Sei sulla pagina 1di 31

Isolated Capital Cities, Accountability and Corruption: Evidence

from US States

The Harvard community has made this article openly available.


Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters.

Citation

Campante, Filipe R., and Quoc-Anh Do. 2014. Isolated Capital


Cities, Accountability and Corruption: Evidence from US States.
American Economic Review 104(8): 2456-81.

Published Version

doi:10.1257/aer.104.8.2456

Accessed

May 29, 2015 4:18:30 PM EDT

Citable Link

http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:8830780

Terms of Use

This article was downloaded from Harvard University's DASH


repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions
applicable to Open Access Policy Articles, as set forth at
http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:dash.current.terms-ofuse#OAP

(Article begins on next page)

Isolated Capital Cities, Accountability, and Corruption:


Evidence from US States
By Filipe R. Campante and Quoc-Anh Do
We show that isolated capital cities are robustly associated with
greater levels of corruption across US states, in line with the view
that this isolation reduces accountability. We then provide direct evidence that the spatial distribution of population relative to
the capital affects different accountability mechanisms: newspapers
cover state politics more when readers are closer to the capital,
voters who live far from the capital are less knowledgeable and interested in state politics, and they turn out less in state elections.
We also find that isolated capitals are associated with more money
in state-level campaigns, and worse public good provision.
JEL: D72, D73, L82, R12, R23, R50
Corruption is widely seen as a major problem, in developing and developed
countries alike, and much has been written on its determinants and correlates.
This paper pursues the first systematic investigation of a hitherto underappreciated element in this story: the spatial distribution of the population in a given
polity of interest, relative to the seat of political power.
This spatial distribution might affect the incentives and opportunities for public
officials to misuse their office for private gain. In particular, it may affect the
degree of accountability, as has long been noted in the particular context of US
state politics. For instance, Wilsons (1966) seminal contribution argued that
state-level politics was particularly prone to corruption because state capitals
are often far from the major metropolitan centers, and thus face a lower level
of scrutiny by citizens and by the media: these isolated capitals have small-city
newspapers, few (and weak) civic associations, and relatively few attentive citizens
Campante: Harvard Kennedy School, 79 JFK St Cambridge, MA 02138 and NBER (email: filipe campante@harvard.edu). Do: Department of Economics and LIEPP, Sciences Po Paris, 28 rue des
Saints-P`
eres 75007 Paris, France (email: quocanh.do@sciences-po.org). We are grateful to three anonymous referees for many helpful suggestions. We also thank Alberto Alesina, Jim Alt, Dave Bakke,
Francesco Caselli, Davin Chor, Thomas Cole, Alan Ehrenhalt, Claudio Ferraz, Jeff Frieden, Ed Glaeser,
Josh Goodman, Rema Hanna, David Lauter, David Luberoff, Andrei Shleifer, Rodrigo Soares, Enrico
Spolaore, Ernesto Stein, David Yanagizawa-Drott, and Katia Zhuravskaya for useful conversations, as
well as numerous seminar participants. Ed Glaeser, Sue Long, Kieu-Trang Nguyen, Nguyen Phu Binh,
Raven Saks, Kristina Tobio, and especially C. Scott Walker gave us invaluable help with the data collection, and Siaw Kiat Hau provided excellent research assistance. Access to TRAC data used in this
research was secured as a result of our appointment as TRAC Fellows at the Transactional Records
Access Clearinghouse (TRAC) at Syracuse University. Campante thanks the Taubman Center for State
and Local Government for generous financial support, and the Economics Department at PUC-Rio for
its outstanding hospitality for much of the period of work on this research. Do thanks Singapore Management University and its Lee Foundation Research Award for generous support over an important
portion of the work on this research. The authors declare that they have no relevant or material financial
interests that relate to the research described in this paper.

THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

MONTH YEAR

with high and vocal standards of public morality. (p. 596). As a result, it is no
accident that state officials in Annapolis, Jefferson City, Trenton, and Springfield
have national reputations for political corruption. (Maxwell and Winters 2005,
p. 3)
Our first contribution is to establish a basic stylized fact that is very much in
line with this accountability view: isolated US state capital cities are associated
with higher levels of corruption. A simple depiction of that can be seen in Figure 1,
where our baseline measure of corruption is plotted against our baseline measure
of the isolation of a states capital city. We show that this connection is very
robust, despite the inherently small sample size, and consistently meaningful from
a quantitative perspective.
[FIGURE 1 HERE]
Quite importantly, we are also able to address the issue of endogeneity, which
is evidently present since the location of the capital city is an institutional choice,
and since it might itself affect the distribution of population. Fortunately, the
historical record documenting the designation of state capitals gives us a plausible
source of exogenous variation: the location of the geographical centroid of each
state. We develop instrumental variables based on that location, and find that the
effect of an isolated capital city on corruption is again significant when estimated
using this strategy.
Our second contribution is to provide direct evidence that isolated capital cities
are associated with lower accountability. We investigate two different realms of
accountability, certainly among the most important: the roles of the media and
of the electoral process. We find that they are indeed affected by the spatial
distribution of population.
When it comes to the media, we show that newspapers give more coverage to
state politics when their readership is more concentrated around the state capital
city. This is matched by individual-level patterns: individuals who live farther
from the state capital are less informed and display less interest in state politics,
but not in politics in general.
When it comes to elections, we find that voter turnout in state elections is
greater in counties that are closer to the state capital. In addition, we also show
that isolated capital cities are associated with a greater role for money in statelevel elections, as measured by campaign contributions, and that, in states with
a relatively isolated capital, firms and individuals who are closer to it contribute
disproportionately more. These are novel empirical regularities, all of which likely
further distort accountability.
Finally, we provide some evidence on whether this pattern of low accountability affects the ultimate provision of public goods: states with isolated capital
cities also seem to spend relatively less, and get worse outcomes, on things like
education, public welfare, and health care. This suggests that low accountability
and corruption induced by isolation do have an impact in terms of government
performance and priorities.

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE

ISOLATED CAPITAL CITIES AND CORRUPTION

The substantial quantitative literature looking at corruption across US states


(e.g. Meier and Holbrook 1992, Fisman and Gatti 2002, Alt and Lassen 2003,
Glaeser and Saks 2006), has pointed at factors ranging from education to historical and cultural factors to the degree of openness of a states political system, but
it has essentially not tested the idea that the isolation of the capital city is related to corruption.1 We also relate to the literature on media and accountability,
particularly in the US, such as Snyder and Stromberg (2010), and Lim, Snyder,
and Stromberg (2012). Our evidence is very much consistent with their finding that a disconnect between media markets and political jurisdictions weakens
accountability.
Most directly, our paper belongs in the intersection between urban economics
and economic geography, on one side, and political economy such as Ades and
Glaeser (1995), Davis and Henderson (2003), Campante and Do (2010), Galiani
and Kim (2011), and Campante, Do, and Guimaraes (2012). A recent literature
in political science has also dealt with the political implications of spatial distributions, as surveyed for instance by Rodden (2010). We add the idea that some
places (e.g. capital cities) are distinctive.
The paper is organized as follows: Section I presents the data, Section II discusses the empirical strategy to deal with endogeneity issues, Section III showcases
the results, and Section IV discusses them. Section V concludes.
I.

Data

We start by describing our data, focusing on the main variables of interest. Our
choices for instrumental variables will be discussed later, within the context of
our empirical strategy. All variables (including control variables), sources, and
descriptive statistics are documented in the Online Appendix.
A.

Isolation of the Capital

We get information on the spatial distribution of population for the 48 continental states with county-level data from the US Census, for all Census years
between 1920 and 2000. We attribute the location of each countys population
to the geographical position of the centroid of the county, and then calculate its
distance to the State House or Assembly.2 From that we compute measures of
1 Some studies have found that population size is positively correlated with corruption (Meier and
Holbrook 1992, Maxwell and Winters 2005), although this relationship is not especially robust (Meier
and Schlesinger 2002, Glaeser and Saks 2006). As for the spatial distribution of population, most effort
has been devoted to looking at urbanization, under the assumption that corruption thrives in cities (Alt
and Lassen 2003). There is some evidence for that assertion, but not robust either (Glaeser and Saks
2006).
2 While finer geographical subdivisions such as Census tract and block are available, the focus on
counties enables us to compute the measures for the years before the population data became consistently
available at those more detailed levels for the entire US, in 1980. We start in 1920 because that is when
detailed county data first becomes available. Alaska and Hawaii are left out as the data for them do not
go as far back in time.

THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

MONTH YEAR

isolation averaged over time, both because the effects of changes in the distribution of population would likely be felt over a relatively long period, and because,
while autocorrelation turns out to be very high, there is nontrivial variation over
time in a number of states.3
Our preferred measure of isolation is the average of the log of the distance of the
states population to the capital city, AvgLogDistance for shorthand. Campante
and Do (2010) show that this measure (uniquely) has a number of desirable properties. (See details and a brief discussion of properties in the Online Appendix.)
It is also rather easy to interpret. To fix ideas, consider an intuitive measure
of isolation of a states capital, namely the distance between the capital and that
states largest city. AvgLogDistance takes this intuition and applies it in more
comprehensive and systematic fashion. First, instead of looking at the largest
city only, it takes into account the entire state without arbitrarily discarding
information. Second, it does so by weighing each place according to its population.
Last but not least, the log transformation ensures that the measure is unbiased
with respect to the measurement error introduced by not having the exact location
of individuals, and thus having to approximate the actual spatial distribution
(Campante and Do 2010).
To further facilitate interpretation, we normalize the measure so that zero represents a situation of minimum isolation, in which all individuals live arbitrarily
close to the State House. Conversely, we set at one the situation where the capital
is maximally isolated, with all individuals living as far from it as possible in the
context of interest.
Given this basic framework, different choices can yield specific versions that
highlight distinct aspects of isolation. We choose to adopt a relatively agnostic
view and experiment with a few options.
The first choice has to do with normalization and what it means to have maximal isolation. To fix ideas, consider that the salience of what happens in the state
capital, for a given citizen, decreases with her distance from it. One possibility
is that salience falls at the same rate across different states, so that distances are
weighted in the same way in states large and small. In this case, we set maximum
isolation as benchmarked by the highest possible level across all states: a measure
of one would correspond to a situation where the entire population of the state is
as far from its capital as it is possible to be far from Austin while remaining in
Texas. We denote this unadjusted measure by AvgLogDistancenot .
Another possibility is that this salience falls to zero beyond the states borders.
In this case, we would want to set the level of maximum isolation in each state
to be a situation where the entire population lives as far from the capital as it
3 We will use different averages depending on the relevant period of analysis but, quite importantly,
our results are essentially unaltered if we use time-specific measures instead (see Online Appendix). Also
importantly, we will leave aside the time variation in our estimation, because the very high autocorrelation
in the isolation measures and the fluctuations over time in the baseline corruption variable, as we will
note, make that variation very noisy, entailing severe econometric problems with standard methods and
thus rendering its use unwarranted.

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE

ISOLATED CAPITAL CITIES AND CORRUPTION

is possible to be in that specific state. This would correspond to an adjusted


version of our measure, AvgLogDistanceadj , which automatically adjusts for the
size of each state.
An important point coming out of this distinction is that AvgLogDistancenot
is in practice highly correlated with the geographical size of the state. At the
same time, we want to distinguish the impact of the distribution of population
from a possible unrelated correlation with geographical size per se. We will do
that by controling for the size and shape of each state in all AvgLogDistancenot
specifications, by including (the log of) the states area and (the log of) the
maximum distance from county centroids to state capital (i.e. the measure that
benchmarks AvgLogDistanceadj ). This will allow us to consider the hypothetical
of comparing states with similar sizes but different degrees of isolation, which
seems to be the relevant experiment.
A second choice has to do with functional form. While AvgLogDistance has the
notable advantage of unbiasedness, its concavity entails a view of accountability
that gives disproportional weight to citizens living relatively close to the capital.
For instance, in the limit, one could imagine a model in which all that matters is
the population that lives within a certain range of the capital; concavity gives us
a way to approximate this without attributing arbitrary limits. An alternative
view would have individual weights decline linearly with distance, and to allow
for this possibility we will consider AvgDistance, without the log transformation,
as a robustness check.4
We will also consider a couple of well-known (inverse) measures of isolation: the
share of population living in the state capital (as of 2010), CapitalShare, and a
dummy for whether the capital is the largest city in the state, CapitalLargest.
These are very coarse and rather unsatisfactory measures, relying on arbitrary
definitions of what counts as the capital city and discarding all the spatial information beyond those arbitrary limits, but we will check them for the sake of
completeness.
B.

Corruption

Our baseline measure of corruption across US states is the oft-used number of


federal convictions for corruption-related crime (relative to the size of the population). (A detailed description of this measure can be found in Glaeser and Saks
(2006).) These refer to cases, typically prosecuted by US Attorneys all over the
country, against public officials and others involved in public corruption, as surveyed and compiled by the Public Integrity Section (PIS) at the US Department of
Justice in their Report to Congress. Federal authorities can claim jurisdiction,
for instance, over corruption-related crime that affects interstate commerce, or
in entities that receive more than $10,000 in federal funds which yields them
4 This measure has all of the other main properties of AvgLogDistance, as noted in the Online
Appendix. The correlation between the two in our sample is around 0.8.

THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

MONTH YEAR

a lot of leeway in pursuing cases related to state and local governments. The
resulting measure has the substantial advantage of being relatively objective, and
focusing on federal convictions alleviates concerns over the differences in resources
and political bias that might affect the variation across states.5
Because the measure is very noisy in terms of its year-on-year fluctuations, we
focus attention on the average number of convictions, for the period 1976-2002.
We use this sample of years to keep comparability with the existing literature
(e.g. Glaeser and Saks 2006, Alt and Lassen 2008).
The baseline measure aggregates state-, federal-, and local-level officials, plus
others involved. This adds noise to the extent that the accountability logic
we focus on pertains most directly to state governments. However, it adds much
relevant information, both because state officials are only a fraction of those
implicated in corruption at the level of state politics, and because one would
expect that a culture of corruption arising at that level would spill over to other
domains of government in the state.6 Still, we consider as an alternative approach
a measure restricted to state-level officials. These are not discriminated on a stateby-state basis in the PIS Report, but some of the information can be recovered
from the Transactional Records Access Clearinghouse (TRACfed) at Syracuse
University, a database compiling information about the federal government. We
have gathered yearly data for each individual state and (fiscal) year between 1986
and 2011, and averaged them over the entire available period.7 We also normalize
the measure, using the number of state government employees (as of 1980).
For the sake of robustness, we will also look at different approaches to measuring
corruption. First, we follow Saiz and Simonsohn (2013) in building a measure
from an online search, using the Exalead tool, for the term corruption close to
the name of each state (performed in 2009).8 Lastly, we consider additionally
(in the Online Appendix) the measure of corruption perceptions in state politics
introduced by Boylan and Long (2002), based on a set of questions posed to
reporters covering State Houses, and the TRACFed-based measure of convictions
of local officials. The former is less objective, but gives us another measure of
state-level corruption; the latter provides a measure of spillovers across different
levels of government.9
5 Still, there obviously is variation related to the functioning of local District Attorney (DA) offices
and federal agencies, introducing measurement error in the variable (Alt and Lassen 2012, Gordon 2009).
6 As an illustration of the former, consider the case involving former Alabama governor Don Siegelman,
who was convicted of corruption charges in 2006. As can be gleaned from the 2006 PIS Report, four
people were convicted in addition to the governor, in relation to the same episode, and none of them
were state officials.
7 This restricted measure is much noisier, not the least because, since there are relatively few statelevel officials compared to other levels, their share in aggregate convictions is relatively small typically
about 10% overall, as compiled in the PIS Report. The average number of convictions per state-year
in the overall measure is about 14, whereas the number for the restricted measure constructed from
TRACfed is just under one.
8 The choice of Exalead is due to its being one of the few engines offering reliable proximity searches
(Saiz and Simonsohn 2013, p.138). They argue that this measure performs well in reproducing the
standard stylized facts found by the literature on corruption, both at the state and country levels.
9 These measures are typically significantly correlated with one another (see Online Appendix). In

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE

ISOLATED CAPITAL CITIES AND CORRUPTION

C.

Placebo Variables

We consider other features of the spatial distribution of population, beyond the


role of the capital city, by looking at the isolation of the states largest city (again
measured by AvgLogDistance). We also check for outcome variables related to
crime and federal prosecutorial efforts, apart from corruption. Here we resort to
a measure of criminal cases brought by prosecutors to federal courts in each state
(as of 2011) in relation to drug offenses, which are by far the most numerous type
among the federal cases.
D.

Accountability

Newspaper Coverage. When it comes to the media as a source of accountability, we focus on state-level political coverage by newspapers, since they tend
to provide far greater coverage of state politics in the US than competing media
such as TV (e.g. Vinson 2003, Druckmann 2005).
We look at newspapers whose print edition content is available online and
searchable at the website NewsLibrary.com covering nearly four thousand
outlets all over the US. We search for the names of each states then-current governors as well as, alternatively, for terms such as state government, state
budget, or state elections, where state refers to the name of each state.10
We only consider mentions to the state in which each newspaper is based.11
We also compute a state-level measure of political coverage. We take the first
principal component of the four search terms for each newspaper (adjusted by
size), and perform a weighted sum of this measure over all newspapers.12 We use
two alternative sets of weights: the circulation of each newspaper in the state,
which for its simplicity is our preferred option, and that circulation weighted
by its geographical concentration, as captured by the ReaderConcentr variable
described below. The latter would put more weight on circulation closer to the
capital, allowing for the possibility that newspapers whose audience is more concentrated around the capital city might have a disproportionate effect on the
behavior of state politicians.
particular, the baseline measure of federal convictions is highly correlated with the measure restricted to
state officials (just under 0.6), and somewhat less so with the measure restricted to local officials (about
0.4). The two restricted measures are significantly correlated with each other (0.33), consistent with
the existence of spillovers. The Exalead measure has a more tenuous correlation with the baseline (0.25,
significant at the 10% level).
10 Similar procedures using NewsLibrary.com have been used, for instance, by Snyder and Stromberg
(2010) and Lim, Snyder, and Stromberg (2012). We look for terms that are not necessarily related to
corruption scandals though it can certainly be the case (and actually is, for some states) that governors
are involved in a few of those to guard against reverse causality namely, the possibility that there is
a lot of media coverage because of the existence of such scandals.
11 We also run a search for a neutral term (Monday), following Gentzkow, Glaeser, and Goldin
(2005), to control for newspaper size.
12 This aggregate measure introduces a source of measurement error, due to the fact that the ABC and
NewsLibrary.com data do not cover the totality of a states newspaper industry. There is no particular
reason to believe that this measurement error is correlated with the underlying value of the variable we
want to measure.

THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

MONTH YEAR

Concentration of Readership around the Capital. We use circulation data


broken down by county, provided by the Audit Bureau of Circulations (ABC). We
compute the AvgLogDistance to the capital analogously to what we described before, only using newspaper readership instead of population.13 We then define the
measure of readership concentration, ReaderConcentr, as 1 AvgLogDistance:
a larger measure of ReaderConcentr implies that a given newspapers audience
is more concentrated around its home states capital. The number of newspapers
with ABC data available is considerably smaller than what NewsLibrary.com covers, so we end up with a total of 436 newspapers in our sample. We leave aside
the circulation of a newspaper outside of its home state, since we are focusing on
coverage of home-state politics.
Citizens Information. We use data from the American National Election
Studies (ANES). In the 1998 pre-election survey, a random sample of voting-age
citizens were interviewed, in California, Georgia, and Illinois. As usual for the
ANES up until 2000, the 1998 survey includes information about the county of
each interview, which we use to compute distance (from the county centroid) to
the state capital. Most interestingly and uniquely, it asks questions that directly
measure knowledge of state politics and interest in news coverage related to state
politics.
We code a dummy for Knowledge that captures whether the individual respondents are able to provide the correct name of at least one candidate in the upcoming gubernatorial elections. We also code a dummy for Interest in state political
news: whether the respondent reports to care about newspaper articles about the
gubernatorial campaign, conditional on her reading newspapers, so as to focus on
potential consumers of print media. Finally, we create a GeneralInterest dummy
based on whether respondents follow public affairs in general , unconstrained to
the state level.
Voter Turnout. We look at turnout in all gubernatorial elections between
1990 and 2012, at the county level, again attributing for simplicity the countys
population to its centroid, and computing the distance between each countys
centroid and the state capital.
Money in State Politics. We look at data on total contributions to electoral
campaigns, comprising all types of state-level office and aggregated at the state
level. We focus on the period 2001-2010, as the state coverage of the data for
previous electoral cycles is somewhat inconsistent. In addition to total contributions, we also focus on county-level contributions coming from a specific industry,
namely real estate, which we choose because it tends not to be spatially concentrated, and because it is one of the industries that contributes the most to
state-level campaigns.14 This will let us look into whether distance from the
13 We use the unadjusted version of AvgLogDistance, but normalization is immaterial here, because
our estimation will use state fixed effects.
14 Out of the classification provided by our source, the National Institute on Money in State Politics,
real estate falls behind only public sector unions and lawyers/lobbyists, which tend to be more naturally
concentrated.

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE

ISOLATED CAPITAL CITIES AND CORRUPTION

capital affects contribution patterns within states.


E.

Public Good Provision

We start with data on the pattern of expenditures by US states (in 2009). Most
of state government expenditures that might be directly ascribed to public good
provision fall under four categories: Education, Public Welfare, Health,
and Hospitals. We take the share of these categories in total spending as
a proxy for resources devoted to public good provision. We also compute the
share devoted to Government Administration, Interest on General Debt, and
Other as a proxy for what is not directly related to public good provision.
These measures do not speak to how effectively resources are spent, so we check
proxies for the ultimate provision of public goods. These are affected by many
factors other than state-level policy, but should still provide useful information.
We use three measures that capture aspects of what should be affected by the type
of public good expenditure we have defined: the Smartest State index (Morgan
Quitno Corporation 2005), which aggregates different measures of educational
inputs and outcomes, the percentage of the population that has health insurance,
and the log of the number of hospital beds per capita.
II.

Empirical Strategy

Our analysis sits on three pillars. First, we will look at the correlation patterns
linking isolated capital cities and corruption; on the other hand, we will look
at direct evidence on whether isolation relates to different accountability mechanisms. The third pillar is about addressing endogeneity concerns regarding those
correlation patterns, related to the facts that the location of the capital city is
an institutional decision and that it affects the spatial distribution of population.
Both of these could be correlated with omitted variables that are also associated
with corruption. For instance, corruption and the location of the capital city
could be jointly determined say, with relatively corrupt states choosing to isolate their capital cities. Alternatively, it could be the case that corruption affects
the population flows that determine how isolated the capital city will ultimately
be say, by pushing economic activity and population away from the capital. We
now turn to the empirical strategy we use to address these confounding factors.
A.

Source of Exogenous Variation

In the absence of something like a natural experiment on the location of capital


cities, a source of exogenous variation in the isolation of the capital comes from a
specific point of interest: each states centroid. Defined as the average coordinate
of the state, the centroid does not depend on the spatial distribution of population,
but only on the states geographical shape.
The first crucial point is that the centroid is an essentially arbitrary location
and should not affect any relevant outcomes in and of itself. This should be true

10

THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

MONTH YEAR

at least once the territorial limits of each state are set.15 Because of that, we
will eventually control, in all of our specifications, for the geographical size of the
state, to guard against the possibility that a correlation between omitted variables
and the expansion or rearrangement of state borders might affect the results.
The second crucial point is that there is a connection between the location of the
centroid and the location of the capital city, which is obviously a necessary condition for the variation in the former to generate meaningful variation in the latter.
As it turns out, the history of the designation of state (and federal) capitals in
the US strongly suggests exactly such a link. This is because concerns with equal
representation led to strong pressures to locate the capital in a relatively central
position, particularly as state capital cities were typically chosen at a time when
transportation and communication costs were substantial (Zagarri 1987, Shelley
1996, Engstrom, Hammond, and Scott 2013). Consistent with that, a quick inspection of any map of the US displaying all state capitals makes it immediately
apparent that many of them are actually in relatively central locations.
B.

Instrumental Variables

The key question is then how to turn this source of exogenous variation into
an instrumental variable. The natural candidate is the isolation of the centroid
in terms of population, CentroidAvgLogDistancenot . We can check that there
does seem to be a positive correlation between the isolation of the capital and the
isolation of the centroid, as illustrated by Figure 2.
[FIGURE 2 HERE]
This proposed instrument purges the direct influence of the endogenous location
of the capital, as it does not depend directly on the latter. However, it is still a
function of the distribution of population, and could thus still be contaminated
by the influence of the capital city over the distribution of population across the
state.
In order to deal directly with that second potential source of exogeneity, we
will combine the role of the centroid with a second source of exogenous variation affecting the spatial distribution of population: the spatial distribution of
economic resources. More specifically, we use spatial data on land suitability for
cultivation, aggregating data on soil and climate properties (Ramankutty et al.
2002).
The idea is that the spatial distribution of land suitability would affect that
of population, particularly in pre-industrial days, as people would be more likely
to settle relatively close to places well-suited for agriculture. The persistence in
population patterns would in turn suggest that this influence should persist as
well. We would thus expect that, in case the most suitable land is relatively far
15 State borders have been generally stable after establishment. For a history of those borders, see
Stein (2008).

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE

ISOLATED CAPITAL CITIES AND CORRUPTION

11

from the centroid, population would tend to be too and the capital city would
be more isolated, to the extent that it tends to be located close to the centroid.
Crucially, it is eminently plausible that spatial patterns in terms of climate and
soil, relative to the states centroid, would neither be meaningfully affected by
current population patterns that could be correlated with corruption, nor likely
to affect corruption through any means other than their impact on the isolation
of the capital.
We thus compute SuitCentroidAvgLogDistancenot for the 48 states in the
continental US, and use it as an alternative instrumental variable. Its main drawback is that, quite naturally, it has a more tenuous correlation with our variable
of interest, namely the isolation of the capital.
C.

Validation

It is instructive to look at the correlation between our two proposed instrumental variables and a number of predetermined variables namely variables
that cannot be affected by contemporaneous levels of corruption or by its current
covariates. We select variables that are essentially geographical in nature.16 One
would expect that, if the instruments were to vary systematically with state characteristics that might correlate with current levels of corruption, thus threatening
the exclusion restriction, this would be picked up by a few of those predetermined
variables.
Table 1 first displays the coefficients on these predetermined variables obtained
by running separate regressions without additional controls (other than the aforementioned geographical size controls). Columns (1)-(2) present the results for the
population and suitability instrument, respectively. Both are uncorrelated with
the predetermined variables, with p-values that are generally quite substantial.
Alternatively, we show in Columns (3)-(4) the results from a single specification
containing all variables. There are essentially no significant coefficients (with one
marginal exception), and the F-test for joint significance also fails to find any
connection.
[TABLE 1 HERE]
States with population or land suitability highly concentrated around the centroid thus look ex ante rather similar to those with low concentration. Interestingly, Column (5) shows this is not true for the basic measure of capital city
isolation, for which we do see statistically significant correlations.
16 We can also add a couple of historical variables measured far back in the past, as contained in the
1878 US Statistical Abstract, which have the drawback of further limiting our already small sample.
These additional results are available in the Online Appendix.

