Sei sulla pagina 1di 19

This article was downloaded by: [24.127.31.

97]
On: 11 November 2013, At: 10:33
Publisher: Routledge
Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered
office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK
African Studies
Publication details, including instructions for authors and
subscription information:
http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/cast20
Studying development/development
studies
Henry Bernstein
a
a
University of London
Published online: 18 Aug 2006.
To cite this article: Henry Bernstein (2006) Studying development/development studies, African
Studies, 65:1, 45-62, DOI: 10.1080/00020180600771733
To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00020180600771733
PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE
Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the
Content) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis,
our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to
the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions
and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors,
and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content
should not be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sources
of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims,
proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever
or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or
arising out of the use of the Content.
This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any
substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing,
systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms &
Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-
and-conditions
Studying Development/Development
Studies
Henry Bernstein
University of London
Alan Thomas (2000:777) usefully distinguishes three main senses or contempor-
ary meanings of the term development thus:
(i) as a vision, description or measure of the state of being of a desirable society;
(ii) as an historical process of social change in which societies are transformed
over long periods;
(iii) as consisting of deliberate efforts aimed at improvement on the part of
various agencies, including governments, all kinds of organisations and
social movements. (Emphases in original)
Underlying this lucid and concise characterisation are the dramatic and
contradictory histories of the formation of the modern world, of how people
located differentially in the times and places of its processes have tried to make
sense of them, and of the effects of those understandings for more or less coherent
political projects and other forms of collective action (combining vision and
deliberate efforts aimed at improvement). The aim of this article is to explore
several implications of these observations with respect to (a) studying develop-
ment, (b) the nature of development studies as a recent academic eld, and (c)
how (and how well) the former may be accommodated with the latter. In doing
so, I look over my shoulder, as it were, at the work and inspiration of Bill
Freund as an economic historian of modern Africa within what I shall term the
great tradition of studying development.
1
Bill established a distinctive academic
niche at the University of Natal (now KwaZulu-Natal) for studying (and teaching)
development, that I touch on at the end.
Studying development
My starting point is Thomass second sense of development cited above: an his-
torical process of social change in which societies are transformed over long
periods. I start here because this is the original source of any meaning of
modern development in effect: that established by the initial (and long) tran-
sitions to capitalism of north-western Europe, and especially that epochal
moment marked by the advent of modern industrialisation in Britain from, say,
the mid- or late eighteenth century onwards. After that, nothing would be the
ISSN 0002-0184 print=ISSN 1469-2872 online/06=010045-18
#2006 Taylor & Francis Group Ltd on behalf of the University of Witwatersrand
DOI: 10.1080=00020180600771733
African Studies, 65, 1, July 2006
D
o
w
n
l
o
a
d
e
d

b
y

[
2
4
.
1
2
7
.
3
1
.
9
7
]

a
t

1
0
:
3
3

1
1

N
o
v
e
m
b
e
r

2
0
1
3

same again and, if one adds for better or worse, then this is probably as near to
commanding a measure of general agreement as any observation of comparable
world-historical scope. Of course, agreement does not bestow innocence.
Indeed, the association of modernity with world-historical processes initiated in
the North (or West or First World in the terminology current not long ago)
and thereafter spreading globally, not least by imposition and coercion, remains
one of the denitive philosophical and political tensions at the core of debate
about development today (Sutcliffe 1999). This is communicated especially
well by a famous (infamous?) dictum that The country that is more developed
industrially only shows to the less developed the image of its own future
(Marx 1976/1867:91), which neatly rolls together inevitability and desirability,
prediction and progress (however painful a dialectic of destruction and creation
getting there might entail).
In short, development in this encompassing sense the material foundation of
modernity is the master theme or grand narrative of the formation of
modern social science, whether centred on the dynamics of accumulation and
its social and institutional conditions (from Locke, say, through Smith and classi-
cal political economy to Marx and then Weber) or on the problems of social order
generated by such revolutionary (bourgeois) transformations of relations of prop-
erty, production and power (from Hobbes, say, to Comte and Durkheim and, once
more, Weber). And social science of Northern/Western provenance, both pro-
duced by and preoccupied with the processes of modern development, becomes an
intellectual and ideological battleground on which the appropriateness and validity
of its knowledge (and modes of producing knowledge), and the desirability of pre-
scriptions derived from them, are ercely contested, not least in relation to the
troubled histories and uncertain futures of development in other parts of the
world (the Third World or South, and now the once Second World too).
A range of theoretical approaches to, and models of, development emerged within
the processes of the development of capitalism and its different times and places,
from the great achievements of eighteenth-century Scottish political economy
(culminating in Adam Smith) on the cusp of industrialisation, through those
who experienced and reected on the full force of industrial capitalism at rst
hand (pre-eminently Marx), to those who contemplated the effects of such com-
prehensive social change for normative order in the newly industrial societies of
Europe (Durkheim, for example); from those in then less developed parts of
Europe who saw capitalist industry as the path to national sovereignty and
power (of whom Friedrich List is emblematic) or socialist primary accumulation
and industrialisation as an alternative to capitalism (Lenin, Preobrazhensky), to
their successors in independent Asia, Latin America and Africa (Nehru, Vargas,
Nkrumah, say, as well as intellectual pioneers of development strategy like
Mahalanobis and Raul Prebisch). These brief examples illustrate various
sources and presuppose interconnections of an intellectually expansive tra-
dition of confronting development as social transformation, generated by what
46 African Studies 65: 1, July 2006
D
o
w
n
l
o
a
d
e
d

b
y

[
2
4
.
1
2
7
.
3
1
.
9
7
]

