Sei sulla pagina 1di 12

No.

524 September 14, 2004 Routing

Three Myths about Voter Turnout


in the United States
by John Samples

Executive Summary

Critics of American politics and elections often Turnout is lower than in other developed
focus on low voter turnout in the United States. nations, but the United States has a different cul-
They argue that voter turnout is steadily declining ture and history than European nations that see
largely because of voter cynicism caused by big large majorities of their citizens go to the polls.
money campaigns and negative political advertis- European standards are not appropriate for judg-
ing. Voter turnout is lower than it was in the ing American turnout.
1960s, but almost the entire decline happened Critics of American politics have misunder-
between 1968 and 1974. Sophisticated and stood voter turnout in the United States. The
detailed studies of both public trust in govern- proposed remedies—limiting political liberty
ment and the consequences of political advertis- through restrictions on campaign finance and
ing show that neither factor has a negative effect on political advertising—are neither analytically
on voter turnout. sound nor necessary for a healthy body politic.

_____________________________________________________________________________________________________
John Samples is director of the Cato Institute’s Center for Representative Government.
Many nations in Introduction Has Turnout Steadily
Europe have Declined?
As the general election of 2004 approach-
higher voter es, critics of American politics will decry low Many people assume Americans are voting
turnout than the voter turnout in the United States. They will less and less, an assumption often repeated but
note that turnout in the United States has rarely examined. Some pundits have made a
United States. But steadily declined since the halcyon days of profession of studying and decrying the puta-
the differences the 1960s. Some critics will trace that puta- tive failure of Americans to live up to their polit-
between U.S. and tive decline to the baleful influence of “big ical obligations. Curtis Gans, an analyst often
money” on voters. The large sums raised and quoted on this issue, has written of America’s
European voting spent by both parties and their campaigns “disintegrating democracy” where “the nation
levels are not will be said to alienate voters and discourage that prides itself on being the best example of
necessarily a participation. After all, if campaign contribu- government of, for, and by the people is rapidly
tors run the show, why bother to vote? Other becoming a nation whose participation is limit-
problem. critics will argue that sharply critical advertis- ed to the interested or zealous few.”1
ing (so-called negative ads) discourages vot- Complaints about U.S. turnout come in
ing by fostering cynicism about the political two versions. Sometimes critics say that the
process. Some self-styled reformers will argue U.S. turnout is among the lowest in devel-
that the harm done to democracy by big oped nations. That is accurate. Many nations
money and negative ads justifies government in Europe have higher voter turnout than the
efforts to restrict campaign finance and to United States. But the differences between
regulate the tone of campaign commercials. U.S. and European voting levels are not nec-
In sum, critics believe the decline in voter essarily a problem. Why should the United
turnout is a sign of sickness in the body States be judged by European standards? We
politic and that limits on political liberty are have a different history and political culture
needed to save the patient. Fortunately, the than most of Europe. Government is smaller
critics’ diagnosis is wrong and their cure in the United States, and politics matters less
unnecessary. to the society and its citizens.

FFigure
igure 11
Turnout oof
Turnout f EEligible
ligible VVoters
oters ininPrPresidential
esidential EleElections,
ctions, 1941948–2000
8–2000
66
64
Eligible Voter Turnout (%)

62
60
58
56
54
52
50
1948 1952 1956 1960 1964 1968 1972 1976 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000
Year

McDonald, George
Source: Michael McDonald, George Mason
Mason University,
University, at
at http://elections.gmu.edu/voter_turnout.htm.
http://elections.gmu.edu/voter_turnout.htm.

2
But has turnout in the United States been turnout has followed two paths, one relative- Candidates,
steadily declining? Experts have traditionally ly high in the 1950s and 1960s and a lower parties, and
measured voter turnout by dividing the path after the mid-1970s. Turnout dropped
number of voters by some measure of poten- into the second, lower path between 1968 groups spend
tial voters. They have gauged potential voters and 1974. The trend since the mid-1970s has money to bring
by the voting age population of a state, a been flat or slightly downward.
number easily obtained from the U.S. Census The two paths of turnout provide a clue to
voters to the
Bureau. That procedure does paint a picture their cause. A cause of the decline must have polls, to stimu-
of a nation slowly abandoning the polls. either increased or decreased sharply from late turnout of
However, that way of measuring turnout is 1968 to 1974 and then have maintained that
misleading. larger or smaller value for the next 30 years. potential
Political scientist Michael McDonald has Campaign spending does not fit either sce- supporters, not
shown that the number of Americans actual- nario: spending has risen steadily since the suppress it.
ly eligible to vote has become progressively 1960s. As we shall see, negative advertising
smaller than the number of Americans of also has varied in ways that undermine the
voting age. In 2004, for example, McDonald belief that such communications have driven
estimates that the United States will have down turnout.
17.5 million people of voting age who are not
eligible to vote. In estimating voter turnout,
this difference changes everything. Campaign Finance and
Calculations based on eligible voters (not the Turnout
voting-age population) show that turnout in
presidential and off-year elections has Why would increases in campaign spend-
remained roughly flat for about 30 years ing cause declines in voter turnout? After all,
(Figures 1 and 2). candidates, parties, and groups spend money
McDonald confirms that voter turnout to bring voters to the polls. They spend
has gone down from its peak in the 1960s, money to stimulate turnout of potential sup-
though turnout has been higher than many porters, not suppress it. One might expect
experts have thought. However, the decline that more money would lead to higher, not
has not been slow and steady. Instead, lower, turnout.

