Sei sulla pagina 1di 31

The European Journal of Finance

ISSN: 1351-847X (Print) 1466-4364 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rejf20

Multi-asset portfolio optimization and outof-sample performance: an evaluation of


BlackLitterman, mean-variance, and nave
diversification approaches
Wolfgang Bessler, Heiko Opfer & Dominik Wolff
To cite this article: Wolfgang Bessler, Heiko Opfer & Dominik Wolff (2014): Multi-asset
portfolio optimization and out-of-sample performance: an evaluation of BlackLitterman,
mean-variance, and nave diversification approaches, The European Journal of Finance, DOI:
10.1080/1351847X.2014.953699
To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/1351847X.2014.953699

Published online: 08 Dec 2014.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 178

View related articles

View Crossmark data

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=rejf20
Download by: [Indian Institute of Technology Madras]

Date: 28 April 2016, At: 00:37

The European Journal of Finance, 2014


http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/1351847X.2014.953699

Multi-asset portfolio optimization and out-of-sample performance: an evaluation


of BlackLitterman, mean-variance, and nave diversification approaches

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

Wolfgang Besslera , Heiko Opferb and Dominik Wolffa


a Center

for Finance and Banking, Justus-Liebig-University Giessen, Giessen, Germany; b Deka Investment GmbH,
Frankfurt, Germany
(Received 16 November 2012; final version received 7 August 2014)
The BlackLitterman model aims to enhance asset allocation decisions by overcoming the problems of
mean-variance portfolio optimization. We propose a sample-based version of the BlackLitterman model
and implement it on a multi-asset portfolio consisting of global stocks, bonds, and commodity indices,
covering the period from January 1993 to December 2011. We test its out-of-sample performance relative
to other asset allocation models and find that BlackLitterman optimized portfolios significantly outperform nave-diversified portfolios (1/N rule and strategic weights), and consistently perform better than
mean-variance, BayesStein, and minimum-variance strategies in terms of out-of-sample Sharpe ratios,
even after controlling for different levels of risk aversion, investment constraints, and transaction costs.
The BL model generates portfolios with lower risk, less extreme asset allocations, and higher diversification across asset classes. Sensitivity analyses indicate that these advantages are due to more stable mixed
return estimates that incorporate the reliability of return predictions, smaller estimation errors, and lower
turnover.
Keywords: portfolio optimization; BlackLitterman; mean-variance; minimum-variance; BayesStein;
nave diversification; 1/N; Markowitz
JEL Classification: C61; G11

1.

Introduction

The traditional mean-variance (MV) portfolio optimization (Markowitz 1952) has played a
prominent role in modern investment theory and has been widely discussed and tested in the
literature. In theory, it provides the investor with the optimal asset allocation if the portfolio
variance and return are the only relevant parameters and future asset returns and the covariance
matrix are given. However, when applied in an asset management setting, estimation errors in
input parameters (Jobson and Korkie 1981a; Michaud 1989), corner solutions (Broadie 1993),
and high transaction costs, resulting from extreme portfolio reallocations (Best and Grauer 1991),
often result in a poor out-of-sample portfolio performance.
Asset managers frequently try to cope with these shortcomings by implementing constraints
on the portfolio weights and turnover. In the literature, several variations and extensions of MV
are discussed that attempt to overcome its limitations. These suggestions range from imposing
portfolio constraints (Frost and Savarino 1988; Jagannathan and Ma 2003; Behr, Guettler, and
Miebs 2013) to the use of factor models (Chan, Karceski, and Lakonishok 1999), and Bayesian
methods for estimating the MV input parameters (Jorion 1985, 1986; Pastor 2000; Pastor and
Corresponding

author. Email: wolfgang.bessler@wirtschaft.uni-giessen.de

2014 Taylor & Francis

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

W. Bessler et al.

Stambaugh 2000). In a recent study, DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2009) analyze whether
MV strategies and various extensions suggested in the literature are able to outperform a navediversified 1/N portfolio across a range of different stock data sets. They report that none of
the different MV strategies consistently outperforms a nave equally weighted portfolio (1/N) in
an out-of-sample setting. However, Kirby and Ostdiek (2012) question these results, suggesting
that the results are mainly due to their research design and their data sets. They show that by
focusing on the tangential portfolio, DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2009) place the MV model
at an inherent disadvantage in terms of turnover and estimation risk. Nevertheless, Kirby and
Ostdiek (2012) also find that the MV approach hardly outperforms the 1/N strategy at statistically
significant levels when transaction costs are included.
In contrast to the professional asset management industry, the academic literature has paid little attention to the performance of the Black and Litterman (1992) model, which was derived
as an alternative approach to portfolio optimization more than 20 years ago. Since then the
BlackLitterman (BL) model has experienced an increasing attention among quantitative portfolio managers (Satchell and Scowcroft 2000; Jones, Lim, and Zangari 2007). In the literature,
only a few authors analyze the rationale of the BL model, provide examples for applying the
methodology, or propose extensions of the model (Lee 2000; Satchell and Scowcroft 2000; Drobetz 2001; Herold 2005; Idzorek 2005; Meucci 2006; Chiarawongse et al. 2012; Bessler and
Wolff 2013). So far, there exists only little empirical evidence for the out-of-sample performance
of the BL model.
Our study contributes to the literature by empirically testing the BL model performance outof-sample. The main objectives are first to analyze whether the BL model is able to alleviate
the typical shortcomings of MV optimization, and second to evaluate its performance relative
to alternative asset allocation strategies in an out-of-sample setting with realistic investment
constraints. We propose a sample-based approach of the BL model that allows us to compute
its out-of-sample performance based on historic data sets. For the period from January 1993 to
December 2011, we compute the out-of-sample performance of BL, MV, and BayesStein (BS),
as one of the most prominent extensions of MV, minimum variance (MinVar), as well as for two
nave diversification approaches and evaluate the performance of each strategy. Furthermore, we
propose variations of the BL model by incorporating different reference portfolios and finally
analyze expansionary and recessionary sub-periods separately.
Relative to other studies on asset allocation strategies such as DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal
(2009), Kirby and Ostdiek (2012), Behr, Guettler, and Miebs (2013), Murtazashvili and Vozlyublennaia (2013), our study extends the literature with respect to the following three aspects.
First, and most importantly, we include the BL model in the analysis. Second, we analyze all optimization strategies for three different investor types with maximum desired portfolio volatilities
of 5%, 10% and 15%, while earlier studies usually focus only on the tangential portfolio. Third,
we implement portfolio optimization strategies based on multi-asset portfolios. Earlier studies
cited above focus solely on stock portfolios. Our empirical analysis covers the asset classes
developed and emerging stocks, government and corporate bonds, as well as commodities. In
particular, we expect that the additional asset classes, government bonds and commodities, offer
high diversification potentials, due to their historically low correlations with stocks. Given that
government bonds usually gain in value during stock market downturns, asset allocation models
that shift wealth from stocks to bonds during these periods should benefit relative to nave strategies such as the 1/N approach. Therefore, it is important to analyze how different asset allocation
strategies performed in a multi-asset context over the last two decades.

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

The European Journal of Finance

Our empirical results offer new insights into several dimensions. We find that for a multi-asset
universe all portfolio optimization strategies outperform relative to nave equally weighted (1/N)
or strategically weighted portfolios. Yet the outperformance is insignificant for most MV and BS
portfolios, which is consistent with the results of Kirby and Ostdiek (2012) and DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2009). However, the BL portfolios exhibit significantly higher Sharpe ratios
than nave strategies and consistently outperform MV. Additionally, BL portfolios have lower
portfolio turnover and offer more diversification across asset classes relative to MV portfolios.
Our sub-period analysis suggests that the BL model outperforms MV and nave-diversified portfolios particularly in recessionary periods. Sensitivity analyses indicate that the superiority of the
BL model results from more stable mixed return estimates that include the reliability of return
estimates (views) and lead to a lower portfolio turnover. A variety of sensitivity analyses indicates that our results are robust to different estimation windows, optimization constraints, and
to restrictions of the optimized portfolio weights. Our results also hold for different levels of
transaction costs and when transaction costs are included in the optimization function as well as
for larger and different sets of asset universes.
The remainder of this study is organized as follows. In Section 2, we discuss the asset allocation models employed, the related literature as well as the employed performance measures. We
provide the data and some descriptive statistics in Section 3 and present and discuss our empirical results in Section 4. Section 5 includes a description and discussion of the robustness checks.
Section 6 concludes.
2.

Methodology

We analyze the out-of-sample performance of different optimization techniques and nave diversification rules. The optimization models employed include three alternative implementations
of the BlackLitterman (BL) model, the mean-variance (MV) and minimum-variance (MinVar)
portfolios, as well as the BayesStein (BS) approach as one of the most prominent extensions of
MV. The nave diversification rules analyzed are equally weighted portfolios (1/N) and strategically weighted portfolios (st.w.). Table 1 summarizes all asset allocation models used in this
study. For the period from January 1993 to December 2011, we calculate monthly optimized
portfolios at the first trading day of each month, based on the different optimization approaches.
In line with DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2009) and Daskalaki and Skiadopoulos (2011),
we employ a rolling sample approach. This means that at any point in time t (month), we
use data available up to and including time t (k observations) to compute optimized portfolio
weights. These weights are then used to compute the out-of-sample realized portfolio return over
the period [t, t + 1]. We repeat this process by moving the sample period one month forward
and computing the optimized weights for the next month. Rolling estimation windows offer the
advantage of being more responsive to structural breaks than expanding estimation windows. To
ensure the robustness of our results, we analyze different estimation window lengths. All optimization models include realistic investment constraints. First, we include a budget restriction
according to Equation (1) which ensures that portfolio weights sum to one:
N


i = 1,

(1)

i=1

where i is the portfolio weight of asset i and N is the number of assets in the portfolio. Second,
we exclude short selling since many institutional investors are restricted to long positions only

W. Bessler et al.
Table 1. Overview of asset allocation models included.
Number

Model

Abbreviation

Nave asset allocation rules


1
2

1/N with rebalancing (benchmark strategy)


Nave diversification (benchmark weights) with rebalancing

1/N
st.w.

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

Portfolio optimization models


3
4
5
6
7
8

Sample-based mean-variance
BayesStein
Minimum-variance
BlackLitterman with strategic weights as reference portfolio
BlackLitterman with 1/N as reference portfolio
BlackLitterman with minimum variance as reference portfolio

MV
BS
MinVar
BL-st.w.
BL-1/N
BL-MinVar

Notes: This table lists the various asset allocation models that we include in this study. The last column
of the table gives the abbreviation used to refer to the strategy in the tables in which the performance of
the various strategies is compared.

(Equation (2)):
i 0, with i = 1, . . . , N.

