Sei sulla pagina 1di 16

The Political Economy of the Indonesias

Negative Investment List (NIL) 2014

Nurman Hidayat / G1502523B


Santi H. Paramitha / G1500382E

IP 6025 Comparative Political Economy


Trimester 2 AY 2015/2016

Introduction
In the globalization era, the removal of investment barriers between states
consequences one state to invest in other states through relatively easy process without
significant problems. Aside from the economic opportunity that arises, globalization signals
higher challenge in terms of competition between states. Since FDI is believed to contribute to
economic growth, states are gearing up to create a business friendly environment with the
purpose to attract more FDI. With regard to that condition, in October 2012, Indonesia
formulated a policy package containing four initatives to boost the investment activities.1 This
policy package was concentrated to address the issues which hinder the investments activities,
through: (1) the deregulation of investment licenses; (2) the acceleration of agriculture and
mining based investment programs by providing tax incentives; (3) the improvement of the
ease of doing business;2 and (4) the formation of more open investment policy through the
new Negative Investment List.3
Noting that Indonesia possesses abundant natural resources, working years' surplus,
growing middle class, as well as huge potential markets, these initiatives are expected to
enhance Indonesia competitiveness in the eyes of foreign investors. In addition to that,
Indonesia has been acknowledged as the 3rd top prospective host economies by UNCTAD
World Investment Report in 2014, in which Indonesia was ranked at the 4th position in 2013.4
This explains the big chunk of investment which contributes 32,57% of Indonesias GDP.5
However, this favorable investment opportunity seems to be challenged as the NIL
2014 released. The NIL 2014 is considered to be contradictory with the governments promise
to give more spaces for investment as mentioned in October 2012 policy package, as it presents
more restriction towards specific sectors such as agriculture and logistic distribution. In some
cases, the sectors which become limitedly opened or sealed for FDI are the sectors which
actually require more foreign investment for the reason of: (1) the lack of national capability
1

Indonesia Economic Quarterly Report December 2013, accessed in February 1 st 2016, through
http://www.worldbank.org/content/dam/Worldbank/document/EAP/Indonesia/IEQ-Dec13-ENGLISH.pdf
2
Ease of doing business refers to the components of doing business index, such as the level of easiness for
setting up new businesses, getting electricity connection, paying taxes, etc. It is released by International Finance
Corporation World Bank Group, please find the detail through http://www.doingbusiness.org/
3
Negative Investment List is a government instrument which regulates limitation of the sectors for investment.
Before the introduction of this policy package, the latest NIL was regulated under Presidential Regulation
number 36 of 2010, called as NIL 2010.
4
UNCTAD World Investment Report 2014, accessed in February 1 st 2016, through
http://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2014_en.pdf
5
Source Ministry of Finance Website, February 5th 2015, http://www.kemenkeu.go.id/Berita/pdb-2014mencapai-rp105427-triliun

to develop the sectors, (2) the huge national demand upon the sectors outcome, and (3) the
economic potency of creating wider employment through opening new business activity.
Embarking from that particular case, this paper intends to examine the relevant
dimensions to understand the case of NIL 2014, such as the formulation mechanism of NIL;
the political economy of NIL 2014 by observing the motives of each actor involved in the
making of NIL 2014 and constructing its interaction model; and the NIL 2014 policy
implications, to answer the following questions:
1.

Why does the government of Indonesia apply more restrictive treatment to specific
sectors through the Negative Investment List (NIL) 2014, under the favorable
investment opportunity? Is there any possibility of business players interests being
granted by the government through the implementation of NIL 2014 upon certain
sectors?

2.

What are the implications for Indonesias economy by applying NIL 2014?
This paper assumes that NIL 2014 is not merely formulated based on the national

interest of supporting domestic economy. There are other reasons incorporated in the
consideration of deciding the sectors to be put on the list. This is rooted on the factual
mechanism that NIL is periodically adjusted based on the government preferences and dialogue
with the existing business players to regulate the sectors which are fully opened, limitedly
opened, or even sealed for the foreign investment.

