, where negotiations in the form of price arrange- necessary to acquire information and apply it to individual
ment for energy saving take place, as for instance, in case of White behaviours and organisational practices), as well as costs of effort,
Certicates (WhC). As shown later, energy saving affects nal discomfort, and reduced status. It can be measured in utils
energy consumption through this factor (u), whilst energy originating from cardinal utility in quantiable terms (Varian,
efciency acts upon the parameter b. To this respect, our analysis 2003).
focuses on the concept of nal energy savings and parameters that As with all forms of disutility, an end-user can be disposed of
inuence them. In the next section, we explain more in-depth sustaining a certain level of effort s in exchange for compensation.
how the exogenous variable u manifests and produces its effects. The compensation that best ts our case is represented by the
return in terms of income (Y) (expressed in h), which is the main
reward (in terms of monetary savings in energy bill) for those who
3.2. Energy saving save energy. Nevertheless, we acknowledge that more psycholo-
gical compensation parameters beyond the nancial one trigger
We already specied that energy saving reduces the unneces- energy saving effort (for instance, feeling proud or being praised
sary nal energy consumption which does not correspond to the for doing the correct thing). The compensation can be stimulated
production of utility and services. The fact that this unnecessary furthermore by policy, when a direct reward for the energy saved
consumption emerges as a by-product of the required consump- on a short-term basis takes place (e.g. monthly) in order to
tion is not completely new in the economic theory of rational provide the correct stimulation of longer-term energy saving
behaviour. In fact, levelling the energy consumption to the exact behaviour and adaptation of energy needs (otherwise, if the
minimum quantity necessary in order to obtain the desired nancial reward is applied on a yearly for instance basis, end-
energy services is not a costless activity. On the contrary, it users miss the insight of their actual daily consumption and
requires a noticeable effort in terms of resources and information. cannot easily adapt their behaviour in the following period). Fig. 1
As a result, an end-user can simply not desire to undertake this represents the indifference curves (u1, u2, u3) between effort and
effort, even at the cost of consuming more energy than necessary. return. These curves demonstrate that the higher the bill
The drivers behind the motivation of a consumer towards reduction, the higher the willingness to invest in energy saving
saving energy from a psychological perspective are explained in a effort in order to achieve this reduction.
study by Abrahamse (2007), which employs the theory of planned Economic theory dictates that on any indifference curve the
behaviour and the value-belief-norm theory. The theory of utility of the consumer does not vary; hence the slope of the
planned behaviour assumes that attitudes, subjective norms and indifference curve indicates the incremental return that is able to
perceived behavioural control determine intentions, which can compensate an end-user for an incremental effort of energy
predict behaviour (Ajzen, 1985; Ajzen and Fishbein, 1980). In saving, maintaining the constant overall utility. The linearity of
the functions is justied with the hypothesis that, in return,
interval values dened by the possibility of saving energy, the
(footnote continued)
people from acting pro-environmentally. Nevertheless, we acknowledge that many
marginal preferences do not change. The arrow indicates the
studies have revealed increasing knowledge is not sufcient to promote energy preference direction with increased levels of utility.
savings, so this model is not validated in several studies. One more intuitive way of representing the indifference curves
2
An important clarication is that the exogenous term u should not be between effort and monetary compensation is to take into
confused with the much documented rebound effect, which is exclusively
account the overall energy bill rather than the return
dependent on income and substitution effects.
3
The social dilemma theory explains situations in which private interests are B QePe
at odds (e.g. comfort and convenience) with collective ones (e.g. environmental
quality). Social dilemmas are dened by two properties: (a) each person has an where B is the total energy bill for end-user, also incorporating the
individual rational strategy with a best pay-off, when not cooperating, at least in avoided income return (expressed in h); Pe the end-use electricity
the short-term. However, if everyone acts at their own interest, collective interests
will be seriously harmed. To this end, the second property (b) assumes that if all
price.
individuals pursue this strategy it results in a decient collective outcome, hence Fig. 2 shows how an energy end-user exchanges incremental
everybody would be better off if they had cooperated. efforts with the reduction in energy bills, the slope being the
ARTICLE IN PRESS
4790 V. Oikonomou et al. / Energy Policy 37 (2009) 47874796

Fig. 3. Technical function of energy saving.