12

THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

III.
A.

MONTH YEAR

Empirical Results
A Stylized Fact

We first look at the basic correlation patterns between our baseline measures
of corruption and the isolation of capital cities, in Table 2.
[TABLE 2 HERE]
In Column (1), we see a strong positive correlation between corruption and
AvgLogDistancenot (measured as an average of the measures calculated up to
1970, i.e. before the time period for which corruption is measured), without
any controls other than geographical size.17 Column (2) then introduces a basic
set of controls, as of 1970. The coefficient of interest is highly significant, and
fairly stable in size. Columns (3) and (4) add as controls other correlates of
corruption that are established in the literature, and our preferred specification
is that of Column (3), which essentially reproduces the basic specification in
Glaeser and Saks (2006). While in Column (4) the size of the coefficient is slightly
reduced, it is robustly statistically significant at the 1% level, quite remarkably
in light of the small sample size.18 The same pattern is also present for our
first alternative measure of isolation, AvgLogDistanceadj , as shown by Columns
(5)-(8) reproducing the four specifications.19
The effect is also meaningful quantitatively. Our preferred specifications coefficient (1.03) implies that an increase of one standard deviation in the isolation of
the capital city (around 0.09, or roughly the increase experienced by Carson City,
NV between 1920 and 2000), would yield a corresponding increase in corruption
(0.10) of around 0.75 standard deviation.20
Let us now consider the robustness of our results, beyond the different specifications in Table 2. We first consider alternative measures of corruption, in Table
3. Columns (1)-(2) reproduce the main specification from our baseline results
(Columns (3) and (7) in Table 2), for the measure of corruption convictions restricted to state officials.21 They very much confirm the message from Table 2.
Even quantitatively, the results are fairly similar, and especially so when we take
into account that this is a noisier measure: an exercise along the lines of what we
17 The

Online Appendix shows that the results are still present without the controls.
results are not sensitive to outliers: they are still present when we run the regressions excluding
one Census region at a time. They also survive measures of party competition and of the breakdown of
state revenues between taxes and other sources. These can all be seen in the Online Appendix.
19 We do not include controls for geographical size, since this is built into the measure of concentration.
The results are not sensitive to that choice (see Online Appendix).
20 For the sake of comparison, Glaeser and Saks (2006) find in their sample an effect of about half of a
standard deviation of a corresponding one-standard-deviation increase in education, a variable that has
been consistently found to be (negatively) correlated with corruption (Alt and Lassen 2003, Glaeser and
Saks 2006).
21 We run weighted regressions, using yearly standard deviations of the measures of convictions for
each state over the sample period of 1986-2011, in order to adjust for the fact that the small number
of convictions entails noise in the measures. The results are essentially the same if we run unweighted
regressions instead (see Online Appendix).
18 The

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE

ISOLATED CAPITAL CITIES AND CORRUPTION

13

have done for the baseline results would yield an effect of just over 0.55 standard
deviation.22
[TABLE 3 HERE]
We then look at the alternative Exalead measure of corruption.23 Columns (3)
and (4) again mimic the main baseline specifications, and again find very similar
results. The estimated quantitative effect is now of about 0.7 standard deviation,
once again very close to the baseline.24
The next step is to check for alternative measures of the isolation of the capital
city. We find that the results are still present with both versions of AvgDistance,
adjusted and unadjusted, as shown in Columns (5) and (6). For the coarser measures, CapitalShare and CapitalLargest, we see negative coefficients in Columns
(7) and (8), consistent with the baseline results. The quantitative implications,
however, suggest in both cases a smaller effect, of about one third of a standard deviation. This is consistent with a substantial measurement error being
introduced by the use of these coarse measures.25
We then probe the results with a few placebo regressions, meant to check
whether the patterns we find in the data are actually related to the isolation of
capital cities and its conjectured link with corruption and accountability. Columns
(1)-(4) in Table 4 use the isolation of the largest city since the latter is also
the capital city in 17 out of 50 states, one might wonder whether the measure of
isolation of the capital could be in fact proxying for that. It has no independent
effect, and its inclusion does not affect the significance or size of the coefficient
on the isolation of the capital.
[TABLE 4 HERE]
From our basic hypothesis about accountability, one would not expect any
particular connection between the isolation of the capital city and the prevalence
of (or federal prosecutorial efforts in pursuing) other types of crime that are
presumably unrelated to state politics. We see in Columns (5)-(8) that indeed
there is no connection between the number of drug cases and the isolation of the
capital.26
22 A positive correlation also holds for a narrow measure restricted to convictions of local officials (see
Online Appendix). This is consistent with the idea that a culture of corruption at the state level spills
over to other levels of government within the state.
23 Since the measure of corruption is computed over a more recent period, we use here the average of
the measures of isolation up to 2000, and use the demographic control variables as of 2000 as well.
24 The regression results are also robust when we use the Boylan and Long (2002) measure of corruption
perceptions in state politics. They are also quantitatively very similar to our baseline: the estimated
coefficient implies that an increase in AvgLogDistancenot by one standard deviation is associated with
an increase in the measure of corruption perception of about 0.75 standard deviation. (See Online
Appendix.)
25 Note that we use the Exalead measure of corruption, in light of the time period for which we
have the population data at the city level. The coefficients are negative, but statistically insignificant,
when we use the baseline measure of convictions, again consistent with substantial measurement error
(see Online Appendix).
26 To check that this is not driven by outliers, we also dropped the states on the Mexico border
which tend to have a disproportionate number of drug-related cases (especially Arizona and New

14

THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

B.

MONTH YEAR

IV Results

We can now check the two-stage least-squares (2SLS) results in Table 5, starting
in Panel A with CentroidAvgLogDistance, the population-based instrument.27
We start off in Columns (1)-(2) by displaying the first-stage results for the full
specification, i.e. with the full set of controls. (The results are similar for
the other specifications.) We can see that it is indeed a significant predictor
of AvgLogDistance. The F-statistic for the excluded instrument is reasonably
high for both AvgLogDistancenot and AvgLogDistanceadj , but relatively close
to standard thresholds for weak-instrument-robust inference.28 We thus show
the p-values as given by the minimum distance version of the Anderson-Rubin
(AR) test, which is robust to weak instruments. Columns (3)-(8) then reproduce
in order, for comparisons sake, the specifications with controls from Table 2.
We see confirmed the significant positive effect of having an isolated capital on
corruption.
[TABLE 5 HERE]
Panel B in turn runs the same exercise using our second, land-suitability-based
instrumental variable, SuitCentroidAvgLogDistancenot . Unsurprisingly in light
of the inherently weaker link between it and the isolation of the capital city, the
first stage is weaker. The instrument is nevertheless still a significant predictor
of the isolation of the capital at the 5% level. Columns (3)-(8) show that we also
find a generally significant effect of the isolation of the capital city on the measure
of corruption.29
C.

Accountability and the Spatial Distribution of Population

We will now look for direct evidence that the accountability of state-level officials is affected by the spatial distribution of population. In particular, we will
consider two possible versions of this hypothesis: the role of the media and the
role of of the electoral process.
Mexico). Columns (7)-(8) show the same pattern holds in that case.
27 The adjusted measure CentroidAvgLogDistance
adj turns out to be a very weak instrument, with
a first-stage F-statistic under 3. Still, the 2SLS results are rather similar, and can be seen in the Online
Appendix.
28 Specifically, the Cragg-Donald Wald F-statistics are 10.34 and 12.52, respectively, for
AvgLogDistancenot and AvgLogDistanceadj . This lies between the 10% and 15% thresholds of the
Stock-Yogo weak instrument maximal IV size critical values (Stock and Yogo 2005), meaning that the
instrument would be considered weak if we were to limit the size of the conventional IV Wald test to at
most 0.1 above its nominal value. We take this to mean that the instrument is not obviously weak, but
in any case we choose to present the robust inference as well.
29 Quite interestingly, the coefficients are remarkably consistent with those obtained in Panel A, even
if estimated a bit less precisely. This suggests that the potential bias stemming from our second source
of endogeneity is not very important in practice. It is reassuring that the evidence for a causal impact of
the isolation of the capital city on corruption seems robust to the different sources of endogeneity, and
also in relation with the potential threat of the relative weakness of the land-suitability instrument.

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE

ISOLATED CAPITAL CITIES AND CORRUPTION

15

The Role of the Media

Newspaper-Level Evidence. The basic hypothesis we check is that a newspapers coverage of state politics is greater when its readers are on average closer
to the state capital. For this we first run regressions of our different measures of
state-level political coverage on the concentration of readership around the capital, ReaderConcentr, controlling for newspaper size, circulation and state fixed
effects. We indeed find coefficients that are generally positive and significant, as
we can see in Table 6.30
[TABLE 6 HERE]
We can also look at this question at an aggregate state level, as opposed to
that of individual newspapers. The regression evidence, in Table 7, confirms that
states with isolated capitals tend to display lower levels of media coverage of state
politics.31 The effect is rather stronger for the AvgLogDistanceadj measure, indicating that what matters most for the connection is how isolated the capital
city is, not so much in terms of absolute distances, but rather relative to the geographical size of the state.32 Similar results obtain with the measure of isolation
of the state centroid in terms of population as an instrument for the isolation of
the capital: we see a significant effect in the case of AvgLogDistanceadj , and no
effect for the case of AvgLogDistancenot (Columns (5)-(6)). That said, statistical significance is sensitive to the exclusion of the states of South Dakota and
Delaware, which calls for caution in the interpretation of the aggregate evidence.
[TABLE 7 HERE]
Individual-Level Evidence. We now look at whether individuals display lower
levels of interest and information regarding state politics when they are farther
away from the state capital. Table 8 shows the results of probit specifications, with
our survey dummy variables for Knowledge and Interest as dependent variables,
and (the log of) distance to the state capital being the main independent variable
of interest.33
30 Note that we would expect the kind of measurement error introduced by leaving aside out-of-state
circulation to lead these estimates to be biased downwards: newspapers with significant out-of-state
circulation would likely have an incentive to provide less coverage of home-state politics, and the concentration of their circulation is being overestimated in our calculation.
31 We include in our set of control variables a dummy for whether the state had an election for governor
in one of the years to which our newspaper search refers (2008 and 2009), to account for coverage possibly
reacting to the proximity of elections.
32 The results are largely the same if we exclude Rhode Island, which turns out to be a positive outlier
in the media coverage variable about five standard deviations greater than the state with the next
largest measure. This is because there is one newspaper, the Providence Journal, that far outstrips the
circulation of all other RI-based newspapers in the sample, This newspaper had a very large measure of
coverage of state politics, and is idiosyncratically driving the state-level measure.
33 For all dependent variables, we first show the specification with county-level controls only, and then
include individual-level controls. In all specifications we cluster the standard errors at the county level
and include state fixed effects, and marginal effects are reported. We also control for the surveyors
assessment of the respondents general level of information about politics and public affairs, so that we
look at the effect of distance conditional on the respondents level of information beyond the confines of
state politics.