Literature Review
Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) can be understood as a cross-border investments flow
made by a firm which located in one country to expand its business by opening a new factory
or purchasing an existing one in another country.6 Previous researches have mentioned that
beyond the possession of natural resources, competitive factor production costs, and larger
market opportunity, the host countrys type of regime is central to explain the countrys
attractiveness and attitude towards FDI.
In terms of countrys attractiveness, the conventional wisdom says that authoritarian
regime provides more promising deals for foreign investors, due to the lack of constraints and
low pressure of labor union on political leaders. The better deals offered by authoritarian
regimes, are mostly related to the cheaper labor wages and dictators protection for the foreign
companies run their business. While authoritarian regimes provide better deals, the democratic

Thomas Oatley, International Political Economy, (US: Pearson Education, Inc, 2012), 161.

regime, on the other hand, offers different appealing consideration for the foreign investors to
plant their money. Democratic regime provides credibility and political stability as the pull
factors. Noting that the democratic regime consists of large veto players, its tendency to violate
its own regulation and promises will be small. Also, as mentioned by Olson, the wellestablished democracy, will ensure the future of the FDI in the host country.
Research upon the countrys attitude towards FDI was conducted by Li and Resnick in
2003. Li and Resnick argue, although the democratic regime owns more likeable factors for
foreign investors, it does not necessarily suggest that democratic country will be more open to
the FDI.7 Their empirical result proves that higher the level of democracy will create better
judicial systems and rule of law as well as multiple avenue for the domestic groups to deliver
their concern. These conditions sometimes may drive the government of democratic countries
to put necessary constraints to the FDI, for the consideration of protecting their domestic
market players from serious foreign competitors.
In addition to that, previous research also finds that individual preferences may also
influence the states attitude towards FDI. As mentioned on Mayda and Rodrik research, they
find that there is a positive relationship between national pride and protectionist preferences
towards FDI. It indicates that the higher the individual national pride within a state, the state
will be less likely to widely open its door for FDI.8 With quite similar view, Sornarajah states
that nationalistic sentiments would hinder the prospect of FDI, particularly when the host
country economy is in the downturn and the prosperous foreign investors are seen as
controlling the economy.9
Besides national pride, Scheve and Slaughter mention that perceived job insecurity also
induces the individual preference for FDI. It is rooted in the assumption that FDI increases the
elasticity of labor demand in the host country, which therefore results in individual perception
to relate FDI to the future of their jobs. Their findings suggest that individuals which perceive
their jobs will be more vulnerable as the FDI flows in, will demonstrate less favorable
preference towards the FDI.10 Furthermore, Pandya research in 2010, confirms that the
individual level of education and is also found to be significant in shaping the preferences. The

Quan Li and Adam Resnick, Reversal of Fortunes: Democratic Institutions and Foreign Direct Investment
Inflows to Developing CountriesInternational Organization 57 No. 1 (2003), 196.
8
Anna Maria Mayda and Dani Rodrik, Why Are Some People (and Countries) More Protectionist Than Others?
European Economic Review 49 No. 6 (2005), 1416.
9
M. Sornarajah, The International Law on Foreign investment, (UK: Cambridge University Press, 2004), 78-79.
10
Kenneth F. Scheve and Matthew J. Slaughter, Labor Market Competition and Individual Preferences over
Immigration Policy Review of Economics and Statistics 83 No. 1 (2001), 141-142.