Fig. 1. Indifference curves between effort of energy savings (s) and income (Y).
So far, we dened the preferences of an end-user with respect
to the disutility of the effort and the utility of energy bill
reduction, and the moral happiness of reducing a collective
environmental and energy problem. However, it is necessary to
examine how the effort of energy saving inuences its effective
energy consumption. In other words, to investigate the function of
the production of energy saving, expressed by the technical
relationship between the effort (the time dedicated to the
acquisition of information and to its application in generating ES
behaviours) and the result, i.e. the reduction of nal energy
consumption.
A technical function, represented in Fig. 3, expresses the
relationship between the effort of saving energy (s) made by
subjects with virtuous behaviour, and the results in terms of
monetary savings in energy bills (B), with energy services being
equal. In other words, it unveils the opportunity cost of investing
in a new energy saving technology to paying a higher bill for
energy consumption. The values of both costs can be compared
when discounted, since the upfront cost of an energy saving
technology does not entail any immediate prot in the short-run.
If the relationship is linear then for each h decrease of the energy
bill a sacrice of one util is required (increased effort, which can
also be translated as a h increase of the investments in energy
saving technologies).
The prole of the curve reminds us, intuitively, that when we
start from a situation in which no care is taken in energy
consumption, thus ending with a maximum energy bill (Bmax),
interesting marginal energy savings can be obtained with little
Fig. 2. Indifference curves between the effort of energy saving (s) and energy bill effort. In this case, the marginal cost of saving energy increases.
(B). This is the standard rule with marginal abatement costs, where
under no effort cheaper abatement options are present and
these costs increase along the marginal abatement cost curve
marginal rate of substitution, here given as a constant due to the (Tietenberg, 2000). In other words, the results of the effort of
relative little impact of energy bill saving on income and energy saving continuously decrease, until they become insignif-
preferences. Fig. 2 also represents an interesting case of icant (levelling of the technical function) and approach the
indifference curves between two bads, instead of the usual technically minimum possible level of nal energy consumption,
representation between two goods. In other words, the end- the required energy services being equal, which corresponds to
user faces the trade-off of reducing energy bill and putting in the minimum energy bill (Bmin). To enhance energy savings below
effort for saving energy, where, based on these curves there are the intersection, as to change the optimal levels of energy savings,
indifference points because of the small impact of bill saving on specic incentive policies are required, targeting at reducing the
preferences. sunk costs of an investment.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
V. Oikonomou et al. / Energy Policy 37 (2009) 47874796 4791

energy savings, but also moral aspects such as environmental


quality and future generations. The substitution rates indicated in
Fig. 4 are likely to vary with goal strength, that is, when normative
goals are strongest, substitution rates are likely to be lower as
compared to situations in which gain or hedonic goals are
strongest. In many cases people are tempted to act on the grounds
of personal interest, while collective interests play a less
important role. However, some people do take into account moral
considerations and thus collective objectives. Energy savings will
generally follow such collective concerns (since the benets in
energy bills are generally low) and this can be explained as moral
normative behaviour. Similar concerns on moral social concerns
and pro-environmental behaviour (including energy savings) are
raised by De Groot and Steg (2008). A study of Abrahamse (2007)
unveiled that household energy use is related to socio-demo-
graphic variables (Brandon and Lewis, 1999; Gatersleben et al.,
2002), which are completely different from the drivers of energy
savings. For instance, households with higher incomes or larger in
size often use more energy, while psychological variables are less
adequate to explain energy consumption patterns, since the latter
are determined by socioeconomic barriers and opportunities.
Nevertheless, from a different angle, households with higher
income can relatively promote easier energy saving measures (e.g.
Fig. 4. Technical function of energy saving and indifference curves between effort purchasing-efcient technologies or installing insulation domes-
of energy saving (s) and energy bills (B). tically). Results for intention to conserve energy detect a direct
association with psychological factors, whereas socio-demo-
graphic characteristics do hardly come into play. Especially,
Combining indifference curves between return and effort and attitudes towards energy conservation and perceived behavioural
the technical function enables us to represent the optimal choices control could explain the variance in intention to conserve energy.
of energy saving, which is found at the point of the curves To this end, higher levels of perceived behavioural control and
intersections. positive attitudes towards energy conservation can drive towards
In Fig. 4, the three linear functions represent three proles of greater energy savings. Behavioural control and attitude change
an indifference curve. The three proles correspond to three can also be triggered by policies of self-monitoring, such as
hypothetical subject groups, characterized by different introduction of smart metering in the market, where end-users
preferences, represented by different substitution rates between can be aware of their actual energy behaviour and in the medium
effort and return. Every group makes more of an effort in ES until long-run get adapted to modifying this behaviour or reducing
the point of equilibrium, where the marginal cost of the effort is unnecessary energy use.
equal to the marginal benet.
To this respect, different levels of energy saving correspond to
3.3. Energy saving and time
different structures of end-users preferences. The group with the
greater substitution rate between return and effort, for example,
manifests little effort, equal to s3 , which is completely reasonable Based on the denition used for the choices of energy saving in
when taking into account that this group associates a high cost to this paper and considering the typical approach of cost-benet
the effort (indifference curve with a bigger slope); on the contrary, analyses, the cost of the effort and the benet in terms of nancial
the group with a lower substitution rate between return and effort savings through reduced bills can be considered like two
will manifest a higher effort level, equal to s1, justied by the instantaneous ows (the time lapse between the two ows
relatively low cost that this group associates with the effort can be measured in a few weeks, indeed a negligible lapse of time
(indifference curve with a small slope). for actualization purposes). Thus, the cost of time can be
Based on this reasoning, we form Eq. (4), which shows that disregarded as one can imagine that the subject does not apply
different levels of s generate different levels of energy bills and to the end-users own choices by any actualization of the cost and
thus of energy saving, when incorporating the value of the benet ows. The same does not apply to energy efciency as a
exogenous variable u. result of investment in new equipments with a life cycle of several
years and corresponding nancial returns in terms of reduced
ES Bmax  Bn =Pe (5) bills.
An important point with this respect is derived from the goal-
framing theory (Lindenberg and Steg, 2007). Because energy
savings generally imply that people have to give up personal 4. Microeconomics of energy efciency
advantages (e.g. comfort) in order to reach a collective goal
(security of energy supply and reduction of GHG emissions), it is In this section, we deal exclusively with issues concerning
unlikely that people will be triggered to save energy solely based energy efciency, differentiating from the background of energy
on individual benet discounting. However, people do not only savings. More specically, we refer to the relationship between
strive for maximising individual benets. The goal-framing theory energy efciency and the rebound effect, the real and shadow
proposes that three goals govern behaviour: hedonic goals to feel energy demand, and on the inuence of time horizon on energy
better right now, a gain goal-frame to guard and improve ones efciency. Similar to the Section 3, we identify variables and
resources, and a normative goal-frame to act appropriately. functions that determine the behaviour towards energy efciency
This implies that people not only consider comfort and costs of improvement.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
4792 V. Oikonomou et al. / Energy Policy 37 (2009) 47874796

