Sei sulla pagina 1di 98

Part 1 Getting Started

Instructors Manual to accompany


Public Finance, Eighth Edition, by Harvey S. Rosen and Ted Gayer
Suggested Answers to End-of-Chapter Discussion Questions
Some of the questions have no single correct answer reasonable people can go off in
different directions. In such cases, the answers provided here sketch only a few possibilities.
Chapter 1 - Introduction
1.

2.

a.

Putins statement is consistent with an organic conception of government.


Individuals and their goals are less important than the state.

b.

Locke makes a clear statement of the mechanistic view of the state in which
individual liberty is of paramount importance.

Libertarians believe in a very limited government and are skeptical about the ability of
government to improve social welfare. Social democrats believe that substantial
government intervention is required for the good of individuals. Someone with an
organic conception of the state believes that the goals of society are set by the state and
individuals are valued only by their contribution to the realization of social goals.
a.

A law prohibiting gambling would probably be opposed by a libertarian and


advocated by a social democrat. Someone with an organic conception of the state
would first decide whether gambling would help to achieve the states goals
before taking a position on this issue. If the view is that gambling keeps
individuals from being productive, then someone with an organic view would
probably be in favor of prohibiting it, but if gambling is considered a good way to
raise more revenue for the state, then they might oppose the prohibition.

b.

Libertarians oppose the law mandating seat belt use, arguing that individuals can
best decide whether or not to use seat belts without government coercion. Social
democrats take the position that the mandate saves lives and ultimately benefits
individuals. The organic view would probably lead to favoring the mandate on the
grounds that reduced health care costs caused by fewer accidents benefit society.

c.

Libertarians oppose the law mandating child safety seats, arguing that individuals
can best decide whether or not to use child safety seats without government
coercion. Social democrats take the position that the mandate saves lives and
ultimately benefits individuals. The organic view would probably lead to favoring
the mandate on the grounds that reduced health care costs caused by fewer
accidents benefit society.

Chapter 1 - Introduction

d.

Libertarians would probably oppose a law prohibiting prostitution, while social


democrats would likely favor such a law. The organic view depends on the type
of society policymakers are attempting to achieve. The law would probably be
favored on moral grounds.

e.

Libertarians would probably oppose a law prohibiting polygamy, while social


democrats would likely favor such a law. The organic view depends on the type
of society policymakers are attempting to achieve. The law would probably be
favored on moral grounds.

f.

Libertarians would likely oppose the law, believing that individual business
owners should make the decision about which language is used for their signs.
Social democrats would also probably oppose the law in order to foster a more
inclusive society. Those with an organic view would probably favor the law if
they hold the view that every member of the society should speak the native
language.

3.

The mechanistic view of government says that the government is a contrivance created
by individuals to better achieve their individual goals. Within the mechanistic tradition,
people could disagree on the obesity tax. Libertarians would say that people can decide
what is best for themselves - whether to consume high calorie food - and do not need
prodding from the government. In contrast, social democrats might argue that people are
too short sighted to know what is good for them, so that government-provided
inducements are appropriate.

4.

a.

If the size of government is measured by direct expenditures, the mandate does not
directly increase it. Costs of compliance, however, may be high and would appear
as an increase in a regulatory budget.

b.

This law would not increase government expenditures, but the high costs of
compliance would increase the regulatory budget.

c.

Its hard to say whether this represents an increase or decrease in the size of
government. One possibility is that GDP stayed the same, and government
purchases of goods and services fell. Another is that government purchases of
goods and services grew, but at a slower rate than the GDP. One must also
consider coincident federal credit and regulatory activities and state and local
budgets.

d.

The federal budget would decrease if grants-in-aid were reduced. However, if


state and local governments offset this by increasing taxes, the size of the
government sector as a whole would not go down as much as one would have
guessed.

Part 1 Getting Started

5.

The inflation erodes the real value of the debt by 0.016 x 420 billion or 6.72 billion.
The fact that inflation reduces the real debt obligation means that this figure should be
included as revenue to the government.

6.

The federal government grew by $910 billion. However, because the price level went up
by 24 percent, in terms of 2005 dollars this amounted to a real increase of $540 billion
(=$2.47 trillion - 1.24*$1.56 trillion=$2.47 trillion-$1.93 trillion). As a proportion of
GDP, federal spending in 1996 was 19.9 percent ($1.56 trillion/$7.82 trillion) and in
2005 it was 19.8 percent ($2.47 trillion/$12.48 trillion). Hence, the size of government
grew in absolute terms and fell slightly in relative terms. To get a more complete answer,
one would want data on the population (to compute real spending per capita). Also, it
would be useful to add in expenditures by state and local governments, to see if the total
size of government fell. Also, although it would be harder to measure, one would want to
try to gain some sense of how the regulatory burden on the economy grew during this
time period.

7.

Relative to GDP, defense spending grew from 4.9 percent of GDP in 1981 to 5.8 percent
of GDP in 1985 and then grew from 2.9 percent of GDP in 2001 to 3.8 percent of GDP in
2005. The increase from 2001 to 2005 was proportionally larger.

Chapter 1 - Introduction

Chapter 2 Tools of Positive Analysis


1.

A change in the marginal tax rate changes the individuals net wage. This generates both
an income effect and a substitution effect. As long as leisure is a normal good, these
effects work in opposite directions. Hence, one cannot tell a priori whether labor supply
increases or decreases. If there were no political or legal impediments, an experimental
study could be conducted in which a control group confronts the status quo, and an
experimental group faces the new tax regime. Other things that affect work effort would
impact both the control group and the experimental group, so any difference in work
effort between the two groups could be attributed to the change in marginal tax rates.

2.

This is a valid criticism of the exercise study and the remedy would be to set up a study
in which individuals are randomly assigned to groups. In an experimental study, the
group engaged in running would not be correlated with good health or a strong heart, so
if they enjoyed longer life expectancy, it could be attributed to running instead of other
factors.

3.

The workers who spend time on a computer probably have other skills and abilities that
contribute to higher wages, so training children to use computers would not necessarily
cause their earnings potential to improve. This study illustrates the difficulty of
determining cause and effect based on correlations. The data do not reveal whether using
a computer causes higher earnings, or whether other factors cause workers to use
computers and to earn higher wages.

4.

The text points out the pitfalls of social experiments: the problem of obtaining a random
sample and the problems of extending results beyond the scope of the experiment.
Participants in the study had found it to their advantage to be a part of the experiment,
which may have resulted in a self-selected population unrepresentative of the wider group
of health care consumers. In addition, the RAND Health Insurance Experiment was of
limited duration, after which the participants would move to some other health plan. This
design could induce certain behavior in the short-run that would not necessarily be
present if the health insurance coverage were permanent rather than transitory. Further,
physicians standard practices are largely determined by the circumstances of the
population as a whole, not the relatively small experimental group.

5.

Random assignment to different class size allows researchers to determine if smaller class
size improved test scores, but if some of the students switched classes, the results could
be biased. For example, students might be randomly assigned to large classes, but they
might have very concerned parents who make an effort to move their children into a
smaller class within the same school or at a different school. In such a case, the students
higher test scores might reflect that they have very involved parents rather than that they
were in a smaller class. If, on the other hand, students changed classes or changed
schools for other reasons, not related to how they might perform on tests, the results
would not be biased.

Part 1 Getting Started

6.

Since only five states reduced income taxes, we could examine what happened in a
control group of states (those with an income tax but with no change in the tax rates) and
compare savings rates between the two. This is important because other factors affect
savings rates, but if other factors affected both the control group and the treatment group,
then we can conclude that the treatment (lower taxes) caused the change in savings. If,
for example, the saving rate for the five states with lower taxes (the treatment group)
increased by two percent, while the savings rate for the other states (the control group)
increased by one percent, then we could conclude that lower taxes caused the saving rate
to increase by one percentthe difference between the two percent increase in the
treatment group and the one percent increase in the control group.

7.

There is a weak, positive relationship between deficits and interest rates, implying that
larger deficits lead to lower interest rates. Inferences based on these data along would be
problematic because there are only a few data points and because it would be more
informative to look at deficits relative to some benchmark, such as GDP, and to express
both interest rates and deficits in real terms, rather than nominal terms. It would also be
useful to control for other factors that can affect interest rates, such as monetary policy
and the level of economic activity.

Chapter 1 - Introduction

Chapter 3 Tools of Normative Analysis


1.

a.

In this particular insurance market, one would not expect asymmetric information
to be much of a problem the probability of a flood is common knowledge.
Moral hazard could be an issue people are more likely to build near a beach if
they have flood insurance. Still, one would expect the market for flood insurance
to operate fairly efficiently.

b.

There is substantial asymmetric information in the markets for medical insurance


for consumers and also malpractice insurance for physicians. For efficient
consumption, the price must be equal to the marginal cost, and the effect of
insurance may be to reduce the perceived price of medical care consumption.
That would lead to consumption above the efficient level. Because of the roles of
regulation, insurance, taxes, and the shifting of costs from the uninsured to the
insured, there is little reason to expect the market to be efficient.

c.

In the stock market, there is good information and thousands of buyers and sellers.
We expect, in general, efficient outcomes.

d.

From a national standpoint, there is a good deal of competition and information


with regards to personal computers. The outcome will likely be efficient for
computer hardware. However, some firms might exercise some market power,
especially in the software market; in these markets network externalities may be
present where the value of a programming language or piece of software is
dependent on the number of others who also use that software.

e.

The private market allocation is likely inefficient without government


intervention. Student loan markets may suffer from asymmetric information the
student knows better than the lender whether he will repay the loan or default on
it, a form of adverse selection. Government intervention does not solve the
adverse selection problem in this case (because participation in the student loan
program is not compulsory), but it may create a market that would not exist
without intervention.

f.

There are several reasons why automobile insurance provision is likely to be


inefficient without government intervention. As with other insurance markets, the
automobile insurance market suffers from asymmetric information. Drivers who
know they are particularly accident prone will be particularly likely to want car
insurance (or policies with greater coverage), while drivers who are less accident
prone (or able to self-insure) might choose to go without insurance. By mandating
that people purchase auto insurance if they choose to drive, the adverse selection
problem is mitigated to some extent (but, again, more accident prone drivers could
still by more generous plans). Another market imperfection, related to
underinsurance has to do with the financial externalities from an automobile
accident. An uninsured motorist who is at fault may not have sufficient income to
cover the costs of the other drivers bills, and instead default on the obligation by

Part 1 Getting Started

g.

2.

Point a represents an equal allocation of water, but it is not efficient because there is no
tangency. Point b is one of many Pareto efficient allocations, representing a case where
Catherine benefits enormously by trade, and Henrys utility is unchanged from the initial
endowment.

AD:

3.

declaring bankruptcy. The bankruptcy floor on costs creates various moral


hazard problems.

1)
2)

The dashed line is positioned at the halfway point on the horizontal axis.
Point b is a tangency

If insurers in California could no longer use location to determine automobile insurance


rates, some of the higher costs incurred by urban residents would be shifted to rural and
suburban residents. This change would reduce efficiency, but the purpose of the policy is
to improve equity, based on an argument that it is unfair that urban residents should have
to pay more for insurance because they are more likely to be involved in accidents.
Social welfare increases if the additional utility enjoyed by urban residents offsets the
loss in utility to rural and suburban residents.

Chapter 1 - Introduction

4.

a.

Social indifference curves are straight lines with slope of 1. As far as society is
concerned, the util to Augustus is equivalent to the util to Livia.

Part 1 Getting Started

b.

Social indifference curves are straight lines with slope of 2. This reflects the fact
that society values a util to Augustus twice as much as a util to Livia.

Chapter 1 - Introduction

10

Part 1 Getting Started

5.

Musgrave (1959) developed the concept of merit goods to describe commodities that
ought to be provided even if the members of society do not demand them. Sin taxes
work the opposite way and apply to commodities that members of society might demand,
but ought not to have.

6.

a.

There is no obvious reason why there is a market failure with burglar alarm calls;
the Los Angeles police could set a response fee equal to the marginal cost.

b.

Welfare economics provides little basis for such a subsidy of wool and mohair
production.

c.

There is no economic reason why cherry pies should be regulated, especially


since there are no such regulations for apple, blueberry, or peach frozen pies.

d.

It is hard to imagine a basis in welfare economics for this regulation for


hairdressers.

e.

This is not an efficient policy. If the problem is that too much water is being
consumed, then the answer is to increase the price of water. On that basis, people
can decide whether or not they want to buy toilets that require less water. Water,
like most other resources, is a private good.

f.

There is no economic reason why the federal government should subsidize the
production of electricity, whether the electricity comes from coal, nuclear power,
or chicken manure. One can assume the question that the R&D process of
creating electricity from chicken manure is already developed, so there is not a
positive externality argument. Since the production of electricity is a private
good, with no obvious violations of the fundamental welfare theorem, there is no
justification.

7.

In this case, the Edgeworth box is actually a line because there is only one good on the
island. The set of possible allocations is a straight line, 100 units long. Every allocation
is Pareto efficient, because the only way to make one person better off is to make another
person worse off. There is no theory in the text to help us decide whether an allocation is
fair. Although splitting the peanuts even between the people may be fair, it may not be
fair if the calorie needs of the people are different. With a social welfare function, we
can make assessments on whether redistribution for society as a whole is a good thing.

8.

Social welfare is maximized when Marks marginal utility of income is equal to Judys
marginal utility of income. Taking the derivative of Marks utility function to find his
marginal utility function yields MUM = 50/(IM1/2) and taking the derivative of Judys
utility function yields MUJ = 100/(IJ1/2). If we set MUM equal to MUJ, the condition for
maximization becomes IJ = 4IM and, since the fixed amount of income is $300, this
means that Mark should have $60 and Judy should have $240 if the goal is to maximize
social welfare = UM + UJ.

11

Chapter 1 - Introduction

9.

Although Victorias marginal rate of substitution is equal to Alberts, these are not equal
to the marginal rate of transformation and the allocation is, therefore, Pareto inefficient.
Both people would give up 2 cups of tea for 1 crumpet but, according to the production
function, could actually get 6 crumpets by giving up 2 cups of tea. By giving up tea and
getting crumpets through the production function, both utilities are raised.

10.

a.

False. As shown in the text, equality of the marginal rates of substitution is a


necessary, but not sufficient, condition. The MRS for each individual must also
equal the MRT.

b.

Uncertain. As long as the allocation is an interior solution in the Edgeworth box,


the marginal rates of substitution must be equal across individuals. This need not
be true, however, at the corners where one consumer has all the goods in the
economy.

c.

False. A policy that leads to a Pareto improvement results in greater efficiency,


but social welfare depends on equity as well as efficiency. A policy that improves
efficiency but creates a loss in equity might reduce social welfare.

d.

Uncertain. The tax reduces efficiency, but if education creates positive


externalities, then increased funding for education improves efficiency. This is a
Pareto-improving policy if the increased efficiency in the education market more
than offsets the reduced efficiency in the market for cigarettes.