16

THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

MONTH YEAR

[TABLE 8 HERE]
Columns (1)-(2) show a robust, significant pattern: individuals who are farther from the state capital are substantially less likely to be informed about state
politics. Columns (3)-(4) show the same goes for the level of interest in state
campaign news, within the subset of newspaper readers. Quantitatively, our
preferred specifications with all individual- and county-level controls imply substantial marginal decreases of about 8 percentage points (from a mean probability
around 66%), and 6 percentage points (off a 40% mean probability), respectively.
Finally, Columns (5)-(6) display a placebo test: the correlation with distance is
distinctly absent when it comes to the level of GeneralInterest in government
and public affairs.
The Role of Voters

We now check whether citizens who are farther away from the capital are also
less likely to vote in state elections. Table 9 (Panel A) runs county-level regressions, with data from all gubernatorial elections between 1990 and 2012, controlling for county demographics (in the preceding Census, for each year), and with
state-year fixed effects so as to focus on within-state and within-election variation.
[TABLE 9 HERE]
We see a negative effect of distance to the capital on turnout in Column (1)
that is statistically significant and quantitatively nontrivial: doubling the distance
from the capital would reduce turnout by around 1.5 percentage points (or onesixth of the within-state standard deviation), from a mean around 45%. Column
(2) further shows that the result is related to the special role of the capital: a
placebo variable (distance to state centroid) is insignificant and barely affects the
main coefficient.
Interestingly, Column (3) shows the effect is much weaker, and statistically
insignificant, for state elections that coincided with presidential elections. In
contrast, the same regression restricted to the sample of off-years where no
federal election took place yields a coefficient that is three times as large (Column
(4)) we can reject the equality of coefficients at the 1% level.
Panel B (Columns (5)-(10) then shows that the result is unaltered if we consider each of the separate six election cycles covered by our data separately: the
coefficient is remarkably consistent, although it gets smaller in the most recent
cycle.34
34 Note that assuming that the relationship that emerges from the county-level data would necessarily
aggregate up to a link between state-level turnout and the isolation of the state capital would be incurring
in the well-known ecological fallacy. As it turns out, there is a weak negative link between turnout and
the isolation of the capital, that is borderline statistically significant (at the 10% level) once states with
presidential-year elections are excluded from the sample. (See Online Appendix.) The difference between
presidential and off-years is also true for every election cycle taken in isolation (see Online Appendix).

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE

ISOLATED CAPITAL CITIES AND CORRUPTION

D.

17

Money in Politics

We now ask whether there is a link between the spatial distribution of population around the state capital and the amount of campaign money in state-level
politics. Table 10 shows a robust positive relationship, at the aggregate state level,
between the isolation of the capital and campaign contributions (controlling for
population and income).
[TABLE 10 HERE]
Columns (1)-(2) show that the result holds for the basic OLS specifications,
which reproduce our preferred specifications for corruption, but with campaign
contributions as our dependent variable. It is also substantial quantitatively: a
one-standard-deviation increase in the isolation of the capital would be associated
with a 30% increase in contributions. Columns (3)-(4) then show the result
survives unscathed when we control for presidential campaign contributions (in
the 2008 election cycle), which helps capture other factors leading to a high general
propensity to engage in this form of political activity (the raw correlation is
0.87). Finally, Columns (5)-(8) show similar results when we again instrument
for AvgLogDistance using the isolation of the centroid with respect to population,
although the same is not true with the alternative instrument.
In light of this aggregate pattern, we then ask whether, within states, individuals or firms who are located closer to the capital have a different propensity to
contribute money to state politics. We look at this question by focusing on one
specific industry whose location is not particularly concentrated spatially, namely
real estate.
We see in Columns (1)-(2) in Table 11 that individuals and firms located in
counties that are farther from the capital spend less in campaign contributions,
both in absolute terms and controlling for income per capita. Columns (3)(5) show that the results stay remarkably consistent when controlling for additional county demographics, when leaving aside counties that report no contributions, and even if we look at contributions at the zipcode level, using withincounty variation only. Quite interestingly, Columns (6)-(7) show that this pattern
comes exclusively from states with relatively isolated capital cities (above median
AvgLogDistancenot ).
[TABLE 11 HERE]
E.

Isolated Capital Cities and the Provision of Public Goods

Last but not least, we look at whether isolated capital cities are associated with
distinct patterns of public good provision. Table 12 displays the results, using
AvgLogDistancenot as independent variable of interest.35
35 We use the control variables from our preferred specification for the baseline results in Table 1,
except that we add ethnic fractionalization in order to take into account the standard result that it
seems to affect the provision of public goods.

18

THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

MONTH YEAR

[TABLE 12 HERE]
Columns (1)-(2) show isolated capital cities are significantly correlated with
lower spending on public good provision, and with more spending on items not
directly related to it. Column (3) then shows a correlation, significant at the 10%
level, with lower levels of public good provision, summarized by the first principal
component of our three measures. The estimates are quantitatively meaningful:
a one-standard-deviation increase in isolation is associated with a drop of around
0.25-0.3 standard deviation in the distribution of spending, and similarly for public good provision. Columns (4)-(6) then display 2SLS specifications, with the
isolation of the centroid with respect to population as the instrument. The results are broadly consistent, although the coefficient for public good provision is
now essentially zero.36
IV.

Discussion

The main message from our results is the substantial evidence of a link between
isolated capital cities and greater levels of corruption across US states. This link
is robust to different specifications and measures of both concepts, and seems to
be specific about corruption, and about the role of the capital city.37 In addition,
while we are short of a true natural experiment where state capitals would have
been randomly assigned, plausible sources of exogenous variation indicate that
our stylized fact is not driven by confounding factors related to the endogeneity
of that choice and its impact on the spatial distribution of population.
This is very much in line with what we have termed the accountability view: the
idea that isolated capitals may see corruption fester because of reduced accountability. We have also found direct evidence for that view, as different mechanisms
are related to the spatial distribution of population.38
First, we saw that newspapers whose audience is on average farther from the
state capital provide less coverage of state politics. Such pattern could be expected, to the extent that media outlets are at least partly trying to provide content that interests their audience (e.g. Mullainathan and Shleifer 2005, Gentzkow
and Shapiro 2010), and to the extent that media consumers are at least somewhat
more interested (ceteris paribus) in what happens close to where they live. We
also found some evidence that states with more isolated capitals have less intense
media coverage of state politics.
36 Results

are similar if we use AvgLogDistanceadj instead (see Online Appendix).


particular, that the results do not extend to other types of federal crime helps alleviate the concern
that they might be driven by differences in the ability, zeal, or resources available to federal prosecutors
at least to the extent that these differences apply across different types of cases.
38 We also find that politicians earn higher salaries in states with more isolated capitals, as proxied by
governor compensation (as a share of per capita income and controlling for the relative desirability of
living in the capital, as captured by relative housing prices). This is consistent lower accountability, in
that one would expect politicians to be able to extract rents both legally as well as illegally (see Online
Appendix).
37 In

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE

ISOLATED CAPITAL CITIES AND CORRUPTION

19

This lower level of media scrutiny could very well lead to, and be reinforced
by, a less informed and less engaged citizenry. Consistent with that, we find that
living farther from the capital substantially decreases the level of interest in state
campaigns among individuals with comparable demographic characteristics and
with a comparable level of information about policy in general. In contrast, it
does not affect the level of interest in public affairs in general. Put together, these
pieces suggest that where individuals are located matters substantively for media
accountability at the state level.
It is thus natural to conjecture that other forms of holding state officials accountable could also be linked to the spatial distribution of population. In particular, one might expect that disengagement to be reflected in lower voter turnout,
and hence less accountability via the electoral process. We find that turnout
in state elections is indeed lower farther from the state capital an empirical
regularity that is novel, to the best of our knowledge, in the US context.39 Notably, the logic of our hypothesis would predict a weaker link between turnout
and distance to the state capital for presidential-year elections, where presumably turnout would be more affected by forces unrelated to state politics. This is
exactly what we find.
Still in the realm of the electoral process, we find a strong positive relationship
between the isolation of the state capital and the amount of money in state-level
campaigns. We can thus speculate that, with lower media scrutiny and reduced
involvement by voters, an isolated capital opens the way for a stronger role of
money in shaping political outcomes.
This interpretation is bolstered by the evidence that firms or individuals who
are located closer to the capital city contribute more, and that this is true only
in states with relatively isolated capitals. These empirical patterns, which are
also novel (to the best of our knowledge), indicate that the aggregate relationship
is not driven by those who are farther from the capital spending money so as
to compensate for lower influence in other dimensions. In short, isolation seems
associated with money in politics, and in ways that further distort the political
process towards those isolated capitals.
This evidence is particularly interesting as it goes against an alternative hypothesis linking isolated capitals and corruption, in the opposite direction from
the accountability view what we may call the capture view. This conjecture,
prominently featured in the historical records on the debate over the location of
US state capitals (Shelley 1996), would posit that a capital city removed from
the major centers of population and economic activity poses a smaller risk of
political capture by special interests. Insofar as such capture would be reflected
in a greater role of money in politics, our results undermine the hypothesis, at
least in a contemporaneous setting.
Our last piece of evidence is that isolated capital cities are also associated
with diminished public good provision. Along with our previous results, this
39 Similar

effects have been detected elsewhere (Hearl, Budge, and Pearson 1996).