4.1. Energy efciency and rebound effects i.e. the decrease of the price of the energy service cannot be
predetermined, since the price of the other factors of produc-
In principle, end-use energy efciency concerns the technical tion might increase (Quirion, 2004).
relationship between the maximum quantity of obtainable  Economy wide effects: Market clearance adjustments (espe-
services (for instance, heating, lighting, cooling, mobility, etc.) cially in fuel markets). These effects consist of the change of
and behavioural changes (for instance, people purchase an the market equilibrium in energy supply and demand relation-
efcient technology that has to be used appropriately) and the ships (and all the factors that they entail, i.e. consumer
quantity of end-use energy consumed. This relationship depends preferences) as a result of the shift of the determinants
on all conversion processes, which transform end-use energy in affecting one energy efcient good.
services and on the boundary conditions of the processes and of  Transformational effects: Changes in technology may also
the end-uses. In other words, similar to Eq. (3), end-use energy change the consumers preferences and introduce new produc-
efciency can be dened as tion techniques that transform the organization of production.
These effects could result in a change in energy consumption
X
n X
n
from the consumers or producers.
Qei bi Qsi
i1 i1
P
where in 1Qei is the total amount of end-use energy consumed Most studies cover in principle the substitution and income
Pn
from all services and i 1biQsi the total quantity of energy effects, since the other effects are difcult to isolate (Hertwich,
services with all relevant conversion efciencies. 2005). Table 1 presents some indicative aggregate rebound effect
Every improvement in energy efciency is reected in a results from several studies and Table 2, some results of
decrease in the relative unit price of energy services (hence, in disaggregated energy efciency measures that could be taken
the price of energy services in relation to the prices of other into account for the effect of measures implemented due to
goods), when investment costs for end-users can have a relatively energy efciency policies.
short payback period (e.g. 5 years for energy saving technologies). Greening and Greene (1998) present a review of 75 estimates
For instance, mobility and cooling have been strongly inuenced of the rebound in the existing literature. These estimates stem
by the decrease in the relative price of end-use energy for unit of from econometric analysis and direct measurements and are
consumption (km and GJ). The economic literature refers to this measured in terms of fuel efciency of specic energy measure
reaction as the direct rebound effect, a similar concept of rather than energy consumption. The key ndings are presented
substitution effect in microeconomics (Ruzzenenti and Basosi, in Table 2.5
2008; Binswanger, 2001; Greening et al., 2000; Haas and The inelastic short-term demand nature of energy use can
Biermayr, 2000; Milne and Boardman, 2000; Bentzen, 2004; increase the use of the energy service that raises the energy
Hertwich, 2003, Herring, 2004; Brannlund et al., 2007). The demanded; hence no actual savings are generated. A practical
rebound effect could be explained from the following causal example can be with a user that exchanges his/her boiler for one
chain: an increase in energy efciency tends to lower the marginal with improved efciency. As a result, the price of one unit of heat
costs of using an energy service4 (Quirion, 2004). will decrease with respect to the price of the other goods. For the
The rebound effect in quantiable terms can be dened as the substitution effect and the income effect this could increase the
ratio of energy savings after the installation of the energy-efcient demand for heating (and thus end-use energy), with a paradoxical
appliances/energy savings without the new energy-efcient result i.e. an increase in consumption caused by an improvement
devices. Greening et al. (2000) distinguished the rebound effect in efciency (although a saturation point exists, which is
between the following: depending on the energy service at stake). The rebound effect in
quantiable terms can be dened as the ratio of energy savings
 Direct rebound effects: The direct effects are the microeconomic after the installation of the energy-efcient appliances to the
price effects that consist of the substitution and income effect. autonomous energy savings without the new energy-efcient
The substitution effect refers to the increase of demand for the devices. In general, the relative decrease in end-use energy price
use of an energy service when its price decreases, as an also has an income effect: higher real spending capacity can push
effect of energy efciency, given the same utility. The income for higher consumption in several energy-consuming goods
effect occurs when the available income increases as a and services, which is frequently called as indirect rebound
result of the reduced price of the energy service that leads to effect. Furthermore, when energy efciency is encompassed in
expenses towards other energy-consuming appliances or uses. pervasive new technologies, in particular, in production processes,
(Hertwich, 2005). Gatersleben et al. (2002) and Steg (1999) the rebound effect can became backre effect, resulting in an
found that income is one of the predictors of household energy increase of energy consumption due to efciency (the so-called
use, indicating that indeed people tend to spend more money KhazzoomBrookes effect). As a whole, substitution and income
on energy as soon as they can afford it. effects have been estimated in the range 1030% of the estimated
 Secondary effects: From the producers side, increased energy energy saving through energy efciency improvement (UK Energy
efciency measures can result in the reduction of the Research Center, 2007).
production costs, which in turn can lead to reduction of the In Fig. 5, an improvement in energy efciency is represented by
price of the energy service and an increase in their total a shift down and to the left of the technical function that links
quantity supplied. In the following equilibrium, the market effort to energy bills. When energy efciency improves, the effort
demand for this energy service will increase reducing, hence being equal, one can obtain considerably greater results in terms
the expected effects from the policy-induced energy savings. of energy consumption. Trivially, one can imagine an end-user
However, this market procedure depends on other parameters, who produces an effort s1 to switch off lights in areas where light
is not needed, thus obtaining a monetary reduction up to B1 (in
the point where the marginal cost of effort is equal to the
4
Energy services could be dened as a commodity that is demanded, i.e. hot
water, refrigeration, heat, etc. In order to produce this commodity energy is
5
needed, alongside with other production factors, like capital, labor and manage- All these rebound effect estimates assume a 10% increase in fuel-consump-
ment. tion efciency.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
V. Oikonomou et al. / Energy Policy 37 (2009) 47874796 4793