(2)

Third, we limit the maximum portfolio volatility in order to distinguish between different
investor types in terms of their maximum desired portfolio risk (Equation (3)):


P ,

(3)
where is the vector of portfolio weights,  is the covariance matrix of the asset returns, and
P is a predefined portfolio volatility constraint. The volatility constraint represents an upper
volatility bound, rather than a target volatility for the optimized portfolio. Such a volatility bound
provides the advantage that the asset allocation model may shift large fractions of wealth to lowrisk government bonds during stock market downturns, thereby preventing losses, whereas for
a specific target volatility (e.g. 10% p.a.) substantial fractions of wealth have to be invested in
stocks even if stock return estimates are negative. In the remainder of this section, we briefly
describe the methodology of the various asset allocation strategies implemented in this study.
2.1

Nave diversification rules

We compute two nave-diversified portfolios that serve as benchmark portfolios for the optimization models. First, we calculate a 1/N strategy that invests equally in the N included assets. This
nave diversified 1/N portfolio is a popular investment strategy for private investors (Benartzi
and Thaler 2001). In a recent study, Plyakha, Uppal, and Vilkov (2012) report that equalweighted (1/N) stock portfolios with monthly rebalancing achieve higher total mean returns,
four factor alphas (Fama and French 1993; Carhart 1997), and Sharpe ratios compared to both
value-weighted and price-weighted portfolios.1
As a second nave diversification strategy, we compute strategically weighted portfolios (st.w.)
in which each asset obtains a strategic weight that is constant over time. We account for three
different investor clienteles a conservative, a moderate, and an aggressive one and set
different strategic weights for bonds, commodities, and stocks depending on the investor type. To

The European Journal of Finance

Table 2. Strategically weighted portfolios.

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

Benchmark portfolio weights


Investor type

Bonds
(%)

Stocks
(%)

Commodities
(%)

Historic volatility
of benchmark
portfolio (% p.a.)

Conservative
Moderate
Aggressive

80
45
10

15
40
65

5
15
25

4.58
6.66
9.72

Optimization
constraint: max.
portfolio volatility
(% p.a.)
5.00
10.00
15.00

Notes: This table provides the strategic weights for the three analyzed investor types: conservative, moderate, and aggressive, which are used to compute nave-diversified portfolios and implied return estimates. Within the asset class stocks,
emerging market stocks obtain a strategic weight of 25%, while developed market stocks obtain a strategic weight of
75%. Accordingly, in the asset class bonds, high-yield corporate bonds have a strategic weight of 25% and government
bonds 75%. We assume that the three investor types prefer a maximum expected portfolio volatility of 5%, 10% and
15%, respectively, which is compatible with the historic volatilities of the benchmark portfolios.

determine strategic weights we rely on the results of earlier studies and on discussions with practitioners. Analyzing multi-asset portfolios including US stocks, bonds, and commodities for the
period from 1974 to 1997, Anson (1999) suggests that a moderate investor should allocate about
15% to commodities. Usually the risk of commodities is similar to equities (Bodie and Rosansky
1980; Gorton and Rouwenhorst 2006) and substantially larger than for bonds. Therefore, we set
the strategic allocation to commodities and stocks lower for conservative investors and higher
for aggressive investors. For the conservative, moderate, and aggressive investor clienteles, the
strategic weights for commodities are 5%, 15%, and 25% and for stocks 15%, 40%, and 65%,
respectively. Accordingly, the strategic weights for bonds are 80% for the conservative investor,
which might be, for instance, reasonable for pension funds, 45% for the moderate investor, and
10% for the aggressive investor type. Table 2 summarizes the strategic weights for the different
investor types. The maximum desired portfolio volatilities are set to 5%, 10%, and 15% for the
conservative, moderate, and aggressive investor clienteles, respectively, which is in line with
the historic volatilities of the strategically weighted portfolios for these investor types before
the evaluation period from 1988 to 1992. We employ these volatility bounds as constraints for
the optimization strategies. As for the optimized portfolios, both nave-diversified portfolios are
rebalanced at every first trading day of each month. Rebalancing, however, only maintains the
nave 1/N or strategic weight for each asset. As robustness check, we also compute equally and
strategically weighted buy-and-hold benchmark portfolios that do not include any rebalancing.
Our findings also hold for the buy-and-hold benchmark portfolios, and the performance differs
only marginally between the portfolios with and without rebalancing. To be parsimonious, we
only report the results with rebalancing.2
2.2

Minimum-variance portfolio

The minimum-variance (MinVar) strategy selects portfolio weights that minimize the variance
of the portfolio returns. The minimization problem is

min 
.
(4)

using rolling estimaTo implement this policy we rely on the sample covariance matrix 
tion windows as described above. The advantage of the minimum-variance approach is that it

W. Bessler et al.

does not require any return estimates, which are usually subject to large estimation errors. The
effects of estimation errors in the covariance matrix are about 10 times smaller than the effects
of estimation errors in returns (Chopra and Ziemba 1993). In line with all other optimization
strategies, we include realistic investment constraints, specifically a budget restriction according
to Equation (1) and disallow short selling according to Equation (2).

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

2.3

Mean-variance (MV) optimized portfolio

In the MV approach (Markowitz 1952), the investor optimizes a trade-off between risk and
return. The mean-variance optimization problem is

,
(5)
max U =  

2
where U is the investors utility, is the vector of expected return estimates, and is the coefficient of risk aversion. The Markowitz optimization framework assumes normally distributed
returns or mean-variance preferences, focusing only on the mean and variance of returns and
ignoring higher moments. Although this seems to be a critical assumption, Landsman and Nelehov (2008) show that it is sufficient that returns are elliptically symmetrically distributed so
that all investor preferences are equivalent to mean-variance preferences. Therefore, it is reasonable to rely on the mean-variance framework for portfolio optimization even if asset returns
are non-normal, but are symmetric. To implement the mean-variance strategy, we employ the
as described above. We include a budget
sample mean and the sample covariance matrix 
restriction according to Equation (1), disallow short selling according to Equation (2), and limit
the maximum allowed portfolio volatility (Equation (3)). The risk aversion coefficient is initially
set to 2 and variations are analyzed as robustness check.
2.4

BayesStein shrinkage portfolio

The BayesStein (BS) approach is one of the most prominent extensions of MV and therefore
included in our analysis. The BS approach, proposed by Jorion (1985, 1986), is based on the
idea of shrinkage estimation by Stein (1955) and James and Stein (1961) and attempts to reduce
estimation error of the input parameters of MV by employing a Bayesian approach for estimating
returns and the covariance matrix. The optimization procedure is the same as in the MV approach
presented in Equation (5). The intuition of BS is to reduce estimation errors by shrinking the
sample mean toward the expected return of the minimum-variance portfolio min with
min = w
min =

1  1


1  1 1

(6)

where 1 is a vector of ones and  is the covariance matrix. BS shrinks the sample estimates by
using return estimates of the form:
BS = (1 ) + min 1 with =

N +2
.
   1 ( min 1)

(N + 2) + K( min 1)

(7)

where
The BS approach estimates the covariance matrix as  = ((K 1)/(K N 2)),

is the expected return of the minimum-variance portfolio,  is the usual unbiased sample

covariance matrix, N is the number of assets included, and K is the sample size (Jorion 1986). In
min

The European Journal of Finance

addition to shrinking the return estimates, the BayesStein approach also adjusts the covariance
matrix that we implement as described in Jorion (1986). We employ the same optimization procedure, optimization constraints, and estimation windows as for the MV approach and analyze
variations of all input parameters as a robustness check.

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

2.5

BlackLitterman portfolio

The BL model is an alternative approach for dealing with estimation errors in return estimates.
It combines two sources of information: neutral (implied) returns and subjective return
estimates. The latter are also referred to as views. The advantage of the BL approach is that
investors can either provide return estimates for each asset or stay neutral for some assets they
feel less comfortable in making return forecasts. Moreover, the reliability of each return estimate can be incorporated allowing investors to distinguish between qualified estimates and pure
guesses.
The basic idea is that investors should only depart from the reference portfolio, which might
be the market or any other benchmark portfolio, if they are able to provide reliable estimates of
future returns. The BL model uses implied returns as a prior that we compute based on the asset
weights of the reference portfolio. The implied excess returns used in the original Black and
Litterman (1992) approach are derived using reverse optimization, assuming that the observable
market or benchmark weights are the result of a mean-variance optimization. Implied returns
used in the BL model are computed as


=
,
(8)
e

where e is the vector of implied asset excess returns,  is the covariance matrix, is the
investors risk aversion coefficient, and is the vector of observable market or benchmark
weights.

The BL framework combines the vector of implied returns
with the investors views
expressed in the vector Q, incorporating the reliability of each view quantified in a matrix . To
derive the combined return estimates, the original Black and Litterman (1992) paper references
Theils mixed estimation model (1971). Figure 1 illustrates the procedure of the BL approach.
The combined return estimates are written as
BL = [( )1 + P 1 P]1 [( )1
+ P 1 Q]

(9)

in which P is a binary matrix containing the information for which asset a subjective return
estimate exists, and is a factor that measures the reliability of implied return estimates. The
combined return estimate is a matrix-weighted average of implied returns and views with
respect to the correlation structure (Lee 2000). The weighting factors are the uncertainty measures of implied returns and subjective return estimates , which we discuss in the following
section.
In the BL approach, the posterior covariance matrix is (Satchell and Scowcroft 2000)


=
+[( )1 + P 1 P]1 .
(10)
BL

After computing combined return estimates and the posterior covariance matrix, a traditional
risk-return optimization is conducted maximizing the investors utility function presented in
Equation (5).

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

W. Bessler et al.

Figure 1. The procedure of the BlackLitterman approach (Idzorek 2005).

2.5.1 Implied returns and the parameter


The reference portfolio used to compute implied returns might have a strong influence on the
out-of-sample performance of the BL model. Therefore, we employ three alternative reference
portfolios: the 1/N portfolio (BL-1/N), the strategically weighted portfolio (BL-st.w.) described
in Section 2.1, and the minimum-variance portfolio (BL-MinVar) described in Section 2.2. The
minimum-variance portfolio might be particularly reasonable for conservative investors, as they
might prefer to invest in the lowest risk portfolio if the reliability of their return estimates is low.
However, for some portfolio managers it might be advantageous to stick to a certain benchmark
if return estimates are uncertain.
The parameter controls how distinctly the optimized portfolio may depart from the reference
portfolio. It reflects the uncertainty of implied returns and can be chosen based on a desired tracking error. Allaj (2013) provides a discussion of the parameter . For very small values ( 0)
the combined returns converge to implied returns and the BL optimized portfolio converges to
the reference portfolio. For large values ( ) the combined returns converge to the views
and the BL optimized portfolio converges to the MV portfolio in which the views are the underlying return estimates. In the literature, the values used for typically range between 0.025 and
0.300 (Black and Litterman 1992; He and Litterman 1999; Drobetz 2001; Idzorek 2005). We start
with setting the parameter at a level of 0.100 and analyze variations in a sensitivity analysis.
2.5.2 Subjective return estimates and their reliability
As described above, the BL model combines implied returns and subjective return estimates.
The literature on the BL model does not provide a clear answer how to derive subjective return
estimates and the reliability of these estimates. Several studies simply assume exogenously given

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

The European Journal of Finance

estimates (He and Litterman 1999; Lee 2000; Drobetz 2001; Idzorek 2005) and suggest confidence intervals of the return estimates as a measure of uncertainty (Black and Litterman 1992).
Since the portfolio performance critically depends on the exogenously assumed estimates, these
approaches are hardly capable to evaluate the performance of the BL model in comparison
to MV and nave-diversified benchmark portfolios. Moreover, mutually estimating returns and
their respective confidence intervals might be a challenging task for analysts and might hinder
a successful implementation of the BL model. Therefore, we employ sample means as subjective return estimates based on rolling estimation windows as in the other optimization models
(MV and BS). However, in contrast to MV and BS, the BL model additionally incorporates the
reliability of these estimates that are expressed in the matrix .
For a portfolio of N assets,  is a N N diagonal matrix with the reliability measures for
the assets on its diagonal. A low reliability in all views results in optimized portfolio weights
close to the reference portfolio. Meucci (2010) proposes to assume simply an overall level of
confidence in the views that is constant over time by setting  as
 