12

Part 1 Getting Started

Chapter 4 Public Goods


1.

2.

3.

4.

a.

Wilderness area is an impure public good at some point, consumption becomes


nonrival; it is, however, nonexcludable.

b.

Satellite television is nonrival in consumption (although it is excludable).

c.

Medical school education is a private good.

d.

Television signals are nonrival in consumption.

e.

An Internet site is nonrival in consumption (although it is excludable).

a.

False. Efficient provision of a public good occurs at the level where total
willingness to pay for an additional unit equals the marginal cost of producing the
additional unit.

b.

False. Due to the free rider problem, it is unlikely that a private business firm
could profitably sell a product that is non-excludable. However, recent research
reveals that the free rider problem is an empirical question and that we should not
take the answer for granted. Public goods may be privately supported through
volunteerism, such as when people who attend a fireworks display voluntarily
contribute enough to pay for the show.

c.

Uncertain. This statement is true if the road is not congested, but when there is
heavy traffic, adding another vehicle can interfere with the drivers already using
the road.

d.

False. There will be more users in larger communities, but all users have access
to the quantity that has been provided since the good is non-rival, so there is no
reasons larger communities would necessarily have to provide a larger quantity of
the non-rival good.

We assume that Cheetahs utility does not enter the social welfare function; hence, her
allocation of labor supply across activities does not matter.
a.

The public good is patrol; the private good is fruit.

b.

Recall that efficiency requires MRSTARZAN + MRSJANE = MRT. MRSTARZAN =


MRSJANE = 2. But MRT = 3. Therefore, MRSTARZAN + MRSJANE MRT. To
achieve an efficient allocation, Cheetah should patrol more.

Research on alternative medicine is a public good if the research leads to treatments or


cures that are non-excludable, meaning that others besides those who discovered the
treatment may profit from the treatments. This would happen if discoveries cannot be
patented. Whether or not it is sensible for government to pay for such research depends
on the potential benefits of the research, which could be substantial if alternative
13

Chapter 1 - Introduction

medicine provides effective treatments,


patented.
5.

and whether or not the treatments can be

Aircrafts are both rival and excludable goods, so public sector production of aircrafts is
not justified on the basis of public goods. If policymakers assume that the benefits of the
mega-jetliner are public, then they would find the efficient level of production by
vertically summing demand curves rather than horizontally summing demand curves.
This causes the benefits to be significantly overstated and could be used to justify such
high costs.

14

Part 1 Getting Started

6.

This debate is similar to the debate about private versus public education. Public sector
production is often associated with higher costs (for both schools and prisons), but there
may be other reasons society would prefer public to private provision. These reasons
typically relate to equity considerations. For schools, the main argument is to make sure
everyone child has the opportunity for a good education. For prisons, there may be a
fundamental conflict between fair and humane treatment of prisoners and keeping costs
low. For example, equity might require that prisoners be fed nutritious meals, but giving
them bread and water for every meal might be less expensive. This question asks
students to give personal opinions about privatizing prisons, so there is no single right
answer.

7.

The experimental results on free-riding suggest that members of the community might
voluntarily contribute about half of the required amount. The reason these citizens
wanted to use private fundraising was because the state government redistributed tax
dollars from wealthy districts to poor districts (the so-called Robin Hood plan), so using
private donations was a way to avoid losing tax dollars to other districts.

8.

There is no compelling reason for museums to be run by the government from the theory
of public goods; thus, it is appropriate to think about privatization. Admissions to
museums are clearly excludable. And viewing the artwork is also rival, because there is
congestion when too many people are consuming the good. Thus, museums may be
thought of as a private good rather than public good. In the United States, many great
museums are run privately (not for profit), and they seem to do quite well. In terms of
private versus public production, the text points out that this decision should be based on
relative wage and material costs in the public and private sector, administrative costs,
diversity of tastes, and distributional issues. There is no compelling reason to think the
private sector would have higher costs than the public sector. In regards to diversity of
tastes, a profit-maximizing private sector museum would likely be more responsive to
consumer tastes than the public sector e.g., adopting new technologies that make the
museum more enjoyable for the typical customer. In regards to distributional issues, it is
likely that the private sector would be less responsive than the public sector. The notion
of commodity egalitarianism, however, is a stretch for museums.

9.

a.

Zachs marginal benefit schedule shows that the marginal benefit of a


lighthouse starts at $90 and declines, and Jacobs marginal benefit starts at
$40 and declines. Neither person values the first lighthouse at its marginal cost of
$100, so neither person would be willing to pay for a lighthouse acting alone.

b.

Zachs marginal benefit is MBZACH=90-Q, and Jacobs is MBJACOB=40-Q. The


marginal benefit for society as a whole is the sum of the two marginal benefits, or
MB=130-2Q (for Q40), and is equal to Zachs marginal benefit schedule
afterwards (for Q>40). The marginal cost is constant at MC=100, so the
intersection of aggregate marginal benefit and marginal cost occurs at a quantity
less than 40. Setting MB=MC gives 130-2Q=100, or Q=15. Net benefit can be
measured as the area between the demand curve and the marginal benefit of the
15th unit. The net benefit is $112.5 for each person, for a total of $225.

15

Chapter 1 - Introduction

10.

Thelmas marginal benefit is MBTHELMA=12-Z, and Louises is MBLOUISE=8-2Z. The


marginal benefit for society as a whole is the sum of the two marginal benefits, or
MB=20-3Z (for Z4), and is equal to Thelmas marginal benefit schedule afterwards (for
Z>4). The marginal cost is constant at MC=16. Setting MB=MC along the first segment
gives 20-3Z=16, or Z=4/3, which is the efficient level of snowplowing. Note that if
either Thelma or Louise had to pay for the entire cost herself, no snowplowing would
occur since the marginal cost of $16 exceeds either of their individual marginal benefits
from the first unit ($12 or $8). Thus, this is clearly a situation when the private market
does not work very well. Also note, however, that if the marginal cost were somewhat
lower, (e.g., MC8), then it is possible that Louise could credibly free ride, and Thelma
would provide the efficient allocation. This occurs because if Thelma believes that
Louise will free ride, Thelma provides her optimal allocation, which occurs on the second
segment of societys MB curve, which is identical to Thelmas MB curve (note that
Louise gets zero marginal benefit for Z>4). Since Louise is completely satiated with this
good at Z=4, her threat to free ride is credit if Thelma provides Z>4.

16

Part 1 Getting Started

Chapter 5 - Externalities
1.

Classical economics explicitly requires that all costs and benefits be taken into account
when assessing the desirability of a given set of resources, so Gores statement is false.
The notion that rescuing the environment should be the central organizing principle for
civilization provides no practical basis for deciding what to do about automobile
emissions (or any other environmental problem), because it provides no framework for
evaluating the tradeoffs that inevitably must be made.

2.

3.

a.

The number of parties per month that would be provided privately is P.

b.

See schedule MSBp.

c.

P*. Give a per-unit subsidy of $b per party.

d.

The total subsidy=abcd. Society comes out ahead by ghc, assuming the subsidy
can be raised without any efficiency costs. (Cassanovas friends gain gchd;
Cassanova loses chd but gains abcd, which is a subsidy cost to government.)

a.

It is very likely that the farmer could negotiate with the neighbors, provided
property rights are clearly defined. The Coase Theorem is therefore applicable.

b.

It is unlikely that property rights could be enforced in terms of catching tropical


fish on the Amazon River. The question states that hundreds of divers illegally
catch these fish and sell them on the black market. If the property rights were
given to the divers, it is not clear who is actually harmed (perhaps society as a
whole) by the depletion of exotic fish. Given the large number of people who are
harmed (in a small amount), and the large number of people who are engaging in
this activity, it is not clear how bribes would flow from society to the divers.

c.

There are too many farmers and too many city-dwellers for a private negotiation.

d.

Too many people are involved for private negotiation and impossible to figure out
how to transfer bribes.

17

Chapter 1 - Introduction

4.

a.

The price of imported oil does not reflect the increased political risk by
effectively subsidizing authoritarian regimes like those in Saudi Arabia.

b.

The tax would estimate the marginal damage (e.g., the increased instability in the
Middle East, etc.) by importing oil from Saudi Arabia.

c.

The supply of TGRs is vertical at 104.5 billion if government seeks to reduce


consumption of gasoline to 104.5 billion. Consumers must have one TGR in
order to buy one gallon of gasoline, plus they must pay the price at the pump.
Limiting TGRs effectively limits the demand for gasoline, so the price per gallon
will fall, but consumers must have TGRs in order to purchase gasoline. If the
market price of one TGR is $0.75, this means that supply and demand intersect at
$0.75, as shown in the graph. This kind of program curbs consumption without
giving government more revenue because consumers are purchasing the TGRs
from each other. However, the total amount of TGRs is limited by government.
Those consumers seeking to purchase more gasoline than allowed by the initial
allocation of TGRs can purchase additional TGRs from other consumers at the
market price of $0.75. By choosing to use a TGR to purchase gasoline, a
consumer incurs an opportunity cost equal to $0.75 since they cannot sell the
TGR once it has been used.

Supply of TGRs

$0.75

Demand for TGRs

104.5 billion

5.

TGRs

The use of the drug to treat sick cows leads to a positive externality (the benefit enjoyed
by air travelers) as well as a negative externality (the costs created by a larger number of
rats and feral dogs). Banning the drug might raise or lower efficiency, depending on
whether the positive externality is larger or whether the negative externality is larger.

18

Part 1 Getting Started

There are many ways to design incentive-based regulations. Policymakers could


determine the efficient level of drug usage and then either allocate or sell the right to use
the drug for sick cows.
6.

There are many policy alternatives for addressing problems with traffic congestion. Most
of these focus on reducing the number of vehicles on the road during high-traffic times,
whether through regulation or through incentive-based programs.

7.

a.

When the Little Pigs hog farm produces on its own, it sets marginal benefit
equal to marginal cost. This occurs at 4 units.

b.

The efficient number of hogs sets marginal benefit equal to marginal social cost,
which is the sum of MC and MD. At 2 units, MB=MSC=13.

c.

The merger internalizes the externality. The combined firm worries about the
joint profit maximization problem, not the profit maximization problem at either
firm alone. Thus, the LP farm produces 2 units, the socially efficient amount.

d.

Before the merger, the LP farm produced 4 units. By cutting back to 2 units, it
loses marginal profit of $3. On the other hand, the Tipsy Vineyards profits
increase by $20. Thus, profits increase by $17 altogether.

8.

Private Marginal Benefit = 10 - X


Private Marginal Cost = $5
External Cost = $2
Without government intervention, PMB = PMC; X = 5 units.
Social efficiency implies PMB = Social Marginal Costs = $5 + $2 = $7; X = 3 units.
Gain to society is the area of the triangle whose base is the distance between the efficient
and actual output levels, and whose height is the difference between private and social
marginal cost. Hence, the efficiency gain is (5 - 3)(7 - 5) = 2.
A Pigouvian tax adds to the private marginal cost the amount of the external cost at the
socially optimal level of production. Here a simple tax of $2 per unit will lead to
efficient production. This tax would raise ($2) (3 units) = $6 in revenue.

9.

In the absence of persuasive evidence on positive externalities for higher education, there
is no efficiency reason for the government to provide a free university education. Society
may decide that a more equitable distribution of income is achieved by subsidizing higher
education, but this is a debate involving value judgments.

19

Chapter 1 - Introduction

10.

11.

a.

The total cost of emissions reduction is minimized only when the marginal costs
are equal across all polluters, therefore a cost-effective solution requires that MC1
= MC2 or that 300e1 = 100e2. Substituting 3e1 for e2 in the formula e1 + e2 = 40
(since the policy goal is to reduce emissions by 40 units) yields the solution. It is
cost-effective for Firm 1 to reduce emissions by 10 units and for Firm 2 to reduce
emissions by 30 units.

b.

In order to achieve cost-effective emission reductions, the emissions fee should be


set equal to $3,000. With this emissions fee, Firm 1 reduces 10 units and Firm 2
reduces 30 units, but Firm 1 has to pay $3,000 for each unit of pollution they
continue to produce, which gives them a tax burden of $3,000 x 90 (Firm 1
generated 100 units in the absence of government intervention) or $270,000.
Firm 2 has a lower tax burden because it is reducing emissions from 80 units to 50
units. Firm 2 pays $3,000 x 50 = $150,000. As the text concludes, the firm that
cuts back pollution less isnt really getting away with anything because it has a
larger tax liability than if it were to cut back more.

c.

From an efficiency standpoint, the initial allocation of permits does not matter. If
the two firms could not trade permits, then Firm 2 would have to undertake all of
the emissions reduction. Initially, Firm 1s MC is zero, while Firm 2s MC is
$4,000, so there is a strong incentive for Firm 2 to purchase permits from Firm 1.
Trading should continue until MC1 = MC2, which is the cost-effective solution.
This means that the market price for permits will equal $3,000, the same as the
emissions fee. At this price, Firm 2 will purchase 10 permits from Firm 2,
allowing Firm 2 to reduce emissions by 30 rather than 40 and requiring Firm 1 to
reduce emissions by 10. This solution is the same as the solution achieved with
the emissions fee. However, Firm 1 is better off because instead of having to pay
taxes, it will receive a payment of $30,000 for its permits. Firm 2 must pay
$30,000 for the extra permits, but it also avoids the payment of taxes. The
government lost $420,000 in tax revenue. The firms must still pay the cost of
emissions reduction, plus Firm 2 must pay for the permits purchased from Firm 1.

If marginal costs turn out to be lower than anticipated, cap-and-trade achieves too little
pollution reduction and an emissions fee achieves too much pollution reduction. With an
inelastic marginal social benefit function, cap-and-trade is not too bad from an efficiency
standpoint, while an emissions fee causes pollution reduction to be much greater than the
efficient level when marginal cost is lower than anticipated. When marginal social
benefits are elastic, the opposite is true.

20

Part 1 Getting Started

Chapter 6 Political Economy


1.

a.

Below, the preferences for Person 1 and Person 2 are drawn. Same procedure is
used for the other three people.

b. C wins in every pairwise vote. Thus, there is a stable majority outcome, despite the
fact that persons 1, 2, and 3 have double-peaked preferences. This demonstrates that
although multi-peaked preferences may lead to voting inconsistencies, this is not
necessarily the case.

2.

The belief that the tax bill will pass because it contains provisions sought by so many
different lawmakers is consistent with the logrolling model. It could be the case that each
lawmaker has inserted favored provisions with the understanding that other lawmakers
will support the overall package provided it contains the provisions they favor.

3.

Without vote-trading, neither bill would pass. If there is vote-trading, then voter B would
agree to support issue X provided voter A supports Issue Y, allowing both bills to pass.
The change in net benefits is +3 for Issue X and -2 for Issue Y, so logrolling results in a
gain of +1.

4.