a
t

1
0
:
3
3

1
1

N
o
v
e
m
b
e
r

2
0
1
3

may be considered its heroic moments and instances, for example, conjunctures of
intensied inter-imperialist and anti-imperialist struggles from the late nineteenth
century. Heroic ideas about the sources and means of development connected,
more and less programmatically (and plausibly), with a range of aspirations and
promises bourgeois authoritarian and liberal, social democratic, socialist
and communist and in ever more highly charged ways as they combined
variously with nationalism as ideology, basis of internal political mobilisation
and external stance.
In unpacking some issues for consideration I draw on two ne, if very different,
attempts to establish a long history of ideas/ideologies and experiences of devel-
opment, and their antinomies, in order to illuminate todays debates. Of the
various motifs that make up the encompassing discursive universe of develop-
ment, the rst and most fundamental is accumulation as central to economic
growth, which in turn required industrialisation in the world created by Britains
pioneering economic revolution. This is nicely encapsulated as the old
orthodoxy of classical political economy in Gavin Kitchings Development and
Underdevelopment in Historical Perspective (1982). Kitching also maintained
that the logic of the old orthodoxy is inescapable for those who aspire to
develop, now as then; the historical and logical necessity of (typically brutal)
primary accumulation is thus the source of original sin, as it were, at the core of
the moral dramas of development and, in Kitchings account, the forms of
(populist) denial they continue to generate throughout the history of modern
capitalism.
The waywardly brilliant work by the late Michael Cowen and Bob Shenton on
Doctrines of Development (1996) centres on the problem of order disclosed by
the disruptions and upheavals of early industrial capitalism and the dangerous
classes it generated, especially in relation to labour markets, employment and
unemployment; how that problem was constituted as an object of social theory
and solutions to it theorised and applied in doctrines of development that
prescribe harmonious development under state trusteeship, hence intentional
versus immanent development in their terms; and the intrinsic contradictions
of such doctrines in both theory and practice, from their early manifestations in
Britain and its colonies (including mid nineteenth-century Australia and
Canada) to todays universe of development discourses and interventions.
In short, the burden of development was to compensate for the negative propen-
sities of capitalism through the reconstruction of social order. To develop, then,
was to ameliorate the social misery which arose out of the immanent process of
capitalist growth (Cowen and Shenton 1996:116).
2
For these two authors, the
immanent process of capitalist growth corresponds to Thomass second sense
of development with which this discussion commenced, while their notion of
development as intent, articulated in doctrines of development and typically prac-
tised through the agency of (state) trusteeship, connects with his third sense of
Studying Development/Development Studies 47
D
o
w
n
l
o
a
d
e
d

b
y

[
2
4
.
1
2
7
.
3
1
.
9
7
]

a
t

1
0
:
3
3

1
1

N
o
v
e
m
b
e
r

2
0
1
3

deliberate efforts aimed at improvement, albeit with some qualication.
3
The
qualication is that development as amelioration, itself a condition of reprodu-
cing immanent capitalist growth (accumulation) in the face of the social
misery and class struggle it generates, hardly provides any more intrinsically or
morally satisfying vision, description or measure of the state of being of a desir-
able society, Thomass rst sense of development and that which pervades
todays rhetoric of ending poverty (see further below).
4
Kitching and Cowen and Shenton share an initial historical reference point in early
capitalist industrialisation and an intellectual debt to the political economy it gen-
erated (in the case of Cowen and Shenton, more particularly to Marx) as well as a
profound antipathy to populist and nationalist claims on development doctrine.
For Kitching the logic of the old orthodoxy rst revealed by the immanent
process of capitalist growth can be adapted to the purposes of primary accumu-
lation as development strategy, exemplied in his book by China which had appro-
priated and refashioned that logic to its own historical circumstances. The case of
China served Kitchings argument in interesting ways; inter alia, he seemed to
view mass line (populist?) elements of Maoist political discourse as rhetorical
rather than inhibiting the pursuit of socialist primary accumulation on the
example of the Soviet model, and contra those who counterposed a Maoist
theory and practice not only to the experience of Stalinism but to the incomplete
break of classic Bolshevism from bourgeois ideas of development and indeed
modernity (Corrigan, Ramsay and Sayer 1978, 1979). Moreover, communist
Chinas embrace of the logic of the old orthodoxy and determined pursuit of it
served as contrast with another fashionable example of the time (if by the early
1980s an increasingly embattled one), namely Julius Nyereres strategy, or at
least ideology, of ujamaa in Tanzania, which Kitching presented as emblematic
of the disasters inherent in populist indeed people-centred development
utopias (1982:Ch 5).
In contrast, Cowen and Shentons insistence on the invention of development as an
ameliorative doctrine and set of state practices to construct social and political
order in capitalism, meant that they did not explore the inventions and doctrines
of development dedicated to achieving accumulation and economic growth. There
may be various reasons for this lacuna, including an aversion to Stalinist and
subsequent Soviet, then Maoist and subsequent Chinese, claims to socialism/
socialist development, perhaps better seen in their view as authoritarian nationalist
rather than socially emancipatory projects (and in any case premature until the
fullest global development of capitalism is realised?). There is also a key, and strik-
ing, step in their historical argument: that while development was invented as a
response to (early) capitalist industrialisation and its characteristic disorder
that is, when an immanent process of accumulation and growth was given it
was then imposed on Britains vast colonial domains as a type of anticipatory
social engineering: the engineering of growth in ways, and at rates, compatible
with social order.
48 African Studies 65: 1, July 2006
D
o
w
n
l
o
a
d
e
d

b
y

[
2
4
.
1
2
7
.
3
1
.
9
7
]