Figure 22
Figure
Turnout oof
Turnout f EEligible
ligible VVoters
oters ininOOff-Year
ff-Year ElElections,
ections, 191948–2000
48–2000

49
Eligible Voter Turnout (%)

47
45
43
41
39
37
35
1950 1954 1958 1962 1966 1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002
Year

Source: Michael McDonald, George Mason University, at http://elections.gmu.edu/voter_turnout.htm.

3
FFigure
igure 33
T rust ininGGovernment,
Trust overnment, 191959–2000
59–2000

80

Percent Expressing High Trust in


70
60

Government
50
40
30
20
10
0
'58 '64 '66 '68 '70 '72 '74 '76 '78 '80 '82 '84 '86 '88 '90 '92 '94 '96 '98 '00
Year

Source: National Election Studies, Center for Political Studies, University of Michigan, The NES Guide to Public
Opinion and Electoral Behavior, 1995–2000, Table 5A.1, http://www.umich.edu/~nes/nesguide/nesguide.htm.

Campaign People concerned about voter turnout some of the time?”


argue that increases in campaign spending A response of “just about always” or
spending does not discourage voting by fostering cynicism. For “most of the time” shows high trust in the
correlate well example, a federal court recently argued that federal government.4 Since 1958 the propor-
“a failure to regulate the arena of campaign tion of Americans showing high trust in the
with public trust. finance allows the influence of wealthy indi- federal government has declined overall
viduals and corporations to drown out the (Figure 3).
voices of individual citizens,” leading to a Although the overall trend is downward,
“political system unresponsive to the needs trust in government has declined and risen
and desires of the public, and causing the pub- twice since 1958. The first decline began in
lic to become disillusioned with and mistrust- 1964 and ended in 1980; the second began in
ful of the political system.”2 The leader of 1984 and ended in 1994. Trust rose for a few
Common Cause told the Rules Committee of years after 1980 and has risen continuously
the U.S. Senate that “large contributions buy since 1994. Once again, campaign spending
access and influence in all aspects of legislative does not correlate well with public trust:
decision-making. And that is exactly why [citi- spending has risen continually since the early
zens] are becoming increasingly cynical about 1970s while trust has gone up and down.
their democracy,” which leads to declines in Soft money contributions, recently
voter turnout.3 The critics assert (1) that our banned by law, were said to be the epitome of
methods of financing campaigns lead to cyni- the influence of money on politics. The soft
cism and (2) that such distrust discourages money exception to federal election law came
voting. We focus on the first conjecture. about in 1979.5 Shortly thereafter, trust in
Over the past 40 years, the National government began to rise, which directly con-
Election Studies Center has asked the follow- tradicts the conjecture that “big money”
ing question every two years: “How much of causes distrust in government. Trust started
the time do you think you can trust the gov- downhill again in 1986 and continued to
ernment in Washington to do what is right— decline until 1994. The partisan of campaign
just about always, most of the time or only finance regulation might be tempted to con-