Yes, it is consistent, because the theory says that when unanimity is required, no
decisions are likely to be made. A majority system might be more suitable, although it is
subject to cycling and other problems.

5.

Assuming that the preferences of Kuwaiti women differ from the preferences of Kuwaiti
men, stronger voter turnout by women could invalidate the median voter theorem. That
is, the results of majority voting would not reflect the preferences of the median voter.

6.

When there is a vote over five options, there is the chance that a potential majority vote is
split between four relatively preferred options, and the fifth option wins. The winning
option may have been voted down if it had been a two-way vote with any of the other

21

Chapter 1 - Introduction

options. Further, if preferences are not single-peaked, cycling and inconsistent public
decisions may emerge.

22

Part 1 Getting Started

7.

Given the U.S. experience with the Budget Enforcement Act of 1990, we would expect
the EU deficit limits to be ineffective. We would expect accounting tricks to mask the
size of the deficits (such as itemizing various budget items as unexpected
emergencies), and if that didnt work, we would expect the deficit rules to be ignored.
This is apparently what is happening. When Germany exceeded the deficit target, no
moves were taken to levy the required fines.

8.

Since rents, by definition, are the returns above a normal return, then when the licenses
are put on the market, their price will be the value of the rents. Hence, the owner of the
peanut license, whoever he or she is, only makes a normal return. Put another way, the
license is an asset that earns a normal rate of return. If the peanut license system were
eliminated, efficiency would be enhanced. But the elimination would, in effect,
confiscate the value of this asset. It is not clear that this is fair. One could also argue that
when someone buys this asset, the purchase is with the understanding that there is some
probability that its value will be reduced by elimination of the program; hence, it is not
unfair to do so.

9.

a.

With the demand curve of Q=100-10P and a perfectly elastic supply curve at P=2,
then the milk is sold at a price of $2, and a quantity of 80 units is sold.

b.

The marginal revenue curve associated with the inverse demand curve P=10(1/10)Q is MR=10-(1/5)Q, while the marginal cost curve is MC=2. The cartel
would ideally produce a quantity where MR=MC, or 10-(1/5)Q=2, or Q=40. The
price associated with a cartel quantity of 40 units is P=10-(1/10)*40, or P=6.

c.

The rent associated with the cartel is the product of the marginal profit per unit
and the number of units produced. The marginal profit per unit of milk is $4 (=$6
price - $2 marginal cost), while 40 units are produced. Thus, the rents equal
$160.

d.

The most the cartel would be willing to contribute to politicians is the full
economic rent of $160. The cartel situation, the quantity of milk produced is too
low from societys point of view. The deadweight loss triangle is computed using
the difference between the cartel output and competitive output as the base of
the triangle, and the difference between the cartel price and competitive price as
the height. Thus, the triangle is equal to (1/2)*(80-40)*($6-$2)=$40.

e.

As Figure 6.5 in the textbook shows, the deadweight loss could now go as high as
the sum of the conventional deadweight loss and the rents, or $160 rents + $80
DWL = $240. This is because, as noted in the text, rent-seeking can use up
resources lobbyists spend their time influencing legislators, consultants testify
before regulatory panels, and advertisers conduct public relations campaigns.
Such resources, which could have been used to produce new goods and services,
are instead consumed in a struggle over the distribution of existing goods and
services. Hence, the rents do not represent a mere lump-sum transfer; it is a
measure of real resources used up to maintain a position of market power.

23

Chapter 1 - Introduction

24

Part 1 Getting Started

10.

Niskanens model of bureaucracy is illustrated in Figure 6.4 of the textbook. In the


aftermath of September 11th, the new concerns over food safety would likely shift the V
curve upward (that is, the value placed on each level of Q). Assuming that C curve (costs
per unit of Q) does not change, then this shift increases the actual number of food
inspectors hired. It is also likely that the slope of the V curve changes, with each
marginal unit of Q becoming more valuable. Thus, the V curve not only shifts upward,
but becomes steeper as well. Both of these effects the shifting of the V curve and the
change in the slope lead to greater values of Q under the bureaucracy model. The
change in the slope leads to a greater value of Q*, the efficient level of output. Thus, the
optimal number of FDA employees and the actual number of FDA employees are likely
to rise.

11.

a.

The outcome of the first election (M vs. H) is M. The outcome of the second
election (H vs. L) is L. The outcome of the third election (L vs. M) is M.
Majority rule leads to a stable outcome since M defeats both H and L. Giving one
person the ability to set the agenda would not affect the outcome in this case.

b.

With the change in Eleanors preference ordering, majority rule no longer


generates a stable outcome. In a vote between M and H, the outcome is H. In a
vote between H and L, the outcome is L. In a vote between L and M, the outcome
is M. So, giving one person the ability to set the agenda affects the outcome. For
example, Abigail prefers H, so she might pit L against M first in order to
eliminate L and avoid having L defeat H.

25

Chapter 1 - Introduction

Chapter 7 Education
1.

There are numerous rationales given for government provision of education. Even
though education is primarily a private good, many argue that educating a child provides
external benefits. However, the existence of a positive externality implies that
government should subsidize education rather than making it free and mandatory. Other
rationales are based on equity, including a belief in commodity egalitarianism.

2.

If households are allowed to supplement public education with private lessons, then the
budget constraint in Figure 4.5 of the textbook is modified by drawing a line starting at
point x (consuming only public education) that runs to the southeast and is parallel to AB.
The figure below is then similar to the analysis of in-kind benefits like food stamps.

Parents can supplement public education


with private lessons

Other Goods
A

BA
ep

Education

26

Part 1 Getting Started

If parents pay for the public schooling (rather than perceiving it as being free), and the
schooling was paid for with a lump sum tax, then the budget constraint shifts in by an
amount that depends on the households share of the tax burden. If the households tax
burden exactly equals the cost of public school, the budget constraint is no longer the line
segment AB but rather the segment CDB, where the segment DB runs along the original
budget constraint, except that the minimum amount of schooling consumed is eP.

Other Goods
Public School is financed by taxes levied on parents
A

BA
ep

3.

Education

The question distinguishes between a private market for higher education, in which
students would have to pay their own tuition, and a system of taxpayer-financed higher
education. The examples cited in France and Germany illustrate a third option of little or
not support of higher education from either private tuition dollars or public tax dollars. If
a government disallows either type of support, then the result will be very little higher
education, or low-quality higher education. For most, the debate centers on the choice
between private support and public support. Some may conclude that efficiency is served
by providing financial support using tax dollars because the free market solution is less
than the socially efficient solution when significant positive externalities are present. To
make this argument, it is important to provide evidence that there are significant positive
externalities. Remember that as long as the earnings of college graduates reflect their
higher productivity, the belief that higher education causes workers to become more
productive does not imply the existence of an externality. From an equity standpoint,
subsidies for college students represent a transfer from taxpayers to college students, so
subsidizing higher education may or may not result in a more equitable distribution of
income.

27

Chapter 1 - Introduction

28

Part 1 Getting Started

4.

a.

If income is $50,000 per year, the budget constraint is a straight line, as shown
below.

Other Goods

$50,000

$50,000

b.

Education

With $8,000 worth of free public education, the family can consumer up to $8,000
worth of education without reducing the consumption of other goods.

Other Goods

$50,000

$8,000

$50,000

29

Education

Chapter 1 - Introduction

c.

The family maximized utility at point A before the introduction of free public
education, and maximizes utility at point B after free public education is
introduced, so the optimal consumption of education fell.

Other Goods

$50,000

$8,000

$50,000

30

Education

Part 1 Getting Started

d.

With an $8,000 education voucher, the family can spend some of its income on
education to purchase more education if it desires. If the optimal point moves
from A to B, as shown in the graph below, then the introduction of vouchers
causes the family to purchase more education.

Other Goods

$50,000

$8,000

5.

$50,000

$58,000

Education

a.

The results might be biased if there are other differences between the two states.
For example, parents might have greater educational attainment in the state whose
teachers have masters degrees and the higher test scores could reflect this rather
than the difference in teachers educational attainment.

b.

The experimental study provides stronger evidence that students whose teachers
have masters degrees will score higher on tests because students were randomly
assigned to be in the control group or the treatment group.

31

Chapter 1 - Introduction

Chapter 8 Cost Benefit Analysis


1.

Yes, one really must ask these questions, although it may seem distasteful. Otherwise,
there is no way to determine which safety precautions are sensible.

2.

The increased time spent at the inspection must be counted as a cost of the program. One
reasonable way to estimate the value of the time would be to use the average wage rate in
the state, and multiply this by the incremental waiting time of 105 minutes.

3.

The present value of $25/.10 = $250.


The present value of the perpetual annual benefit = B + B/(1 + r) + B/(1 + r)2 + = B (r
+ 1 - r)/r = B/r.

4.

a.

The internal rate of return is the discount rate that would make the projects net
present value (NPV) equal zero. To solve for the internal rate of return, , set the
present value of benefits minus the present value of costs equal to zero. If we
assume the benefit of using the bicycle is immediate (and worth $170), there is
also the benefit of re-selling the bicycle for $350, but it cant be re-sold until next
year, so must be discounted. Therefore, NPV is 170 + [350/(1+)] 500 = 0.
Solving this expression for yields = 6 percent. If we assume that the benefits
of the vacation will not be enjoyed for one year, then NPV is [(170+350)/(1+)]
500 and setting this expression equal to zero and solving for yields = 4
percent.

b.

If the discount rate is 5 percent, purchasing the bicycle is a good idea if is 6


percent, but a bad idea if is 4 percent.

a.

Bill is willing to pay 25 cents to save 5 minutes, so he values time at 5 cents per
minute. The subway saves him 10 minutes per trip, or 50 cents. The value of 10
trips per year is $5. The cost of each trip is 40 cents, or $4 per year. The annual
net benefit to Bill is therefore $1. The present value of the benefits = $5/.25 =
$20; the present value of the costs is $4/.25 = $16.

b.

Total benefits = $20x55,000=$1,100,000.


Total costs = $16x55,000 = $880,000.
Net benefits = $220,000.

c.

Costs = $1.25 x 55,000 = $68,750.


Benefits =($62,500/1.25) + ($62,500/1.252) = $90,000.
Net benefit = $21,250.

d.

The subway project has a higher present value. If a dollar to the poor is valued
the same as a dollar to the middle class, choose the subway project.

5.

32

Part 1 Getting Started

e.

Let = distributional weight. set


220,000 = -68,750 + [(62,500/1.25) + (62,500/1.252)]
= 3.21
This distribution weight means that $1 of income to a poor person must be viewed
as more important than $3.21 to the middle class for the legal services to be done.

6.

$100 billion invested for 100 years at 5 percent per year would generate over $13 trillion,
a little more than twice the $700 billion in damage caused by the climate change. There
might be other considerations offered when evaluating this proposal, but the critic is
correct from a financial standpoint.

7.

This question demonstrates that assessing the costs and benefits of different proposals
often involves value judgments, and may reflect attitudes toward government. For
example, a libertarian would argue that if carpooling resulted in lower costs for
individuals, then they would already be carpooling and would not need a government
requirement to force them to carpool.

8.

The Senators slip revealed her interest in creating and protecting jobs in California by
keeping the project alive.

9.

Currie and Gruber (1996) find the cost of the expansion per life saved was approximately
$1.6 million. According to Viscusi and Aldy (2003), the value of a statistical life is
between $4 million and $9 million. If all of these calculations are correct, then the
Medicaid expansion passes a cost-benefit test.

33

Chapter 1 - Introduction

Chapter 9 The Health Care Market


1.

The quotation contains several serious errors. First, concern with health care costs does
not mean that health care is not a good. Economists do not care about the cost of
health care per se. Rather, the issue is whether there are distortions in the market that
lead to more than an efficient amount being consumed. Second, it makes a lot of
difference how money is spent. One can create employment by hiring people to dig
ditches and then fill them up, but this produces nothing useful in the way of goods and
services. Thus, employment in the health care sector is not desirable in itself. It is
desirable to the extent that it is associated with the production of an efficient quantity of
health care services.

2.

Examining Figure 9.4, we can see why health care costs increased for the state of
Tennessee. As insurance coverage increases, this lowers the cost of medical expenses for
those who were previously did not have insurance, which increases the overall amount of
medical services they consume. Before receiving insurance, these people demand Mo
units of medical services, and the amount they pay is represented by the area OP oaMo.
But after receiving insurance coverage, they demand M1 amounts of medical services,
paying only OjhM1, while their insurance pays jPobh. The increase in insurance
payments is sizable for two reasons first, by providing coverage, it pays for the majority
of the already sizable medical expenses incurred by this group, and second, the
introduction of insurance makes the group consume even more medical services. In
short, if the people who designed the Tennessee program had realized that the demand
curve for medical services is downward sloping, they would not have been surprised at
the consequences of their program.
To explain why HMOs have been unable to contain long-run health care costs, it is
necessary to consider the effect of technology on health care costs in the long-term. The
inherent problem is that the market for medical care places a large premium on using the
latest and most-developed medicines and machinery for treating patients. These
technologies tend to be expensive. Hence, while introducing HMOs can lead to a once
and for all decrease in the rate of change in health care costs, there is nothing that an
HMO can do to lower the cost of continually providing the latest in medical treatments.

3.

Moral hazard arises when obtaining insurance leads to changes in behavior that increase
the likelihood of the adverse outcome. When government offers free gas to drivers who
run out of fuel on the freeway, drivers are more likely to take advantage of this offer
when the price of gasoline is higher.

4.

Efficient insurance balances the gains from reducing risk against the losses associated
with moral hazard by requiring high out-of-pocket payments for low-cost medical
services and more generous benefits for expensive services. Providing this drug to
patients through a third-party payer meets the condition for efficient insurance.

34

Part 1 Getting Started

5.

6.

7.

a.

P=100-25Q=$50, so Q=2 visits per year. Total cost is ($50)(2) = $100.

b.

With 50 percent coinsurance, the individual pays $25 per visit and the quantity
demanded is 3 visits per year. The individuals out-of-pocket costs are $75 and
the insurance company pays $75 ($25 per visit, 3 visits per year).

c.

The introduction of insurance caused the quantity demanded to increase from 2 to


3 because the individuals effective price fell from $50 to $25, but the marginal
cost is still $50 per visit. The individual consumes medical services past the point
where the marginal benefit to the individual equals the marginal cost, leading to
inefficiency or deadweight loss. The marginal cost of the third visit is $50, but
the marginal benefit is $25, so the deadweight loss is equal to this difference, or
$25. If the method presented in Figure 9.4 is applied, the deadweight triangle will
have an area equal to $12.50.

d.

If the marginal benefit of visiting the doctor is $50, there is no deadweight loss
because marginal benefit equals marginal cost.

a.

There is a 95 percent chance of no illness, in which case income is $30,000, and a


5 percent chance of illness, in which case income is $10,000 because of the
$20,000 loss. Thus, expected income is (0.95)(30,000) + (0.05)(10,000) =
29,000. The utility of having income of $29,000 with certainty is 11.66, but the
expected utility is only (0.95)U(30,000) + (0.05)U(10,000) = (0.95)(11.695) +
(0.05)(10.597) = 11.64.

b.