support for FDI inflows within a state will decrease in a condition where the educational
background is low, and increase as the educational background is high.11
Aside from the regime effects and individual preferences, Goodman, Spar, and Yoffie
explain another factor contributes to the countrys attitude towards FDI, which is the relations
of FDI to imports. Their results show that in the situation when FDI is considered as import
complementary, there will be a split in the domestic industry, with the domestic business player
of the host country will request for more protectionist measure from the government for FDI.12
On the other hand, when the FDI is taken as substitute to import, the demand of domestic
business players of host country for protection declines, as the protection benefits are becoming
irrelevant.13
However, apart from the sole reliance on the power of the government, the growing
economic conditions in developing countries support the birth of local companies and
entrepreneurs to play in the domestic markets. Given the considerable number of the local
business players, it then becomes imperative to note the role of business players in shaping the
governments decision. In regard to that, slightly different from the existing approach which
considers the regime type, individual preferences, and FDI relations to import as the influential
factors to the states attractiveness and attitude towards FDI, this paper seeks to examine the
case of the Negative Investment List (NIL) year of 2014 in Indonesia. The research will be
developed by scrutinizing the interaction between business players and government in making
restrictive policies towards FDI. This still dovetails with the previous research findings, which
shows that more democratic country will provide more spaces for the domestic groups to
vocalize their concern to the government, in which, when the domestic group pressure and
lobby are strong, the governments are urged to accommodate their requests.

Discussions

Negative Investment List


Formulation Mechanism
All of direct investment activities in Indonesia are regulated under the Law Number 25
of 2007 on Investment. According to this law, all business fields in Indonesia are open for
11

Sonal S. Pandya, Labor Market and the Demand for Foreign Direct Investment International Organization 64
No. 3 (2010), 406.
12
John B. Goodman, Debora Spar, and David B. Yoffie, Foreign Direct Investment and the Demand of the
Protection in the US, International Organization 50 No. 4 (1996), 569.
13
Ibid., 587

investment, unless those which are stated as close or open with a certain condition14 on the NIL
or have been regulated by other law. Noting that NIL is an instrument of investment restriction
that is codified in the form of Presidential Regulation, thus the agenda setting in NIL is more
flexible compared to the restriction which is regulated through legislation, because it only
involves the executive element as the policy makers. However, any setting on investment
restriction through NIL has its own level of complexity since each drafting process attracts a
lot of attention from business and political circles.
NIL is evaluated periodically. Those adjustments are done by taking into account the
economic development and national interest. The adjustment process of NIL is coordinated by
the Investment Coordinating Board (BKPM) to involve the related Ministries and the business
players representative. The related ministries and business players may submit their proposal
accompanied by supporting reasons during the evaluation process of NIL. The proposals
subsequently are discussed bilaterally with BKPM and multilaterally in a coordination meeting
with the Coordinating Ministry for Economic Affairs. This suggests that the evaluation of the
previous NIL and the formulation of the new NIL, involve not only the governments branches
but also the business players as the major actors in NIL policy-making.
Grounding to the assumption that the business players are basically profit maximizers
while the government and politicians are survival maximizers, this paper views that the above
mentioned mechanism, opens the opportunity for lobbying process between the business
players and government in every formulation of NIL. A particular business players may ask
for protection to maximize their profits. To successfully get protection, they create a
collectively powerful lobbying power to the government by using the business association. In
the name of business association, they actively lobby the government for their collective
interests. In accordance with this realm, this paper explores the motivation of each actor above
on the latest investment restriction policy-making codified in NIL 2014 as replacement of NIL
2010.

Negative Investment List (NIL) 2014


NIL 2014 was enacted on 23 April 2014, on the same month with the general elections
and only three months to the presidential election on July 2014. Its formulation process had
14

Fully open means all business player are allowed to conduct a business in those area, close means none of
private sector are allowed, while open with condition means that those business sectors are allowed but subject
to certain requirement, such as only open for small-medium enterprise, only open for domestic investment, or
could be open for foreign investment with certain ceiling equity.