20

THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

MONTH YEAR

paints a picture of isolated capital cities associated with low accountability and
corruption, with important detrimental effects on the states performance as a
provider of public goods.
As a final note, the direct evidence linking isolated capital cities to lower accountability also gives us fresh perspective on the basic stylized fact that links
them to greater corruption. One important limitation shared by all of our measures of corruption is that they capture not only what they are meant to, but
also accountability, to one degree or another. This is certainly a source of measurement error, but the evidence on accountability suggests that the true extent
of corruption in states with isolated capitals is relatively underestimated by our
measures. This would work against our stylized fact.
V.

Concluding Remarks

It is interesting to speculate about the connection between isolated capitals, accountability, and corruption, going into the future: could the death of distance
mean that the isolation of capital cities would become relatively less important?
In addition, the associated retreat of newspapers could also weaken the specific
media accountability mechanism we detect. This is an interesting topic for future
research, but it certainly need not be the case: casual observation suggests that
online media are not immune from a bias towards local coverage consistent with
demand-driven bias and there could also be countervailing forces.40
More broadly, our work sheds light on the long-run implications of institutional
choices and their spatial content. The importance of the location of the capital
city is highlighted both by the historical record in the US, where the issue was
prominently discussed and fought over both at the state and federal levels, and
by the many instances of countries relocating their capitals. We have shown
one reason that makes it important, as it affects institutional performance along
important dimensions even in a fully democratic context. In terms of policy, one is
led to conclude that polities with isolated capital cities require extra vigilance, to
counteract their tendency towards reduced accountability. Put simply, watchdogs
need to bark louder when there is a higher chance that people are not paying much
attention.
VI.

References

Ades, Alberto F. and Edward L. Glaeser. 1995. Trade and Circus:


Explaining Urban Giants. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(1): 195227.
Alt, James E. and David Dreyer Lassen. 2003. The Political Economy
of Institutions and Corruption in American States. Journal of Theoretical
Politics, 15(3):341-365
40 As an illustration: conversations with people in the newspaper industry suggest that coverage of
state politics is often the first to be cut, and likely more so when the capital is isolated because
newspapers need to focus on what is most interesting for their dwindling readership, or because it is
easier to lay off someone who is in a distant capital.

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE

ISOLATED CAPITAL CITIES AND CORRUPTION

21

Alt, James E. and David Dreyer Lassen 2008. Political and Judicial
Checks on Corruption: Evidence from American State Governments. Economics and Politics, 20(1): 33-61.
Alt, James E. and David Dreyer Lassen. 2012. Enforcement and Public
Corruption: Evidence from the American States. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization (forthcoming).
Boylan, Richard T. and Cheryl X. Long. 2002. Measuring Public Corruption in the American States: A Survey of State House Reporters. State
Politics & Policy Quarterly, 3(4): 420-438.
Campante, Filipe R. and Quoc-Anh Do. 2010. A Centered Index of
Spatial Concentration: Expected Influence Approach and Application to
Population and Capital Cities. Harvard Kennedy School (unpublished).
Campante, Filipe R., Quoc-Anh Do and Bernardo Guimaraes. 2012.
Isolated Capital Cities and Misgovernance: Theory and Evidence. Harvard Kennedy School (unpublished).
Davis, James C. and J. Vernon Henderson. 2003. Evidence on the Political Economy of the Urbanization Process. Journal of Urban Economics,
53(1): 98-125.
Druckmann, James N. 2005. Media Matter: How Newspapers and Television News Cover Campaigns and Influence Voters. Political Communication, 22: 463-481
Engstrom, Erik J., Jesse R. Hammond, and John T. Scott 2013. Capitol Mobility: Madisonian Representation and the Location and Relocation of Capitals in the United States. American Political Science Review,
107(2): 225-240.
Fisman, Raymond and Roberta Gatti 2002. Decentralization and Corruption: Evidence from U.S. Federal Transfer Programs. Public Choice,
113(1-2): 25-35.
Galiani, Sebastian and Sukkoo Kim. 2011. Political Centralization and
Urban Primacy: Evidence from National and Provincial Capitals in the
Americas. In Understanding Long-Run Economic Growth: Geography, Institutions, and the Knowledge Economy, ed. Dora L. Costa and Naomi R.
Lamoreaux, 121-154. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Gentzkow, Matthew, Edward L. Glaeser, and Claudia Goldin. 2005.
The Rise of the Fourth Estate: How Newspapers Became Informative and
Why It Mattered. In Corruption and Reform: Lessons from Americas
Economic History, ed. Edward L. Glaeser and Claudia Goldin, 187-230.
Cambridge, MA: NBER.
Gentzkow, Matthew and Jesse M. Shapiro. 2010. What Drives Media
Slant? Evidence from U.S. Daily Newspapers Econometrica, 78(1): 35-71.
Glaeser, Edward L. and Raven E. Saks. 2006. Corruption in America.
Journal of Public Economics, 90: 1053-1072.

22

THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW

MONTH YEAR

Gordon, Sanford C. 2009. Assessing Partisan Bias in Federal Public Corruption Prosecutions. American Political Science Review, 103(4): 534-554.
Hearl, Derek J., Ian Budge, and Bernard Pearson. 1996. Distinctiveness
of regional voting: A comparative analysis across the European Community
(1979-1993). Electoral Studies, 15(2): 167-182.
Lim, Claire S.H., James M. Snyder, Jr, and David Stromberg. 2012.
The Judge, the Politician, and the Press: Newspaper Coverage and Criminal Sentencing Across Electoral Systems. Unpublished.
Maxwell, Amanda E. and Richard F. Winters. 2005. Political Corruption in America. Unpublished.
Meier, Kenneth J. and Thomas M. Holbrook 1992. I seen my opportunities and I tookem: Political Corruption in the American States. Journal
of Politics 54: 135-155.
Meier, Kenneth J. and Thomas Schlesinger. 2002. Variations in Corruption among the American States. In Political Corruption: Concepts and
Contexts, ed. Arnold Heidenheimer and Michael Johnson, 627-644. New
Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Publishers.
Morgan Quitno Corporation. 2005. Education State Rankings : 2005-2006.
Lawrence, KS: Morgan Quitno.
Mullainathan, Sendhil and Andrei Shleifer. 2005. The Market for News.
American Economic Review, 95(4): 1031-1053.
Ramankutty, Navin, Jonathan A. Foley, John Norman, and Kevin
McSweeney. 2002. The Global Distribution of Cultivable Lands: Current Patterns and Sensitivity to Possible Climate Change. Global Ecology
and Biogeography, 11(5): 377-392.
Rodden, Jonathan. 2010. The Geographic Distribution of Political Preferences. Annual Review of Political Science, 13: 321-340.
Saiz, Albert and Uri Simonsohn. 2013. Proxying for Unobservable Variables with Internet Document Frequency. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(1): 137-165.
Shelley, Fred M. 1996. Political Geography of the United States. New York,
NY: Guilford Press.
Snyder, James M., Jr. and David Stromberg. 2010. Press Coverage and
Political Accountability. Journal of Political Economy, 118(2): 355-408.
Stein, Mark. 2008. How the States Got Their Shapes. New York: Collins
(Smithsonian Books).
Stock, James H. and Motohiro Yogo. 2005. Testing for Weak Instruments
in Linear IV Regression. In Identification and Inference for Econometric
Models: Essays in Honor of Thomas Rothenberg, ed. Donald W. K. Andrews and James H. Stock, 109-120. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University
Press, 2005, 80108.

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE

ISOLATED CAPITAL CITIES AND CORRUPTION

23

Vinson, C. Danielle. 2003. Local Media Coverage of Congress and Its Members: Through Local Eyes. Cresskill NJ, Hampton Press.
Wilson, James Q. 1966. Corruption: The Shame of the States. Public
Interest, 2: 28-38.
Zagarri, Rosemarie. 1987. The Politics of Size: Representation in the United
States, 1776-1850. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

TABLE 1. CORRELATIONS WITH PREDETERMINED VARIABLES

Variable

Log Total Border


Latitude

(1)
Centroid
AvgLogDistnot
(population)
Individual

(2)
Centroid
AvgLogDistnot
(suitability)
Individual

(3)
Centroid
AvgLogDistnot
(population)
Joint

(4)
Centroid
AvgLogDistnot
(suitability)
Joint

(5)

(6)

AvgLogDistnot

AvgLogDistnot

Individual

Joint

0.0115

0.0080

0.0151

0.0139

-0.0363

-0.0463

[0.565]

[0.418]

[0.489]

[0.343]

[0.242]

[0.147]

0.0004

-0.0001

0.0012

-0.0004

-0.0020

0.0003

[0.590]

[0.810]

[0.216]

[0.444]

[0.231]

[0.883]

Longitude

-0.0003

0.0003

-0.0003

0.0006*

-0.0009

0.0003

[0.539]

[0.305]

[0.725]

[0.075]

[0.254]

[0.737]

Log Distance to DC

-0.0027

0.0009

0.0060

-0.0024

-0.0140

-0.0099

[0.742]

[0.834]

[0.614]

[0.556]

[0.193]

[0.441]

Date of Statehood

-0.0002

0.0000

-0.0001

-0.0000

-0.0004*

-0.0001

[0.177]

[0.612]

[0.380]

[0.755]

[0.090]

[0.656]

Log Elevation Span

-0.0049

0.0004

-0.0074

-0.0023

-0.0257***

-0.0204*

[0.307]

[0.881]

[0.175]

[0.340]

[0.009]

[0.057]