An actuarially fair premium would be $1,000 since there is a one in twenty


chance that the insurance company will have to cover losses of $20,000. If the
individual buys insurance for $1,000, then they have certain income of $29,000
and the utility of $29,000 is 11.66.

c.

Setting the expected utility equal to 11.64 and solving for income yields
approximately $28,388, indicating that the individual is indifferent between
bearing the risk and having expected income of $29,000 or purchasing insurance
with a certain income of $28,388. If the insurance costs $30,000 - $28,388 =
$1,612, the individual is indifferent between having insurance and not having
insurance, so $1,612 is the most theyd be willing to pay (allow some difference
for rounding).

If the probability of being caught is 0.2 and the fine is $100, the expected cost is $20. If
the probability of being caught is 0.1 and the fine is $200, the expected cost is again $20.
With the first option, the expected value of littering is 0.8(B) + 0.2(B - $100), whereas
the expected value of littering with the second option is 0.9(B) + 0.1(B - $200), where B
is the benefit of littering. Since expected utility is higher for the first option, assuming
diminishing marginal utility, the second option would have a stronger deterrent effect and
lead to a larger reduction in littering. In addition, setting higher fines is cheaper than
employing more police officers.

35

Chapter 1 - Introduction

Chapter 10 Government and the Market for Health Care


1.

One explanation discussed in the chapter is that the shift toward managed care led to a
one-time decrease in expenditures, but advances in medical technology continued,
resulting in concomitant growth in expenditures. This explanation implies that HMOs
helped prevent rising health care costs during the 1990s, but have been unable to keep
costs low due to rapid advances in technology. The structure of HMOs creates incentives
for health care providers to skimp on the quality of care. HMOs used gag rules that
prohibited physicians from discussing treatment options that were not covered by the
plan, but government regulation has since banned these gag rules, allowing patients
greater access to information. Medical technology creates new, and often more
expensive, treatment options, which many patients believe they should have. It has
become increasingly difficult for HMOs to keep costs down by denying more expensive
treatment options, especially since they can no longer prevent physicians from informing
patients of these options.

2.

Medicare covers nearly the entire population aged 65 and older and is not means tested.
About 99 percent of the eligible population chooses to enroll in supplementary medical
insurance (SMI), or Part B of Medicare, which pays for physicians and services rendered
outside the hospital. Patients pay a monthly premium, a small annual deductible, and a
20 percent coinsurance rate. The Medicare program has not improved the health status of
the elderly very much, but is has led to significant benefits in the form of reducing the
risk of facing major reductions in consumption due to medical expenses.

3.

Allowing individuals to join the Medicare prescription drug benefit plan at any time
would like lead to an adverse selection problem. As individuals age and their health
deteriorates, the likelihood that they will need expensive prescription drugs increases. If
individuals wait until several years after becoming eligible for Medicare to add the
prescription drug benefit plan, they pay less in premiums, which adds to the already
enormous expense of the Medicare drug benefit.

36

Part 1 Getting Started

4.

The budget constraint initially has units of Medigap on the x-axis, and other goods on the
y-axis. Given initial prices of $1 per unit for each good, and $30,000 of income, the
budget constraint has a slope of -1, and the intercepts on both axes are at 30,000 units. It
is assumed that the initial utility maximizing bundle consumes 5,000 units of Medigap,
hence the indifference curve is tangent at (5000,25000). All of this is illustrated in the
figure below.
Medigap choice without minimum
standards
Other Goods

30,000

25,000

U0

5,000

30,000

37

Medigap
efficiency units

Chapter 1 - Introduction

After the minimum Medigap mandate, the consumer can either choose 0 units of
Medigap or 8,000 or more units of Medigap. Thus, part of the budget constraint is
eliminated (though the overall shape remains the same as before). After the mandate, the
point (0,30000) is available, as well as all of the points to the southeast of the point
(8000,22000). Clearly, the persons utility must fall since the preferred choice,
(5000,25000) is no longer available. If the person attains a higher level of utility as
(0,30000) compared with (8000,22000), the person chooses to not purchase Medigap. In
this case, the marginal rate of substitution is no longer equal to the price ratio. This is
illustrated below.

Medigap choice with minimum standards;


no Medigap is purchased
Other Goods

30,000

25,000

U0
U1

22,000

5,000

8,000

30,000

38

Medigap
efficiency units

Part 1 Getting Started

5.

If individuals are allowed to purchase supplemental private insurance, then the budget
constraint in Figure 10.5 of the textbook is modified by drawing a line starting at point B
that runs to the southeast and is parallel to AC.

Individuals can purchase supplemental


private insurance

Other Goods
A
B

C
M
Health Insurance

39

Chapter 1 - Introduction

If individuals pay for health insurance (rather than perceiving it as being free), and the
insurance was paid for with a lump sum tax, then the budget constraint shifts in by an
amount that depends on the households share of the tax burden. If the households tax
burden exactly equals the cost of health insurance, the budget constraint is no longer the
line segment AD but rather the segment BCD, where the segment CD runs along the
original budget constraint, except that the minimum amount of health insurance
consumed is M.

Other Goods
Government health insurance is financed by taxes
A

D
M
Health Insurance

40

Part 1 Getting Started

Chapter 11 Social Security


1.

With adverse selection, insurance contracts with more comprehensive coverage are
chosen by people with higher unobserved accident probabilities. To make up for the fact
that a benefit is more likely to be paid to such individuals, the insurer charges a higher
premium per unit of insurance coverage.

2.

Individuals who do not save enough for their retirement years may believe that the
government will feel obliged to come to their aid if they are in a sufficiently desperate
situation. With this belief, younger individuals may purposely neglect to save
adequately. One justification for the compulsory nature of Social Security is to address
the inefficiently low saving caused by moral hazard.

3.

Use the basic formula for balance in a pay-as-you-go social security system:
t =(Nb/Nw)*(B/w).
Call 1990 year 1 and 2050 year 2. Then
t1 = .267*(B/w)1
t2 = .458*(B/w)2
It follows that to keep (B/w)1=(B/w)2 we require t2/t1=.458/.267=1.71. That is, tax rates
would have to increase by 71 percent. Similarly, to keep the initial tax rate constant, we
would require (B/w)2/(B/w)1=.267/.458=0.58. Benefits would have to fall almost by half.

4.

Social Security redistributes incomes from younger generations to older generations,


from men to women, from high- to low-income individuals, and from two-earner to oneearner married couples.
Social Security benefits older generations because it is largely financed on a pay-as-yougo basis. The most extreme example is Ida Fuller, the first Social Security beneficiary,
who paid only $24.85 and received benefits of $20,897 over her lifetime.
Women have gained because they have lived longer. The text cites Liebmans
calculations, which show that among people who retired in the 1990s, on average men
came out behind by about $43,000 while women came out ahead by $37,000.
For recent and future retirees, generally the higher the earnings, the smaller the gain from
Social Security. For example, a high-earner single male who retires in the year 2015 is
expected to lose $196,350 to Social Security, whereas a low-earner single male retiring at
the same time is expected to lose only $8,605. The difference occurs because the payroll
tax used to finance Social Security is proportional, up to $94,200 in 2006, so most
workers are paying the same percentage of earnings to Social Security. Benefits are
related to contributions, but not proportionately, so the low-income individuals come out
better.

41

Chapter 1 - Introduction

One-earner married couples benefit because a non-working spouse is entitled to 50


percent of a working spouses benefit. For a two-earner married couple, the individual
with lower earnings may gain little or nothing in benefits from working, since he or she
would have been entitled to benefits based on the other spouses earnings.
5.

Austens quote seems like it could relate adverse selection, but perhaps more likely, to
moral hazard. The quote If you observe, people always live forever when there is any
annuity to be paid them in a sense sounds like they act differently (e.g., better diet, more
exercise, etc.) when an annuity is to be paid the idea of moral hazard. In contrast,
adverse selection suggests that people who expect to live a long time to be the ones who
purchase annuities. A recent paper by Finkelstein and Poterba (NBER working paper,
December 2000) found that mortality patterns are consistent with models of asymmetric
information and that annuity insurance markets may be characterized by adverse
selection.

6.

Equation (9.1) relates taxes paid into the Social Security system to the dependency ratio
and the replacement ratio, that is, t=(Nb/ Nw)*(B/w). If the goal of public policy is to
maintain a constant level of benefits, B, rather than a constant replacement ratio, (B/w),
then taxes may not need to be raised. If there is wage growth (through productivity), then
it is possible to maintain B at a constant level, even if the dependency ratio is growing.
By rearranging the equation, we can see that B=t*w*(Nb/ Nw)-1. That is, increases in
wage rates (the second term) offset increases in the dependency ratio (the third term).
Thus, constant benefits do not necessarily imply higher tax rates.

7.

The statement about how the different rates of return in the stock market and government
bond market affect the solvency of the trust fund is false. If the trust fund buys stocks,
someone else has to buy the government bonds that it was holding. So, there is no new
saving and no new capacity to take care of future retirees.

42

Part 1 Getting Started

8.

a.

The problem does not provide information about the utility function, so the
optimal point is where the indifference curve is drawn tangent to the budget line,
which can occur at different values depending on how the curve is drawn. In the
diagram below, the optimal point involves saving $8,000 and future consumption
consists of period 2 income ($5,000) plus savings with interest ($8,800).
Future
Consumption
$27,000

$13,800

Optimal Point

Endowment
Point

$5,000

$12,000

b.

$20,000

$25,545

Present
Consumption

If Social Security takes $3,000 from the individual in the first period and pays
him this amount with interest in the second period, then private savings falls from
$8,000 to $5,000. There would be no change in optimal consumption values.

43

Chapter 1 - Introduction

9.

If the implicit rate of return from Social Security is lower than the private return, the
budget line becomes flatter at the endowment point as present consumption falls from
$20,000 to $17,000 when $3,000 is taken for social security. This middle segment of the
budget line is flatter, reflecting the lower rate of return on Social Security compared to
private saving. For savings beyond the $3,000 taken for Social Security, the private rate
of return is available, so the budget line is parallel to the original line. This would cause
the optimal point to change and put the individual on a lower indifference curve. In the
graph below, the effect is to increase private saving slightly.

$27,000

$13,800

..

First Optimal
Point

New Optimal
Point

Endowment
Point

$5,000

$12,000 $17,000 $20,000

10.

$25,545

Present
Consumption

For those who argue that the scheme for financing Social Security is unfair because
people with low earnings are taxed at a higher rate than those with high earnings, the key
issue is that the cumulative payroll tax of 12.4 percent is capped for each person, after
which the payroll tax is zero (this ignores the 2.9 percent uncapped Medicare tax,
however). The earnings ceiling in 2004 is $87,900. Hence, Social Security payroll taxes
as a share of earnings fall after the ceiling is passed thus, the Social Security payroll tax
may be thought of as regressive. The opponents to this view note that the above analysis
only focuses on taxes paid, not benefits received. As shown in Table 11.3, Social
Security redistributes from high earners to low earners, and the formula for the primary
insurance amount offers extremely high replacement rates to very low earners, and much
lower replacement rates to high earners. Thus, the net tax payment (taxes minus benefits)
is likely to be progressive, not regressive. One critical assumption in this kind of analysis
is how one computes lifetime benefits e.g., do we assume that low earners and high
earners live the same number of years?

44

Part 1 Getting Started

11.

If the expected present value of the benefit reduction just equals the decrease in taxes,
then the solvency of the system is unaffected. The pay-as-you-go formula shows that the
system is solvent if taxes collected equal benefits paid, or twNw = BNb. Dividing both
sides by the number of covered workers yields tw = B(Nb/Nw). If a worker diverts $1,000
from payroll taxes to a private account, then the left-hand side of this expression falls by
$1,000. To maintain solvency, the right-hand side must also fall by $1,000, so benefits
must fall by 1,000 times the ratio Nw/Nb. If, for example, there are three covered workers
for every retired worker, so that Nw/Nb is equal to 3, then the necessary reduction in the
expected value of benefits is $3,000. If a worker invests $1,000 for 40 years at about 3
percent per year, that worker will have enough in his private account to compensate for
the lost benefits. If the offset rate is lower than the rate of return workers can earn on
private accounts, workers will gain, and vice versa.

45

Chapter 1 - Introduction

Chapter 12 Income Redistribution: Conceptual Issues


1.

Utilitarianism suggests that social welfare is a function of individuals utilities. Whether


the rich are vulgar is irrelevant, so this part of the statement is inconsistent with
utilitarianism. On the other hand, Steins assertion that inequality per se is unimportant is
inconsistent with utilitarianism.

2.

a.

To maximize W, set marginal utilities equal; the constraint is Is + Ic = 100.


So,
400 - 2Is = 400 - 6Ic.
substituting Ic = 100 - Is gives us 2Is = 6 (100 - Is ).
Therefore, Is = 75, Ic = 25.

b.

If only Charity matters, then give money to Charity until MUc = 0 (unless all the
money in the economy is exhausted first).
So,
400-6 Ic = 0; hence, Ic = 66.67.
Giving any more money to Charity causes her marginal utility to become negative,
which is not optimal. Note that we dont care if the remaining money ($33.33) is
given to Simon or not.
If only Simon matters, then, proceeding as above, MUs. 0 if Is = 100; hence, giving
all the money to Simon is optimal. (In fact, we would like to give him up to
$200.)

c.

MUs = MUc for all levels of income. Hence, society is indifferent among all
distributions of income.

46

Part 1 Getting Started

3.

Suppose the government is initially providing an in-kind benefit of 10 units of free public
transportation, worth $2 each, so the cost of the subsidy is $20. Without the subsidy,
income is $40. With no subsidy, the consumer maximizes utility at point A, and with an
in-kind benefit of 10 units of free public transportation, the consumer maximizes utility at
point B. A cash subsidy equal to $20 would allow the consumer to reach point B as well,
so the government could convert an in-kind subsidy valued at $20 to a cash subsidy of
$20 and leave people equally well off.
Other goods

10

20

30

Public Transportation

Another possibility is that the utility-maximizing point for a cash subsidy differs from the
utility-maximizing point for an in-kind subsidy, as illustrated in the next graph.

47

Chapter 1 - Introduction

In this case, an in-kind subsidy, costing $20, would allow the consumer to move from
point A to point B, while a cash subsidy of $20 would make the consumer better off at
point B. In order to make the consumer equally well off, the cash subsidy should be a
little less than $20.

Other goods

B
C
A

10

20

48

30

Public Transportation

Part 1 Getting Started

4.