4
clude that the “abuses” of soft money became be that money has little if any effect on trust in
clear only in 1986 and along with the Iran- government?
Contra scandal caused a decline in trust. More sophisticated analyses support that
Unfortunately for that theory, soft money conclusion.11 The correlation coefficient
began to grow in 1995 when President between congressional spending on elections
Clinton and his advisers raised such contri- and trust in government from 1982 to 2000
butions to pay for an extensive advertising is about zero.12 We need not rely on general
campaign designed to prepare the ground for correlations alone. Several studies that con-
his reelection.6 In other words, just at the trol for other factors affecting trust in gov-
moment the alleged soft money “abuses” ernment have shown that campaign spend-
started, trust in government began to rise. In ing has little influence on public trust or effi-
general, if we look at soft money spending in cacy (the belief that citizens can make a dif-
presidential election years, we find a positive ference in politics). John J. Coleman of the
relationship between soft money and trust in University of Wisconsin and Paul F. Manna
the federal government. In order words, of the College of William and Mary looked
growth in soft money spending tends to be closely at the effects of spending on public
moderately associated with growth in trust.7 trust in the 1994 and 1996 elections, taking
Other public opinion data support a simi- all relevant factors into account.13 They con-
lar conclusion. For example, the number of cluded, “Spending by incumbents and chal-
Americans who agree with the statement lengers seems to have little substantive
“People don’t have a say in what the govern- impact on trust and efficacy.”14
ment does” dropped like a stone during the Some recent research on state campaign
period when soft money fundraising rose finance law points to the same conclusion.
rapidly. By 2002 the number agreeing with the State campaign finance laws vary a great deal:
statement was near its all-time low.8 The same some have contribution limits, some had
can be said of the number of people who spending limits prior to 1976, others offer
believed that public officials don’t care what public financing, and many require disclosure
people think or who answered “not much” of contributions. Since the state laws vary, sta-
when asked “how much does the government tistical analysis can determine the effects of
listen to the people?”9 Public belief in the various campaign finance regulations on pub-
responsiveness of the government appears to lic trust in government and voter turnout.
have risen during a period of increased cam- David Primo and Jeffrey Milyo have studied
paign spending and soft money fundraising. the effects of state campaign finance laws on
Step back again from the trust data. When public trust in government. Their study
did trust in government go up? In 1980 and includes a comprehensive collection of state
1994. What happened in those two years? laws as well as 50 years of surveys concerning
Outsiders promising limits on government public trust in government. They conclude:
and lower taxes won the presidency and the “The results suggest that there may be some
Congress. Overall, increases in trust are modest improvement in efficacy from disclo-
strongly associated with declines in the federal sure laws, and perhaps even [from] limits on
government’s share of the nation’s wealth.10 contributions from organizations; however,
Moreover, both years saw victories by the evidence showing a perverse effect of pub-
Republicans, the party that traditionally raises lic financing is at least as strong. Finally, there Campaign
and spends more money on elections. If cam- is no evidence that either mandatory expendi-
paign spending causes distrust in government, ture limits or limits on individual contribu-
spending has
why has trust in government gone up only tions have an appreciable impact on efficacy.” little influence on
when the political party associated with rais- The perverse effect of public financing is the public trust or
ing and spending a lot of money on cam- most surprising of these findings: public
paigns has won watershed elections? Could it financing of elections “has a statistically sig- efficacy.

5
Other factors nificant negative effect on efficacy.”15 Other ment. The asserted line of causality from
affect public research by Milyo and Primo concerns the campaign finance to distrust of government
relationship between campaign finance laws does not exist. Given that, campaign finance
confidence in and voter turnout. If the critics were correct, cannot cause declines in voter turnout.
government far we would expect that contribution or spend-
ing limits or public financing would have pos-
more than itive and significant effects on turnout in Negative Ads
campaign states that adopt such restrictions. After all,
finance. such laws would presumably blunt the influ- For intellectuals, television runs a close
ence of private campaign contributions and second to campaign contributions as the
thereby increase trust in government and fos- pathogen plaguing American democracy.
ter higher turnout. Recent research examining Analysts note that most campaign spending
turnout for every gubernatorial election in the goes to television ads and that campaigns
United States from 1950 to 2000 found that have “turned increasingly hostile and ugly.”
none of those restrictions had any effect on Attack ads, the argument continues, have
voter turnout. Disclosure appears to increase “become the norm rather than the excep-
turnout by about 2 percent.16 tion.”18 Aesthetics aside, critics have tried to
Other factors affect public confidence in link such advertising to declining turnout.
government far more than campaign finance. Others claim that private financing of cam-
Nathaniel Persily and Kelli Lammie have paigns fosters negative ads and that limits on
recently examined the factors affecting public spending would improve the tone of public
confidence in government. According to the discourse.19
appearances argument, Persily and Lammie What is a “negative ad”? The term is rarely
should have found that some feature of the defined explicitly. Critics use the term to
campaign finance system, taking all other fac- mean any advertising that attacks or is critical
tors into account, causes a decline in public of an opponent. “Negative campaigning
confidence in government. They found focuses on the weaknesses and faults of the
instead that Americans’ “confidence in the sys- opposition: the mistakes they have made, the
tem of representative government”—specifi- flaws in their character or performance, the
cally, their beliefs that government officials are bad policies they would pursue.” As two
not “crooked” and that government is “run for experts remark, “Negative campaigning is not
the benefit of all”—are associated with their lying and stealing and cheating, it is criticiz-
positions in society, their general tendency to ing the opponent.” Positive campaigning, in
trust others, their beliefs about what govern- contrast, emphasizes the merits of a candi-
ment should do, and their ideological or date and the beneficial policies he would pur-
philosophical disagreement with the policies sue.20 Looked at this way, negative advertising
of incumbent officeholders. For Persily and provides valuable information to the elec-
Lammie, their regressions indicate that torate. Some people believe negative advertis-
“trends in general attitudes of corruption ing harms democracy by driving down voter
seem unrelated to anything happening in the turnout. Are they correct?
campaign finance system (i.e., a rise in contri-
butions or the introduction of a particular The Effects of Negative Ads on
reform).”17 Other factors, not campaign Democracy
finance, seem to cause declines in public con- General Data. Given that voter turnout
fidence in government. dropped in the early 1970s, we would expect
The evidence shows that spending has no campaigns to have turned negative at that
effect on public trust. Indeed, multivariate time and remained so. Steven E. Finkel of
analysis suggests that other factors account the University of Virginia and John G. Geer
for changes in public confidence in govern- of Vanderbilt University examined most tele-