 
1
 P .
(11)
= P
c
In this approach, it is assumed that the reliability of views is proportional to the reliability
of implied returns with the proportionality factor 1/c. As a result no additional and time-varying
information on the reliability of views is included. We suggest that the out-of-sample performance of the BL model is superior if reasonable and time-varying information on the reliability
of views is included. Therefore, we measure the reliability of each view i based on historic
forecast errors i . For this, we employ the same rolling estimation windows as for return estimates and estimate the uncertainty of return estimates as the variance of historic forecast errors.
We analyze different estimation window lengths as robustness check. The idea is that in uncertain market environments when the last months return estimates differ strongly from the realized
returns, the reliability for the subsequent return estimate is likely to be lower, resulting in portfolios closer to the reference portfolio. In contrast, in stable market conditions when the last months
return forecasts are close to the realized returns, the return estimate for the next period should be
more reliable and the optimized portfolio may depart more from the reference portfolio.
We analyze the contribution of this historic reliability measure by comparing the out-of-sample
portfolio performance of our approach with the assumption of an overall time-invariant level of
confidence in the views as in Meucci (2010) by substituting  according to Equation (11).
2.6

Performance measures

We calculate several performance measures to evaluate the optimized portfolios. First, we compute the moments of the net portfolio returns (after transaction costs) for each optimization
strategy i. Further, we determine the out-of-sample net Sharpe ratio as the fraction of the outof-sample mean net excess return (mean return after transaction costs less risk-free rate) divided
by the standard deviation of out-of-sample net returns.

i = RNet,i Rf .
SR
Net,i

(12)

Using Sharpe ratios as performance measure is often criticized, because asset return distributions are usually non-normal. However, Meyer (1987) shows that the general LS condition

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

10

W. Bessler et al.

(location and scale) of returns is sufficient to rely on the - framework. Therefore, relying
on Sharpe ratios is reasonable even for asymmetric return distributions and fat tails as long as
the LS condition holds. We use the two-sample statistic to test if the difference in Sharpe ratios
of two portfolios is significant (Opdyke 2007). In contrast to earlier Sharpe ratio tests (Jobson
and Korkie 1981b; Lo 2002), this test is appropriate under very general conditions stationary
and ergodic returns. Most important for our analysis, the test permits autocorrelated and nonnormal distributed returns and allows for a likely high correlation between the portfolio returns
of different strategies.3
As alternative performance measure, we compute the Omega ratio (Shadwick and Keating
2002) also referred to as gain-loss ratio. It measures the average gains to average losses in which
we define gains as returns above the risk-free rate and losses as returns below the risk-free rate.
Hence, investments with a larger Omega measure are preferable. Formally, the omega measure is

(1/T) Tt=1 max(0, rt,i rf )
,
(13)
Omegai =

(1/T) Tt=1 max(0, rf rt,i )
where ri,t is the return of asset i at time t and rf is the risk-free rate. The advantage of the Omega
measure is that it does not require any assumption on the distribution of returns.
As alternative risk measures besides volatility, we compute the maximum drawdown (MDD)
as proposed by Grossman and Zhou (1993). The MDD reflects the maximum accumulated loss
that an investor may suffer during the entire investment period if she buys the portfolio at a high
price and subsequently sells at the lowest price. As the Omega measure, it does not require any
assumption on the return distribution. We compute the percentage maximum drawdown (MDD)
of strategy i as




Pi,t Pi,t
,
(14)
MDDi = Maxi,t(0,T) Maxi,t(0,t)
Pi,t
where Pi,t is the price of portfolio i at time t, when the portfolio is bought, and Pi,t is the price
of portfolio i at time t*, when the portfolio is sold.
Furthermore, we compute the portfolio turnover, in line with Daskalaki and Skiadopoulos
(2011) and DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2009), which quantifies the extent of trading required
to implement a certain strategy. The portfolio turnover PTi of strategy i is the average absolute
change of the portfolio weights over the T rebalancing points in time and across the N assets:
PTi =

T
N
1 
(|i,j,t+1 i,j,t+ |)
T t=1 j=1

(15)

in which i,j,t is the weight of asset j at time t under strategy i; i,j,t+ is the portfolio weight before
rebalancing at t + 1; and i,j,t+1 is the desired portfolio weight at t + 1, after rebalancing. i,j,t
is usually different from i,j,t+ due to changes in asset prices between t and t + 1.
We account for trading costs by assuming proportional transaction costs of 30 basis points of
the transaction volume in the base case and compute all performance measures after transaction
costs. As a robustness check, we analyze the impact of different transaction costs.
3.

Data

To construct multi-asset portfolios we include global stocks, bonds, and commodity indices in
the investment universe. We use the MSCI World and MSCI Emerging Markets stock indices

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

The European Journal of Finance

11

to cover both developed and emerging markets. Emerging markets usually provide higher stock
returns than developed markets because they have a higher exposure to additional risk factors
such as illiquidity or institutional and political conditions (Iqbal, Brooks, and Galagedera 2010).
Chiou, Lee, and Chang (2009) find that international diversification is beneficial for US investors,
reducing portfolio volatility, and improving risk-adjusted returns.
Government bond returns typically have low or even negative correlations with stock returns
and often prices of government bonds increase during stock market downturns. To ensure their
role as a low-risk investment we employ US government bonds, thereby eliminating default and
currency risks. To represent US government bond investments we rely on the Bank of America/Merill Lynch US Government Bond Index (all maturities). In addition, we include the Bank
of America/Merill Lynch US High Yield 100 Bond Index to add exposure to corporate default
risk. This index is expected to provide higher returns and higher risks compared to government
bonds, but lower returns and lower risks compared to stock indices.
The S&P GSCI Light Energy Index represents a diversified commodity investment, providing
investors with an exposure to a wide range of commodity price changes. While the main determinants of the S&P GSCI Index are energy prices, the S&P GSCI Light Energy Index offers
more balance across different commodity classes. At the end of our sample period, it reflects
the price developments on the future markets for energy (37.4%), agricultural products (31.2%),
and livestock (10%), as well as industry (14%) and precious metals (7.4%). Commodities should
have low correlations with the traditional asset classes such as stocks and bonds, because their
prices depend on different risk factors such as weather, geographical conditions, and supply
constraints. Moreover, as several studies document a positive correlation between commodity returns and future inflation, investing in commodities is often viewed as a hedge against
inflation (Bodie and Rosansky 1980; Erb and Harvey 2006; Gorton and Rouwenhorst 2006).
Several studies also find that by including commodities, the efficient frontier of stock-bond portfolios improved (for instance, Satyanarayan and Varangis 1996; Abanomey and Mathur 1999;
Anson 1999; Jensen, Johnson, and Mercer 2000). More recent evidence suggests that diversification benefits of commodities are regime-dependent (Cheung and Miu 2010), but that portfolio
benefits of commodities in out-of-sample optimized portfolios are ambiguous (Daskalaki and
Skiadopoulos 2011; You and Daigler 2013). However, given that investors still perceive commodities as an important asset class in portfolio optimization, we include commodities in our
analysis.
We obtain monthly total return index data for the period from January 1988 to December
2011 from Thomson Reuters Datastream. All data are denominated in US dollar. In line with
DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2009), we use the three months US T-Bill rate as the risk-free
rate. Because we need several years of historical data to set up the first optimized portfolio the
evaluation period ranges from January 1993 to December 2011. Table 3 provides descriptive
statistics of the monthly asset returns for the full evaluation period.
The table shows similar annualized mean returns for stock and bond indices ranging from
6.16% to 8.00% p.a. For the entire period, the average return of the commodity index is slightly
lower than the average risk-free rate of 3.12%, resulting in a negative Sharpe ratio. The US
Government Bond Index generates the highest Sharpe ratio of 0.655. The maximum drawdowns
(MDD) of the assets reveal that the maximum loss an investor could have suffered during the
evaluation period by investing in stocks was between 55.16% and 63.04% of the invested capital. This figure was 59.95% for commodities, 27.21% for the US High Yield Bond Index, and
5.29% for the US Government Bond Index. The JarqueBera statistic is significant for all asset

12

W. Bessler et al.
Table 3. Descriptive statistics of asset returns (January 1993December 2011).

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

MSCI World MSCI EM US Gov. Bonds


Mean return p.a. (%)
SD p.a. (%)
Skewness
Kurtosis
Sharpe ratio
MDD (%)
JB
Observations

6.71
16.61
0.90
5.34
0.22
55.16
82.47*
228

8.00
25.40
0.93
5.93
0.19
63.04
114.61*
228

6.16
4.64
0.04
4.26
0.66
5.29
15.10*
228

US High Yield
Bonds

S&P GSCI
Light Energy

7.31
8.44
1.47
10.44
0.50
27.21
608.24*
228

2.66
16.58
1.29
8.45
0.03
59.95
339.20*
228

Notes: This table provides sample moments, Sharpe ratios, maximum drawdown, and JarqueBera statistics
of the five asset classes considered in the empirical analysis. The period covers the months from January 1993
to December 2011. Mean return p.a. denotes annualized time-series mean of monthly returns, while SD
p.a. denotes the associated annualized standard deviation. Skewness and Kurtosis represent the third and
fourth moment of the return distribution. Sharpe ratio shows the annualized Sharpe ratios of the respective
asset classes using the average 19932011 risk-free interest rate of 3.12% per year. MDD shows the maximum
drawdown of the respective asset class during the period from January 1993 to December 2011 and JB is the
JarqueBera statistic for testing normality of returns.
*Statistically significant at the 1% level.

classes. Hence, the assumption of normal distributed returns has to be rejected. However, as mentioned above, Meyer (1987) shows that the general LS condition (location and scale) of returns
is sufficient to apply the mean-variance framework.
Table 4 presents evidence on potential diversification effects in terms of pair-wise correlation
coefficients. Over the entire period the diversification benefits when investing only in stocks
are limited. The correlation between the MSCI World and MSCI Emerging Markets is highly
significant and larger than 0.8, indicating a strong co-movement of developed and emerging
stock markets. While the US-High-Yield-Bond Index and commodities offer a slightly better
diversification effect with correlation coefficients ranging between 0.35 and 0.65, the highest
diversification potential during our sample period is provided by investing in the US Government
Bond Index, which is reflected in negative correlation coefficients and positive Sharpe ratios.
Consequently, we expect to find significant portfolio benefits by applying the BL, BS, and MV
frameworks on a multi-asset portfolio, including bonds and commodities, rather than on a stockonly portfolio.
4.
4.1

Empirical results
Results for the full sample

Table 5 summarizes the out-of-sample performance of the different asset allocation strategies for
the three investor types conservative, moderate, and aggressive for the base case over the
full evaluation period from January 1993 to December 2011. In the base case, we use 36 months
rolling estimation windows for the covariance matrix and 12 months for return estimates. We
use shorter estimation windows for return estimates as we expect the correlation structure and
variances to be more stable. In robustness checks, we provide the results for different estimation
windows (5.2). The strategically weighted portfolio (st.w.) is computed according to the asset
weights in Table 2. Within the asset class stocks, the strategic weights are specified to be 25%
for emerging markets and 75% for developed markets. Accordingly, for the asset class bonds,

The European Journal of Finance

13

Table 4. Correlation matrix of asset classes (January 1993December 2011).