a
t

1
0
:
3
3

1
1

N
o
v
e
m
b
e
r

2
0
1
3

Examples of this include their account (Cowen and Shenton 1996:4256) of the
ideas and legacy of James Mill (17731836), a signicant political economist,
ofcer of the East India Company, and one of a long line of British writers
who addressed the question of India as a codicil of the European invention of
development; and their notion of Fabian colonialism (Cowen and Shenton
1991a; see also their 1991b). This suggests how British colonialism in Africa
sought to achieve a trusteeship that could deliver economic progress without
social and political disruption, that could gradually introduce Africans to the pro-
duction and consumption of commodities as the material foundation of civilisation
while maintaining or adapting customary bases of order (rural community,
tribal identity and cohesion, patriarchal and chiey authority). Africans were
not, therefore, to be allowed any immediate and unbridled enjoyment of such
bourgeois rights as private title in land and access to bank credit, which could
stimulate a dangerous individualism on one hand, and on the other hand collective
action by colonial subjects on the basis of class interests. No doubt Cowen and
Shenton considered that such attempts to combine progress with order in fact con-
strain progress in the sense disclosed by immanent capitalist development, and
that this constraint on accumulation is intrinsic to all policies and practices
informed by doctrines of development, after political independence as well as
during colonial rule.
As implied above, the effect of this stance is to displace any consideration by
Cowen and Shenton of developmental states committed to driving a programme
of accumulation, industrialisation and economic growth rather than, or above, any
other goal(s). A recent article by Pablo Idahosa and Bob Shenton seems to expand
the historical frame of reference of the invention of development/doctrines of
development in an overview of attempt(s) to forestall European domination
through a self-conscious project of national development that entailed state
modernisation in nineteenth-century Africa: Egypt, Ethiopia, Tunisia, the
Merina kingdom of Madagascar, Asante, and South Africa before the mineral
revolution (Idahosa and Shenton 2004:76, and 7281 passim). However, all the
cases surveyed, except that of South Africa, were abortive attempts at national
development ended by colonial conquest and rule (ibid:789), and the
authors more general scepticism about developmental states is evident.
The point I wish to make is quite simple but has a broad historical resonance. It is
that a self-conscious project of national development pursued by various would-
be modernising regimes in the conditions of an internationalising economic and
political system in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries could, and did, generate
other forms of development doctrine centred, quite explicitly, on buildingthe sover-
eignty and power of states. This included a growing recognition that, in an era of
industrialisation, international political and military strength rested on the absolute
and relative economic strength commanded by states and their ability to acquire
advanced weaponry (preferably by establishing the capacity to design and manu-
facture it).
5
It is strikingin howmanycases the primary reference of suchaspirations
Studying Development/Development Studies 49
D
o
w
n
l
o
a
d
e
d

b
y

[
2
4
.
1
2
7
.
3
1
.
9
7
]

a
t

1
0
:
3
3

1
1

N
o
v
e
m
b
e
r

2
0
1
3

to modernisation from Peter the Great in the early eighteenth century to the
nineteenth-century African examples adduced by Idahosa and Shenton or the
Tanzimat reforms of the Ottoman rulers was the acquisition of (modern,
Western) education and knowledge, and especially the scientic and technical
knowledge manifested in military engineering. The most compelling of
nineteenth-century instances, of course, is that of Meiji Japan the rst undeniably
successful developmental state of the era of industrial capitalism, surely, and one
with scant regard for any doctrine of development centred on amelioration?
What I take from Kitchings, and Cowen and Shentons, valuable long histories
of ideas about development is the various ways in which the centrality of accumu-
lation to modern economic growth has been perceived and acted on including
resisted both ideologically and practically in the various times and places,
moments and sites, of the formation of the modern world over, say, the last 250
years. This dynamic has generated various doctrines of development from the
late eighteenth century rather than, I suggest, the single genus identied by
Cowen and Shenton.
6
That centrality of accumulation, with all its ramied con-
ditions and consequences, and its manifestations in the socially and spatially
combined and uneven development of capitalism, remains the starting point
for studying development. Paths of accumulation, their successes and failures,
are inextricably bound up with contradictory social relations of class, of gender,
of town and countryside, of ethnicity and nationality, of all the characteristic
dimensions of capitalist divisions of labour; with the struggles those divisions
and contradictions generate over property and power, production and productivity,
livelihood, social justice and dignity; and with the forms of social agency and col-
lective action, and their effectiveness, that those struggles pit against each other,
create and transform.
Two further points deserve emphasis because of their salience to more recent and
current preoccupations in development as both doctrine and eld of study, which
I turn to next. One is to suggest that the original sources of the great tradition in
classical political economy conceptualised processes of modern economic growth
qua accumulation, the development of markets (commodication) and of social
and technical divisions of labour, and so on above all as the growth (and
indeed formation) of national economies: Adam Smiths wealth of nations,
Marxs country that is more developed industrially (cited above), and Lenins
Development of Capitalism in Russia (1964/1899) the fullest study in classic
Marxism of contemporary processes of capitalist development in a backward
country that proceeds with virtually no reference to the international capitalist
economy in which late Tsarist Russia was located (and by which in effect its back-
wardness was dened) nor to its effects for capitalist development in Russia
(Bernstein 2004:202, n22).
7
Of course, Marx was profoundly aware of the
world historical character of capital, and of the growing importance of inter-
national trade when he wrote, but he left little theorisation of capitalism as
world system or international division of labour. And Lenin, to meet the political
50 African Studies 65: 1, July 2006
D
o
w
n
l
o
a
d
e
d

b
y

[
2
4
.
1
2
7
.
3
1
.
9
7
]

a
t

1
0
:
3
3

1
1

N
o
v
e
m
b
e
r

2
0
1
3

imperative of addressing the causes of the First World War, famously theorised
imperialism and the centrality to it of a nance capital now much evolved institu-
tionally since Marxs time. Lenins Imperialism (1964/1917) arguably generated
more ideological heat for anti-imperialist struggles than it cast analytical light on
the functioning of the capitalist world economy and the prospects of development
in its vast colonial and quasi-colonial peripheries. The consideration of those
prospects became much more explicitly international in the period after the
Second World War in the context of, rst, decolonisation in Asia and Africa
and superpower rivalry, and then in the context of globalisation (see below).
The other point is the absence so far in this exposition of any convincing example
of Alan Thomass rst sense of development as vision, description or measure of
the state of being of a desirable society (see below). This is partly an effect of my
selection of Kitching and Cowen and Shenton as guides to the long history of
development ideas, with their shared emphasis on typically painful processes of
primary accumulation, whether immanent or intentional, required to provide
the material foundations for a desirable society. Moreover, visions of a desirable
society whether populist, nationalist, or self-styled socialist that seek to
circumvent the compelling disciplines of accumulation and to deliver the fruits
of development before their material basis is assured are, in the view of these
authors, utopian and destructive of prospects of a better life, especially for those
(the poor, the people, the nation, workers and peasants) in whose name
their promises are articulated.
8
On the historical canvas so broadly (and roughly) sketched here, I want only to point
to Gareth Stedman Jones recent An End to Poverty? (2004) which brings to light
the rst debates . . . about the possibility of a world without poverty. Those debates
occurred in the late eighteenth century, that is, more or less contemporaneously with
the initial theorisation of the old orthodoxy (Kitching) and invention of develop-
ment (Cowen and Shenton). The key gures were Thomas Paine (17371809) and
Antoine-Nicolas de Condorcet (17621794),
9
representatives of a distinctively
modern form of radicalism (ibid:42) inspired by the experiences of the American
and French Revolutions, who argued for a comprehensive systemof social security
based on universal entitlements and funded by redistributive taxation. The wealth to
support this system that would end poverty and its attendant insecurities and indig-
nities (of which Paine was so eloquent a critic) was generated by the growth model
of AdamSmiths commercial society; howit could do so was worked out through
Condorcets revolutionary social mathematics. Stedman Jones argues that these
ideas were lost in the reaction that followed the French revolution and, after a
long political hiatus, were nally realised in the welfare state of the twentieth
century; in his view, they nowneed to be incorporated in a revived, and combative,
social democratic programme able to confront the global barbarities of contempor-
ary neo-liberalism. This, then, is one vision of a desirable society, rst articulated
together with a method for measuring well being and modelling the scal means
of achieving it, relevant to studying development today.
10
Studying Development/Development Studies 51
D
o
w
n
l
o
a
d
e
d