6
vised presidential ads since 1960 and rated Their experiment exposed a treatment and a
each as positive or negative. In fact, advertis- control group to negative ads. The results indi-
ing during presidential campaigns became cated that negative ads drove down turnout by
progressively more positive from 1964 to 5 percent. They followed the experiments by
1976, the latter year being the most positive looking at the effects of negative campaigns on
in tone of any campaign from 1964 to turnout in the actual 1990 Senate contests.
1992.21 The year turnout collapsed, 1972, fell The scholars again found that negative cam-
during the time of a rising tone of presiden- paigns reduced turnout by 4 percent.22 They
tial campaigning. While the tone of presi- concluded that negative campaigning drives
dential campaigning declined after 1976, down turnout by making “voters disenchanted
turnout has remained essentially flat. In fact, with the business of politics as usual” and by
the 1992 election featured both the best lowering “confidence in the responsiveness of
voter turnout after 1970 and the worst tone electoral institutions and public officials.”23
of all the years measured. Put another way, They argued that negative ads would especially
the sharpest decline ever recorded in the reduce participation by political independents
tone of presidential campaigns is associated whose disgust with the tone of campaigns
with the largest rise in voter turnout in the would drive them away from the voting booth
30-year period studied. Negative campaign- in disproportionate numbers. Following up on
Negative ads
ing does not correlate negatively with that conjecture, the same authors conducted are positively
turnout by eligible voters. In fact, the data experiments in the 1992 presidential elections associated with a
suggest the opposite conclusion, especially that indicated that negative advertising led to
in the 1992 election: negative ads are posi- an 11 percent decline in intention to vote rise in turnout.
tively associated with a rise in turnout. among political independents.24
Experimental Evidence. About a decade ago, Those studies have at least three problems.
a team of scholars (hereafter the Ansolabehere First, the experiments did not use actual cam-
group) conducted experiments that seemed to paign advertisements. Second, the larger sta-
indicate that attack ads drive down turnout. tistical study of the Senate campaigns mea-

Figure 44
Figure
Voter T
Voter urnout aand
Turnout nd CCampaign
ampaign ToTone,
ne, 191960–92
60–92

70
63.8 62.8 61.5 60.6
60 56.2 57.2
56.3 54.9
Tone and Turnout (%)

54.7 54.2
50
Voter Turnout
40
36.3 Positive Ads
30
28.5
24.3 23
20
18.9 14.6
10 12

0 0.8
1960 1964 1968 1972 1976 1980 1984 1988 1992
Year

Source: Steven E. Finkel and John G. Geer, “A Spot Check: Casting Doubt on the Demobilizing Effect of Attack
Advertising,” American Journal of Political Science 42 (April 1998): 582, Figure 1.