MSCI World MSCI EM US Gov. Bonds

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

MSCI World
MSCI Emerging Markets
US Gov. Bond Index
US High Yield Bond Index
S&P GSCI Light Energy

1
0.811*
0.182*
0.652*
0.470*

1
0.221*
0.619*
0.463*

1
0.069
0.128**

US High Yield
Bonds

S&P GSCI
Light Energy

1
0.353*

Notes: This table provides the correlation matrix for the asset classes considered in the analysis over the period from
January 1993 to December 2011.
*Statistically significant at the 1% level.
**Statistically significant at the 5% level.

the strategic weights are set to 75% for government bonds and to 25% for high-yield corporate bonds. In the equal-weighted (1/N) portfolio, all five asset classes obtain an equal portfolio
weight of 20%.
The performance evaluation in Table 5 reveals that the three BL approaches, with different
reference portfolios, yield larger Sharpe ratios and Omega measures than MV, BS, MinVar, and
both nave-diversified portfolios for all investor types. The Sharpe ratios of the BL portfolios are
significantly larger (5% level) than that of the nave-diversified 1/N strategy. In contrast, the MV
strategy does not result in a significant outperformance relative to the 1/N strategy.
Our results suggest that the impact of the reference portfolio on the performance of the BL
approach is rather low. For all analyzed reference portfolios, the BL optimization leads to a
consistently superior performance relative to MV, BS, and both nave-diversified portfolios. This
result holds for all investor types. We also observe that for the conservative investor type, the BLMinVar approach performs slightly better than the other BL approaches. For aggressive investors,
however, the BL model based on strategic weights as reference portfolio performs marginally
better.
Our risk measures volatility and maximum drawdown (MDD) indicate a consistently lower
risk for all BL optimized portfolios in comparison to MV and BS, independent of the investor
type. At first, it seems surprising that the ex post realized volatilities differ from the ex ante
determined volatility constraints of 5%, 10%, and 15%, but the explanation is rather straightforward. On the one hand, the sample volatility estimates include estimation errors that may lead to
a discrepancy between ex ante estimated volatility and ex post realized volatility. On the other
hand, the optimization framework with volatility constraint as described in Equation (5) does
not necessarily favor the asset allocation with the largest possible volatility that is close to the
volatility constraint. The optimized portfolio is rather determined by the trade-off between risk
and return. For instance, in recessionary periods with negative expected stock returns, the optimization framework is likely to allocate a large fraction of the portfolio to low-risk government
bonds, independent of the volatility constraint. Therefore, the average volatility over the entire
evaluation period is below the volatility constraint for all optimization models.
Table 5 also presents the average yearly portfolio turnover as an indicator for the magnitude
of trading volume and transaction costs required to implement a certain strategy. However, all
performance measures already include transaction costs. The results reveal that for all investor
types the BL approach requires a lower portfolio turnover and, therefore, has lower transaction
costs relative to the MV approach. The BL-st.w. approach, for instance, yields an average yearly

14

BL-st.w.

BL-1/N

Investor type: conservative


Net mean return p.a. (%)
Volatility p.a. (%)
Net Sharpe ratio
Net Omega measure
Net MDD (%)
VaR99% (%)
Avrg. number of assets
Avrg. turnover p.a.

7.81
5.16
0.91
1.96
5.99
2.77
3.32
2.13

7.79
5.22
0.89
1.93
6.07
3.04
3.79
2.06

7.86
5.13
0.92
1.98
6.17
2.87
3.20
2.11

Investor type: moderate


Net mean return p.a. (%)
Volatility p.a. (%)
Net Sharpe ratio
Net Omega measure
Net MDD (%)
VaR99% (%)
Avrg. number of assets
Avrg. turnover p.a.

9.58
8.65
0.75##
1.77
9.46
6.36
3.26
3.32

9.51
8.87
0.72
1.73
11.02
6.91
3.48
3.29

9.28
8.05
0.76
1.81
9.21
5.52
2.86
3.28
10.37##
9.85
0.74##
1.82
12.10
6.73
2.63
3.89

Investor type: aggressive


Net mean return p.a. (%)
Volatility p.a. (%)
Net Sharpe ratio
Net Omega measure
Net MDD (%)
VaR99% (%)
Avrg. number of assets
Avrg. turnover p.a.

11.72##
11.68
0.74#
1.79
14.39
9.43
3.12
3.62

11.32##
11.30
0.73##
1.78
11.67
7.86
3.21
3.83

BL-MinVar

BS

MV

Min Var

st.w.

1/N

st.w. B&H

1/N B&H

7.31
5.27
0.79
1.78
7.30
3.33
2.91
1.96

7.29
6.08
0.68
1.69
9.41
3.92
2.69
2.67

6.09
4.17
0.71
1.70
7.45
2.74
3.71
0.77

6.29
4.86
0.65
1.66
13.99
3.16
5.00
0.18

6.08
11.08
0.27
1.24
40.59
9.72
5.00
0.29

6.51
5.07
0.67
1.67
14.19
9.70
5.00
0.00

6.25
11.08
0.28
1.25
40.50
12.33
5.00
0.00

8.27
9.40
0.55
1.48
14.35
6.87
2.33
3.34

8.21
10.37
0.49
1.46
16.18
7.53
2.16
4.44

6.03
9.16
0.32
1.27
35.10
7.65
5.00
0.27

6.08
11.08
0.27
1.24
40.59
9.72
5.00
0.29

6.39
9.52
0.34
1.31
35.30
9.70
5.00
0.00

6.25
11.08
0.28
1.25
40.50
12.33
5.00
0.00

9.46
12.38
0.51
1.51
22.23
10.26
1.86
4.76

10.35
13.62
0.53
1.53
24.59
10.77
1.72
4.61

5.81
14.27
0.19
1.15
50.99
12.38
5.00
0.25

6.08
11.08
0.27
1.24
40.59
9.72
5.00
0.29

6.27
14.74
0.21
1.18
52.04
9.70
5.00
0.00

6.25
11.08
0.28
1.25
40.50
12.33
5.00
0.00

Notes: This table reports the portfolio performance measures for the full sample from 1993 to 2011 in the base case. In all optimized portfolios, the maximum expected
volatility is constrained to 5%, 10%, and 15% p.a. for the conservative, moderate, and aggressive investor type, respectively. All portfolios are rebalanced at the first trading
day of every month. */**, # /## , / indicate a significantly higher Sharpe ratio compared to mean-variance, the strategically weighted benchmark, and the 1/N benchmark at
the significance levels of 1% and 5%, respectively.

W. Bessler et al.

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

Table 5. Empirical results for the full sample (evaluation period 19932011).

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

The European Journal of Finance

15

turnover equal to 3.32 times the portfolio volume for the moderate investor, while the yearly
turnover for MV equals 4.44 times the portfolio volume. The explanation for this result is that
the combined return estimates used in the BL approach are more stable over time than the sample
means used in MV, which is indicated by a lower variance of return estimates (unreported).
Additionally, we find that the average number of assets in the optimized portfolio, as an indicator for the magnitude of diversification across asset classes, is higher for BL than for MV and
BS portfolios. Consequently, BL portfolios offer more diversification across asset classes and
have less extreme allocations. A possible explanation is that the combined return estimates used
in the BL approach are less heterogeneous. Figure 2 presents the optimized portfolio weights for
BL and MV optimization for the three investor types during the 19932011 period. In line with
the turnover and diversification measures, the figure reveals less extreme portfolio reallocations
and a stronger benchmark orientation of the BL optimized portfolios relative to MV.
Our findings for the multi-asset data set suggest a slight outperformance of the sample-based
MV approach relative to nave-diversified strategies. In line with Kirby and Ostdiek (2012), the
level of outperformance (after transaction costs) of MV is insignificant. However, our findings
differ from that of DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2009) and Murtazashvili and Vozlyublennaia
(2013) who conclude that none of the variations of MV is able to outperform a nave 1/N
strategy. One explanation is the difference in the employed data set. While both earlier studies analyze stock-only portfolios, we additionally include government bonds, corporate bonds,
and commodities that should result in broader diversification and might enhance the portfolio
optimization benefits. Particularly, by including government bonds, asset allocation models may
outperform nave strategies if they actively shift wealth from stocks to bonds during stock market downturns and vice versa. In fact, Figure 2 shows that for both, BL and MV, and across all
investor types, the optimized portfolios are shifted completely to government bonds during the
stock market downturns between 2000 and 2003 (end of the new economy period) and between
2008 and 2009 (the financial crisis).
However, while the multi-asset approach might explain why MV performs superior in our
analysis relative to the DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2009) study, additional analyses are
required to explain the reasons for the performance differences between BL, BS, and MV
approaches. To obtain additional insights, we analyze the return estimates used in the optimization approaches. We find that for all assets the forecast error of estimated to subsequently
realized returns, measured as mean absolute error (MAE), is consistently lower for mixed return
estimates employed in the BL approach than for return estimates employed in the BS and MV
approaches. Additionally, we compute the coefficients of determination (R2 ) as the squared correlation between forecasted and subsequently realized returns and use it as an indicator for the
ex post performance. In line with the results for the MAE, we find that the coefficients of determination of forecasted returns to subsequently realized returns are larger for BL mixed return
estimates than for BS shrinked return estimates and for sample mean returns employed in MV.
The analyses of forecast errors are available from the authors upon request.
4.2

Performance of optimized portfolios in different market environments

To offer additional explanations for the performance of the asset allocation strategies in different
market environments, we divide the full evaluation period (19932011) into several sub-periods.
Expansionary and recessionary sub-periods are determined on an ex ante basis from monetary
policy and stock market signals. We combine both approaches to reduce the number of subperiods as well as the probability of incorrect signals (Bessler, Holler, and Kurmann 2012). The

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

16

W. Bessler et al.

Figure 2. BL and MV optimized portfolio weights (base case).


Notes: This figure reports the optimized portfolio weights for the full sample from 1993 to 2011 in the base
case. The optimized portfolios are constraint to a maximum expected volatility of 5%, 10%, and 15% for
the conservative, moderate, and aggressive investor type, respectively. All portfolios are rebalanced at the
first trading day of every month.

monetary cycle is the first change of the short-term interest rate by the central bank that runs
counter to the previous trend (Jensen and Mercer 2003). The stock market signal is determined
as the intersection of the 24-months moving average of the MSCI World with the actual index
from either below (expansionary state) or above (recessionary state), indicating a change in the
business cycle. For the transition from one state to another, it is required that both instruments,
the monetary policy and the stock market, provide a consistent signal. In Figure 3, we present
the definition of sub-periods derived from the joint monetary policy and stock market signals,
where shaded areas denote recessionary periods.
The first sub-period ranges from January 1993 to January 2001 and includes a number of
events such as the Asian crisis, the Russian default, and the buildup of the new economy bubble.

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

The European Journal of Finance

17

Figure 3. Definition of sub-periods.


Notes: The figure shows the definition of individual sub-periods conditional on monetary policy signals as
well as stock market signals. Shaded areas denote down markets/recessionary periods.

