Sei sulla pagina 1di 13

Lagrange multiplier

Lagrange multiplier

1

In mathematical optimization, the method of Lagrange multipliers (named after Joseph Louis Lagrange) is a strategy for finding the local maxima and minima of a function subject to equality constraints.

For instance (see Figure 1), consider the optimization problem

maximize

see Figure 1), consider the optimization problem maximize subject to We need both and to have

subject to

We need both and to have continuous

first partial derivatives. We introduce a new variable ( ) called a Lagrange multiplier and study the Lagrange function (or Lagrangian) defined by

and study the Lagrange function (or Lagrangian) defined by where the subtracted. If term may be
where the subtracted. If term may be either added or is a maximum of for
where the
subtracted. If
term may be either added or
is a maximum of
for
the
original
constrained
problem,
then
there
exists
such
that
is a stationary point for the

Lagrange function (stationary points are those points where the partial derivatives of

points are those points where the partial derivatives of are zero, i.e. ). However, not all

are zero, i.e.

those points where the partial derivatives of are zero, i.e. ). However, not all stationary points

). However, not

all stationary points yield a solution of the original problem. Thus, the method of Lagrange multipliers yields a necessary condition for optimality in constrained problems. [1][2][3][4][5] Sufficient conditions for a minimum or maximum also exist.

Introduction

conditions for a minimum or maximum also exist. Introduction Figure 1: Find x and y to

Figure 1: Find x and y to maximize

red)

.
.

subject to a constraint (shown in

and y to maximize red) . subject to a constraint (shown in Figure 2: Contour map

Figure 2: Contour map of Figure 1. The red line shows the constraint

Contour map of Figure 1. The red line shows the constraint . The blue lines are

. The blue lines are contours of

line shows the constraint . The blue lines are contours of . The point where the

. The point where the

, the

red line tangentially touches a blue contour is our solution.Since

solution is a maximization of

One of the most common problems in calculus is that of finding maxima or minima (in general, "extrema") of a function, but it is often difficult to find a closed form for the function being extremized. Such difficulties often arise when one wishes to maximize or minimize a function subject to fixed outside conditions or constraints. The method of Lagrange multipliers is a powerful tool for solving this class of problems without the need to explicitly solve the conditions and use them to eliminate extra variables.

Consider the two-dimensional problem introduced above:

maximize

subject to

Consider the two-dimensional problem introduced above: maximize subject to We can visualize contour s of f

We can visualize contours of f given by

Consider the two-dimensional problem introduced above: maximize subject to We can visualize contour s of f

Lagrange multiplier

2

Lagrange multiplier 2 for various values of , and the contour of given by . Suppose

for various values of , and the contour of given by

.
.

Suppose we walk along the contour line with . In general the contour lines of and may be distinct, so

. In general the contour lines of and may be distinct, so following the contour line
. In general the contour lines of and may be distinct, so following the contour line

following the contour line for one could intersect with or cross the contour lines of . This is equivalent to

saying that while moving along the contour line for the value of can vary. Only when the contour line for

meets contour lines offor the value of can vary. Only when the contour line for contour lines touch but

contour lines touch but do not cross. The contour lines of f and g touch when the tangent vectors of the contour lines are parallel. Since the gradient of a

function is perpendicular to the contour lines, this is the same as saying that the gradients of f and g are parallel. Thus

saying that the gradients of f and g are parallel. Thus tangentially , do we not
saying that the gradients of f and g are parallel. Thus tangentially , do we not
saying that the gradients of f and g are parallel. Thus tangentially , do we not

tangentially, do we not increase or decrease the value of

tangentially , do we not increase or decrease the value of — that is, when the

that is, when the

we want points

where ,
where
,

and

where

of — that is, when the we want points where , and where and are the

and

— that is, when the we want points where , and where and are the respective
— that is, when the we want points where , and where and are the respective

are the respective gradients. The constant is required because although the two gradient vectors are parallel, the

magnitudes of the gradient vectors are generally not equal.