7
sured “negativity” by press reports on the tone no harm to democracy and may well increase
of a campaign. If the press reported campaigns turnout.30
as more negative than they were, the Finkel and Geer studied closely most of
researchers’ conclusions would be off target. the presidential campaign ads that had run
Finally, and most important, their findings in the United States since 1960. They decided
have not been replicated in subsequent stud- whether each ad was positive or negative and
ies. Indeed, other scholars have found that constructed an index that measured the over-
negative ads improve democracy in theory and all proportion of ads that was positive. Finkel
practice. and Geer then looked at the relationship
Specific Studies. A moment’s reflection sug- between the tone of the presidential cam-
gests several reasons why negative ads would paign ads and turnout (including the partic-
boost turnout. Negative ads contain relevant ipation of political independents), control-
information for a voter, and scholars have ling for many other factors that are known to
long known that more knowledgeable voters affect turnout. Their findings are striking:
are more likely to participate. Negative infor-
mation helps voters discriminate between can- • Advertising tone has essentially no
didates and thereby gives them a reason to go effect on turnout of the electorate, once
to the polls. Finally, negative messages may other factors are taken into account.
stir up voters, creating more enthusiasm and • Campaigns with more negative adver-
involvement in an election and, perhaps, a tisements have a slightly higher rate of
desire to learn more about the candidates.25 As turnout among independents than
two scholars point out, “Criticism of an oppo- more positive campaigns, again taking
nent—particularly strong criticism—sends a other factors into account.31
message that something of substance is at
stake in the election, that its outcome matters, Finkel and Geer conclude “that exposure
and that this is a choice voters should care to negative campaign advertisements has no
about.”26 demobilizing effect among the general pub-
Tough critical electoral advertising does lic or among Independents.”32
fall short of the norms of the seminar room, Other researchers have tried to estimate the
but those norms are unrealistic for a nation in effects of being exposed to political ads. Paul
which most people do not care much about Freedman and Kenneth Goldstein examined
participating in politics.27 Voting involves the advertising in the 1997 Virginia guberna-
costs and benefits to citizens. In the United torial election. They not only evaluated the
States many people appear to believe that the tone of the commercials but also closely
costs outweigh the benefits. More citizens tracked when and where campaign ads
might vote if the costs of voting were lower. appeared. Their effort marks the most precise
One major cost is gaining information about measure we have of voters’ exposure to politi-
the candidates and issues at stake in an elec- cal advertising. Once again taking account of
tion. Negative ads provide relevant, critical other factors that might affect turnout, they
information in a brief, easily grasped format. found that negative advertising strongly
Several studies Far from being pathological, the brevity and increased turnout. Strikingly, ads that con-
have found that tone of electoral ads lower the costs of voting. veyed a positive or more mixed message
critical ads at The conjecture that negative ads stimu- seemed to lower turnout. Freedman and
late turnout at the polls has become the Goldstein conclude that “it is primarily the
least do no harm “emerging conventional wisdom” among negative spots that have a mobilizing effect on
to democracy and scholars studying the question.28 Scholars voters.”33
have not been able to show that negative ads Critics of negative ads might object that
may well increase reduce turnout.29 At the same time, several those two studies are not representative of what
turnout. studies have found that critical ads at least do we “know” about negative ads. Fortunately, two

8
political scientists have considered all studies of about their sponsor and negative claims about Negative
negative ads up to 1999 to provide some gener- his opponent). They also obtained data about advertising does
al conclusions. They performed a “meta analy- when and where the ads ran and the television
sis” of 117 findings about negative ads drawn viewing habits of individuals in various parts not harm
from 52 separate studies. Their work addressed of the country. American
three questions: “Do citizens dislike negative They found that positive ads have no effect
ads? Are negative ads more effective than posi- on turnout but “negative ads have a signifi-
democracy or its
tive ads? Does negative advertising reduce elec- cant and substantial mobilizing effect.” The political culture.
toral participation?” Their statistical analysis of increases in turnout brought by negative ads
the research literature found more than offset the decreases caused by the
overall volume of ads. More concretely,
• no reliable statistical basis for conclud- Goldstein and Freedman looked at the pro-
ing that negative ads are liked less than gressive effects of negative ads on the likeli-
positive ones, hood that an “average voter” would go to the
• no evidence that negative political polls.35 Table 1 summarizes their results.
advertisements are any more effective Overall, exposing the average voter to
than positive political ads, and heavy doses of negative ads would, all things
• little evidence that widespread use of considered, increase his likelihood of voting
negative ads imperils electoral participa- by over 10 percent. Lighter doses, an “aver-
tion. age” exposure for example, increase the prob-
ability of voting by 3 percent.36
The authors conclude that “participatory The most recent contribution to the
democracy may be on the wane in the United scholarly literature on the effects of negative
States, but the evidence reviewed here sug- campaign advertising confirms earlier find-
gests that negative political advertising has ings. Joshua Clinton and John Lapinski con-
relatively little to do with it.”34 structed a large controlled and randomized
More recently, two political scientists, experiment to discern the immediate and
Kenneth Goldstein and Paul Freedman, have long-term effects of ads on voting. The
studied negative ads by using a commercial researchers found that “it is never the case
database that identifies where and how often a that exposure to negative advertising decreas-
campaign commercial appears. Their research es either the reported probability of voting or
assistant then coded each ad in the 1996 pres- the actual voting.” They also report “no evi-
idential race as positive, purely negative, or dence” that political independents are most
contrast (ads that have positive information susceptible to negative ads. Contrary to earli-