Table 1
Empirical studies presenting aggregate rebound effects.

Study Content Results

Khazoom (1986) Electricity-heated homes in Sacramento, CA Long-run REf of 65%


Dubin et al. (1986) Households participating in a program of improving the efciency of home heating REf between 8% and 13%
Dinan (1987) Households whose dwellings were weatherized REf small but statistically
signicant
Hirst (1987) Evaluation of Residential Weatherization program throughout the Pacic NW, comparison REf between 5% and 25%
of the behavior of participants with non-participants
Bentzen (2004) US manufacturing energy consumption REf around 24%
Laitner (2000) US REf around 23%
Davis (2004) Evidence from eld trials of a front loading clothes washer for 104 households REf around 5.6%
Schipper and Grubb (2000) Reviewing of studies covering 8090% of energy use in OECD countries REf between 5% and 15%
Berkhout et al. (2000) Studies estimating the effect of energy taxes in the Netherlands REf between 0% and 15%
Haas and Biermayr (2000) Space heating in Austria REf between 20% and 30%
Sorrell et al. (2009) Personal transport in Europe REf around 10%
Schwarz and Taylor (1995) Heating in households in US REf between 1.4% and 3.4%
Douthitt (1986) Heating in households in Canada Long-run REf 3560%
Haas et al. (1998) Heating in households in Austria REf around 1548%
Guertin et al. (2003) Heating in households in Canada REf around 2947%
Nesbakken (2001) Heating households in Norway REf around 21%
Klein (1987) Heating households in US REf between 25% and 29%
Dubin et al. (1986) Space cooling in households in US REf between 1% and 26%

Source: adapted from Binswanger (2001) and Sorrell et al. (2009).

Table 2
Overview of 75 studies on the rebound effect according to sectors and energy
services.

Sector Energy service Rebound effect estimate (%)

Consumers
Space heating 1030
Space cooling 050
Water heating 1040
Residential lighting 512
Appliances white goods 0

Firms
Process uses (short-run) 020
Lighting (short-run) 02
Long-run aggregate impacts

Economy wide effects


Change in total output growth 0.48

Source: (Greening et al., 2000).