To incorporate these conditions into one equation, we introduce an auxiliary function

into one equation, we introduce an auxiliary function and solve This is the method of Lagrange

and solve

one equation, we introduce an auxiliary function and solve This is the method of Lagrange multipliers.
one equation, we introduce an auxiliary function and solve This is the method of Lagrange multipliers.
one equation, we introduce an auxiliary function and solve This is the method of Lagrange multipliers.

This is the method of Lagrange multipliers. Note that implies .

is the method of Lagrange multipliers. Note that implies . The constrained extrema of are critical

The constrained extrema of are critical points of the Lagrangian , but they are not necessarily local extrema of

(see Examp le 2 below). ple 2 below).

One may reformulate the Lagrangian as a Hamiltonian, in which case the solutions are local minima for the Hamiltonian. This is done in optimal control theory, in the form of Pontryagin's minimum principle.

The fact that solutions of the Lagrangian are not necessarily extrema also poses difficulties for numerical optimization. This can be addressed by computing the magnitude of the gradient, as the zeros of the magnitude are necessarily local minima, as illustrated in the numerical optimization example.

Lagrange multiplier

3

Handling multiple constraints

The method of Lagrange multipliers can also accommodate multiple constraints. To see how this is done, we need to reexamine the problem in a slightly different manner because the concept of crossingdiscussed above becomes rapidly unclear when we consider the types of constraints that are created when we have more than one constraint acting together.

As an example, consider a paraboloid with a constraint that is a single point (as might be created if we had 2 line constraints that intersect). Even though the level set (i.e., contour line) seems to be crossingthat point and its gradient doesn't seem to be parallel to the gradients of either of the two line constraints, in fact, the relation between that point and the contour lines are similar to relation of a line tangent to a sphere in 3D space. So the point still can be considered "tangent" to the level contours. And the point is obviously a maximum and a minimum because there is only one point on the paraboloid that meets the constraint.

While this example seems a bit odd, it is easy to understand and is representative of the sort of effectiveconstraint that appears quite often when we deal with multiple constraints intersecting. Thus, we take a slightly different approach below to explain and derive the Lagrange Multipliers method with any number of constraints.

Throughout

variables

this

will

section,

be

the

independent

by

denoted

and, as a group, we will denote them as .
and, as a group, we will
denote them as
.

Also, the function being analyzed will be

denoted by

equations

be

the function being analyzed will be denoted by equations be and the constraints will by the

and the constraints will

by

the

represented

by equations be and the constraints will by the represented A paraboloid, some of its level
by equations be and the constraints will by the represented A paraboloid, some of its level

A paraboloid, some of its level sets (aka contour lines) and 2 line constraints.

its level sets (aka contour lines) and 2 line constraints. Zooming in on the levels sets

Zooming in on the levels sets and constraints, we see that the two constraint lines intersect to form a "joint" constraint that is a point. Since there is only one point to analyze, the corresponding point on the paraboloid is automatically a minimum and maximum. Even though the simplified reasoning presented in sections above seems to fail because the level set appears to "cross" the point and at the same time its gradient is not parallel to the gradients of either constraint, in fact, the relation between this point and the level contours are similar to relation of a line tangent to a sphere in 3D space. So the point still can be considered "tangent" to the level contours.

.

The basic idea remains essentially the same: if we consider only the points that satisfy the constraints (i.e. are in the

the points that satisfy the constraints (i.e. are in the constraints), then a point is a

constraints), then a point is a stationary point (i.e. a point in a flatregion) of f if and only if the

constraints at that point do not allow movement in a direction where f changes value.