TTable
able 11
NNegative Ads
egative Ads aand
nd TTurnout
urnout

Effect of
Effect of Negative
Negative Ads
Ads
Exposure to
Exposure to Negative
Negative Ads
Ads Probability of
Probability of Voting
Voting on Turnout
on Turnout (percent)
(percent)

None
None 0.761
0.761
Average
Average 0.789
0.789 2.8
2.8
One standard
One standard deviation
deviation above
above average
average 0.833
0.833 4.4
4.4
Two standard
Two standard deviations
deviations above
above average
average 0.869
0.869 3.6
3.6

Source: Ken
Source: Ken Goldstein
Goldstein and
and Paul
Paul Freedman,
Freedman, “Campaign
“Campaign Advertising
Advertising and
and Voter
Voter Turnout:
Turnout: New
New Evidence
Evidence for
for
aa Stimulation
Stimulation Effect,”
Effect,” Journal
Journalof
ofPolitics
Politics64,
64,no.
no.33(August
(August2002):
2002):721–40.
721–40.

9
er studies, Clinton and Lapinski found only Those who already hold office begin their
limited evidence that negative advertising reelection campaigns with enormous advan-
stimulates voting.37 tages in name recognition and resources (staff
Summary. Social scientists have become work, campaign money, and so on).
increasingly skillful and sophisticated at Incumbents also benefit from the value voters
measuring the effects of advertising on citi- put on experience.40 Incumbents do not lose
zens. Their conclusions about negative ads unless challengers find some way to become
are clear. Negative advertising does not harm known in a district and to call into question
American democracy or its political culture. the incumbent’s record. Challengers may use
If negative ads did not exist, fewer people positive ads to make their names more recog-
might well turn out to vote. If higher turnout nized by voters, but calling the incumbent into
is better for democracy than lower turnout, question requires criticism that is sharp and
negative ads may make a valuable contribu- memorable: “Challengers certainly hope to
tion to American democracy. convince people of their own virtues . . . but
they are not likely to get far without directly
Constitutional Considerations undermining support for the incumbent.”
If negative ads did lower turnout, what Not surprisingly, researchers found that 18
Any government could government do? Some people argue percent of voters could name something they
regulation of that Americans should consider the tradeoff disliked about an incumbent who won reelec-
negative ads between free expression and voter turnout, tion; in contrast, in districts where incum-
suggesting that government regulation of bents lost, 46 percent of voters could name a
would involve ads may be warranted.38 Americans may want reason to dislike the officeholder.41
controlling the to consider the tradeoff, but any government A more recent study of Senate elections
regulation of negative ads would involve con- makes a similar point. Richard Lau and Gerald
content of speech, trolling the content of speech, which the Pomper looked at U.S. Senate races from 1988
which the First First Amendment forbids. to 1998 to see who used negative appeals to
Amendment Even if we bracketed the constitutional voters. Taking all things in account, they
questions, some research suggests that found that challengers in general, candidates
forbids. boosting turnout through ad regulation in open seat races, Republican candidates, can-
would require distinguishing “useful nega- didates with less money than their opponents,
tive information” (which boosts turnout) and candidates facing negative campaigns
from “shrill mudslinging” (which discour- were more likely than everyone else to use neg-
ages voting).39 Should government be given ative appeals.42 Lau and Pomper’s conclusions
the power to distinguish good and bad nega- suggest that negative ads are a tool for candi-
tive ads? Wouldn’t “mudslinging ads” simply dates facing an uphill battle, candidates likely
be defined as ads that effectively criticize the to lose unless something changes. Challengers
individuals or groups who have the power to and candidates with less money (often the
regulate campaign advertising? That likely same persons) obviously need some weapon to
outcome highlights the wisdom of the fight their battles. Negative ads are that
phrase “Congress shall make no law” in the weapon.
First Amendment. If negative ads were a pub-
lic problem—and the evidence says they are
not—the best policy response would be criti- Conclusion
cism and shame, coupled with vigorous
media reporting and evaluation of campaign Many things are taken for granted in
advertising. American politics—and none more than the
Limits on negative ads would also make belief that voter turnout has steadily
American elections less competitive. Any lim- decreased over the past 30 years largely as a
its on attack ads inevitably favor incumbents. result of a noxious combination of big