b
y

[
2
4
.
1
2
7
.
3
1
.
9
7
]

a
t

1
0
:
3
3

1
1

N
o
v
e
m
b
e
r

2
0
1
3

Development studies
The conjuncture after the Second World War inherited doctrines of development,
and their associated institutions and practices, invented and applied to manage
class (and other social) conict in industrial capitalist heartlands and colonial per-
ipheries and to formulate projects of national accumulation, state modernis-
ation, and the like. However, in post-war conditions the rhetoric of development
now centred much more emphatically on the kind of vision of a desirable
society rst constructed in distinctively modern fashion by Paine and Condorcet.
The principal goal was now to overcome poverty, ignorance and disease (in a
common catchphrase of the 1950s) through appropriate strategies of growth,
distribution and the provision of public goods. National development thus
centred on the welfare of all citizens became the ofcial programme of the
newly independent states of Asia and Africa, whose decolonisation provided
one vital terrain among others of rivalry between the USA and USSR. In pursuing
their rivalry in the Third World the USA and USSR established as super-
powers by the outcome of the Second World War claimed the superiority of
their own socioeconomic systems, and paths of development, as models for less
developed countries to emulate with the support of nancial and technical assist-
ance (foreign aid). In this context, then, not only did the rhetoric of development
doctrine shift towards visions of a desirable society encompassing in their opti-
mism and ideological currency, but the institutional apparatus of development
expanded, in part through a novel internationalisation of its agencies (in the
United Nations and Bretton Woods systems, as well as new forms of inter-state
association generated by superpower rivalry).
In short, here is one connection between the two points indicated at the end of the
previous section: the extension of development doctrine to creating the conditions
of well being of all citizens (and as quickly as possible) and the internationalisa-
tion of this vision and of efforts to achieve it. In fact, the context following the end
of the Second World War, just outlined, encouraged approaches to development
more explicitly and rmly rooted in questions about its international conditions.
These approaches assimilated the key themes of the great tradition
transformations of pre-capitalist agrarian structures, patterns of accumulation
and industrialisation, state modernisation and technical change, and the like,
within individual countries to how the prospects of progress in poor countries
are affected by the functioning of international markets, divisions of labour,
ows of capital and technology, and other aspects of a world economy, and like-
wise by the structures and dynamics of an international political system shaped by
superpower rivalry and the novel strategic importance it gave to (some) newly
independent poor countries.
This global political and intellectual context was key to the emergence of devel-
opment studies as an academic eld. I nd it useful to employ a restrictive or insti-
tutional denition of development studies as the kinds of teaching and research
52 African Studies 65: 1, July 2006
D
o
w
n
l
o
a
d
e
d

b
y

[
2
4
.
1
2
7
.
3
1
.
9
7
]

a
t

1
0
:
3
3

1
1

N
o
v
e
m
b
e
r

2
0
1
3

done in university development studies departments, centres, institutes and so on,
that is, as sites of an academic specialism of recent provenance (in fact, mostly
since the 1960s).
11
The reason is that this enables exploration of whether, how
and how much development studies is able to connect with, draw on, and
indeed contribute to, the great tradition of studying development. Certainly,
what justies development studies as a specialism in its own right is the presump-
tion that it is dedicated and equipped to generate applied knowledge in the formu-
lation and implementation of development policies and interventions. In short, and
as Thomas (2000) rightly observes, the notion of development studies is imbued
with the intent to develop at the core of Cowen and Shentons theorisation of
doctrines of development. As policy science development studies is centred
on two sets of issues: those of economic growth and how to promote it, and of
poverty and how to overcome it, principally in what is now known as the
(global) South. Virtually all intellectual production in the name of development
studies can be assimilated to one or other of these two overarching goals or,
most characteristically, claims to connect them in virtuous models or paths of
development.
Elsewhere (Bernstein 2005) I have sketched two main periods in the career of
development studies in the sense outlined, which I summarise here in (regrettably)
even more truncated form. The rst is that of its founding moment (in the 1950s
and 1960s) in the global context indicated, also the golden period of the long
boom of the capitalist world economy marked by a labour-friendly (for rich
countries) and development-friendly (for poor countries) international regime
established under US hegemony (Silver and Arrighi 2000:55) at least friendly
relative to what was to come later. This founding moment of development studies
was able to ask big questions about development, and to pursue big ideas in
seeking to answer them, in part because of the stimulus of apparently world-
historical alternatives, and in part because of an assumption that the state in
newly independent (and other poor) countries had a central role in planning and
managing economic and social development. This assumption held across a
very wide range of the political and ideological spectrum, albeit with a marked
inuence of social democratic ideas associated with a structuralist macroeco-
nomics and a kind of international Keynesianism applied to issues of aid and
trade. Both were aspects of what was now identied as development economics,
to various degrees linked to, and informed by, the great tradition of studying
development and its foundation in political economy.
12
Of course, attempts to draw on that expansive intellectual tradition for the applied
tasks of policy advice and design with which development studies was charged
often generated various tensions and confronted various (political) constraints,
including in relations with the governments and aid agencies that established
development studies centres and institutes in the 1950s and 1960s and/or
supported them with contracts for advanced training, applied research and
consultancy. Nor was this new profession of development studies staffed entirely
Studying Development/Development Studies 53
D
o
w
n
l
o
a
d
e
d

b
y

[
2
4
.
1
2
7
.
3
1
.
9
7
]