-0.0017

-0.0004

-0.0025

-0.0002

0.0001

-0.0019

[0.181]

[0.682]

[0.190]

[0.851]

[0.979]

[0.542]

Percentage of Water Area


Log Navigable Waterways

0.0016

-0.0006

0.0016

-0.0007

0.0071*

0.0036

[0.287]

[0.316]

[0.464]

[0.630]

[0.087]

[0.452]

-0.0036

-0.0116

-0.0277

-0.0112

0.0478

0.0151

[0.869]

[0.354]

[0.221]

[0.498]

[0.343]

[0.756]

F statistic

1.04

1.25

1.46

P-value

0.428

0.295

0.200

Share of Arable Land (1950)

Notes: p-values in brackets. Columns (1), (2), (5): Coefficients from individual regressions of AvgLogDistance on Log Area, Log Maximum Distance, and reported
variable. Columns (3), (4), (6): Coefficients from multiple regression of AvgLogDistance on Log Area, Log Maximum Distance, and all reported variables. F statistic
and p-value are for the joint hypothesis of significance of reported coefficients. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

TABLE 2. CORRUPTION AND ISOLATION OF THE CAPITAL CITY: AVG LOG DISTANCE
Dep. Var.: Corruption

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

AvgLogDistancenot

1.0477***

1.1666***

1.0307***

0.7932***

[0.215]

[0.247]

[0.322]

[0.276]

AvgLogDistanceadj

Basic Control Variables

Control Variables I

Control Variables II

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

0.8245***

0.8383***

0.8023***

0.5734**

[0.168]

[0.190]

[0.200]

[0.223]

Observations

48

48

48

48

48

48

48

48

R-squared

0.257

0.465

0.532

0.609

0.232

0.406

0.525

0.598

Notes: Robust standard errors in brackets. OLS regressions. Dependent variable: Corruption = Federal convictions for corruption-related crime relative to population,
avg. 1976-2002. Independent variables as of 1970 (AvgLogDistance average 1920-1970). All AvgLogDistancenot specifications include Log Area and Log Maximum
Distance. Basic Control Variables: Log Income, Log Population, % College. Control variables I: Share of government employment, % Urban, Census Region
dummies. Control variables II: Racial dissimilarity, Regulation index, Share of value added in mining. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

TABLE 3. CORRUPTION AND ISOLATION OF THE CAPITAL CITY: ROBUSTNESS

Dep. Var.:
AvgLogDistancenot

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

State Officials

State Officials

Corruption
(Exalead)

Corruption
(Exalead)

Corruption

Corruption

Corruption
(Exalead)

Corruption
(Exalead)

0.1311**

0.0020**

[0.064]
AvgLogDistanceadj

[0.001]
0.0741*

0.0018**

[0.043]

[0.001]

AvgDistancenot

0.7733***
[0.284]

AvgDistanceadj

0.4710***
[0.091]

Capital Share

-0.0011**
[0.0005]

Capital Largest

-0.0001*
[0.0001]

Observations
R-squared

48

48

48

48

48

48

50

50

0.591

0.551

0.395

0.398

0.485

0.553

0.340

0.328

Notes: Robust standard errors in brackets. OLS regressions; Columns (1)-(2): Weighted OLS regressions (Weight = 0.0000001 + st. dev. of conviction sample).
Dependent variables: State Officials = Federal convictions of state public officials for corruption-related crime per 100 state government employees, avg. 1986-2011.
Corruption (Exalead) = Number of search hits for corruption close to state name divided by number of search hits for state name, using Exalead search tool (in
2009). Corruption = Federal convictions for corruption-related crime relative to population, avg. 1976-2002. Independent variables as of 1970 (AvgLogDistance avg.
1920-1970) in Columns (1)-(2) and (5)-(6), as of 2000 (AvgLogDistance avg. 1920-2000) in Columns (3)-(4) and (7)-(8). Control variables: Log Area and Log
Maximum Distance (for AvgLogDistancenot specifications only), Log Income, Log Population, % College, Share of government employment, % Urban, Census
Region dummies. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

TABLE 4. PLACEBO TESTS

Dep. Var.:
AvgLogDistancenot (largest city)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

Corruption

Corruption

Corruption

Corruption

Drug Cases

Drug Cases

Drug Cases

Drug Cases

0.4817

-0.0109

[0.298]

[0.336]
0.2564

-0.2019

[0.222]

[0.242]

AvgLogDistanceadj (largest city)


AvgLogDistancenot

1.0366***

-4.4612

[0.378]

[13.799]

AvgLogDistanceadj
Observations
R-squared

-3.9185
[9.765]

0.8921***

1.0907

-9.5891

[0.236]

[9.201]

[8.288]

48

48

48

48

48

48

44

44

0.422

0.532

0.370

0.532

0.339

0.322

0.394

0.417

Notes: Robust standard errors in brackets. OLS regressions. Dependent variables: Corruption = Federal convictions for corruption-related crime relative to population,
avg. 1976-2002; Drug Cases = Criminal defendants commenced in federal courts, 2011. Independent variables as of 1970 (AvgLogDistance avg. 1920-1970) for
columns (1)-(4), as of 2000 (AvgLogDistance avg. 1920-2000) in Columns (5)-(8). Control variables: Log Area and Log Maximum Distance (for AvgLogDistancenot
specifications only), Log Income, Log Population, % College, Share of government employment, % Urban, Regional dummies. Columns (7)-(8) exclude Mexico
border states (CA, AZ, NM, TX). *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

TABLE 5. CORRUPTION AND ISOLATION OF THE CAPITAL CITY: ADDRESSING CAUSALITY

Dep. Var.: Corruption

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

1st Stage

1st Stage

2SLS

2SLS

2SLS

2SLS

2SLS

2SLS

1.0851***

1.4880***

1.3880***

1.2725***

[0.287]

[0.489]

[0.441]

[0.458]

Panel A: (Population Centroid)


AvgLogDistancenot

0.8708***

1.8280***

1.7360***

1.5857***

[0.250]

[0.583]

[0.546]

[0.567]

AvgLogDistanceadj
Basic Control

Control Var. I

Control Var. II

Observations

48

48

48

48

48

48

48

48

R-squared

0.851

0.677

0.387

0.463

0.538

0.398

0.481

0.551

F-statistic

12.15

14.27

0.002

0.002

0.003

0.002

0.002

0.003

0.8999

1.4495**

1.2610**

[0.776]

[0.734]

[0.618]

AR p-value

Panel B: (Land Suitability Centroid)


AvgLogDistancenot

1.2427**
[0.456]

AvgLogDistanceadj

1.1403

1.7231**

1.4375**

[0.976]

[0.858]

[0.681]

1.4166**
[0.530]

Basic Control

Control Var. I

Control Var. II

Observations

X
X

48

48

48

48

48

48

48

48

R-squared (centered)

0.828

0.607

0.465

0.465

0.562

0.456

0.469

0.553

F-statistic

7.42

7.15

0.333

0.033

0.014

0.333

0.033

0.015

AR p-value

Notes: Robust standard errors in brackets. Dependent variable: Corruption = Federal convictions for corruption-related crime relative to population, avg. 1976-2002.
Independent variables as of 1970 (AvgLogDistance: avg. 1920-1970). Basic Control variables: Log Income, Log Population, % College, Log Area, Log Maximum
Distance. Control Variables I: Share of government employment, % Urban, Census Region dummies. Control Variables II: Racial dissimilarity, Regulation index, Share
of value added in mining. IV: Centroid AvgLogDistancenot of population (Panel A) and land suitability (Panel B). AR p-value: p-value from Anderson-Rubin
(minimum distance) test. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

TABLE 6. NEWSPAPER COVERAGE OF STATE POLITICS AND THE CONCENTRATION OF CIRCULATION AROUND THE CAPITAL

Dep. Var.: Number of Search


Hits
ReaderConcentr

Observations
R-squared

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

State Elections

State Budget

State Government

Governors Name

884.057***

983.524***

1,164.911**

1,377.846***

[304.295]

[284.500]

[555.114]

[239.350]

431

436

436

436

0.783

0.770

0.789

0.716

Notes: Robust standard errors in brackets, clustered by state. OLS regressions. Dependent variable: Number of search hits for each term in NewsLibrary.com
(01/01/2008 to 12/31/2009). Control variables: Log of daily circulation, Number of search hits for Monday, state fixed effects. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

TABLE 7. MEDIA COVERAGE AND ISOLATION OF THE CAPITAL CITY

Dep. Var.: Media Coverage

AvgLogDistancenot

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

Circ. Weighted

AvgLogDistance
Weighted

Circ. Weighted

AvgLogDistance
Weighted

Circ. Weighted
2SLS
Population

Circ. Weighted
2SLS
Population

-2.3921

-2.1841

-4.4325

[3.379]

[3.285]

[2.730]

AvgLogDistanceadj

-4.7810*

-5.2566**

-3.6317*

[2.529]

[2.589]

[2.169]

Observations

47

47

47

47

46

46

AR p-value

0.115

0.115

0.460

0.451

0.246

0.237

0.554

0.570

R-squared

Notes: Robust standard errors in brackets. OLS regressions except where noted. Dependent variable: First principal component of weighted search hits for each of the
terms in Table 7 (weighted by newspaper circulation or AvgLogDistance-weighted newspaper circulation, as indicated), divided by hits for Monday. Independent
variables as of 2000 (AvgLogDistance avg. 1920-2000). Control variables: Log Area and Log Maximum Distance (for AvgLogDistancenot specifications), Log Income,
Log Population, % College, Share of government employment, Regional dummies, Dummy for election in 2008-2009. Columns (5)-(6) exclude Rhode Island. The
state of Montana is missing from the media coverage sample. Instrument: centroid AvgLogDistancenot of population. AR p-value: p-value from Anderson-Rubin
(minimum distance) test. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