marginal benet in terms of monetary reduction of electricity


bills). By installing uorescent lights which are considerably more
efcient, the same subject with the same effort s1 could obtain a
reduction in bills to the level B3. However, in the new conditions, it
is better for an end-user to reduce the effort level to s2 (in the new
point where the marginal cost of effort is equal to the marginal Fig. 5. Energy saving and energy efciency.
benet in terms of the reduction in energy bills), thus obtaining
an electricity bill equal to B2 lower than the initial one, a fact that
precisely recalls the rebound effect. The increase in efciency normative goals are more likely to keep on putting effort in energy
therefore allows, in a certain way, a double dividend for the conservation actions, because this is still the right thing to do.
consumer: less effort in energy saving and, simultaneously, less Even if the theory suggests relating the rst category to high
money spent on energy bills. The trade-off between effort and income and the second category to lower income end-users,
energy bill saving, when an increase in efciency is present intuitively the reality appears rather more complex.
at-work, will depend on the prole of the indifference curves:
consumers who attribute a very high disutility to the effort will
reduce it substantially, and vice versa, consumers with a marginal 4.2. Real and shadow energy demand
utility of income relatively high with respect to the effort, will
choose to limit their bills further. Especially,. people with strong End-use energy demand is a function of the price of energy,
hedonic goals will be tempted to reduce their efforts to conserve given the technology used and end-users preferences. This
energy (as this makes them feel good), while people with strong relationship is explained in Eq. (6).
ARTICLE IN PRESS
4794 V. Oikonomou et al. / Energy Policy 37 (2009) 47874796

nies (ESCOs) can use and can plan their commercial strategies
upon. Alternatively, policy schemes that address nancing options
for such actions could be set in place, which could enable
investments of more expensive energy saving projects and
overcome nancial and other market barriers faced by end-users.

4.3. Energy efciency and time

Differently from the case of ES, in the choices of new


equipment that generates end-use energy efciency the time
factor plays an important role. The temporal distribution of costs
and benets is considerably different, with strong initial invest-
ments and multiannual return ows. The discount rate used in the
evaluation of investments in EE affects the actual value of the
shaded area in Fig. 6.

5. Energy saving and energy efciency as value reservoirs

Both energy efciency and energy saving in the end-uses can


be considered as potential reservoirs of resources extractable
through actions and investments. The economic value contained
in these pools can be subdivided in two components:

1. Private economic value
2. Public economic value

The rst component represents the reward for actions and


investments in energy efciency. The economic analysis should, in
addition to quantifying the deposits of this value, identify the
reasons that lead to a greater or lesser exploitation in different
markets, geographical, and regulation conditions. With efcient
and well-functioning markets, these deposits should be attractive
to companies that identify, quantify, and exploit them, bringing
energy savings and energy efciency to optimal levels from the
Fig. 6. Real and shadow energy demand and energy efciency.
point of view of utility and private prots. The second component
concerns externalities and public goods associated with end-use
De f Pe (6)
energy consumption, such as air pollution, security of supply, and
where De is the end-use energy demand. the continuity of service. Combined energy efciency and
Consumers are interested in energy services (Qs) that end-use environmental policies, if properly ne-tuned with minimum or
energy can supply (heating, lighting, cooling, mobility, other); no overlaps, can address both issues simultaneously, where with
these services are connected to the quantity of end-use energy by the same actions (energy saving) private economic value can be
a previously introduced technical parameter (Eq. (1)). increased and adverse environmental effects minimized. Such
Fig. 6 outlines the relationship between end-use energy could be the hypothetical case, for instance, of quota schemes on
demand, the energy services and the shadow end-use energy the purchase of clean energy, with a parallel benet on the
demand, throughout the effects of improvement in efciency. decrease of energy demand.
Given the demand curve D and the price p1, the quantity Qe1 of It is necessary to highlight the fact that the relationship
requested nal energy is related to the quantity Qs1 of energy between energy policies and externalities, in particular environ-
services obtained, according to the technical function with mental externalities, can have distorted effects. For instance, the
parameter b1. With an improvement in efciency, represented rebound effect signals that a policy based on the dissemination of
by the rotation of the technical function in an anti-clockwise energy efciency could bring, in the medium to long-term, an
direction (b2), the same quantity Qs1 of energy services can be increase in consumption and therefore emissions, with opposite
obtained with a smaller quantity Qe2 of nal energy, which effects to those desired in any environmental strategy.
constitutes the shadow end-use energy demand of the Paradoxically, in order to avoid that the private gains derived
consumer. The curve of the shadow demand (Ds) is built, with from energy efciency are shifted towards increased consumption
respect to the curve of real demand (D), following the (of energy or other goods, with a consequent elimination of the
correspondence between every possible energy price and the environmental potential of energy efciency), the necessity to
quantity of nal energy strictly necessary (Qe2), with an move the gains of end-users, with some form of public policy,
improvement in efciency in order to obtain the desired level of towards investments in natural capital should be addressed
energy services. (Wackernagel and Rees, 1997). Only in these conditions the public
The shaded area represents the monetary savings in the energy environmental value of energy efciency could be completely
bill potentially associable to the improvement in energy efciency. exploited. Naturally, the proposed correction requires us to
These savings are, with respect to the social energy efciency address the problem of the energy efciency incentive with
value, the private economic benet that Energy Service Compa- private subjects that would see their return reduced from an
ARTICLE IN PRESS
V. Oikonomou et al. / Energy Policy 37 (2009) 47874796 4795