a
t

1
0
:
3
3

1
1

N
o
v
e
m
b
e
r

2
0
1
3

by intellectual adepts of the great tradition; it also accommodated, for example,
the redeployment of former colonial ofcials (notably in Britain, France, Belgium
and the Netherlands). This represented one type of continuity with the practices of
previous doctrines of development (on which see the post-colonial argument of
Kothari 2005)
13
; a more strategic continuity is argued for some of the practices
and politics of colonial development regimes in India following independence
(for example Bose 1997, Chatterjee 1998) and in the independent states of sub-
Saharan Africa (for example Cooper 2002, especially Ch 5).
If the record of development studies, even in the more heroic rst phase of its
career, is much more mixed, ambiguous and imbued with tension than can be
traced here, what of the apparent puzzle of its (almost) seamless shift to a
second phase under the neo-liberal ascendance since the 1980s? Both champions
and critics of the newly established development studies shared an understanding
that its principal rationale as policy science was to nd ways of assisting state-led
development. As neo-liberalism quickly gained a hegemonic position in develop-
ment theory and policy from the 1980s, manifested in the supremacy of the World
Bank in the production of contemporary development doctrine (see Moore, in
press), and in a context of now virtually unchallenged capitalist globalisation,
the question arose whether development studies retained any purpose. This
question made sense, and yet development studies has not disappeared with the
withering away of state-led development (if hardly of the state). This is explicable
in part by what I have characterised as a double paradox, whereby less becomes
more and more becomes less (Bernstein 2005).
The rst paradox is that less intervention as prescribed in neo-liberal development
theory means more intervention in practice. First, the major shifts of development
theory, policy discourse and design, and modalities of intervention in the period of
neo-liberal ascendance, spearheaded by the World Bank, require a great deal of
work to replace what preceded them in the period of state-led development.
14
And the intellectual and political labour of deconstruction requires a greater prac-
tical labour of reconstruction, from the demands of legitimation by intellectual and
technical expertise including presenting claims to better results of neo-liberal
policies to the design and implementation (policing?) of structural adjustment
packages to the nuts and bolts of reforming particular institutions and practices.
Second, after a brief initial moment of market triumphalism in the early 1980s (get
the prices right and all else will follow: growth, prosperity, and stability), it
became evident that a few decisive strokes of policy to roll back states and liberate
markets was not enough to achieve accelerated economic growth and reduce
poverty. Freeing the market to carry out the tasks of economic growth for
which it is deemed uniquely suited rapidly escalated into an extraordinarily ambi-
tious, or grandiose, project of social engineering that amounts to establishing
bourgeois civilisation on a global scale. Comprehensive market reform confronted
similarly comprehensive state reform (rather than simply contraction) as a
54 African Studies 65: 1, July 2006
D
o
w
n
l
o
a
d
e
d

b
y

[
2
4
.
1
2
7
.
3
1
.
9
7
]

a
t

1
0
:
3
3

1
1

N
o
v
e
m
b
e
r

2
0
1
3

condition of the former; in turn, the pursuit of good governance quickly extended
to, and embraced, notions of civil society and social institutions more generally.
In short, the terrain of development discourse and the range of aid-funded
interventions have become ever more inclusive to encompass the reshaping, or
transformation, of political and social (and, by implication, cultural) as well as
economic institutions and practices.
The scope of development studies has thus expanded greatly, in line with the
agenda of development doctrine orchestrated by the World Bank and the
agenda of international security under US hegemony in a post-Soviet world.
That expansion of objects of intervention has proceeded principally by agglomera-
tion. To what may be considered the constant preoccupations of development
theory for example, in international economics (trade, investment, and
today above all? capital markets), macroeconomics (exchange, interest,
ination and savings rates, employment, productivity), and social policy (health,
education) are added state reform, the (re)design and management of public
institutions, clear and properly enforced property rights, democratisation, civil
society and the sources of social capital, small-scale credit, non-governmental
organisation (NGO) management, (environmentally) sustainable development,
women/gender and development, children and development, refugees and
development, humanitarian emergencies and interventions, and post-conict
resolution (among other examples).
At the same time, more becomes less as the (market-centred) core of this
expanded agenda is framed, and its key policies justied, above all through the
restrictive framework of neo-classical economics, whose hegemony has spiralled
during this period of rampant neo-liberalism.
15
On the other hand, the supply of
various practitioners demanded by the expanded range of development interven-
tions indicated for example, experts in public administration or those dealing
with the soft areas of welfare, community-level and other self-help interven-
tions
16
does not require or encourage any broader intellectual vision, rationale
or formation (only the profession of economist requires an academic training of
any rigour, albeit within its extremely narrow and technicist intellectual culture.)
In the founding moment of development studies, key questions of development
strategy were framed within serious attempts, from different viewpoints and yield-
ing different interpretations, to understand the massive upheavals that created the
contemporary world and continued to shape it.
17
This is now displaced intellec-
tually by the most narrow (and ahistorical) of approaches in economics and ideo-
logically by such notions as pro-poor (market) growth, which expresses nicely
the commitment of contemporary development doctrine to win-win solutions
and its faith that an inclusive and globalising market economy, or more
broadly bourgeois civilisation, contains no intrinsic obstacles to a better life for
all. There is so much to gain with relatively little pain; the only losers will be
rent seekers and others who fail to play by the rules of the game.
18
Studying Development/Development Studies 55
D
o
w
n
l
o
a
d
e
d

b
y

[
2
4
.
1
2
7
.
3
1
.
9
7
]