Lagrange multiplier

4

Once we have located the stationary points, we need to do further tests to see if we have found a minimum, a maximum or just a stationary point that is neither.

a maximum or just a stationary point that is neither. We start by considering the level
a maximum or just a stationary point that is neither. We start by considering the level

We start by considering the level set of f at . The set of vectors containing the directions in which

we can move and still remain in the same level set are the directions where the value of f does not change (i.e. the change equals zero). Thus, for every vector v in , the following relation must hold:

for every vector v in , the following relation must hold: where the notation more compact
for every vector v in , the following relation must hold: where the notation more compact

where the notation

more compact geometric form that helps our intuition:

more compact geometric form that helps our intuition: above means the -component of the vector v

above means the

geometric form that helps our intuition: above means the -component of the vector v . The

-component of the vector v. The equation above can be rewritten in a

of the vector v . The equation above can be rewritten in a This makes it

This makes it clear that if we are at p, then all directions from this point that do not change the value of f must be perpendicular to (the gradient of f at p).

f must be perpendicular to (the gradient of f at p ). Now let us consider

Now let us consider the effect of the constraints. Each constraint limits the directions that we can move from a particular point and still satisfy the constraint. We can use the same procedure, to look for the set of vectors

containing the directions in which we can move and still satisfy the constraint. As above, for every vector v in , the following relation must hold:

for every vector v in , the following relation must hold: From this, we see that
for every vector v in , the following relation must hold: From this, we see that
for every vector v in , the following relation must hold: From this, we see that

From this, we see that at point p, all directions from this point that will still satisfy this constraint must be

perpendicular to

Now we are ready to refine our idea further and complete the method: a point on f is a constrained stationary point if and only if the direction that changes f violates at least one of the constraints. (We can see that this is true because if a direction that changes f did not violate any constraints, then there would be a legalpoint nearby with a higher or lower value for f and the current point would then not be a stationary point.)

.
.

Single constraint revisited

For a single constraint, we use the statement above to say that at stationary points the direction that changes f is in the same direction that violates the constraint. To determine if two vectors are in the same direction, we note that if two vectors start from the same point and are in the same direction, then one vector can always reachthe other by changing its length and/or flipping to point the opposite way along the same direction line. In this way, we can succinctly state that two vectors point in the same direction if and only if one of them can be multiplied by some real number such that they become equal to the other. So, for our purposes, we require that:

equal to the other. So, for our purposes, we require that: If we now add another

If we now add another simultaneous equation to guarantee that we only perform this test when we are at a point that satisfies the constraint, we end up with 2 simultaneous equations that when solved, identify all constrained stationary points:

the constraint, we end up with 2 simultaneous equations that when solved, identify all constrained stationary

Lagrange multiplier

5

Note that the above is a succinct way of writing the equations. Fully expanded, there are

way of writing the equations. Fully expanded, there are equations that need to be solved for

equations that need to be solved for the variables which are

equations that need to be solved for the variables which are and : Multiple constraints simultaneous

and

:
:
that need to be solved for the variables which are and : Multiple constraints simultaneous For

Multiple constraints

simultaneous

For more than one constraint, the same reasoning applies. If two or more constraints are active together, each constraint contributes a direction that will violate it. Together, these violation directionsform a violation space, where infinitesimal movement in any direction within the space will violate one or more constraints. Thus, to satisfy multiple constraints we can state (using this new terminology) that at the stationary points, the direction that changes f is in the violation spacecreated by the constraints acting jointly.

The violation space created by the constraints consists of all points that can be reached by adding any linear combination of violation direction vectorsin other words, all the points that are reachablewhen we use the

individual violation directions as the basis of the space. Thus, we can succinctly state that v is in the space defined by

we can succinctly state that v is in the space defined by if and only if

if and only if there exists a set of multipliers

by if and only if there exists a set of “ multipliers ” such that: which

such that:

if there exists a set of “ multipliers ” such that: which for our purposes, translates

which for our purposes, translates to stating that the direction that changes f at p is in the violation spacedefined by

the constraints

in the “ violation space ” defined by the constraints if and only if: As before,

if and only if:

space ” defined by the constraints if and only if: As before, we now add simultaneous