energy taxation policy or an increase in energy price, nancing also moral aspects such as environmental quality and future
new investments. generations. Questionnaire study data has revealed that although
Broadly speaking, it seems that every policy on end-use energy higher income groups can consume more energy and theoretically
efciency should be coupled with policies aimed at raising the can afford to invest more in energy efciency, there is a direct
cost of energy through Pigouvian taxes or tradable rights markets, association between intention to conserve energy and psycholo-
which could compensate the rebound effect setting nal prices gical factors, whereas socio-demographic characteristics do
nearer to the social cost of economic choices. Another strategy for hardly come into play. To this end, higher levels of perceived
energy efciency policy is moralization, which implies convincing behavioural control and positive attitudes towards energy con-
people that they should protect collective environmental qualities servation can drive towards greater energy savings. Behavioural
(despite it may also involve some individual costs), and that their control and attitude change can also be triggered by policies of
contribution will be socially helpful. self-monitoring, such as introduction of smart metering in the
market.
A third aspect we explored is the rebound effect, which is a
6. Conclusions and outlook typical income effect and originates from the increased energy
efciency that allows a double dividend for the end-user: less
Microeconomic analysis of private behaviour in relation to effort in energy saving and, simultaneously, less money spent on
end-use energy demand and consumption gives rational founda- energy bills and more space for increased energy use in the future.
tions to the outline and implementation of public energy The trade-off between effort and energy bill saving, when an
efciency policy instruments. The present analysis suggests a increase in efciency is present at-work, will depend on the
theoretical framework in which private choices in energy overall perception towards energy saving: consumers who
conservation and energy efciency are explained in terms of attribute a very high disutility to the effort will reduce it
private preferences and costs: in this cadre they produce sensitively, and vice versa, consumers with a marginal utility of
controversial effects, mainly for rebound phenomena. Still, the income relatively high with respect to the effort, will choose to
economic rationality in energy use and energy conservation is limit their bills further. Energy policy on efciency should be
often debated and depends on various parameters. integrated with nancial or market-based policies, which can
Initially, we differentiated between the concepts of energy minimize the rebound effect by setting private costs of using
efciency and energy conservation, often used in parallel in energy closer to the social costs, hence reducing the externalities.
literature. Energy savings addresses the reduction of nal energy Finally, we consider that this analysis can provide a useful
use, while energy efciency concerns the technical ratio between insight for policymakers when designing policies for energy
the quantity of primary energy consumed and the maximum efciency improvement, since departing from the normative
quantity of energy services obtainable. Policies can address each aspects of end-users rational behaviour, more parameters have
one or both aspects simultaneously. to be taken into account that generate a differentiated behaviour.
Departing from the microeconomic theory, we aim at under- More specically, some key policy lessons summarized from this
standing drivers for promoting energy saving beyond energy study are: (a) policies can be smart targeting at both use and
prices. To this end, we integrated some theories well established investments, (b) taxing individuals is not enough for long-run
in environmental psychology in order to identify parameters that energy saving, as information campaigns and market instruments
affect end-users behaviour for both energy efciency and energy are necessary to induce collective behaviour, (c) policies stressing
savings. From a rationalist information decit model, for instance, the moral obligation to conserve energy can increase their
we can extract that a parameterized energy use depends on acceptability, (d) nancial compensation for savings must take
awareness, trust, and commitment, moral obligation, cultural place in the short-run in order to enable end-users to monitor
norms, routine practices, and habits, social networks and fashion. their daily energy use, (e) behavioural change can be triggered in
Some of these issues, like awareness and social behaviour, can be the medium-run by self-monitoring policies, which can modify
tackled with respective information diffusion policies, which the end usage, and (f) enabling nancing options through policy
target at these specic-market barriers. Other parameters ex- schemes can overcome substantial market barriers of consumers
plaining the energy users behaviour are found in the theory of towards energy efciency investments.
planned behaviour i.e. people make planned, rational decisions
and behavioural choices are motivated by self-interest, hassle,
time and social approval and the theory value-belief-norm theory Acknowledgement
(i.e. general values of people determine environmentally oriented
behaviour). To this end, policies that impose a cost (e.g. in the This paper was reviewed and presented in the International
form of taxation) on individual energy behaviour do not lead to Energy Workshop (2008) of the International Energy Agency.
common action. Therefore, internalizing the common benet by
proper information in individual decisions concerning energy use References
can indeed lead to energy savings in the long-run. Alternative
policies that can target at a certain extent this social dilemma Abrahamse, W., 2007. Energy Conservation through behavioral change: Examining
could involve a form of market trading, where negotiations in the the effectiveness of a tailor-made approach, Master thesis, University of
form of price arrangement for energy saving take place, as for Groningen, the Netherlands. Download at: /http://dissertations.ub.rug.nl/
faculties/ppsw/2007/w.abrahamse/S.
instance in case of White Certicates or other market-based Ajzen, I., 1985. From intentions to actions: a theory of planned behavior. In: Kuhl, J.,
mechanisms. Beckmann, J. (Eds.), Action Control: From Cognition to Behavior. Springer,
Moving a step further, we expressed with the private utility Berlin, pp. 1139.
Ajzen, I., Fishbein, M., 1980. Understanding Attitudes and Predicting Social
theory the relationship between the effort of energy savings and
Behavior. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.
the results in terms of monetary savings in energy bills, or in other Alcott, B., 2008. The sufciency strategy: would rich-world frugality lower
words, the opportunity cost of investing in energy saving and environmental impact? Ecological Economics 64 (4), 770786.
enjoying more comfort from energy consumption. Our main Bentzen, J., 2004. Estimating the rebound effect in US manufacturing energy
consumption. Energy Economics 26 (1), 123134.
nding there, by incorporating the goal-framing theory is that Berkhout, P.H.G., Muskens, J.C., Velthuijsen, J.W., 2000. Dening the rebound effect.
people not only consider comfort and costs of energy savings, but Energy Policy 28 (67), 425432.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
4796 V. Oikonomou et al. / Energy Policy 37 (2009) 47874796