been started from the end of 2012 and was originally scheduled for completion at the end of
2013. At first, according to the government, the new NIL aimed to encourage more investment
activities by introducing a more liberal policy measures. The Government was also reaffirmed
to further loosen the restrictions for foreign investment by opening up a greater investment
opportunities in infrastructure through Public-Private Partnership (PPP) schemes. In addition,
the government also said that it would be a more open investment policy in a number of sectors
such as pharmaceutical industry, transportation, and specialty hospitals.
Later, this announcement got a lot of negative responses in the media.15 Towards these
initiatives, many parties accused the government for failing to protect the national interest. A
similar sentiment was expressed by domestic business players that calling for a number of
protection from competition with foreign investors. Upon this situation, the government tried
to soften the debate stating that the discussions were still unfinished and turned to express its
commitment to balance the national interest.16 It took a quite long time for the NIL to be fully
released in April 2014, showing that there was a tough negotiation between government and
the business players to accommodate those kind of national interest.
In NIL 2014, there are several business field provisions that change from NIL 2010 as
presented in Tabel 1. Some sectors are more relaxed and some other are more restrictive
towards foreign investment. NIL 2014 relaxes the limitations on foreign ownership in sectors
such as in infrastructures including electricity generation, transmission and power distribution,
port facilities, pharmaceutical industry, and transportation. On the other side, NIL 2014 also
introduces new restrictions in business retail, trade services including distribution,
warehousing and cold storage, onshore oil production services, as well as horticulture sectors.
In comparison, many perceive that NIL 2014 is becoming more protectionist towards FDI
rather than NIL 2010.17

15

Erlangga Djumena, Asing Semakin Mendominasi Ekonomi Indonesia, KOMPAS, November 7th 2013,
http://bisniskeuangan.kompas.com/read/2013/11/07/0756260/Asing.Semakin.Mendominasi.Ekonomi.Indone
sia
16
Ibid.
17
Michael Taylor and Randy Faby, Foreign Investor Unhappy With Some Indonesias New Investment Rules,
Reuters,
May
14th
2014,
http://www.reuters.com/article/indonesia-economy-investmentidUSL3N0NV3L920140514

Table 1
Investment Policy Changes from NIL 2010 to NIL 201418
Political Economy of NIL 2014
To understand the dynamics of political economy in the process of formation
investment policy in Indonesia, this paper identifies at least two major actors involved in NIL
formation, namely government and business players. From the government side, it consists of
the president and the ministries of the related sectors, where the president and all the ministers
stand as politicians. Therefore, it is essential to analyze what kind of political incentives the
government possess by imposing NIL. Two polar groups are identified within the business

18

Compiled from the Presidential Regulation No. 36 of 2010 and Presidential Regulation No. 39 of 2014.

players. The first group is domestic business players that generally demands for protection
while the second group is foreign business players that prefer investment liberalization to
protection. In the following section, this paper will explain those actors profile and their
motivations in NIL policy-making, then finally draw the interaction model among those.

Actor 1: Business Players


First, we start to identify the profiles and motivations of business players that involve
in policy formation of NIL. At the stage of collecting inputs, the government opens a wide
opportunity for the business players, whether they are domestic or foreign players and whether
as an individual firm or through a business association, to provide input for the evaluation of
previous NIL and produce the new version of NIL. The foreign groups are more likely to
support liberalization in contrary with the domestic groups which generally demand for more
protective policies.
However, on the next stage of NIL policy discussion, the government engage Apindo
(The Employers' Association of Indonesia) as the only party to represent business players.19
The Apindos members consist of both domestic and multinational companies in Indonesia, in
which its MNC members are concentrated in the manufacturing sector. Noting that the board
of Apindo is dominated by domestic business players, its policy preferences on the formation
of NIL tends to bring along the nationalistic concern.
During the development of NIL, Apindo expresses its support for the government's
plans to liberalize investment in infrastructure, electricity, and manufacturing industry.
However, Apindo also demands the government to maintain the protection in retail trade20 and
impose new restriction on logistic distribution sectors, including distribution, warehousing, and
cold storage.21 According to Apindo chairman, Sofjan Wanandi, such protection is necessary
to provide business opportunities for domestic entrepreneurs. He argues that domestic
employers have been unable to compete with foreign investors in manufacturing due to lack of
capital and technology, hence the retail and distribution sector need to be protected so not all
sectors can be controlled by foreigners.
19