10
money and negative ads. Voter turnout is 10. Since 1964 the correlation between trust in
government and federal spending as a percentage
lower than it was in the 1960s, but almost all of GDP is .61. This is an intriguing though not
the decline came between 1968 and 1974. definitive result. Other factors may have affected
General data as well as careful studies of the the trust measure over that time.
causes of voter turnout indicate that neither
11. A similar argument about soft money can be
campaign finance nor negative advertising found in Nathaniel Persily and Kelli Lammie,
has alienated voters and kept them away “Perceptions of Corruption and Campaign
from the polls. No justification exists for lim- Finance: When Public Opinion Constitutes
iting the rights of citizens to donate to cam- Constitutional Law,” University of Pennsylvania Law
Review 153 (forthcoming December 2004). See also
paigns or fund political advertising as a way Figure 2 therein, which indicates the relevant
to promote voter turnout. trends in soft money and public opinion.

12. The actual number is .013. David Primo reports


a similar finding; see David Primo, “Public
Notes Opinion and Campaign Finance: A Skeptical Look
1. Curtis Gans, “Table for One, Please: America’s at Senator McCain’s Claims,” Cato Institute
Disintegrating Democracy,” Washington Monthly, Briefing Paper no. 60, January 31, 2001.
July–August 2000.
13. Coleman and Manna’s methods, data, and
2. Jacobus v. State of Alaska, 338 F.3d. 1107 (2003). variables are discussed in John J. Coleman and
Paul F. Manna, “Congressional Campaign
3. See Scott Harshbarger, Testimony to the Rules Spending and the Quality of Democracy,” Journal
Committee, U.S. Senate, April 5, 2000, http://www. of Politics 62, no. 3 (2000): 763–65.
commoncause.org/publications/april00/0405test.
htm. 14. See ibid., p. 766. That conclusion reflects the
minuscule coefficients for candidate spending
4. The NES has asked other questions related to reported in Table 1 in ibid, p. 767.
trust in government. For example, since 1964 it has
asked, “Would you say the government is pretty 15. David M. Primo and Jeffrey Milyo, “Campaign
much run by a few big interests looking out for Finance and Political Efficacy: Evidence from the
themselves or that it is run for the benefit of all the States,” Paper presented at the 2003 Annual
people?” Responses to this question have a 98 per- Meeting of the American Political Science
cent correlation with responses to the general trust Association, Philadelphia, August 2003.
question noted in the text. The two questions clear-
ly tap into the same set of attitudes and may be 16. See David Primo and Jeffrey Milyo, “State
treated for present purposes as identical. Campaign Finance Laws and the Turnout
Decision,” Harris School Working Paper Series
5. Anthony Corrado, “Party Soft Money,” in 04.10, March 2004. The authors’ analysis controls
Campaign Finance Reform: A Sourcebook, ed. Anthony for several factors that typically affect turnout.
Corrado et al. (Washington: Brookings Institution They did find that poll taxes, when legal,
Press, 1997), pp. 171–72. depressed turnout by about 13 percent. The find-
ings of this study are preliminary. The authors
6. Michael Kelly, “Soft Money, No Crime?” plan to deal with concerns about endogeneity
Washington Post, November 27, 1997, p. A29. (states with low turnout may pass campaign
finance laws to bring voters to the polls) in a
7. The correlation coefficient is +.37. I focus on future study.
presidential election years to produce comparable
data. Soft money spending in off-year elections 17. Persily and Lammie.
was much lower than in presidential years so it is
necessary to control for the presidential race. 18. Stephen Ansolabehere et al., “Does Attack
Advertising Demobilize the Electorate?” American
8. National Election Studies, Center for Political Political Science Review 88 (December 1994): 829.
Studies, University of Michigan, The NES Guide to
Public Opinion and Electoral Behavior, 1995–2000, 19. Ronald Dworkin, “The Curse of American
Table 5B.2, http://www.umich.edu/~nes/nesguide Politics,” New York Review of Books, October 17,
/nesguide.htm. 1996, pp. 19–24.