This period consists of 97 months and can be characterized as expanding with increasing values
in developed stock markets and relatively high interest rates with T-Bills yielding, on average,
4.77% p.a. The second sub-period between February 2001 and June 2004 covers the end of the
new economy period and the subsequent rebound of international stock markets. It includes 41
months and is characterized as recessionary with bearish stock markets and an average riskfree rate of 1.85% p.a. The third sub-period ranges from July 2004 to February 2008 covering 44
months, and containing bullish stock markets and high interest rates. The average risk-free rate
in this period is 3.67% p.a. The final sub-period from March 2008 to December 2011 includes
46 months and incorporates the financial crisis that led to substantial declines in the values of
equities and alternative asset classes, such as commodities and hedge funds. The average riskfree rate in the fourth period was only 0.37% p.a.
The performance of the out-of-sample optimized portfolios for the four sub-periods is summarized in Table 6 for the moderate investor.4 We find that BL optimized portfolios outperform
BS and MV in all four sub-periods and perform superior than nave-diversified portfolios in
three of four sub-periods. For both recessionary sub-periods, we observe substantially higher
Sharpe ratios for the BL strategies relative to MV. Naturally, due to the shorter time series of subperiods, the power of the significance test is lower relative to the full period so that differences
in Sharpe ratios are not significant at the 5% level anymore. In comparison to BayesStein and
both nave-diversified portfolios, all BL approaches achieve a substantially higher performance
in both recessionary periods.
In contrast, for both expansionary periods we find a relatively smaller outperformance of BL
in comparison to MV and BS. In the third sub-sample, which covers the bullish stock markets between July 2004 and February 2008, the nave-diversified portfolios outperform all other
optimization strategies (BL, BS, MV, and MinVar).
For all sub-periods, the BL optimized portfolios are less risky than BS, MV, and both navediversified portfolios. This is indicated by a lower maximum drawdown and is consistent with

18

W. Bessler et al.

Table 6. Analysis of sub-periods.

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

BL-st.w. BL-1/N BL-MinVar


January 1993January 2001
Net mean return p.a. (%)
10.25
Volatility p.a. (%)
9.16
Net Sharpe ratio
0.60
Net MDD (%)
9.46
Avrg. number of assets
2.95
Avrg. turnover p.a.
4.16
Avrg. risk rate
4.77%
Obs.
97
February 2001June 2004
Net mean return p.a. (%)
Volatility p.a. (%)
Net Sharpe ratio
Net MDD (%)
Avrg. number of assets
Avrg. turnover p.a.
Avrg. risk-free rate
Obs.

7.77
6.40
0.92
6.52
2.76
2.67
1.85%
41

July 2004February 2008


Net mean return p.a. (%)
Volatility p.a. (%)
Net Sharpe ratio
Net MDD (%)
Avrg. number of assets
Avrg. turnover p.a.
Avrg. risk-free rate
Obs.

13.81
9.41
1.08
6.63
3.84
3.45
3.67%
44

March 2008December 2011


Net mean return p.a. (%)
Volatility p.a. (%)
Net Sharpe ratio
Net MDD (%)
Avrg. number of assets
Avrg. turnover p.a.
Avrg. risk-free rate
Obs.

5.84
8.63
0.63
9.34
3.81
2.02
0.37%
47

BS

MV

MinVar

st.w.

1/N

10.02
9.51
0.55
9.03
3.21
4.03
4.77%
97

9.97
8.07
0.65
9.21
2.70
4.04
4.77%
97

10.93 10.41
10.34 11.08
0.60 0.51
11.42 12.93
2.35 2.09
2.95 5.48
4.77% 4.77%
97
97

6.78
7.86 6.74
3.92
6.90 8.30
0.51
0.45 0.24
5.72
15.32 19.41
3.70
5.00 5.00
0.83
0.22 0.26
4.77% 4.77% 4.77%
97
97
97

7.26
6.54
0.83
7.08
3.10
3.12
1.85%
41

8.14
6.02
1.04**
4.88
2.32
1.95
1.85%
41

5.25 5.01
7.60 8.05
0.45 0.39
9.43 10.67
2.10 1.90
4.03 4.42
1.85% 1.85%
41
41

5.97
3.71 5.19
4.84
8.32 10.00
0.85
0.22 0.33
3.40
14.19 17.37
4.56
5.00 5.00
0.62
0.30 0.31
1.85% 1.85% 1.85%
41
41
41

14.05
13.36
9.54
9.38
1.09
1.03
6.69
7.25
3.84
3.59
3.24
4.08
3.67% 3.67%
44
44

10.71 11.97
9.42 11.35
0.75 0.73
8.98 10.48
2.66 2.59
4.24 4.20
3.67% 3.67%
44
44

6.60
10.51 12.44
2.80
5.08 6.66
1.05
1.35 1.32
6.65
34.14 39.57
3.95
5.00 5.00
0.97
0.22 0.25
3.67% 3.67% 3.67%
44
44
44

6.21
8.73
0.67
11.02
4.06
1.97
0.37%
47

3.17 3.00
8.79 9.75
0.32 0.27
14.35 16.18
2.21 2.13
2.10 2.57
0.37% 0.37%
47
47

4.31
0.14 0.43
5.08
15.04 18.10
0.78 0.01 0.04
7.45
35.10 40.59
2.77
5.00 5.00
0.59
0.39 0.38
0.37% 0.37% 0.37%
47
47
47

5.06
8.28
0.57
6.90
3.00
2.10
0.37%
47

Notes: This table reports portfolio performance measures for the four sub-periods from 1993 to 2011 for the moderate
investor type. In all optimized portfolios, the maximum expected volatility is constrained to 10% p.a. All portfolios
are rebalanced at the first trading day of every month. */** Indicate a significantly higher Sharpe ratio compared to
mean-variance at the significance levels of 1% and 5%, respectively.

the analysis of the full sample. Furthermore, the analysis reveals consistently lower portfolio
turnovers and, hence, lower transaction costs for BL compared to MV for all sub-periods. Additionally, for all sub-periods BL portfolios are more diversified across asset classes than MV and
BS portfolios as indicated by a higher average number of assets in the optimized portfolios. Overall, our results suggest that the BL model outperforms MV, BS, and nave-diversified portfolios
particularly in recessionary periods. The explanation is that the BL model reacts more quickly to
changes in the economic cycle and adjusts the asset allocation more rapidly.

The European Journal of Finance

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

5.

19

Robustness checks

We perform a variety of robustness checks and sensitivity analyses to confirm the robustness of
our results. We vary the constraints on optimized portfolio weights and relax the short selling
constraint (Section 5.1). We analyze variations in all input parameters (Section 5.3) and estimation windows (Section 5.2) and modify the level of transaction costs and, alternatively, include
transaction costs in the optimization function (Section 5.4). Finally, we alter the investment universe and employ different sets of assets (Section 5.5). We primarily report the results for the
BL-st.w. strategy because the results for the other reference portfolios used in the BL approach
(st.w., 1/N, MinVar) are qualitatively similar. The same applies for the three investor types in that
we focus on the moderate investor type, as the results for the others are similar. All unreported
results are available upon request.
5.1

Alternative optimization constraints

5.1.1 Restrictions on optimized portfolio weights


It is possible that the portfolio composition of the benchmark differs substantially from the allocation of the optimized portfolios and consequently the nave-diversified benchmark portfolio
is inappropriate. Therefore, we repeat the optimizations relative to the strategically weighted
benchmark and restrict the optimized portfolio weight for each asset so that the maximum absolute deviation from the benchmark weight reported in Table 2 does not exceed a certain threshold.
This is an approach frequently used by practitioners to cope with the shortcomings of MV optimization. Table 7 presents the results for a maximum absolute deviation from the benchmark
weight of 15% points. The results confirm our findings for the base case. This holds for the
out-of-sample Sharpe ratios as well as for the portfolio risk (MDD), the portfolio diversification,
and the portfolio turnover. Intuitively, restricting asset weights lowers the portfolio turnover and
increases the average number of assets in the portfolios for all strategies.5
5.1.2 Short selling constraint
To investigate whether our findings are sensitive to the short selling constraint, we allow for short
positions in the optimization. The new results (unreported) confirm that the BL approach yields
superior portfolio performance (Sharpe ratios and Omega measures) with lower risk (volatility,
MDD, value-at-risk) compared to MV and BS approaches. When short selling is feasible the
performance of all optimization strategies improves despite higher turnover and transaction costs.
5.1.3 Volatility constraint
Next, we vary the portfolio volatility restriction, while keeping the strategic weights of stocks,
bonds, and commodities constant at the level of 40%, 45%, and 15% (moderate portfolio according to Table 2), respectively. Panel A of Table 8 shows that our results are robust for volatility
constraints between 5% and 20%. This holds for the out-of-sample Sharpe ratios, the portfolio
risk (MDD), the portfolio diversification, and the portfolio turnover.
5.1.4 Variations of the risk aversion parameter
The results for variations of the risk aversion coefficient between 0.5 and 10.0 we report in panel
B of Table 8. Again, we find that our results are robust to different risk aversion coefficients. This
holds for the out-of-sample Sharpe ratios, the portfolio risk (MDD), the portfolio diversification,

20

W. Bessler et al.

Table 7. Restriction of optimized portfolio weights.

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

BL-st.w.
Conservative
Net Sharpe ratio
Net Omega measure
Net MDD (%)
Avrg. number of assets
Avrg. turnover p.a.
Moderate
Net Sharpe ratio
Net Omega measure
Net MDD (%)
Avrg. number of assets
Avrg. turnover p.a.
Aggressive
Net Sharpe ratio
Net Omega measure
Net MDD (%)
Avrg. number of assets
Avrg. turnover p.a.

BL-1/N

BL-MinVar

BS

0.95
2.02
7.86
4.42
1.11

0.86
1.88
8.46
4.20
1.00

0.91
1.97
6.49
3.91
0.99

0.77
1.77
9.76
3.48
1.36

0.64##
1.60
21.84
4.45
1.44

0.65##
1.62
20.46
4.48
1.32

0.62##
1.62
19.33
4.31
1.42

0.40##
1.36
40.37
4.21
1.49

0.41##
1.37
39.87
4.36
1.44

0.44##
1.41
38.61
4.52
1.46

MV

MinVar st.w.

1/N

0.73
1.71
10.83
3.51
1.53

0.74
1.73
7.67
3.69
0.51

0.65 0.27
1.66 1.24
13.99 40.59
5.00 5.00
0.18 0.29

0.52
1.48
25.02
3.91
1.80

0.49
1.44
25.99
3.88
1.87

0.32 0.27
1.27 1.24
35.10 40.59
5.00 5.00
0.27 0.29

0.25
1.22
43.31
4.28
1.89

0.31
1.27
43.33
4.15
1.64

0.19 0.27
1.15 1.24
50.99 40.59
5.00 5.00
0.25 0.29

Notes: This table reports the portfolio performance measures for the full sample from 1993 to 2011. In all optimized
portfolios, the asset weights are restricted to a maximum absolute deviation of 15% from the respective benchmark
weight reported in Table 2. The maximum expected volatility is constrained to 5%, 10%, and 15% p.a. for the
conservative, moderate, and aggressive investor type, respectively. All portfolios are rebalanced at the first trading
day of each month. */**, # /## , / indicate a significantly higher Sharpe ratio compared to mean-variance, the
strategically weighted benchmark, and the 1/N benchmark at the significance levels of 1% and 5%, respectively.

as well as the portfolio turnover. The BL model performs best for risk aversion coefficients
between 2 and 4, which is in line with the assumed moderate investor type.
5.2

Alternative estimation windows

Panels C and D of Table 8 present the results for different estimation windows for the covariance
matrix and the return estimates. In line with the base case results, we find consistently higher
net Sharpe ratios for the BL approach in comparison to MV and both nave-diversified portfolios for all analyzed estimation windows. The results are insignificant for much shorter and
longer estimation windows. The portfolio turnover increases dramatically for very short estimation windows (one to six months), resulting in substantial transaction costs and a relatively lower
performance compared to the nave-diversified portfolios. For long estimation windows ( 36
months for returns), the responsiveness to structural breaks such as stock market downturns is
reduced, resulting in lower out-of-sample Sharpe ratios for all optimization approaches. An analysis of the autocorrelation functions of the asset returns confirms that only the last months returns
are significantly correlated with current returns, while returns with a lag longer than 12 months
hardly provide any explanatory power.
We identify optimal estimation windows between 36 and 48 months for the covariance matrix
and around 12 months for the return estimates for the BL approach. The insignificant results of
the BL model for very long and very short return estimation windows highlight the importance
of accurate and responsive return estimates. However, further research is required to analyze the
performance of the BL approach for alternative return estimates.