Apindo is the largest business association in Indonesia that covers all business sectors running in Indonesia.
At that time, the government responded this request by keeping the closed investment status for the retail
trade business and further providing more details in regard to what kind of retail trade business being listed as
closed (which had not been mentioned in the prior NIL 2010).
21
Linda Yusman, Retail, Distribution should be Put on Negative List: Apindo, The Jakarta Post, May 11th 2013,
accessed through
http://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/05/11/retail-distribution-should-be-put-negative-listapindo.html
20

From those explanations, this paper assumes that Apindo would likely to demand for
protection with certain ceiling foreign equities limitation rather than full restriction to FDI. In
this case, foreign investors would be required to set up a joint venture company with domestic
players, showing that the presence of foreign investors must bring benefits for local
entrepreneurs, became partners and not competitors.22 The second preference would be full
protection from foreign investment in retail trade and distribution sectors. While the last
preference would be to let government in maintaining a liberal policy in those sectors. In order
to maximize its probability for success in this lobbying, business players may offer any kind
of political support to the incumbent (government) to win the upcoming elections, given that
2014 general election and the presidential election were coming soon.

Actor 2: Governments
To examine the motivation of the government, this paper employs electoral cycles
(office-seeking policy makers) model to test whether the government has an office-seeking
motivation in NIL policy making. This paper is engrained on the assumption that politicians,
including incumbent governments are basically survival maximizers. Voters will be an
important consideration for them to decide what policies will be taken. Government tends to
target specific policies that can satisfy the median voter (Downs 1975).23 In Indonesia, the
median voters are dominated by workers or lower and middle classes. This class will tend to
favor pro-employment policies rather than low inflation. As in general, people easily forget the
old policy outcomes, voters have a tendency to assess the government performance through the
latest policy outcomes. On this premise, the government has a political incentive to pursue
specific measures that can spur growth and combat unemployment mainly on the time leading
up to elections. (Nordhaus 1975).24 The purpose is none other to lure voters at the next election.
In relation to those premises, NIL formulation that began in late 2012 (1.5 years ahead
of elections) initially aims to reverse the economic downturn by opening up to attract more
FDI in attempt to reduce unemployment and boost economic growth. Nevertheless, in
November 2013, apparently that liberal policy was reaping a lot of negative responses in the
media. Many put the commitment of the government of securing national interest into question.

22

Satria Sambijantoro, Door Widens for Foreign Investors, The Jakarta Post, November 7th 2013, accessed
through http://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/11/07/door-widens-foreign-investors.html
23
Antony Downs, An Economic Theory of Political Action in Democracy Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 65,
No 2 (April 1957), 135-150.
24
William D. Nordhaus, The Political Business Cycle The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 42, No. 2 (Apr.,
1975), 169-190.