a
t

1
0
:
3
3

1
1

N
o
v
e
m
b
e
r

2
0
1
3

The commitment to such win-win policy solutions to continuing problems of
economic growth and poverty imposes another kind of constraint on (or reduction
of) the intellectual spaces of development studies. It is the credo of what Ferguson
(1990) memorably termed an anti-politics machine that depoliticises develop-
ment doctrine, and marginalises or displaces investigation and understanding of
the sources, dynamics and effects of typically savage social inequality in the
South, and of no less savage relations of power and inequality in the international
economic and political system. It elides consideration of the often violent social
upheavals and struggles that characterise the processes and outcomes of the
development of capitalism.
Studying development/development studies
What I have termed here the great tradition of studying development is rooted
intellectually in political economy (if not exclusively so); is consistently moder-
nist; and is intrinsically historical indeed it can not be thought, to use an
Althusserian expression, other than in intrinsically historical terms. It provides a
frame of reference, a set of themes, and a wealth of ideas and interpretations, con-
testations and debates, across the main social science disciplines, including history
and especially economic history perhaps.
19
How well its themes and debates, its
intellectually expansive and politically contentious character, can be accommo-
dated within development studies as a recent academic specialism and branch
of policy science, justied by the intent to development, is another matter.
How much it has been accommodated is, to a large degree, an empirical question
to which we cannot expect any single or simple answer. I have suggested,
however, that it is more difcult to ensure knowledge of the great tradition and
appreciation of its contemporary relevance in the current phase of the academic
career of development studies, for several kinds of reasons.
The rst and most fundamental reason is the economic and political changes in the
world in the last thirty years or so, including those often associated with globali-
sation (the unprecedented freedom and scale of mobility of capital), the demise of
state socialism, and the political and ideological power of a neo-liberalism that
presents itself as the common sense of the epoch. Indeed achieving that effect
is, in a profound sense, the function of much ideological and intellectual pro-
duction, which indicates a second kind of reason. In relation to the social sciences,
a pincer movement of the imperialising ambitions of neo-classical economics and
of post-modernism (broadly dened) assaults the great traditions of social
science, including that of studying development. Moreover, the two arms of this
pincer movement exhibit a perverse complementarity, partly indicated by their
shared antipathy to properly historical explanation.
20
A third, more proximate, reason is how the larger changes indicated of econ-
omic and political forces and their effects for the conditions and tendencies of
ideological and intellectual production affect the organisation and fortunes of
56 African Studies 65: 1, July 2006
D
o
w
n
l
o
a
d
e
d

b
y

[
2
4
.
1
2
7
.
3
1
.
9
7
]

a
t

1
0
:
3
3

1
1

N
o
v
e
m
b
e
r

2
0
1
3

the academy. This is also (and inevitably) an uneven process, because of the very
different institutional histories of universities, and of the types and degrees of
pressure that can be effectively imposed on them by public policy especially,
of course, where government principally funds universities. In the United
Kingdom, and I suspect elsewhere, the generally increasing bite of value for
money agendas in university modernisation combines with the demand of
(ofcial) aid agencies for applied research informed by a neo-liberal agenda, to
exacerbate the tensions between intellectual and practical objectives inherent
to development studies to the detriment of the former.
How much does this matter? Bill Freund contends that development studies as a
university subject (must) contain a non-applied theoretical, political, sociological
and historical aspect (personal communication).
21
This, of course, resonates and
upholds the purpose and scope of the great tradition of studying development.
My response is that to champion the substance of that view and to pursue its
intellectual commitment is a challenge across the social sciences more generally,
given todays pressures on the spaces and opportunities for social science scholar-
ship that is independently minded or in insufcient demand in the higher education
marketplace,
22
let alone that is overtly critical and seeks to connect with opposi-
tional forms of politics, for example, the public sociology advocated by Michael
Burawoy (2004a). Burawoy (2004b) has extended his discussion to South Africa
to consider the dilemmas faced by a tradition of oppositional and activist
sociology in the face of the normalisation of university life after apartheid,
and the demands it imposes in line with (generally conservative) public policy
reform almost everywhere (see also Webster 2004).
I am sceptical that development studies today offers much space and opportunity
for critical scholarship in the great tradition of studying development, for the
reasons given above and however much one might wish it were otherwise.
And here it is worth noting the particular, indeed unique, achievement of Bill
Freund in creating what must have been the only department of economic
history and development studies in the world, where he was able to exemplify
the teaching and study of development within the great tradition of comparative
history informed by political economy (and has continued to do so). However,
and symptomatically of the wider issues considered here, later a wholly separate
School of Development Studies (SODS) was established in the same university on
the back of a professional or applied Masters programme in development
(together with applied research and consultancy).
23
It remains my view, then, that the concerns and intellectual commitments exem-
plied by Bill Freund as student of development are better engaged with on the
more general terrain of the social sciences and the ample horizons of its battle-
elds. Here is where I would locate a William Freund Institute for the Study of
Development, whose agenda could be informed by such instructive reections
on studying development as those by Leys (1996), Sutcliffe (1999), Thomas
Studying Development/Development Studies 57
D
o
w
n
l
o
a
d
e
d

b
y

[
2
4
.
1
2
7
.
3
1
.
9
7
]

a
t

1
0
:
3
3

1
1

N
o
v
e
m
b
e
r

2
0
1
3

(2000) and Chang (2003) that I have cited.
24
Development studies under which
name (ag of convenience?) Bill was able to establish a wholly exceptional
enclave for a while (because it was so personal an invention and preserve?) is
today too restricted, incoherent and ckle an academic entity to offer a convincing
space for contemplating, renewing and advancing the great tradition of studying
development.
Notes
1. It is tting that this festschrift includes Fred Cooper and Bob Shenton, historians of Africa who
have also made major contributions to our understanding of ideas and practices of develop-
ment. It is also gratifying that the historians of doctrines of development on whom I draw
below, in addition to Bob Shenton, also produced original and signicant historical research
on Africa, namely Michael Cowen and Gavin Kitching who both worked on Central Province,
Kenya.
2. Or, in full Comtean vein: Development was the means by which progress would be subsumed
by order (Cowen and Shenton 1995:34).
3. In fact, Thomas (2000) structures the argument of his thoughtful essay on the condition of
Development Studies today around Cowen and Shentons distinction between immanent and
intentional development.
4. Development doctrine thus sometimes seems close to what was called the social problem in
Britain and mainland western Europe during the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries,
namely how to remove the hostility of the working classes towards private property or to over-
come the antagonism between labour and capital through some form of amelioration of the
social misery that Cowen and Shenton point to (Stedman Jones 2004:224, and Ch 6
Resolving The Social Problem).
5. See the masterly synthesis and interpretation of Kennedy (1989), especially chapter 4 on
Industrialization and the Shifting Global Balances, 181585, the key period of the examples
noted here. My colleague Chris Cramer (personal communication) points out the absence of
military factors and concerns in Ha-Joon Changs otherwise illuminating historical survey
(2002) of the centrality of state action to the economic development of the industrial capitalist
powers.
6. Albeit traced and analysed by them in far greater depth and detail, and with far greater benet,
than can be adequately conveyed here; the value of their argument in reminding us of the cen-
trality of questions of order to doctrines of development (in however implicit a fashion) is dif-
cult to overstate (see note 18 below).
7. I have argued elsewhere that the agrarian question of classic Marxism, and debates among
Marxist historians on the original transition(s) to agrarian capitalism in north-western
Europe, employ an internalist framework, the effects of which are especially problematic
when that understanding of the agrarian question is deployed to analyse development in the
contemporary South (Bernstein 1996; also 2004).
8. A theme continued with even more overt provocation in Gavin Kitchings book on development
and (through?) globalization (2001), which is a kind of sequel to his earlier book cited here.
9. Condorcet after he dropped the de.
10. On which see Stedman Jones article A history of ending poverty in The Guardian (London)
of 2 July 2005, where he addresses the Making Poverty History campaign and its topical dra-
matisations of sub-Saharan Africa by emphasising the radical insistence of Paine and Condorcet
on entitlement as opposed to charity. Seers (1969) is a classic statement of a social democratic
meaning of development in what I call below the founding moment of development studies.
58 African Studies 65: 1, July 2006
D
o
w
n
l
o
a
d
e
d