Bertoldi, P., Rezessy, S., Oikonomou, V., Boza-Kiss, B., 2009. Feed-in tariff for energy Jackson, T., 2007. Sustainable consumption. In: Atkinson, Giles, Dietz, Simon,
saving: thinking of the design. European Council for Energy Efcient Economy Neumayer, Eric (Eds.), Handbook Sustainable Development. Edward Elgar,
(ECEEE) Summer Study Proceedings, France. Cheltenham, pp. 254268.
Binswanger, M., 2001. Technological progress and sustainable development: what Khazoom, D.J., 1986. An Econometric Model Integrating Conservation in the
about the rebound effect? Ecological Economics 36, 119132. Estimation of The Residential Demand for Electricity. JAI Press, Greenwich.
Bor, Y.J., 2008. Consistent multi-level energy efciency indicators and their policy Klein, Y.L., 1987. Residential energy conservation choices of poor households during
implications. Energy Economics 30 (5), 24012419. a period of rising energy prices. Resources and Energy 9 (4), 363378.
Brandon, G., Lewis, A., 1999. Reducing household energy consumption: a Laitner, J.A., 2000. Energy efciency: rebounding to a sound analytical perspective.
qualitative and quantitative eld study. Journal of Environmental Psychology Energy Policy 28 (67), 471475.
19, 7585. Lindenberg, S., Steg, L., 2007. Normative, gain and hedonic goal frames guiding
Brannlund, R., Ghalwash, T., Nordstrom, J., 2007. Increased energy efciency and environmental behavior. Journal of Social Issues 65 (1), 117137.
the rebound effect: effects on consumption and emissions. Energy Economics Milne, G., Boardman, B., 2000. Making cold homes warmer: the effect of energy
29 (1), 117. efciency improvements in low-income homes. A report to the energy action
Burgess, J., Harrisson, C., Filius, P., 1998. Environmental communication and the grants agency charitable trust. Energy Policy 28 (67), 411424.
cultural politics of environmental citizenship. Environment and Planning A 30 Mintel International Group Ltd, 1997. Energy Efciency and the Consumer. Mintel
(1), 14451460. International Group, London.
Clinch, J.P., Healy, J.D., University College Dublin Department of Environmental Nesbakken, R., 2001. Energy consumption for space heating: a discrete-continuous
Studies, 2000. Cost-benet analysis of domestic energy efciency. Dublin, approach. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 103 (1), 165184.
University College Dublin Department of Environmental Studies. Owens, S., Drifll, L., 2008. How to change attitudes and behaviours in the context
Davis, L.W., 2004. The Rebound Effect for Energy Efcient Residential Durable of energy. Energy Policy 36 (12), 44124418.
Goods. University of Wisconsin, Madison. Poortinga, W., Steg, L., Vlek, C., Wiersma, G., 2003. Household preferences for
De Groot, J., Steg, L., 2008. Value orientations to explain beliefs related to energy saving measures: a conjoint analysis. Journal of Economic Psychology
environmental signicant behavior: how to measure egoistic, altruistic, and (24), 4964.
biospheric value orientations. Environment and Behavior 40 (3), 330354. Poortinga, W., Steg, L., Vlek, C., 2004. Values, environmental concern and
Dinan, T.M., 1987. An Analysis of The Impact of The Residential Retrot on Indoor environmental behavior: a study into household energy use. Environment
Temperature Choice. Oak Ridge National Laboratory. and Behavior 36, 7093.
Douthitt, R.A., 1986. The demand for residential space and water heating fuel by Quirion, P., 2004. Les certicats blancs face aux autres instruments de politique
energy conserving households. The Journal of Consumer Affairs 20 (2), 231248. publique pour les economies denergie : bilan de literature economiques et
Dubin, J.A., Miedema, A.K., Chandran, R.V., 1986. Price effects of energy-efcient priorites de recherche. Institut Francais de lEnergie.
technologies a study of residential demand for heating and cooling. Rand Ruzzenenti, F., Basosi, R., 2008. The role of the power/efciency misconception in
Journal of Economics 17 (3), 310325. the rebound effects size debate: does efciency actually lead to a power