This momentum is also captured by the domestic business players to reinforce their
lobbying power in asking for investment protection through NIL. The rising of nationalist and
protectionist sentiment in closer to the elections, makes the government to delay the enactment
of NIL and continue to negotiate in balancing the national (domestic players) interest. Due to
the tight time to the election, an investment policy would likely to become ineffective
instrument to stimulate investment, employment, and growth in a short time.
Pragmatically, signalling pro nationalist by accommodating a little protectionist policy,
may give more political incentives for the incumbent government to reap political support in a
short time. First, to lure voters. Second, to open up the possibility of cooperation with business
players in an effort to win the election. From the situation, the government tends to
accommodate protectionist policy as demanded by domestic business players. This policy can
become a popular policy with a fashionable jargon of for the sake of national interest.
Interaction Model between Government and Business Players Representative (Apindo)
This section explains the interaction model in NIL policy-making between the
Government and Apindo as the representative from business players. The model is constructed
based on the profile and the possible incentives for both players as been descripted in the
previous section. By considering its possible incentives, this paper predicts the order of each
players preferences from the highest to the lowest as follows. Apindo prefers a moderate
protection with certain ceiling limitation for foreign equities; over full protection; over no
protection. Apindo gets its most preferred outcome, suppose payoff of 3, if it demands for
ceiling limitation and the government complies. Apindo locks its next best outcome, payoff of
2, if it seeks a full protection and the government agrees. Lastly, Apindo acquires the lowest
outcome, payoff of 0, if it does not pursue any protection or if the government rejects its
demands.
The government favors investment liberalization over all other alternatives; slightly
dislikes foreign investment limitation with a certain maximum amount of shares; and detests
full restriction on foreign investment, but also wants to meet its constituents expectation to
balance the national interest. Accordingly, the government prefers no investment restrictions
if none protection is demanded. It yields the best outcome for government, suppose payoff of
3. In turn, if Apindo demands for protection policy, the government prefers granting a mild
protection with a particular foreign equity limitation (payoff of 2) over rejecting its
constituents voices (payoff of 1), but prefers to repudiate a constituent (payoff of 1) rather

10

than grants a full investment protection (payoff of 0). The possible payoff and interaction
model between the Government and Apindo are illustrated in Figure 1.

Government and Apindo:


Strategic Interaction over Investment Policy
Government
(G)
Lobby for
full protection

Apindo
(A)

Government
(G)
Lobby for

Accept

(2,0)

Reject

(0,1)

Accept

(3,2)

Reject

(0,1)

ceiling limitation
Do not lobby
for protection

(0,3)
Figure 1
Interaction between Government and Apindo during the Formulation of NIL 201425
Based on these preferences and game settings, the Apindos best strategy is to lobby
government for imposing ceiling limitation on foreign equities. If Apindo is doing so, the
government would likely allow its demand and Apindo will attain its best possible payoff (3).
In contrast, if Apindo asks for full protection or does not lobby at all, it will not receive any
protection and will be left with the lowest payoff of 0. This lobbying game will meet its
equilibrium condition when Apindo asks for ceiling limitation and government yields its
lobbying efforts.

Policy Implications
The aforementioned section has elaborated the circumstance which influences why NIL
2014 is formulated the way it is. Morevover, this section will further explain how the NIL 2014
25

Adapted from Frieden, Jeffrey A. Actor and Preferences in International Relations in Strategic Choice in
International Relations ed. David A. Lake and Robert Powell. New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1999, 43.

11

affects the Indonesian economy. The implications of the execution of NIL 2014 can be divided
into two aspects, which are (1) the implications towards the domestic business players and (2)
implications towards the future of investment activities in Indonesia.
First, this paper argues that in some sectors, the regulation of NIL 2014 is too focused
on accommodating the demand of the specific business players in the name of the national
interest without really paying attention to the national capability and demand. It later results to
the imbalance of the national supply and demand.
As mentioned on the previous section, the restriction on retail trade creates incentive
for the domestic business players while disadvantage the foreign investor because of the entry
barrier. In addition, in the case of restriction on the logistic distribution, the World Bank Report
in 2013 states that Indonesias logistic cost reached to 24% of Indonesia GDP, higher than
other countries in the region.26 This high cost and long logistic distribution process are mainly
caused by the high demands which are not met by the limited number and the poor capacities
of logistic distribution providers in Indonesia, which actually can be altered by opening the
sectors for the foreign companies to operate.
However, what the government decided through NIL 2014 is paradoxical. Instead of
opening the sectors for the foreign companies, it decides to limit the sectors for the reason of
protecting the national interest. This decision champions the domestic players which run their
business in the logistic distribution since it is a strategic sector which demand will be relatively
stable or even higher. Oppositely, it generates difficulty for the other domestic business players
which business requires logistic distribution to market their commodities, as evident on the
hiking logistic distribution cost to become 26,4% of Indonesias GDP in 2015.27
Secondly, the introduction of the more protective NIL in 2014 triggers the perception
towards the Indonesias investment climate to go south, as shown on the UNCTAD World
Investment Report 2015. While the prior report suggests Indonesia will be number 3 among
the worlds top prospective host economies, Indonesia falls down to rank 14 in the period of