With a $50 cash grant, an individual could purchase 10 units of food, since the
market value of each unit of food is $5. Assume household income is $50 and
that the market value of other goods is also $5 per unit. Adding the $50 cash
grant would give the individual $100 to spend on some combination of food and
other goods and the relevant budget line would be AC in the graph below. If,
instead, the individual is given $50 worth of food stamps, then the budget line is
the horizontal line DB and the segment BC. If the utility-maximizing
combination of food and other goods had been at point E with the cash grant (or
any other point on the segment AB), then switching from a cash grant to food
stamps would force the individual to a lower indifference curve and the new
equilibrium would occur at point B.
It is possible that switching from food stamps to a cash grant would make the
individual better off, as illustrated by a movement from point B to point E in the
graph below.
It is also possible that the individual would choose the same combination
regardless of whether he is given a cash grant or food stamps (if the higher
indifference curve were tangent to the budget line on the segment BC), in which
case it would make no difference.
There is no circumstance under which switching from food stamps to a cash grant
would make the individual worse off, given the assumptions of the model.

Other Goods
A
20

D
B

C
20

10

Food

49

Chapter 1 - Introduction

50

Part 1 Getting Started

5.

According to the maximin criterion, social welfare depends on the utility of the individual
who has the minimum utility in the society. A peculiar implication of this criterion, as
noted by Feldstein, is that if society has the opportunity to raise the welfare of the least
advantaged by a slight amount, but make almost everyone else substantially worse off
except for a few individuals who would become extremely wealthy, then society should
pursue this opportunity. Transferring large sums of income from the middle class to both
the poor and the rich would achieve this end, and so would be supported by someone
with the maximin social welfare function.

6.

a.

False. Society is indifferent between a util to each individual, not a dollar to each
individual. Imagine that UL=I and UJ=2I. Then each dollar given to Jonathan
raises welfare more than the same dollar given to Lynne.

b.

True. The social welfare function assumes a cardinal interpretation of utility so


that comparisons across people are valid.

c.

False. Departures from complete equality raise social welfare to the extent that
they raise the welfare of the person with the minimum level of utility. For
example, with the utility functions UL=I and UJ=2I, the social welfare function
W=min[UL,UJ] would allocate twice as much income to Lynne than Jonathan.

51

Chapter 1 - Introduction

7.

Initially the price of food was $2 and the price of other goods was $1. The black market
for food stamps changes the price of food sold to $1. In Figure 12.3 of the textbook, as
one moves to the northwest from point F, the segment will now have a slope (in
absolute value) of 1 rather than 2. The black market may make the individual better off if
the best point on her budget constraint AFD was initially at the corner solution of point F,
and the black market certainly does not make her worse off. It is important to note that
the black market does not always make the recipient better off. If the (absolute value) of
the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) were between 1 and 2, the indifference curve
would not cut into the new part of the budget constraint with the black market.
Black market where food stamps are sold
for fifty cents on the dollar, no better off
Other Goods

Sell food stamps for other


goods on black market

F
U0

D
Food
Stamp
Allotment

Food

52

Part 1 Getting Started

If the MRS were less than (or equal to) 1 in absolute value, the person would be made
better off and would reduce food consumption by selling the food stamps on the black
market.
FIGURE 7.7b Black market where food
stamps are sold for fifty cents on the dollar,
higher utility

Other Goods

Sell food stamps for other


goods on black market

U1
U0

D
Food Stamp
Guarantee

8.

Food

Pareto efficient redistribution is a reallocation of income that increases (or does not
decrease) the utility of all consumers. With these two consumers, Marshas utility
increases as Sherrys utility increases. Thus, it may be possible to reallocate income from
Marsha to Sherry and raise both of their utility. With Sherrys initial utility function of
US=100YS1/2, her utility with $100 of income is US=100($100)1/2, or US=1,000. With
Marshas initial utility function of UM=100YM1/2+0.8US, her utility with $100 of income
is UM=100($100)1/2+0.8(1,000), or UM=1,800. If the social welfare function is additive,
then initial welfare is W=US+UM=1,000+1,800=2,800. If $36 is reallocated from Marsha
to Sherry, then Sherrys income is now $136 and Marshas is now $64. With Sherrys
utility function, her utility with $136 of income is US=100($136)1/2, or US=1,166.190.
With Marshas utility function, her utility with $64 of income is
UM=100($64)1/2+0.8(1,166.190), or UM=800+932.952=1,732.952. In this case, Sherrys
utility increases from 1,000 to 1,166.190, while Marshas utility falls from 1,800 to
1,732.952. Social welfare increases with this redistribution, going from 2,800 to
2,899.142. Thus, this redistribution increases social welfare, but is not Pareto efficient
redistribution.

53

Chapter 1 - Introduction

Chapter 13 Expenditure Programs for the Poor


1.

2.

a.

Note that the figure below shows the correct shape of the budget constraint, but
the numbers themselves are outdated. With a wage rate of $10 per hour,
Elizabeth earns $100. Because the deduction in California is $225, none of her
earnings are counted against the $645 welfare benefit. Thus, her total income is
$745 (=$100+$645).

b.

The actual welfare benefits collected by a person equals B=G-t(Earnings-D),


where B=actual benefits, G=welfare grant, t=tax rate on earned income, and
D=standard deduction. Thus, (Earnings-D) is the net earnings that are taxed away
in the form of reduced benefits. When benefits equal zero (B=0), the expression
becomes 0=G-t(Earnings-D), which collapses to: Earnings=G/t+D. This is known
as the breakeven formula. In the California context here, the expression
becomes Earnings=$645/0.5 + 225, or Earnings=$1,515. With a wage rate of $10
per hour, this corresponds to 151.5 hours of work per month.

c.

The diagram shows the correct shape of the budget constraint, but the 577 figure
should be replaced with 645 and the 9 hours should be replaced with 22.5.

d.

The diagram above shows one possibility in this case, Elizabeth is both working
and on welfare but she collects a reduced welfare benefit in this case.

One could gather data on the earnings of those in the program, as well as earnings data
from nonparticipants. Regress the earnings variable on demographic variables and other
factors that determine earnings (such as education and experience), and a variable that
indicates whether the individual participated in the training program. Factors that affect
local employment conditions, such as unemployment levels, may help explain earnings,
54

Part 1 Getting Started

but they may also explain participation in the program. The econometric strategy should
be chosen carefully to account for this.
3.

a.

Without the program in effect, Loiss budget constraint is the line AD. With the
program in effect, her budget constraint is ABCD. The grant is reduced to zero if
Lois works 20 hours per month since her hourly wage rate is $10.

Income
$10T

$200

D
T - 20

Leisure Hours

b.

Many low-wage earners would be better off working zero hours with this kind of
program in place, as shown in Figure 13.6.

c.

If the implicit marginal tax rate on the grant is 66.67 percent, then Lois can work
30 hours before losing the full $200 grant. Her budget constraint changes to
AECD, as shown in the next graph.

55

Chapter 1 - Introduction

Income
$10T

E
C

$200

D
T - 30 T - 20

56

Leisure Hours

Part 1 Getting Started

d.

In the graph below, the highest indifference curve corresponds to the program
with a 66.67 percent marginal tax rate, the middle indifference curve to the
program with a 100 percent marginal tax rate, and the lowest indifference curve to
no program. Hours worked fall to zero with the 100 percent marginal tax rate,
while hours worked fall some, but not all the way to zero, with the 66.67 percent
marginal tax rate. There is insufficient information to predict how many hours
Lois will work in each case. In general, the lower marginal tax rate strengthens
work incentives, as illustrated in Figures 13-4 and 13-6.

Income
$10T

$200

T - 30 T - 20

57

Leisure Hours

Chapter 1 - Introduction

4.

He participates in the public housing program as long as P1P2cacef.

5.

As illustrated below, the budget constraint with food stamps has a notch in it, similar to
the analysis of Medicaid in Figure 13.9 of the textbook. At the notch, the marginal tax
rate is greater than 100%. One key difference from the figure in the textbook is that the
marginal tax rate on earned income for Medicaid is 0% until the Medicaid notch, while
the marginal tax rate on earned income for food stamps is 24% until the food stamp
notch. The reason the food stamp notch exists at all is that there is a gross income
test, where a recipient is ineligible if income is higher than the limit. The
characterization in the textbook that at some point near the poverty line, food stamps
worth about $1,250 are suddenly lost implicitly assumes that childcare costs are quite
high. This is likely to be true for many households. In the year 2004, this monthly
(annual) gross income limit was $1,994 per month ($23,928 per year) for a family of
four, while the monthly guarantee was $471 ($5,652 per year). Assuming the family had
earnings at the limit of $1,994 of earnings during the month, and after applying a 20%
earnings deduction and a $134 monthly standard deduction, the household would receive
a monthly (annual) benefit of $32 ($384). We arrive at this number using the equation
B=G-t(E-.2E-D)=471-.3(.8*1994-134)=$471-$438.36=$32.64, which is then rounded
down to $32. In this case, B=actual benefits received, G=food stamp guarantee, t=tax
rate, E=earnings, and D=standard deduction. Increasing annual earnings by $1 from
$23,928 to $23,929 would reduce food stamp benefits from $384 to $0; hence the food

58

Part 1 Getting Started

stamp notch. This notch would be even higher if the household qualified for a childcare
deduction, child support deduction, or shelter deduction. The childcare deduction ranges
between $175 and $200 per child per month. Assuming this family of four consisted of a
mother and three children, each with $175 of monthly childcare costs, then B=G-t(E-.2ED-C)=471-.3(.8*1994-134-525)=$471-$280.86=$190.14, which is then rounded down to
$190. The modification here is that C=childcare costs. This amount corresponds to an
annual food stamp benefit of $2,280. The figure below draws the budget constraint using
annual levels for the food stamp program, using 2004 rules and assumes no childcare
expenses.

Other Goods or
Annual Income

The food stamp notch with 24% tax rate


on earned income

Food stamp notch; eligibility


determined separately from
benefits. Notch = $384

Statutory food stamp


maximum = $5,652

$23,928

Leisure

59

Chapter 1 - Introduction

6.

For an individual who is not working while on welfare, in this case the highest
indifference curve touches the budget constraint on the right vertical axis. Note that the
marginal rate of substitution (MRS) does not necessarily equal the after-tax wage rate at
the time endowment rather, it is possible that the person would want to consume more
leisure than the time endowment but is obviously constrained from doing so.
Individual is on welfare and does not work
at all
Other Goods

Statutory TANF
benefit

U0
MRS>(1-t)w

Leisure

60

Part 1 Getting Started

7.

In all cases, the demand curve for housing slopes downward.


a.
If the price of low income housing gets bid up but there is no increase in the stock
of housing, then the supply curve is perfectly inelastic, e.g., vertical.
Demand curve shifts outward, perfectly
inelastic supply
PHOUSING
S

P1

P0

D1
D0

Q0

QHOUSING

61

Chapter 1 - Introduction

b.

If there is no increase in the price of housing, but there is an increase in the stock
of housing, then the supply curve is perfectly elastic, e.g., horizontal.
FIGURE 8.7b Demand curve shifts
outward, perfectly elastic supply

PHOUSING

P0

D1
D0

Q0

Q1

62

QHOUSING

Part 1 Getting Started

c.

If there is an increase in both the price and quantity of housing, then the supply
curve slopes upward.
FIGURE 8.7c Demand curve shifts outward,
upward sloping supply curve

PHOUSING

P1

P0

D1
D0

Q0

Q1

QHOUSING

According to Sinai and Waldfogel, there is partial crowding out, consistent with case c
above. Although the underlying housing stock itself is probably quite inelastic in the
short-run, the number of rental homes can be more elastic as (potential) landlords convert
vacation homes or vacant homes into rental units.
8.

a.

When Eleanors hours (earnings) go from 0 to 1,000 ($0 to $8,000), she qualifies
for an additional earned income tax credit (EITC) worth $3,200 (=0.4*8,000).
Thus, her income goes up from $0 to $11,200. Note to instructors the
distinction between earnings and income may cause confusion in the students
answers.

b.

When Eleanors hours (earnings) go from 1,000 to 1,500 ($8,000 to $12,000), she
qualifies for the maximum EITC (according to Figure 13.8 in the textbook). She
receives the full EITC when her earnings exceed $10,510, at which time the credit
equals $4,204 (=0.4*$10,510). The earnings between $10,510 and $12,000 face
neither a subsidy nor phase-out from the EITC. Thus, her income goes up from
$11,200 to $16,204.

c.

When Eleanors hours (earnings) go from 1,500 to 2,000 ($12,000 to $16,000),


she moves into the range where the EITC is phased out. According to Figure 13.8

63

Chapter 1 - Introduction

in the textbook, she receives the maximum subsidy of $4,204 until her earnings
exceed $14,730. For the marginal earnings between $14,730 and $16,000, the
EITC is reduced at a 21.06% tax rate. Thus, her EITC falls by $267.46 from
$4,204 to $3,936.54 (=4,204-0.2106*(16,000-14,730)). Her income rises from
$16,204 to $19,936.54.
9.

Since Peter does not have to pay Social Security and Medicare payroll taxes on
unemployment benefits, approximately 55 percent of his after-tax income is replaced by
unemployment insurance. The existence of UI may make workers more likely to accept
employment in industries where the probability of future layoffs is great. UI may also
induce the unemployed to spend more time looking for work than they would have
otherwise. These moral hazard problems are likely to be more serious as the after-tax
replacement rate rises.

64

Part 1 Getting Started

Chapter 14 Taxation and Income Distribution


1.

2.

a.

The workers assertion is correct if the demand for her services is perfectly
elastic. This assumption is not realistic. The demand for these services would be
perfectly elastic if there were perfect substitutes available and no differentiation,
which is unlikely.

b.

The statutory incidence of a tax does not determine its economic incidence.
Levying the tax on patrons would not make a difference.

As shown in the graph, the subsidy acts to increase the demand for prescription drugs, so
the price rises. However, consumers pay P2 subsidy, so the elderly benefit by paying
less for prescription drugs and consuming more.

$
S

P2
P1
P2 - subsidy
D + Subsidy
D

Q1

65

Q2

Chapter 1 - Introduction

3.

4.

One expects that those factors that are used intensively in tobacco production will bear
the burden of the tax. Assuming, for example, that tobacco production is capitalintensive, one expects owners of all capital (not just those with investments in tobacco) to
bear some of the burden.

5.

a.

Before-tax equilibrium: P = $10 and Q = 300,000


After-tax equilibrium: P = $10.60 and Q = 288,000
Consumers pay $10.60 and producers receive $9.60.

b.

Revenue = $288,000. Consumers bear 60 percent of the tax burden and producers
bear 40 percent. So, $172,800 comes from consumers and $115,200 from
producers.

c.

With a more elastic demand curve, quantity consumed will decrease even more as
a result of the tax, so the liquor tax will be more effective at reducing
consumption among young drinkers.

66

Part 1 Getting Started

6.