As before, we now add simultaneous equation to guarantee that we only perform this test when we are at a point that satisfies every constraint, we end up with simultaneous equations that when solved, identify all constrained stationary points:

when solved, identify all constrained stationary points: The method is complete now (from the standpoint of

The method is complete now (from the standpoint of solving the problem of finding stationary points) but as mathematicians delight in doing, these equations can be further condensed into an even more elegant and succinct form. Lagrange must have cleverly noticed that the equations above look like partial derivatives of some larger scalar function L that takes all the and all the as inputs. Next, he might then

takes all the and all the as inputs. Next, he might then have noticed that setting
takes all the and all the as inputs. Next, he might then have noticed that setting

have noticed that setting every equation equal to zero is exactly what one would have to do to solve for the unconstrained stationary points of that larger function. Finally, he showed that a larger function L with partial

Lagrange multiplier

6

derivatives that are exactly the ones we require can be constructed very simply as below:

the ones we require can be constructed very simply as below: Solving the equation above for

Solving the equation above for its unconstrained stationary points generates exactly the same stationary points as

solving for the constrained stationary points of f under the constraints

In Lagranges honor, the function above is called a Lagrangian, the scalars are called Lagrange

.
.

Multipliers and this optimization method itself is called The Method of Lagrange Multipliers. The method of Lagrange multipliers is generalized by the KarushKuhnTucker conditions, which can also take into account inequality constraints of the form h(x) c.

Interpretation of the Lagrange multipliers

Often the Lagrange multipliers have an interpretation as some quantity of interest. For example, if the Lagrangian expression is

of interest. For example, if the Lagrangian expression is then So , λ k is the

then

interest. For example, if the Lagrangian expression is then So , λ k is the rate

So, λ k is the rate of change of the quantity being optimized as a function of the constraint variable. As examples, in Lagrangian mechanics the equations of motion are derived by finding stationary points of the action, the time integral of the difference between kinetic and potential energy. Thus, the force on a particle due to a scalar potential, , can be interpreted as a Lagrange multiplier determining the change in action (transfer of potential to kinetic energy) following a variation in the particle's constrained trajectory. In control theory this is formulated instead as costate equations.

Moreover, by the envelope theorem the optimal value of a Lagrange multiplier has an interpretation as the marginal effect of the corresponding constraint constant upon the optimal attainable value of the original objective function: if we denote values at the optimum with an asterisk, then it can be shown that

at the optimum with an asterisk, then it can be shown that For example, in economics
at the optimum with an asterisk, then it can be shown that For example, in economics

For example, in economics the optimal profit to a player is calculated subject to a constrained space of actions, where a Lagrange multiplier is the change in the optimal value of the objective function (profit) due to the relaxation of a given constraint (e.g. through a change in income); in such a context is the marginal cost of the constraint, and is referred to as the shadow price.

change in income); in such a context is the marginal cost of the constraint, and is

Lagrange multiplier

7

Sufficient conditions

Sufficient conditions for a constrained local maximum or minimum can be stated in terms of a sequence of principal minors (determinants of upper-left-justified sub-matrices) of the bordered Hessian matrix of second derivatives of the Lagrangian expression. [6]

Examples

Example 1

Suppose

we

to

subject to the constraint

. The feasible set is the unit

wish

maximize

the constraint . The feasible set is the unit wish maximize circle, and the level set

circle, and the level sets of f are diagonal lines (with slope -1), so we can see graphically that the maximum occurs at , and that the minimum

. Using the method of Lagrange multipliers,

we have

hence

occurs at
occurs at
,
,
.
.

Setting

the

multipliers, we have hence occurs at , . Setting the of equations gradient yields the system

of equations

gradient yields the system

at , . Setting the of equations gradient yields the system Fig. 3. Illustration of the

Fig. 3. Illustration of the constrained optimization problem

Fig. 3. Illustration of the constrained optimization problem where the last equation is the original constraint.

where the last equation is the original constraint.