26

World Bank Website, High Logistics Costs Impede Higher Economic Growth For Indonesia, Says Joint Report,
September 6th 2016, accessed through
http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-release/2013/09/06/high-logistics-costs-impede-highereconomic-growth-for-indonesia
27
Reiy Schreiben, Tingginya Biaya Logistik Dan Solusi Untuk Menekan Biaya Logistik Di Indonesia, Indonesian
Logistic Association (Asosiasi Logistik Indonesia) Website, accessed on February 5 th 2016 through
http://www.ali.web.id/detail_article.php?id=69

12

2015 to 2017.28 Although it is later reported that Indonesias FDI inflow grow about 20%,29 its
FDI is now more concentrated to specific sectors, which leave the other potential sectors being
uncultivated. This insinuates that the more restrictive measure on NIL 2014 reduces the
opportunity of the new business players entrance to Indonesia from various business
background. Finally, the fact that Indonesia owns quite stable democratic regime, abundant
natural resources, and huge labor advantage will be a waste, as they are no longer attractive for
the FDI. Without further improvement on the existing NIL 2014, it is expected to jeopardize
the Indonesias investment activities future.

Conclusion
Starting with questioning the government of Indonesias more restrictive measure
towards FDI through the implementation of NIL 2014, this paper finally discovers several
findings to explain why the NIL 2014 is contradictory with the initial agenda of the government
to spur the investment activities and growth in Indonesia.
First, this paper finds that there is a compromised interests between the government and
the business players during the formulation of NIL 2014. Related with the argument of Li and
Resnick in the earlier section, the democracy allows the dialogue between the government and
the business players within a country. In the case of Indonesia, the business players under the
Apindo request for the government to set necessary barricade to the sectors which in fact need
more foreign investment to develop, noting the limited availability of domestic capital and the
lack of domestic business players capacity of doing so. Considering that the period of new
election is approaching, the government with its office-seeking motive then accommodates the
Apindo request in exchange of the political support.
Second, the negative response from the society and media upon the first initiative of
the government to open more rooms for FDI, showing that national sentiment plays important
role in shaping the economic policy outcome in Indonesia. This is particularly consistent with
the research of Mayda and Rodrick, as well as Sornarajah, about the positive relation between
nationalistic sentiments and protectionist measure towards FDI.
Third, the case of NIL 2014 in the logistic distribution sector, also suggests that when
government accommodate the interests of small groups of the business players, it will conceive
28

UNCTAD World Investment Report 2015, accessed in February 6 th 2016, through


http://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2015_en.pdf
29
Galih Gumelar, Naik 20%, Investasi Asing di Indonesia Tertinggi di ASEAN, CNN Indonesia, June 25th 2016,
accessed through http://www.cnnindonesia.com/ekonomi/20150625010145-92-62208/naik-20-investasiasing-di-indonesia-tertinggi-di-asean/