The equilibrium price can be calculated by setting the quantity supplied equal to the
quantity demanded:
(i)
(ii)

QD = a - bP
QS = c + dP

If QD = QS, then the equilibrium price can be determined as follows:

a bP c dP
a c (b d ) P
ac
P
bd
The equilibrium output can be determined by substituting the equilibrium price into either
the supply or demand equation.
Substituting into the demand equation:

Q a bP
ac
Q a b

bd
Substituting into the supply equation:
Q c dP
ac
Q c d

bd
If a unit tax of u dollars is imposed on the commodity, then it doesnt matter which party
it is imposed upon (the consumer or producer); the new equilibrium will be the same in
a 1
a 1
Q
P CT Q u
b b
b b
either case. If the unit tax is imposed upon the consumer, then the price the consumer
pays is u higher than the price received by the supplier. The consumers price without
the tax, PC, and price that includes the tax, PCT, are:
PC

Similarly, the price received by the producer in the absence of the tax, P P, is u lower than
the price received with the imposition of the tax, PPT. These prices are expressed below:
c
1
P P Q
d
d

c
1
P PT Q u
d
d

67

Chapter 1 - Introduction

The equilibrium that prevails after the imposition of the tax can be found by setting P CT =
PP or PC = PPT -- in the end, both approaches will yield the same answer. First, we can
derive the solution setting PCT = PP:
P CT P P
a 1
c
1
Q u Q
b b
d
d
a c
1 1
u Q
b d
b d
da bc dbu b d

Q
db
db
da bc dbu
Q
bd

Next, setting PC = PPT:


P C P PT
a 1
c
1
Q Q u
b b
d
d
a c
1 1
u Q
b d
b d
da bc dbu b d

Q
db
db
da bc dbu
Q
bd

Therefore, both approaches lead to the same outcome.

68

Part 1 Getting Started

7.

8.

a.

A part-time worker with annual income of $9,000 pays no taxes since everyone
gets a $10,000 deduction.

b.

A retail salesperson with annual income of $45,000 has taxable income of


$35,000 and pays $1750 in taxes (5 percent of taxable income). As a percentage
of income, the average tax rate is 3.89% ($1750 is 3.89% of $45,000). Compared
to the part-time worker, the salesperson has $36,000 more in income and pays
$1750 more in taxes, so the marginal tax rate is 4.86%.

c.

An advertising executive with annual income of $600,000 pays $2,500 in taxes


since no tax is levied above $50,000 in taxable income. As a percentage of
income, the average tax rate is 0.42%. Compared to the salesperson, the
executive has $555,000 more in income and pays $750 more in taxes, so the
marginal tax rate is 0.14%.

The equation T=-4000+.2I is somewhat similar to the exercise in Table 14.1. If we


follow the text and define progressivity with respect to average tax rates rather than
marginal tax rates, then the average tax rate equal ATR=(-4000/I)+.2 for any income
level. Clearly this average tax rate converges to ATR=20% as income gets large, and is
lower for lower income levels. Replicating Table 14.1 for the tax system given here, we
get:
Income
$2,000
3,000
5,000
10,000
30,000

9.

Tax Liability
$-3,600
$-3,400
$-3,000
$-2,000
$2,000

Average Tax Rate


-1.80
-1.13
-0.60
-0.20
0.066

Marginal Tax Rate


0.2
0.2
0.2
0.2
0.2

a.

After New York City increased the tax from $0.08 to $1.50 per pack of cigarettes,
the quantity demanded went down and revenues went up. Define TR1 as the total
revenue after the tax, and TR0 as the total revenue before the tax. Then TR0=QP
and TR1=(Q-dQ)(P+dP)=QP+QdP-PdQ-dQdP. Ignore the last term, dQdP,
which is of second order importance. Then dTR=QdP-PdQ. If this change in
revenue is positive, then dTR=QdP-PdQ>0, or QdP/PdQ>1. Thus (1/D)>1 or
D<1. Thus, the absolute value of the elasticity of demand is less than 1, or
demand must be inelastic in this case.

b.

The spokesmans comment was made just one month after the tax increase was
enacted. As more time passes and consumers are able to adjust (e.g., by quitting
smoking, substituting to other forms of tobacco that are not taxed in the same
way, etc.), it is expected that the long-run elasticity of demand for cigarettes will
be larger in absolute value (e.g., become relatively more elastic), and revenues
will likely fall.

69

Chapter 1 - Introduction

10.

The imposition of a payroll tax has no effect on employment when the supply of labor is
perfectly inelastic, as shown below. If, on the other hand, the supply of labor is upwardsloping, the imposition of a payroll tax would cause equilibrium employment to fall, and
cutting the tax would then have a positive effect on hiring, as suggested by the editorial.
It is realistic to assume that, although labor supply is inelastic, it is not perfectly inelastic.

Wage
Rate per
hour

SL

W1
W2
DL
DL

L1 = L2

Hours per year

The next graph shows an upward-sloping supply, and illustrates how the tax reduces
equilibrium employment. Cutting the tax would cause the demand curve to shift back to
the right, toward the original demand curve, and cause equilibrium employment to move
back toward L1.

70

Part 1 Getting Started

Wage
Rate per
hour

SL

W1
W2
DL
DL

L2 L1

71

Hours per year

Chapter 1 - Introduction

Chapter 15 Taxation and Efficiency


1.

a.

The supply of land is fixed, or perfectly inelastic, so there is no excess burden


because the lower price that sellers receive does not cause quantity supplied to
fall.

b.

If consumers purchase cell phones in other states in order to avoid the tax, then the
excess burden will be quite large.

c.

It is possible that companies could identify themselves as high-tech in order to


receive the subsidy. Thus, the supply is quite elastic, and there will be substantial
excess burden.

d.

Consumers and sellers will likely agree to avoid cups and glasses in order to avoid
the tax. A tax that is easily avoided does not have much of an impact, except to
create some inconvenience, and does not raise revenue.

e.

A tax on all computer software will have a smaller excess burden (relative to
revenues collected) than a tax on one particular type of software like the Excel
spreadsheet. This is because it is easier to substitute away from one type of
software than software in general.

f.

There are many good substitutes for blueberries. Therefore, their demand is quite
elastic, and a tax on them will have a substantial excess burden, relative to the
size of revenues collected.

2.

Equation 15.3 relates excess burden to elasticity, price, quantity, and the tax rate.
Replacing a general sales tax with a tax on a few products would require a higher tax rate,
which increases excess burden, other things equal. The equation indicates that it is better
to tax many commodities at a lower rate than to tax a few commodities at a higher rate.

3.

The quote is misleading. The way in which the presence of the t-squared makes the tax
more important is that when the tax increases, the excess burden increases with its
square. Thus, when the tax doubles, the excess burden quadruples.

4.

Figure 15.9 shows how a tax on market activity leads to "too much" nonmarket activity.
More generally, the model shows that when different sectors are taxed at different rates,
the allocation of resources is distorted, and real income falls as a result. The more
pervasive distortionary taxes are in an economy, the more severe the misallocation of
resources, and the lower is real income. Hence, it is no surprise that economies with a lot
of distortionary taxes tend to grow relatively slowly.

5.

It is likely that the elasticity of demand for television is quite inelastic. It follows that the
excess burden from a $233 per year television tax is small relative to the revenues that are
collected.

72

Part 1 Getting Started

6. The horizontal distance OO measures the total amount of capital available in society.
Any point along OO represents some allocation of capital between the manufacturing
sector and the non-manufacturing sector. Assume that firms allocate capital between the
two sectors to maximize total incomes. It follows that the value of the marginal product
of capital is the same in both sectors. In the graph below, equilibrium occurs where OK*
units of capital are devoted to the non-manufacturing sector and OK* units of capital are
devoted to the manufacturing sector.
Now assume that a subsidy is available for the purchase of capital goods in the
manufacturing sector, but not in the non-manufacturing sector. The subsidy raises the
rate of return on capital in the manufacturing sector to (1+s)VMPMANU and causes an
increase in the allocation of capital to the manufacturing sector to OKS, along with a
decrease in the allocation of capital to the non-manufacturing sector to OKS. The excess
burden is equal to the shaded triangle in the graph.

(1+s)R2
R1
R2
(1+s)VMPMANU
VMPMANU

KS
Capital used in the nonmanufacturing sector

VMPNON-MANU

K*
Capital used in the
manufacturing sector

73

Chapter 1 - Introduction

7.

a.

The value of the marginal product of capital in the corporate sector is given by
VMPc=100-Kc, and the value of the marginal product of capital in the
noncorporate sector is given by VMPn=80-2Kn. With 50 units of capital
altogether in society (Kc+Kn=50), and no taxation, capital should be allocated
so that the values of the marginal products in each sector are equalized. Thus,
setting VMPc=VMPn gives 100-Kc=80-2Kn and substituting in the constraint of
50 units gives 100-50+Kn=80-2Kn or Kn=10. This implies that Kc=40. This is
illustrated below:
Allocation of capital to the corporate and
non-corporate sectors

VMPCORPORATE

VMPNONCORPORATE

100

80

VMPN=80-2KN

VMPC=100-KC

KC=40
KN=10

QCORPORATE

b.

QNONCORPORATE

If a unit tax of $6 is leveled on capital employed in the corporate sector, the aftertax value of the marginal product in the corporate sector falls. It is now given by
VMPc=100-Kc-6=94-Kc. Now setting VMPc=VMPn gives 94-Kc=80-2Kn and
substituting in the constraint of 50 units gives 94-50+Kn=80-2Kn or Kn=12. This
implies that Kc=38. This is illustrated below:

74

Part 1 Getting Started

FIGURE 13.7b Reallocation after perunit tax on corporate capital


VMPCORPORATE

VMPNONCORPORATE

100
94
80

Excess burden from


$6 per unit tax

VMPN=80-2KN

QCORPORATE

VMPC=94-KC

KC=38
KN=12

QNONCORPORATE

Thus, K=2 and the tax wedge is t=$6, so the excess burden is (2)($6)=$6.

75

Chapter 1 - Introduction

8.

a.

Before-tax equilibrium: P = $10 and Q = 300,000


After-tax equilibrium: P = $10.60 and Q = 288,000
Consumers pay $10.60 and producers receive $9.60.
Excess Burden = (12,000)($0.60) + (12,000)($0.40) = $6,000.

P
tax revenue

S
$10.60

excess burden

$10
unit tax

$9.60

D0
D1

288,000

b.

300,000

If the negative external cost were equal to $1 per gallon, then a $1 tax would
achieve an efficient allocation and would create no excess burden. With a
negative external cost of $0.50 per gallon, there is still an excess burden
associated with a $1 per gallon tax, but it is smaller since the efficient level of
output in this market would be between 288,000 and 300,000.

76

Part 1 Getting Started

Chapter 16 Efficient and Equitable Taxation


1.

Assuming that all other commodities (except for cable and satellite television) were
untaxed, then optimal tax policy suggests the commodities should be taxed according to
the inverse elasticity rule. Goolsbee and Petrin (2004) find that the elasticity of demand
for basic cable service is -0.51, and the demand for direct broadcast satellites is -7.40.
Applying the inverse elasticity rule would imply that:
(tBASIC/tSATELLITE)=(SATELLITE/BASIC)=(7.40/0.51)=14.5
Thus, tax rates on basic cable should be 14.5 times higher than tax rates on satellite
television because basic cable is inelastically demanded, while demand for satellite
television is highly elastic. Among the assumptions that go into the inverse elasticity rule
are that goods are neither complements nor substitutes, and that the elasticities are the
Hicksian compensated elasticities rather than the Marshallian uncompensated elasticities.
In this case, it is likely that the first of these assumptions is false basic cable and
satellite television are likely substitutes for each other. The Hicksian and Marshallian
demand elasticities are likely to be close to each other because the income effects are
likely to be small for this commodity.

2.

Although the tax schedule is progressive, the incidence is not clear at all. This is
determined by the relative demand and supply elasticities for expensive cars. One may
argue that behavior will be distorted only at the margin, and hence demanders largely
bear the burden. However, administration of this tax would not be straightforward: One
could imagine methods of evasion such as misrepresenting invoices or selling the car in
parts!

3.

The beard tax was progressive because it was a function of social position. Its hard to
know about the efficiency consequences unless one knows more about the price elasticity
of demand for the privilege of having a beard. If the elasticity was small, then it would
be an efficient tax. However, conventional notions of horizontal equity suggest that the
tax was unfair.

4.

If the nut fee is truly collected whether or not the farmer collects nuts, then it is
independent of the farmer's behavior. Hence, it is a lump-sum tax, and perfectly efficient
(unless it drives some individuals out of farming). However, optimal tax theory tells us
that we must consider equity as well as efficiency considerations. If the fee is the same
for all households, regardless of their incomes, then it is regressive. With a conventional
utilitarian welfare function, this is unlikely to be optimal. Because farmers who are not
alike in relevant aspects (e.g., income) pay the same tax, the nut tax would seem to
violate horizontal equity. Things become even worse when we bring city-dwellers, who
don't have to pay the nut tax at all, into the picture.
Moral: An efficient tax need not be optimal or horizontally equitable.

77

Chapter 1 - Introduction

5.

An unregulated, profit-maximizing natural monopolist will produce Q1 units of output


and charge a price per unit equal to P1. Since price is greater than marginal cost, the
monopolists output is inefficient. The efficient level of output is Q*, where price equals
marginal cost. Excess burden is the area between the demand curve and the marginal
cost curve between output levels Q1 and Q*.
If the firm is required by law to charge average cost, then price will be P2 and the firm
can break even by producing Q2 units of output. Q2 is below Q*, so although average
cost pricing leads to more output than at the profit-maximizing level, it still falls short of
the efficient amount and there is still an excess burden, measured as the area between the
demand curve and the marginal cost curve between output levels Q2 and Q*.
$

P1

P2

AC
MC
D

MR
Q1

6.

Q2

Q*

The marginal benefit of underreporting is equal to the taxes saved, which is simply the
persons marginal tax rate, or MB = t. The expected marginal cost of underreporting $1
of income is equal to the product of the probability of getting caught and the fine per
dollar of underreporting, or MC = *Marginal Penalty. The optimal amount of
underreporting, R* equals zero if MC MB. Thus, if *Marginal Penalty t, then there
will be no underreporting. With = 0.02 and t = 0.35, the inequality becomes
0.02*Marginal Penalty 0.35, or Marginal Penalty $17.50. With a fine of $17.50 (or
more), Sharlene would not cheat on her taxes.

78

Part 1 Getting Started

7.

The problem with a one-time tax on profits is that the government has an incentive to
renege on its promise. The time inconsistency of optimal policy occurs when the
government cannot implement an optimal tax policy because the stated policy is
inconsistent with the governments incentives over time. Since pharmaceutical
companies know that government has an incentive to impose a tax on profits more than
once, their behavior will be affected by the tax, creating an excess burden.

8.

a.

It is true that a proportional tax on all commodities (including leisure) is


equivalent to a lump sum tax. To illustrate, consider the simplest example where
there are only two goods: consumption goods and leisure. The budget constraint
is equal to: pCC+wL=I, where pC and w are the prices of consumption goods and
leisure, C and L are the quantities of consumption and leisure, and I is income.
Then a proportional tax on all goods changes the budget constraint to: (1)pCC+(1-)wL=I, or rearranging, pCC+wL=I, where I=I/(1-)<I. Thus, a
proportional tax on all goods does not change relative prices and is equivalent to
taking away income. So it is equivalent to a lump sum tax.

b.