The first two equations yield and equation yields , so and thus the maximum is
The first two equations yield
and
equation yields
,
so
and
thus the maximum is
, which is attained at
.

, where

and thus the maximum is , which is attained at . , where . Substituting into

. Substituting into the last

, which implies that the stationary points are

. Evaluating the objective function f at these points yields

points are . Evaluating the objective function f at these points yields , and the minimum

, and the minimum is

, which is attained at

Lagrange multiplier

8

Example 2

Suppose we want to find the maximum values of

8 Example 2 Suppose we want to find the maximum values of y the origin with

y

the

origin with radius 3, that is, subject to the constraint

coordinates lie on the circle around

with the condition

that

the

x

and

lie on the circle around with the condition that the x and As there is just

As there is just a single constraint, we will use only one multiplier, say λ.

The constraint g(x, y)-3 is identically zero on the circle of radius 3. So any multiple of g(x, y)-3 may be added to f(x, y) leaving f(x, y) unchanged in the region of interest (above the circle where our original constraint is satisfied). Let

the circle where our original constraint is satisfied). Let Fig. 4. Illustration of the constrained optimization

Fig. 4. Illustration of the constrained optimization problem

Fig. 4. Illustration of the constrained optimization problem The critical values of occur where its gradient

The critical values of

occur where its gradient is zero. The partial derivatives are

where its gradient is zero. The partial derivatives are Equation (iii) is just the original constraint.

Equation (iii) is just the original constraint. Equation (i) implies

must have

we have that,

or λ = y. In the first case, if x = 0 then we

by (iii) and then by (ii) λ = 0. In the second case, if λ = y and substituting into equation (ii)

case, if λ = − y and substituting into equation (ii) Then x 2 = 2
case, if λ = − y and substituting into equation (ii) Then x 2 = 2
case, if λ = − y and substituting into equation (ii) Then x 2 = 2

Then x 2 = 2y 2 . Substituting into equation (iii) and solving for y gives this value of y:

equation (iii) and solving for y gives this value of y : Thus there are six

Thus there are six critical points:

gives this value of y : Thus there are six critical points: Evaluating the objective at

Evaluating the objective at these points, we find

points: Evaluating the objective at these points, we find Therefore, the objective function attains the global

Therefore, the objective function attains the global maximum (subject to the constraints) at

may be determined by consideration of the Hessian matrix of

be determined by consideration of the Hessian matrix of and the The point is a local

and the

by consideration of the Hessian matrix of and the The point is a local minimum and

The point

consideration of the Hessian matrix of and the The point is a local minimum and of

is a local minimum and

of

. , it is
.
,
it
is

not

the The point is a local minimum and of . , it is not local is

local

is a local maximum, as

extremum.

We

, we can choose a

have

Note that while is a critical small positive and a small of either sign to
Note that
while
is
a
critical
small positive
and a small
of either sign to get

point

a

. Given any neighborhood of

.
.

values both greater and less than

Lagrange multiplier

9

Example 3: entropy

Suppose we wish to find the discrete probability distribution on the points

information entropy. This is the same as saying that we wish to find the least biased probability distribution on the points . In other words, we wish to maximize the Shannon entropy equation:

words, we wish to maximize the Shannon entropy equation: with maximal For this to be a

with maximal

to maximize the Shannon entropy equation: with maximal For this to be a probability distribution the
to maximize the Shannon entropy equation: with maximal For this to be a probability distribution the

For this to be a probability distribution the sum of the probabilities

constraint is

distribution the sum of the probabilities constraint is = 1: at each point must equal 1,

= 1:

distribution the sum of the probabilities constraint is = 1: at each point must equal 1,

at each point

sum of the probabilities constraint is = 1: at each point must equal 1, so our

must equal 1, so our

constraint is = 1: at each point must equal 1, so our We use Lagrange multipliers

We use Lagrange multipliers to find the point of maximum entropy,

on
on

. We require that:

to find the point of maximum entropy, on . We require that: which gives a system

which gives a system of n equations,

on . We require that: which gives a system of n equations, , such that: ,

, such that:

that: which gives a system of n equations, , such that: , across all discrete probability