5.00%
Maximum
volatility p.a.

BL-st.w.

7.50%

BS

MV

BL-st.w.

BS

10%
MV

15%

20%

Benchmark

BL-st.w.

BS

MV

BL-st.w.

BS

MV

BL-st.w.

BS

MV

st.w.

1/N

0.75##
9.46
3.26

0.55
14.35
2.33

0.49
16.18
2.16

0.75##
11.18
3.00

0.51
22.23
1.86

0.53
24.59
1.71

0.74##
16.41
2.76

0.50
27.90
1.52

0.49
27.98
1.35

0.32
35.10
5.00

0.27
40.59
5.00

3.34

4.44

3.80

4.61

3.61

4.36

0.27

0.29

Panel A: Variation of optimization constraint: maximum allowed portfolio volatility


Net Sharpe ratio
Net MDD (%)
Avrg. number of
assets
Avrg. turnover
p.a.

0.92##
5.88
3.64

0.79##
9.30
2.91

0.68
9.41
2.69

0.80##
7.58
3.45

0.63
9.82
2.59

0.54
11.54
2.41

2.00

1.96

2.67

2.80

2.78

3.79

3.32

3.91

4.07

Panel B: Variation of risk aversion coefficient


0.5
Delta

BL-st.w.

Net Sharpe ratio


0.61
Net MDD
11.62%
Avrg. number of 2.79
assets
Avrg. turnover
3.72
p.a.

BS
0.54
14.35%
2.31
3.48

1
MV

BL-st.w.

0.47
0.68
16.18% 10.35%
2.17
2.95
4.48

3.62

BS

MV

BL-st.w.

0.54
0.48
0.75##
14.35% 16.18% 9.46%
2.31
2.16
3.26
3.38

4.49

3.32

BS

MV

BL-st.w.

0.55
0.49
0.78##
14.35% 16.18% 9.94%
2.33
2.16
3.93
3.34

4.44

2.74

BS

MV

BL-st.w.

0.53
0.50
0.69##
14.35% 16.18% 18.59%
2.35
2.19
4.53
3.32

4.44

2.04

BS

Benchmark
MV

st.w.

0.58
0.48
0.32
10.93% 15.81% 35.10%
2.42
2.25
5.00
3.36

4.35

0.27

1/N
0.27
40.59%
5.00
0.29

Panel C: Variation of estimation window for covariance matrix


Estimation
window
number of
months

12
BL-st.w.

Net Sharpe ratio


0.63
Net MDD
16.13%
Avrg. number of 3.04
assets
Avrg. turnover
4.34
p.a.

BS
0.66
10.18%
2.37
3.29

24
MV

BL-st.w.

0.56
0.73##
18.28% 14.58%
1.90
3.14
4.63

3.56

36
BS

MV

BL-st.w.

0.58
0.48
0.75##
14.04% 15.73% 9.46%
2.16
2.09
3.26
2.86

4.33

3.32

48
BS

MV

BL-st.w.

0.55
0.49
0.75##
14.35% 16.18% 8.97%
2.33
2.16
3.38
3.34

4.44

3.48

60
BS

MV

BL-st.w.

0.42
0.46
0.73
17.55% 16.99% 8.76%
2.38
2.24
3.41
3.51

4.60

3.27

BS

Benchmark
MV

st.w.

0.44
0.47
0.32
16.82% 18.26% 35.10%
2.50
2.29
5.00
3.31

4.59

0.27

1/N
0.27
40.59%
5.00
0.29

21

(Continued).

The European Journal of Finance

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

Table 8. Variation of optimization constraints, risk aversion coefficients, and estimation windows.

W. Bessler et al.

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

22

Table 8. Continued.
5.00%
Maximum
volatility p.a.

BL-st.w.

BS

7.50%

MV

BL-st.w.

BS

Panel D: Variation of estimation window for historic return estimates


Estimation
1
6
window
number of
months
BL-st.w.
BS
MV
BL-st.w.
BS
Net Sharpe ratio
Net MDD
Avrg. number of
assets
Avrg. turnover
p.a.

0.45
14.48%
2.97

0.26
0.23
19.59% 22.69%
2.10
2.01

12.30

14.44

15.29

0.57
15.65%
3.10
4.76

10%

MV

BS

MV

BL-st.w.

12
MV

0.53
0.32
15.69% 24.93%
2.26
2.15
5.68

BL-st.w.

15%

6.41

BL-st.w.

BS

3.34

MV

BL-st.w.

18
MV

0.75## 0.55
0.49
9.46% 14.35% 16.18%
3.26
2.33
2.16
3.32

BS

20%

4.44

BL-st.w.
0.56
17.45%
3.38
2.92

BS

MV

36
MV

0.43
0.33
19.44% 20.58%
2.24
2.13
2.45

BS

Benchmark

4.07

BL-st.w.
0.48
28.95%
3.69
1.81

BS

st.w.

Benchmark
MV

st.w.

0.44
0.34
0.32
22.70% 30.87% 35.10%
2.17
2.03
5.00
2.64

1/N

2.80

0.27

1/N
0.27
40.59%
5.00
0.29

Notes: The table shows sensitivity analysis for different optimization constraints, risk aversion coefficients, and estimation windows for the moderate investor type and the full
sample from 1993 to 2011. / , # /## , / indicate a significantly higher Sharpe ratio compared to mean-variance, the strategically weighted benchmark, and the 1/N benchmark
at the significance levels of 1% and 5%, respectively.

The European Journal of Finance

23

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

Relative to BS, the BL approach performs consistently superior with one exception: for a 12months estimation window for the covariance matrix, the BS approach achieves a slightly higher
Sharpe ratio than BL. However, further analysis suggests that this result is due to inflating the
covariance matrix in the BS model, which is equivalent to reducing the volatility constraint to
6.74%.6 With a volatility constraint of 6.74%, the BL and MV approaches yield a Sharpe ratio of
0.83 and 0.56 (unreported), respectively. Hence, when comparing equally constrained portfolios,
the BL approach outperforms BS and MV, which confirms our base case results.

5.3

Varying BL model parameters and 

We present the results for variations of the BL parameters and  in Table 9. The MV, BS,
and nave-diversified portfolios are insensitive to alternative values of and  and, hence, are
constant in this analysis. First, we vary the parameter in the BL model that captures the confidence in implied returns. For values of close to zero, the unconstrained optimized BL portfolio
converges to the benchmark portfolio. In contrast, for very large values of , the optimized BL
portfolio converges to the MV optimized portfolio. Panel A of Table 9 shows that for the commonly used values for between 0.025 and 1.00 (Black and Litterman 1992; He and Litterman
1999; Drobetz 2001; Idzorek 2005), our results are robust. This holds for the out-of-sample
Sharpe ratios as well as for the portfolio risk (MDD), the portfolio diversification, and the portfolio turnover. Furthermore, we observe that the BL portfolios deviation from the benchmark
declines with lower values of , which results in declining tracking errors. This is consistent with
the interpretation of as an uncertainty measure of implied returns and confirms its function to
control the desired deviation from the reference portfolio.
Second, we vary the estimation window for , which quantifies the reliability of views based
on the historic estimation errors of return forecasts. Panel B of Table 9 confirms that our results
are robust for estimation windows of  between 6 and 36 months. Third, we assume an overall
time-invariant level of confidence in the views (Meucci 2010) by substituting  according
to Equation (11). In the approach no additional time-varying information on the reliability of
views is included. Panel C of Table 9 presents the results for different overall time-invariant
levels of confidence, measured by the scalar c. We find that for all confidence levels (scalars c
between 0.1 and 100), the outperformance of the BL model relative to MV vanishes. Therefore, it
seems that including time-varying information on the reliability of return estimates is an essential
factor for the superior performance of the BL model relative to MV. This leads, on the one hand,
to an investment close to the reference portfolio when market conditions are uncertain and, on
the other hand, to larger deviations from this reference portfolio when markets are more stable
and return forecasts are more reliable.

5.4

The impact of transaction costs

To analyze the impact of transaction costs, we first vary the variable transaction costs between
0 and 50 basis points and then include variable transaction costs in the optimization function.
The net Sharpe ratio measures for different levels of transaction costs are provided in Table 10.
We find that for all analyzed levels of transaction costs, the BL portfolios outperform all other
strategies and perform consistently better than MV and both nave-diversified portfolios.

24

Panel A: Variation of level of confidence of implied returns ( )


BS
Parameter
Net Sharpe ratio
Net MDD (%)
Avrg. number of assets
Avrg. turnover p.a.
Tracking error (%)

n/a

Net Sharpe ratio


Net MDD (%)
Avrg. number of assets
Avrg. turnover p.a.
Tracking error (%)

0.3

0.15

0.1

0.05

0.71##

0.75##

0.77##

0.55
0.49
0.67
0.67
14.35
16.18
10.79 10.01 9.58
9.46
10.34
2.33
2.16
2.72
2.86 3.06
3.26
3.87
3.34
4.44
4.01
3.88 3.56
3.32
2.79
2.17
2.50
2.34
2.20 2.12
2.03
1.68
Panel B: Variation of estimation window for uncertainty measure of views ()
BS

Estimation window size (months)


for estimating the uncertainty of views

BL-st.w.: varying parameter

MV

n/a

MV
(

0)

BL-st.w
3

12

Parameter c

n/a

Net Sharpe ratio


Net MDD (%)
Avrg. number of assets
Avrg. turnover p.a.
Tracking error (%)

0.55
14.35
2.33
3.34
2.17

MV
(

)
0.49
16.18
2.16
4.44
2.50

BL-st.w
0.1
0.46
29.13
4.86
1.14
0.51

0.52 0.51
15.68 15.60
2.67 2.44
4.07 4.38
2.02 2.23

0.025

0.51
15.74
2.34
4.45
2.40

18

24

st.w
36

(

0.74
11.08
3.30
2.98
2.07

20

0.52
15.74
2.33
4.44
2.33

0.51
15.88
2.24
4.47
2.37

100
0.49
16.09
2.17
4.44
2.42

)
0.32
35.10
5.00
0.27

varying overall confidence level c for views


10

0)
0.32
35.10
5.00
0.27

varying estimation window for 

0.55
0.49
0.52
0.68 0.75## 0.73
0.76##
14.35
16.18
13.01 13.66 9.46
10.53
10.64
2.33
2.16
2.89
3.15 3.26
3.22
3.26
3.34
4.44
6.28
4.28 3.32
3.10
2.98
2.17
2.50
2.17
2.18 2.03
2.07
2.09
Panel C: Variation of assumed overall level of confidence in views (c)
BS

st.w.

st.w
(

0)
0.32
35.10
5.00
0.27

Notes: The table shows sensitivity analyses for setting different model parameters in the BL model for the moderate investor type and the full sample from 1993 to 2011. The
strategically weighted benchmark is the reference portfolio for BL and is used to compute tracking errors. */**, # /## , / indicate a significantly higher Sharpe ratio compared
to mean-variance, the strategically weighted benchmark, and the 1/N benchmark at the significance levels of 1% and 5%, respectively.