It is (usually) false that efficiency is maximized when all commodities are taxed
at the same rate; this will not be true if leisure is untaxed. Imagine a more
complicated budget constraint: pCC+pFF+wL=I. If leisure cannot be taxed, then
a tax on commodities leads to a budget constraint of (1-)pCC+(1-)pFF+wL=I,
which does change the relative price of leisure compared with food or
consumption goods. Thus, it is not a lump sum tax. Instead, the inverse elasticity
rule given in equation (16.9) would suggest that the ratio of the tax rates are
inversely related to the ratio of the compensated demand elasticities for all
commodities that can be taxed. That is, (tC/tF)=(F/C).

c.

It is true that average cost pricing for a natural monopoly allows the enterprise to
break even, but the outcome is inefficient. Figure 16.3 in the textbook shows the
typical natural monopoly problem, with an initial fixed cost, and an everdeclining marginal cost curve. In this case, the average cost curve is always
declining, but above the marginal cost curve. Setting P=AC results in an output
level of ZA and zero economic profits. The figure illustrates, however, that the
marginal benefit of more output exceeds the marginal cost, so the efficient level
of production occurs at P=MC, or an output level Z*>ZA. The deadweight loss is
the area between the demand curve DZ and marginal cost curve, going from ZA to
Z*. If output were at the efficient level, however, there would be economic losses
rather than zero profits.

d.

One notion of horizontal equity is that people in equal positions should be treated
equally by the tax system. Under this traditional notion of horizontal equity, the
fact that Toms workplace provides free access to a fitness room suggests this
kind of compensation should be taxed; Jerry pays full taxes on his
compensation while Tom does not. Another notion of horizontal equity relies on
the utility definition of horizontal equity. This concept says that if two individuals
have the same utility without taxes, they should have the same utility with taxes,

79

Chapter 1 - Introduction

and the taxes should not affect the utility ordering. One implication of the utility
definition is that any existing tax structure does not violate the notion of
horizontal equity if individuals are free to choose their activities and expenditures.
If Tom and Jerry have free choice between the two different jobs (and identical
preferences), then the net after-tax rewards (including amenities) must be the
same at both jobs; otherwise there would be migration. In this case, the beforetax wage on Toms job adjusts for the fact that there is a fringe benefit.

80

Part 1 Getting Started

Chapter 17 The Personal Income Tax


1.

The Haig-Simons definition of income is the net change in the individuals power to
consume during a given period. This criterion suggests the inclusion of all sources of
potential increases in consumption and also implies that any decreases in an individuals
power to consume should be subtracted in determining income. Overall, it reflects the
broadest possible base of income. Allowing capital losses of $5,000 to be deductible
against other forms of income, rather than the current $3,000, would move the tax system
more in the direction of the Haig-Simons criterion.

2.

Personal fitness expenses should be counted as income according to the Haig-Simons


definition, since they represent a net increase in the individuals power to consume. It
would be difficult to devise a consistent system for determining whether such benefits
should be taxable since the availability of personal fitness equipment does not prove that
the individual used the equipment. It would also be difficult to accurately measure the
value of such consumption.

3.

Suppose Jones buys the oil stock for $1,000 at the start of period 0. At the start of
period 1, he has two options.
a.

Hold the oil stock one more period, then sell.

b.

Sell the oil stock, buy the gold stock and hold it for one period.
In both cases, it is assumed that all assets are sold, and any taxes paid at the end of
period 2. What are the returns to option a)? At a 10 percent rate of appreciation,
the oil stock is worth $1,210 after period 2, the capital gain is $210 and assuming
a 29 percent rate applies to capital gains, the capital gains tax is 28 percent of
$210 or $58.80. Thus, Jones is left with $1,210 - $58.80 or $1,151.20 after tax.
If Jones follows strategy b), the value of the oil stock at the start of period 1 is
$1,000, the capital gain is $100, and the tax $28. Thus Jones has $1,672 left over
to proceeds (V) from selling the gold stock at the end of period 1.
V = Value of gold stock taxes
= (1+r)($1,072) (.28)[(1+r)($1,072)-($1,072)]
= (1+r)($1,072) (.28)r($1,072)
= $1,072 + .72r($1,072)
Setting V = $1,151.20 (same as oil stock):
$1,151.20 = $1,072 + .72r($1.072) r=10.26%
Thus the gold stock must pay a premium of 0.26% (10.26% - 10%) over the oil
stock in order to overcome the tax cost of realizing the capital gain.

81

Chapter 1 - Introduction

4.

If same-sex couples were allowed to legally marry, they would be subject to the marriage
penalty, resulting in an increase in income tax revenues.

5.

For an itemizer, a $500 tax deduction lowers the tax bill by t*deduction. Thus, for an
itemizer with a 30% marginal tax rate, the tax bill is lowered by 30%*$500, or $150. A
(refundable) tax credit, on the other hand, directly lowers the tax bill by that amount, in
this case, $500.

6.

a.

With a tax rate of t=0.3, and a nominal interest rate of i=0.13, the nominal aftertax rate of interest is (1-t)i=(1-0.3)0.13=0.091. With an expected inflation rate of
=0.08, the real after-tax rate of interest is (1-t)i-=(1-0.3)0.13-0.08=0.0910.08=0.011.

b.

If the expected inflation rate increased by 3 percentage points to =0.11, and the
nominal interest rate also increases by 3 percentage points to i=0.16, then the real
after-tax rate of interest is now (1-t)i-=(1-0.3)0.16-0.11=0.112-0.11=0.02. The
real after-tax rate of return falls from 1.1% to 0.2%. This is because the tax
system taxes nominal, not real, returns.

c.

In general, consider two rates of inflation, <. The key question is when taxes
are present, by how much must the nominal interest rate increase in order to have
the same real rate of return. This is calculated by equating real rates of return
under different inflation rates (holding constant taxes): (1-t)i-=(1-t)i-. One
can rearrange this equation: (-)=(1-t)(i-i), or (i-i)= (-)/(1-t). This can in
turn be expressed as: i=/(1-t). Intuitively, the left-hand side of this final
equation is the change in nominal interest rates that keeps the real after-tax rate of
interest unchanged. It is equal to the change in the expected inflation rate divided
by (1-t). Thus, returning to part 6b, for a 3 percentage point change in the
inflation rate and a marginal tax rate of t=0.30, nominal interest rates would have
to increase by approximately 4.3 percentage points.

7.

Much of the public debate concerning the marriage tax focuses on whether it is fairer to
tax individuals or families. Beliefs concerning the choice of the fairest taxable unit are
influenced by value judgments and by attitudes toward the role of the family in society.
Nobel laureate Ed Prescott suggests that the design of the tax system should avoid using
the tax system to either encourage or discourage marriage, whenever possible.

8.

The Haig-Simons definition of income provides no rationale for reducing the tax rates on
certain types of income. Some economists hope that reduced tax rates on dividends,
capital gains, and labor income will strengthen incentives to work, save, and invest.
Others are not convinced, and there are many arguments on both sides of the issue.

82

Part 1 Getting Started

9.

a.

b.

10.

i.

A family of four would receive four exemptions that totaled $13,200


(4*$3,300) in 2006.

ii.

Ignoring other features like the exemption phaseout, an increase in income


of $2,500 leads to an increase in taxes of $875 with a marginal tax rate of
35% ($875=$2,500*35%).

iii.

Personal exemptions are reduced by 2 percentage points for each $2,500


increase in AGI.
Thus, the exemption falls from $13,200 to
98%*$13,200, and taxable income goes up by 2%*$13,200, or $264.

iv.

The additional increase in taxable income of $264 increases the tax


liability by 35%*$264, or $92.40.

v.

The total change in tax liability,


($875+$92.40)/$2,500, or 38.696%.

i.

With an extra $100 in income, the family would owe an additional


35%*$100, or $35 in taxes.

ii.

Otherwise allowable itemized deductions are reduced by 2 percent of the


amount by which AGI exceeds $150,500. However, the reduction cannot
be more than 80 percent of the total of itemized deductions. An additional
$100 in AGI may reduce itemized deductions by $2 if AGI exceeds
$150,500. This would mean an increase in taxable income of $102.

iii.

Assuming the additional income caused allowable itemized deductions to


fall by $2, the familys tax liability increased by 35%*$102, or $35.70.

iv.

The effective tax rate is ($35.70)/$100=35.7%.

the

effective

tax

rate,

is

Of the $4,000 of earnings that Sam has, he is able to invest (1-tI)*earnings in the market,
or (1-0.25)*$4,000=$3,000. Assume that when he saves the money in a taxable account,
he has to pay taxes each year on the capital gains, and that those capital gains are treated
as ordinary income and taxed at 25%. In this case, his after-tax rate of return is (1-tI)*r,
or (1-0.25)*8%, or 6%. Thus, after 10 years of investment, the amount of money in the
taxable savings account is $3,000*(1.06)10=$5,372.54. If he invests the money in a Roth
IRA, the money accrues at the before-tax rate of return, and there is no tax liability at the
end. Thus, the amount in the Roth IRA is $3,000*(1.08)10=$6,476.77. It turns out that
the key difference between a traditional IRA and a Roth IRA is whether the income tax
rate today differs from the income tax rate in retirement. Thus, the amount in the Roth
IRA would be identical to that of a traditional IRA if tax rates 10 years from now were
the same 25%.

83

Chapter 1 - Introduction

Chapter 18 Personal Taxation and Behavior


1.

The supply of labor (and other factors) in and out of a city is more elastic than the supply
of factors to the nation as a whole. Therefore, an income tax reduction at the city level is
likely to lose less revenue than such a reduction at the federal level, ceteris paribus. Just
as one can think of welfare-induced migration for poor households, one can think of
tax-induced migration for businesses and possibly workers. If the city lowers tax rates
(and other cities do not respond accordingly), then one imagines that a number of
businesses will enter that state and spur economic activity.

2.

If individuals view their loss in the labor income taxes as offset by the benefits of public
services, labor supply falls by AB hours. This is the compensated change in hours with
respect to a change in the net wage rate.
3.

84

Part 1 Getting Started

4.

The effect of the change in the highest marginal tax rate on the individuals budget
constraint is demonstrated below:
Income

Leisure
The resulting change in the tax rate moves part of the budget line out to the new, dotted
budget constraint. This policy has an effect on labor supply analogous to the effect of an
increase in an individuals wage rate on labor supply: it is theoretically ambiguous. The
reason for this ambiguity is that there are two competing effects -- a substitution effect
which acts to decrease leisure, and an income effect which increases leisure. The
decrease in the tax rate makes leisure more expensive, so the substitution effect dictates
that less of it is to be consumed. However, there is extra income provided by this tax cut,
and the income effect makes the individual want to consume more leisure. These two
competing effects make the overall change in labor supply ambiguous. Existing
empirical work suggests that for prime age males, the income and substitution effects
more or less cancel each other out. For working wives, the substitution effect dominates,
meaning that the reduction in marginal tax rates would tend to increase their labor supply.
The effect on savings can be demonstrated using a diagram illustrating the change in the
intertemporal budget constraint that results from this tax change:

Future
Consumption

E
Current Consumption

The policy moves the endowment point from point E to E, and it changes the slope of
the intertemporal budget constraint, which is equal to [1 + (1-t)r], where t is the tax
rate, and r is the real interest rate. Once again, the overall effect of this policy on

85

Chapter 1 - Introduction

savings will be ambiguous, since there are again competing income and substitution
effects. The extra income gained from the tax cut will make this individual want to opt
for more consumption in both periods (now and in the future), so this will cause savings
to increase (intuitively, the individual will consume some of her extra income now, and
some in the next period). However, the tax cut will also change the slope of the budget
line. This causes a substitution affect which makes consuming in the current period more
expensive (so savings will increase), but it causes income to rise, which makes this
individual want to consumer more in the current period. The counteracting effects make
it difficult for us to say what will happen to overall savings. Econometric work suggests
that changes in marginal tax rates have little effect on individual saving.
Lastly, the effect on tax revenues will be negative (a decrease in the tax rate will have a
direct effect in this case). However, this decrease will not be as pronounced as we might
think. First, to the extent that some individuals work more, taxable income will increase.
More importantly, individuals will opt for more taxable income instead of nontaxable
income as the tax rate falls. For instance, since fringe benefits are like non-taxable
income, an individual will prefer them to cash payments (which are taxable) when the tax
rate is high. However, the opposite is true when the tax rate falls. Thus, although with a
lower tax rate less revenue is collected from a given tax base, this decrease is somewhat
counteracted by the increase in the base itself. That said, there is no evidence that the
increase in the base would be large enough to make the tax self-financing.
5.

The interest rate cut may be successful at stimulating consumer spending. Reducing the
rate of return on savings reduces the opportunity cost of current consumption, which
tends to increase current consumption and lower saving (the substitution effect). On the
other hand, the fact that the interest rate is lower makes it harder for a saver to achieve
any future consumption goal (the income effect), so the effect may be to increase saving
and reduce current consumption. The policy will have the desired results if the
substitution effect dominates the income effect.

6.

Increasing tax rates will not increase tax revenue if European tax rates are on the righthand side of the Laffer Curve (Figure 18.6), where the tax rate exceeds tA.

7.

A rational person will increase savings in reaction to reduced interest rates, as suggested
by the financial columnist, if the income effect is stronger than the substitution effect.
This would result in a downward-sloping supply of savings curve.

8.

The individual receives a benefit equal to the market rental value of the house because he
lives in the house. Whether he lives in the house or not, he receives a net benefit; the
only difference is that when he rents out the house, he explicitly receives the rent in cash,
while if he lives in the house, he effectively pays himself. Implicit or not, it is still
income, and under a Haig-Simons income tax, it should be taxed.

86

Part 1 Getting Started

9.

a.

The supply curve is given by S = -100 + 200wn. The gross wage is w = 10, and
the net wage is wn = (1-t)w = (1-t)10. The difference, then, between the gross and
net wage for any tax rate is w - wn = 10t. This is the tax collected per hour of
work.
The tax revenue for any given hours of work is then the product of the tax
collected per hour of work and the labor supply curve:
tax revenue

= 10t*(-100+200(1-t)10)
= -1,000t + 20,000t -20,000t2
= 19,000t - 20,000t2

The tax rate t = 0.7 is beyond the revenue maximizing point (this can be shown by
computing tax revenue for a slightly lower tax rate, like t=0.69.
b.

Taking the derivative:


dTax Revenue/dt=0
yields 19,000-40,000t=0, or
t = (19,000/40,000), or
t = 0.475 as the revenue maximizing tax rate.

87

Chapter 1 - Introduction

Chapter 19 The Corporation Tax


1.