b
y

[
2
4
.
1
2
7
.
3
1
.
9
7
]

a
t

1
0
:
3
3

1
1

N
o
v
e
m
b
e
r

2
0
1
3

11. Although the conception of development studies extends beyond academic entities that bear
the name. Its establishment and prole as a distinct academic eld in the South may have been
patchy because national development, and how best to achieve it, was the principal preoccu-
pation across social science departments and institutes in Asian and African universities follow-
ing political independence, as to a large extent in Latin America. At one time to be an
economist, say, in India or Tanzania or Chile was, in effect, to be a development economist.
12. My view of the intellectual range of vision and vitality of the founding moment of development
studies is more positive than that of Colin Leys in the magisterial title essay of his Rise and Fall
of Development Theory (1996). Dudley Seers (see note 11) had a key institutional as well as
intellectual role in Britain as the founding director of the Institute of Development Studies at
the University of Sussex.
13. In my own experience of development studies in Britain the characteristic, and defensive,
stance of most such colonial veterans, former District Ofcers and the like, was an ideology
of practicality and anti-intellectualism.
14. What needed replacement included the contributions of the Bank and other donors to the debris
of that period, produced inter alia by the incoherence of aid policies and practices and the
frustrations and tensions generated by their results.
15. Including the latest ambitions of its theorists to subsume much of the agenda of sociological and
political inquiry within the paradigm of neo-classical economics (Fine 2002).
16. Where NGO activity concentrates and the jargon of participation, empowerment, stake-
holders and the like is most pervasive, along with tendencies to celebrate the local and
indigenous: the Gemeinschaftlichkeit (community-ness) of the natives once more?
17. Indeed, it can be argued that notions of development strategy of any substantive content are
largely absent from the intellectual framework of neo-liberal policy science. What has
been largely abandoned from the founding moment of development studies is that central atten-
tion to issues of economic planning, public investment and accumulation, together with the
expansive conceptions of public goods with which they were then associated. In effect, there
is now no intellectually legitimate basis for a development economics, only a universal econ-
omics of maximising behaviour. Ha-Joon Chang is among the most prolic and incisive
champions today of reviving and reinstating development economics (Chang 2003).
18. Those who fail to play by the rules are criminalised by the discourse, in effect; rent-seekers, for
example, are associated with corruption, while social actors and practices that disturb the social
and political order of an emergent global bourgeois civilisation exemplify criminal violence. A
recent addition to the concerns of development studies stimulated, funded and steered by aid
donors is the area of state collapse, crisis states, and so on. In a provocative book, Dufeld
(2001) explores the connections between development doctrine and global order/security.
19. Bill Freund (1996:128) has observed that economic history is probably more capable (than
other branches of history) of explaining the constraints and limitations, the range of the
possible that development has taken, a proposition that is explored and illustrated in the over-
view his article provides.
20. Fred Cooper and Randall Packard (1997:3) suggest that The ultramodernist [by which they
mean neo-liberal] and the postmodernist critiques have a lot in common, especially their
abstractions from the institutions and structures in which economic action takes place and
which shape a power-knowledge regime. The ultramodernists see power only as a removable
distortion to an otherwise self-regulating market. The postmodernists locate the power-
knowledge regime in a vaguely dened West or in the alleged claims of European social
science to have found universal categories for understanding and manipulating social life
everywhere.
21. The other side of this coin is his question: How can you sustain a discipline teaching stuff
like poverty alleviation or an introduction to current buzzwords or survey techniques?
(same source). Indeed, but if theres buoyant demand for professional staff from aid agencies
Studying Development/Development Studies 59
D
o
w
n
l
o
a
d
e
d

b
y

[
2
4
.
1
2
7
.
3
1
.
9
7
]