W. Bessler et al.

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

Table 9. Variation of BL model parameters.

The European Journal of Finance

25

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

Table 10. The influence of transaction costs.


Variable transaction
costs in basis points

BL-st.w.

BL-1/N

BL-MinVar

BS

MV

st.w.

1/N

MinVar

5
10
20
30
40
50

0.85##
0.83##
0.79##
0.75##
0.71
0.67

0.82##
0.80##
0.76##
0.72
0.68
0.64**

0.87##
0.85##
0.81##
0.76
0.72
0.68

0.64
0.62
0.59
0.55
0.51
0.47

0.61
0.58
0.54
0.49
0.45
0.40

0.32
0.32
0.32
0.32
0.31
0.31

0.27
0.27
0.27
0.27
0.26
0.26

0.76##
0.75#
0.73#
0.71#
0.69#
0.67#

Notes: The table shows a sensitivity analysis for different levels of transaction costs for the moderate investor type
and the full sample from 1993 to 2011. */**, # /## , / indicate a significantly higher Sharpe ratio compared to meanvariance, the strategically weighted benchmark, and the 1/N benchmark at the significance levels of 1% and 5%,
respectively.

Alternatively, we include variable transaction costs in the optimization function. The optimization problem with transaction costs is

,
max U =   

(16)

where is a vector that contains the changes in portfolio weights required to rebalance the
portfolio at the monthly rebalancing dates, and is the vector of variable transaction costs of
the assets. The results in Table 11 confirm our findings for the base case. This holds for the
out-of-sample Sharpe ratios as well as for the portfolio risk (MDD), the portfolio diversification,
and the portfolio turnover. As expected, including transaction costs in the optimization function
substantially reduces portfolio turnover for all optimization strategies and it slightly enhances
performance after transaction costs for most strategies.
5.5

Alternative asset universes

To check whether our results are robust to different sets of assets, we repeat our analysis
using different and larger asset universes. First, we include two alternative multi-asset portfolios containing a larger number of stock indices. Second, we employ stock-only portfolios as in
DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2009) to investigate the benefits of additional asset classes
such as bonds and commodities for our asset allocation models relative to nave-diversified
portfolios. The multi-asset portfolios include a larger number of stock indices denominated in
USD and Euro, reflecting USD and Euro investors. The USD multi-asset portfolio contains eight
MSCI stock indices (France, Germany, UK, Canada, USA, Italy, Japan, and Switzerland), complemented by US government bonds (Datastream Government Bond Index) and commodities
(S&P GSCI). The evaluation period is 19932011. The Euro multi-asset universe includes European government bonds, European corporate high-yield bonds, as well as four currency-hedged
regional stock indices (MSCI Europe, MSCI North America, MSCI Pacific, and MSCI Emerging
Markets) and the Euro-currency-hedged S&P GSCI commodity index. Based on the availability
of data, the evaluation period is 19992011.
The first stock-only portfolio is based on international country indices (International Stocks)
and includes eight MSCI stock indices (France, Germany, the UK, Canada, the USA, Italy, Japan,
and Switzerland) as in DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2009). The second stock-only portfolio

26

W. Bessler et al.

Table 11. Considering transaction costs in the optimization function.


BL-st.w.

BL-1/N

BL-MinVar

0.96
2.03
6.50
4.39
0.73

0.86
1.90
6.69
4.28
0.82

0.92
1.99
6.09
3.73
0.82

Moderate
Net Sharpe ratio
0.76##
Net Omega measure
1.78
Net MDD (%)
13.89
Avrg. number of assets 4.12
Avrg. turnover p.a.
1.27

0.83##
1.87
8.45
3.85
1.34

0.85##
1.92
7.56
3.42
1.34

Aggressive
Net Sharpe ratio
0.72#
Net Omega measure
1.77
Net MDD (%)
17.98
Avrg. number of assets 3.28
Avrg. turnover p.a.
1.71

0.73##
1.78
14.72
3.30
1.77

0.77##
1.86
11.00
2.91
1.87

BS

MV

MinVar

st.w.

1/N

0.82
1.85
7.35
2.86
1.58

0.73
1.72
7.80
2.72
2.16

0.64
1.61
8.35
3.81
0.21

0.65 0.27
1.66 1.24
13.99 40.59
5.00 5.00
0.18 0.29

0.50
1.47
13.75
2.39
3.25

0.50
1.47
16.18
2.21
3.81

0.32 0.27
1.27 1.24
35.10 40.59
5.00 5.00
0.27 0.29

0.52
1.52
22.23
1.97
3.67

0.53
1.53
24.59
1.75
4.10

0.19 0.27
1.15 1.24
50.99 40.59
5.00 5.00
0.25 0.29

Conservative

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

Net Sharpe ratio


Net Omega measure
Net MDD (%)
Avrg. number of assets
Avrg. turnover p.a.

Notes: This table reports the portfolio performance measures for the full sample from 1993 to 2011 when considering
transaction costs in the optimization function according to Equation (16). The variable transaction costs are set to 30 bp
for all assets. The maximum expected volatility is constrained to 5%, 10%, and 15% p.a. for the conservative, moderate, and aggressive investor type, respectively. */**, # /## , / indicate a significantly higher Sharpe ratio compared to
mean-variance, the strategically weighted benchmark, and the 1/N benchmark at the significance levels of 1% and 5%,
respectively.

includes industry indices for US stocks (US-industries) such as Oil and Gas, Basic Materials, Industrials, Consumer Goods, Health Care, Telecom, Utilities, Financials, Technology, and
Consumer Services for the 19932011 period (Datastream indices).
Panel A of Table 12 presents the performance measures (Sharpe ratios) for the two alternative multi-asset universes for a moderate investor. The conclusions for the conservative and
aggressive investors are similar. The results confirm the base case in that the BL portfolios are
consistently superior relative to the MV, BS, and nave approaches. The MV and BS portfolios
also perform slightly better than nave-diversified portfolios. However, the outperformance of
BS and MV is lower in magnitude and insignificant.
Panel B of Table 12 contains the results for stock-only asset universes.7 Because the risk of
stock-only portfolios is substantially larger than for mixed portfolios, we compute the optimization models for the aggressive investor with volatility threshold of 15% p.a. As in our base
case results, the BL model performs consistently better than MV and BS. However, similar
to DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2009) and Murtazashvili and Vozlyublennaia (2013), we
find that for stock-only portfolios none of the optimization models is able to outperform navediversified portfolios such as the 1/N strategy. The likely explanation for this finding is that
in stock-only portfolios the diversification effects and the benefits of reallocating the portfolio
over time are lower and are outweighed by estimation errors (as discussed by Murtazashvili
and Vozlyublennaia 2013) and transaction costs. We conclude that in order to outperform navediversified portfolios, optimization models require more precise return estimates than provided

The European Journal of Finance

27

Table 12. Alternative asset universes.

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

Asset
universe

Period

Number of
assets s/b/c

BL-st.w.

BL-1/N

BL-Min
Var

BS MV st.w. 1/N

Panel A: Multi-asset universes


Base case
19932011
Multi-asset USD 19932011
Multi-asset EUR 19992011

2/2/1
8/1/1
4/2/1

0.75##
0.78**
0.83##

0.72
0.77##
0.76

0.76
0.74
0.81##

0.55 0.49 0.32 0.27


0.68 0.51 0.43 0.28
0.46 0.45 0.27 0.18

Panel B: Stock-only universes


Int-stocks
19932011
US-industries
19932011

8/0/0
10/0/0

/
/

0.19
0.34

0.15
0.38

0.06 0.01
0.23 0.29

0.28
0.36

Notes: This table reports the portfolio performance (Sharpe ratios) for different asset universes. The column number of
assets shows the number of assets considered in the asset universe, where s is the number of stock indices, b is the number
of bond indices, and c is the number of commodity indices. */**, # /## , / indicate a significantly higher Sharpe ratio
compared to mean-variance, the strategically weighted benchmark, and the 1/N benchmark at the significance levels of
1% and 5%, respectively.

by sample moments. Alternatively, quantitative investors need an asset universe that includes
not only stocks, but also a broader set of assets, providing larger diversification effects and larger
benefits from dynamically reallocating the portfolio, thereby enabling optimization strategies to
provide superior results relative to nave diversification strategies.

6.

Conclusion

We implement a sample-based version of the BL model and analyze its out-of-sample performance relative to BS, MV, minimum-variance, and nave-diversified portfolios based on
multi-asset rolling sample optimizations for the period from January 1993 to December 2011.
To ensure the comparability of all optimization approaches, we use the same sample moments in
all approaches. Our empirical results contribute to the literature in several dimensions. We find
that the BL model generates a consistently higher out-of-sample performance (Sharpe ratios and
Omega measures) relative to MV, BS, and minimum-variance optimized portfolios. In comparison to nave diversification strategies with equal or strategic portfolio weights, the BL model
significantly performs better in almost all analyzed cases even after transaction costs.
Furthermore, BL portfolios are less risky as indicated by lower volatility and maximum drawdown (MDD) measures, and are more diversified across asset classes, including a larger number
of assets compared to MV and BS optimized portfolios. Sensitivity analyses suggest that the outof-sample outperformance of the BL model compared to MV is due to incorporating additional
information on the reliability of return estimates, resulting in more stable and more accurate
return estimates and consequently in a lower portfolio turnover.
We separate the full sample (19932011) into four sub-periods based on the monetary cycle
and stock market signals and find that the BL model outperforms MV and BS in all four subperiods, but the outperformance is larger in magnitude during recessionary periods. In line with
the results for the full sample period, we observe the additional benefits of the BL strategy relative
to MV in all sub-periods, such as lower risk (maximum drawdown and volatility), lower portfolio
turnover, and broader portfolio diversification.
The robustness checks confirm that our results are insensitive to restricting optimized portfolio
weights, to short selling restrictions, to all input parameter variations, and to different levels of

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

28

W. Bessler et al.

transaction costs. This holds even when transaction costs are included in the optimization function. Finally, our results hold for larger and different sets of assets. For stock-only portfolios,
the BL approaches consistently perform better than MV and BS optimization. However, when
investing solely in stocks, we find that none of the optimization models is able to outperform
consistently nave-diversified portfolios such as the 1/N strategy. For these stock portfolios, the
diversification effects are lower, and the estimation errors and transaction costs seem to outweigh the benefits of reallocating the portfolio over time. Hence, to outperform nave-diversified
portfolios, optimization models require more precise return estimates than provided by sample
moments or an asset universe that includes not only stocks, but also a broader set of assets
offering larger diversification effects and higher benefits of reallocating the portfolio over time.
Both enable optimization strategies to demonstrate their strengths vis--vis nave diversification
strategies.
Overall, we provide empirical evidence that the BL model consistently performs superior relative to MV and BS, and significantly outperforms nave strategies for all analyzed data sets,
sub-periods, and robustness checks. Consequently, quantitative portfolio managers may be able
to improve their asset allocation decisions when employing the BL approach rather than the MV
or BS framework.
Acknowledgements
We are grateful to Chris Adcock (editor) and two anonymous referees for helpful advice and comments that significantly
improved the quality of this research. The authors also thank Lawrence Kryzanowski, Paul Sderlind, Michael Frmmel,
as well as participants at the European Financial Management Symposium 2012, the 19th Annual Meeting of the German
Finance Association 2012, the International Annual Conference of the German OR Society 2012, and the Verein fuer
Socialpolitik Annual Congress 2012 for helpful comments and suggestions.