13

an imbalance supply and demand which gains those who are being protected while burdens
the more broader society. Besides, the restrictive measure without proper cost and benefit
consideration will hinder the economic growth and ditch the the sectors which should pose
greater benefits for the whole economy if they are optimally developed.
At the end, this paper concludes that specific interest groups, media pressure, national
perception towards FDI, and political concideration are the important factors which may lead
the government towards the protectionist policy in Indonesia. In which, the implications of the
protectionist policy in the name of national interest somehow does not nationally bring optimal
benefits to the whole society, since it is proven to conversely compensate only specific groups
within society with whom the government compromise its interests.
Bibliography
Books
Oatley, Thomas. International Political Economy. US: Pearson Education Inc, 2012.
Frieden, Jeffrey A. Actor and Preferences in International Relations in Strategic Choice in
International Relations ed. David A. Lake and Robert Powell. New Jersey: Princeton
University Press, 1999.
Sornarajah, M. The International Law on Foreign investment. UK: Cambridge University
Press, 2004.
Journals
Goodman, John B. Debora Spar and David B. Yoffie. Foreign Direct Investment and the
Demand of the Protection in the US, International Organization 50 No. 4 (1996): 565 591.
Li, Quan and Adam Resnick. Reversal of Fortunes: Democratic Institutions and Foreign
Direct Investment Inflows to Developing CountriesInternational Organization 57 No. 1
(2003): 175 211.
Mayda, Anna Maria and Dani Rodrik. Why Are Some People (and Countries) More
Protectionist Than Others? European Economic Review 49 No. 6 (2005): 1393 - 1430.
Pandya, Sonal S. Labor Market and the Demand for Foreign Direct Investment International
Organization 64 No. 3 (2010): 389 409.
Scheve, Kenneth F. and Matthew J. Slaughter. Labor Market Competition and Individual
Preferences over Immigration Policy Review of Economics and Statistics 83 No. 1 (2001):
133 145.

14

Reports
Indonesia Economic Quarterly Report December 2013, accessed in February 1st 2016, through
http://www.worldbank.org/content/dam/Worldbank/document/EAP/Indonesia/IEQ-Dec13ENGLISH.pdf
UNCTAD World Investment Report 2014, accessed in February 1st 2016, through
http://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2014_en.pdf
UNCTAD World Investment Report 2015, accessed in February 6th 2016, through
http://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/wir2015_en.pdf
News and Website
Djumena, Erlangga. Asing Semakin Mendominasi Ekonomi Indonesia, KOMPAS,
November 7th 2013,
http://bisniskeuangan.kompas.com/read/2013/11/07/0756260/Asing.Semakin.Mendominasi.E
konomi.Indonesia
Gumelar, Galih. Naik 20%, Investasi Asing di Indonesia Tertinggi di ASEAN, CNN
Indonesia,
June
25th
2016,
accessed
through
http://www.cnnindonesia.com/ekonomi/20150625010145-92-62208/naik-20-investasi-asingdi-indonesia-tertinggi-di-asean/
International Finance Corporation World Bank Group, http://www.doingbusiness.org/
Ministry of Finance Website, February 5th 2015, http://www.kemenkeu.go.id/Berita/pdb-2014mencapai-rp105427-triliun
Sambijantoro, Satria. Door Widens for Foreign Investors, The Jakarta Post, November 7th
2013, accessed through http://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/11/07/door-widensforeign-investors.html
Schreiben, Reiy Schreiben. Tingginya Biaya Logistik Dan Solusi Untuk Menekan Biaya
Logistik Di Indonesia, Indonesian Logistic Association (Asosiasi Logistik Indonesia)
Website,
accessed
on
February
5th
2016
through
http://www.ali.web.id/detail_article.php?id=69
Taylor, Michael and Randy Faby. Foreign Investor Unhappy With Some Indonesias New
Investment Rules, Reuters, May 14th 2014, http://www.reuters.com/article/indonesiaeconomy-investment-idUSL3N0NV3L920140514
World Bank Website, High Logistics Costs Impede Higher Economic Growth For Indonesia,
Says
Joint
Report,
September
6th
2016,
accessed
through
http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/press-release/2013/09/06/high-logistics-costs-impedehigher-economic-growth-for-indonesia
Yusman, Linda.Retail, Distribution should be Put on Negative List: Apindo, The Jakarta
Post, May 11th 2013, accessed through
http://www.thejakartapost.com/news/2013/05/11/retail-distribution-should-be-put-negativelist-apindo.html

15

Potrebbero piacerti anche