, across all discrete probability distributions

, such that: , across all discrete probability distributions Carrying out the differentiation of these n

Carrying out the differentiation of these n equations, we get

out the differentiation of these n equations, we get This shows that all are equal (because

This shows that all

of these n equations, we get This shows that all are equal (because they depend on
of these n equations, we get This shows that all are equal (because they depend on

are equal (because they depend on λ only). By using the constraint j p j = 1, we find

Hence, the uniform distribution is the distribution with the greatest entropy, among distributions on n points.

Lagrange multiplier

10

Example 4: numerical optimization

With Lagrange multipliers, the critical points occur at saddle points, rather than at local maxima (or minima). Unfortunately, many numerical optimization techniques, such as hill climbing, gradient descent, some of the quasi-Newton methods, among others, are designed to find local maxima (or minima) and not saddle points. For this reason, one must either modify the formulation to ensure that it's a minimization problem (for example, by extremizing the square of the gradient of the Lagrangian as below), or else use an optimization technique that finds stationary points (such as Newton's method without an extremum seeking line search) and not necessarily extrema.

seeking line search ) and not necessarily extrema. Lagrange multipliers cause the critical points to occur

Lagrange multipliers cause the critical points to occur at saddle points.

cause the critical points to occur at saddle points. The magnitude of the gradient can be

The magnitude of the gradient can be used to force the critical points to occur at

local minima.

As a simple example, consider the problem of finding the value of that minimizes

constrained

problem of finding the value of that minimizes constrained , . such is that (This problem
, .
,
.

such

is

that

(This

problem

somewhat

pathological because there are only two values that satisfy this constraint, but it is useful for illustration purposes because the corresponding unconstrained function can be visualized in three dimensions.)

Using Lagrange multipliers, this problem

can

optimization problem:

unconstrained

be

converted

into

an

can optimization problem: unconstrained be converted into an two critical points occur at and . The

two

critical

points

occur

at

be converted into an two critical points occur at and . The points where In order

and

.
.

The

points where

In order to solve this problem with a numerical optimization technique, we must first transform this problem such that the

critical points occur at local minima. This is done by computing the magnitude of the gradient of the unconstrained optimization problem.

First, we compute the partial derivative of the unconstrained problem with respect to each variable:

saddle

unconstrained problem with respect to each variable: saddle If the target function is not easily differentiable,
unconstrained problem with respect to each variable: saddle If the target function is not easily differentiable,

If the target function is not easily differentiable, the differential with respect to each variable can be approximated as

Lagrange multiplier

11

,
,
,
,

where is a small value.

Lagrange multiplier 1 1 , , where is a small value. Next, we compute the magnitude

Next, we compute the magnitude of the gradient, which is the square root of the sum of the squares of the partial derivatives:

root of the sum of the squares of the partial derivatives: (Since magnitude is always non-negative,

(Since magnitude is always non-negative, optimizing over the squared-magnitude is equivalent to optimizing over the magnitude. Thus, the ``square root" may be omitted from these equations with no expected difference in the results of optimization.)

The critical points of

critical points in

of optimization.) The critical points of critical points in occur at and , just as in

occur at

The critical points of critical points in occur at and , just as in . Unlike

and

The critical points of critical points in occur at and , just as in . Unlike

, just as in

points of critical points in occur at and , just as in . Unlike the critical

. Unlike the critical points in

in occur at and , just as in . Unlike the critical points in , however,

, however, the

occur at local minima, so numerical optimization techniques can be used to find them.

Applications

Economics

Constrained optimization plays a central role in economics. For example, the choice problem for a consumer is represented as one of maximizing a utility function subject to a budget constraint. The Lagrange multiplier has an economic interpretation as the shadow price associated with the constraint, in this example the marginal utility of income. Other examples include profit maximization for a firm, along with various macroeconomic applications.