Notes
1. Value-weighted portfolios weight constituents proportional to their relative market weights and price-weighted
portfolios allocate the fraction of each constituent proportional to its actual market price.
2. Moreover, benchmark portfolios with rebalancing are more common in institutional asset management and we expect
the performance of the portfolios with rebalancing to be less sensitive to the evaluation period compared to the
buy-and-hold portfolio because the portfolio composition of the buy-and-hold portfolio varies over time based on
the relative performance of the assets during the evaluation period.
3. See Opdyke (2007) for a detailed description of the Sharpe ratio test.
4. The results for the other investor types are qualitatively similar so that we only report the performance measures
for the moderate investor. We use the same continuous sample to compute optimized portfolios and divide the
resulting return time series into four sub-samples, thereby avoiding the problems of rolling sample estimations on a
discontinuous sample.
5. It seems surprising that restricting asset weights results in higher Sharpe ratios for conservative investors, but to
an inferior performance for moderate and aggressive investors. The explanation is that the restriction of the asset
weights for the aggressive (moderate) investor results in a maximum portfolio weight of government bonds below
22.5% (50%). Therefore, in periods of stock market downturns, the asset allocation algorithm cannot fully reallocate
the portfolio into the safe asset, thereby loosing performance relative to the unrestricted case.
6. In the BS approach the sample covariance matrix is inflated by the factor (T 1)/(T N 2), where T is the
sample size and N is the number of assets. While for larger observation windows the covariance matrix inflation
in the BS approach plays only a minor role, it gets pronounced for a shorter estimation window of only 12 months
as the inflation
factor increases to 2.2 (T = 12; N = 5). In this case, the expected portfolio volatility increases by
the factor 2.2 = 1.48. Because the volatility constraint requires the expected portfolio volatility to be below 10%,
inflating
the covariance matrix by a factor of 2.2 is equal to setting the volatility constraint to a level of 6.74%
(10%/ 2.2) instead of 10%.

The European Journal of Finance

29

7. For the stock-only case, we do not compute strategically weighted portfolios as strategic weights are only used to
determine the fraction of stocks relative to bonds and commodities and we do not have any reason to set different
strategic weights for different industries or countries on an ex ante basis.

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

References
Abanomey, W. S., and I. Mathur. 1999. The Hedging Benefits of Commodity Futures in International Portfolio
Diversification. The Journal of Alternative Investments 2 (3): 5162.
Allaj, E. 2013. The Black-Litterman Model: A Consistent Estimation of the Parameter Tau. Financial Markets and
Portfolio Management 27 (2): 217251.
Anson, M. J. P. 1999. Maximizing Utility with Commodity Futures Diversification. The Journal of Portfolio
Management 25 (4): 8694.
Behr, P., A. Guettler, and F. Miebs. 2013. On Portfolio Optimization: Imposing the Right Constraints. Journal of
Banking & Finance 37 (4): 12321242.
Benartzi, S., and R. H. Thaler. 2001. Naive Diversification Strategies in Defined Contribution Saving Plans. American
Economic Review 91 (1): 7998.
Bessler, W., J. Holler, and P. Kurmann. 2012. Hedge Funds and Optimal Asset Allocation: Bayesian Expectations and
Spanning Tests. Financial Markets and Portfolio Management 26 (1): 109141.
Best, M. J., and R. R. Grauer. 1991. On the Sensitivity of Mean-Variance-Efficient Portfolios to Changes in Asset
Means: Some Analytical and Computational Results. Review of Financial Studies 4 (2): 315342.
Black, F., and R. Litterman. 1992. Global Portfolio Optimization. Financial Analysts Journal 48 (5): 2843.
Bodie, Z., and V. I. Rosansky. 1980. Risk and Return in Commodity Futures. Financial Analysts Journal 36 (3): 2739.
Broadie, M. 1993. Computing Efficient Frontiers Using Estimated Parameters. Annals of Operations Research 45 (1):
2158.
Carhart, M. M. 1997. On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance. Journal of Finance 52 (1): 5782.
Chan, L. K. C., J. J. Karceski, and J. Lakonishok. 1999. On Portfolio Optimization: Forecasting Covariances and
Choosing the Risk Model. Review of Financial Studies 12 (5): 937974.
Cheung, C. S., and P. Miu. 2010. Diversification Benefits of Commodity Futures. Journal of International Financial
Markets, Institutions, and Money 20 (5): 451474.
Chiarawongse, A., S. Kiatsupaibul, S. Tirapat, and B. van Roy. 2012. Portfolio Selection with Qualitative Input.
Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2): 489496.
Chiou, W.-J. P., A. C. Lee, and C.-C. A. Chang. 2009. Do Investors Still Benefit from International Diversification with
Investment Constraints? The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 49 (2): 448483.
Chopra, V. K., and W. T. Ziemba. 1993. The Effect of Errors in Means, Variances, and Covariances on Optimal Portfolio
Choice. The Journal of Portfolio Management 19 (2): 611.
Daskalaki, C., and G. Skiadopoulos. 2011. Should Investors Include Commodities in Their Portfolios After All? New
Evidence. Journal of Banking & Finance 35 (10): 26062626.
DeMiguel, V., L. Garlappi, and R. Uppal. 2009. Optimal Versus Naive Diversification: How Inefficient Is the 1/N
Portfolio Strategy? Review of Financial Studies 22 (5): 19151953.
Drobetz, W. 2001. How to Avoid the Pitfalls in Portfolio Optimization? Putting the Black-Litterman Approach at Work.
Financial Markets and Portfolio Management 15 (1): 5975.
Erb, C. B., and C. R. Harvey. 2006. The Strategic and Tactical Value of Commodity Futures. Financial Analysts
Journal 62 (2): 6997.
Fama, E. F., and K. R. French. 1993. Common Risk Factors in the Returns of Stocks and Bonds. Journal of Financial
Economics 33 (1): 356.
Frost, P. A., and J. E. Savarino. 1988. For Better Performance: Constrain Portfolio Weights. The Journal of Portfolio
Management 15 (1): 2934.
Gorton, G, and K. G. Rouwenhorst. 2006. Facts and Fantasies about Commodity Futures. Financial Analysts Journal
62 (2): 4768.
Grossman, S. J., and Z. Zhou. 1993. Optimal Investment Strategies for Controlling Drawdowns. Mathematical Finance
3 (3): 241276.
He, G., and R. Litterman. 1999. The Intuition Behind the Black Litterman Model Portfolios. Investment Management
Research, Goldman Sachs Quantitative Resources Group, 115.
Herold, U. 2005. Computing Implied Returns in a Meaningful Way. Journal of Asset Management 6 (1): 5364.

Downloaded by [Indian Institute of Technology Madras] at 00:37 28 April 2016

30

W. Bessler et al.

Idzorek, T. M. 2005. A Step-by-Step Guide Through the Black-Litterman Model, Incorporating User Specified Confidence
Levels. Chicago: Ibbotson Associates, 132.
Iqbal, J., R. Brooks, and D. U. A. Galagedera. 2010. Testing Conditional Asset Pricing Models: An Emerging Market
Perspective. Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (5): 897918.
Jagannathan, R., and T. Ma. 2003. Risk Reduction in Large Portfolios: Why Imposing the Wrong Constraint Helps.
The Journal of Finance 58 (4): 16511684.
James, W., and C. Stein. 1961. Estimation with Quadratic Loss. Proceedings of the 4th Berkeley Symposium on
Probability and Statistics 1: 361379.
Jensen, G. R., R. R. Johnson, and Jeffrey M. Mercer. 2000. Efficient Use of Commodity Futures in Diversified
Portfolios. Journal of Futures Markets 20 (5): 489506.
Jensen, G. R., and J. M. Mercer. 2003. New Evidence on Optimal Asset Allocation. The Financial Review 38 (3):
435454.
Jobson, J. D., and R. M. Korkie. 1981a. Putting Markowitz Theory to Work. The Journal of Portfolio Management 7
(4): 7074.
Jobson, J. D., and B. M. Korkie. 1981b. Performance Hypothesis Testing with the Sharpe and Treynor Measures. The
Journal of Finance 36 (4): 889908.
Jones, R. C., T. Lim, and P. J. Zangari. 2007. The Black-Litterman Model for Structured Equity Portfolios. The Journal
of Portfolio Management 33 (2): 2433.
Jorion, P. 1985. International Portfolio Diversification with Estimation Risk. The Journal of Business 58 (3): 259278.
Jorion, P. 1986. Bayes-Stein Estimation for Portfolio Analysis. The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 21
(3): 279292.
Kirby, C., and B. Ostdiek. 2012. Its All in the Timing: Simple Active Portfolio Strategies That Outperform Naive
Diversification. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 47 (2): 437467.
Landsman, Z., and J. Nelehov. 2008. Steins Lemma for Elliptical Random Vectors. Journal of Multivariate Analysis
99 (5): 912927.
Lee, W. 2000. Advanced Theory and Methodology of Tactical Asset Allocation. New Hope: Frank J. Fabozzi Associates,
125136.
Lo, A. W. 2002. The Statistics of Sharpe Ratios. Financial Analysts Journal 58 (4): 3652.
Markowitz, H. 1952. Portfolio Selection. Journal of Finance 7 (1): 7791.
Meucci, A. 2006. Beyond Black-Litterman in Practice: A Five-Step Recipe to Input Views on Non-normal Markets.
Risk 19 (9): 114119.
Meucci, A. 2010. The Black-Litterman Approach: Original Model and Extensions. Working Paper, SYMMYS.
Meyer, J. 1987. Two Moment Decision Models and Expected Utility Maximization. American Economic Review 77
(3): 421430.
Michaud, R. O. 1989. The Markowitz Optimization Enigma: Is the Optimized Optimal? Financial Analysts Journal
45 (1): 3142.
Murtazashvili, I., and N. Vozlyublennaia. 2013. Diversification Strategies: Do Limited Data Constrain Investors?
Journal of Financial Research 36 (2): 215232.
Opdyke, J. D. 2007. Comparing Sharpe Ratios: So Where Are the p-Values? Journal of Asset Management 8 (5):
308336.
Pastor, L. 2000. Portfolio Selection and Asset Pricing Models. The Journal of Finance 50 (1): 179223.
Pastor, L., and R. F. Stambaugh. 2000. Comparing Asset Pricing Models: An Investment Perspective. Journal of
Financial Economics 56 (3): 335381.
Plyakha, Y., R. Uppal, and G. Vilkov. 2012. Why Does an Equal-Weighted Portfolio Outperform Value- and PriceWeighted Portfolios. Working Paper, Goethe University Frankfurt.
Satchell, S., and A. Scowcroft. 2000. A Demystifcation of the Black Litterman Model: Managing Quantitative and
Traditional Portfolio Constructions. Journal of Asset Management 1 (2): 138150.
Satyanarayan, S., and P. Varangis. 1996. Diversification Benefits of Commodity Assets in Global Portfolios. The
Journal of Investing 5 (1): 6978.
Shadwick, W. F., and C. Keating. 2002. A Universal Performance Measure. Journal of Performance Measurement 6
(3): 5984.
Stein, C. 1955. Inadmissibility of the Usual Estimator for the Mean of a Multivariate Normal Distribution. 3rd Berkeley
Symposium on Probability and Statistics 1 (399): 197206.
Theil, H. 1971. Principles of Econometrics. New York: Wiley.
You, Leyuan, and Robert T. Daigler. 2013. A Markowitz Optimization of Commodity Futures Portfolios. The Journal
of Futures Markets 33 (4): 343368.

Potrebbero piacerti anche