A corporation may use retained earnings to increase dividends, but shareholders pay
additional income taxes as a result. Even though the franchises werent particularly
profitable, it may have been in the shareholders best interest to purchase them instead of
paying additional dividends.

2.

a.

The real value of depreciation allowances, of equation (19.1), falls.

b.

When falls, the user cost of capital increases.

c.

Index appreciation allowances.

3.

If the $20 million is expensed, the firm gets a deduction of $20 million in the current
year. If the $20 million is depreciated, the deductions are spread over time (in a way that
depends on the specifics of the depreciation schedule). The present value of the future
flow of deductions is less than $20 million. Because the package design will yield
benefits that extend over a period of time, it would seem sensible to view it as a capital
expenditure. If so, depreciation is appropriate, and the IRS was right.

4.

The user cost of capital, C, in Equation 19.4 is:


C = (r + )/[(1 - )x(1 t)]
Where t is the individual tax rate on dividend income. Suppose Lee Enterprises can lend
their money out and receive an after-tax rate of return of 10 percent. Assume that they
could also buy a new printing press that would experience economic depreciation of 2
percent annually. Ignoring taxes, the printing press would have to generate a 12 percent
return to cover depreciation. If the corporate tax rate is 35 percent and the marginal rate
on dividends is 20 percent, the printing press would have to earn a before-tax return of
23.07 percent to give Lee Enterprises the same after-tax return as lending money at 10
percent. Reducing the marginal rate on dividends lowers the necessary rate from 23.07
percent to 21.7 percent, therefore making it more likely that the purchase of a new
printing press would be a profitable investment. If Lee Enterprises did not immediately
buy more presses, this does not prove that the lower tax on dividends had no effect, but
does imply that reducing the user cost from 23.07 percent to 21.7 percent was not enough
to justify this particular investment.

5.

This statement assumes that the corporate tax is equivalent to an income tax. Table 14.2
shows that a proportional tax on both capital and labor is equivalent to an income tax.
Thus, the statement assumes that the corporate tax is a proportional tax on both capital
and labor.

88

Part 1 Getting Started

6.

A retroactive rebate of the alternative minimum tax for corporations would simply be a
lump sum transfer. Thus, according to neoclassical theory, such a rebate would not have
an effect on investment, because it does not affect the user cost of capital. The user cost
of capital depends on current individual and corporate tax rates, after-tax rates of return
in the capital market, economic depreciation, depreciation allowances, and investment tax
credits. None of these is affected by the AMT rebate described in the text. Moreover,
because the firms involved in the AMT rebate were very large, it is hard to imagine that
the rebate would relax liquidity constraints either.

7.

ONeills statement that, as chief executive of Alcoa, he never made an investment


decision based on the tax code, is problematic for the shareholders of Alcoa. It makes
no sense to ignore tax incentives when making business decisions; that is, after-tax
returns are what matter. ONeills lack of tax sophistication likely lowered the value of
Alcoa relative to what it would have been had he taken account of the tax system.

8.

The MIPS financial instrument, which could interchangeably be called debt or equity,
would be attractive to a corporation because firms would want tax authorities to view the
instrument as debt because the interest paid is tax deductible. On the other hand, firms
want potential investors to view the instrument as equity, because more debt makes the
firm a riskier investment. Although the tax law might be forced to view this MIPS
instrument as debt, there is no reason why investors in the market (or credit rating
agencies) would then view it as equity, however. In principle, investors and credit
agencies should be able to see through such accounting gimmicks, though in practice, the
accounting scandals showed that this was not the case.

9.
The user cost of capital (ignoring depreciation allowances and investment tax
credits) is given by equation (17.4) in the textbook, C=(r+)/[(1-)(1-t)], where r=after tax rate of
return in the capital market, =economic depreciation, =corporate tax rate, and t=individual tax
rate. Substituting the numbers from the problem into the formula, gives the user cost:
C=(.08+.01)/[(.65)*(.7)]=.1978. Since the projects return, 30%, is higher than this user cost of
19.8%, the company does invest in the project

89

Chapter 1 - Introduction

Chapter 20 Deficit Finance


1.

a.

The government borrowing to finance a Memorial Day parade increases the


national debt. In designing an accounting system for the government, the
borrowing in this case should, in fact, increase the national debt.

b.

The sale of the Statue of Liberty to private entrepreneurs would decrease the
national debt under current measurement. In the discussion on capital spending,
the exercise here is similar to the sale of nondefense federal buildings in 2002. In
designing an accounting system, this transaction is simply an exchange of assets
and should have no effect on the debt, rather than decreasing the debt. The
current system ignores tangible assets.

c.

The law promising free (future) medical care to children under five affects future
spending, not current spending. As such, it does not affect the current
measurement of the debt. This is similar to the discussion of the implicit
legislative promises about Social Security. In designing an accounting system,
the present value of the entitlement should be counted as a current expense, so the
debt should increase. The current system ignores implicit obligations.

d.

The $100 tax would reduce the size of the national debt. The implicit promise to
pay Lynne back $105 next year does not increase the size of the debt, assuming
this is similar to the implicit promise to pay Social Security in the future. In
designing an accounting system, again, this implicit promise should be counted.
Assuming the present discounted value of the of the $105 paid back next year
equals the $100 tax this year, then the impact on the debt should be zero, rather
than to decrease it.

e.

The $100 bond would increase the size of the national debt. The present value of
these payments is the amount by which the bond contributes to the debt. In
designing an accounting system for the government, the borrowing in this case
should, in fact, increase the national debt.

2.

Germanys government owns tangible assets, including gold. Selling the gold might give
the appearance of temporarily reducing the current year deficit, but is not a sensible longterm strategy.

3.

The arrival of surpluses in the late 1990s, and the subsequent spending spree, are
consistent with Milton Friedmans view of deficits and government spending. His view
is that, What is predetermined is not spending but the politically tolerable deficits.
Since the deficit is fixed, increases in revenue lead to one-to-one increases in spending.

4.

If the elasticity is zero, then taxing labor markets creates no distortion. But in the
presence of taxes on capital income, crowding out in the capital market will generate an
excess burden. Therefore, use tax finance.

90

Part 1 Getting Started

5.

Whether or not the burden of the debt is borne by future generations is controversial.
One view is that an internal debt creates no net burden for future generations because it is
simply an intragenerational transfer. However, in an overlapping generations model, debt
finance can produce a real burden on future generations. The burden of the debt also
depends on whether debt finance crowds out private investment. If it does, future
generations have a smaller capital stock and, hence, lower real incomes, all other things
equal. In a Ricardian model, voluntary transfers across generations undo the effects of
debt policy, so crowding out does not occur.

6.

The benefits-received principle, which states that the beneficiaries of a particular


government spending program should pay for it, suggests that deficit finance is
appropriate for war if the benefits are received by future generations. An efficiency
standpoint would say that debt is appropriate if the expenditure is temporary, and there
are not major pre-existing distortions in capital markets.

91

Chapter 1 - Introduction

Chapter 21 Fundamental Tax Reform: Taxes on Consumption and Wealth


1.

a.

The income tax is 50 percent, so Zach pays 50%*$10,000 = $5,000 in income


taxes in the first period. In the second period, he earns $500 in interest (10% of
savings = 10%*$5,000 = $500), so he pays taxes on interest of 50%*$500 = $250.
The present value of Zachs lifetime tax payments equals $5,000 + [$250/(1.1)] =
$5,227.27.

b.

In the second period, Zach has savings and interest equal to $5,500. He can
consume $3,667 in period 2 and must then pay 50%*$3,667 = $1,833.50 in
consumption taxes. The present value of Zachs lifetime tax payments is then
equal to $5,000 + [$1,833.50/(1.1)] = $6,667.
These calculations demonstrate the transitional problem in moving to a
consumption tax because Zach had to pay high taxes during period 1 when he
earned most of his income, and then had to pay high taxes during period 2 when
he did his consuming.

2.

The burden of the estate tax includes the resources used in estate planning and the effects
of estate planning. Many families may alter their behavior in reaction to the estate tax
and, if this results in less efficiency, the estate tax creates an excess burden that is not
reflected by the number of taxable estates or the amount of tax revenue collected.

3.

There is a fundamental confusion here. There is no reason to assume that the incidence
of a general consumption tax (a VAT) will be the same as the incidence of a partial factor
tax (corporate income tax).

4.

a.

For a fan giving a million-dollar ball to McGwire or Sosa, there would be a federal
gift tax liability. Depending on the fan's circumstances, it could reach $150,000 or
more. The person receiving the gift owes no tax.

b.

If the fan keeps the ball, the fan would owe no tax now. But the ball would
become part of his or her estate, taxable after death under the estate tax.

c.

The fan can avoid tax entirely by giving the ball to a charity, since he could
entirely deduct the value of the ball from his taxable income. The charity could
sell the ball; the proceeds from the sale would not be taxed.

d.

If the fan sells the ball, the fan owes tax on the net proceeds, just as the seller of
any property would. The transaction would put the fan in the highest tax bracket,
so that the marginal tax rate on the proceeds would be 39.6 percent.

e.

If the fan holds onto the ball for a year, it becomes a long-term capital asset,
subject to the maximum capital-gains tax rate of 28 percent. Unless the fan thinks
that there is going to be a substantial drop in the market value of the ball, he or
she should hold onto it for a year.

92

Part 1 Getting Started

5.

a.

The expression What you earn is what you keep is false, because a consumption
tax is equivalent to a tax on wages. The two are related by the expression
(1+)=1/(1-t), where =consumption tax rate and t=income tax rate.

b.

The expression, Investment and savings would soar may be true. A


consumption tax raises the return to saving, but because of the conflict between
income and substitution effects, one cannot know whether or not this will increase
saving. Figures 18.9 and 18.10 in the textbook illustrate these possibilities.

c.

The statement that There is no evading the Fairtax is false. Evasion can be a
major problem with retail sales taxes, especially at high rates.

6.

In the simplest possible case, the budget constraint is pC = wH, where p is the price of
consumption, C is units of consumption, w is the wage rate, and H is hours of work.
With an income tax, pC=(1-t)wH, where t=income tax rate. With a consumption tax,
(1+)pC=wH, where =consumption tax rate. Thus, for any income tax rate t, we can
find a consumption tax rate, , that is equivalent by solving the expression: (1+)=1/(1-t).

7.

a.

We can conclude that an income tax generates an excess burden if it creates a tax
wedge between the amount a borrower pays and the amount a lender receives.
With a 25% income tax and an interest rate of 8%, lenders receive (1 t)r = 6%.
Since interest paid is tax deductible, borrowers pay (1 t)r = 6%. Therefore,
there is no tax wedge and no excess burden.

b.

If interest payments are not tax deductible, then borrowers pay 8%, while lenders
receive 6% after taxes. Since there is a wedge between the two rates, the income
tax creates an excess burden in this case.

c.

If the income tax rate is t = 0.25, then (1+) = 1/(1-0.25) = 4/3, so the equivalent
consumption tax is = 1/3. A consumption tax leaves unchanged the market rate
of return because the receipt of interest income by itself does not create a tax
liability. If interest payments are not tax deductible, there is no wedge between
the rate lenders receive and the rate borrowers pay, so there is no excess burden.

d.

If interest payments are tax deductible, then there is a wedge between the rate
lenders receive and the rate borrowers pay, so the tax creates an excess burden.
With a consumption tax rate of 1/3, borrowing $1 and paying 8% interest causes
the tax liability to fall and the after-tax interest rate borrowers must pay is (1 t)r
= (2/3)0.08 = 5.36%. In this case, the wedge between the rate lenders receive
(8%) and the rate borrowers pay (5.36%) is even larger than for a 25% income tax
when interest payments were not tax deductible, so the excess burden is larger.
Note that there is an excess burden associated with an income tax only when
interest payments are not tax deductible, while there is an excess burden
associated with a consumption tax only when interest payments are tax
deductible.

93

Chapter 1 - Introduction

8.

Under an income tax, Amy's burden is $1,000*t in the first period, and .08($800)t in the
second period (e.g., her investment income is taxed). Shirley's burden is identical in the
first period, $1,000*t, but is lower in the second period, equal to .08($700)t. This is
because Shirley consumed more in the first period and saved less. Thus, Amy has a
higher lifetime tax burden because she has higher investment income. Under a
proportional consumption tax, Amy and Shirley have the same lifetime tax burden,
$1,000*, where is the consumption tax rate.

94

Part 1 Getting Started

Chapter 22 Public Finance in a Federal System


1.

If there are inter-jurisdictional externalities, then gun control is a federal issue. For
example, if lax gun control in one state leads to more crime in another state, there are
inter-jurisdictional externalities.

2.

Superficially, it seems a violation of horizontal equity for two people with identical
properties to pay different taxes on them. However, the phenomenon of capitalization
requires that we distinguish carefully between the owners at the time the tax is levied and
the current owners. A property with an unduly high tax rate will sell for a lower price,
other things being the same. Thus, a high tax rate does not necessarily make an
individual who buys the property after the tax is imposed worse off. Indeed, equalizing
assessment ratios could generate a whole new set of horizontal inequities.

3.

95

Chapter 1 - Introduction

c.

4.

Virtually all studies conclude that a dollar received by a community in the form of a grant
results in greater public spending than a dollar increase in community income. This
phenomenon has been dubbed the flypaper effect, because the money seems to stick in
the sector where it initially hits.

5.

The figure looks essentially like Figure 22.6 (without segment JH). What actually
happens to spending on education depends on the income elasticity. The government
need not increase spending on education by the full amount of lottery money collected
because the rest of the state revenue is fungible. Thus, if previously 20 percent of general
state revenue had been spent on education, after the lottery is implemented, perhaps only
17 percent of general state revenue is spent on education.

96

Part 1 Getting Started

6.

In the figure below, the (constant) marginal cost of hiring a firefighter is C. The demands
for the two communities are D1 and D2. Suppose that initially the quantity is set at Q0.
After decentralization, each community hires firefighters up to the point where the
marginal benefit equals marginal cost, i.e., where their respective demand curves
intersect C. This is at Q1 for community 1 and Q2 for community 2. Community 1 gains
abc. Community 2 gains dbe. Community 1 gains more because its demand curve is
more inelastic.

7.

The user-fee view of property taxes regards property taxes as payment for local public
services. The statement its presence would raise property values and the extra tax
revenues would easily repay the construction costs reflects this view -- that people pay
for the recreational services made available by the part with their property taxes. The
statement is not consistent with the traditional view or the new view, both of which
ignore the local services aspect.

8.

Originally, the effective state price of $1 spending on welfare recipients was $0.50 with a
one-for-one federal match rate. If the federal match rate changes to two-for-one, the
effective state prices of $1 spending falls to $0.33, or a 34 percent change in the price.
Using Baickers (2001) elasticity estimate of 0.38, a 34 percent change in price should
increase state spending by 12.92% (=0.38*34%).

97

Chapter 1 - Introduction

98

Potrebbero piacerti anche