Control theory

In optimal control theory, the Lagrange multipliers are interpreted as costate variables, and Lagrange multipliers are reformulated as the minimization of the Hamiltonian, in Pontryagin's minimum principle.

References

[1] Bertsekas, Dimitri P. (1999). Nonlinear Programming (Second ed.). Cambridge, MA.: Athena Scientific. ISBN 1-886529-00-0. [2] Vapnyarskii, I.B. (2001), "Lagrange multipliers" (http://www.encyclopediaofmath.org/index.php?title=Lagrange_multipliers), in Hazewinkel, Michiel, Encyclopedia of Mathematics, Springer, ISBN 978-1-55608-010-4, .

• Lasdon, Leon S. (1970). Optimization theory for large systems. Macmillan series in operations research. New York: The Macmillan Company. pp. xi+523. MR337317.

• Lasdon, Leon S. (2002). Optimization theory for large systems (reprint of the 1970 Macmillan ed.). Mineola, New York: Dover

Publications, Inc

pp. xiii+523. MR1888251.

[4] Hiriart-Urruty, Jean-Baptiste; Lemaréchal, Claude (1993). "XII Abstract duality for practitioners". Convex analysis and minimization algorithms, Volume II: Advanced theory and bundle methods. Grundlehren der Mathematischen Wissenschaften [Fundamental Principles of Mathematical Sciences]. 306. Berlin: Springer-Verlag. pp. 136193 (and Bibliographical comments on pp. 334335). ISBN 3-540-56852-2.

MR1295240.

[5] Lemaréchal, Claude (2001). "Lagrangian relaxation". In Michael Jünger and Denis Naddef. Computational combinatorial optimization:

Papers from the Spring School held in Schloß Dagstuhl, May 1519, 2000. Lecture Notes in Computer Science. 2241. Berlin:

Springer-Verlag. pp. 112156. doi:10.1007/3-540-45586-8_4. ISBN 3-540-42877-1. MR1900016. [6] Chiang, Alpha C., Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics, McGraw-Hill, third edition, 1984: p. 386.

Lagrange multiplier

12

External links

Exposition

• Conceptual introduction (http://www.slimy.com/~steuard/teaching/tutorials/Lagrange.html) (plus a brief discussion of Lagrange multipliers in the calculus of variations as used in physics)

• Lagrange Multipliers for Quadratic Forms With Linear Constraints (http://www.eece.ksu.edu/~bala/notes/ lagrange.pdf) by Kenneth H. Carpenter

For additional text and interactive applets

• Simple explanation with an example of governments using taxes as Lagrange multipliers (http://www.umiacs.

• Lagrange Multipliers without Permanent Scarring (http://nlp.cs.berkeley.edu/tutorials/lagrange-multipliers. pdf) Explanation with focus on the intuition by Dan Klein

• Video Lecture of Lagrange Multipliers (http://midnighttutor.com/Lagrange_multiplier.html)

• MIT Video Lecture on Lagrange Multipliers (http://www.academicearth.org/lectures/lagrange-multipliers)

• Slides accompanying Bertsekas's nonlinear optimization text (http://www.athenasc.com/NLP_Slides.pdf), with details on Lagrange multipliers (lectures 11 and 12)

• Method of Lagrange multipliers with complex variables (http://blog.daum.net/kipid/8307235) by kipid