9. Ibid., Tables 5B.3 and 5C.1. 20. William G. Mayer, “In Defense of Negative

11
Campaigning,” Political Science Quarterly 111, no. 3 sis.” Martin Wattenberg and Craig Brians conclud-
(1996): 440–41. See also Richard Lau and Gerald ed that “in 1992, recollection of negative campaign
Pomper, “Negative Campaigning by US Senate ads was actually associated with significantly high-
Candidates,” Party Politics 7 (January 2001): 81. er turnout, and in 1996, there was no significant
relationship.” Martin P. Wattenberg and Craig
21. Steven E. Finkel and John G. Geer, “A Spot Leonard Brians, “Negative Campaign Advertising:
Check: Casting Doubt on the Demobilizing Demobilizer or Mobilizer?” American Political
Effect of Attack Advertising,” American Journal of Science Review 93 (December 1999): 892. Critics
Political Science 42 (April 1998): 582, Figure 1. Lau have noted that this conclusion depends on voter
and Pomper found no systematic trend in the use recall of ads, which is subject to distortion and
of negative ads in their study of Senate races from error. Stephen D. Ansolabehere, Shanto Iyengar,
1988 to 1998; see Lau and Pomper, p. 77. and Adam Simon, “Replicating Experiments Using
Aggregate and Survey Data: The Case of Negative
22. Stephen Ansolabehere and Shanto Iyengar, Advertising and Turnout,” American Political Science
Going Negative: How Political Advertisements Shrink Review 93, no. 4 (December 1999): 901–9.
and Polarize the Electorate (New York: Free Press,
1995), p. 833. 31. Finkel and Geer, pp. 584–86.

23. Ibid., p. 835. 32. Ibid., p. 587. Finkel and Geer’s study has some
limitations. They have a lot of data on the tone of
24. Ibid., p. 111. campaign ads. They do not know, however, how
often and where the ads were shown. In their
25. Finkel and Geer, p. 577. index, however, each ad has equal weight and
equal exposure.
26. Paul Freedman and Ken Goldstein,
“Measuring Media Exposure and the Effects of 33. A change of one standard deviation in expo-
Negative Campaign Ads,” American Journal of sure to negative ads resulted in an increase of
Political Science 43 (October 1999): 1190. three points in the probability of turnout.
Freedman and Goldstein, pp. 1198–2000.
27. John R. Hibbing and Elizabeth Theiss-Morse,
Stealth Democracy: American’s Beliefs about How 34. Richard Lau et al., “The Effects of Negative
Government Should Work (New York: Cambridge Political Advertisements: A Meta-Analytic Assess-
University Press, 2002). ment,” American Political Science Review 93 (December
1999): 856–58. “Meta-analysis refers to the analysis
28. Ken Goldstein and Paul Freedman, “Campaign of analyses . . . the statistical analysis of a large col-
Advertising and Voter Turnout: New Evidence for lection of analysis results from individual studies for
a Stimulation Effect,” Journal of Politics 64 (August the purpose of integrating the findings.” Gene V.
2002): 722. Glass, “Primary, Secondary, and Meta-analysis of
Research,” Educational Researcher 5 (1976): 3.
29. Some work has found a generally positive
though nuanced effect of negative advertising. One 35. Goldstein and Freedman, pp. 721–40.
study of U.S. Senate campaigns concluded that
people distinguish between relevant negative infor- 36. Ibid., p. 735.
mation presented in an appropriate manner and
irrelevant, shrill, and pejorative ads. Ads seen as 37. Joshua D. Clinton and John S. Lapinski,
legitimate criticism draw people into the voting “‘Targeted’ Advertising and Voter Turnout: An
booth. In contrast, “harsh and irrelevant” negative Experimental Study of the 2000 Presidential
messages seem to discourage voting. The study Election,” Journal of Politics 66 (February 2004): 92.
also found that “mudslinging”—providing harsh
and irrelevant information—discouraged turnout 38. Ansolabehere and Iyengar, p. 836.
more among political independents, people with
little interest in politics, and political novices. See 39. Kahn and Kenney, p. 887.
Kim Fridkin Kahn and Patrick J. Kenney, “Do
Negative Campaigns Mobilize or Suppress 40. Mayer, p. 451, n. 29.
Turnout? Clarifying the Relationship between
Negativity and Participation,” American Political 41. Ibid., p. 451, quoting research by Gary
Science Review 93 (December 1999): 877–89. Jacobson on the 1980 and 1982 elections.

30. Other studies support the “mobilization the- 42. Lau and Pomper, p. 79.

Published by the Cato Institute, Policy Analysis is a regular Additional copies of Policy Analysis are $6.00 each ($3.00
series evaluating government policies and offering proposals each for five or more). To order, or for a complete listing of
for reform. Nothing in Policy Analysis should be construed as available studies, write the Cato Institute, 1000 Massachusetts
necessarily reflecting the views of the Cato Institute or as an Ave., N.W.,12Washington, D.C. 20001 or call toll
attempt to aid or hinder the passage of any bill before Con- free 1-800-767-1241 (8:30 a.m.-4:30 p.m. eastern
gress. Contact the Cato Institute for reprint permission. time). Fax (202) 842-3490 • www.cato.org

Potrebbero piacerti anche