Gardner, G.T., Stern, P.C., 2002. Environmental Problems and Human Behavior, 2nd enhancement? Energy Policy 36 (9), 36263632.
ed. Pearson, Boston, MA. Sanstad, A., Howarth, R., 1994. Consumer Rationality and Energy efciency. ACEEE
Gatersleben, B., Steg, L., Vlek, C., 2002. Measurement and determinants of Summer Study on Energy Efciency in Buildings.
environmentally signicant consumer behavior. Environment and Behavior Schipper, L., Grubb, M., 2000. On the rebound? Feedback between energy
34 (3), 335362. intensities and energy uses in IEA countries. Energy Policy 28, 367388.
Greening, L.A., Greene, D.L., 1998. Energy use, technical efciency, and the rebound Schwarz, P.M., Taylor, T.N., 1995. Cold hands, warm hearth: climate, net take back,
effect: a review of the literature. Oak Ridge National Laboratory, Center for and household comfort. Energy Journal 16 (1), 4154.
transportation analysis. Sorrell, S., 2004. The Economics of Energy Efciency: Barriers to Cost-Effective
Greening, L.A., Greene, D.L., Diglio, C., 2000. Energy efciency and consumption Investment. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
the rebound effect a survey. Energy Policy 28 (67), 389401. Sorrell, S., Dimitropoulos, J., Sommerville, M., 2009. Empirical estimates of the
Guertin, C., Kumbhakar, S., Duraiappah, A., 2003. Determining demand for energy direct rebound effect: a review. Energy Policy 37, 13561371.
services: investigating income-driven behaviours. International Institute for Steg, L., 1999. Verspilde energie? Wat doen en laten Nederlanders voor het milieu
Sustainable Development. (Wasted energy? What the Dutch do and dont do to protect the environment).
Haas, R., Auer, H., Biermayr, P., 1998. The impact of consumer behavior on residential Den Haag: VUGA/Social and Cultural Planning Ofce of the Netherlands.
energy demand for space heating. Energy and Buildings 27 (2), 195205. (English summary available on: /http://www.scp.nl/boeken/cahiers/cah156/
Haas, R., Biermayr, P., 2000. The rebound effect for space heating Empirical uk/samenvatting.htmS).
evidence from Austria. Energy Policy 28 (67), 403410. Steg, L., 2008. Promoting household energy conservation. Energy Policy 36,
Herring, H., 2004. Energy efciencya critical view. Energy 31 (1), 1020. 44494453.
Hertwich, E., 2003. Consumption and the rebound effect: the consideration of Steg, L., Dreijerink, L., Abrahamse, W., 2005. Factors inuencing the acceptability of
information and communication technologies. In: Proceedings of the SETA- energy policies: testing VBN theory. Journal of Environmental Psychology 25
CISIE Case Study Symposium, Lausanne. (4), 415425.
Hertwich, E.G., 2005. Consumption and the rebound effect: an industrial ecology Stern, P.C., 2000. Toward a coherent theory of environmentally signicant
perspective. Journal of Industrial Ecology 9 (12), 8598. behaviour. Journal of Social Issues 56, 407424.
Hirst, E., 1987. Changes in indoor after retrot based on electricity billing and Tietenberg, T., 2000. Environmental and Natural Resource Economics, Colby
weather data. Energy Systems Policy 10, 99110. College.
Howarth, R., Andersson, B., 1993. Market barriers to energy efciency. Energy UK Energy Research Center, 2007. The Rebound Effect: an assessment of the
Economics 15 (4), 262272. evidence for economy-wide energy savings from improved energy efciency,
Howarth, R., Haddad, B.M., Paton, B., 2000. The economics of energy efciency: Download at: /www.ukerc.ac.uk/Downloads/PDF/07/0710ReboundEffect/
insights from voluntary participation programs. Energy Policy 28 (67), 0710ReboundEffectReport.pdfS.
477486. Varian, H.R., 2003. Intermediate Microeconomics, A Modern Approach. Norton &
IEA, 1997. Indicators of Energy Use and Efciency: Understanding the Link between Company, New York.
Energy and Human Activity. OECD/IEA, Paris. Wackernagel, M., Rees, W., 1997. Perceptual and structural barriers to investing in
Jaffe, A.B., Stavins, R.N., 1994. The energy-efciency gap. What does it mean? natural capital: economics from an ecological footprint perspective. Ecological
Energy Policy 22 (10), 804810. Economics 20 (1), 324.

Potrebbero piacerti anche