Article Sources and Contributors

13

Article Sources and Contributors

Lagrange multiplier Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?oldid=540229950 Contributors: 00Ragora00, 2001:630:12:1061:8D:751C:4F05:77F1, 2001:690:2380:7770:418:A4DC:EE3A:9D71, 45Factoid44, AManWithNoPlan, Ahoerstemeier, Albmont, Andrebis, Andrewcanis, Anonymous Dissident, Arishth, AvicAWB, Bdmy, Beconomist, Ben pcc, BenFrantzDale, Bh3u4m, BiT, Btwied, CALR, CRGreathouse, Catslash, Charles Matthews, ChrisChiasson, Cvdwoest, Cyan, DavidFHoughton, Doranb, Dragonflare82, Dry.eats, Duoduoduo, Dvfinnh, Dysprosia, EconoPhysicist, Eichkaetzle, Enochlau, Falsifian, Favonian, Francis Tyers, Giftlite, Giladbr, Grubber, Hakeem.gadi, Hanspi, Hashproduct, Hdlh, Headbomb, Headlessplatter, Hess88, Hgkamath, Humble2000, Isheden, JRSpriggs, JaGa, Jacobmelgaard, Jitse Niesen, Jluttine, John Quiggin, Joseph Myers, Kartoffler, Kevmitch, Kiefer.Wolfowitz, Kramer, LOL, LachlanA, Larry R. Holmgren, Laughsinthestocks, Lethe, Loggie, Lost-n-translation, Lovibond, Lx008, M0nkey, MaSt, Markmathman, Marra, Mattrbunique, Mcld, Mct mht, Mebden, Megapapo, Michael Hardy, Michaelbusch, Mike409, MisterSheik, Mitus08, Mo-Al, Mohammad Al-Aggan, Momet, Natcase, Naught101, Nbarth, Nealeyoung, NeuronExMachina, Nexcis, Olawlor, Oleg Alexandrov, Paolo.dL, Patrick O'Leary, Paul Vernaza, PetaRZ, PlatypeanArchcow, Publichealthguru, Pz0, Qblik, Qiyangduan, Quang thai, Quidproquo2004, Rade Kutil, Rasinj, Ravster, Rbonvall, RexNL, Rhesusminus, Rjwilmsi, Robinh, Rodrigo braz, RogueNinja, Rumping, Sagi Harel, Sboehringer, Sd1074, Set theorist, Setsanto, Sfjohnsen, Shreevatsa, Simplifix, Smartech, Sploonie, Steuard, Sullivan.t.j, Sun Creator, Sverdrup, Sławomir Biały, Talgalili, Tcnuk, The Anome, Thehotelambush, Thenub314, Thr4wn, Tim Starling, Tomas e, Triathematician, Trifon Triantafillidis, Unbound, Urdutext, User A1, VKokielov, Vincent kraeutler, Wagnerjp25, Weijunhuang, Wtmitchell, Xxanthippe, Yinhao.ding, Zerodamage, Zvika, Zzdts, 261 anonymous edits

Image Sources, Licenses and Contributors

Image:LagrangeMultipliers3D.png Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=File:LagrangeMultipliers3D.png License: Public Domain Contributors: Nexcis

Image:LagrangeMultipliers2D.svg Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=File:LagrangeMultipliers2D.svg License: Public Domain Contributors: Nexcis

Image:As wiki lgm parab.svg Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=File:As_wiki_lgm_parab.svg License: Creative Commons Attribution-Sharealike 3.0 Contributors:

As_wiki_lgm_parab.png: Andrebis derivative work: Zerodamage

Image:As wiki lgm levelsets.svg Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=File:As_wiki_lgm_levelsets.svg License: Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 Contributors:

As_wiki_lgm_levelsets.png: Andrebis derivative work: Zerodamage

Image:Lagrange very simple.svg Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=File:Lagrange_very_simple.svg License: Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike 3.0 Unported Contributors: Lagrange_very_simple.jpg: User:Jacobmelgaard derivative work: Zerodamage

Image:Lagrange simple.svg Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=File:Lagrange_simple.svg License: Creative Commons Attribution-Sharealike 3.0 Contributors:

User:Jacobmelgaard, User:Zerodamage

Image:lagnum1.png Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=File:Lagnum1.png License: Public Domain Contributors: User:Headlessplatter

Image:lagnum2.png Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=File:Lagnum2.png License: Public Domain Contributors: User:Headlessplatter

License

Creative Commons Attribution-Share Alike 3.0 Unported

//creativecommons.org/licenses/by-sa/3.0/