a
t

1
0
:
3
3

1
1

N
o
v
e
m
b
e
r

2
0
1
3

with an expanded agenda of interventions (illustrated above), and a plentiful supply of recruits
who want to make careers in development, hence need to know how to alleviate poverty (!) as
well as how to use the latest buzzwords uently (talk the talk) . . . ? For advanced buzzword
capacity see the portrait of Jim Fingers Adams, spin doctor to World Bank president Hardwick
Hardwicke, in Michael Holmans contemporary satire (2005).
22. In the context of this festschrift, it is sobering to note that there remains only one department
of economic history at a British university (at the London School of Economics); on the
fortunes of economic history as an academic discipline in Britain, see Negley Hartes
cameo account of The Economic History Society, 19262001 on the Societys website
(www.ehs.org.uk); also Peter Wardleys review of The Oxford Encyclopaedia of Economic
History in the Times Higher Education Supplement, 29 October 2004 (Outlook poor for a
once rich group).
23. This is not to say that SODS (where some of my best friends . . . ) is dominated by a rampant
neo-liberal agenda, but it does confront global dilemmas in a broadly similar manner to soci-
ology in South Africa as indicated by Burawoy (above). Those dilemmas in part stem from
having to negotiate with ofcial agencies (both national and international) that dene current
development doctrine in ways that shape how it is taught in academic development studies.
Non-applied theoretical, political, sociological and historical aspect(s) of the intellectually
serious study of development are not priorities in that curriculum and indeed may be seen
as obstructive of the proper training of development professionals who will be judged
(ostensibly) on their ability to deliver.
24. On the analogy of a Wolpe Institute of Social Theory imagined by Michael Burawoy in his 2004
lecture From Liberation to Reconstruction: Theory and Practice in the Life of Harold Wolpe,
the full text of which can be found on the website of the Harold Wolpe Memorial Trust
(www.wolpetrust.org.za).
References
Bernstein, H. 1996. Agrarian Questions Then and Now, in H. Bernstein and T. Brass
(eds), Agrarian Questions: Essays in Appreciation of T. J. Byres. London: Frank Cass,
pp 2259.
2004. Changing Before Our Very Eyes: Agrarian Questions and the Politics of
Land in Capitalism today. Journal of Agrarian Change 4(34), special issue on Redis-
tributive Land Reform Today T. J. Byres (ed):190225.
2005. Development Studies and the Marxists, in U. Kothari (ed), A Radical History
of Development Studies: Individuals, Institutions and Ideologies. London: Zed Books,
pp 111137.
Bose, S. 1997. Instruments and Idioms of Colonial and National Development: Indias
Historical Experience in Comparative Perspective, in F. Cooper and R. Packard (eds),
International Development and the Social Sciences. Essays on the History and Politics
of Knowledge. Berkeley: University of California Press, pp 4563.
Burawoy, M. 2004a. Public Sociologies: Contradictions, Dilemmas, and Possibilities.
Social Forces 82:16031618.
2004b. Public Sociology: South African Dilemmas in a Global Context. Society in
Transition 35:1126.
60 African Studies 65: 1, July 2006
D
o
w
n
l
o
a
d
e
d

b
y

[
2
4
.
1
2
7
.
3
1
.
9
7
]

a
t

1
0
:
3
3

1
1

N
o
v
e
m
b
e
r

2
0
1
3

Chang, H.-J. 2002. Kicking Away The Ladder. Development Strategy in Historical
Perspective. London: Anthem Press.
(ed) 2003. Rethinking Development Economics: London: Anthem Press.
Chatterjee, P. 1998. Development Planning and the Indian State, in T. J. Byres (ed), The
State, Development Planning and Liberalisation in India. Delhi: Oxford University Press,
pp 82103.
Cooper, F. 2002. Africa Since 1940. The Past of the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Cooper, F. and Packard, R. 1997. Introduction, in F. Cooper and R. Packard (eds),
International Development and the Social Sciences. Essays on the History and Politics
of Knowledge (eds). Berkeley: University of California Press, pp 141.
Corrigan, P., Ramsay, H. and Sayer, D. 1978. Socialist Construction and Marxist Theory.
Bolshevism and its Critique. London: Macmillan.
1979. For Mao. Essays in Historical Materialism. London: Macmillan.
Cowen, M.P. and Shenton, R.W. 1991a. The Origin and Course of Fabian Colonialism in
Africa. Journal of Historical Sociology 4(2):14374.
1991b. Bankers, Peasants and Land in British West Africa 19051937. Journal of
Peasant Studies 19(1):2658.
1995. The Invention of Development, in J. Crush (ed), Power of Development.
London: Routledge, pp 2743.
1996. Doctrines of Development. London: Routledge.
Dufeld, M. 2001. Global Governance and the New Wars. The Merging of Development
and Security. London: Zed Books.
Ferguson, J. 1990. The Anti-Politics Machine: Development, Depoliticization and
Bureaucratic Power in Lesotho. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Fine, B. 2002. Economics Imperialism and the New Development Economics as Kuhnian
Paradigm Shift? World Development 30:20572070.
Freund, W.M. 1996. Economic History in South Africa: An Introductory Overview.
South African Historical Journal 34:127150.
Holman, M. 2005. Last Order at Harrods: An African Tale. Edinburgh: Polygon.
Idahosa, P.E.L. and Shenton, B. 2004. The Africanists New Clothes. Historical
Materialism 12(4):67113.
Kitching, G. 1982. Development and Underdevelopment in Historical Perspective:
Populism, Nationalism and Industrialization. London: Methuen.
Kitching, G. 2001. Seeking Social Justice through Globalization. Escaping a Nationalist
Perspective. University Park PA: Pennsylvania State University Press.
Studying Development/Development Studies 61
D
o
w
n
l
o
a
d
e
d

b
y

[
2
4
.
1
2
7
.
3
1
.
9
7
]

a
t

1
0
:
3
3

1
1

N
o
v
e
m
b
e
r

2
0
1
3

Kothari, U. 2005. From Colonial Administration to Development Studies: A Post-
Colonial Critique of the History of Development Studies, in U. Kothari (ed), A
Radical History of Development Studies: Individuals, Institutions and Ideologies.
London: Zed Books, pp 4766.
Lenin, V.I. 1964/1899. The Development of Capitalism in Russia. Collected Works,
Vol 3. Moscow: Progress Publishers.
1964/1917. Imperialism, The Highest Stage of Capitalism. Collected Works, Vol 22.
Moscow: Progress Publishers.
Marx, K. 1976/1867. Capital, A Critique of Political Economy Vol 1. Harmondsworth:
Penguin Books.
Moore, D. (ed). In press. The World Bank: Constructing Hegemony or Alleviating
Poverty? Scottsville: University of KwaZulu-Natal Press.
Seers, D. 1969. The Meaning of Development. International Development Review
11(4):26.
Silver, B. and Arrighi, G. 2000. Workers North and South, in L. Panitch and C. Leys
(eds), The Socialist Register 2001. London: Merlin Press, pp 5376.
Sutcliffe, B. 1999. The Place of Development in Theories of Imperialism and
Globalization, in R. Munck and D. OHearn (eds), Critical Development Theory:
Contributions to a New Paradigm. London: Zed Books, pp 135153.
Thomas, A. 2000. Development as Practice in a Liberal Capitalist World. Journal of
International Development 12:773787.
Webster, E. 2004. Sociology in South Africa: Its Past, Present and Future. Society in
Transition 35:2741.
62 African Studies 65: 1, July 2006
D
o
w
n
l
o
a
d
e
d

b
y

[
2
4
.
1
2
7
.
3
1
.
9
7
]

a
t

1
0
:
3
3

1
1

N
o
v
e
m
b
e
r

2
0
1
3

Potrebbero piacerti anche