TABLE 8. DISTANCE TO THE CAPITAL AND INDIVIDUAL ENGAGEMENT WITH STATE POLITICS

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

Dep. Var.:

Knowledge

Knowledge

Interest

Interest

Gen. Interest

Gen. Interest

LogDistance Capital

-0.0623***

-0.0836***

-0.0326

-0.0649**

-0.0001

-0.0120

[0.0205]

[0.0252]

[0.0227]

[0.0288]

[0.0218]

[0.0275]

State Fixed Effects

County Controls

Individual Controls
Observations

780

780

652

648

780

776

Mean of dep. variable

0.662

0.662

0.403

0.403

0.590

0.590

Pseudo R-squared

0.033

0.172

0.021

0.160

0.014

0.207

Notes: Robust standard errors in brackets, clustered by county. Probit regressions, marginal effects reported. Dependent variables: Knowledge = Dummy for knowing
name of at least one candidate in gubernatorial elections; Interest = Dummy for caring a great deal, quite a bit, or some about newspaper articles regarding
gubernatorial elections (conditional on reading newspapers); General Interest = Dummy for reporting interest in government and public affairs most of the time or
some of the time. County Controls: population, percent urban, population density, percent non-White, median age, median income, and median schooling (from 1990
Census); Individual Controls: dummies for age, occupation, sex, income, and political party identication, and number of children and general level of information
(from ANES). All columns include state fixed effects. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

TABLE 9. DISTANCE TO THE CAPITAL AND TURNOUT IN STATE ELECTIONS


Panel A: All electoral cycles
(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

All Years

All Years

Presidential Years

Off Years

-0.0180***

-0.0191***

-0.0053

-0.0341***

[0.002]

[0.003]

[0.003]

[0.005]

Dep. Var.:
Turnout in State Elections
LogDistance to Capital

LogDistance to Centroid

-0.0031
[0.002]

State Fixed Effects

Control Variables

Observations

18,518

18,518

3,471

2,288

R-squared

0.819

0.814

0.768

0.770

Panel B: Individual cycles


Dep. Var.:
Turnout in State Elections

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

(10)

1990-1992

1993-1996

1997-2000

2001-2004

2005-2008

2009-2012

LogDistance to Capital

-0.0176***

-0.0169***

-0.0180***

-0.0171***

-0.0192***

-0.0149***

[0.003]

[0.003]

[0.003]

[0.002]

[0.003]

[0.002]

State Fixed Effects

Control Variables

Observations

2,956

3,073

3,069

3,117

3,073

3,230

R-squared

0.845

0.800

0.823

0.840

0.836

0.846

Notes: Robust standard errors in brackets, clustered by state. OLS regressions. Dependent variable: Turnout in state election, county-level (1990-2012). Independent
variables: Log Distance to Capital, Log Distance to Centroid. Control variables: Log Density of Population over 18, % High School and above, % College and above,
Log Median Household Income, Poverty Rate, Shares of population under 5, 5-17, 18-24, 25-44, 45-64, 65-74, 75-84, 85 and above, Shares of census-defined races, all
from the preceding census, and Gini coefficient, Racial fractionalization, Religious fractionalization from 1990. All columns include state fixed effects. *** p<0.01, **
p<0.05, * p<0.1.

TABLE 10. CAMPAIGN CONTRIBUTIONS AND ISOLATION OF THE CAPITAL CITY

Dep. Var.: Log State Contributions


AvgLogDistancenot

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

OLS

OLS

OLS

OLS

2SLS
Population

2SLS
Population

2SLS
Land Suit.

2SLS
Land. Suit.

3.0146***

2.4782**

5.0364***

1.6361

[0.942]

[1.080]

[1.679]

[2.339]

AvgLogDistanceadj

2.4241***

1.9627**

4.0473***

1.3751

[0.788]

[0.856]

[1.372]

[1.988]

Log Presid. Contributions

Observations

0.3171

0.3407*

0.1854

0.2163

0.3605**

0.3670**

[0.207]

[0.200]

[0.216]

[0.206]

[0.173]

[0.171]

48

48

48

48

48

48

48

48

R-squared

0.903

0.899

0.910

0.907

0.897

0.896

0.909

0.907

AR p-value

0.002

0.002

0.505

0.505

Notes: Robust standard errors in brackets. Dependent variable: Log of Campaign Contributions to state-level campaigns, 2001-2010. Independent variables as of 2000
(AvgLogDistance: avg. 1920-2000). Control variables (as of 2000): Log of Campaign Contributions to presidential campaigns (2008): Log Area and Log Maximum
Distance (AvgLogDistancenot specifications only), Log Income, Log Population, % College (all columns), Share of government employment, %Urban, Regional
dummies (except for Columns (1) and (4)). IV: centroid AvgLogDistancenot of population and land suitability. AR p-value: p-value from Anderson-Rubin (minimum
distance) test. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

TABLE 11. DISTANCE TO THE CAPITAL AND CAMPAIGN CONTRIBUTIONS FROM REAL ESTATE INDUSTRY
(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

Dep. Var.: Real Estate


Campaign Contribution

By county

By county

By county

Counties with
positive contribs.

By zipcode

Counties in
Low Avg.
LogDist. States

Counties in
High Avg.
LogDist. States

Log Distance to Capital

-1.2649***

-0.1797**

-0.2052**

-0.2146***

-0.3093***

0.0001

-0.3678***

[0.181]

[0.081]

[0.083]

[0.049]

[0.112]

[0.100]

[0.119]

Basic Controls
County Controls

Zero-Contrib Excluded

County Fixed Effects


X

Observations

3,105

3,104

3,050

2,207

40,347

1,199

1,851

R-squared

0.334

0.688

0.708

0.736

0.311

0.730

0.700

State Fixed Effects

Notes: Robust standard errors in brackets, clustered by state. Observation unit: County (Zipcode in Column (5)). Dependent variable: Log of campaign contributions
to state-level campaigns, 2001-2010, from the real estate industry based in each county (zipcode in Column (5)). Counties with zero contribution excluded in Column
(4). Column (6) sample is restricted to states below median AvgLogDistancenot, Column (7) sample is restricted to states above median AvgLogDistancenot.
Independent variables: Log Distance to Capital. Basic control variables: Log Population over 18, Log Median Household Income. County control variables: % High
School and above, % College and above, Poverty Rate, Log Land Area, Shares of population under 5, 5-17, 18-24, 25-44, 45-64, 65-74, 75-84, 85 and above, Shares
of census-defined races, all from 2000 census, and Gini coefficient, Racial fractionalization, Religious fractionalization from 1990. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

TABLE 12. PUBLIC GOODS AND ISOLATION OF THE CAPITAL CITY

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

OLS

OLS

OLS

2SLS

2SLS

2SLS

PG Exp.

Oth. Exp.

PG Prov.

PG Exp.

Oth. Exp.

PG Prov.

-0.478***

0.319***

-2.690*

-0.552**

0.330**

-0.405

[0.137]

[0.102]

[1.533]

[0.217]

[0.149]

[2.517]

48

48

48

48

48

48

AR p-value

0.021

0.041

0.874

R-squared

0.451

0.593

0.877

0.448

0.593

0.871

Dep. Var.:
AvgLogDistancenot

Observations

Notes: Robust standard errors in brackets. Dependent variables: PG Exp. (Public Good Expenditures) = Share of state expenditures on education, public welfare,
health, and hospitals in 2008; Oth. Exp. (Other Expenditures) = Share of state expenditures on government administration, interest on debt, and other in 2008; PG
Prov. (Public Good Provision) = First principal component of Smart State Index (2005), % of population with health insurance (2008-9), and log of hospital beds
per capita (2009). Independent variables: AvgLogDistancenot avg 1920-2000. Control variables: Log Area and Log Maximum Distance, Log Income, Log Population,
% College, Share of government employment, Racial dissimilarity, % Urban, Regional dummies (all specifications). IV: centroid AvgLogDistancenot of population.
AR p-value: p-value from Anderson-Rubin (minimum distance) test. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

.6

FIGURE 1
MS

.5

LA
SD
IL
NY
MT
ND

TN

.4

OK
SC
GA

.3

VA

AL
PA
OH
KY

WV
RI

.2

MA

NJ

DE
MD

CT

ME
IN

UTNH

.1

CO

VT

MN

KS
AR MI
NC
AZ WI
NE
IA

.5

NM
MO
ID

.6
.7
Average Log Distance
Corruption

WY NV

TX

CA

WA

OR

.4

FL

.8

Fitted values

Notes: Corruption = Federal convictions of public officials for corruption--related crime (average 1976-2002); Independent variables: AvgLogDistancenot
(average 1920-1970)

FIGURE 2

.8

FL
WY

ND

.7
MD

MO

VT
UT

.5

CO

TX

AL
KS MS
NC
LA TN
KY IA
OH
WI
MI
OR
OK
VA
AR AZ
SC
NE
GA
WV
ME
MN
IN
NJ

WA

.6

MT
NM

CA

NV
SD

NYIL
ID

PA

NH

DE

CT
MA

.4

RI

-.05
0
.05
Population-Average Log Distance (not adjusted) to Centroid (residuals)
Capital Population-AvgLogDistance (not adjusted)

Fitted values

Notes: Capital Population-Average Log Distances (not adjusted) (average 1920-1970) residuals from regression of AvgLogDistancenot on Log Area and Log
Maximum Distance.

Potrebbero piacerti anche